university of new south wales school of economics...isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s...

63
University of New South Wales School of Economics Honours Thesis An Empirical Analysis of Disaggregated Australian Service Exports Author: William Weatherburn Student ID: 3379847 Supervisor: A/Prof Glenn Otto Dr. Pei-Cheng Yu Bachelor of Economics (Economics) (Honours) and Bachelor of Science (Psychology) 31 st October, 2017

Upload: others

Post on 21-Feb-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

University of New South Wales

School of Economics

Honours Thesis

An Empirical Analysis of Disaggregated Australian ServiceExports

Author:

William Weatherburn

Student ID: 3379847

Supervisor:

A/Prof Glenn Otto

Dr. Pei-Cheng Yu

Bachelor of Economics (Economics) (Honours)

and

Bachelor of Science (Psychology)

31st October, 2017

Page 2: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Declaration

I declare that this thesis is my own work and that, to the best of my knowledge, it

contains no material that has been published or written by another person except

where due acknowledgement has been made. This thesis has not been submitted for

award of any other degree or diploma at the University of New South Wales or at

any other educational institution.

.....................................

Bill Weatherburn

31st October, 2017

i

Page 3: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Acknowledgements

I will be ever grateful to Glenn Otto for your assistance in developing this thesis topic

and for the considerable help throughout the year. I am particularly appreciative

of the time taken to explain and interpret various econometric techniques. A big

thank you to P.C Yu for your thesis feedback, referee reports and the general day

to day hilarity of your one liners.

Thanks also to Tess Stafford for your extensive and considerate advice on all aspects

of the thesis development. However, I think it is my grammar that has most

improved from your teaching.

An immense thanks to my family and Jordan for supporting and encouraging me

throughout my entire time at university.

Finally, I would not have survived Honours, yet alone enjoyed my time, if it were

not for my fellow classmates. Thanks to Helena for her amazing social planning,

Beatrix for commiserating with me over Micro theory, Sarah for arvo tea times,

Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly

wasting away hours discussing East Africa, Barath for the inexorable dry jokes, Jun

for being Jun and Simon for the coffee breaks, the precision but mostly for the

insight into Sydney’s hipster scene.

ii

Page 4: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Contents

Declaration i

Acknowledgements ii

Table of Contents iii

Abstract vii

1 Introduction 1

2 Literature Review 4

2.1 Export Demand . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4

2.2 Service Exports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

2.3 Disaggregating Services . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8

2.4 Disaggregate Australian Services . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

3 Approach and Variables 11

3.1 Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11

3.1.1 Gravity Model Variables and Data Sources . . . . . . . . . . . 11

3.1.2 Time Series Variables and Data Sources . . . . . . . . . . . . 13

3.1.3 The Use of Nominal Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

4 The Gravity Model 16

4.1 The Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

5 Cointegration 21

5.1 Stationarity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

5.2 Test for Cointegration . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24

6 Autoregressive Distributed Lag Model 26

6.1 The Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26

6.1.1 Nominal Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

6.1.2 Real Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

iii

Page 5: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

6.2 Inference using Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares . . . . . . . . . . . 30

7 Error Correction Model 32

7.1 The Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

7.2 Nominal Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

7.3 Real Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

7.4 Asymmetric Exchange Rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36

7.5 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38

8 Conclusion 39

A Gravity Model 43

B Cointegration 44

C ARDL 46

D ECM 47

iv

Page 6: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

List of Tables

4.1 Gravity Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

5.1 ADF and KPSS Tests . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23

5.2 Engle-Granger Tests . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24

6.1 Long Run Elasticities Nominal ARDL Model . . . . . . . . . . 28

6.2 Long Run Elasticities Real ARDL Model . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

7.1 Nominal Error Correction Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

7.2 Real Error Correction Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

7.3 ECM with Asymmetric Exchange Rate Effects . . . . . . . . . 37

A.1 Gravity Model Using Random Effects Estimation . . . . . . . 43

B.1 ADF Tests (Real Data) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

B.2 Engle-Granger Tests (Real Data) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

B.3 ADF Tests on the First Difference of the Series (Nominal

Data) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45

B.4 ADF Tests on the First Difference of the Series (Real Data) 45

C.1 Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares Results . . . . . . . . . . . . 46

D.1 Complete Error Correction Model (Nominal Data) . . . . . . 47

D.2 Complete Error Correction Model with Trend (Nominal Data) 48

D.3 Complete Error Correction Model (Real Data) . . . . . . . . . 49

D.4 Error Correction Model for Government Exports (Real Data) 49

D.5 Complete Error Correction Model with Trend (Real Data) . 50

D.6 Error Correction Model with Asymmetric Exchange Rate

Effects (Nominal Data) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50

D.7 Error Correction Model with Asymmetric Exchange Rate

Effects (Real Data) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51

v

Page 7: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

List of Figures

3.1 Composition of Australian Service Exports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

4.1 Relationship Between Aggregate Service Exports and Distance . . . . 19

5.1 Australia’s Service Exports . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

5.2 Cointegrating Errors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

6.1 Service Exports (Real Data) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

7.1 Fitted, Actual and Residual Plots . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

D.1 Fitted, Actual and Residual Plots of all Error Correction Models . . . . . 52

vi

Page 8: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

An Empirical Analysis of Disaggregated

Australian Service Exports

William Weatherburn

Abstract

I empirically model the demand for Australian service exports. Rather than consider

service exports in the aggregate, I disaggregate service exports into nine categories.

Using three export data sets and a variety of econometric techniques, I find that

there are vast differences in how service exports are affected by economic growth,

the exchange rate, the distance between Australia and its trading partners and

whether the trading partner speaks English as an official language. I find that

education exports are the most sensitive to economic growth but the least affected

by fluctuations in the exchange rate. I also find that, despite the absence of

transportation costs, all service exports are negatively affected by distance. Finally,

I find mixed evidence for cointegration between individual service exports, the

exchange rate and trading partner GDP. It is evident that examining services in

the aggregate masks how sensitive individual categories of services are to standard

trade variables.

vii

Page 9: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Chapter 1

Introduction

Over the 40 year period from 1977 to 2017, the value of Australia’s service exports

rose from $0.93 billion to $71 billion.1 In 2016, service exports exceeded agricultural

exports by over 60% and three quarters of the Australian population was employed

in the service sector.2 Despite the importance of services to the Australian economy,

there have been few empirical studies of Australia’s service exports. Most studies are

restricted to large, multi-country analyses that assume goods and service exports are

interchangeable (Senhadji and Montenegro, 1999). If service exports are examined,

they are almost always considered in the aggregate (Ceglowski, 2006; Kouparitsas,

Luo, Smith, et al., 2017). The purpose of this paper is to add to the sparse literature

on Australia’s disaggregate service export industry. I divide services into nine

categories and estimate the long-run elasticities of income demand as well as the

sensitivity of these exports to the exchange rate. I also examine whether factors

that determine the trade in goods, such as sharing a common language and the

distance between trading partners, also determine the export of Australian services.

I ask whether the aggregation of service exports masks how responsive the individual

categories are to these variables.

The definition of a service is an activity that is intangible and does not result in

ownership upon sale. A doctor diagnosing a patient is a service, as is guiding tourists

up the Sydney Harbour Bridge. A service export is simply a service that is bought

by foreigners. It includes obvious activities such as tourism but also more complex

activities such as the selling of financial products to other countries. The paucity of

research into Australian services can be partly explained by the difficulty involved

in measuring the value as well as the volume of these activities.

In Australia, services have long been viewed as a means of increasing Australia’s

export revenue. For instance, one argument for the deregulation of the financial

sector in the 1980’s was that Australia could develop into the financial hub of

Asia. The interest in promoting Australia’s service exports faded at the turn of

the century as China’s economic development stimulated a demand for commodities

1Nominal data obtained from Australian Bureau of Statistics Catalogue 536801.2Data obtained from Australian Bureau of Statistics Catalogue 536801.

1

Page 10: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

which saw a 345% rise in the price of coal and an 820% rise in the price in iron

ore in the space of ten years.3 As the price of these commodities has now fallen,

the push to encourage Australian service exports is back at the forefront of policy

discussion and is likely to remain so. The long-term prospects of coal as an export

are looking increasingly grim. Concerns about climate change and clean air, as

well as the growing investment in gas-fired power stations has meant that coal will

not play as significant a role in electrical generation as it has done in the past.

Commentators as varied as British Petroleum (BP) and the Grantham Institute (an

environmental think tank) predict that the world demand for coal could peak in as

little as eight years. In response, the Australian government has singled out tourism,

health and finance as services that could fill this possible revenue void (Productivity

Commission, 2015).

Unfortunately, there has been little empirical analysis of how Australian services

are affected by standard trade variables such as foreign income, prices, the exchange

rate and the distance between Australia and its trading partners. Do education

and financial services rise by the same amount when the world economy grows at

one percent? How sensitive to the exchange rate are transport services? And is

Australia’s distance from its trading partners a severe hindrance to the trade in

services? These are all important questions if Australia wishes to transition away

from being a commodity-exporting country.

To answer these questions, I use a variety of econometric techniques that have

been used extensively in the trade literature. Using a simple Gravity Model I find

that trading partner GDP, sharing a common language and the distance between

Australia and its neighbours all have a statistically significant effect on Australia’s

service exports. Distance has a strong impact on all Australia’s service exports

but the effect differs greatly between the exports. For instance, a 1% increase in

the distance between Australia and a trading partner reduces telecommunication

exports by 0.7% but insurance and pension services by 3%.

I then formulate export demand equations as a function of trading partner income

and the exchange rate; a specification that is consistent with Cheng (2016) and

Senhadji and Montenegro (1999). As both exports and income trend upward, there

is a concern that normal ordinary least squares techniques would lead to a spurious

regression. Export demand equations are therefore estimated using a cointegration

framework. Augmented Dickey Fuller tests clearly indicate that the exchange rate,

3Calculated as the simple percentage change in price from June 2003 to June 2013. Data fromIndex Mundi.

2

Page 11: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

GDP and all categories of exports are non-stationary variables. However, the results

of cointegration tests lead to contradictory conclusions. A bounds testing procedure

(Pesaran, Shin, and Smith, 2001) indicates that service exports are cointegrated

with income and the exchange rate. However, Engle-Granger tests do not support

this conclusion. Under the assumption that the variables are actually cointegrated,

an error correction model is estimated to examine the short run dynamics of service

export demand. All service categories are found to respond quickly to deviations

from the long-run equilibrium. For example, other business services correct by 25%

each year if there is a deviation from the long-term equilibrium in the previous

period.

To examine the long run impact of shocks to the exchange rate and trading partner

income an autoregressive distributed lag model is estimated. The long run income

elasticity for total service exports is 1.2 and this is consistent with the estimates

of Marquez (2006) and Cheng (2016). The long run exchange rate elasticity for

total service exports is -1.0. This suggests that Australian service exports are

more sensitive to the exchange rate than U.S services. As hypothesised, the

aggregate elasticities hide a great deal of variation among the individual service

export categories. For example, the exchange rate elasticity estimates range from

-0.4 (education) to -2.5 (telecommunication).

The primary contribution of this thesis is that, to the best of my knowledge, it is

the first empirical study of disaggregated Australian service exports. I find that

service exports are not homogeneous products. They respond very differently to

changes in foreign income and the exchange rate. An implication of this is that,

as the world economy grows, all service industries will benefit but they will do so

unequally. The travel sector stands to increase the most and the transport sector

the least. A second implication is that government policies that depreciate the

Australian dollar will only be effective at boosting certain service exports. I find

that telecommunication services are very sensitive to currency fluctuations but that

education exports respond little.

