property rights from 157 slums in bangalore”...“satellites, slums and social networks: evidence...

40
“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore” Erik Wibbels Department of Political Science Duke University Anirudh Krishna Sanford School of Public Policy Duke University M S Sriram Faculty of Public Policy Indian Institute of Management Bangalore Version 2.0 For most households, the single most important asset is their home, and insecurity of ownership in that asset is associated with all manner of difficulties. Obviously the protection of property rights looms large in the literature on development. This paper seeks to understand both the consequences and causes of tenure security. Our contribution to this area of research is two-fold. First, building on a massive data collection effort in 157 slums in Bangalore we describe a setting in which collectively held property rights serve many of the functions of individual title. Where slums are formally recognized, i.e. when the government acknowledges the existence of a habitable settlement, households behave as if they had private title, and the additional receipt of private title does little to change household behavior or enhance wellbeing. Indeed, we develop and test the claim that the poor find collective rights easier to defend than private ones. Second, we provide and test an argument on the origins of these collectively held property rights. Our argument links the density of slum-level social networks to the capacity of slum residents to trade votes and collective action for formal recognition by the government. In emphasizing the explanatory power of local social networks, our argument echoes Ostrom’s (1990) work on the role of social coordination, albeit with a more explicit focus on the need for urban communities to engage in political exchanges with the broader political system to extract protection. This and related ongoing work in several hundred additional slums has implications for research on economic development, property rights, political networks and social heterogeneity. NOTE: The authors would like to thank the Jana Urban Foundation, Shafali Sharma, and a host of fabulous field researchers for their help in collecting the data for this project. Adam Auerbach and Gareth Nellis provided generous comments on an even earlier draft.

Upload: others

Post on 05-Apr-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

“Satellites,SlumsandSocialNetworks:EvidenceontheOriginsandConsequencesof

PropertyRightsfrom157SlumsinBangalore”

ErikWibbelsDepartmentofPoliticalScience

DukeUniversity

AnirudhKrishnaSanfordSchoolofPublicPolicy

DukeUniversity

MSSriramFacultyofPublicPolicy

IndianInstituteofManagementBangalore

Version2.0

Formosthouseholds,thesinglemostimportantassetistheirhome,andinsecurityofownershipinthatassetisassociatedwithallmannerofdifficulties.Obviouslytheprotectionofpropertyrightsloomslargeintheliteratureondevelopment.Thispaperseekstounderstandboththeconsequencesandcausesoftenuresecurity.Ourcontributiontothisareaofresearchistwo-fold.First,buildingonamassivedatacollectioneffortin157slumsinBangalorewedescribeasettinginwhichcollectivelyheldpropertyrightsservemanyofthefunctionsofindividualtitle.Whereslumsareformallyrecognized,i.e.whenthegovernmentacknowledgestheexistenceofahabitablesettlement,householdsbehaveasiftheyhadprivatetitle,andtheadditionalreceiptofprivatetitledoeslittletochangehouseholdbehaviororenhancewellbeing.Indeed,wedevelopandtesttheclaimthatthepoorfindcollectiverightseasiertodefendthanprivateones.Second,weprovideandtestanargumentontheoriginsofthesecollectivelyheldpropertyrights.Ourargumentlinksthedensityofslum-levelsocialnetworkstothecapacityofslumresidentstotradevotesandcollectiveactionforformalrecognitionbythegovernment.Inemphasizingtheexplanatorypoweroflocalsocialnetworks,ourargumentechoesOstrom’s(1990)workontheroleofsocialcoordination,albeitwithamoreexplicitfocusontheneedforurbancommunitiestoengageinpoliticalexchangeswiththebroaderpoliticalsystemtoextractprotection.Thisandrelatedongoingworkinseveralhundredadditionalslumshasimplicationsforresearchoneconomicdevelopment,propertyrights,politicalnetworksandsocialheterogeneity.NOTE:TheauthorswouldliketothanktheJanaUrbanFoundation,ShafaliSharma,andahostoffabulousfieldresearchersfortheirhelpincollectingthedataforthisproject.AdamAuerbachandGarethNellisprovidedgenerouscommentsonanevenearlierdraft.

Page 2: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Oneofthedefiningfeaturesoftheeconomiclivesofthepoorisinsecurity—insecurityrootedinuncertainemployment,poorhealth,irregularaccesstofood,arbitrarypublicofficials,andtheexpropriationofassets.Formosthouseholds,theirsinglemostimportantassetistheirhome,andinsecurityofownershipinthatassetisassociatedwithallmannerofdifficulties.Obviouslytheprotectionofpropertyrightsloomslargeintheliteratureondevelopment,butitiseasytolosesightofwhatlandtenureinsecuritymeansforhouseholds.Onebriefstoryfromourresearchservestofixideas:PattandurAgraharawasaverypoorinformalsettlementinBangalorethathousedabout800peoplescrapingbyonthemarginsofabooming,globalizedmetropolis.Settledin2008byruralmigrantsfromAndhraPradeshandMaharashtrainsearchofwork,manyofitsresidentshadlivedthereforyearsinhomesconstructedfromwoodandplastictarp.OurfieldteaminterviewedresidentsonSeptember11,2012.Afewweekslater,satelliteimageryshowsthatnotonesinglehomeremained.Appendix1providesPatttandurAgrahara’sstoryinafewpictures.Thispaperseekstounderstandboththeconsequencesandcausesoftenuresecurity.Privatepropertyrightsplayacentralroleininstitutionalapproachestodevelopment(North1981;DeSoto2000;BesleyandGhatak2009;GoldsteinandUdry2008).Theguaranteeofpropertyrightsensuresthatownersandinvestorscannotbealienatedfromtheirassets;assets,therefore,canreliablyserveascollateral,promoteinvestment,andserveasanimpulsetothedevelopmentoffinancialmarkets.Historyislitteredwithexamplesofimprovementsinthesecurityoflanddrivingincreasesinproductivity,includingtheintroductionofbarbedwireintheAmericanwestandtheenclosureofEnglishcommonlands.Afondnessforprivatetitlehasdrivendecadesoflandmanagementprogrammingintheinternationaldonorcommunity.Therearethreeoverarchingchallengestothecentralroleofprivatelandtitleinpromotingdevelopment.First,thereisgrowingevidencethattitlinguntoitselfandinmanycontextsprovideslimitedbenefits.Inseveralstudies,titledoesnotleadtoincreasedaccesstofinancialmarkets,investmentinhomes,orreductionsinpoverty(vanGelder2009;Payneetal.2009;).Thesenullfindingsonprivatepropertyrightsprobablyhavemultipleroots,includingthedifficultyofenforcingprivatetitleandthethinnessoffinancialmarketsinmanycountries.Secondandrelatedly,thereisalargebodyofevidencethatalternativeformsofpropertyrights,oftencommunallyheld,servetoprovideconsiderablesecurityandprovideanalternativetoformal,individualtitle(Ostrom1990;DeiningerandBinswanger1999;Payneetal.2009).Thesealternativeformsofpropertyrightsmightbeparticularlyvaluabletothepoor,ifthedefenseofindividualtitlerequiresresourcesand/ortheruleoflawisweak.Thirdandfinally,despitearichbodyoftheoryandhistoriographyontheoriginsofindividualpropertyrights,particularlyinWesternEurope(North1990;NorthandWeingast1989),muchoftheworkaimsatexplainingcross-countrydifferences.Suchaccountsprovidelimitedinsightintowhyandhowpropertyrightsareoftenhighlyunevenwithincountries(Boone2013),norhowthepoliticalpoweroflandholdersmightconditiondevelopmentaloutcomesinsettingscharacterizedbyunevenpropertyrights(GoldsteinandUdry2008).Ourcontributiontothisareaofresearchisthree-fold.First,buildingonamassivedatacollectioneffortin157slumswedescribeanewempiricalsetting,namelytheslumsof

Page 3: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Bangalore,inwhichcollectivelyheldpropertyrightsservemanyofthefunctionsofindividualtitle.Whereslumsareformallyrecognized,i.e.whenthegovernmentacknowledgestheexistenceofahabitablesettlement,householdsbehaveasiftheyhadprivatetitle,andtheadditionalreceiptofprivatetitledoeslittletoimprovesecurityoftenure,changehouseholdbehaviororenhancewellbeing.Putdifferently,slumrecognitionwouldalmostcertainlyhavebeenenoughtoprotecttheresidentsofPatttandurAgraharafromthelossoftheirhomes,evenintheabsenceofprivatetitle.Wedevelopandtesttheclaimthatthepoorfindcollectiverightseasiertodefendthanprivateones.Second,weprovideandtestanargumentontheoriginsofthesecollectivelyheldpropertyrights.Ourargumentlinksthedensityofslum-levelsocialnetworkstothecapacityofslumresidentstotradevotesandcollectiveactionforformalrecognitionbythegovernment.Inemphasizingtheexplanatorypoweroflocalsocialnetworksandcollectiveaction,ourargumentechoesOstrom’s(1990)workontheroleofsocialcoordination,albeitwithamoreexplicitfocusontheneedforurbancommunitiestoengageinpoliticalexchangeswiththebroaderpoliticalsystemtoextractlegalrecognitionandprotection.Consistentwiththisargument,oursurveyexperimentalevidencesuggeststhathouseholdsindenselyorganizedslumsaremorelikelytodeploytheirvotesinamannersuggestedbylocalleaders.Thirdandrelatedly,wecontributetoawaveofworkthatisbringingthestudyofpropertyrightstocities.Agrowingbodyofworkonslumsaside(Marx,StokerandSuri2015;GalianiandSchargrodsky2010;Field2007),muchofthemicroworkonpropertyrightshasfocusedonruralareas.Yetrecentdecadeshaveseenaboomincities,theproliferationofslums,andanexplosionofpropertyconflictsbearingontheurbanpoor.Citiesofferdistinctcharacteristics,rangingfromhighpopulationdensities,thecapacitytoeasilydisrupttrafficandservices,welldevelopedpropertymarkets,gangs,andconsiderablepresenceofgovernmentpersonnelthatshapethecapacityofslumdwellerstoprotecttheirhomes.Giventhathundredsofmillionsofthepoorliveinslums,understandingthenatureandoriginsoftheirpropertyrightsiscrucial.Weproceedinfivesections.Inthefollowingsection,weplacedebatesabouturbanpropertyrightsinthebroadercontextofthenewinstitutionaleconomicsandlayoutaseriesofquestionsthatweseektoanswer.Insection2,wefleshoutourargument.Insection3wedescribeourempiricalsettinganddatacollectionefforts.Insection4,weprovideevidencebearingontherelationshipbetweenslumrecognition,privatetitleandaseriesofkeyhouseholdleveloutcomes,includingtheaccumulationofassets,accesstoformalfinancialmarkets,andperceivedsecurityoflandtenure.Insection5,weprovideapreliminarytestofourargumentlinkingthesocialcoherenceandpoliticalmobilizationofslumstotheircapacitytoextractlegalrecognitionfromthegovernment.Wealsopresentsurveyexperimentalevidenceontheincidenceofvoteselling,whichsuggeststhatvotersindenselyorganizedcommunitiesaremorelikelytovoteinamannerconsistentwithlocalvotebrokers.Weconcludewithbroaderimplicationsfortheliteratureonpropertyrightsanddevelopmentaswellasthegrowingbodyofworkonurbangovernanceinthedevelopingworld.II.PropertyRights,PrivateTitleandDevelopment

