the ‘economics of attention’: a new avenue of research … the “economics of attention”: a...

31
THE ‘ECONOMICS OF ATTENTION’: A NEW AVENUE OF RESEARCH IN COGNITIVE ECONOMICS Documents de travail GREDEG GREDEG Working Papers Series Agnès Festré Pierre Garrouste GREDEG WP No. 2012-12 http://www.gredeg.cnrs.fr/working-papers.html Les opinions exprimées dans la série des Documents de travail GREDEG sont celles des auteurs et ne reflèlent pas nécessairement celles de l’institution. Les documents n’ont pas été soumis à un rapport formel et sont donc inclus dans cette série pour obtenir des commentaires et encourager la discussion. Les droits sur les documents appartiennent aux auteurs. The views expressed in the GREDEG Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the institution. The Working Papers have not undergone formal review and approval. Such papers are included in this series to elicit feedback and to encourage debate. Copyright belongs to the author(s). Groupe de REcherche en Droit, Economie, Gestion UMR CNRS 7321

Upload: dangdieu

Post on 01-May-2018

223 views

Category:

Documents


4 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

THE ‘ECONOMICS OF ATTENTION’: A NEW AVENUE OF RESEARCH IN COGNITIVE ECONOMICS

Documents de travail GREDEG GREDEG Working Papers Series

Agnès FestréPierre Garrouste

GREDEG WP No. 2012-12

http://www.gredeg.cnrs.fr/working-papers.html

Les opinions exprimées dans la série des Documents de travail GREDEG sont celles des auteurs et ne reflèlent pas nécessairement celles de l’institution. Les documents n’ont pas été soumis à un rapport formel et sont donc inclus dans cette série pour obtenir des commentaires et encourager la discussion. Les droits sur les documents appartiennent aux auteurs.

The views expressed in the GREDEG Working Paper Series are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the institution. The Working Papers have not undergone formal review and approval. Such papers are included in this series to elicit feedback and to encourage debate. Copyright belongs to the author(s).

Groupe de REcherche en Droit, Economie, GestionUMR CNRS 7321

Page 2: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

1

The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics

by Agnès Festré

University of Picardie (CRIISEA) and University of Nice-Sophia Antipolis (GREDEG1)

and

Pierre Garrouste

University Nice-Sophia Antipolis (GREDEG)

Introduction

One of the main problems of our contemporary economies is not the access to information but

rather information overload, which competes with an insufficient and limited amount of

attention. The rising activity of bloggers or the intense use of social networks (Facebook,

Twitter, etc.) is a clear indication of how crucial this problem is today. One of the main

consequences of this limited attention is indeed that information goods providers are seeking

to capture users’ attention by more and more sophisticated devices that permit to

search, filter and communicate the data that are relevant and useful for consumers (Varian and

Shapiro, 1999). This is why we speak nowadays of the “economics of attention2”. In recent

years, several economists have addressed the problem of limited attention, which Camerer

(2003) listed as one of the more important topics of behavioural economics3. Even in the field

of macroeconomic policy, rational inattention – namely, which parts of macroeconomic data

should rational agents evaluate if limited-processing capacity forces them to discard part of

the data? – has been pinpointed by central bankers as one of the lessons to be drawn from the

1 GREDEG is a Research Group in Law, Economics and Management, UMR 7321, University of Nice-Sophia

Antipolis and CNRS (National Center for Scientific Research).

2 The first appearance of the notion of attention in this field is due to Michael Goldhaber (1997) in a seminal on-

line article where he describes the economics of attention as a sub-field of the “Internet economics”, focusing on

the time-consuming dimension of information, especially when it is overflowing as it is the case in the so-called

Internet Economy where “information glut” have now become commonplace. In such contexts, attention (rather

than information or even knowledge) has become a critical economic resource for decision-making, and attention

a major incentive for business.

3 “Another interesting psychological concept, neglected in behavioral economics until recently, is limited

attention. Attention is the ultimate scarce cognitive resource. It is possible to learn to attend to many stimuli at

the same time—as busy financial-market floor traders and cell-phone-using drivers do—but long-term memory

suffers. Scarce attention might be useful for explaining economic phenomena like organizational structure

(division of labor expands organizational attention but is constrained by the need to coordinate) and advertising

(which “grabs” attention).” (Camerer, 2003, p. 16).

Page 3: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

2

2008 financial crisis4 and by some economists as an alternative to the assumption of rational

expectations in inflation forecasting notably (Akerlof, Dickens and Perry 2000, Sims 2003,

Shiller 1997). In the field of financial theory, a paper by Hirschleifer and Teoh (2003)

analyzes the implications of investors’ limited attention for firms’ information policy and

financial market equilibrium.

In management sciences, Davenport and Beck (2001) look at attention from the perspective of

business economics. In other scientific fields such as biology, Dukas (2004) reviews the

evolutionary roots of limited attention and its role in the fitness of animals.

The concept of attention is however a very old one in social sciences. Originally a

philosophical, then a psychological concept, it became popularized in economics thanks to

Herbert Simon, whose work on information and cybernetics in the 50s focused on the

interference between information and cognitive capacities, thus making crucial the issue of

attention scarcity. Contrary to what is usually assumed in economic analysis, namely

unlimited perfect rationality, he considered that the human brain had inherent limits due to

both language articulation and storage capacity.

In particular, we think that the notion of attention could be fruitfully applied to many other

concrete situations than those considered so far, as well as to more abstract theoretical issues

such as, for instance, the problem of convergence of individual decisions or actions towards a

focal point raised for the first time by Schelling in 1960.

This chapter is an attempt to assess the fertility of an economic approach of attention that

draws insights from other disciplines, more specifically, cognitive psychology. This endeavor

also aims at opening up new directions in research in cognitive economics (for a presentation

of existing approaches in cognitive economics, see Egidi and Rizzello 2004, 2 vols.).

The chapter is organized as follows. Section 1 shows that the historical roots of the notion of

attention arose from philosophy, then became an object of intense study in psychology and

subsequently penetrated the fields of economics and organization sciences. Section 2presents

the main characteristics of what is called nowadays the ‘economics of attention’. Section 3

concludes by developing a research agenda on this topic.

4 As indicated by Trichet in his opening address dedicated to “Lessons from the crisis for macroeconomics and

finance theory” at the ECB Central Banking Conference held in Frankfurt in November 2010: “When the crisis

came, the serious limitations of existing economic and financial models immediately became apparent. (…) we

may need to consider a richer characterisation of expectation formation. Rational expectations theory has

brought macroeconomic analysis a long way over the past four decades. But there is a clear need to reexamine

this assumption. Very encouraging work is under way on new concepts, such as learning and rational

inattention.”

Page 4: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

3

1. The historical roots of the notion of attention

1.1.Originally a philosophical, then a psychological concept

At its origin the concept of attention was mainly interesting philosophers. Aristotle, for

instance, in De Anima, accepted the assumption that the stronger stimulus tends to extrude the

weaker, but did not conclude that, as a consequence, two objects could be perceived

simultaneously (see Hatfield, 1995, p.8). In fact, before the birth of psychology as an

autonomous science in the 18th

century5, philosophers typically considered attention with the

context of apperception, which refers to the mechanism by which something is identified from

a substrata and new ideas became associated with existing ones. Malebranche (1675) viewed

attention as a natural mechanism allowing the perceptions to be clearer. Condillac (1754)

considered that attention could be identified to sensation and distinguished ‘passive’ attention

(given by the senses) from ‘active’ attention (linked with memory). Leibniz (1704) suggested,

using the metaphor of one’s loss of awareness of the constant sound of a waterfall, that events

could cease to be apperceived (i.e., represented in consciousness) without specific attention.

He therefore claimed that attention determined both what is and what is not apperceived6.

The term of apperception was still employed in the 19th

century by Wundt (1832-1920), one

of the founders of modern psychology, in order to describe different concentric fields of

awareness from general (Blickfeld) to focal (Blickpunkt) features of human awareness. But

one of the most influential works on attention in psychology is found in William James’s

Principles of Psychology (1890), where attention is defined as follows:

“Every one knows what attention is[7]

. It is the taking possession by the mind, in clear

and vivid form, of one out of what seem several simultaneously possible objects or

trains of thought. Focalization, concentration, of consciousness are of its essence. It

5 For a history of the concept of attention in psychology, see Hatfield ([1995] 1998).

Hatfield ([1995] 1998) claims that the notion of attention has been introduced in psychology in 1730 by Wolff

(1738). 6 For a history of the notion of attention in philosophy, see Théodule Ribot (1889) and the introduction by Serge

Nicolas of Ribot (2007). 7 One century later, Pashler points out the difficulty one has to define and grasp the concept of attention: “No one

knows what attention is, … and…There may even not be an ‘it’ there to be known about (although of course

there might be)”. (Pashler, 1998, p. 1).