3

Page 12: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Chapter 2

Literature Review

2.1 Export Demand

International trade is one of the oldest areas of study in economics and there is

an extensive body of literature on the trade in goods. Most studies assume that

exports are not perfect substitutes for domestic goods. This allows countries to

be both importers and exporters of the same good and for there to be differences

in the price of the domestic good and foreign good (Goldstein and Khan, 1985).

The demand for a particular country’s export is then a function of trading partner

income and the price of the good. Beginning with Houthakker and Magee (1969) and

continuing to the present, this specification is estimated empirically in the following

manner:

Log(exportt) = β0 + β1Log(incomet) + β2Log(pricet) + µt

Where income refers to the income of the purchasing country and price refers to the

price of the export. The coefficient on income gives the elasticity of income demand:

the percentage change in exports when the trading partners income rises by one

percent. Similarly, the coefficient on price gives the price elasticity of the export:

the percentage change in exports when the price of the export rises by one percent.

Houthakker and Magee estimate the income elasticities of imports and exports for

26 countries and find that, for certain countries, the income elasticity of imports

was different to the income elasticity of exports; a finding that helped explain the

current account of these countries. For instance, in the United States, the import

income elasticity was 1.5 and this is considerably larger than the export income

elasticity of 1.0. This implies, that if the U.S and world economies grow at the same

rate, the United States will import more than it exports causing a deterioration in

the current account. For other countries, such as Japan, the opposite is true: the

income elasticity is much higher for exports than imports, which is consistent with

Japan’s current account surplus.

The use of ordinary least squares to estimate this specification dominated trade

research until concerns about time trends in the variables were raised. As exports,

GDP and prices all drift upwards with time, the statistical significance of the results

4

Page 13: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

may be only attributable to the trend. To account for this, (Senhadji, 1998) and

Senhadji and Montenegro (1999) use cointegration techniques to estimate price and

income elasticities. For imports, the income elasticities are found to be higher than

the estimates of Houthakker and Magee, while the export income elasticities are

found to be lower. The general pattern, that countries with large current account

deficits (the United States and Australia) have a higher income elasticity for imports

than exports, continues to hold.

Senhadji and Montenegro also examine differences in income elasticities across

geographical regions. They find that Asian countries have higher income elasticities

than both developed and developing countries. This indicates that, as the world

economy grows, Asian exports will grow at a faster rate. This is taken as further

evidence that the historical economic growth of Asian economies is attributable to

international trade. In contrast, the authors find that African countries have the

lowest export income elasticities. The authors do not speculate on why this is the

case but it is possibly due to the fact that African exports are primarily agricultural

goods. As countries grow and develop, their demand for agricultural goods is likely

to be outstripped by their demand for manufactured goods and commodities. The

finding suggests that as the world economy grows, African exports will not keep

pace with the rest of the worlds’ export growth.

Empirical analysis has also attempted to identify factors that determine trade

flows. This is routinely done using the Gravity Model, which derives its name

from Newton’s law of gravity. Tinbergen (1962) appropriated the equation for use

in economics and used it to link trade flows to the economic size of the trading

partner and the physical distance between them. The simplest expression of the

model is:

Tradei,j =GDPi ×GDPjDistancei,j

Where trade is the bilateral trade flow between country i and country j ; GDP is

the measure of the economic size of country i and country j and Distance is the

distance between the two countries. Empirically, the equation has proven successful.

Exports rise in proportion to the economic size of the trading partner, imports rise

in proportion to the size of the origin country and both are negatively affected by the

distance between countries (Head and Mayer, 2013). For instance, Brun, Carrere,

Guillaumont, and De Melo (2005) find that a one percent increase in distance reduces

trade by one percent. They also find that, for wealthy countries, the effect of distance

on trade has declined over time; a result they attribute to globalisation.

5

Page 14: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

The Gravity Model has also been estimated using unilateral export trade flows. In

this situation the dependent variable is the export volume of one particular country

to a number of its trading partners. This allows the researcher to focus on the

determinants of a country’s exports rather than the determinants of exports in

general. For instance, Moldovan and Covaci (2015) use a unilateral Gravity Model

to examine Lithuania’s exports. They find that the distance between Lithuania and

its trading partners has a significant affect on many of Lithuania’s service exports.

Recent empirical literature has focused on the effects of other variables while

controlling for the effects of economic size and distance. For example, sharing

a common language or currency is typically significant in explaining trade (Head

and Mayer, 2013) whilst large time zone differences have a negative effect on trade

(Moldovan and Covaci, 2015). An interesting study by Anderson and Van Wincoop

(2003) uses the Gravity Model to examine the effect of the U.S-Canada border on

trade. Domestic trade between the U.S states and between the Canadian provinces

is compared to the international trade between the two countries. Anderson finds

that domestic trade is much larger than international trade, even after controlling for

economic size, population and distance. Anderson estimates that the international

border is responsible for reducing bilateral trade by 30%. This is surprising large

considering that the U.S-Canada border is informal by international standards.

2.2 Service Exports

In almost all of the previously mentioned research, the dependent variable was

a measure of total export value. This is a natural way to compare countries

and examine current account issues however, it is likely to lead to a significant

degree of aggregation bias. It is improbable that exports as diverse as iron ore,

heavy machinery and tourism would all be similarly affected by foreign income, the

exchange rate and the distance between the trading partners. In acknowledgement

of these issues, it is routine to use disaggregated trade data and examine the trade in

different goods and services separately. A multitude of authors have examined the

trade in goods (see Goldstein and Khan, 1985 for a review) and such is the depth

of this literature that there are even estimates of the sensitivity of German beer

exports to the exchange rate (Dreyer and Fedoseeva, 2016).1 However, research on

the trade in services has largely been ignored.

Unfortunately, there is no a priori reason why the results of studies that have

1They find that a 1% appreciation reduces beer exports by 0.43%.

6

Page 15: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

examined goods should be generalisable to the trade in services. Indeed, the effects

of foreign demand, prices and the exchange rate on goods exports and service

exports should be different for at least two reasons. First, while the production and

consumption of goods is often separated in time, the production and consumption

of services occurs simultaneously. For instance, it would not be unusual to import

canned beans from Mexico that had been produced months prior, but flying to

Madagascar is a service export that is produced and consumed at the same time.

Second, unlike goods, once a service has been purchased it is not typically able to

be resold. For these reasons the aggregation of goods and services in trade studies

is likely to yield inaccurate results. This aggregation bias can be substantial. In

a 2016 country profile of Montenegro, the International Monetary Fund concludes

that a one percent increase in foreign income boosts service exports by 2.6% but

has no effect on the value of the goods Montenegro exports (IMF, 2016).

These recent elasticity estimates are often obtained using a cointegration framework.

If evidence of cointegration is found, there exists a stable long-run relationship

which exhibits short-run deviations. A small number of studies have used this

approach to examine services trade. For example, Hung, Viana, et al. (1995) finds

that U.S tourism exports, their price and world GDP are cointegrated. Hung and

Viana conclude that tourism trade is more sensitive to world income growth than

merchandise trade suggesting that in the future, the U.S tourism industry will

expand at a faster rate then the U.S manufacturing industry.

To assess the determinants of services trade, a number of studies instead use the

Gravity Model. As with the trade in goods, most studies find that the trade in

services is positively related to the economic size of the trading partners (Ceglowski,

2006; Walsh, 2006). In contrast, there is some debate in the role that distance plays

in the trade in services. Distance affects the trade in goods because of transport

costs. Shipping coal or heavy machinery is expensive and countries that have to

export to far away markets are at a disadvantage. It is not clear that the same

reasoning is applicable to services, as services are rarely transported.2 On the other

hand, physical proximity may be the primary reason services are being purchased

in the first place.

The findings in the literature are inconclusive. Ceglowski (2006) finds that a one

percent increase in the distance between trading partners reduces service trade flows

by approximately 0.8%. In contrast, Walsh (2006) and Van Nho and Huong (2014)

find that distance has no effect on service trade flows. These different conclusions

2The obvious exception being tourism.

7

Page 16: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

are likely to be due to the use of different econometric techniques and different

data sets. Ceglowski aggregates the service trade flows of 28 countries while Van

Nho looked at the service exports of just Vietnam to the rest of the world. It

is probable that the effect of distance on services trade differs between countries.

Furthermore, although Ceglowski and Walsh use the same data set, Walsh compares

estimates using pooled OLS, random effects and the Hausman and Taylor model.

Walsh favours the Hausman and Taylor model as it corrects for correlation between

independent variables but it is only using this estimation technique that he finds

distance insignificant.

2.3 Disaggregating Services

In the limited research on the trade in services most papers have used aggregated

service data. It seems likely that the determinants of services as heterogeneous

as tourism, finance and telecommunications would be different. Indeed, Moldovan

and Covaci (2015) use a Gravity Model to examine service exports and find that

the effects of distance, time zone differences and European Union membership all

depend upon the type of service. For example, distance has a negative effect on the

export of transport services but has no effect on communication or other business

exports.

Marquez (2006) explicitly assesses the impact of using aggregate data in service trade

studies by comparing U.S service imports and U.S service exports. Using aggregate

data, the income elasticity of exports is roughly similar to the income elasticity of

imports (1.3 and 1.5). However, this masks the variation across service categories.

Private service exports have an export income elasticity of 3.2 whilst travel exports

have an income elasticity of 1.5. For both categories, the export elasticity was

larger than the import elasticity. This implies that, as the world economy expands,

service exports will outweigh service imports and that the U.S service industries will

not benefit equally. All else is held constant, the export of other business services

will increase at more than twice the rate as the export of travel services. Marquez

concludes that using disaggregated data is the most important aspect of econometric

modelling in service trade studies.

Following Marquez, Cheng (2016) compares disaggregated and aggregated U.S

service exports using a cointegration approach and three different trade models.

All models supported the conclusion that effect of income and prices on trade was

largely dependent on the type of service. Cheng finds that the use of aggregate

service data disguises the effect that changes in the exchange rate have on service

8

Page 17: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

trade. In the aggregate, service trade is significantly affected by the exchange rate

but certain components, such as intellectual property and insurance and pension

services, are not affected by changes in the exchange rate in the short run or long

run.

2.4 Disaggregate Australian Services

Despite its importance to the Australian economy, there has been no study that

has analysed the demand for Australian service exports. Kouparitsas et al. (2017)

come close as they model the demand for Australian service exports, but they use

aggregate service data. They also assume that the foreign income elasticity is one

in order to estimate the elasticity of substitution of Australia’s service exports.

Most of the limited research on disaggregated services trade has been centred on

the exports of the United States. The results from United States data may not be

applicable to Australia, due to the different composition of our exports, the financial

dominance of the United States and the differences in our primary trading partners.

Yet, if Australia is to shift from exporting commodities to exporting services it is

important to understand the determinants of these exports and, in particular, how

they are affected by world economic growth.

This paper will add to the sparse literature on the Australian service export sector.

First, I estimate a Gravity Model to see if Australian service exports can be

explained using standard trade variables. Second, I test for cointegration between

each category of export, the exchange rate and trading partner income. Third, I

estimate an Autoregressive Distributed Lag model to obtain the long run income

and exchange rate elasticities. Finally, I estimate an Error Correction Model to

examine the short run dynamics of service exports, the exchange rate and trading

partner income.

These estimates are important because the responsiveness of service exports to

global income has implications for Australia’s balance of payments. Will rising

service exports be able to outweigh the rise in imports as the Australian economy

grows? If not, and if commodity exports also decline, Australia’s current account

will deteriorate further. Furthermore, policies that aim to increase exports by

depreciating the exchange rate assume that service exports will respond to this

depreciation. As services have only been studied in the aggregate, this assumption

has not been tested for any particular service category. It is important to know

which of these service exports are responsive in order to assess the effectiveness of

9

Page 18: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

policy changes designed to stimulate demand for Australia’s exports.