Page 4: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Privatepropertyrightsarecentraltostandardaccountsofeconomicandpoliticaldevelopment.Contractarianmodelsofthestateemphasizetheroleoftaxationandpropertyprotectionsinpromotingtheaccountableexerciseofpower(NorthandWeingast1989;AnsellandSamuels2014;Stasavage2010).Asneweconomicinterestsarise,theyseekprivatepropertyprotectionsfromthestateasameanstoprotecttheirassets;whererulersbehaveasstationarybanditsinterestedinsustainingdevelopment,theyprovidepropertyprotectionsandabidebypoliticalchecksandbalancesasthecostofencouragingprivateinvestment.Thisaccountdovetailsnicelywithmodelsthatemphasizetheimportanceofprivatepropertyrightsfordevelopment(North1981,1990;Besley1995).Accordingtotheseaccounts,privatetitletolandhasatleastthreekeybenefits.First,sincepropertyissuchalargeshareofmostfamily’sassets,secureownershipservesasakeyformofcollateralthatincreasesthesupplyofformalcreditandpromotesinvestment.Privatetitlethusprovidesstimulustofinancialmarkets,thedensityofwhichiscloselyassociatedwitheconomicdevelopment(Pagano1993;deSoto2000;NorthandWeingast1989).Second,privatetitleincreasestheliquidityoflandmarketsbyreducinginformationasymmetriesandriskassociatedwithtransactinginassetsofdubiousqualityandlegality.Thisisparticularlytrueinurbanareaswerelandisexpensiveandthequalityofservicesoftenvariessignificantlyacrossneighborhoods.AsDeiningerandBinswangernote,“onewouldexpectthetransferabilityoflandbroughtaboutbybetter-definedpropertyrightstobeofincreasingrelevancewithhigherlevelsofpopulationdensityandnonagriculturaldevelopment.”1Thirdandfinally,privatetitlereduceswastefulinvestmentsinmeasuresaimedatprotectinginsecureland/homesandliberatesthoseresourcesforproductiveinvestment.Inaruralcommunitythoseresourcesmightinvolvetheeffortsinvolvedprotectinglandfromcompetingfarmersorranchers.Inurbanareas,thisinvolvesthetimespentathomekeepingthievesorbulldozersatbay;timethatcannotbespentworkingoutsidetheslum(Field2007).Inthesecases,privateinvestmentsinprotectionareindividuallyefficientbutsociallywasteful,andprivatelandtitleservestopromoteefficiency.Thereisagreatdealofrigorousevidencethattheprovisionofprivatelandtitleandtheenforcementofthosetitleshasimportanteffects—insomecasesitincreasesemploymentoutsidethehome(Field2007),increasesinvestmentsinhomesandchildren(GalianiandSchargrodsky2010;Field2008;VanGelder2009;Deiningeretal.2011),increasesproductivity(Hornbeck2010),andpromotesapositiveorientationtowardthemarket(DiTellaetal.2007).Thesefindingshavehelpedpromoteatwodecadelongeffortamonginternationaldonorstoformalizelandrightsandprovideprivatetitleacrossmany,manycountriesinthedevelopingworld(Baharoglu2002).2BiginitiativesincludetheHighLevelCommissionfortheLegalEmpowermentofthePoor,the1999UN-HabitatGlobalCampaignforSecureTenureandtheWorldBank’slongrunningLand-TitlingProgram.Thoughanopennesstoalternative,traditionalapproachestotenuresecurityhasgrown 11999:p.251.2Thesereasonswhyprivatetitlemightnotpromoteefficiencydonotaccountforthefactthattheymight,infact,detractfromsocialwelfare.Thismighthappenwhenprivatetitlingprogramsareignorantofon-the-groundrealitiesandthereforepromotea“raceforrights”thatbenefitsthepowerfulanddisplacestraditionalrightsholdersorusers.

Page 5: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

throughtime,donorshavetypicallyconsideredprivatetitlethebedrockofmodern,efficientandtransparentlandadministration.3AsDurand-LasserveandSelodsummarize,“Theinfluenceofthepropertyrightsapproachondonors’thinkingonlandpolicyandadministrationappearstohavebecomehegemonic….”4Therearetwocentralcritiquesoftheemphasisonprivatelandrights—oneempiricalandtheothertheoretical.First,thereisnowadecent-sizedbodyofevidence,muchofitlinkedtoevaluationsoftitlingprogramsacrossthedevelopingworld,suggestingthatprivatetitledoesnotalwaysworkasthecommandingheightsofthenewinstitutionaleconomicswouldsuggest,particularlyinurbansettings.Whilethelinkbetweentitleandinvestmentinhousingseemsquitesolid,theevidencelinkingtitlingtoimprovedaccesstocreditandtheformalfinancialsectorisweak(Durand-Lasserve2009;GalianiandSchargrodsky2005;Varley2002).Thefindingsontheimpactoftitlingonlabormarketoutcomesisalsohighlyheterogeneous,withnoeffectsinBuenosAires,Argentina(GalianiandSchargrodsky2005)andGuyaquil,Ecuador(Rose2006)standingagainstlargepositiveeffectsinLima,Peru(Field2007).Therearemanypotentialreasonsfortheweakeffects,includingimperfectfinancialmarkets,governancefailuresintheenforcementoftitles,increasedinsecurityresultingfrommarket-drivendisplacement,etc.Second,asaddressedmostthoroughlybyOstromandcolleagues,communaltenuresystemscanbeanefficientalternativetoprivatetitleinmanagingresources(Ostrom1990;cites).TheyargueandshowinsettingsasdiverseastheMaasaiofKenyaandalpinecommunitiesofSwitzerlandthatunderageneralsetofconditions,locallydevelopedinstitutionsforcollectivelymanagingcommonpoolresourcescanserveasacooperative,non-governmentalandefficientalternativetoprivatetitle.Otherformsofmanagingcollectiveproperty,suchasthosepracticedbychiefsinGhana,mightindeedsacrificeefficiency,buttheydosoinfavorofothervaluableaspectsofsocialwelfare,suchascaringfortheleastwelloffthatarenotaddressedbyprivatepropertymarkets(PandeandUdry2005).Inourempiricalcontext,collectivelyheldrightsareembodiedin“slumrecognition”;formalrecognitionoccurswhentherelevantgovernmentagency(whichhaschangedovertime)rulesthattheslumisonhabitablelandandthatitsresidentscanlegallyresidethere.Atitsmostbasic,slumrecognitionentailstherighttonotbeforciblyremovedfromoneshome.Recognitionappliestotheslumasawholeandatleastformallypermits(butdoesnotrequire)thecitygovernmenttoprovidebasicservicestotheslum.Whileworkoncommonpoolresourcesandtraditionallandtenureprovideanimportantlinchpininourunderstandingofcollectivepropertyrights,therearetwounderlyingquestionsthatweseektoaddress.First,wheredothesealternativeformsoftenuresecuritycomefrom?Big,macro-historicalaccountsontheemergenceofpropertyrightsaside,thesecurityofpropertyrightsareoftenhighlyunevenwithincountries(Boone2013),andwhererightsareambiguous,theirsecurityismediatedbythepoliticalinfluenceoflandholders(GoldsteinandUdry2008).InOstrom’sownworkitisnotalwaysclearwhy 3TheUNexplicitlyrecognizes“avarietyofformsoflegaltenure”(2002:p.25),butitisquitevagueonwhatthosemightbe.TheWorldBank,likewiserecognizescustomaryuse,butitsprogrammingistypicallyaimedattitling(WorldBank2011).41997,p.29.

Page 6: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

somecommunitiessettleonacooperativeequilibriumformanagingcommonpoolresourceswhileothersdonot.Herpath-breakingworkonthecooperativemanagementofcattlegrazinginTörbel,Switzerland,forinstance,doesnotexplainwhythesameinstitutionsandpracticesdidnotdevelopinKippel,analpinecommunityofthesamereligion,language,sizeandecologyinthesamecanton(Demarchi2014).Second,howistenuresecurityachievedspecificallyinurbansettings,wheresettlementsarenecessarilyembeddedinbroadersocialandpoliticalstructures?Whileahugeamountofresearchhasexploredhowtenuresecurityaffectsbehaviorinagricultural,forest,andranchingcommunities,considerablylessworkhasfocusedonlandissuesinurbanareas.Oneresultisthatmuchoftheworkinthecommonpooltraditionhasfocusedstrictlyoncommunitycharacteristicsgoverningpropertyrightsratherthanthebroaderpoliticalregimeinwhichcommunitiesareoftenembedded.Pastoralistsandfishingcommunitiesmightbefreetogoverneconomicresourcesinwhatevermannertheychoose,butthatisrarelythecaseinthedevelopingworld’scities.Inslums,propertyrightsemergeornotasaresultoftheinteractionbetweenhouseholds,localleadersandcityandstategovernments.YetasPayneetal.summarize,“Surprisinglyfewindependentstudiesexistoflandtitlingprogrammesinurbanorperi-urbanareasoflow-andmiddle-incomecountries.”(2009:444).Thisisunfortunatebecauseurbanizationhasresultedinboomingcitypopulationsacrossthedevelopingworld,andaspoor,ruralmigrantshaveenteredcitieswithouttheresourcesand/orwilltoformallyintegratethemintotheeconomicandpoliticallivesoftheseboomingmetropolises,thenumberandpopulationsofslumshaveexploded.Asnotedabove,thereareseveralexamplesofexcellentevaluationsofrandomizedor“as-if”randomizedroll-outsofprivatetitleincitiesthatshowimportantpositiveeffectsonhouseholdwellbeing.5Thosefindingsareimportant,butpropertyrightsareveryrarelyrandomlyassigned,andtheiracquisitiontypicallyrequirespoliticalcontestation.Totheextentrandomizedprogramevaluationsexploitdonor-orgovernment-drivenexperiments,it’sunclearhowwelltheyspeaktotheday-to-daystruggleforpropertyprotectionfacedbyhundredsofmillionsoftheurbanpooraroundtheworld.III.SocialNetworks,CollectiveActionandSharedPropertyRightsOurargumentproceedsintwosteps.Inthefirst,wediscussourexpectationthatthecollectively-heldlandrightembodiedinslumrecognitionplaysamoresignificantroleinhouseholdbehaviorthanindividualtitle.Inthesecondstagewedevelopanargumentaimedatexplainingwhysomesettlementsachieverecognitionandothersdonot.Beforeproceeding,however,itisworthclarifyingthedistinctionbetweenthelegalrecognitionofslumsandindividual,privatetitletoproperty.InBangalore,legalrecognitionappliestotheslumasawhole,impliesthatitislegallyhabitable,andprovideslegalfoundationforthecitygovernmenttoprovidebasicservicestothesettlementasawhole.Privatetitle(knownashakkupatra)impliesthatanindividualhouseholdownsthehome.Asettlementmustberecognizedbeforeindividualscanreceivetitle,butnotallindividualsinrecognizedsettlementsreceiveprivatetitles.Indeed,inoursamplehouseholdsinrecognized

5SeethepapersbyField,whoacrossarangeofoutcomes,evaluatesajointGovernmentofPeruandWorldBankprojectthatprovidedtitletomorethan1.2millionurbanhouseholds.