Page 5: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

4

implies withdrawal from some things in order to deal effectively with others and is a

condition which has a real opposite in the confused, dazed, scatterbrained state which

in French is called distraction and Zerstreutheit in German.” (James, The Principles of

Psychology, 1890, p. 403-404).

In James’ time, the method more commonly used to study attention was introspection, except

for earlier isolate attempts to measure attention and one of the major debate of this period was

whether it was possible to split attention (i.e., to attend to two things at a time) or to attend to

something in a state of distraction8.

But unfortunately, while methods to measure attention were developing, the study of attention

as a mental process became marginalized by the rise of behaviourism and positivism.

Behaviourism’s principal advocates John Watson, was interested primarily in stimulus-

response relations, and therefore, confined attention to an operational concept defined in

terms of discriminative response to external stimuli9.

Interest in attention revived during the cognitive revolution of the 1940s, when engineers and

applied psychologists became involved in problems of man-machine interaction in various

military contexts. Gradually, the individual came to be viewed as a processor of information.

From this perspective, attention was conceived, in compliance with the principles of

information theory (Shannon 1948), as a function of the improbability of an event to happen

and of the frequency of similar past events (which provides a measure of the surprise value or

the degree of novelty). Thus an event that has never been experienced before has a high

surprise value and should attract attention, even if it lacks any specific associations or

consequences. This seems at odds with the diffused, even though paradoxical, idea that

8 As reminded by Hatfield ([1995] 1998), the first empirical works attempting to measure attention can be traced

back to Wolff (1738) or Bonnet (1755). Later one, Donders (1858), a Dutch ophthalmologist, provided one of

the first major advances in measuring attention while working on the anomalies of accommodation and

refraction on the eye (physiologic dioptrics), using mental chronometry. Pillsbury (1906) suggested three

methods for measuring attention: the first relied upon tests that measured performance of a task judged to require

a high degree of attention; the second measured diminished attention through decreased performance; and the

third gauged the strength of attention by the stimulus level required to distract the individual. In parallel,

Titchener (1908) identified seven laws that were empirically discovered by psychologists working on attention:

“clearness is an attribute of sensation”, “the law of two levels” – which accepts that clearness of one part-

contents of consciousness implies the decreased clearness of all the rest , the law of accommodation”, “the law

of prior entry”, “the law of limited range”, “the law of temporal instability” and “the law for measuring the

degree of attention” (see Hatfield, [1995] 1998). 9 Previous experiments between 1907 and 1910 by the Russian physiologists Pavlov and Bekhterev on dogs and

animals showed that the conditioned responses to stimuli included measureable signs of attention such as

pricked-up ears, head turned towards the stimulus, increased muscular tension, etc.

Page 6: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

5

attention depends on both the unexpectedness of events and of their familiar association. This

drawback, together with the recognition by cognitive psychologists of the incalculable effect

of past experience on the information carried by any binary digit ultimately led them to

abandon information theory.

In modern psychology, traditional views have focused on selective attention10

, following

seminal experiments by Colin Cherry (1953) and Broadbent (1958) on dichotic listening:

subjects use a set of headphones to listen to two streams of words in different ears and

selectively attend to one stream. Attention was modeled as a selection filter and the main

research question was whether the selection filter operated before or after cognitive

processing (early vs. late selection models of attention11

).

Recent advances in imaging technology, particularly the development of functional magnetic

resonance imaging (fMRI) in the 1990s, have provided evidence of a neural correlate of

selective attention (Posner and Raichle, 1994) in agreement with former experiments

performed on monkeys in the 1960s12

.

In 1973, Kahneman developed a famous model of executive attention13

which broke with the

prevailing tradition of filter theories14

, by relying on the assumption that there is one central

10

Selective attention is often loosely defined. A few definitions from the literature are: “the differential

processing of simultaneous sources of information” (Johnson and Dark, 1986, p. 44); “a system of cognitive

processes that manages the burden of having too much to do at once by prioritizing among stimuli to be

processed” (Carr, 2004, p. 56); and “the generic term for those mechanisms which lead our experience to be

dominated by one thing rather than another’ (Driver, 2001, p. 53). Nowadays, one point of agreement is that

selective attention is a broad concept covering many distinct mechanisms operating in a variety of brain systems,

if not the entire system rather than one specific function or mechanism as some scientists maintain. For instance,

Posner (2004) localized this function in the “attentional organ system”, LaBerge (2004) in the “triangular

circuit” and McKnight (2007) in the synchronization of activity between prefrontal, parietal and mediotemporal

cortex. 11

Broadbent (1958) and Triesman (1969) conclude in favor of early selection models, showing that attention

shuts down or attenuates processing in the unattended ear before the mind can analyze its semantic content. At

the opposite, Deutsch and Deutsch (1963) support the late selection view by showing that the content in both

ears is analyzed semantically, even if the words in the unattended ear cannot access consciousness. Results like

that of MacKay (1973) posed problems for filters theories, by showing that even unconscious stimuli could be

processed to a high degree. For a survey on the early literature on attention in psychology, see Kahneman and

Triesman (1984). 12

For instance, Robert Wurtz, a neuroscientist specialized in physiology of the visual system at the National

Institute of Health began to record electrical signals from the brains of macaques trained to perform attentional

tasks in the beginning of the 70s. 13

The notion of executive attention is even more loosely defined that the one of selective attention. It is defined

by Posner and Rothbarth (1998) as “the regulation of thought, emotion and behavior.” (Posner and Rothbart,

1998, p. 1915). Norman and Shallice include planning, conflict resolution, decision-making, error correction,

and overcoming habitual responses to perform novel or difficult tasks as executive processes (Norman and

Shallice, 1986, pp. 2-3). The consensus seems that executive attention involves centralized supervisory control,

which and requires two important functions 1) information about and 2) causal influence over the things

supervised and controlled.

Page 7: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

6

resource limited capacity for attention (based in the frontal cortex) for which all activities

requiring attention compete15

. It is to be noted that this model derives from Kahneman’s

well-known dual-task system based on the differentiation between endogenous (voluntary)

and exogeneous (involuntary/automatic) control in. In Kahneman’s words, voluntary attention

means that the subject attends to stimuli because they are relevant to a task that he has chosen

to perform (Kahneman 1973, p. 4), whereas involuntary attention is related to level of arousal,

which is largely controlled by the properties of the stimuli to which an organism is exposed.”

(p. 3). Kahneman’s model has been criticized on the ground that it involved a “homunculus

problem”: to wit, “a little man inside the brain” (Allport, 1980, p. 113) who directs attention.

For Stinson (2009), this homunculus problem16

is attached to all theories of attention when

top-down17

, or executive attention is thought of as a cause rather than an effect. Moreover,

Stinson argues that neither empirical evidence in neurosciences nor computational models

purporting to support causal executive theories of attention can set down the issue in a

14

See, for instance, the highly influential feature integration theory of Triesman and Gelade (1980). According

to this theory, attention binds different features of an object (e.g. color and shape) into consciously experiences

wholes. 15

Pashler (1998) summarises the empirical evidence obtained in attention psychology research under the term

controlled parallel processing, asserting that capacity limits and perceptual gating both characterize human

perceptual processing (Pashler 1998, p. 224). According to this author, many controversies in psychology

research result from the fact that some researchers identify the concept of attention with the allocation of a

limited processing capacity to a given set of items, while others relate attention to the selection of this set by a

gating mechanism. The gating mechanism implies that mental resources are allocated only to those items that

have passed the perceptual filter, while the rest is ignored. Wickens (1980) refers to Kahneman’s model as an

approach focusing on the ‘energetic’ side of attention as compared to filter theories that focus on its ‘selective’

side. As summarized by Ruz, “whereas selection theories aimed at localizing the point in the processing chain

(from perception to motor responses) at which irrelevant stimuli were filtered out (i.e., the location of the

‘bottleneck’), energetic views investigated how resources were divided among tasks or the unitary or multiple

nature of this ‘attentional energy’.” (Ruz, 2006, p. 499).

16 “The homunculus problem could more generally be attached to any explanation of how a mechanism achieves

a given ability that involves the assumption that some part of the mechanism has the ability.” (Stinson, 2009, p.

7) 17

Another distinction found in the psychological literature is between bottom-up and top-down approaches of

attention. Bottom-up attention is thought of as arising directly from outside stimuli (e.g. flashing lights, sudden

noises, or any stimulus that has either instinctive or learned importance, such as the sight of a predator, or the

sound of your name). These stimuli evoke stronger neural responses than less salient stimuli regardless of task,

environment, or training. Top-down attention is thought of as arising from internal stimuli such as memories and

thought.