10

Page 19: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Chapter 3

Approach and Variables

3.1 Approach

This paper makes use of two distinct data sets on disaggregated service exports and

this leads to a broad division in the methods used to examine them. The first data

set is panel data on disaggregated Australian service exports to particular countries.

For example, it provides the value of Australian tourism exports to China from 2000

to 2016. I use this data set to estimate a Gravity Model. The advantage of this

data set is that it provides a rich source of information on Australia’s service exports

across time and destination. The disadvantages of this data set are that the sample

size is small and that certain export categories are missing. Hence, I make use of a

second, time series data set. This provides information on Australia’s disaggregated

service exports to the rest of the world over a 45 year period. For example, the value

of Australian tourism exports to the rest of the world in 2001. I use this data set to

estimate a variety of time series models.

3.1.1 Gravity Model Variables and Data Sources

I estimate Gravity Models using five variables: Trading Partner GDP, Australia’s

GDP, Distance, Common Language and Service Exports. A description of these

variables and data sources are provided below.

Service Exports

Services are considered an export when a foreigner purchases an Australian service

even if the individual is in Australia. Data on service exports is sourced from the

Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS).1 It is annual data, measured in Australian

dollars at current prices and the sample period is from 2000 to 2016. The gravity

model is estimated for seven different service exports. The following list provides a

short description on what each category of export includes.

(i) Finance: The purchase of Australian financial products or services.

(ii) Insurance and Pension: The purchase of insurance policies. Includes pension, life

and freight insurance.

1Catalogue 536805500405

11

Page 20: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

(iii) Other Business: A diverse category that includes payments relating to research

and development, management consulting, legal, accounting and waste treatment

services.

(iv) Telecommunication, Computer and Information Systems: The purchase of

telecommunication, computer or information services.

(v) Transport: Includes expenditure on all forms of transportation (by sea, air and

land) for passengers and freight. Also includes postal and courier services.

(vi) Travel: Expenditure on business and personal travel. Education services are a

sub-category.

(vii) Aggregate: The total value of services exports of Australia. It includes a number

of smaller service categories that are not examined in this thesis.

Trading Partner GDP

Trading partner GDP is measured in current United States’ dollars and is the sum

of the GDP of Australia’s 23 largest service export destinations. The countries

include: Canada, China, France, Germany, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Ireland,

Italy, Japan, South Korea, Malaysia, Netherlands, Norway, Singapore, Philippines,

United States, United Kingdom, Vietnam, Sweden, South Africa and Switzerland.

The source is the World Bank database and the sample period is 2000 to 2016.

Australia’s GDP

Australia’s GDP is measured in current United States dollars. The source is the

World Bank database and the sample period is 2000 to 2016.

Distance

Distance is the kilometre distance between a country’s capital city and its trading

partner. The source is the French database: Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et

d’Informations Internationales (CEPII). It is calculated using the great circle

formula which measures the minimum distance between two points along the Earth’s

surface.

Common Language

Common language is a dummy variable equal to one if the trading partner speaks

English as an official language. The source is also the CEPII database.

12

Page 21: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

3.1.2 Time Series Variables and Data Sources

I also analyse Australia’s service export demand using a time series approach over

a 45 year period. One issue with this strategy is that these variables trend upwards

with time. For example, both exports and GDP have risen considerably since 1972.

I deal with this problem by modelling service export demand in a cointegration

framework. This is consistent with other studies that have looked for cointegration

in trade. For example, Senhadji and Montenegro (1999) find the that for many

countries there is a stable relationship between total exports, export prices and

world GDP. My approach follows that of Cheng (2016) who finds that U.S service

exports, world GDP and the exchange rate have a cointegrating relationship. The

three variables I use for the time series analysis are the Trade Weighted Index,

Trading Partner GDP and Service Exports. A description of these variables and

data sources are provided below.

Service Exports

Ten different service exports categories are examined. Seven of these are identical

to the categories described above. The additional three categories are:

(i) Education: personal travel for educational reasons. Are a sub-category of travel

exports.

(ii) Government: Includes payments relating to embassies, consulates and military

agencies.

(iii) Tourism: As defined by the ABS, it is not a distinct category. It is calculated by

the ABS as the addition of personal travel services and passenger transport services.

Figure 3.1 plots a selection of the categories of services as a percentage of total

service exports. Travel services are by far the largest category while transport’s

share has fallen. The data on exports is quarterly, measured in Australian dollars

at current prices and the sample period of the data set is from 1972 to 2016. The

source is the ABS.2

Trade Weighted Index

The trade weighted index (TWI) is a measure of the nominal exchange rate. It is

calculated by the Reserve Bank of Australia and measures changes in the Australian

dollar relative to a basket of currencies weighted by the size of their trading

relationship with Australia. The source is the ABS.3

2Catalogue 5368011a3Catalogue 5302019

13

Page 22: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Figure 3.1: Composition of Australian Service Exports

Trading Partner GDP

Trading partner GDP is measured in current United States dollars and is the sum of

the GDP of Australia’s 23 largest service export destinations. The countries used to

calculate the measure are the same as those used in the gravity model. The source

is the World Bank database and the sample period is from 1972 to 2016.

All variables, except the language dummy, are expressed in their log value in order

to obtain percentage changes.

14

Page 23: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

3.1.3 The Use of Nominal Data

Throughout the paper, I generally use data that measures variables in nominal

terms. This is not ideal as it is difficult to determine whether export values have risen

due to an increase in prices or an increase in volume. Working with real measures

would be preferred except that they are not available for most of Australia’s service

exports.

For the time series data, real measures of five service exports are published. The

exports are education, government, insurance and pension and travel services. I

repeat my time series analysis using this real data to check the robustness of my

nominal findings.

The nominal exports could have been deflated as is in Houthakker and Magee (1969)

or Marquez (2006), however, this is problematic because most price indices available

are calculated using a basket of goods and services. Deflating individual service

exports using these aggregate price indices would substantially bias my estimates

(Goldstein and Khan, 1985). To ensure consistency with the export data and to

explore nominal trade relationships I also use measures of nominal GDP and the

nominal exchange rate even though real measures are readily available.

15

Page 24: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Chapter 4

The Gravity Model

As foreshadowed earlier I begin with a preliminary analysis of the service data using

a Gravity Model. The Gravity Model takes advantage of cross-country variations

in trade flows to examine what determines a country’s trade. It has been used

successfully to explain the determinants of the trade in disaggregate goods and

trade in aggregate services. To the best of my knowledge it has never been applied

to disaggregated Australian services. The simple model in this paper fills this

research gap and confirms that disaggregated Australian service exports have the

same determinants as goods exports.

4.1 The Model

The specification I use follows Tinbergen (1962) but only considers the exports of

Australia rather than bilateral trade. The equation I estimate is as follows:

ln(XAu,j,t) = β0 + β1ln(GDPAu,t) + β2ln(GDP ∗j,t)− β3ln(DistanceAu,j) + β4Lang + εt

Where X is the service export and the index Au, j, t, indicate the value of exports

from Australia to country j at time t. GDPAu is the GDP of Australia and GDP*

is the GDP of the trading partner. GDP is the measure of the economic size of the

country and represents the quantity of exports that the country is able to supply

and demand. The variable Distance is the kilometre distance between Canberra and

the capital city of country j. Lang is a dummy variable equal to one if Australia’s

trading partner speaks English as an official language. Its addition is a common

modification of the original specification.

Sharing a common language with a trading partner is expected to have a positive

effect on the trade in services since this is a robust finding in the literature for both

the trade in goods (Head and Mayer, 2013) and in services (Moldovan and Covaci,

2015; Walsh, 2006). Indeed, Walsh found that it was one of the most important

determinants of services trade. This is because having a common language is often

viewed as a proxy for historical ties (Head and Mayer, 2013) or a measure of the

ease of doing business. In this context, it is expected to be important because the

16

Page 25: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

buying and selling of services requires a high degree of communication.

I expect that the economic size of Australia and of Australia’s trading partner

will be positively related to Australia’s export of services. A positive relationship

between GDP and exports is consistent finding in the literature (Head and Mayer,

2013). Larger economies should require more services and should have the capacity

to supply more services. As this paper only examines the export of Australian

services, rather than bilateral trade, it is expected that the effect of trading partner

GDP will be larger than the effect of Australia’s GDP.

The effect of distance on exports is expected to be negative as distance is usually

a proxy for transaction costs such as transportation (Head and Mayer, 2013).

Although services rarely need to be transported, Kimura and Lee (2006) find that

the trade in services is more affected by distance than the trade in goods. This is

possibly due to the fact that the provision of services requires physical proximity.

However, as Kimura and Lee acknowledge, their use of aggregate service data may

hide the fact that distance has heterogeneous effects on different services.

The Gravity Model was estimated using pooled OLS and random effects methods.

These methods are commonly applied to the Gravity Model (Walsh, 2006) but have

well-known drawbacks. They require the improbable assumption that unobserved

factors do not affect the explanatory variables. In this context that would mean that

unobserved factors of a country, such as its productivity, do not affect the country’s

GDP. Alternatively, the equation could have been estimated using a fixed effects

model. This would have been statistically superior as it would have removed the

effects of the unobserved factors that affect exports. However, its implementation

would also remove the interesting, non-time varying determinants: distance and

common language. Although far from perfect, pooled OLS and random effects

provide a sufficient means of examining whether the trade in services is determined

by the same variables as the trade in goods.

The pooled OLS estimates can be seen in table 4.1. The estimates using the

random effects model are reasonably similar and are reported in the appendix

(table A.1). Heteroscedasticity robust standard errors are used throughout. As

hypothesised, trading partner GDP has a large positive effect on Australia’s export

of services. For all services except telecommunication services, the coefficient on

trading partner GDP is significant at the 5% level. For each of these categories,

the effect of increasing trading partner income is moderate; ranging from 0.34

(telecommunication) to 0.69 (insurance and pension). In contrast, Australia’s GDP

17

Page 26: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Table 4.1: Gravity Model

ExportEstimated Coefficients

(Robust Standard Errors)GDP∗ GDPAu Dist Comm Lang c R2

Aggregate 0.56∗ 0.05 −1.37∗ 0.67∗ 16.69∗ 0.68(0.07) (0.08) (0.19) (0.25) (2.41)

Finance 0.46∗ 0.24 −0.87∗ 0.98∗ 5.52 0.22(0.18) (0.27) (0.41) (0.63) (6.49)

Insurance & Pens 0.69∗ −0.14 −2.95∗ 0.71 26.89∗ 0.64(0.14) (0.16) (0.43) (0.38) (4.60)

Other Business 0.44∗ 0.40∗ −1.07∗ 1.26∗ 4.69 0.41(0.14) (0.16) (0.31) (0.45) (3.52)

Telecomms CIS 0.34 −0.06 −0.70∗ 1.21∗ 15.26∗ 0.28(0.19) (0.23) (0.37) (0.45) (5.87)

Transport 0.44∗ −0.34∗ −1.32∗ 0.33∗ 28.05∗ 0.34(0.05) (0.11) (0.11) (0.11) (2.93)

Travel 0.56∗ 0.02 −1.47∗ 0.41 17.81∗ 0.66(0.09) (0.10) (0.20) (0.25) (2.82)

*p-value < 0.01Sample 2000 - 2015

does not appear to have much of an effect on the export of most categories of

services as the estimates are not statistically different from zero at the 1% level. The

exceptions are other business and transport services. Strangely though, transport

exports are found to decline when Australia’s GDP rises. It is not clear why this

would be the case but it implies that as Australia gets wealthier, foreign companies

and individuals stop using Australian air and freight transport.