Page 7: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

settlementsareevenlydividedbetweenthosewithandwithoutprivatetitle.Theprocessofachievingrecognitionoftentakesyears;politicalpressureandinducementsofdifferentkindsplayalargepartinwhogetsrecognitionandwhen.Thesubsequentprocessofreceivingprivatetitlecantakeyetadditionalyears.Individualtitlesarenotdeliveredenmassetohouseholdsinrecognizedsettlementsbutareprovidedatthediscretionoftheadministrativeandpoliticalmachineryofthecity.Appendix2describesinadditionaldetailtheprocessofmovingfrominitialsettlementtolegalrecognitiontoprivatetitleinBangalore.Butthekeypointtomakehereisthatthisdistinctionbetweencollectivelyheldprotectionsembeddedinslum-levellegalrecognitionandprivatelyheldtitleisquitecommoninthedevelopingworld.Thoughweareunawareofanysystematic,cross-nationaldataonurbanpropertyregimes,ourownreadingofcountry-specificregulationssuggeststhatlegalrecognitionisoftenaprerequisitefortitleandthatrecognitionandtitlecomewithdistinctbundlesofrightsacrossagreatmanycountries.6III.2:SlumRecognition,PrivateTitleandHouseholdWellbeingTurningtoanalyticsandfocusingfirstonthehousehold-leveleffectsoflegalrecognitionandprivatetitle,wearguethatlegalrecognitionshouldhavealargereffectonthesecurityoftenureandthefinancialbehaviorofhouseholdsthantheprovisionofprivatetitles.ThestandardDeSoto-likeclaimisthattheprovisionofprivatetitlesprovidessecurity,anassetthatcaneaseparticipationinformalfinancialmarkets,andtherebyprovidethefoundationforentrepreneurialismandtheaccumulationofassets.Yetlegalrecognitionalonegreatlycomplicatesthecapacityofoutsideagents—betheylanddevelopersorpolice—toalienateresidentsfromtheirhomes.Legalrecognition,forinstance,allbutprecludesthegovernmentfromdisplacingresidents.Ofcourse,thecomplexityofanyefforttoenforcelegalrecognitionviathecourtsinthefaceofoutsideencroachmentisuncertainandcostly,butthesameholdsforindividualtitleholders,whichisexactlywhyweexpectindividualtitletohaveamodestimpactonbehavioroncelegalrecognitionisachieved.Indeed,inlightofthelimitedfinancialresourcesofindividualpoorpeopletoprotecttheirprivatetitleagainstencroachment,weexpectthatslum-levelcollectionactionisasurermeanstoprotectrightsthanprivateavenues.Sincecollectiveactionismorelikelywhenencroachmentsbearonsharedrightsratherthanprivatetitles,wehypothesizethatperceivedtenuresecurityfallswithprivatetitle.Second,withlegalrecognitioncomestheprospectofpublicservices—servicessuchassewagegutters,accesstowater,andapublictoiletthathavevery,verylargeeffectsonhouseholdwellbeing.Indeed,ourneighborhoodsurveyaskedresidentswhytheyhadsoughtrecognition(whetheritwasprovidedornot),andtheoverwhelmingcommonresponseisthattheywantedaccesstobasicfacilities,evenastheprospectoflegaltitleloomedlargeaswell.Third,legalrecognitionofhabitability,evenintheabsenceofprivatetitle,shouldhaveitsgreatesteffectwhereland-relatedinvestmentsproduceahighrateofreturn,wheretenureisitsmosttenuous,andwherecertificationwillberecognizedbythird

6WehavedoneaninitialreviewoftherelevantregulationsinGhana,SouthAfrica,Ethiopia,Kenya,Nigeria,Egypt,Brazil,Bolivia,Colombia,Peru,Thailand,Vietnam,Turkey,andBangladesh.

Page 8: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

parties(betheypropertydevelopers,competingclaimants,orpotentialhomebuyers).Legalrecognitionofaslumfulfillstheseconditions.III.3:ThePoliticalOriginsofSlumRecognitionButwhyaresomecommunitiesabletoachievelegalrecognitionwhileothersarenot?Slumrecognitionresultsfromapoliticalprocesswherebycityofficialsmakeadecisionasaresultofthephysicalcharacteristicsofthelandandtheextenttowhichpoliticalofficialsseeitintheirinteresttosupporttheclaimsofresidents.Fromthepointofviewofresourceconstrainedelectedofficials,itmakesmostsensetoworkonbehalfofresidentswhoprovidethemostelectoralbenefits.Thosebenefitsincludevotesandpoliticalmobilization.Fromthepointofviewofresidents,thisrequirescollectionaction.Collectiveactioncan,ofcourse,helpresistattemptstodisplacesettlementsbygovernmentofficialsandlandspeculators.Butmoreimportantly,collectiveactionoffersthecapacitytopressurelocaladministrativeandelectedofficialsandexchangevotesforbenefits.Collectiveactionvis-à-visvotingproducesvotebanks.Givenitsobviousimpactontenuresecurityandhouseholdwellbeing,oneofthemostimportantbenefitsthatresidentscanextractfromgovernmentofficialsinexchangeforvotesandmobilizationisslumrecognition.Whileitisclearthatthecommonpoolresourceproblemisdistinctfromthatfacingslumdwellers,theunderlyingcollectiveactionproblemissimilar.7LikethecommonsproblemthatOstromfocusedon,slumrecognitionisalocalpublicgoodsubjecttocollectiveactionproblems.Ifthecommonsareover-fishedasaresultofuncooperativebehavior,theyaredestroyedforall;ifslumdwellersbehaveuncooperatively,legalrecognitionisunlikelyandthecommunitysuffers.Onceasettlementisrecognized,allofitshomesbenefitfromanincreaseintenuresecurity,whetherthehouseholdscontributedtothepoliticaldemandsofachievingrecognitionornot.Underabroadsetofconditions,theutilitymaximizingresponsetothissettingistodefectfromparticipatinginthepoliticalorganizationthatincreasesthelikelihoodofrecognition,andifenoughhouseholdsdefectthesettlementcannotprotest,attendelectionralliesorserveasavotebank.Andrecognitionwillnothappen.Theprevalenceofcompetingpartyoperativeswhoofferindividual,clientelisticbenefitsforvotesonelectiondayservesasatemptationtodefectfromelectoralcoordinationandsuccessfulvotingbanking.Theoretical,experimentalandobservationalresearchhasalsoshown,however,thatundercertainconditions,cooperativesolutionstocollectiveactionproblemsarepossible(Olson1965;Axelrod1981).Iteratedinteractions,institutionsforinformationrevelation,cartels,andnormsofreciprocityallhelpalignindividualutilitymaximizationwithsocialwelfare.AsOstromnotes,“Somehowparticipantsmustfindwaysofcreatingmutuallyreinforcingexpectationsandtrusttoovercometheperverseshort-runtemptationstheyface.”8Shegoesontonotethatthiscanhappenviamutuallearningandnormdevelopmentintightsocialnetworksorbyagreeingtofollowsomeoneelse’slead.Densesocialnetworksarecharacterizedbyalargenumberoftiesamongtheirmembersandtheirlocalleadersor 7Urbanproperty,forinstance,isnon-renewableandthelanditselfdoesnotprovidesustenanceoraprimarysourceofwell-being(whichistypicallyachievedviathelabormarket).82001:p.176.

Page 9: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

votebrokers.Consistentwithwell-establishedtheorizingonnetworks(Huckfeldt1983;UzziandSpiro2005;Wardetal2011),densenetworksinslumsprovidetwocrucialmechanismsforcollaborationandcoordinatingcollectiveaction.First,theyprovideamonitoringtechnologythatprovidesinformationonhowmembersofthenetworkbehave.Whileitisverydifficultforformalpartiesandotheroutsiderstoknowwhetherindividualslumresidentsmobilizeontheirbehalforvoteinaparticularway,itismucheasierfortightlyknitneighborsandlocalleaderswholiveinthosecommunitiestoknowthesethingsabouteachother.Adensesocialnetwork,moreover,providesameansofefficientlytransmittingthatinformationtoothermembersoftheneighborhood.Second,densesocialnetworksprovideamechanismforsanctioningcommunitymemberswhodeviatefromsociallyexpectedbehaviorandmonitoringprincipal-agentrelationshipsbetweenlocalleadersandcitizens(Auerbach2014).Inthecontextofslumpolitics,thismightinvolveaninabilitytoextracthouseholdbenefitsfromneighborhoodleadersorvotebrokers.Third,localleadersorvotebrokersserveasfocalpointsforcoordinatingwithinthecommunitywhileservingasthepublicfaceandfixervis-à-viselectedandadministrativeofficials.9Thisislikelytomattermostatelectiontime,whenlocalleadersservetocoordinatethevote-seekingneedsofpartieswithvotersinasettlementwhomustvotetogetheriftheyaretoserveasasuccessfulvotebank.Inshort,theinformationandsanctioningprovidedbydensenetworksprovidethetoolsforovercomingslum-levelcollectiveactionandexchanginganentirevotebankforthetenureprotectionembodiedinslumrecognition.10Whencomparedtosmallcommunitiesmanagingcommonpoolresources,slumdwellersfaceanumberofobstaclestocooperativebehavior.Theydonotrelyonacommonresourceformaterialwell-being;theyhavehighlyvariedemploymentrelations;11slumsareoftenquiteheterogeneousintermsoflanguage,religion,casteandethnicity;andtheyaredeeplyembeddedinabroadersetofeconomicandpoliticalrelationsthatthreatenlocalresourcesandimpingeonpurelyneighborhood-basedsolutionstoproblems.Ontheotherhand,theurbanpoorhavesomeadvantagesoverruralcommunities.Slumsettlementshaveclearlydelineatedboundaries(residentsinvariablyknowwheretheirsettlementendsandothersbegin)thatpasturesandfarmsoftendonot.Unliketheircounterpartsinthecountryside,theyareembeddedindenselypopulatedsettingsthatpromotethekindofiteratedinteractionsthatcanpromotetrust.Asaresult,theycanalsoengageinthemonitoringandsanctioningthatfacilitatecollectivechoiceandconflictresolutionarrangements.12Suchconditionscanalsobepropitiousfortheemergenceofaccountablelocalleadershipthatcanserveasfocalpointsforcoordinatingcollectiveaction.Finally,whilehierarchy,social

9SeeStokesetal.2013forthemostcomprehensivestatementontheroleofvotebrokersinelectoralpolitics.Theirfocusisontherelationshipbetweenvotebrokersandparties.SeeRojoandWibbels(2014)forafocusontherelationshipbetweenlocalvotebrokersandslumresidents. 10Itgoeswithoutsayingthatwhileslumnetworksmaywellreflectcooperativebehavior,theymightalsoreflectthecoercionthatisinherentinwell-organizedslumleadersthreateningresidentsbywithholdingofhouseholdaidintheeventtheysufferfromacrisis.ThisneednotbeaPutnamesque,idealizedlocaldemocracyforittowork.11Laboringinacommonworkplacewas,ofcourse,akeyprecursortounion-basedcollectiveactionamongworkersintheindustrialeconomiesofWesternEuropeandNorthAmericaintheirfordistheydays.12Itgoeswithoutsayingthatthiskindofsocialmonitoringandsanctioningneednotbedemocratic.