But this distinction (like the distinction between early and late selection – see above) is somewhat troublesome

since 1) it is not enough for a stimulus to be right in front of your eyes for you to attend to it as the examples of

“inattentional blindness” (Rees, Russell, Frith and Driver, 1999) and “change blindness” (Rensink, O’Reagan

and Clark, 1997) exemplify; 2) like similar distinctions between automatic vs. controlled, stimulus-driven vs.

goal-directed, passive vs. active, and exogenous vs. endogenous, it has both literal and metaphorical meanings,

and could either imply direction of processing or level of automacity, although the two meanings do not always

match (Stinson, 2009, p. 139).

Page 8: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

7

satisfactory way18

. If trying to define attention as a whole, and attempting localizing it as such

in the brain seems a fruitless approach, a decomposition strategy aiming at developing

taxonomy of attention at the appropriate level of explanation is potentially useful for

suggesting provisional definitions of what attention might be. For instance, in the taxonomy

provided by Posner and Fan (2004), attention is conceptualized as a system of different

anatomical areas that is composed by three distinct and specialized modules: the alerting

network; the orienting network and the executive network19

. For authors who conceive science

as a self-corrective enterprise, such decomposition can be used to support, modify or falsifies

proposed mental taxonomies of the mind. The problem is due to the fact that different

taxonomies of attention coexist. It is not problematic per se but the result is that the empirical

results could be very different. As an example, the relations between attention, working

memory and intelligence depend on the kind of attention that is used. Sustained attention is

significantly correlated with intelligence but divided attention is not (Schweizer and

Moosbruger, 2004, p. 330).

Attention is now viewed by some psychologists as functioning as networks connecting

distributed areas of the brain, although these “networks support not only the general functions

of attention common to all people, but also the individual differences that relate to aspects of

temperament and intelligences.” (Posner and Rothbart, 2007, p. 18).

In a nutschell, in recent years, there has been extensive research aimed at supporting the

production of mental taxonomy, with converging evidence coming from different domains

(psychology, psychophysiology, cognitive sciences, psychophysics, and so on)20

.

Let us no investigate how the notion of attention penetrated the field of economics.

18

Whether the study of the biological basis of cognition (thanks to the introduction of neuroimaging techniques

in particular) can be useful for the understanding of cognitive processes in general (or those involved by

attention in particular) is in itself a controversial issue. A first line of criticism argues that the understanding of

higher cognitive functions in the brain is impossible given the lack of modularity of these processes and the

nonlinear and dynamic nature of brain functioning (Uttal, 2001). A second line of criticisms claims that

cognitive processes are independent of its biological implementation, and thus the information about the brain is

not relevant to explain how cognition takes place (Fodor, 1999). 19

The alerting network is conceptually related to ‘energetic’ theories of attention and generates change in the

preparatory state of the organism in expectation of an incoming stimulus; the orienting network selects stimuli

from sensory input and involves both voluntary and automatic changes in the allocation of attention, while the

executive network monitors and resolves conflicts between different representations in the control of behavior.

20 Eye tracking as an example is used to analyze the way individuals read (and then learn to read) (Just and

Carpenter 1980; Baccino and Manunta, 2005) but also the effects of advertising (Pieters, Rosenberg and Wedel,

1999; Pieters, Wedel and Zhang , 2007) and more generally the relations between eye movements and

individuals’ behavior.

Page 9: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

8

1.2. The diffusion of the notion of attention in economics and organizational

sciences

The beginning of the diffusion of the notion of attention into economics and

organizational sciences may be traced back to Herbert Simon.

Ocasio (1997), who is known for having developed an “attention-based view” of the firm,

refers to Simon’s early work on administrative behaviour (1947) and reminds that Simon’s

well-known ‘limited rationality’ assumption hinges on the limited attentional capability of

humans and serves as a justification for the existence of organizations and institutions as

means of orienting attention. As Simon wrote, “Organizations and institutions provide the

general stimuli and attention-directors that channelize the behaviors of the members of the

group, and that provide the members with the intermediate objectives that stimulate action.”

(Simon, 1947, pp. 100-101). Simon’s contribution is therefore characterized by a dual

emphasis on cognition (limited attention capacity) and structure (how organization shapes

individual’s attention). In later works, he anticipated some of the topical economic literature

devoted to attention allocation in information-rich environments (see e.g. Falkinger 2007

2008): “(…) in an information-rich world, the wealth of information (…) creates a poverty of

attention and a need to allocate that attention efficiently among the overabundance of

information sources that might consume it.” (Simon, 1971, p. 40).

Simon’s influence first penetrated the field of organization theory, where the concept of

attention has a long history and tradition (see Festré and Garrouste 2012). Different authors

have stressed different aspects of attention allocation and structuring, but not in a unified

perspective. In particular, they have emphasized either attention as shaped by routines and

bounded rationality (March and Simon, 1958; Cyert and March, 1963), or alternatively, how

attention as loosely coupled through enactment processes (Weick, 1979) and organized

anarchy (Cohen, March and Olsen, 1972). But in the process, as pointed out by Ocasio, “the

effects of the social structure on the channelling and distribution of decision-makers’ attention

have been greatly deemphasized if not entirely ignored.” (Ocasio, 1997, p. 188). Ocasio

(1997) tries to restore this important feature of Simon’s contribution by developing an

explanation for firm behaviour based on the structuring of organizational attention.

Organization attention processing and regulation is shown to be the result of three principles:

at the level of individual cognition, the principle of focus of attention links attentional

processing to individual cognition and behaviour; at the level of social cognition, the principle

Page 10: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

9

of situated attention highlights the importance of the situational context in explaining what

decision-makers attend to; at the organizational level, the principle of structural distribution of

attention builds explain how the firm’s economic and social structures regulate and channel

issues, answers, and decision-makers into the activities, communications, and procedures that

constitute the situational context of decision-making.

Rerup (2010) extends Ocasio’s framework by focusing not only on top-down senior

management processes in directing attention but also on their synchronization with bottom-up

processes, which are ignored by Ocasio’s approach. This “synchronized prospective

attention” (as he calls it) is of prime importance when non-salient but potentially very

damaging threats are involved in organizations. These situations are characteristic of the

health care sector (Madsen et al. 2006), of military or intelligent activities (Baker and Hulse,

2009), or of air traffic control, were organizations need to swiftly allocate attention to

emerging issues.

Research on visual attention using eye tracking techniques21

has also been a source of

inspiration for management sciences in general and marketing in particular. Pieters and

Warlop (1999) analyse the impact of time pressure and task motivation on visual attention

during brand choice. First, they show that consumers with high task motivation filter brand

information less and pictorial information more. Second, they show that consumers under

time pressure filter textual ingredient information more, and pictorial information less. Those

results have interesting implication for packaging and shelf lay-outs strategies.

Pieters, Rosenberg and Wedel (1999) address attention wear-out and the impact of repetition

on advertising effectiveness using eye-tracking methodology and scanpath theory22

. Their

findings confirm that attention duration drops over repeated exposures to advertisements and

suggest that when consumers can control exposure duration themselves, such as with print or

electronic advertising, they adapt exposure duration to limit satiation. In a related study,

Pieters and Wedel (2007) test whether consumers can control their visual attention to

21

Major contributors to visual attention are LaBerge (1983) and Eriksen and St James (1986). La Berge was

inspired by the work of William James and developed the so-called “spotlight” model, which describes visual

attention as having a focus, a fringe, and a margin. Eriksen and St James developed a second model, called the

“zoom-lens” model, which extends the spotlight model by adding the property for attention to be changing in

size. Michael Posner (Op. Cit) is also known for his seminal work in the 1990s on selective visual attention. 22

Scanpath theory (Noton and Stark 1971, Stark 1994) postulates relatively stable patterns of eye fixations. In

the context of print advertising, those features facilitate identification of the advertisements’ content in repeated

exposures.

Page 11: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

10

advertising with processing goals23

and a free-viewing condition. They show that an ad-

memorization goal enhances attention to the body text, pictorial and brand design objects,

whereas a brand-learning goal enhances attention to the body text but simultaneously inhibits

attention to the pictorial design. Those results supports the thesis that ad informativeness and

attention is goal contingent rather than a dumb process guided by perceptual salience of the ad

stimuli only. In the same vein, Orquin (2011) applies eye tracking techniques and provides

insights for designing product packages so as to catch attention of consumers on supposedly

relevant features such as health cues for instance.

Robert Lanham24

(2006), who attempts to trace the intellectual roots of what he calls the

“economics of attention”, also refer to Gregory Bateson and Friedrich von Hayek as forunners

of the ‘economics of attention’ (for a more precise history of economic thought account of the

notion of attention, see Festré and Garrouste, 2012) . On the one hand, Bateson (1972)

insisted on the scarcity of conscious attention, an economy he called ‘systemic awareness’.

On the other hand, Sensory Order (1952), Hayek defines attention as a “state of excitatory

preparedness”, which is not restricted to the conscious level (it can be involuntary) and which

is of pecular importance for permitting “a social or conventional representation of the world

which [the individual] share with his fellows.” (Hayek, 1952, p. 140 and p. 142).