The relationship between distance and Australia’s aggregate service exports after

controlling for economic size can be seen in figure 4.1. As hypothesised, the distance

between Australia and its trading partner has a negative effect on Australia’s

exports. The effect is strong. If all else is held constant, a one percent increase in

distance reduces service exports by at least 0.7% (telecommunication) and at most

2.9% (insurance and pension). The coefficient on distance is statistically significant

for all categories of service exports at the 1% level.

These results support the argument that distance significantly and negatively affects

service trade despite the absence of transportation costs. My estimate for the effect

of distance on aggregate services exports is -1.3. This is similar to Moldovan and

Covaci (2015), who find that the effect of distance on aggregate Lithuanian service

exports is -1.5. These estimates are considerably larger than those obtained from

examining bilateral trade flows (import and export data). Ceglowski (2006) utilises

18

Page 27: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Figure 4.1: Relationship Between Aggregate Service Exports andDistance

import and export data on 28 countries to estimate that total service trade is reduced

by 0.85% when the trading countries are 1% further apart. This suggests that

Australian service imports are not greatly affected by distance; a topic for future

studies.

Sharing a common language with the trading partner has a positive effect on all

categories of service exports but the magnitude of the effect varies. Other business

services are particularly influenced by sharing a common language; rising by 1.3

percent if all else is held constant. This is not surprising considering this export

includes professional services such as consulting and legal advice, which rely heavily

on verbal communication. Unexpectedly, sharing a common language does not have

a statistically significant effect on the export of travel services. Together, these

results imply that people decide to come to Australia based more on their wealth

and proximity rather than because of a shared cultural history or because they can

easily communicate with locals.

Taken together, these results are strongly supportive of the argument that service

exports are determined by the same factors as goods exports. The results are in line

with expectations: all else held constant, countries that are wealthy, physically close

and speak English as an official language will demand more Australian services than

those that do not fit these characteristics. The most important finding is that the

19

Page 28: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

effect of these variables on exports depends upon the service category. Thus, it would

be misleading to assume the aggregate estimates apply to all service categories.

20

Page 29: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Chapter 5

Cointegration

Although the Gravity Model is useful, further analysis is constrained by lack of

data. There are only 16 years of panel data that describes the destination of

disaggregated Australian service exports. Furthermore, some categories of services,

such as education, government and tourism, are missing. As a primary aim of this

thesis is to look at the long run determinants of services I continue my analysis using

the second, time series data set. This includes a greater number of service export

categories and provides the value of service exports to the rest of the world over a

45 year period. I begin by empirically testing for cointegration.

5.1 Stationarity

Cointegration analysis was introduced by Engle and Granger (1987) and it takes

advantage of the fact that some time series variables share a common trend. If a

variable has a stochastic trend, its probability distribution depends upon time and

it is said to be non-stationary (Stock and Watson, 2003). Engle and Granger show

that if a number of non-stationary time series are combined it may be possible to find

a combination of the series that is stationary. When this happens the relationship

is said to be cointegrated. A cointegrated relationship implies that there exists a

stable, long term relationship between the variables (Enders, 2010). This, is turn,

implies that past deviations from the long run equilibrium will impact future values

of the variables.

I test for a cointegrating relationship between world GDP, the exchange rate and

disaggregated Australian service exports. If one is found, past values of world GDP

and the exchange rate can be used to predict future Australian service exports.

The first requirement for cointegration is that the variables are non-stationary due

to a unit root. A plot of Australia’s service exports, figure 5.1, suggests none of them

are stationary variables. I empirically test whether service exports, world GDP and

the exchange rate are non-stationary using Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) and

KPSS tests.

21

Page 30: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Figure 5.1: Australia’s Service Exports

For the ADF test, the following equation is estimated:

∆yt = a0 + a1yt−1 +n∑i=1

βi∆yt−i + εt (5.1)

Where, y is the series that is being tested. The coefficient of interest is a1. The

null hypothesis is that a1 is equal to zero. If it is, the equation is entirely in first

differences and there is evidence that the series has a unit root (Enders, 2010). If

the null hypothesis is rejected, the residuals do not have a unit root and hence, are

stationary. Equation 5.1 requires the correct number of lags to be included. I select

the lag length using the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC).

As noted ealier, a plot of the data suggested that each series trended upward with

time. Hence, I also estimate equation 5.1 with a deterministic time trend included

as an explanatory variable. If this is the actual data generating process the power to

detect a unit root will increase with the inclusion of this trend term. I also conduct

a KPSS test on each series as proposed by Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt, and Shin

(1992). In the KPSS test, the null hypothesis is that the series is stationary. This is

22

Page 31: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

the opposite null to that of the ADF test. The test involves the following equation:

yt = a0 + βt+ γt∑i=1

zi + εt (5.2)

Where y is the series that is being tested and zi is a random walk process. The null

hypothesis is that γ is equal to zero. If so, the series is stationary if β = 0 and trend

stationary if β 6= 0 (Greene, 2003). The ADF and KPSS test statistics can be seen

in table 5.1.

Table 5.1: ADF and KPSS Tests

Dependent Variable ADF KPSSNo Trend Trend No Trend Trend

Aggregate -3.52* -1.10 0.83* 0.22*Education -3.54* 1.21 0.85* 0.23*Finance -2.79 -3.18 0.67* 0.13*Government -4.57* -2.45 0.82* 0.22*Ins. Pens. -1.96 -1.76 0.70* 0.19*Other Business -1.45 -2.62 0.83* 0.115Tele. CIS. -1.85 -2.84 0.59* 0.11Tourism -3.64 -0.75 0.82* 0.23*Transport -5.67 -1.50 0.75* 0.23*Travel -4.08 -1.05 0.83* 0.23*GDP -2.25 -1.65 0.85* 0.21*Exchange Rate -2.73 -1.97 0.433 0.21*Critical Value 5% -2.93 -3.52 0.46 0.15

Sample 1972 - 2016*Exceeds critical Value

Critical values derived by Dickey and Fuller (1979) and Kwiatkowski et al. (1992)

The majority of the ADF tests do not reject the null hypothesis of a unit root. The

majority of the KPSS tests do reject the null hypothesis of stationarity. This is

strong evidence that all the variables are non-stationary. As expected, the inclusion

of a trend term is an important determinant of these results.

I also conduct ADF tests on the five service exports for which real data is available.

The results are in appendix table B.1. The results are consistent with the nominal

data. There is evidence at the 5% level that the variables are non-stationary and the

inclusion of a time trend is an important determinant of this conclusion. Finally, I

conduct the ADF and KPSS tests on the first difference of each series to ensure they

are not second order integrated. The results confirm the series are first difference

23

Page 32: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

stationary and can be seen in the appendix tables B.3 and B.4.

5.2 Test for Cointegration

As the variables are non-stationary it is possible for there to be a cointegrating

relationship between the service export, the exchange rate and trading partner GDP.

I test for cointegration using the Engle-Granger two step methodology. In the first

stage, the following equation is estimated by ordinary least squares for each category

of service export:

ln(Exportt) = β0 + β1ln(Yt) + β2ln(ERt) + εt (5.3)

Equation 5.3 represents the long run relationship between the service export, GDP

(Yt) and the exchange rate (ERt). If this relationship is cointegrated, the residuals,

εt, must be stationary. Hence, in the second stage, I test for a unit root in the

residuals using an ADF test. If the null hypothesis of a unit root can be rejected,

the long run relationship is cointegrated. Again, as GDP and exports drift upwards

with time, I re-estimate the long run equation (eq. 5.3) with the inclusion of a linear

time trend. I then redo the ADF tests on the new residuals.

Table 5.2: Engle-Granger Tests

Dependent Variable Test StatisticsNo Trend Trend

Aggregate -2.72 -3.48Education -4.27* -3.48Finance -3.48 -3.47Government -5.12* -5.12*Ins. Pens. -2.78 -2.79Other Business -2.79 -2.97Tele. CIS. -2.96 -4.07Tourism -3.20 -2.11Transport -3.25 -2.92Travel -2.52 -2.24Critical Value 5% -3.92 -4.13

Sample 1972 - 2016*Exceeds critical value

Critical values derived by MacKinnon (1990)

The results of the Engle-Granger tests are in table 5.2. Without the inclusion of

a linear trend term only education and government services could reject the null

24

Page 33: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

hypothesis of the residuals having a unit root at the 5% level of significance. With

the inclusion of a trend, only government services could reject this null hypothesis.

Using the available real data confirms these findings, only government services are

statistically significant at the 5% level. The results are in appendix table B.2. Thus,

only for government services is there evidence for a cointegrating relationship.

For illustrative purposes, in figure 5.2 I plot the estimated residuals of the long run

equation (eq. 5.3) when the export is government services and when it is other

business services. The residuals from government exports are undoubtedly more

stable then the residuals of other business exports. However, the residuals of other

business services are clearly not trending upwards or downwards.

Figure 5.2: Cointegrating Errors

Taken together, the results suggest that the majority of service exports are not

cointegrated with GDP and the exchange rate. This is irrespective of whether a

trend term is included in the long run equation. However, the residual plots do

not indicate that they are trending. Thus, it is possible that the failure to detect

cointegration may be due to the low power of the Engle-Granger test or the limited

number of observations in my data set.

25

Page 34: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Chapter 6

Autoregressive Distributed Lag Model

In this chapter, I examine Australia’s service export demand relationships using an

Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) formulation as developed by Pesaran and

Shin (1998). The ARDL framework is useful because it provides another, more

powerful means of testing for the presence of a cointegrating relationship between

exports, GDP and the exchange rate. It also provides estimates of the long run

income elasticity of demand and the long run exchange rate elasticity for each

category of service export.

6.1 The Model

The ARDL specification has a number of desirable features. Its dynamic structure

allows lagged values of the export as well as lagged values of GDP and the exchange

rate to effect current exports. This is an appealing property given that many service

contracts are written in advance and that it may take time for exporters to be

affected by fluctuations in the exchange rate. The model has been used widely in

the trade literature to estimate elasticities. Senhadji and Montenegro (1999) find

that African nations have the lowest export price elasticities whilst Marquez (2006)

finds that U.S services exhibit asymmetric import and export income elasticities.

The specification I use follows Cheng (2016) closely.

∆Xt = α0 + β1Xt−1 + β2Yt−1 + β3ERt−1+ (6.1)ρ∑j=0

α1∆Xt−j +

ρ∑j=0

α2∆Yt−j +

ρ∑j=0

α3∆ERt−j + εt

Where X is the service export, Y is trading partner GDP and ER is the exchange

rate.1 ∆ denotes the first difference operator, t denotes the time period and the

number of lags is ρ. I use a general to specific approach to determine the appropriate

number of lags in the model. Lag selection is made using the Akaike Information

Criterion (AIC) where a lower AIC is preferred. I test for serial correlation in the first

order residuals of each ARDL model using the Breusch-Godfrey Lagrange Multiplier

(LM) test. All variables are in log values.

1Measured by TWI

26

Page 35: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

In the long run, the change in exports, GDP and the exchange rate will be zero.

Therefore, the long run elasticity with respect to world income and the exchange

rate can be derived respectively using:

ηIncome =β2β1

ηExchangeRate =β3β1

The long run income elasticity is expected to be positive: a rise in trading partner

GDP should increase Australia’s exports. The long run exchange rate elasticity is

expected to be negative: an appreciation in the exchange rate should reduce service

exports.

I again test for cointegration between the export, trading partner GDP and the

exchange rate using a bounds testing procedure as proposed by Pesaran et al.