Page 10: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

distanceandinequalitymilitateagainstcooperation(Chandrasekharetal.2015)innetworks,slumstypicallyevincealowlevelofeconomicinequality.Alargebodyofresearchmakesclearthatthestrengthofpropertyrightsarecontingentontechnology(Hornbeck2010)andpoliticalpower(GoldsteinandUdry2008).Inaveryabstractsense,onecanconsiderthecapacitytoorganizeandcoordinatecollectiveactionasa“social”technologythatimprovesthesecurityoftenureinmuchthesamewaythatprivateenclosureofcommonlandandbarbedwireprovidedanimpetusfordevelopmentinpre-industrialEnglandandthelate19thcenturyU.S.Thesearen’ttechnologiesthatprecludeviolationsofpropertyrights,buttheymakethemlesslikely.Thekeydifferenceinslumssettlementsisthatthesocialtechnologyproducesacollectivepropertyrightwithimportantprivatebenefits.IV.EmpiricalSetting:SlumsinBangaloreThediscussionaboveyieldsfourkeyhypothesesthatwetest:1)Slumrecognitionhasalargereffectonhouseholdbehaviorthanprivatetitle;2)Tenuresecurityincreaseswithslumrecognitionbutdecreaseswithprivatetitle;and3)Theprobabilityofachievingslumrecognitionisincreasinginthesocialdensityofslumsettlements;and4)Votersindensepoliticalnetworksaremorelikelytovoteinamannerrecommendedbytheirlocalleader.WetestthesehypotheseswithdatafromacombinationofhouseholdandneighborhoodsurveydatafromslumsinBangalore,India.Bangaloreisacityofabout8.5millionthathasgrownrapidlyoverrecentdecadesasithasbecometheepicenterofIndia’sITrevolution.Theprospectofjobshasresultedinconsiderableruraltourbanmigration,andanexplosioninthenumberandsizeofslumsettlements.Studyingslumsisdifficult.Giventhedynamicnatureofurbandevelopment,governmentinformationaboutslumsistypicallyoutdatedorwrong.UrbanizationandslumgrowthinBangaloreseemtobetypicalofothercitiesinthedevelopingworld.Newmigrantsarrivewithvaryinglevelsofconnectionstothecity;thepoorestamongstthemsettleinplasticandwoodstructures,ofttimesonthemostmarginaloflands—landsthatmightbeownedbythefederalgovernment,thestate,thecityorprivatelandowners.Overtime,settlementsmightsurvivelongenoughtogrow.Atleastformally,suchsettlementsarenotentitledtoeventhemostbasicofpublicservices.UnderafairlyvaguesetofconditionsestablishedbytheKarnatakaSlumAreasActof1973,slumsmightbelegallyrecognizedornotbythestate(andlater,thecity)government;alternatively,theymightberehabilitated.13Iflegallydeclareduninhabitable,residentsaresupposedtoberelocated.Onceasettlementhasbeenlegallyrecognized,however,ithastherighttobasicservices.BetweenthefactthattheSlumActissubjecttobroadinterpretationandthattheKarnatakaSlumDevelopmentBoard(KSDB)andtheBangaloreMetropolitanAuthority(BBMP)sufferfromanexcessofdemands,itcomesasnosurprisethatadministrativeofficialsreportthattheprioritizationofcasesisresponsivetopoliticalpressure.

13Seep.8oftheActandnotehowopentointerpretationthestatuteis:http://ksdb.kar.nic.in/docs/Board_Docs/Karnataka%20Slum%20Development%20Act.pdf

Page 11: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Inordertounderstandthesedynamics,wehaveundertakenthreewavesofhouseholdsurveysbetween2010and2015in62settlements.ThefirstwaveofsurveyswasundertakenbetweenJuneandAugust2010.Followingmostpriorresearch,weobtainedalistofslumsfromthestateslumauthority(KSDB)andrandomlyselected14slums.Surveysof1,481householdswerecarriedoutbyalocallyrecruitedresearchteam.Theinterviewsshowedthat“slums”ontheofficiallistrepresentthepinnacleofavasticeberg,homenotsomuchtothepoorestpeopleastoasettledlower-middleclass,mostofwhomhavelivedinBangaloreformultiplegenerations.Inthissetofsettlements,multi-storypermanentconstructionprevails;electricityconnectionsandcleandrinkingwateraretypical;TVs,pressurecookers,andelectricfansarecommonlyowned;povertyislowcomparedtotheaverageforthecity.41percentownthehomesinwhichtheylive,andofthem,70percentpossessofficialpapersestablishingownershipofthelandonwhichtheirhomeswerebuilt.Itbecameclearthatinordertostudythe“real”slums,placesthatcomecloserbothtotheUN-HABITATdefinitionofslumaswellasthecommon-senseunderstandingoftheterm,wewouldhavetolookatslumsnotongovernmentlists.Buthowdoesonecreatealistofunlistedslumstostudy?Sinceexistingdatasourcesareoflittlehelp,welookedatsatelliteimagesavailableonGoogleEarth.14Afterseveraliterationsbetweensatellite-imageidentificationanddetailedverificationontheground,weshortlistedalistofcriteriaforidentifyinglow-incomesettlements.Basedonthefollowingidentificationcriteria,weinitiallyidentified279low-incomepolygons:

• lackofspacebetweenhousingunits;• roofsthatappearedtobelow-qualitybasedonbrownorweatheredgreycoloring;• ahodgepodgepatternofhousingunits;• lackofproperroads(ifthereareroads,theyarebrown,narrowandunpaved);• lackofshadowsadjoiningtheshelterunits,signifyingthattheyarelowtothe

ground,thusnotmulti-storied.

On-the-groundverificationsofatotalof193low-incomesettlementshelpedusidentifyarangeofsettlements,fromnotifiedslumsondeclaredgovernmentlandallthewayto“bluepolygon”,tentsettlementthatareneitherofficiallylistednorrecognized.Bluepolygonsarethepoorestsettlements,andmostofthemarecompletelylackingineventhemostbasicservices.Homesinthesenewersettlementsareingeneralcoveredbyblueplasticsheets(referredtoastarpaulins,butmadeofplasticbasedmaterial).Weundertookdetailedinvestigationsinasampleof18bluepolygonsettlementsbetweenAugustandDecember2012,conductinginterviewswithatotalof631households,alittlemorethanhalfofallhouseholdsthenlivinginthesettlements.Weselectedhouseholdsforinterviewsfollowingaprocessofrandomselection(pickingeverysecondhouseholdstartingfromacommonpoint).Theseresidentstendedtobesuspiciousofoutsiders.Appealstolocalleadersortheownersoftheselandswereoftennecessaryinordertogainentry. 14Wefoundthatexaminingimagesatanaltitudeof4,000feetwasmosthelpfulforourpurposes.Formostsettlements,therearesatelliteimagesstartingin2000.However,someonlyhaveimagesdatingbackto2002or2004.Similarly,thevastmajorityhasanupdated2011image,butsomeonlysomehaveimagesdatingto2010.

Page 12: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Inthethird,mostrecentwaveofsurveys,webeganlookingattheintermediateslums–thosebetweenthehighest(notifiedordeclared)andlowest(blue-polygon)slums.Homesintheseslumsareconstructedfrommaterialsrangingfromwoodtoconcrete.Roofsrangefromplastictomouldsheeting(akintothinmetalroofs)toconcrete.Alltold,thesehouseholdscoverthebroadrangebetweenthetwoendpointsofslumsettlements—theverypoorestresidentswholiveinbluepolygonslumstothelowermiddleclasswhooccupylong-recognized“slums”.BeginninginMay2015,weinterviewed30+householdsineachof30settlementsrepresentingarangeofphysicalandlegalstatuses.15Wealsoresampled30householdsin5bluepolygonsettlementswehadinvestigatedin2012and5declaredsettlementswehadsampledin2010.Alltold,wecollecteddatafrom1,272households.Bothduringandbetweenthethreewavesofhouseholdsurveys,fieldteamsconductedneighborhoodsurveys,i.e.focusgroupswithasmallgroupofresidents,in171slumsinordertogetthesettlement’shistory,physicalcharacteristics,demographics,neighborhoodorganization,andlegalstatus.Theyalsogeoreferencedtheboundariesofthesettlements.Figure1providestwoGoogleEarthimagesofslumboundariesfromthepointofviewofa4kmx5kmand800mx400msectionofthecity.ofthoseneighborhoodsurveysareintheprocessofbeingdouble-checked,andsoweareleftwith157neighborhoodsurveys.Alltold,wedrawonevidencefrom3,384householdinterviews,157neighborhoodsurveys,andyearsofadministrativedatacollection.

Figure1Here

V.Results:Assets,FinancialMarkets,andHousingSecurityInordertocomparetheeffectofslumrecognitionandprivatetitleonhouseholdbehavior,wetakethreeslicesatthedatawitheachslicecorrespondingtoakeymicro-leveloutcomeofinterestinresearchonpropertyrights.First,weanalyzetheaccumulationofassets,sincetenuresecurityispositedtoincreaseoverallmaterialwellbeingthroughseveralpaths.Second,weanalyzeaccesstoformalfinancialmarkets,sincethisparticularmechanismloomslargeinaccountslinkingprivatetitletohouseholddevelopmentandthereisalargebodyofevidencethatinformalfinancialmarketsareextremelyexpensiveforthepoor.Thirdandfinally,wefocusonhouseholdperceptionsoftenuresecurity.Ononehand,privatetitlenecessarilyrequiresanimprovedperceptionoftenuresecurityifitistohaveanymaterialeffectonhouseholdbehavior(VanGelder2009).Ontheotherhand,weclaimthatcollectivepropertyrightsareeasiertodefendforthepoorthanprivatetitles;whiletheformercanbedefendedwithcollectiveaction,thelattercanonlybedefendedwithprivateresources,whichareinshortsupplyformostslumresidents.Tomeasureassetaccumulation,werelyonthefirstcomponentfromaprincipalcomponentanalysisofanextensiveseriesofsurveyquestionsaskingrespondentsiftheirhousehold 15Weestablishedthesampleintervalbydividingthenumberofhouseholdsby30andagainpursuedtheleft-handsiderule.Weinterviewedmorethan30inslumswhereourinitialfieldworkyieldedlessthan40percentmalerespondents.Inthosecaseswereturnedtothesettlementstopurposivelysampleanadditional8men.