Let us now investigate how the notion of attention is dealt with in current economic analysis.

2. The “economics of attention”: The state of the art

Very broadly, one can distinguish between two different approaches of attention economics.

On the one hand, attention economics is considered as a ramification of information

economics which derives from Shannon’s mathematical theory of communication (Shannon

1948). This approach assumes full rationality and deals with sub-optimalities caused by

asymmetric information and information overload. Key empirical issues relate to information

pollution and its solutions (market-based mechanisms, institutional or regulatory devices). On

the other hand, attention economics also refers to economic approaches that characterize

limited attention as a justification for near-rational or bounded rational behaviors.

23

Those processes include two learning goals (ad-memorization and brand learning), one appreciation goal and

one evaluation goal. 24

Robert Lanham is Professor emeritus of English literature at UCLA. His book The Economics of Attention is

about the move from an economic system based on things and objects to an economics of attention where the

central commodity is not stuff but style, i.e., what he labels fluff, for style is what competes for our attention

amid the din and deluge of new media in order for us to make sense of overflowing information.

Page 12: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

11

2.1. Attention economics as a ramification of the economics of information

According to this approach, “attention economics” is conceived as a ramification of the so-

called “economics of information and networks” (cf. Varian and Shapiro 1999). From this

perspective, the specific questions raised by the attention economy are amenable to standard

economic analysis. Attention is described as a scarce good that is likely to be depleted due to

an overload of information. This implies that the real value that is brought by an information

provider is given by its capacity to localize, to filter and to communicate the relevant

information to users. It is no coincidence that most successful websites are Internet search

engines since those websites allow users to find the most relevant information while avoiding

all the rest of non useful information. For instance, the success of Google lies in precise

assignment of advertisement links to the context of the keywords that are searched by the

user. Briefly, from this perspective, attention economics is about the interplay of attention and

information, and discuss the various possibilities of information providers to particularize

information in order to catch users’ attention. Business strategies of price or product

differentiation such as price discrimination (personalized price or preferably group pricing

due to the existence of network externalities, switching costs and product sharing) or product

differentiation (e.g. providing two versions of the same information good in order to favor

self-selection of consumers) provide ways to capture attention. In other words, more and more

detailed and precise methods of acquisition of information on the user’s needs, and

consequent exact targeting of the advertising are a key to successful marketing strategies. In a

nutshell, the objective is not only to attract the attention of the user but also to give him/her

with higher utility providing him with more relevant information, i.e., to pay attention to

him/her. Amazon.com provides a good illustration of the twofold perspective of “catching the

attention on something or somebody” on one hand, and on “paying attention to someone” on

the other.

Some of the features of the website are indeed dedicated to make clients feel they are paid

attention to: e.g., personalized services such as historical record of personal account, updates

sent via e-mails, twitter or text, recommendations, polls, discussion forums, etc. Some others,

by contrast, are clearly intended to catch the attention of clients: e.g., hits, free trials of

services, free applications, deals of the day, shopping and shipping facilities, etc.

Page 13: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

12

The fact that attention is becoming a rare resource has dramatic empirical consequences for

information users. An important literature looks indeed at the problem raised by the explosion

of electronic interactions and particularly to development of web spam. It is costly for the

receiver to open spam just because first he does not know ex ante if the message he opens is

or not a spam, and second he needs to mobilize, perhaps loosely his attention on the message.

There is then an asymmetry of information between the sender, who knows the contents of the

message and the receiver, who does not. Typically, this situation is a case of externality,

whereby information pollution is imposed by the sender of the message to the receiver. Three

main solutions – namely, technological, institutional or market-based – have been proposed to

reduce the welfare losses induced by spams. The two first are intuitive, trying to set up anti-

spam filters for the first and enforcing laws for the second25

. The third one includes stamps

(Kraut et al. 2002 2005), surcharges on communications and auctions (Zandt, 2001) or

attention bond mechanism (Loder, Van Alstyne and Wash, 2004). Market-based solutions

relates to Ronald Coase’s (1960) ideas to control externalities. They are either based on

experiments that are design to test whether charging a price for sending electronic mails could

have a disciplinary effect on senders or/and whether it may inform recipients about the value

of a message to the sender before they read it (Kraut et al. 2005). Zandt (2001) discusses the

potential benefit of implementing mechanisms for allocating attention such as surcharges on

communications and auctions. He shows that the mechanisms increase the cost of sending

messages and shift the task of screening messages from the receivers to the senders. An

increase in the supposedly low communication cost benefits most (but not all) receivers. By

contrast it is beneficial to receivers only if this tax is redistributed to them by lump-sum

transfers to receivers or if the sender’s information about the receivers is accurate. Loder, Van

Alstyne and Wash (2004) shows the superiority of the Coasian solution of individual

negotiation over the worth of a given message (e.g. the information known to the sender

rather than the content of the message) rather than a unilateral decision by a controlling party

in presence of information asymmetry. Even if such negotiation itself however consumes

attention and carries with it an attention cost, in certain cases, recipients can be better off than

even a cost-free perfect filter. In this model, the attention cost consists in ‘attention bonds’

that play the role of screening devices.

Some other works like the one of Huberman and Wu (2007) try to understand how attention

propagates and eventually fades away as a result of collective action.

25

According with Lodor, Van Alstyne, and Wash (2004), the laws are difficult to enforce, in particular because

the spammers are very much fly-by-night creatures.

Page 14: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

13

In sum, it is interesting to note that the economics of attention seen as a ramification of

information theory conveys two conflicting rationales for economic agents, depending on

whether it focuses on the user or the provider of information: on one side, there are economic

and management models that analyze how it is possible for firms to capture the attention of

customers or audiences in order to make money from it; on the other side, one finds analyses

that focus on the overload of information from the viewpoint of consumers and provide

solutions in order to protect the attention of users from information overload and pollution.

Kessous, Mellet and Zouinar (2010), who adopt an economic sociology perspective, point out

this discrepancy in the literature and interpret effective innovations in the digital economy as

attempts to reconcile customer relationship (CRM26

) and vendor relationship (VRM27

)

management practices.

As already mentioned, the economic literature on attention also includes approaches that

borrow from cognitive psychology and characterize limited attention as a justification for

near-rational or bounded rational behaviors.

2.2. Attention and ‘bounded’ rationality

The other strand of literature on attention economics is tightly related to the heritage of

Herbert Simon. As well known, this heritage has given rise to two different interpretations

depending on which part of the work of Simon is focused on: the pars destruens, criticizing

neoclassical view, or the pars construens, consisting of an attempt to model behavior in a

more realistic way (cf. Rizzello 1999).

26

CRM is a widely implemented model for managing a company’s interactions with customers, clients, and

sales prospects. It involves using technology to organize, automate, and synchronize business processes—

principally sales activities, but also those for marketing, customer service, and technical support. The overall

goals are to find, attract, and win new clients; nurture and retain those the company already has; entice former

clients back into the fold; and reduce the costs of marketing and client service

27 AttentionTrust provides a good example of VRM practices. It consists of a set of principles to govern the

attention economy on the self-ownership of the data we create, and specialized software to regulate their use.

Specifically, AttentionTrust believes that we all have the right 1) to own at least a copy of our data, 2) to store

that data where we want and move it when we want, 3) to exchange it for something of value to us, and 4) to

know what others intend to do with our data, so that we can make informed decisions about who should have

access to it. (http://www.attentiontrust.org/blog). More generally, VRM is a category of business activity made

possible by software tools that provide customers with both independence from vendors and better means for

engaging with vendors. The term was coined by Mike Vizard on a Gillmor Gang podcast on September 1, 2006,

in a conversation with Doc Searls about the project Searls had recently started as a fellow at the Berkman Center

for Internet & Society at Harvard University. It was conceived as the necessary complement of CRM.

Page 15: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

14

According to the first interpretation, bounded rationality is seen as a limitation to human

rationality. This is the line privileged by Kahneman and Tversky in the debate on heuristics

and bias when they considered that experimental findings represented deviations from the

norm of rationality conveyed by expected utility theory. By contrast, the second interpretation

implies that bounded rationality is seen as an adaptive capacity. This conception is endorsed

by the stream on ‘ecological rationality’ (Smith, Nobel Lecture 2002; Gigerenzer and Todd

1999) according to which fast, information-economizing and frugal heuristics based on salient

rules can be efficient means of reasoning28

. In such a perspective, rationality is contingent to

the institutional environment and can only be measured in an evolutionary perspective.