(2001). This method uses an F-test to test for the joint significance of the one

period lag of the explanatory variables in equation 6.1. The null hypothesis, H0,

is: β1 = β2 = β3 = 0. If the null hypothesis can be rejected, there is evidence for

a cointegrating relationship. The critical values of the bounds test are supplied by

Pesaran et al. (2001). The lower bound assumes all variables are I(0) and the upper

bound assumes they are all variables are I(1). If the test statistic is smaller than

the lower bound, the null is not rejected. If it is larger than the upper bound, the

null is rejected. If it falls within the bounds, the test is inconclusive.

6.1.1 Nominal Data

Table 6.1 provides the long run income and exchange rate elasticities and the bounds

test for cointegration. It also provides the lag structure of each ARDL equation.

For example, aggregate services has three lags of the dependent variable, two lags

of trading partner GDP and four lags of the exchange rate. In the final coloumn is

the p-value of the Breusch-Godfrey LM test for serial correlation. I find no evidence

of serial correlation in any of the ARDL equations at the 1% level.

For all categories of services, a rise in trading partner income is associated with a rise

in Australian exports. For all categories of services except other business services,

an appreciation in the exchange rate reduces Australian exports. As hypothesised,

the aggregation of services masks a great deal of variation between the service

exports. The long run income elasticity for total service exports is 1.2% and the

long run exchange rate elasticity is negative 1%. Yet, a one percent increase in

27

Page 36: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Table 6.1: Long Run Elasticities Nominal ARDL Model

ExportLong Run Elasticity Bounds Lag LMGDP ER Test Structure p-value

Aggregate 1.18 −1.00 6.68∗∗ 3, 2, 4 0.59Education 2.13 −0.32 12.08∗∗ 3, 0, 0 0.91Finance 1.71 −1.76 3.71∗ 3, 2, 0 0.48Government 0.66 −0.33 8.24∗∗ 3, 1, 0 0.57Insurance & Pens 0.86 −2.43 6.21∗∗ 4, 3, 3 0.06Other Business 1.49 0.35 4.43∗ 2, 0, 0 0.38Tele CIS 1.33 −2.45 6.02∗∗ 4, 2, 2 0.43Tourism 1.39 −1.37 19.57∗∗ 5, 1, 2 0.50Transport 0.44 −1.55 14.02∗∗ 1, 0, 4 0.73Travel 1.55 −1.21 20.73∗∗ 4, 0, 0 0.08

**Exceeds 5% critical values [3.79, 4.85]*Exceeds 10% critical values [2.86, 3.53]

Critical values derived by Pesaran et al. (2001)

foreign income is associated with only a 0.4% rise in transport services but a 2.1%

increase education exports. Similarly, the effect of a one percent appreciation of

the exchange rate ranges from -0.32% (education) to -2.5% (telecommunication and

information systems).

I am unsure why other business exports would rise when the Australian dollar

appreciates. All other estimated elasticities appear reasonable. For instance, I find

that rising foreign income has a large positive effect on both tourism and education

exports but exchange rate changes have very different effects on each category. This

is intuitive; foreign tourists have the option of travelling to a wide variety of countries

and will do so for only a relatively short period of time. The prevailing exchange

rate will have a big influence on whether they come to Australia. In contrast,

the majority of education exports are to people wanting a university education in

Australia. This is a commitment of at least three years and one that is not often

taken later in life. For these reasons, fluctuations in the exchange rate would be

expected to have little impact on education exports.

Table 6.1 also provides the test statistic for the bounds test for each category of

service export. The null hypothesis is that there is no cointegrating relationship. For

eight of the ten categories of service exports this null hypothesis could be rejected

at the 5% level. This is evidence that the export, GDP and the exchange rate

are cointegrated. For financial service exports and other business services the null

hypothesis could be rejected at the 10% level. Thus, in contrast to the Engle-Granger

28

Page 37: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

tests, the bounds test provides strong evidence that many of the Australia’s service

export categories are cointegrated. This is possibly due to the different small sample

properties of the tests or because the ARDL bounds test allows for the variables to

be a mixture of stationary and first difference stationary (Pesaran et al., 2001).

6.1.2 Real Data

As the long-run relationship between exports, GDP and the exchange rate is better

conceptualised in terms of real, not nominal values, I re-estimate the ARDL model

(6.1) using real data. There are only five categories of services for which this is

possible: education, finance, government, insurance and pension and travel services.

I also use real measures of the exchange rate and trading partner GDP. My analysis

is robust if the real and nominal estimates are consistent.

Table 6.2: Long Run Elasticities Real ARDL Model

ExportLong Run Elasticity Bounds Lag LMGDP ER Test Structure p-value

Education 3.71 −1.71 9.48∗ 3, 1, 1 0.62Finance 1.24 0.28 4.08∗∗ 1 ,2, 1 0.87Government 0.47 −0.24 13.36∗ 2, 0, 0 0.29Insurance & Pens −5.82 6.72 9.02∗ 4, 0, 0 0.06Travel 2.43 −1.12 7.78∗ 2, 0, 0 0.11

**Exceeds 5% critical values [3.88, 4.61]*Exceeds 10% critical values [3.38 4.02]

Critical values derived by Pesaran et al. (2001)

The long run elasticity estimates and the results of the bounds test can be seen in

table 6.2. For government exports, the real and nominal elasticities are consistent.

For the other four exports, the results using the real data are different to the results

using the nominal data. For education and travel exports, the magnitude of the

income elasticities increases while the exchange rate elasticity is similar. For financial

exports the income elasticity is smaller and the exchange rate elasticity is positive.

This implies that financial exports increase when the Australian dollar appreciates

despite the fact they are now more expensive. This does not seem plausible. More

problematically, the income elasticity for insurance and pension services is negative.

This suggests that insurance and pension exports decrease when our trading partners

get wealthier. This is also not likely. To better understand these results I plot the

five services categories in figure 6.1.

29

Page 38: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Figure 6.1: Service Exports (Real Data)

The first aspect to note is that the sample size is much smaller. The first real

observation is in 1986, 14 years after the first nominal observation. It is possible

that my sample size is now too small for accurate estimation. The second aspect to

note is that, while real travel, finance and education exports have risen considerably,

real government services have been almost constant over the period. This explains

the very low income and exchange rate elasticities of government exports. Finally,

real insurance and pension exports rose from 1986 to 1999 but fell from 1999 to

2016. This is surprising as trading partner income grew immensely over the entire

period. This suggests that there are unobserved factors that have affected insurance

and pension exports. Perhaps a policy change or competition from other countries

is responsible.

6.2 Inference using Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares

As exports, GDP and the exchange rate are cointegrated, the estimates of the

coefficients are consistent, however, the distribution of these estimates is not normal.

This means that inference based on the t-statistics in the long run equation (5.3)

and the ARDL model may be inaccurate (Stock and Watson, 2003).

One solution to this problem is to use dynamic ordinary least squares (DOLS)

(Stock and Watson, 1993). This procedure uses past values, present values and

30

Page 39: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

future values of the change in variables in order to make valid statistical inference

about the estimated coefficients. The DOLS equation I estimate is:

Xt = β0 + β1Xt + β2Yt + β3ERt+ (6.2)ρ∑

j=−ρ

δj∆Xt−j +

ρ∑j=−ρ

δj∆Yt−j +

ρ∑j=−ρ

δj∆ERt−j + εt

Where, again, X is the service export, Y is trading partner GDP and ER is the

exchange rate. ∆ denotes the first difference operator, t denotes the time period

and the number of leads and lags is ρ. I use the AIC to determine the appropriate

number of leads and lags and HAC standard errors to correct for heteroscedasticity

and autocorrelation (Newey and West, 1986).

Appendix table C.1 provides the estimates of β1, β2 and β3 as well as the associated

p-values. The DOLS estimation confirms the results of the ARDL model. The

effects of trading partner GDP and the exchange rate are statistically significant

at the 5% level for nearly all categories of service exports. The only exception is

the coefficient on the exchange rate for education exports. This is not significant at

even the 10% level. This result is congruent with the low estimated exchange rate

elasticity in ARDL model. Together, the results suggest that education exports are

not affected by the exchange rate.

I note that, for most categories of services, the suggested number of leads and lags

is at least four. This is a considerable number as I have three variables and a small

sample size. A large number of leads and lags quickly reduces degrees of freedom

and this weakens my ability to draw inference.

31

Page 40: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Chapter 7

Error Correction Model

For most categories of services, the bounds tests provides strong evidence of

cointegration. This implies that there exists a stable, long term relationship between

trading partner GDP, the exchange rate and the service export. This in turn implies

that, if there is a deviation from the long-term equilibrium among the variables, one

or more of the variables will adjust to restore the equilibrium. In this chapter, I

use an error correction framework to estimate how quickly this equilibrium will be

restored. The Error Correction Models (ECM) also provide estimates of the short

run effects of trading partner GDP and the exchange rate on service export growth.

7.1 The Model

I develop error correction models of service export growth using the form proposed

by Engle and Granger (1987):

∆Xt = α0 + αX(Xt−1 − β1Yt−1 − β2ERt−1)+ (7.1)ρ∑j=1

α1j∆Xt−j +

ρ∑j=1

α2j∆Yt−j +

ρ∑j=1

α3j∆ERt−j + εt

Where X is the service export, Y is the trading partner GDP and ER is the exchange

rate. Equation 7.1 indicates that the growth in service exports is a function of past

periods’ GDP growth, export growth, exchange rate change and the deviation from

long run equilibrium in the previous period, (Xt−1 − β1Yt−1 − β2ERt−1).

Following from Engle and Granger (1987), the lagged residuals from the long run

equation (5.3), et−1, are used as an estimate for the expression (Xt−1 − β1Yt−1 −β2ERt−1). Hence, the error correction model I estimate for each service category is:

∆Xt = α0 + αX et−1+ (7.2)ρ∑j=1

α1j∆Xt−j +

ρ∑j=1

α2j∆Yt−j +

ρ∑j=1

α3j∆ERt−j + εt

Where, αX is the speed of adjustment coefficient that describes how quickly the

32

Page 41: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

long run relationship is restored. If the variables are cointegrated, I expect αX to

be negative and statistically significant.

The coefficients on the lags, αj indicate the short run effects of that variable on

export growth. The appropriate lag length is determined on the basis of each

lag’s statistical significance while also ensuring that the errors, εt, are serially

uncorrelated. I test for serial correlation in the first order residuals of each ECM

model using the Breusch-Godfrey LM test. All variables are in log values.

It is important to note that, in a cointegrating relationship, it is usually assumed

that all the variables play a role in adjusting to the long run equilibrium. Hence,

in theory, the error correction model could be re-estimated with exports as an

explanatory variable and GDP or the exchange rate as the dependent variable. In

this context however, it is likely that only service exports act to restore the long

term relationship. This is because the income of Australia’s trading partners and the

exchange rate are likely to be weakly exogenous. I argue foreign income is weakly

exogenous because it is improbable that Australia’s service exports cause the GDP

growth of our trading partners. The exchange rate is also weakly exogenous in this

context because I am examining disaggregated service exports. Individually these

make up a very small proportion of total exports and as such, changes in the volume

of these service exports should not cause changes in the exchange rate.