Page 13: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

ownsasetofassets.16Theresultingassetindexrangesfrom-3.5to5.9withastandarddeviationof2.WeestimateOLSregressionswitherrorsclusteredbyslum(inthenextiterationIwillestimateHLMsforModels5and6).Wereportresultsfromsixmodels.Thefirstoneincludesonlythoseindividual-levelcovariatesforwhichwehavethebestcoverage:whetherthehouseholdhasafemalehead,religiousaffiliationandcaste;thesecondmodeladdsrespondentageandthenumberofyearsthehouseholdhasbeeninthehome,twoquestionsthatwerenotaskedinthefirstroundofhouseholdsurveys.Models3and4addanindicatorvariableforwhetherthehouseholdhasprivatetitletothecovariatesinModels1and2.Finally,Models5and6includeanindicatorvariableforwhetherornottheslumhasbeenrecognizedbythegovernment.17AcomparisonofModels3and4withmodels5and6providessomeinitialinsightintotheshareofthetotalvarianceslumrecognitionaccountsforandhowmuchoftheinitialtitlingresultsareactuallyduetoslumrecognition.ThefulltabularresultsarereportedinAppendixA.3.Theyshowthatgeneralcasteandreligiousminorityhouseholds(i.e.the“caste”variable)arewealthierthanscheduledcaste,scheduledtribeandOBChouseholds.Likewise,householdsthathavelivedintheirhomeslongertendtobewealthier.Moretoourinterestintenure,Models3and4suggestthathavingprivatetitleisassociatedwithconsiderablywealthierhouseholds,andinclusionofthevariableraisestheshareofvarianceexplainedto12and32percent,respectively.TheinclusionoftheslumrecognitionvariableinModels5and6haveamuchlargereffectonthefindings.Thecoefficientsonprivatetitleremainssignificant,buttheirsizefallbybetweentwo-thirdsandthree-quarters;theslumrecognitionvariablealsoexplainsaveryimpressiveshareofthevarianceastheR-squaredsincreaseto.61and.76.Figure2providesavisualmeansofassessingthesimulatedeffectofslumrecognitionandprivatetitleonhouseholdwealth.ItcontraststhepredictedlevelofassetaccumulationderivedfromModel5whenaslumisnotrecognized,whenitisrecognized,whenahomeownerdoesnothavetitle,andwhentheydo.Theobviousandhugedifferenceoccursbetweenrecognizedandunrecognizedslums;householdsinunrecognizedslumsaremuch,muchpoorerthanthoseinrecognizedslums.Theadditionoftitledoeshaveapositiveadditionaleffectonassetaccumulation,butitisquitesmallbycomparison.Thus,privatelytitledhouseholdsare,onaverage,alittlebitwealthierthanthosewithouttitle.Furthertotheseresults,principalcomponentsanalysisontheentireassetlist,privatetitleandslumrecognitionyieldsaprincipalcomponentonwhichslumrecognitionloadsverystrongly,whilehomeownershipdoesnot.Theseresultsarerobusttomoresophisticatedmodelingapproachesthatexplicitlyincorporatethemultilevelnatureofourdata,includingtwo-level,mixed-effectsregression.

Figure2HereTherelativelysmallfindingonprivatetitleisinteresting,becauseoneinferentialchallengewhenrelyingonthiskindofcross-sectionaldataisthattheprovisionofformaltitlemight 16Thequestionsaswhetherornottherespondent’shouseholdowns:arickshaw,bicycle,car,DVDplayer,gasstove,worktools,agriculturalland,ceilingfan,mobilephone,motorbike,CDplayer,apettybusiness,pressurecooker,pumpstove,radio,refrigerator,sewingmachine,andtelevision.1773percentofrespondentsliveinrecognizedslums.

Page 14: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

promotethelocalpropertymarket,increaseprices,anddrawinwealthierbuyers;theresultissometimesreferredtoasmarket-drivendisplacement.Putdifferently,householdswithtitlecouldbewealthierindependentoftitlestatus,andthiswouldbereflectedintheaccumulationofmoreassetsbeforeownersboughtintoaneighborhood.Wedonotfindevidenceconsistentwithsuchaselectioneffect.Wenextturntotherelationshipbetweenprivatetitle,slumrecognitionandhouseholdengagementwiththeformalfinancialsector.Ourdependentvariableiswhetherornotahouseholdusesaformalsavingsinstitution.Homesavingsareaveryinefficientmeansofsaving,becausetheyaresubjecttotheftandtemptation(BanjerjeeandDuflo2011),andformalsavingshavebeenassociatedwithverylargeimprovementsinhouseholdwellbeingandfutureproductivity(Bruneetal.2015).InIndia,householdshaveaccesstomanysavingsinstitutions,andwecodethemallas“1”.18Inoursample,41percentofhouseholdsmakeuseofoneortheothersavingsinstitution.Oursamplesizefallsinthissetofmodelsbecausethesavingsquestionwasonlyaskedinthe2012and2015surveywaves.Weestimatelogisticregressionmodelsusingmaximumlikelihoodwithslum-clusteredstandarderrorsanddeploythesamesetofcovariatesdiscussedabove;theresultsarerobusttorandomeffectlogitestimation.AppendixA.3reportsthetabularresultsofthreemodels,onewithjusttheindividual-levelcovariates,asecondwiththeindicatorforhouseholdtitle,andathirdthatincludesthemeasureofslum-levellegalrecognition.Inthiscaseweareexplainingrelativelylittleofthevariation,butconsistentwiththepatterndescribedaboveslumrecognitionisdoingmuchofthework,evenasprivatetitlehasasignificantbutsmallereffect.Toeaseinterpretation,wesimulatethepredictedprobabilityofusingformalsavingsinstitutionsoffModel3atthedifferentvaluesofrecognitionandtitle.TheresultsarepresentedinFigure3.Thefigureshowsthatshiftingfromanunrecognizedslumtoarecognizedoneincreasestheprobabilityofformalsavingsfrom.23to.36,anincreaseof57percentoffthebaselineprobability;subsequentlymovingfromanuntitledhouseholdtoatitledoneincreasestheprobabilityofformalsavingsfrom.36to.45,oranincreaseof25percent.Bothoftheseincreasesassubstantivelylarge,eveniftheifslumrecognitionissomewhatlarger.

Figure3Here

Ourlastattempttoassesstheeffectofslumrecognitionandtitleonhouseholdsturnstotheextenttowhichtheirsettlementfeelssecurefromeviction.Inthe2015surveyweaskedrespondents:“Wehaveheardthatsometimesfamiliesarethreatenedwithevictionfromtheirhomes.Whataboutinyoursettlement?Domostpeoplefeelveryinsecure,somewhatinsecure,alittlebitinsecure,orverysecureintheirhome?”Nearlyallofthetheorizedbenefitsoftitlearerootedinasenseofsecurity,sothisquestionprovidesusleverageonthecognitiveeffectofslumrecognitionandprivatetitle.Thisalsoallowsustoexamineourclaimthatthepoorwillfindcollectivetitleseasiertodefendthanindividualonesandthereforefeelmoresecurewithlegalrecognitionbutwithoutprivatetitle.Respondents 18Theoptionsare:chitfunds,selfhelpgroups,MFIs,cooperatives,banks,postoffices,andinsurancecompanies.

Page 15: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

weregivenasetofoptionsrangingfromverysecuretoveryinsecure.Wefitorderedlogitmodels,whereinsecurityisincreasingacrossthedependentvariable,withthesamesetofcovariatesdiscussedabove.WereporttheresultsforthreemodelsinAppendixA.4.Thethreemodelspaintastraightforwardpicture.Individualcharacteristicshavenobearingonhowsecurerespondentsfeelfromeviction,andhavingprivatetitledoesnoteither.Theonlyvariablethatimpactsperceivedtenuresecurityisslumrecognition.Toeaseinterpretation,wesimulatethepredictedprobabilityofarespondentresponding“veryinsecure”andpresenttheresultsinFigure3.Thefigureshowsthatatypicalrespondentinanunrecognizedslumhasabouta30percentpredictedprobabilityoffeelingveryinsecureintheirtenure;thatfallstolessthan15percentforresidentsofrecognizedsettlements.Thefigurealsoshowsthatthereisasmall,insignificantincreaseinthepredictedprobabilityoffeelingveryinsecurewhenahouseholdhasprivatetitle.Thisinsignificantresultisnotworthmakingmuchof,butitisconsistentwithafearofmarket-drivendisplacementandgentrificationthatcanoccurwiththeintroductionofindividualtitle.19ItisalsoconsistentwithnulleffectsoftitlingonperceivedsecurityinPeruandelsewhere,whereformalizationofsettlementsismoreimportantthanindividualtitle(Baharoglu2002).Aswiththeearlierresults,thesearerobusttoestimationapproachesthatexplicitlymodelthehierarchicalnatureofthedata.

Figure4HereVI.Results:ThePoliticalOriginsofLegalRecognitionGiventhatslumrecognitionprovideshouseholdswithincreasedconfidencethattheywillnotbeevicted,encouragesaccesstoformalfinancialmarketsandisassociatedwiththeaccumulationofwealth,itisnosurprisethatitiscovetedbyagreatmanyresidentsofinformalsettlementsinBangalore.Butwhydosomeslumsachieveitwhileothersdonot?OnepossibilityisthatthemunicipalgovernmentofBangalore(BBMP)andtheKarnatakaSlumDevelopmentBoard(KSDB)followthetechnicalsetofcriteriaestablishedintheSlumRecoveryAct.TheAct,however,allowsforsubstantialinterpretation,andboththeBBMPandKSDBareunder-fundedagenciesoverwhelmedwithwork.Asperourtheoreticaldiscussionabove,wehypothesizethatformalrecognitionistheresultofapoliticalstruggle.InterviewswithemployeesinboththeBBMPandKSDBsuggestthatelectedofficialsplayacrucialroleinsensitizingtheagenciestotheimportanceofworkingwithsomesettlements.Indeedandasperourtheoreticaldiscussionabove,weexpectthatformalrecognitionistheresultofapoliticalstruggle.Wehypothesizethatsettlementsthataredenselyorganizedwillbeabletocapturetheattentionofcorporators(officialselectedinward-wisecityelections)andmembersofthestatelegislativeassembly(MLAs)andtherebyaremorelikelytoachieverecognition.

19EvidencefromJakarta,forinstance,showsthatmarketpricesareabout50%higherforregisteredpropertiesinthecentralbusinessdistrict(DowallandLeaf1990).