To be sure, the emerging macroeconomic literature on rational inattention we have hinted at

in the introduction is clearly to be related to the first interpretation. But, unlike former

attempts in terms of adaptive expectations, assuming rational inattention or limited attention

provides microfoundations for economic behavior that look enough like the familiar rational

expectation assumption to ensure usefulness and tractability, while the implications for policy

are different enough to be interesting (Sims 2003, p. 1). For instance, Akerlof, Dickens and

Perry (2000) show that assuming near-rational wage and price setting in macroeconomic

modeling does not impair the robustness of the results and is consistent with some empirical

findings. On the other hand, the assumption of limited attention is based on observations that

have been documented by Shiller (1997): people usually misperceive effective real (as

opposed to nominal) changes either because inflation is low and therefore, not a matter of

focal awareness or because their attention is focus on local concerns and therefore, not taking

into account pay available to them in alternative jobs contrary to what general equilibrium

theory postulates they do (Shiller, 1997, pp. 31-32). Shafir, Diamond, and Tversky (1997)

reach similar conclusions. In one vignette, which they related to respondents, these authors

draw a contrast between Ann, who receives a 2 percent nominal salary increase at zero

inflation, and Barbara, who gets a 5 percent nominal salary increase at 4 percent inflation.

Most respondents correctly considered that Ann would be better off economically, but they

28

The « heuristics and biais » program of Kahneman and Tversky (cf. Tversky and Kahneman, 1974) refers to a

conception of rationality that permits to preserve Savage’s (1954) theory of choice under uncertainty and

founded behavioural economics, which may be described as “a set of exceptions that modifies but leaves intact

the canonical model of rational choice, not least since it is irrational to suppose that people in general behave

irrationally.” (The Economist, 29-04-2006).

On the other hand, the “fast and frugal heuristics” program (Gigerenzer and Goldstein 1996) violates

fundamental tenets of classical rationality. In particular, the assumption that individuals neither look up nor

integrate all information conveys a context-dependent conception of rationality that Vernon Smith will later label

‘ecological rationality’, which refers to the effectiveness of a behavioral rule within its ecological context

(Vernon Smith’s Nobel Lecture 2002).

Page 16: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

15

also said that Barbara would be happier and less likely to leave her job. In a slightly different

way Reis (2006b) assumes that producers29

face costs of acquiring, absorbing and processing

information. “When the producer does obtain information, conditional on it he or she decides

whether to set prices or quantities, which price to charge or which quantities to sell for the

duration of the plan, and next to plan.” (Reis, 2006b, 795). Those assumptions and findings

have several important implications: First, they imply that a not too low positive rate of

inflation should permit a higher level of employment to be sustained, at a cost which would be

rather small. Second, they suggest that if inflation increases, the costs of being less than

perfectly rational about it should also rise, inducing people to switch their behavior to take

inflation into full account. And third, if higher satisfaction at low rates of inflation leads to

higher morale, less shirking, higher productivity, and less turnover, then firms face a different

efficiency wage constraint at low rates of inflation than they face at either zero inflation or at

high rates of inflation, when worker’s attitudes toward inflation may become more rational.

Therefore, there should be a positive but low optimal rate of inflation that minimizes the

sustainable level of unemployment.

In the same vein, Falkinger (2008) develops a general equilibrium model based on empirical

research comparing information-rich and information-poor economies. Explicit reference to

Simon’s work is made. In particular, Simon’s idea that information wealth implies a poverty

of attention is further explored by using a framework where consumers are conceived as

passive signal receivers whereas information providers are seeking to catch their attention by

sending messages. Falkinger also refers to Kahneman’s dual-task approach by considering

that individuals are endowed with a limited mental capacity. How they (voluntarily) process

an additional signal depends on the spare capacity left after the load imposed by exposure to

other signals. Moreover, there exists a minimum (marginal) strength of a message in order for

it to be perceived by the consumers. When total signal exposure lies below a certain level,

there is no interference between different signals. Beyond this point, capacity limits lead to

such interference. Falkinger concludes that information-rich economies characterized as of

lacking enough attention (contrary to information-poor economies) reach an inefficient

equilibrium due to attention-seekers engaging in wasteful signaling in the competition for

attention. In addition, Falkinger notes that there may be consequences for welfare to the

extent that the set of information attended to in information-rich economies is not guaranteed

to be optimal.

29

In Reis (2006a) the consumers are considered as having a limited attention.

Page 17: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

16

The second interpretation of limited attention derived from bounded rationality is embodied in

a second series of theoretical and experimental developments, which focus on attention

allocation in problem solving and stress the importance of processes in decision making. The

experimental contributions (see Camerer et al. 1993, Camerer and Johnson 2004, Costa-

Gomes 2001 2006, Gabaix et al. 2006) use the ‘Mouselab’ programming language to measure

subjects’ information acquisition. Information is hidden behind boxes on a computer screen

and subjects have to use the computer mouse to open (or close) the boxes in order to get

(costly) information that helps solving a problem (of income maximization) in a given limited

period of time. On the one hand, Mouselab records permit to know the order and duration of

information acquisition. On the other hand, since one screen box can be open at any time, it is

possible to know what information is acquired on a second-by-second basis throughout the

experiment. Gabaix et al. (2006) provide a step further by testing a theoretical process-based

model of cognition based on partially myopic cost-benefit calculations which they label the

Directed Cognition (DC) model (Gabaix and Laibson 2005). This model predicts rather well

experimental findings using the Mouselab technology. However, experiments also reveal a

deviation from the DC model by supporting the existence of some heuristics like the “box

heuristic”, namely, the tendency for subjects to become more and more likely to end an

analysis of a problem the more boxes they open holding fixed the economic benefit of

additional analysis. This means that to a certain extent, subjects display a partial insensitivity

to the particular circumstances of the problem they face, a cognitive bias similar to what

Camerer and Lovallo (1999) have labeled “system neglect”.

This literature also parallels earlier work on the notion of accessibility and salience by

Kahneman. In the Kahneman’s dual cognitive system based on the distinction between

intuition (system 1) and reasoning (system 2)30

, accessibility, i.e., “the ease with which

particular mental contents come to mind” (Higgins 1996 quoted by Kahneman in his 2002

Nobel Lecture, Kahneman 2003, p. 1452) is conceived as cumulative: experimental evidence

shows that the more a person acquires information and competence in a particular domain, the

more he (or she) becomes able to recall and use part of his knowledge. In Kahneman’s own

terms: “The acquisition of skill selectively increases the accessibility of useful responses and

of productive ways to organize information. The master chess player does not see the same

board as the novice, and the skill of visualizing the tower that could be built from an array of

30

As noted by Egidi (2012, p. 205), this distinction was first introduced by Schneider and Shiffrin (1977).

Page 18: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

17

blocks could surely be improved by prolonged practice. (Kahneman in his Nobel Lecture,

Kahneman 2003, p. 1453). This implies that accessibility has different levels and that some

operations demand more mental efforts than others. Moreover, accessibility is largely

dependent on salience, especially in the intuitive ‘system 1’:

“Physical salience also determines accessibility: if a larger green letter and a small blue

letter are shown at the same time, ‘green’ will come to mind first. However, salience can

be overcome by deliberate attention: an instruction to look for the smaller letter will

enhance the accessibility of all its features” (Kahneman, Nobel Lecture 2002, 2003, p.

1453).

From this quotation we understand that salience is a key feature of accessibility but that it

may easily be manipulated by directing attention to specific features that either give access or

hide others. In the Gorilla experiment of Simons and Chabris (1999), people are told to count

the number of passes between players wearing white. The results of this experiment suggest

that the likelihood of noticing an unexpected object (here the Gorilla), depends on the

similarity of that object to other objects in the display and on how difficult the priming

monitoring task is. One could imagine an experimenter to tell slightly different instructions,

e.g. to count the number of passes between players wearing black instead of white T-shirts

and see whether the similarity in terms of color (black) between the Gorilla and the T-shirts

enhances the accessibility to the Gorilla or not. Another variant of the Gorilla experiment has

been made using ‘subliminal priming’ of people to race by showing them stereotypically

black and white names. When subsequently shown the ‘invisible gorilla’ video, “only 45% of

the participants exposed to the White names noticed the gorilla. But 70% of the participants

who saw the Black names noticed the gorilla.”31

In sum, Kahneman’s concept of accessibility is related to the notion of stimulus, salience,

selective attention, and response activation or priming.

Finally, salience is not a purely individual characteristic. It also happens at the collective level

as the game “target the two” of Cohen and Bacdayan (1994) and Egidi and Narduzzo (1997)

as well as experiments by Mehta, Starmer and Sugden (1994) illustrate.

In the next section, we suggest a research agenda that derives from this promising strand of

the literature.

31

http://www.stanford.edu/group/gender/cgi-bin/wordpressblog/2011/07/the-continued-dehumanization-of-

blacks/

Page 19: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

18

3. Research agenda on the “economics of attention” and conclusion

The surveyed literature on the economics of attention shows clearly that there does not exist a

unified theoretical framework in order to deal with the notion of attention in economics. In

this section, we attempt to define a research agenda for future developments on the role of

attention in economic decisions by focusing on three different levels: individual,

organizational and social.