7.2 Nominal Data

Table 7.1: Nominal Error Correction Model

∆ExporttCoefficients

αX ∆Exportt−1 ∆GDPt−1 ∆TWIt−1

Aggregate −0.055 0.331∗∗∗ 0.545 −0.109Education −0.115 0.978∗∗∗ 0.480 −0.112Finance −0.346∗ 0.248 1.592 0.125Government −0.531∗∗∗ 0.162∗∗ −0.064 0.055Insurance & Pens−0.099∗∗ 0.735∗∗∗ 0.185 0.433∗∗

Other Business −0.249∗∗ 0.222 0.542 −0.162Telecomms CIS −0.209 0.480 −1.146 0.788Tourism −0.106 0.268∗∗ 0.713∗∗ −0.316∗∗

Transport −0.196∗ 0.461∗∗∗ 0.312 0.055Travel −0.011 0.056 0.592∗∗∗ −0.482∗∗∗

***p-value < 0.01, **p-value < 0.05, *p-value < 0.10

33

Page 42: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Table 7.1 provides the results from the ECM for all service exports categories. The

full results, with standard errors reported, can be seen in the appendix (table D.1).

For all categories, αX , the speed of adjustment coefficient is negative and reasonably

large. This indicates that the growth of service exports in the current period will be

lower if there was a positive discrepancy in the long run relationship in the previous

period. If the discrepancy is negative, the growth in services in the current period

will be higher than if there was no discrepancy. For example, if there is a deviation

from the long run equilibrium for financial exports, then 0.35% of this deviation

is corrected over the year. It is important to note that the speed of adjustment

terms vary greatly in their magnitude. While the estimate for service exports in the

aggregate is only -0.05, the estimates range from -0.01 (travel) to -0.5 (government).

Once again, this confirms the importance of using disaggregated export data.

The speed of adjustment parameters are significant at the 5% level for government,

insurance and pension and other business services. The parameters are significant at

the 10% level for finance and transport services. The lack of statistical significance

is evidence that those exports are not cointegrated with GDP and the exchange rate.

However, this may be a result of the short data set and the use of lags that further

reduce the power to detect a statistically significant result.

To assess how well the error correction models fit the data, I plot the fitted, actual

and residual values. Figure 7.1 depicts the values for other business exports, a

category for which the speed of adjustment term was significant, and the values

for aggregate services, a category for which the speed of adjustment term was

insignificant.

Figure 7.1: Fitted, Actual and Residual Plots

34

Page 43: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

A comparison of the actual values to the fitted values in the respective models

indicates that the ECM fits the data for both categories of exports well. However,

the residuals for aggregate services are more volatile than the residuals for other

business services. This provides visual confirmation that a cointegration framework

is more appropriate for some export categories than others. It also highlights yet

again the importance of using diaggregated data. While aggregate services are not

cointegrated, some of the categories of services that make up this aggregate are

cointegrated. This information can be utilised for forecasting purposes. The plots

for the remaining service export categories can be seen in the appendix, figure D.1.

Cointegration may be better modelled with a linear time trend in the long run

equation. The inclusion of this term moderately increases the magnitude of the speed

of adjustment coefficient in the ECM for all service exports. These results can be

seen in the appendix table D.2. The speed of adjustment parameters for financial and

telecommunication services are now also significant at the 5% level. Problematically,

for transport and travel exports, the inclusion of the trend term turns the speed of

adjustment parameter positive. This is an issue because it implies that if travel or

transport exports are growing above the long run level in the previous period they

will increase in the current period. This is not congruent with cointegration and

indicates that there is no long term stable relationship.

7.3 Real Data

Table 7.2: Real Error Correction Model

∆ExporttCoefficients

αX ∆Exportt−1 ∆GDPt−1 ∆TWIt−1

Education −0.148 0.561∗∗ 1.680 −0.366Finance −0.356∗ 0.044 9.879∗∗ −0.079Government−1.544∗∗ 0.493∗∗ 0.680 −0.070Ins Pens −0.244∗∗ 0.380∗∗∗ −0.266 1.236Travel −0.356∗∗ 0.188 0.263 −0.244

***p-value < 0.01, **p-value < 0.05, *p-value < 0.10

As a robustness check, I re-estimate the error correction models using real data for

the services for which it is available. The results are in table 7.2. Encouragingly, the

speed of adjustment term remains negative and three of the five speed of adjustment

coefficients are significant at at least the 5% level and one is significant at the 10%

level. A full table of results with standard errors can be found in the appendix (table

35

Page 44: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

D.3).

Unfortunately, compared to nominal data, the use of real data changes the

magnitude of the speed of adjustment parameter. For education and financial

services this change is not substantial. For travel services, the estimate with real

data is 35 times larger than the nominal estimate and is statistically significant. I

am unsure what would cause this but it is clear that there are issues in using nominal

data for travel exports.

Using real data, the coefficient on government services is above one and significant

which does not make economic sense. It implies that if there is a positive

discrepancy in the long run relationship then there will be a correction of 150%.

This implies, that in the current period, there is a negative discrepancy in the long

run relationship. This discrepancy will then over correct by 150% in the next period

and equilibrium will never be restored. In an attempt to rectify this problem, I

estimate the government long run equation with a date dummy variable to account

for the large increase in government exports for the 2000 Olympic Games. The

speed of adjustment estimate remains greater than one although it did decrease to

1.2. The results are in appendix table D.4.

Finally, if a linear trend term is also included in the long run equation (eq. 5.3), the

estimate for the speed of adjustment term for all categories of exports changes only

slightly. The results are in appendix table D.5.

7.4 Asymmetric Exchange Rates

One potential issue with the error correction model is that it is assumed that changes

in the growth rate of the explanatory variables have symmetric effects on service

export growth. For example, say that the error correction model estimates that

when exchange rates change by 1%, export growth changes by 2%. It is implicitly

assumed that this 2% change is applicable to appreciations and depreciations; when

exchange rates depreciate, export growth rises by 2% and when they appreciate,

export growth falls by 2%.

It is possible that this is not an appropriate assumption. A small number of studies

find that exports respond strongly to appreciations but not to depreciations (Dreyer

and Fedoseeva, 2016; Elbejaoui et al., 2013). This is known as asymmetric exchange

rate effects and it may occur because when the exchange rate appreciates, it makes

export immediately uncompetitive but when they depreciate it does not lead to

36

Page 45: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

the rapid growth and development of the export industry. If this is the case, my

estimates of exchange rate elasticities and the speed of adjustment term will be

incorrect. In the case of appreciations, the estimates will be negatively biased and

in the case of depreciations, they will be positively biased. I examine this issue by

allowing for asymmetric exchange rate effects to affect export growth. I use the

following error correction model:

∆Xt = α0 + αD(D∗∆ER)t−1 + αX et−1+ (7.3)ρ∑j=1

α1j∆Xt−j +

ρ∑j=1

α2j∆Yt−j +

ρ∑j=1

α3j∆ERt−j + εt

Where, D is a dummy variable equal to one if the exchange rate appreciated from

last year, ∆ER is the change in the exchange rate and all other variables are identical

to before. The interaction term captures the short run effects of an appreciation

of the exchange rate on service export growth. The coefficient of interest is αD. If

αD is statistically significant then appreciations of the exchange rate affect service

export growth more than depreciations do.

Table 7.3: ECM with Asymmetric Exchange Rate Effects

∆ExporttCoefficients

αD Speed of Adjust. ∆Exportt−1 ∆GDPt−1 ∆TWIt−1

Aggregate 0.013 −0.055 0.331∗∗∗ 0.545 −0.114Education −0.073 −0.113 0.978∗∗∗ 0.486∗∗ −0.083Finance −4.594∗ −0.428 0.286 1.734 2.178Government 0.210 −0.532∗∗ 0.165 −0.081 −0.031Insurance & Pens 0.112 −0.097∗∗ 0.736∗∗∗ 0.180 0.387Other Business 2.538∗∗ −0.284∗∗ 0.303∗∗ 0.335 −1.208∗

Telecomms, CIS −2.951 −0.193∗ 0.330 −1.625∗∗ 2.470∗∗

Tourism 0.221 −0.108 0.286 0.680∗∗∗ −0.396Transport 0.040 −0.195 0.463∗∗∗ 0.308 0.039Travel −0.167 −0.075 0.231 0.619∗∗∗ −0.317

***p-value < 0.01, **p-value < 0.05, *p-value < 0.10

The results from estimating equation 7.3 using nominal data can be seen in table 7.3

(the full nominal results are in appendix table D.6). At the 5% level, the only service

export category for which αD is statistically significant is other business services.

Therefore, for all other exports, I fail to find evidence of asymmetric exchange rate

effects on service export growth.

37

Page 46: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

I repeat my analysis using the available real data and the results are in the appendix

(table D.7). The real results support the nominal results, at the 5% level, αD was

not statistically significant for any export category. This suggests that exchange

rates affect export growth in a symmetric manner and that my estimated exchange

rate elasticities are valid.

7.5 Summary

The findings of this chapter indicate that disaggregated service exports can be

modelled in an error correction framework. The speed of adjustment coefficient is

consistently negative and reasonably sized. This suggests that service export growth

will adjust downwards in the current period if it exceeded the long run growth rate

in the previous period. This information can be used to more accurately forecast

Australia’s service exports.

The size of the speed of adjustment coefficient differs greatly between the export

categories. Again, this indicates that it would be misleading to assume the estimate

obtained from aggregate data apply to all service export categories. Unfortunately,

this coefficient is not statistically significant for the majority of service categories.

This suggests that most service exports are not cointegrated with the exchange

rate and trading partner GDP. This is supportive of the Engle-Granger tests but

contradicts the results of the bounds tests.

I fail to find evidence of short run, asymmetric exchange rate effects on service

export growth and this supports the validity of my elasticity estimates. However,

the failure to find evidence of asymmetric effects could be due my analysis only

considering short run dynamics. Perhaps asymmetries affect export growth in the

long run.

38

Page 47: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Chapter 8

Conclusion

My results indicate that using disaggregated trade data is crucial if one wants to

understand Australia’s export of services. Utilising three data sets and a variety of

econometric approaches, I find that different service exports respond very differently

to the exchange rate, foreign income, distance between Australia and its trading

partners and whether those partners speak English as an official language.

The lack of research into disaggregated services means there with a few studies

with which to compare my results for Australian services to their international

counterparts. Only Marquez (2006) and Cheng (2016), who examine American

service exports are comparable. At an aggregate level, my estimate of the long run

income elasticities for aggregate service exports is 1.2. This is reasonably consistent

with Marquez’s estimate of 1.0 and Cheng’s estimate of 1.3.

At a disaggregated level, Australian and U.S long run income elasticities are similar.

I find that a one percent increase in trading partner income increases Australian

transport exports by 0.4% while Cheng (2016) finds American transport exports

rise by 0.6%. Australian and American telecommunication, insurance and financial

services are similarly affected by rising foreign income. A notable difference between

the two countries’ exports is travel services. I estimate Australian travel services rise

by 1.6% in response to a one percent increase in foreign income. However, Cheng

estimates that U.S travel exports rise by only 0.7% in response to the same change

in foreign income.

On the other hand, Australian and U.S service exports have very different long

run exchange rate elasticities. With the exception of other business services, all

Australian service exports respond more strongly to an appreciation of the exchange

rate than their American counterparts. For instance, I estimate Australian financial

service exports fall by 1.8% when the exchange rate appreciates by 1% while

Cheng estimates that American financial exports rise by 0.1% when the U.S dollar

appreciates by 1%. It is possible that the U.S dollar’s role as the world’s reserve

currency makes U.S exports less exposed to currency fluctuations compared to the

Australian service exports. These differences between my estimates for Australia

39

Page 48: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

and Cheng’s estimates for the U.S suggests it would be inappropriate to generalise

the findings to other countries.

My results also indicate that Australian service exports will grow significantly as the

world economy continues to grow. The income elasticity of aggregate service exports

was greater than one; suggesting that in the future, Australia’s export growth

will outpace the income growth of our trading partners. All else held constant,

the industries that should benefit most from this rise are travel exports (including

education) and financial exports. Transport industries are expected to benefit the

least.