Page 16: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Totestthisproposition,weinitiallyrelyonneighborhoodsurveysof157slums.Thesesurveysprovideinformationonthelegalstatusoftheslum,itslocationvis-à-vissensitiveland(i.e.landthatislegallydifficulttorecognizeashabitable),thedemographicsofhabitants,andthesizeandageofthesettlement.Wealsoderivefromthesurveystwoindirectindicatorsofslum-levelsocialdensityandpoliticalengagement.Thefirstisanestimateoftheshareoftheinhabitantswhoparticipateinaneighborhoodgroup,wheretheneighborhoodgroupsrangefrommicro-financegroupstoneighborhoodself-helpassociationstocommunitysafetyassociations.Thesecondisaroughmeasureofthepoliticalengagementofasettlement.Respondentswhereaskedwhotheywouldgotointheeventthesettlementhadalocalserviceneedorproblem.Respondentsweregivenarangeofoptions,whichweturnintoanindicatorvariabletakingonavalueof“1”ifthesettlementwouldturntoapoliticalofficial—betheyanMLA,acorporator,apartyofficialoralocalleader.20Weestimatelogitmodelswithrecognitionstatusasthedependentvariable.AppendixA.5presentsthetabularresults,whichshowthatinthreeoutoffourmodels,themeasuresofsocialdensityandpoliticalengagementarepositivelyandsignificantlycorrelatedwithslumrecognition.Figure5presentstheresultsgraphically.Itshowsthatunderconditionsofsocialanomie,thereisa20percentpredictedprobablityofrecognition;thatclimbstoover80percentwheneveryoneintheslumparticipates(whichdoesoccurinoursample!).Theseresultsarerobusttotheinclusionofmeasuresoflandtype(industrialwastesitesandgarbagedumpsmilitateagainstrecognition)andlandownership(thefederalgovernmentisnotoriouslydifficulttoworkwith).Obviously,thesearepreliminaryresults,buttheyarebroadlysuggestivethatsocialandpoliticallyorganizedneighborhoodsaremorelikelytoachieveslumrecognition,evenafterwetakeaccountofphysical,historicalanddemographiccharacteristicsthatmightimpactadministrativedecisions.

Figure5HereOurhouseholdsurveysofferthepotentialformuchricheranalysisinfuturedrafts.Wehavequestionsthatallowustoassesstheextenttowhichindivualhouseholdsareconnectedtotheprofessionalandpoliticallivesofthebroadercity;othersthatallowustoassessinterpersonaltrustandsharedattendanceatweddings;andyetothersthatallowustomeasuretheextenttowhichpartisanorientationandneighborhoodleadershiparesharedacrosshouseholds.Figure6providesaviewofthehugevariationacrossslumsinsocialattitudesandpoliticalcoherence.Thefigureshowstheslum-wisedistributionofhouseholdresponsestothefollowingquestions:

• Doyouthinkyourneighborhoodisaneffectivevotebank?(top-leftpanel,theshareofhouseholdswhosayyes);

20Theotheroptionsforwhotheslummightturntoare:Yourself,Relatives,Friends,Neighbors,ReligiousLeaders,Employers(Contractor/Mukaddam),anagent,Caste/ReligiousOrganizations,oranNGO.

Page 17: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

• Canyougivemethenameofthefirstmostimportantleaderofyourneighborhood?(top-rightpanel,theshareofrespondentsnamingthesameperson);

• Pleasetellmewhetheryouagreeordisagreewiththefollowingstatement:'Mostpeoplewholiveinthisneighborhoodcanbetrusted'(bottom-left,theshareresponding“stronglyagree”or“somewhatagree”);

• Supposethat10ofyourneighborswereinvitedtohelpincommunitywork,suchasacommunitywaterproject,cleaningofgutters,orweedingonthesideoftheroad.Howmanydoyouthinkwouldshowup?(bottom-right,themeanresponse,byslum).

Obviously,thereareslumswherehouseholdsthinktheyarestrongvotebanks,wherenearlyeveryoneagreesonwhothelocalleaderis,andwheresocialtrustandengagementarehigh.Therearealsoslumswithnoneofthesecharacteristics.Interestingly,preliminaryanalysissuggeststhatthisisnotsimplyafunctionofhowlongsettlementshaveexisted,theirsocialheterogeneityortheresourcesavailabletotheirhouseholds.

Figure6HereVI.2:LocalLeadershipCentralityandLegalRecognitionRecentworkonclientelismsuggeststhatlocalleaders/partybrokersplayacrucialroleinmediatingtherelationshipbetweenlocalcitizensandthebroaderpoliticalworld(Stokesetal.2013;Auerbach2014;RojoandWibbels2014),andagrowingbodyofworkemphasizestheroleofleadershipinmobilizinglatentsocialcapital(Krishna2007;Ostrom2001;AhlquistandLevi2011).Wedonothavedetailedleadershipdataforall157slums,butinthe2015householdsurveywedidaskrespondentsthenamesofthemostimportantlocalleaders.21Afterturningtheresultingnamesintoadjacencymatrices,weareabletoconstructnetworkgraphswhichprovideasenseofhowthese40slumsareorganizedataverylocallevel.Figure7providessixsuchgraphsthatrepresentthediverserangeofleadershipnetworks.FromUttarahalli,whereallbutonerespondentrecognizethesameleader,toGorguntepalay,whichischaracterizedbyalmosttotalpoliticalanomie,todifferentformsofbipolarand/orpartiallyorganizedsettlements,thereishugevariationinthemicro-politicalorganizationoftheseneighborhoods.Asapurelydescriptivematter,residentsinslumswithmorecentralizedleadershipnetworksreporthigherlevelsofinterpersonaltrust,greatersuccessinslum-levelvotebanking,andlessfrequentandseriousintra-slumconflict.

Figure7Thoughoneshouldbeskepticalofnetworkmeasuresdrawnfromsamples(ChandrasekharandLewis2011),weintroduceameasureofleadershipcentralityinto 21Dealingwithpropernamesinsurveysisverydifficult.Giventhepropensityformisspellingsanddifferentversionsofthesamenames,thesupervisorsandenumeratorsharmonizedthenameseachday.Inambiguouscases,supervisorscalledrespondentsforclarification(wecollectedcellphonenumbers).

Page 18: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

theslumrecognitionmodelsdesribedabove.Wemeasurenetworkcentralityusingaverageharmonicclosenessandincludenon-respondentsasisolates.22TheresultsarepresentedgraphicallyinFigure8.Obviouslythereisagooddealofuncertaintyaroundtheprediction,butthefiguresuggeststhatmovementfromtheleasttomostcentralizedleadershipnetworkincreasestheprobabilityofrecognitionfrom.4to.9.

Figure8HereObviouslythereisscantprospectofcausallyidentifyingtheeffectoflocalsocialstructureonslumrecognitionandlandtitling—wecannotexperimentonsocialstructureorleadershipcapability,andconvincinginstrumentsarenowheretobeseen.Nevertheless,wecandesignresearchtogetatplausiblemechanisms.Themostimportantmechanismlinkingthedensityoflocalleadershipnetworkstopoliticaloutcomesrunsthroughvoting.Wherelocalleadersservetocoordinatelocalvotersthesettlementservesasavotebank,andthereiswidespreadrecognitionthatelectedofficialsinIndiatargetresourcestotheirvotebanks.Toseeifthatisthecase,weranalistexperimentinthe2005surveywave.23BuildingonsimilarsurveyexperimentsbyGonzalez-Ocantosetal.(2012),eachrespondentwasgiventhefollowingintroduction:

Peopledecidewhotovoteforbasedonmanydifferentconsiderations.Iwillreadyousomeofthereasonspeoplehavetoldus.Pleasetellmehowmanyoftheseinfluenceyourvotechoice.Don’ttellmewhichones,justtellmehowmany.

Thecontrolwasgiventhreeinnocuousoptionsthatweredesignedtoavoidceilingeffects:TravelingtoBJPheadquarterstospeakwiththepartyheadabouttheelection;listeningtoradiocoverageofthecampaign;anddiscussingtheelectionwithfriendsorfamily.Thetreatmentgroupwasgivenafourthoption,namely“Thesuggestionsofyourneighborhoodleaderbecausehe/shehasmadearrangementswithapoliticalparty.”Appendix6reportsthatrandomassignmentsuccessfullyproducedbalanceonahostofindividual-levelcharacteristics.Weareweaklypoweredtolookatheterogeneouseffects(approximately200observationsperbin),butFigure9reportsthemaineffectofthetreatment(leftpanel),andthemeancountandcorresponding95%confidenceintervalsforthetreatedwhoareincommunitieswith:a)decentralizedleadershipnetworks;andb)centralizedleadershipnetworks(rightpanel).24Themeandifferencebetweenthetreatmentandcontrolgroupsforthesampleasawholeisinsignificant.Thedifferencebetweenthetreatedindecentralizedversuscentralizedslumsissignificantat.04,andthedifferencebetweenthetwoimpliesthat13percentmorevotersinsettlementswithcentralizedleadershipnetworksvoteinmannersconsistentwiththeeffortsoftheleader.Moresophisticatedtreatmentofthissurveyexperimentaldataisyettocome,butwearealsobusily

22Forexample,aleaderwith4followerswillhavecloseness4,becauses/heisdistance1from4othernodes.Eachofthisleader'sfollowershascloseness2.5,becauses/heisdistance1fromtheleaderanddistance2fromeachoftheotherfollowers(1/1+3*(1/2)=2.5).Thenetworkischaracterizedbytakingtheaverageoverallnodes.23ThesurveywasprogrammedinODKanddeliveredbytablet.Therandomizationwasachievedviarandomnumbergenerator. 24 I define centralized settlements as those with average harmonic closeness scores above the mean

Page 19: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

matchingvotingboothdatatoslumboundariesinordertoassesswhere,whenandhowslumsdo,infact,voteasvotebanks.

Figure9HereVII.ConclusionInourempiricalsetting,itistruethatincreasingtenuresecuritydoesindeeedleadtowealthandsavings.Butthemostimportantbarriertosecurityisnotprivatetitlesomuchasitisacollectively-heldtenureembodiedinslumrecognition.ThiscollectivelyheldrightbearsresemblancetoacommonpoolresourcealaOstrom,butitisdistincttotheextentthatitrequiresrecognitionandenforcementbyoutsidepoliticalandlegalauthorities.Theinterfacebetweenlocalcommunitiesandthatbroaderpoliticalworldisconditionedbymobilizationandthecapacitytodelivervotes.Thatcapacityreflectsmanyofthecharacteristicsthatareconsistentwiththesharedmanagementofcommonpoolresourcesinruralandforestcommunities.Unlikeinthoseisolatedcommunities,however,theurbanpoormustbepoliticallyattractivetooutsiderswhomakekeydecisions.Wheretheyare,theyaremorelikelytoextractslumrecognition,andrecognitionhasverylargepositiveeffectsforhousehold-andcommunity-leveldevelopment.Ourfindingsarebroadlyconsistentwiththegrowingcallforafocusontenuresecurityattheexpenseofformaltenureprovision(seeDurand-Lasserve2009forareview). Interestingly,thecapacitytobecomepoliticallyattractiveisunrelatedtothecasteorreligiousheterogeneityofcommunities.ItseemsthereisconsiderableroomforhumanagencyintheslumsofBangalore. Thereareseveralanglesforfuturework.Subsequentrevisionsofthismanuscriptwillbringmorehouseholdlevelevidencetobearonthedensityofsocialnetworksintheslumsandcoverawiderrangeofhousehold-levelfinancialbehavior.Inextensions,wewillfocusexplicitlyonexplaininghighlyvariedaccesstokeypublicservices,theelectoralbehaviorofsettlements,andtheroleoflocalleadershipandpoliticalnetworksinconditioningslum-andhousehold-leveloutcomes.Finally,wewouldliketoexploreinfinerdetailthemicrofoundationsunderpinningourfindingsinthispaper.Ouraccountandevidencebegtwobigquestions,onebearingonvariationacrossspaceandtheotherbearingonvariationovertime.Thefirstquestionis:Howwellwillthesefindingstravel?Ourempiricsaredrawnfromslumsandgovernmentinonecity.Giventhatthereissubstantialleewayforcityandstategovernmentstomanageinformalsettlements(Durand-LasserveandRoyston2012),itisimportanttoresearchthesedynamicsinothercitiesinIndiaandother“worldcities”inthedevelopingworldthatsharethesameboomsthathavedrivenurbanpropertydynamicsinBangalore.Questionsabound:Howdolandlawsbearonrecognition?Howdoesvariationintheorganizationofcitygovernmentimpactthepoliticsofurbanlandtenure?OurinitialworksuggeststhatthelegaldistinctionbetweenslumrecognitionandindividualtitleinIndiadoesmapontopropertyregimeselsewhere,butthereisalotofworktobedone.

