the solow growth model - uniwersytet warszawskicoin.wne.uw.edu.pl/siwinska/lecture9_2019a.pdf ·...

43
Long run economic growth, part 2. The Solow growth model Macroeconomics II Joanna Siwińska-Gorzelak WNE UW

Upload: others

Post on 09-Feb-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Long run economic growth, part 2. The Solow growth model

    Macroeconomics IIJoanna Siwińska-Gorzelak

    WNE UW

  • The Solow growth model

    • The seminal Solow growth model dates back to 1950’s and belongs to the fundamentals of growth theory

    • The Solow model is remarkable for its simplicity

    • The Solow model is a good starting point and a springboard for further models

    • We will analyze it in continuous time, we make the time units (the difference between t and t+1) as small as possible

    • At the centre of the model is the neoclassical production function

  • The neoclassical production function

    Production function is neoclassical when is characterised by :

    1. Constant returns to scale in capital and labour

    aY = A aK; aN

    2. Positive & diminishing marginal product of capital and labour:

    𝐹𝐾 =𝑑𝑌

    𝑑𝐾> 0;

    𝑑𝐹𝐾𝑑𝐾

    < 0

    𝐹𝑁 =𝑑𝑌

    𝑑𝑁> 0;

    𝑑𝐹𝑁𝑑𝑁

    < 0

    3. Inada conditions

    lim𝐾→0

    𝐹𝐾 = ∞ lim𝐾→∞

    𝐹𝐾 = 0

    lim𝑁→0

    𝐹𝑁 = ∞ lim𝑁→∞

    𝐹𝑁 = 0

  • Other important assumptions of the Solow

    model• One sector economy that produces a homogenous good that can

    be consumed or invested

    – The economy is closed, there is no government sector:𝐺𝑡 = 0; 𝑁𝑋𝑡 = 0; 𝑌𝑡 = 𝐶𝑡 + 𝐼𝑡

    • The saving rate ‘s’ is constant: 𝑆𝑡 = 𝑠𝑌𝑡; 𝑠 > 0

    𝑆𝑡 = 𝑠𝑌𝑡 = 𝐼𝑡

    • The population growth ‘n’ rate is constant

    𝑛 =ሶ𝑁𝑡𝑁

    • The depreciation rate of capital ‘d’ is constant

  • A temporary assumption (just for now)

    • To make our analysis easier, we will assume that

    technology is constant and equal to 1

    • We will change this assumption very soon

    • For now, the (neoclassical) production function is:

    Y=A F (K, N) = F (K, N)

  • Per capita production function

    • Since the production function is characterised by

    constant returns to scale, we can write :

    •𝑌𝑡

    𝑁𝑡= 𝐹

    1

    𝑁𝑡𝐾𝑡 ,

    1

    𝑁𝑡𝑁𝑡 = 𝐹

    𝐾𝑡

    𝑁𝑡, 1

    • We will use the following notation:

    • Hence, the production function can be written in

    intensive form as

    • 𝑦𝑡 = 𝑓(𝑘𝑡)

    N

    Kk

    N

    Yy == ,

  • Per capital production function…

    • …is still characterised by:

    • 𝑓𝑘 =𝜕𝑓𝑡

    𝜕𝑘𝑡> 0,

    𝜕𝑓𝑘

    𝜕𝑘𝑡< 0

    • lim𝑘→0

    𝑓𝑘 = ∞, lim𝑘→∞

    𝑓𝑘 = 0

  • Qunatities „per worker”

    • Since 𝑌𝑡 = 𝐶𝑡 + 𝐼𝑡, then if we express this equation per worker, we will get:

    𝑌𝑡𝑁𝑡

    =𝐶𝑡𝑁𝑡

    +𝐼𝑡𝑁𝑡

    𝑦𝑡 = 𝑐𝑡 + 𝑖𝑡,

    • All „per worker” qunatities are denoted by lower case (small) letters .

    • An excpetion is the saving reate (s), or the saved fraction of income.

    • Consumption per worker is given by:𝑐𝑡 = 1 − 𝑠 𝑦𝑡

    8

  • A neoclassical per capita production

    function

  • Notice that

    • The per capita production function depends only on

    per capita capital stock

    • If we understand the dynamics of capital per capita

    we can understand economic growth!