Australia’s goods exports are also expected to grow faster than world income.

Senhadji and Montenegro (1999) estimate that the long run income elasticity for

Australian exports is 2.6, while Norman (2007) estimates that the elasticity of

Australian manufactured goods is 2.2. These estimates are larger than my estimated

income elasticity of aggregate services. This suggests that Australian service exports

are less responsive to changes in world income than goods exports. This may reflect

the fact that Australia’s major trading partners are developing economies (primarily

in Asia) and Australia’s major manufacturing exports (iron, steel and machinery) are

inputs into production. Perhaps as Australia’s trading partners grow, they require

far more of these types of goods then they require services.

I find mixed evidence that individual service exports are cointegrated with world

GDP and the exchange rate. The statistical success is dependent upon the type of

service, the econometric method and whether nominal or real data is used. However,

no evidence was found that aggregate services were cointegrated. This suggests that,

when forecasting service exports, disaggregated data should be used in order to

improve accuracy. If the service categories can be assumed to be cointegrated, my

estimates suggest that the exports adjust quickly to deviations from their long run

growth rate. For most categories of services, approximately 10 to 20 percent of this

disequilibrium will be corrected in the first year.

I also find that distance negatively affects Australian service exports. Aggregate

service exports are reduced by 1.37% when the distance of the trading partner

increases by 1%. This is comparable to the effect of distance on goods; Brun

(2017) estimates that distance reduces goods trade by 1.35%. This finding supports

the argument that the physical proximity of the trading partner is an important

determinant of service trade. However, it remains to be seen through what

mechanism distance is operating. For travel and transport services, the mechanism

40

Page 49: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

would be the same for that of goods: distance would reflect transport costs. Yet

most other services do not incur significant transportation costs. Is distance actually

a proxy for time zone differences or does it reflect the fact that countries close to

Australia are more knowledgeable of Australia’s business environment? These are

questions for future studies.

In comparing nominal data to real data, I find that my results change; sometimes

dramatically. For example, using real but not nominal data, there is evidence that

travel exports are cointegrated. And using real data the estimated income elasticity

is almost 60% larger than the estimated income elasticity using nominal data. This

suggests that my nominal findings are conflated by movements in export prices and

export value. However, I was unable to investigate this further as real measures

were not available for the majority of service categories.

Real measures are not available because price indices of disaggregated services are

not published. This leads to a second concern: in the literature, it is common to

specify export demand equations as a function of prices as well as foreign income.

This was not possible for my analysis and, as such, I have omitted any consideration

of how the price of Australian service exports influences their demand. In order to

conduct future research and to check the robustness of my results, improvements

will need to be made in the data coverage of service exports.

Some of my findings raise more questions than they answer. Although it is reasonable

to find that industries vary in their response to foreign demand, why has the

enormous growth in global income over the past 40 years benefitted some Australian

services so much more than others? For instance, travel exports have grown rapidly

while insurance and pension services have declined from their peak 16 years ago.

Is the inexorable rise in travel exports solely attributable to the growing wealth in

Asian economies? Or, are there domestic and international policy changes that are

responsible? The fact that insurance and pension exports have declined suggests

there are other factors at play. These are critical considerations for future research.

The results of this paper provide the first insight into the Australian service export

industry. They are an initial step in understanding how Australia can shift from

exporting commodities to exporting services. I find that there are vast differences

in how Australian services respond to standard trade variables. However, as all

Australian services have moderately large exchange rate elasticities, government

policies that depreciate the Australian dollar should have a positive impact on

the service export industry. Furthermore, my results indicate that the use of

41

Page 50: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

disaggregate service data should be an important consideration in future research

and could improve the accuracy of service export forecasts.

42

Page 51: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Appendix A

Gravity Model

Table A.1: Gravity Model Using Random Effects Estimation

ExportEstimated Coefficients

(Robust Standard Errors)GDP∗ GDPAu Dist Comm Lang c R2

Aggregate 0.73∗ −0.07∗ −1.60∗ 0.65∗∗ 17.37∗ 0.67(0.16) (0.09) (0.29) (0.27) (2.28)

Finance 0.53 0.19 −0.96 0.99 5.55 0.22(0.32) (0.30) (0.59) (0.63) (6.69)

Insurance & Pens 0.75∗ −0.17∗ −3.04∗ 0.71∗∗ 27.27∗ 0.64(0.21) (0.14) (0.56) (0.39) (4.50)

Other Business 0.31∗∗ 0.49∗ −0.89∗ 1.28∗ 3.97 0.40(0.15) (0.17) (0.34) (0.48) (3.62)

Telecomms CIS 0.50∗ −0.17 −0.92∗∗ 1.24∗ 15.96∗ 0.27(0.18) (0.22) (0.42) (0.45) (6.18)

Transport 0.62∗ −0.47∗ −1.54∗ 0.34 28.90∗ 0.31(0.16) (0.15) (0.38) (0.45) (4.17)

Travel 0.75∗ −0.11 −1.71∗ 0.39 18.55∗ 0.65(0.17) (0.12) (0.30) (0.27) (2.61)

*p-value <0.01, **p-value < 0.05

Sample 2000 - 2015

43

Page 52: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Appendix B

Cointegration

Table B.1: ADF Tests (Real Data)

Dependent Variable Test StatisticNo Trend Trend

Education -2.86 -0.21Finance -2.56 -4.53∗

Government -2.64 -4.63∗

Insurance & Pens -3.58∗ -3.45∗

Travel -2.98∗ -3.08GDP -1.51 -2.50ER -1.43 -2.28

Critical Value 5% 2.96 3.57Sample 1986 - 2016

*Exceeds critical valueCritical values derived by Dickey and Fuller (1979)

Table B.2: Engle-Granger Tests (Real Data)

Dependent Variable Test StatisticNo Trend Trend

Education -1.91 -3.10Finance -2.94 -2.69

Government -6.22∗ -5.64∗

Insurance & Pens -3.11 -3.08Travel -1.71 -3.74

Critical Value 5% -3.92 -4.13Sample 1986 - 2016

*Exceeds critical valueCritical values derived by MacKinnon (1990)

44

Page 53: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Table B.3: ADF Tests on the First Difference of the Series (NominalData)

Dependent Variable ADFNo Trend Trend

∆ Aggregate -1.32 -3.89*∆ Education 0.02 -4.09*∆ Finance -4.75* -4.81*∆ Government -5.90* -7.61*∆ Ins. Pens. -2.66 -3.55*∆ Other Business -5.82* -5.88*∆ Tele. CIS. -3.47* -3.46∆ Tourism -1.23 -4.53*∆ Transport -3.70* -5.79*∆ Travel -1.38 -5.09*∆ ER -5.03* -5.32*∆ GDP -4.19* -2.70Critical Value 5% -2.93 -3.52

Sample 1972 - 2016*Exceeds critical value

Critical values derived by Dickey and Fuller (1979)

Table B.4: ADF Tests on the First Difference of the Series (Real Data)

Dependent Variable ADFNo Trend Trend

∆ Education -4.84* -4.54*∆ Finance -3.72* -3.70*∆ Government -4.39* -4.34*∆ Ins. Pens. -5.72* -5.61*∆ Travel -3.02* -4.38*∆ ER -4.18* -4.38*∆ GDP -5.73* -5.66*Critical Value 5% -2.99 -3.60

Sample 1986 - 2016*Exceeds critical value

Critical values derived by Dickey and Fuller (1979)

45

Page 54: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Appendix C

ARDL

Table C.1: Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares Results

ExportCoefficient Estimates S.E. of Leads,

GDP ER Constant Reg Lags

Aggregate Services 1.30 -0.60 -9.50 0.05 4, 4S.E. 0.04 0.14 1.06

P-Value 0.00 0.00 0.00

Education 2.29 0.26 -31.90 0.10 4, 3S.E. 0.07 0.17 1.55

P-Value 0.00 0.15 0.00

Finance 2.28 -4.58 -13.84 0.23 4, 3S.E. 0.72 1.67 6.44

P-Value 0.01 0.02 0.06

Government 0.84 -0.68 -5.26 0.08 4, 0S.E. 0.02 0.07 0.50

P-Value 0.00 0.00 0.00

Insurance and Pens -0.03 -3.06 20.23 0.14 4, 4S.E. 0.09 0.31 2.24

P-Value 0.74 0.00 0.00

Other Business 1.95 1.16 -30.48 0.22 4, 4S.E. 0.15 0.44 3.87

P-Value 0.00 0.02 0.00

Telecomms & CIS 1.46 -2.59 -7.18 0.08 3, 3S.E. 0.37 0.91 2.80

P-Value 0.01 0.04 0.05

Tourism 1.53 -1.03 -12.22 0.05 4, 4S.E. 0.04 0.15 1.01

P-Value 0.00 0.00 0.00

Transport 0.53 -1.34 5.16 0.06 4, 4S.E. 0.05 0.14 1.33

P-Value 0.00 0.00 0.00

Travel 1.69 -0.82 -15.99 0.05 4, 4S.E. 0.04 0.14 1.03

P-Value 0.00 0.00 0.00

AIC used to determine lead and lag lengthS.E are Newey-West (1986) HAC adjusted

46

Page 55: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Appendix D

ECM

Table D.1: Complete Error Correction Model (Nominal Data)

∆ExporttCoefficients LM

αX ∆Exportt−1 ∆GDPt−1 ∆TWIt−1 p-valueAggregate −0.055 0.331∗∗∗ 0.545 −0.109 0.25

(−0.072) (0.126) (0.157) (0.104)Education −0.115 0.978∗∗∗ 0.480 −0.112 0.18

(0.072) (0.112) (0.327) (0.215)Finance −0.346∗ 0.248 1.592 0.125 0.44

(0.179) (0.198) (1.021) (0.687)Government −0.531∗∗∗ 0.162∗∗ −0.064 0.055 0.85

(0.194) (0.177) (0.340) (0.213)Insurance & Pens −0.099∗∗ 0.735∗∗∗ 0.185 0.433∗∗ 0.23

(0.044) (0.109) (0.341) (0.221)Other Business −0.249∗∗ 0.222 0.542 −0.162 0.22

(−0.249) (0.222) (0.542) (−0.162)Telecomms & CIS−0.209 0.480 −1.146 0.788 0.06

(0.134) (0.242) (0.800) (0.459)Tourism −0.106 0.268∗∗ 0.713∗∗ −0.316∗∗∗ 0.36

(−0.018) (0.136) (0.488) (−0.448)Transport −0.196∗ 0.461∗∗∗ 0.312 0.055 0.75

(−0.196) (0.461) (0.312) (0.055)Travel −0.011 0.056 0.592∗∗∗ −0.482∗∗∗ 0.48

(−0.011) (0.056) (0.592) (−0.482)***p-value < 0.01,**p-value < 0.05,**p-value < 0.10

(Robust Standard Errors)Sample 1972 - 2016 (Reduced Sample for Telecomms & CIS and Finance)

47

Page 56: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Table D.2: Complete Error Correction Model with Trend (NominalData)

∆ExporttCoefficients LM

αX ∆Exportt−1 ∆GDPt−1 ∆TWIt−1 p-valueAggregate Services−0.107 0.358∗∗∗ 0.494∗∗ −0.067 0.16

(0.091) (0.126) (0.165) (0.112)Education −0.156∗ 0.958∗∗∗ 0.468 −0.067 0.31

(0.080) (0.112) (0.318) (0.214)Finance −0.414∗∗ 0.283 1.375 0.041 0.44

(0.196) (0.200) (1.037) (0.670)Government −0.531∗∗∗ 0.161 −0.065 0.053 0.83

(0.193) (0.177) (0.340) (0.213)Insurance & Pens −0.180∗∗∗ 0.502∗∗∗ −0.147 0.646∗∗∗ 0.15