Page 20: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Finally,wehavedonelittletoaddresstheobviousquestionthatbedevilsmostworkonsocialcapitalandsocialnetworks:Wheredoesdensesocialorganizationcomesfrom?Wearelimitedbythecross-sectionalnatureofourdata,butweadmittoagoodbitoftheoreticaluncertaintyaswell.Dodensesocialnetworksandpoliticallymobilizedslumsemergefromsomeideal,primordialsocialconditionsearlyinaslum’shistory?Ordogoodneighborhood,wardandMLAleaders(i.e.successfulpoliticalentrepreneurs)producedenselyorganizedcommunitiesandvotebanksbyvirtueoforganizing,constituencyservice,andthecontinuousapplicationofhardwork.Considerableresearchonsocialheterogeneitysuggeststhatcaste-andreligious-baseddiversityshouldplayanimportantroleinconditioningthecapacityoflocalcommunitiestoengageincollectiveaction,andwecanpointtoparticularsettlementswherethatseemstobethecase.Yet,wefindnosystematicevidencethatmoreheterogeneousslumshavemorespartansocialnetworksorarelesspoliticallyengaged.Obviouslythismightsimplyreflectthemodestnumberofslumswecandrawevidencefrom,butitisworthnotingthatoursampleisaboutaslargeasthecross-countrysamplesthathavedrivenmuchofthecurrentthinkingontherelationshipbetweensocialheterogeneity,publicgoodsprovisionanddevelopment(Alesinaetal.2003).Emprically,studyingtheemergenceandevolutionofsocialnetworksinarealworldsettingsuchasslums(i.e.asettingthatisnotwellcapturedbyFacebook,LinkedInorothersocialnetworksitesthathaveprovidedimportantinsight)isincrediblydifficult.Butitisforexactlythatreasonthatourlong-runningworkinBangaloreisnowherenearcomplete.

Page 21: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

ReferencesAhlquist,JohnandMargaretLevi.2011.“Leadership:WhatItMeans,WhatItDoes,andWhatWeWanttoKnowAboutIt.”AnnualReviewofPoliticalScience14:1-24.Alesina,Alberto,ArnaudDevleeschauwer,WilliamEasterly,SergioKurlatandRomainWacziarg.2003.“Fractionalization.”JournalofEconomicGrowth8:155-94.Auerbach,Adam.2014.“ClientsandCommunities:ThePoliticalEconomyofPartyNetworkOrganizationandDevelopmentinIndia’sUrbanSlums.”WorkingPaper,AmericanUniversity.Baharoglu,Deniz.2002.“WorldBankExperienceinLandManagementandtheDebateonTenureSecurity.”HousingResearchBackground-LandManagementPaper.Banerjee,AbhijitandEstherDuflo.2011.Pooreconomics:Aradicalrethinkingofthewaytofightglobalpoverty.PublicAffairs.BesleyandGhatak.2009.“PropertyRightsandEconomicDevelopment.”InDaniRodrikandMarkRosenzweig,editors:HandbookofDevelopmentEconomics,Vol.5,TheNetherlands:North-Holland,2010,pp.4525-4595.Besley,BurchardiandGhatak.2012.“IncentivesandtheDeSotoEffect.”QuarterlyJournalofEconomicsBrune,Lasse,etal.“FacilitatingSavingsforAgriculture:FieldExperimentalEvidencefromMalawi.”No.w20946.NationalBureauofEconomicResearch,2015.Chandrasekhar,ArunandRandallLewis.2011.“EconometricsofSampledNetworks.”WorkingPaper,StanfordDepartmentofEconomics.Deininger,KlausandHansBinswanger.1999.“EvolutionoftheWorldBank’sLandPolicy:Principles,Experience,andFutureChallenges.”TheWorldBankResearchObserver14:247-76.Deiningeretal.2011.“ImpactofLandCertificationonTenureSecurity,Investment,andLandMarketParticipation:EvidencefromEthiopia.”LandEconomicsDemarchi,Scott.2014.“Institutions,DomainRestrictionsandCognition.”Manuscript,DepartmentofPoliticalScience,DukeUniversity.deSoto,Hernando.1990.TheOtherPath:TheInvisibleRevolutionintheThirdWorld.PerennialLibrary.

Page 22: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

DiTella,Rafael,SebastianGalianiandErnestoSchargrodsky.2007.“TheFormationofBeliefs:EvidencefromtheAllocationofLandTitlestoSquatters.”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics122:209-41.Durand-Lasserve,AlainandLaurenRoyston.2012Field,Erica.2005.“PropertyRightsandInvestmentinUrbanSlums.”JournaloftheEuropeanEconomicAssociationPapersandProceedings3:279-290.Field,Erica.2007.“EntitledtoWork:UrbanPropertyRightsandLaborSupplyinPeru.”TheQuarterlyJournalofEconomics122:1561-1602.Galiani,SebastianandESchargrodsky.2010.“Propertyrightsforthepoor:Effectsoflandtitling.”JournalofPublicEconomics94:700-29.Goldstein,MarkusandChristopherUdry.2008.“TheProfitsofPower:LandRightsandAgriculturalInvestmentinGhana.”JournalofPoliticalEconomy116:981-1022.Gonzalez-Ocantos,Ezequiel,ChadKiewetdeJone,CarlosMelendex,JavierOsorioandDavidNickerson.2012.“VoteBuyingandSocialDesirabilityBias:ExperimentalEvidencefromNicaragua.”AmericanJournalofPoliticalScience56:202-17.Hornbeck,Richard.2010."Barbedwire:Propertyrightsandagriculturaldevelopment."TheQuarterlyJournalofEconomics125:767-810.Krishna,Anirudh.2007.“HowDoesSocialCapitalGrow?ASeven-YearStudyofVillagesinIndia”.JournalofPolitics,69:941-956.Marx,StokerandSuri.2015.“ThereisnoFreeHouse:EthnicPatronageandPropertyRightsinaKenyanSlum.”WorkingPaperMIT.North,Douglas.1990.Institutions,InstitutionalChange,andEconomicPerformance.NewYork:CambridgeUniversityPress.North,DouglasandBarryWeingast.1989.“ConstitutionsandCommitment:TheEvolutionofInstitutionsGoverningPublicChoiceinSeventeenthCenturyEngland,JournalofEconomicHistory49:803-32.Ostrom,Elinor.1990.Governingthecommons:Theevolutionofinstitutionsforcollectiveaction.NewYork:CambridgeUniversityPress.Ostrom,Elinor.2001.“SocialCapital:AFadoraFundamentalConcept?”InParthaDasguptaandIsmailSerageldin,eds.SocialCapital:AMultifacetedPerspective.Washington,DC:WorldBankPublications.

Page 23: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Payne,Geoffrey,AlainDurand-Lasserve,andCaroleRakodi.2009.“SocialandEconomicImpactsofLandTitlingProgramsinUrbanandPeriurbanAreas:AShortReviewoftheLiterature.”UrbanLandMarkets133-16

Pagano,Marco.1993."FinancialMarketsandGrowth:AnOverview."EuropeanEconomicReview37:613-622.Pande,RohiniandChristopherUdry.2005.“InstitutionsandDevelopment:AViewfromBelow.”IntheProceedingsofthe9thWorldCongressoftheEconometricSociety,editedbyR.Blundell,W.Newey,andT.Persson.NewYork:CambridgeUniversityPress.Rojo,GuadalupeandErikWibbels.2014.“PoliticalNetworks,ClientelismandPublicGoods:EvidencefromSlumsinUdaipur,India.”WorkingPaper,DukeUniversity.Stokes,Susan,ThadDunning,MarceloNazarenoandValeriaBrusco.2013.Brokers,VotersandClientelism:ThePuzzleofDistributivePolitics.NewYork:CambridgeUniversityPress.UN-HABITAT.2002.“TheGlobalCampaignonUrbanGovernance.”ConceptNote,Nairobi,Kenya.VanGelder,Jean-Louis.2009.“LegalTenureSecurity,PerceivedTenureSecurityandHousingImprovementinBuenosAires:AnAttempttowardsIntegration.”InternationalJournalofUrbanandRegionalResearch33:126-46.WorldBank.2011.“LandTenurePolicy:SecuringRightstoReducePovertyandPromoteRuralGrowth.”WashingtonDC:TheWorldBank.

Page 24: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Figure1:GeotaggedSlumBoundaries,

4x5km(toppanel)and800x1400m(bottompanel)

Page 25: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Figure2:

Note:Thefiguredisplaysthepredictedscoreontheassetindex(and95%confidenceintervals)simulatedfromModel5inTableA.2whenaslumisrecognizedornotandwhenahouseholdhastitleornot.

Page 26: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Figure3:

Note:Thefigurepresentsthepredictedprobability(and95%confidenceintervals)ofusingaformalsavingsinstitutionassimulatedfromModel4inTableA.3.

Page 27: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Figure4:

Note:Thetoppanelofthefigurepresentsthepredictedprobability(and95%confidenceintervals)offeelingveryinsecurewithregardstothethreatofevictionassimulatedfromModel3inTableA.4whenaslumisrecognizedandnotandwhenahouseholdhastitleandnot.Thebottompanelisirrelevant.

Page 28: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Figure5:

Note:Theleftpanelofthefigurepresentsthepredictedprobabilityofaslumbeinglegallyrecognizedastheshareofitsresidentsparticipateinaneighborhoodorganization;theresultsaresimulatedoffModel1inAppendixA.5.Therightpanelpresentsthepredictedprobabilityofaslumbeinglegallyrecognizedwhenitsresidentshaveapoliticalrepresentativewhotheyturntointheeventofproblemswithlocalservices;theresultsaresimulatedoffModel3inAppendixA.5.

Page 29: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Figure6:

Note:Thefigurepresentsthekerneldensityofslum-levelmeansto(orsharesof)householdrespondentstothefollowingquestions:Doyouthinkyourneighborhoodisaneffectivevotebank?(top-leftpanel);Canyougivemethenameofthefirstmostimportantleaderofyourneighborhood?(top-right,thisisthesharenamingthesameperson);Pleasetellmewhetheryouagreeordisagreewiththefollowingstatement:'Mostpeoplewholiveinthisneighborhoodcanbetrusted'(bottom-left,theshareresponding“stronglyagree”or“somewhatagree”);Supposethat10ofyourneighborswereinvitedtohelpincommunitywork,suchasacommunitywaterproject,cleaningofgutters,orweedingonthesideoftheroad.Howmanydoyouthinkwouldshowup?(bottom-right,themeanresponse,byslum).