3.1. At the individual level

A preliminary distinction needs to be made between ‘paying attention to someone’ and

‘paying attention to something’. In the first case and in compliance with the theoretical

literature on others-regarding preferences, individuals are no more supposed to be indifferent

to others. Moreover, as evidenced by experiments on bargaining games, the level of

generosity of agents is context-dependent (see e.g. Levitt and List 2007 for a comparison

between laboratory and field experiments). By the same token, it could be conjectured that the

attention that people pay to others varies according to the setting (competitive vs. cooperative)

or the social distance (akin vs. stranger). In the case of paying attention to something and

assuming limited attention, it is important to know first, what is the extend of the attention

scarcity and second, how individuals deals with it. The first question is linked to the idea that

individuals, as in Camerer and Johnson (2004), do not search for the same information

because they vary in the way they solve a problem. The second question concerns the variety

of alternative uses of a given information depending on the problem that is faced.

Several directions of research follow from these questions. A first line of research could be to

explore the various ways an individual pays attention to somebody or to something according

to different parameters. As an example, it is possible to run experiments that make people

competing or cooperating and investigate whether it has an impact on the strength of their

attention to others. In order to test for the strength, it would be necessary to run experiments

where the degree of social distance between players can be controlled (in terms of gender, age

and activity). A possible treatment could consist in matching a group of old people with a

group of young people. A second direction could be to identify and measure different kinds of

attentional determinants. For instance, one can consider that attention paid to something

depends on the nature of the problem to be solved, the type of performance index, the salience

of a signal and the emotional context. As for the first determinant, the replication of Camerer

Page 20: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

19

and Johnson (2004)’s experiments could be a means to test for the type of problem to be

solved. As for the second, it could be interesting to run experiments where the elapsed time

and, alternatively, the correctness of the answer given to a problem would constitute the

performance indices. As for the third, the question amounts to evaluate how strong a signal

must be in order to have an impact on behavior and how it competes with other signals. In

essence, this would provide an empirical test of Falkinger (2008) model which involves the

determination of a minimum of the strength of a signal in order for the information to be

perceived by the consumers. Finally, it could be interesting to analyze the relationships

between emotion and attention. For instance, experiments using trash vs. sweet stimuli before

subjects play a given game could be run.

Ultimately, these investigations should contribute to increased knowledge of relevant

dimensions of attention at the individual level. It could possibly lead to the definition of an

individual’s utility function that takes into account the fact that attention is bounded and that

its strength and direction depend on a set of factors that are possible to identify by means of

controlled experiments.

3.2. At the organizational level

The implications of attention scarcity for firm structure are linked with how attention

coordination of heterogeneous individuals’ attention happens. Because cues have asymmetric

salience and are interpreted differently (see Rerup, 2010), it is important to analyse 1) the

way(s) individuals converge in terms of the attention they pay on the same or different

information and 2) how they succeed in coordinating their interpretation in order to take a

common decision.

Accordingly a first direction could be to study the way individuals pay attention to the same

information, in what context they pay an equal or unequal attention, and the way they give

attention to complementary information assuming that they have to take a common decision.

Experiments could be run, where first individuals have the same sets of information in terms

of price and quality of a good and have to decide collectively whether or not to buy it and

second, they have sets of information concerning either the price or the quality of a good and

have to decide collectively whether or not to buy it.

Page 21: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

20

Another perspective of research could be to look at the way individuals’ attention converges

towards a solution when these individuals have to coordinate their actions. Accordingly

people would have to play games with different sets of information and different ways of

evaluating their performance. As in a moral hazard model, people have private information

and one can investigate 1) the conditions under which an optimal contract can be proposed by

a principal to his/her agents; 2) whether the principal is induced or not to screen hidden

actions; and 3) if the agents tend or not to signal their information if they may benefit from

this signaling. In these experiments, attention scarcity would be assumed by introducing a

limited time for subjects to decide.

3.3. At the social level

Unlike the individual and organizational levels, at the social level, individuals are not

consciously willing to take a collective action. They only undertake to solve a problem of

coordination. There is now an important literature on focal points and salience (Schelling,

1978; Bacharach and Bernasconi, 1997; Sugden, 1995, 2011) in order to explain the

emergence of a solution when facing a coordination problem. Basically the idea is to explain

how people solve social dilemma that are characterized by the absence of equilibrium (i.e. the

fashion game played sequentially) or by the presence of multiple (i.e. the pure coordination

game) or sub-optimal equilibrium (i.e. the prisoner dilemma). The objective would be here to

test the theoretical results that this literature has produced. As an example, it could be possible

to use pure coordination games where some information is added in order for individuals to

discriminate between different possible solutions. Another possibility would be to test for the

emergence of a mixed equilibrium in a battle of sexes game when the information sets are

given to people playing the game. This is indeed not far from Bacharach and Bernasconi

(1997) experiments of the Variable Frame Theory of focal points in matching games.

Another line of research could be to combine explanations given by economists and other

social scientists in order to explain the convergence of individuals’ attention toward collective

attention. In social philosophy for instance there are recent works due to Gilbert (1989) or

Tuomela (2000) that try to explain the emergence of collective action by considering that

“collective action problems typically have the structure of a Prisoner's Dilemma game or a

Chicken game” (Tuomela, 2001, p.3). From a different perspective, sociologists emphasize

that joint attention is a mental condition for interactive cooperation to emerge. Accordingly it

Page 22: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

21

might be interesting to compare and try to integrate both explanations given by sociologists

and economists of the emergence of collective action as based on collective attention.

Acknowledgments

We thank warmly Roger Koppl for his comments and suggestions on an early version of this

chapter presented at the Annual Conference of the Society for the Development of Austrian

Economics held in Washington DC, 19-21 November 2011.

Page 23: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

22

References

Akerlof, G. A., Dickens, W.T., and Perry, G.L. 2000. “Near-rational wage and price setting

and the long-run Phillips Curve.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 1-60.

Allport, D.A. 1980. “Attention and performance.” In G. Claxton (ed.), Cognitive Psychology:

New Directions. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

Aristotle [330 B.C.] 1984. Sense and sensibilia, trans. by J. I. Beare. In Complete Works of

Aristotle, edited by J. Barnes, 2 vols. Princeton: Bollingen.

Baccino, T., Manunta, Y. 2005. “Eye-fixation-related potentials: Insights into parafoveal

processing.” Journal of Psychophysiology, 19(3): 204-215.

Bacharach, M., Bernasconi, M. 1997. “The variable frame theory of focal points: An

experimental study.” Games and Economic Behavior, 19: 1-45.

Baker, P., Hulse, C. 2009 “U.S. had early signals of a terror plot, Obama says.” New York

Times, December 30.

Bateson, G. 1972. Steps to an Ecology of Mind. Chicago, The University of Chicago Press.

Bonnet, Ch. 1760. Essai analytique sur les facultés de l’âme. Copenhagen: Philibert.

Brainard, W.C. and Perry, G.L. 2000. “Making policy in a changing world.” In J. Tobin and

G. Perry (Eds.), Economic Events, Ideas, and Policies: The 1960s and After, Brookings

Institution Press.

Broadbent, D. 1958. Perception and Communication. Pergamon Press.

Camerer, C.F. 2003. “The behavioral challenge to economics: understanding normal people.”

Paper presented at Federal Bank of Boston 48th Conference on 'How humans behave:

Implications for economics and policy', June.

Camerer, C. F., Johnson, E., Rymon,T., Sen, S. 1993. “Cognition and framing in sequential

bargaining for gains and losses.” In K. Binmore, A. Kirman and P. Tani (Eds.), Frontiers of

game theory, Cambridge, MA., MIT Press, pp. 27-47.

Camerer, C.F., Johnson, E.J. 2004. “Thinking about attention in games: Backward and

forward induction.” In I. Brocas and J. D. Carrillo (Eds.),The psychology of economic

decisions (vol.2.): Reasons and choices, Oxford, Oxford University Press, pp. 111-129.

Camerer, C., Lovallo, D. 1999. “Over confidence and excess entry: An experimental

approach.” American Economic Review 89: 306-318.

Carr, T.H. 2004. “A multilevel approach to selective attention: Monitoring environmental

space, choosing stimuli for deep processing, and retrieving information from memory.” In

M.I. Posner (ed.), Cognitive neuroscience of attention. New York: Guilford Press, pp. 56-71.

Cherry, E.C. 1953. “Some experiments on the recognition of speech; with one and with two

ears.” Journal of the Acoustical Society of America, 25: 975-979.

Page 24: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

23

Coase, R. 1960. “The problem of social cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 11(1): 67-73.

Cohen, M. D., Bacdayan, P. (1994). “Organizational Routines Are Stored as Procedural

Memory: Evidence Form a Laboratory Study.” Organization Science 5(4): 554-568.