  • The accumulation of capital per person

    • We know that capital in period t+1 is given by:𝐾𝑡+1= 𝐾𝑡 + 𝐼𝑡 − 𝑑𝐾𝑡

    𝐾𝑡+1−𝐾𝑡 = ሶ𝐾𝑡 = 𝑠𝑌𝑡 − 𝑑𝐾𝑡

    • Notice that we are interested in the dynamics of capital per worker (k)

    𝜕𝑘𝑡𝜕𝑡

    =𝜕𝐾𝑡𝑁𝑡𝜕𝑡

    =ሶ𝐾𝑡𝑁𝑡 − ሶ𝑁𝑡𝐾𝑡

    𝑁𝑡2 =

    ሶ𝐾𝑡

    𝑁𝑡

    𝑁𝑡𝑁𝑡

    −ሶ𝑁𝑡𝐾𝑡

    𝑁𝑡2 =

    =𝑠𝑌𝑡 − 𝑑𝐾𝑡

    𝑁𝑡−

    ሶ𝑁𝑡

    𝑁𝑡

    𝐾𝑡

    𝑁𝑡= 𝑠𝑦𝑡 − 𝑑𝑘𝑡 − 𝑛𝑘𝑡

    11

  • The accumulation of capital per person

    Fundamental equation of the (simple) Solow growth model:

    ሶ𝒌 = 𝒔𝒚𝒕 − (𝒅 + 𝒏)𝒌𝒕

  • Saving and investment

    y

    k

    f(k)

    sf(k)

    k1

    y1

    i1

    c1

  • The „effective deprecation” or „break-even

    investment”

    y

    k

    (d+n) k

    Investment needed to keep ‘k’at a constant level

  • Moving toward the steady-state

    y

    k

    sf(k)

    (d+n)k

    k*k1

    investment

    depreciation

    k

  • The steady state

    • Recall: ሶ𝑘 = 𝑠𝑦𝑡 − (𝑠 + 𝑛)𝑘𝑡

    •If investment is just enough to finance effective depreciation:

    𝑠𝑦𝑡 = (𝑑 + 𝑛)𝑘𝑡

    •then capital per worker will remain constant: ሶ𝑘 = 0

    This constant value, denoted k*, is called the steady state value of capital stock.

  • The steady-state

  • The steady-state

    y

    k

    y*

    y=f(k)

    s f(k)

    k*

    (+n) k

  • The steady-state

    • The only possible steady-state capital–labor ratio is k*

    • Output at that point is y* = f(k*); consumption is c* = f(k*) – s f(k*) = f(k*)-(n + d)k*

    • If k begins at some level other than k*, it will move toward k*

    – For k below k*, saving > the amount of investment needed to keep k constant, so k rises

    – For k above k*, saving < the amount of investment needed to keep k constant, so k falls

  • The steady-state

    • We have established that in the steady-state, capital per person is constant.

    • That, of course implies that output per person and consumption per person are also constant:

    0===•••

    cyk

  • The Solow’s suprise

    • Investment in new capital cannot lead to continued growth in per capita income.

    • What can lead to sustained growth of output per person?

    • As we will see next week – technology!

  • The steady-state

    • What about the growth rates of K (capital) and Y (output)in the steady-state?

    • Recall that K=kN; Y=yN

    • Therefore:

    •ሶ𝐾

    𝐾=

    ሶ(𝑘𝑁)

    𝑘𝑁=

    ሶ𝑘𝑁+𝑘 ሶ𝑁

    𝑘𝑁=

    ሶ𝑘

    𝑘+

    ሶ𝑁

    𝑁

    • In the steady-state:

    •ሶ𝐾

    𝐾= 0 + 𝑛 = 0

    • Exactly the same reasoning applies to ሶ𝑌

    𝑌

  • The steady-state - summary

    • In the steady-state, the per worker values are stable:

    • In the steady-state, Y & K & C exhibit are characterized by steady growth rate equal to the rate of growth of population:

    0===

    •••

    c

    c

    y

    y

    k

    k

    nC

    C

    Y

    Y

    K

    K===

    •••

  • Steady-state: a Cobb-Douglas production function

    • Assume a Cobb-Douglas function:

    • 𝑌𝑡 = 𝐾𝑡∝𝑁𝑡

    • Intensive form (per worker):

    • 𝑦𝑡 = 𝑘𝑡∝

    • The steady-state:

    • ሶ𝑘 = 0

    • ሶ𝑘 = 𝑠𝑘∝ − 𝑑 + 𝑛 𝑘 = 0

    • 𝑠𝑘∝ = 𝑑 + 𝑛 𝑘

    •𝑠

    (𝑑+𝑛)= 𝑘1−∝

    +=

    1

    1

    )(*

    nd

    sk

  • The Solow Model

    • To summarize:– With no productivity growth, the economy reaches a

    steady state, with constant capital per person (or capital–labor ratio), output per person, and consumption per person

    – In the steady-state, the amount of capital per person output per person and consumption per person depend, among others on:

    • the saving rate (s)

    • the rate of population growth (n)

    • and on the depreciation rate (d)

  • The effect of an increased saving rate on the steady-state capital and output per person

  • An increase in the saving rate

    An increase of s increases k*, and y*.

    y

    k

    y1*

    y=f(k)

    s1 f(k)

    k1*

    (+n) k

    k2*

    y2*

    s2 f(k)

  • Prediction:

    • Higher s higher k*.

    • And since y = f(k) , higher k* higher y* .

    • Thus, the Solow model predicts that countries with

    higher rates of saving and investment

    will have higher levels of capital and income per

    worker in the long run.