Page 30: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Figure7:LeadershipNetworksinSeveralSlums

Page 31: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Figure8:

Note:Leadershipcentralityismeasuredastheaverageharmoniccloseness,i.e.themeanofthesumoftheinversedistancesofeachnodetoalltheothernodes.

Page 32: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

FigureX:SurveyExperimentalEvidenceonLeadershipNetworksandVoting

Page 33: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

AppendixA.1:TenureInsecurityinPictures—theCaseofPattandurAgraharaSettlement

Page 34: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

AppendixA.2:LegalRecognitionandPrivateTitleinBangaloreTheprocessofgettinganindividualpropertytitleiscomplexandpassesthroughmultiplestages,ateachofwhichitcangetderailedorsubstantiallydelayed.Sustainedpoliticalpressureisusuallynecessarytogofromonestagetothenext.Thisprocess,asitwasdescribedforusbyanexperiencedadministratorwhohasdealtwithslumsinKarnatakaformanyyears,typicallystartswiththeoccupationofavacantpieceoflandinacity,onwhichtheoccupantscarveoutplotsandbuildarudimentaryshack.Bluepolygonslumscorrespond,thus,totheveryfirststageofalongdrawn-outprocess,butsometimesthisprocessendsrightthere.Goingtothenextstageusuallyinvolvesacquiringvoteridentificationcards,establishingtheholderasabonafideresidentofBangalore.WiththehelpoftheirVoterIDs,individualsareabletoacquireelectricityconnectionsfortheirshacksandarationcard(whichestablishesanentitlementtobuycommoditiesatgovernment-subsidizedfair-priceshops).Afterasubstantialnumberofresidentsinaslumsettlementhavegarneredsuchpapers,officialdocumentationwhichtheycanattachtotheirclaimforbeingrecognizedasa“slum”andregisteredintheofficialrecord,thenextsteptowardobtainingapropertytitleistaken,mostoftenwiththehelpofalocalpoliticalentrepreneur,whomightbeanelectedofficialorapartyorganizer.ThisstepinvolvesthepresentationofapetitiontotheKarnatakaSlumDevelopmentBoard(KSDB),formerlytheKarnatakaStateClearanceBoard,whichischargedwiththeresponsibilityof“recognizing”thesesettlementsasslums,andforprovidingservicestosuchsettlementsasitrecognizes,thoughonoccasion,bowingtopoliticalpressure,theBoardhasbeenprovidingserviceseventonon-recognizedslums.TheprocessofgrantingofficialrecognitiontoasettlementthatpresentsapetitionisgovernedbytheprovisionsoftheKarnatakaSlumAreas(ImprovementandClearance)Actof1973.Anumberofstepsaremandated,whichinexpedientcasesgettelescopedandrushedthrough,butinothercases,aredealtwithatasnail’space.Pressureandinducementsofdifferentkindsplayalargepartinwhogetsrecognitionandwhen.Addingtothemessinessandconfusion,multipleagencies,includingthemunicipalcorporation(orBBMP)havealsobeeninvolvedingrantingrecognitiontoslums.Ifthelanduponwhichasettlementislocatedis“clear,”inthesensethatitdoesnotbelongtoadepartmentofthefederalgovernment(alargeamountofpubliclandinthecityisownedbythemilitaryandtherailwaysdepartment,alegacyofcolonialrule)anddoesnotformpartofanaturaldrainagechannel,situponahazardouswastesiteorbeenzonedfornon-residentialuse(althoughtheselasttwoobjectionscanbefinagled)–thenthenextstageoftheodysseyleadingtoeventualpropertytitlescanbeembarkedupon.KSDBofficialsconductapreliminarysurvey,roughlymappingtheboundariesofthesettlementandconductingacensusofthosewholivethere.Theyknowtheywillhavetoundertakeanothercensuslater,sothisfirstcensusisarough-and-readyaffair.Theysubmittheirreporttoseniorgovernmentofficials,uponwhosesatisfaction,thenextstageintheprocessisputinplace.AdraftnotificationissubsequentlyissuedundertherelatedprovisionoftheSlumAct.Objectionsareinvitedfromthepublic.Ifthelandonwhichthesettlementisbasedisthepropertyofaprivateowner,thepetitionforrecognitionoftendiesthere.

Page 35: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

Petitionswhichsucceedatthisstage,usuallyinvolvingsettlementsbasedon“clear”publiclands(orothersinwhichtheprivateownerbecomescomplicit)aretakentothenextstage.Thepreliminarynotificationissuedbythestategovernmentisreissuedasafinalnotification.Itisatthisstage,i.e.,aftergettingthefinalofficialnotification,thataslumbecomesofficiallyeligibleforreceivingbothmunicipalservicesandpropertytitlesfortheregisteredresidents(knownashakkupatrainthelocalparlance).Municipalservicescomemuchbeforetitlesaregivenout.Beforegrantingtitles,asecondsurveymustbecarriedout.Often,severalyearspassbeforesuchasurveygetstobeconducted.Evenafterward,onlyIDcardsareissued;gettingafulltitlecantakeanotherfewyears.Residentsofanotifiedslumwhodonothavetitlesenjoytheprotectionofknowingthattheycannotbeabruptlydislocated;notificationgivesthemarighttolivethere.Theyaresometimesissuedwith“possessioncertificates.”Butuntiltheygetafulltitle(thehakkupatra),theycannotsell,mortgageorotherwisetransfertheirproperties,atleastonformalpropertymarkets.2,487ofthehouseholdsinoursampleliveinslumsthathavebeenofficiallyrecognized,butonly40percenthaveahakkupatra.

Page 36: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

AppendixA.3:Assets Model1 Model2 Model3 Model4 Table5 Table6

Female-HeadedHH 0.128 -0.0705 -0.0312 -0.0623 -0.214* -0.166

(0.97) (-0.50) (-0.24) (-0.45) (-2.21) (-1.50)

Hindu 0.0195 0.351 -0.0721 0.294 0.0760 -0.0796

(0.08) (1.24) (-0.27) (1.11) (0.72) (-0.68)

Caste 1.090*** 1.772*** 0.970*** 1.704*** 0.501*** 0.411**

(4.18) (6.98) (4.02) (7.10) (5.21) (3.32)

Age

0.00648

0.00478

0.00164

(1.40)

(0.98)

(0.77)

YearsinHouse

0.0652***

0.0435***

0.00204

(7.98)

(4.13)

(0.58)

Title

1.117*** 1.324*** 0.434*** 0.315*

(4.07) (3.50) (3.53) (2.22)

SlumRecognized

3.349*** 3.972***

(11.51) (17.20)

_cons -0.272 -2.267*** -0.628 -2.447*** -2.782*** -2.916*** (-0.84) (-5.40) (-1.66) (-6.28) (-12.40) (-18.27)R-sq 0.048 0.265 0.121 0.321 0.608 0.761F 7.138 21.59 8.062 27.69 96.65 237.1N 3358 1897 3328 1877 3328 1877tstatisticsinparentheses

="*p<0.05 **p<0.01 ***p<0.001"

Page 37: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

AppendixA.3:UseofFormalSavings

Model1 Model2 Model3Model4(HLM)

Female-HeadedHH -0.145 -0.147 -0.143 -0.134

(-1.05) (-1.04) (-1.01) (-0.74)

Hindu 0.0597 0.0954 0.0269 0.0218

(0.33) (0.50) (0.13) (0.12)

Caste 0.185 0.177 0.0317 0.0228

(1.14) (1.08) (0.19) (0.14)

Age -0.00482 -0.00547 -0.00581 -0.00633

(-0.98) (-1.09) (-1.14) (-1.19)

YearsinHouse 0.00748 -0.00200 -0.00579 -0.00651

(1.86) (-0.48) (-1.37) (-1.34)

Title

0.561*** 0.397** 0.412**

(4.41) (3.24) (2.85)

SlumRecognized

0.591*** 0.609***

(4.00) (3.66)

_cons -0.582* -0.710* -0.878** -0.868**

(-2.17) (-2.46) (-2.83) (-3.13)

RandomEffect

-1.551** (-3.09)pseudoR-sq 0.004 0.014 0.023

AIC 1727.7 1690.2 1676.9 1677.5N 1318 1298 1298 1298

tstatisticsinparentheses=*p<0.05

Page 38: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

AppendixA.4:InsecurityinTenure Model1 Model2 Model3

Female-HeadedHH 0.0615 0.0771 0.0527

(0.34) (0.42) (0.29)

Hindu -0.0979 -0.0988 -0.0772

(-0.49) (-0.49) (-0.39)

Caste 0.0527 0.0397 0.125

(0.30) (0.22) (0.67)

Age 0.00638 0.00619 0.00659

(1.00) (0.96) (1.03)

YearsinHouse -0.00445 -0.00430 -0.000560

(-0.86) (-0.85) (-0.12)

Title

-0.00309 0.169

(-0.02) (1.34)

SlumRecognized

-1.038*** (-9.96)cut1

_cons -1.060*** -1.053*** -1.731***

(-4.07) (-3.79) (-6.66)

cut2 _cons -0.0535 -0.0576 -0.719**

(-0.21) (-0.22) (-2.67)

cut3 _cons 1.788*** 1.775*** 1.155***

(6.82) (6.30) (4.41)pseudoR-sq 0.001 0.001 0.015AIC 3269.8 3234.3 3191.9N 1221 1206 1206tstatisticsinparentheses

="*p<0.05 **p<0.01

Page 39: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

AppendixA.5: Model1 Model2 Model3 Model4NeighborhoodOrganization 0.0321** 0.0258*

(2.89) (2.12)

PoliticalEngagement

1.179** 0.480

(2.71) (0.99)

SettlementAge

0.131**

0.135**

(2.98)

(3.07)

SettlementAge-squared

-0.00105**

-0.00109**

(-2.72)

(-2.82)

NumberofHouseholds

0.000112

0.0000588

(1.11)

(0.62)

PercentHindu

-0.00799

-0.00522

(-0.83)

(-0.56)

PercentGeneralandOBC

-0.0107

-0.0144

(-0.75)

(-1.02)

Constant -1.217*** -3.788** -1.705*** -3.999** (-5.53) (-2.62) (-4.44) (-2.77)pseudoR-sq 0.051 0.172 0.044 0.149AIC 185.9 171.0 187.2 175.2N 157 154 157 154tstatisticsinparentheses

="*p<0.05 **p<0.01 ***p<0.001"

Page 40: Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”...“Satellites, Slums and Social Networks: Evidence on the Origins and Consequences of Property Rights from 157 Slums in Bangalore”

AppendixA.6BalanceTestonSurveyExperimentalTreatment

Variables Control Treatment DifferenceAge 41.212 40.517 0.695

OwnHome 0.571 0.558 0.013Female 0.384 0.427 -0.043

FemaleHeadedHH 0.141 0.171 -0.03Hindu 0.778 0.817 -0.039

Assets(PC) 0.916 0.798 0.119Caste 0.359 0.323 0.036

YearsinHouse 16.778 16.274 0.504

Note:Noneofthedifferencesarestatisticallysignificant