Cohen, M.D., March, J.G. and Olsen, J.JP. 1972. “A garbage can model of organizational

choice.” Administrative Science Quarterly, 17: 1-25.

Condillac, E.B. 1754. Traité des sensations (2 vol.). Paris : De Bure Aîné.

Costa-Gomes, M. A., Crawford, V.P. 2001. “Cognition and behavior in normal-form games:

An experimental study.” Econometrica 69(5): 1193-1235.

Costa-Gomes, M. A., Crawford, V.P. 2006. “Cognition and behavior in two-person guessing

games: An experimental study.” American Economic Review 96(5): 1737-1768.

Cyert, R.M., March, J.G. 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ.:

Prentice-Hall.

Davenport, T. H., Beck, J.C. 2001. The attention economy: Understanding the new currency

of business. Harvard : Harvard Business School Press.

Deutsch, J.A. and Deutsch, D. 1963. “Attention: some theoretical considerations.”

Psychological Review, 70: 80-90.

Down, A. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy, New York: Harper.

Driver, J. 2001. “A selective review of selective attention research form the past century.”

British Journal of Psychology, 92, 53-78.

Dukas, R. 2004. “Causes and consequences of limited attention.” Brain Behavior and

Evolution 63: 197-210.

Egidi, M. 2012. “The cognitive explanation of economic behaviour: from Simon to

Kahneman.” In R. Arena, A. Festré and N. Lazaric (Eds.), Handbook of Knowledge and

Economics, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.

Egidi, M., Narduzzo, A. 1997. “The emergence of path dependent behaviors in cooperative

contexts.” International Journal of Industrial Organization 15(6): 677-709.

Egidi, M., Rizello, S. (Eds.) 2004. Cognitive Economics (vol. I and II), Aldershot, Edward

Elgar.

Eriksen, C. and St James, J. 1986. “Visual attention within and around the field of focal

attention: A zoom lens model.” Perception & Psychophysics, 40(4): 225-240.

Fair, R.C. 2000. “Testing the NAIRU Model for the United-States.” Review of Economics and

Statistics, 82(1): 64-71.

Falkinger, J. 2007. “Attention economics.” Journal of Economic Theory 133(1): 266-274.

Page 25: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

24

Falkinger, J. 2008. “Limited attention as a scarce resource in information-rich economies.”

The Economic Journal, 118: 1596-1620.

Festré, A., Garrouste, P. 2012. “The ‘economics of attention’: Historical roots and their

relevance for current debates”, GREDEG working paper.

Fodor, J. 1999. “Let your brain alone.” London Review of Books, 21, 19.

Gigerenzer, G., Goldstein, D.G. 1996. “Reasoning the fast and frugal way: models of

bounded rationality.” Psychological Review, 103(4): 650-669.

Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P.M. & the ABD Research Group. 1999. Simple heuristics that make us

smart. Oxford, Oxford University Press.

Gilbert, M. (1989). On Social Facts. London: Routledge.

Goldhaber, M. H. (1997), “The Attention Economy and the Net”, First Monday 2 (4),

<http://www.firstmonday.org/issues/issue2_4/goldhaber/>.

James, W. 1890. The Principles of Psychology. New York: H. Holt and Company.

Johnston, W.W. and Dark, V.J. 1986. “Selective attention.” Annual Review of Psychology, 37:

43-75.

Gabaix, X., Laibson, D. 2005. “Bounded rationality and directed cognition “ Mimeo.

Gabaix, X., Laibson, D., Moloche, G., Weinberg, S. 2006. “Costly information-acquisition:

experimental analysis of a boundedly rational model.” American Economic Review, 96: 1043-

1068.

Hatfield, G. [1995] 1998. “Attention in early scientific psychology.” IRCS Report 95-29,

Institute for Research in Cognitive Science, University of Pennsylvania. Reprinted in 1998 in

R. D. Wright (Ed.), Visual Attention, Oxford, Oxford University Press, pp. 3-25.

Hayek, F.A. 1952. The Sensory Order: An Inquiry into the Foundations of Theoretical

Psychology. The University of Chicago Press.

Higgins, E.T. 1996. Knowledge activation: Accessibility, applicability, and salience. In T.

Higgins and A. Kruglanski (Eds.), Social Psychology: Handbook of basic principles, New

York, Guilford Press, pp. 133-168.

Hirshleifer, D. and Teoh, S.H. 2003. “Limited attention, information disclosure, and financial

reporting.” Journal of Accounting and Economic, 36: 337-386.

Huberman, B.A., Wu, F. 2007. “Novelty and collective attention.” Proceedings of the

National Academy of Sciences of the United States, 104(45): 17599-17601.

Johnson, W. A., Dark, V.J. (1986). “Selective attention.” Annual Review of Psychology 37:

43-75.

Page 26: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

25

Just, M.A., Carpenter, P.A. 1980. “A theory of reading: From eye fixations to

comprehension”, Psychological Review, 87: 329-354.

Kahneman, D. 1973. Attention and Effort. Englewoof Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

Kahneman, D. (2002, 2003). “Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral

economics.”, Nobel Prize Lecture, December 8, also in The American Economic Review,

93(5): 1449-1475.

Kahneman, D., Tversky, A. 1979. “Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk.”

Econometrica, 47, pp. 263-91.

Kahneman, D. and Triesman, A. 1984. “Changing views of attention and automaticity.” In R.

Parasuranam and D.R. Davies (eds.), Varieties of attention. Orlando, FL: Academic Press.

Kessous, E., Mellet, K., Zouinar, M. 2010. « L'Economie de l'attention : entre protection des

ressources cognitives et extraction de la valeur. » Sociologie du Travail, 52(3): 359-373.

King, R.G. and Watson, M.W. 1994. “The Post-War U.S. Phillips curve: A revisionist

Econometric History.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 41: 157-219.

Kirzner, Israel. 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago

Press.

Kirzner, I. 1997. “Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: An Austrian

approach.” Journal of Economic Literature, 35(1): 60-85.

Kraut, R. E., Sunder, S., Telang, R., Filer, D., Cronin, M. 2002. “Markets for attention: will

postage for email help?” Working paper, available at

http///basic.fluid.cs.cmu.edu/articles/kraut02.

Kraut, R. E., Sunder, S., Telang, R., Morris, J. (2005). Pricing electronic mail to solve the

problem of spam. Human-Computer Interaction, 20: 195-223.

LaBerge, D. 1983. “Spatial extent of attention to letters and words.” Journal of Experimental

Psychology, Human perception and Performance, 9(3): 371-379.

LaBerge, D. 2004. “Attention, awareness, and the triangular circuit.” In B.J. Baars, W.P.

Banks, and J.B. Newman (eds.), Essential sources in the scientific study of consciousness,

Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press, pp. 291-318.

Lanham, R. 2006. The Economics of Attention: Style and Substance in the Age of Information.

Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Leibniz, G.W. 1704. Nouveaux essais sur l’entendement humain. New Edition. Paris: Garnier-

Flammarion 1966.

Levitt, S.D., List, J.A. 2007. “What do laboratory experiments tell us about the real world?”

Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(2): 153-175.

Page 27: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

26

Loder, T.C., Van Alstyne, M.W., Wash, R.L. (2004). Information asymmetry and thwarting

spam. SSRN Working Paper n° 488444.

MacKay, D.G. 1973. “Aspects of a theory of comprehension, memory, and attention.” In B.J.

Baars, W.P. Banks, and J.B. Newman (eds.), Essential sources in the scientific study of

consciousness, Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press, pp. 235-250.

Madsen, P., Desai, V., Roberts, K., Wong, D. 2006. “Mitigating hazards through continuing

design: The birth and evolution of a pediatric intensive care unit.” Organization Science, 17:

239-248.

Malebranche, Nicolas de. 1675. De la recherche de la vérité, où l’on traite de la nature de

l’esprit de l’homme et de l’usage qu’il doit en faire pour éviter l’erreur dans les sciences (2

vol.). Paris : A. Pralard.

March, J. G., Simon, H.A. (1958). Organizations. New York: Wiley.

Mehta, J., Starmer, C., Sugden, R. 1994. “The nature of salience: An experimental

investigation of pure coordination games.” American Economic Review 84(3): 658-673.

McKnight, R.T. 2007. “Neural networks debunk phrenology.” Science, 309:75.

Neumann, O. 1971. Aufmerksamkeit. In Historisches Woerterbuch der Philosophie, new. Ed.

By J. Ritter. Darmstadt: Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft, vol. 1, cols. 635-645.

Norman, D.A. and Shallice, T. 1986. “Attention to action: Willed and automatic control of

behavior.” In R.J. Davidson, G.E. Schwartz, and D. Shapiro (Eds.), Consciousnesss and self-

regulation: Advances in research and theory. New York: Plenum Press, pp. 1-18.

Noton, D. and Stark, L. 1971.”Scanpaths in eye movements during pattern perception.”

Science, 171: 398-311.