  • The effect of a higher population growth rate on the steady-state capital–labor ratio

  • Population growth rate and GDP per capita

    30

  • The Solow Model

    • Should a policy goal be to reduce population growth?– Doing so will raise consumption per worker– Note however that the Solow model also assumes that

    the proportion of the population of working age is fixed (exactly: population = workers)

    • But when population growth changes, this may change the % of the working-age population

    • Changes in cohort sizes may cause problems for social security systems and areas like health care

  • The Golden Rule: Introduction

    • Different values of s lead to different steady states. How do we know which is the “best” steady state?

    • The “best” steady state has the highest possible consumption per person: c* = (1–s) f(k*).

    • An increase in s

    – leads to higher k* and y*, which raises c*

    – reduces consumption’s share of income (1–s), which lowers c*.

    • So, how do we find the s and k* that maximize c* (in the steady-state)?

  • The Golden Rule capital stock

    the Golden Rule level of capital per worker:the steady state value of k that maximizes steady-state consumption per person.

    *

    goldk =

    To find it, first express c* in terms of k*:

    c* = y* − i*

    = f (k*) − sy*

    = f (k*) − (d+n)k*

    In the steady state:

    sy* = (d+n)k*

  • • Then, differentiate with respect to k, to find the value of k* that maximises c*:

    The Golden Rule capital stock

    )(*)('

    0)(*)('*

    *

    0*

    *

    *)(*)(*

    ndkf

    ndkfdk

    dc

    dk

    dc

    kndkfc

    +=

    =+−=

    =

    +−=

  • Graph

    f(k*) and (d+n)k*;

    look for the

    point where

    the gap between

    them is biggest.

    The Golden Rule capital stocksteady state output and

    depreciation

    steady-state capital per

    worker, k*

    f(k*)

    (d+n)k*

    *

    goldk

    *

    goldc

    * *

    gold goldi k=* *( )gold goldy f k=

  • The Golden Rule capital stock

    c* = f(k*) − (d+n)k*

    is biggest where the

    slope of the

    production function

    equals

    the slope of the

    depreciation line:

    steady-state capital per

    worker, k*

    f(k*)

    k*

    *

    goldk

    *

    goldc

    MPK = (d+n)

  • The golden rule: an example using C-D p.f.• Let’s assume a Cobb-Douglas production function:

    • 𝑌𝑡 = 𝐾𝑡∝𝑁𝑡

    • In intensive form:

    • 𝑦 = 𝑘∝

    • Consumption in the steady-state is:

    • ሶ𝑐∗ = 𝑓 𝑘 − 𝑑 + 𝑛 𝑘

    • Maximise it with respect to capital

    •𝑑𝑐∗

    𝑑𝑘=∝ 𝑘𝐺𝑂𝐿𝐷

    ∝−1 − d + n = 0

    • 𝑘𝐺𝑂𝐿𝐷∝−1 =

    𝑑+𝑛

    • 𝑘𝐺𝑂𝐿𝐷∗ = (

    𝑑+𝑛)

    1

    1−∝

    • This is the steady-state level of capital per worker that maximises consumption per worker

  • How much do we need to save, to achieve „k GOLD”?

    • Recall that in the steady-state:

    • 𝑘∗ =𝑠

    𝑑+𝑛

    1

    1−∝

    • Since the „golden-rule” level of capital per person is also the steady-state capital per person, then we know that

    • 𝑘∗ = 𝑘𝐺𝑂𝐿𝐷∗

    •𝑠

    𝑑+𝑛

    1

    1−∝= (∝

    𝑑+𝑛)

    1

    1−∝

    • This implies that the saving rate s that is needed to reach maximum consumption in the steady state is equal to α

    • 𝑠𝐺𝑂𝐿𝐷 =∝

  • The transition to the „Golden Rule” steady-state

    • The economy does NOT have a tendency to move toward the „Golden Rule” steady state.

    • Achieving the Golden Rule requires thatpolicymakers adjust s to reach sgold

    • This adjustment leads to a new steady state with higher consumption.

    • But what happens to consumption during the transition to the Golden Rule?

  • Starting with too much capital

    then increasing c*

    requires a fall in s.

    In the transition to

    the Golden Rule,

    consumption is

    higher at all points

    in time.

    If goldk k* *

    timet0

    c

    i

    y

  • Starting with too little capital

    then increasing c*

    requires an increase in s.

    Future generations enjoy higher consumption, but the current one experiences an initial drop in consumption.

    If goldk k* *

    timet0

    c

    i

    y

  • Summary

    • The economy will reach a steady-state, where the values of capital & output & consumption per worker will be constant

    • Investment in new capital (and the growth of population) cannot lead to continued growth in per capita income.

    • GDP per worker in the steady-state depends on (among others): the saving rate and the population growth rate

  • What’s ahead?

    • Discussing convergence (next week)

    • Adding technology to the Solow’s model (next week)

    • A very quick glimpse at different growth models