(0.041) (0.144) (0.290) (0.188)Other Business −0.309∗∗∗ 0.262 0.570 −0.080∗∗ 0.39

(0.109) (0.148) (0.451) (0.326)Telecomms & CIS −0.687∗∗ 0.535∗∗ 0.063 0.475 0.87

(0.278) (0.239) (0.927) (0.512)Tourism −0.143 0.284∗∗ 0.668∗∗∗ −0.269 0.51

(0.099) (0.126) (0.234) (0.161)Transport 0.120 0.009∗∗∗ 0.186 0.957 0.74

(0.104) (0.154) (0.252) (0.158)Travel 0.001 0.049 0.605∗∗∗ −0.491∗∗∗ 0.47

(0.102) (0.163) (0.217) (0.156)***p-value < 0.01,**p-value < 0.05,**p-value < 0.10

(Robust Standard Errors)Sample 1972 - 2016 (Reduced Sample for Telecomms & CIS and Finance)

48

Page 57: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Table D.3: Complete Error Correction Model (Real Data)

∆ExporttCoefficients LM

αX ∆Exportt−1 ∆GDPt−1 ∆TWIt−1 p-valueEducation −0.148 0.561∗∗ 1.680 −0.366 0.76

(0.090) (0.117) (1.148) (0.253)Finance −0.356∗∗∗ 0.044 9.879∗∗ −0.079 0.66

(0.177) (0.198) (4.503) (0.894)Government −1.544∗∗ 0.493∗∗ 0.680 −0.070 0.39

(0.275) (0.198) (1.176) (0.214)Insurance & Pens−0.244∗∗ 0.380∗ −0.266 1.236 0.14

(0.084) (0.183) (1.937) (0.408)Travel −0.356∗∗ 0.188 0.263 −0.244 0.21

(0.163) (0.148) (1.031) (0.249)***p-value < 0.01,**p-value < 0.05,*p-value < 0.10

(Robust Standard Errors)Sample 1986 - 2016

Table D.4: Error Correction Model for Government Exports (RealData)

∆ExporttCoefficients LM

αX ∆Exportt−1 ∆GDPt−1 ∆TWIt−1 p-valueGovernment−1.292∗∗∗ −0.226 1.236 −0.030 0.10

0.532 0.206 1.434 0.293***p-value < 0.01,**p-value < 0.05,*p-value < 0.10

A date dummy for 2000 is included in the long run equation(Robust Standard Errors)

Sample 1986 - 2016

49

Page 58: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Table D.5: Complete Error Correction Model with Trend (Real Data)

∆ExporttCoefficients LM

αX ∆Exportt−1 ∆GDPt−1 ∆TWIt−1 p-valueEducation −0.197∗∗ 0.554∗∗∗ 0.974 −0.330 0.61

(0.092) (0.114) (1.238) (0.232)Finance −0.337 0.030 9.176 −0.194 0.33

(0.199) (0.203) (4.618) (0.953)Government −1.493∗∗∗ 0.443∗∗ 0.384 −0.145 0.90

(0.289) (0.204) (1.237) (0.224)Insurance & Pens−0.233∗∗∗ 0.366∗∗ −0.687 1.204 0.14

(0.081) (0.184) (1.916) (0.408)Travel −0.317∗ 0.218 0.039 −0.317 0.06

(0.158) (0.154) (1.111) (0.237)***p-value < 0.01,**p-value < 0.05,*p-value < 0.10

(Robust Standard Errors)Sample 1986 - 2016

Table D.6: Error Correction Model with Asymmetric Exchange RateEffects (Nominal Data)

∆ExporttCoefficients LM

D∗∆ER αX ∆Exportt−1 ∆GDPt−1 ∆TWIt−1 p-value

Aggregate 0.013 −0.055 0.331∗∗∗ 0.545 −0.114 0.25(0.329) (−0.072) (0.126) (0.157) (0.013)

Education −0.073 −0.113 0.978∗∗∗ 0.486∗∗ −0.083 0.17(0.608) (0.059) (0.212) (0.215) (0.400)

Finance −4.594∗ −0.428 0.286 1.734 2.178 0.30(2.432) (0.234) (0.154) (1.050) (1.138)

Government 0.210 −0.532∗∗ 0.165 −0.081 −0.031 0.82(0.603) (0.224) (0.167) (0.243) (0.300)

Insurance & Pens 0.112 −0.097∗∗ 0.736∗∗∗ 0.180 0.387 0.18(0.816) (0.046) (0.102) (0.291) (0.414)

Other Business 2.538∗∗ −0.284∗∗ 0.303∗∗ 0.335 −1.208∗ 0.77(1.241) (0.119) (0.140) (0.389) (0.671)

Telecomms, CIS −2.951 −0.193∗ 0.330 −1.625∗∗ 2.470∗∗ 0.15(1.172) (0.111) (0.161) (0.581) (0.876)

Tourism 0.221 −0.108 0.286 0.680∗∗∗ −0.396 0.39(0.455) (0.072) (0.174) (0.240) (0.247)

Transport 0.040 −0.195 0.463∗∗∗ 0.308 0.039 0.73(0.424) (0.137) (0.150) (0.229) (0.196)

Travel −0.167 −0.075 0.231 0.619∗∗∗ −0.317 0.02(0.438) (0.066) (0.198) (0.205) (0.228)

***p-value < 0.01, **p-value < 0.05, *p-value < 0.10(Robust Standard Errors)

Sample 1972 - 2016 (Reduced Sample for Telecomms & CIS and Finance)

50

Page 59: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Table D.7: Error Correction Model with Asymmetric Exchange RateEffects (Real Data)

∆ExporttCoefficients LM

D∗∆ER αX ∆Exportt−1 ∆GDPt−1 ∆TWIt−1 p-value

Education −0.073 −0.113 0.978∗∗∗ 0.486∗∗ −0.083 0.7696(0.608) (0.059) (0.212) (0.215) (0.400)

Finance −4.594∗ −0.428 0.286 1.734 2.178 0.2291(2.432) (0.234) (0.154) (1.050) (1.138)

Government 0.210 −0.532∗∗ 0.165 −0.081 −0.031 0.3837(0.603) (0.224) (0.167) (0.243) (0.300)

Insurance & Pens 0.112 −0.097∗∗ 0.736∗∗∗ 0.180 0.387 0.0182(0.816) (0.046) (0.102) (0.291) (0.414)

Travel −0.167 −0.075 0.231 0.619∗∗∗ −0.317 0.4154(0.438) (0.066) (0.198) (0.205) (0.228)

***p-value < 0.01, **p-value < 0.05, *p-value < 0.10(Robust Standard Errors)

Sample 1986 - 2016

51

Page 60: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Figure D.1: Fitted, Actual and Residual Plots of all Error CorrectionModels

52

Page 61: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Bibliography

Anderson, J. E. and E. Van Wincoop (2003). Gravity with gravitas: a solution to

the border puzzle. The American Economic Review 93 (1), 170–192.

Brun, J.-F., C. Carrere, P. Guillaumont, and J. De Melo (2005). Has distance died?

evidence from a panel gravity model. The World Bank Economic Review 19 (1),

99–120.

Ceglowski, J. (2006). Does gravity matter in a service economy? Review of World

Economics 142 (2), 307–329.

Cheng, K. M. (2016). Import, export and income elasticities: Evidence from us

trade in services. First Draft for the 91st WEAI Conference.

Dickey, D. A. and W. A. Fuller (1979). Distribution of the estimators for

autoregressive time series with a unit root. Journal of the American Statistical

Association 74 (366a), 427–431.

Dreyer, H. and S. Fedoseeva (2016). Gravity models and asymmetric exchange rate

effects: Insights from German beer exports. Agribusiness 32 (2), 289–295.

Elbejaoui, H. J. et al. (2013). Asymmetric effects of exchange rate variations: An

empirical analysis for four advanced countries. International Economics (135-136),

29–46.

Enders, W. (2010). Applied Econometric Time Series. John Wiley & Sons.

Engle, R. F. and C. W. Granger (1987). Co-integration and error correction:

representation, estimation, and testing. Econometrica, 251–276.

Goldstein, M. and M. Khan (1985). Income and Price Elasticities in Foreign Trade

in: R. Jones and P. Kenen, Handbook of International Economics. North Holland:

Amsterdam.

Greene, W. H. (2003). Econometric Analysis. Pearson Education India.

53

Page 62: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Head, K. and T. Mayer (2013). Gravity equations: Workhorse, toolkit, and

cookbook.

Houthakker, H. S. and S. P. Magee (1969). Income and price elasticities in world

trade. The Review of Economics and Statistics , 111–125.

Hung, J. H., S. Viana, et al. (1995). Modelling us services trade flows: a

cointegration-ecm approach. Technical report.

IMF (2016). Montenegro. International Monetary Fund Country Report (16/80),

1–12.

Kimura, F. and H.-H. Lee (2006). The gravity equation in international trade in

services. Review of World Economics 142 (1), 92–121.

Kouparitsas, M., L. Luo, J. Smith, et al. (2017). Modelling Australia’s exports of

non-commodity goods and services. Technical report, The Treasury, Australian

Government.

Kwiatkowski, D., P. C. Phillips, P. Schmidt, and Y. Shin (1992). Testing the null

hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root: How sure are we

that economic time series have a unit root? Journal of Econometrics 54 (1-3),

159–178.

MacKinnon, J. (1990). Critical values for cointegration tests. Department of

Economics, University of California San Diego.

Marquez, J. (2006). Estimating elasticities for us trade in services. Economic

modelling 23 (2), 276–307.

Moldovan, S. and G. Covaci (2015). Determinants of service exports of Lithuania:

a gravity model approach. Stockholm School of Economics .

Newey, W. K. and K. D. West (1986). A simple, positive semi-definite,

heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix.

Norman, D. (2007). Modelling manufactured exports: Evidence from Australian

states. Australasian Journal of Regional Studies 13 (2), 154.

Pesaran, M. H. and Y. Shin (1998). An autoregressive distributed-lag modelling

approach to cointegration analysis. Econometric Society Monographs 31, 371–

413.

Pesaran, M. H., Y. Shin, and R. J. Smith (2001). Bounds testing approaches to the

analysis of level relationships. Journal of Applied Econometrics 16 (3), 289–326.

54

Page 63: University of New South Wales School of Economics...Isabel for scrutinising all of the world’s geo-political problems, Binal for pleasantly wasting away hours discussing East Africa,

Senhadji, A. (1998). Time-series estimation of structural import demand equations:

a cross-country analysis. Staff Papers 45 (2), 236–268.

Senhadji, A. S. and C. E. Montenegro (1999). Time series analysis of export demand

equations: a cross-country analysis. IMF staff papers 46 (3), 259–273.

Stock, J. H. and M. W. Watson (1993). A simple estimator of cointegrating vectors

in higher order integrated systems. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric

Society , 783–820.

Stock, J. H. and M. W. Watson (2003). Introduction to Econometrics, Volume 104.

Addison Wesley Boston.

Tinbergen, J. (1962). An analysis of world trade flows. Shaping the world economy ,

1–117.

Van Nho, P. and V. T. Huong (2014). Analyzing the determinants of service trade

flows between Vietnam and the European Union - a gravity model approach. VNU

Journal of Science: Economics and Business 30 (5E).

Walsh, K. (2006). Trade in services: does gravity hold? A gravity model approach

to estimating barriers to services trade. IIIS Discussion Paper (183).

55