Ocasio, W. 1997. “Towards an attention-based view of the firm.” Strategic Management

Journal, 18(7): 187-206.

Orquin, J. L. (2011). “Attention to health cues on product packages.” Journal of Eye

Tracking, Visual Cognition and Emotion, 1(1): 59-63.

Pashler, H.E. 1998. The Psychology of Attention. Cambridge: Mass.: MIT Press.

Pieters F.G.M. and L. Warlop (1999), Visual attention during brand choice: The impact of

time pressure and task motivation. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 16, 1-16.

Pieters, F.G.M. and Wedel, M. 2007. “Goal Control of Attention to Advertising: The Yarbus

Implication”, Journal of Consumer Research, 34: 224-233.

Pieters F.G.M., Rosbergen, E. and Wedel, M. 1999. “Visual attention to repeated print

advertising: A test of scanpath theory.” Journal of Marketing Research, 36(4): 424-438.

Pillsbury, W.B. 1906. L’attention. Paris: Octave Doin.

Page 28: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

27

Posner, M.I. 1994. “Attention: The mechanisms of consciousness.” Proceedings of the

National Academy of Sciences USA, 91: 7398-403.

Posner, M.I. 2004. Cognitive neuroscience of attention. New York: Guilford Press.

Posner, M.I. and Fan J. 2004. “Attention as an organ system.” In J.R. Pomerantz and M.C.

Crai (Eds.), Topics in integrative neuroscience: from cells to cognition, Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.

Posner, M.I. and Raichle, M. 1994. Images of Mind. Scientific American Library.

Posner, M.I. and Rothbarth, M.K. 1998. “Executive attention: Conflict, target selection, and

cognitive control.” In R. Parasuraman (ed.), The executive brain, Cambridge Mass.: MIT

Press, pp. 401-423.

Rees, G., Russell, C., Frith, C.D. and Driver, J. 1999. “Inattentional blindness versus

inattentional amnesia for fixated but ignored words.” In B.J. Baars, W.P. Banks, and J.B.

Newman (eds.), Essential sources in the scientific study of consciousness, Cambridge, Mass.:

The MIT Press, pp. 227-234.

Reis, R. 2006a. “Inattentive consumers.” Journal of monetary economics, 53: 1761-1800.

Reis, R. 2006b. “Inattentive producers.” Review of Economic Studies, 73: 793-821.

Rensink, R.A., O’Reagan, J.K. and Clark J.J. 1997. “To see or not to see: The need for

attention to perceive changes in scenes.” In B.J. Baars, W.P. Banks, and J.B. Newman (eds.),

Essential sources in the scientific study of consciousness, Cambridge, Mass.: The MIT Press,

pp. 251-261.

Rerup, C. 2010. “Prospective attention: Synchronizing top-down and bottom-up attention to

non-salient issues.” Working Paper.

Ribot, T. [1889], 2007. Psychologie de l’attention. New Edition 2007, Paris: L’Harmattan.

Rizzello, S. 1999. The Economics of the Mind. Aldershot, Edward Elgar.

Ruz, M. 2006. “Let the brain explain the mind: The case of attention.” Philosophical

Psychology, 19(4): 495-505.

Romer (Eds.), Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy, Chicago: University of Chicago

Press.

Schelling, T.C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Oxford, Oxford University Press.

Schelling, T.C. 1978. Micromotives and Macro Behavior. New York, W.W. Norton and Co.

Schneider, W., Shiffrin, R.M. 1977. “Controlled and automatic human information

processing: Perceptual learning, automatic attending and a general theory.” Psychological

Review 84(2): 127-190.

Schweizer, K., Moosbrugger, H. 2004. “Attention and working memory as predictors of

intelligence.” Intelligence 32: 329-347.

Page 29: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

28

Shafir, E., Diamond, P. and Tversky, A. 1997. “Money illusion.” Quarterly Journal of

Economics, 112(2): 341-74

Shannon, C. E. 1948. “A mathematical theory of communication.” Bell System Technical

Journal, 27: 379-423 and 623-656.

Shiller, R. 1997. “Why do people dislike inflation?” In Christina.D. Romer and David .H.

Romer (Eds.). In Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy, Chicago: University of

Chicago Press.

Sims, C. A. 2003. “Implications of rational inattention.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 53:

1761-1800.

Smith, V. 2002. “Nobel Lecture”, December 8, Interdisciplinary Center for Economic

Science, George Mason University, Fairfax.

Sugden, R. 2011. “Salience, inductive reasoning and the emergence of conventions.” Journal

of Economic Behavior & Organization 79(1-2): 35-47.

Simon, H. A. 1947. Administrative Behavior: A Study of Decision-making Processes in

Administrative Organizations. Chicago, IL.: Macmillan.

Simon, H.A. 1971. “Designing Organizations for an Information-Rich World”, written at

Baltimore, MD, in Martin Greenberger, Computers, Communication, and the Public Interest,

The Johns Hopkins Press.

Simons, D. J., Chabris, C.F. 1999. “Gorilla in our midst: Sustained inattentional blindness for

dynamics events.” Perception, 28(9): 1059-1074.

Stark, L. 1994. “Sequences of fixations and saccades in reading.” In J. Ygge, G. Lennerstrand

(Eds.), Eye movements in reading. Tarrytown, NY: Elsevier Science Inc., pp. 151-163.

Stinson, C. 2009. “Searching for the source of executive attention.” Psyche, 15(1): 137-154.

Sugden, R. 1995. “A theory of focal points.” The Economic Journal 105(430): 533-550.

Titchener, E. B. 1908. Lectures on the elementary psychology of feeling and attention.

New York: Macmillan.

Trichet, J-C. 2010, Opening address at the ECB Central Banking Conference,

Frankfurt, 18 November 2010.

Triesman, A.M. 1969. “Strategies and models of selective attention.” In B.J. Baars, W.P.

Banks, and J.B. Newman (Eds.), Essential sources in the scientific study of consciousness.

Cambridge, Mass.: Academic Press, pp. 207-226.

Triesman, A.M and Gelade, G. 1980. “A feature-integration theory of attention.” Cognitive

Psychology, 12: 97-136.

Tuomela, R. 2000. Cooperation: A Philosophical Study. Kluwer Academic Publisher.

Page 30: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

29

Tuomela, R. 2001. “Collective Intentionality and Social Agents” Paper invited for the AI

conference IMF, Toulouse, May 21-23, 2001.

Tversky A., Kahneman, D. 1974. “Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases.”

Science, 185: 1124-1131.

Uttal, W.R. 2001. The new phrenology: The limits of localizing cognitive processes in the

brain. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Varian, H. R., Shapiro, C. 1999. Information Rules: A strategic Guide to the Network

Economy. Harvard: Harvard Business School Press.

Weick, K.M. 1979. The Social Psychology of Organizing (2nd Edition). New York, Random

House.

Wicksens, C.D. 1980. “The structure of attentional resources.” In R.S. Nickerson (ed.),

Attention and Performance VIII, Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum, pp. 239-258.

Wolff, C. 1738. Psychologia empirica. Frankfurt and Leipzig: Officina Libraria Rengeriana.

Zandt, T. v. 2001. Information overload in a network of targeted information. CEPR

Discussion Paper n° 2836, London.

Page 31: The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research … The “economics of attention”: a new avenue of research in cognitive economics by Agnès Festré University of Picardie

DOCUMENTS DE TRAVAIL GREDEG PARUS EN 2012GREDEG Working Papers Released in 2012

2012-01 Frédéric Marty Les clauses environnementales dans les marchés publics : perspectives économiques2012-02 Christophe Charlier Distrust and Barriers to International Trade in Food Products: An Analysis of the US- Poultry Dispute2012-03 Gérard Mondello The Equivalence of Strict Liability and Negligence Rule: A Trompe-l’Œil Perspective2012-04 Agnès Festré & Pierre Garrouste Somebody May Scold You! A Dictator Experiment2012-05 Dorian Jullien & Nicolas Vallois A Probabilistic Ghost in the Experimental Machine2012-06 Gérard Mondello Ambiguity, Agency Relationships, and Adverse Selection2012-07 Flora Bellone, Kozo Kiyota, Toshiyuki Matsuura, Patrick Musso & Lionel Nesta International Productivity Gaps and the Export Status of Firms: Evidence from France and Japan2012-08 Tiziana Assenza & Domenico Delli Gatti E. Pluribus Unum: Macroeconomic Modelling for Multi-Agent Economies2012-09 Catherine Guillemineau Financial Reforms, International Financial Flows, and Growth in Advanced Economies2012-10 Dino Borie Social Decision Theory and Non-Strategic Behaviour2012-11 Edward Lorenz Social Capital and Enterprise Innovative Performance: A Multi-Level Analysis of Developing Nations2012-12 Agnès Festré & Pierre Garrouste The ‘Economics of Attention’: A New Avenue of Research in Cognitive Economics