debraj ray - new york university30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990...

16
L E I Debraj Ray, University of Warwick, Summer Inequality and Divergence Slides : Introduction Slides : Occupational Choice Slides : Economic Growth and the Capital Share Inequality and Conict Slides : Polarization and Fractionalization Slides : Some Empirical Findings Slides (preliminary): Notes on Class Conict I. Inequality and Divergence: Introduction

Upload: others

Post on 03-Oct-2020

7 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

L������� �� E������� I���������

Debraj Ray, University of Warwick, Summer ����

Inequality and Divergence

Slides �: Introduction

Slides �: Occupational Choice

Slides �: Economic Growth and the Capital Share

Inequality and Con�ict

Slides �: Polarization and Fractionalization

Slides �: Some Empirical Findings

Slides � (preliminary): Notes on Class Con�ict

I. Inequality and Divergence: Introduction

Page 2: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

T�� G���� U-T���

The �nancial crisis sparked a new interest in inequality.

But inequality has been historically high

Growing steadily through late ��th century

Wol�, Piketty, Saez, Atkinson, many others

A classical view (due to Kuznets ����, ����)

Inequality rises and then falls with development

Instead: The Great U-Turn

Uneven versus compensatory changes

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

50%

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Sha

re o

f top

dec

ile in

nat

iona

l inc

ome

Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010

The top decile share in U.S. national income dropped from 45-50% in the 1910s-1920s to less than 35% in the 1950s (this is the fall documented by Kuznets); it then rose from less than 35% in the 1970s to 45-50% in the 2000s-2010s. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c.

Source: Piketty (����)

Page 3: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

50%

1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Sha

re o

f top

dec

ile in

tota

l inc

ome

The top decile income share was higher in Europe than in the U.S. in 1900-1910; it is a lot higher in the U.S. in 2000-2010. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c.

Figure 9.8. Income inequality: Europe vs. the United States, 1900-2010

U.S.

Europe

Source: Piketty (����)

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

16%

18%

20%

22%

24%

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Sha

re o

f top

per

cent

ile in

tota

l inc

ome

The share of top percentile in total income rose since the 1970s in all Anglo-saxon countries, but with different magnitudes. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c.

Figure 9.2. Income inequality in Anglo-saxon countries, 1910-2010

U.S. U.K.

Canada Australia

Source: Piketty (����)

Page 4: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

8%

9%

10%

11%

12%

1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

Sha

re o

f top

0.1

% in

tota

l inc

ome

The share of the top 0.1% highest incomes in total income rose sharply since the 1970s in all Anglo-saxon countries, but with varying magnitudes. Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c.

Figure 9.5. The top 0.1% income share in Anglo-saxon countries, 1910-2010

U.S. U.K.

Canada Australia

Source: Piketty (����)

P��������W��� I����-C������ I���������

Within-country:

Kuznets

Cross-country:

Solow

Neither story appears to work too well.

Page 5: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

C����-C������ C����������: T�� P����� �� H������ R����������

Baumol (AER ����): �� countries, among the richest in the world today.

In order of poorest to richest in ����: Japan, Finland, Sweden, Norway, Germany,

Italy, Austria, France, Canada, Denmark, the United States, the Netherlands,

Switzerland, Belgium, the United Kingdom, and Australia.

Angus Maddison: per-capita incomes for ����.

Idea: regress ����–���� growth rate on ���� incomes.

ln y����i � ln y����i = A+ b ln y����i + ✏i

Unconditional convergence) b ' �1.

Get b = �0.995, R2 = 0.88.

What’s wrong with this picture?

Page 6: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

De Long critique (AER ����):

Add seven more countries to Maddison’s ��.

In ����, they had as much claim to membership in the “convergence club” as

any included in the ��: Argentina, Chile, East Germany, Ireland, New Zealand,

Portugal, and Spain.

New Zealand, Argentina, and Chile were in the list of top ten recipients of British

and French overseas investment (in per capita terms) as late as ����.

All had per capita GDP higher than Finland in ����.

Strategy: drop Japan (why?), add the �.

Slope still negative, though loses signi�cance.

Correct for measurement error, game over.

Page 7: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

Updated Maddison dataset ����, �� countries:

1"

2"

3"

4"

5.8" 6.3" 6.8" 7.3" 7.8"

log"pe

r1capita"income"grow

th,"187012010"

log"per1capita"income,"1870"(in"1990"dollars)"

Black points are Maddison’s �� on which Baumol (����) was based.

C������ �� ��� ���� C������

A recent book by Piketty:

summarizes the evidence (compelling and useful)

describes three “fundamental laws”

is a runaway hit in the United States, touching a raw nerve

Page 8: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

P������’� T���� F���������� L���

The First Fundamental Law:

Capital IncomeTotal Income

=Capital IncomeCapital Stock

⇥ Capital StockTotal Income

.

Share of capital income equals rate of return on capital multiplied by the

capital-output ratio.

Useful in organizing our mental accounting system.

Not an explanation.

The Second Fundamental Law:

Growth rate equals savings rate divided by capital-output ratio.

Basic capital accumulation equation:

K(t+ 1) = [1� �(t)]K(t) + I(t) = [1� �(t)]K(t) + s(t)Y (t)

Convert to growth rates:

G(t) =s(t)

✓(t)� �(t),

where G(t) = [K(t+ 1)�K(t))]/K(t) and ✓(t) = K(t)/Y (t).

Approximate per-capita version: subtract n(t), the rate of population growth.

g(t) ' s(t)

✓(t)� �(t)� n(t),

Note: This isn’t a theory unless you take a stand on one or more of the variables.

Page 9: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

B��������: “E���������” C������-O����� R����� U���� G����� R����!

Piketty:

“If one now combines variations in growth rates with variations in savings rate, it is

easy to explain why di�erent countries accumulate very di�erent quantities of

capital. . .One particularly clear case is that of Japan: with a savings rate close to ��

percent a year and a growth rate barely above � percent, it is hardly surprising that

Japan has over the long run accumulated a capital stock worth six to seven years

of national income. This is an automatic consequence of the [second] dynamic law

of accumulation.” (p.���)

“The very sharp increase in private wealth observed in the rich countries, and

especially in Europe and Japan, between ���� and ���� thus can be explained

largely by slower growth coupled with continued high savings, using the [second]

law . . . ” (p. ���)

The Third Fundamental Law:

r > g

Page 10: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

r > g: “T�� C������ C������������ �� C���������”

“Whenever the rate of return on capital is signi�cantly and durably higher than the

growth rate of the economy, . . .wealth originating in the past automatically grows

more rapidly than wealth stemming from work.”

“This inequality expresses a fundamental logical contradiction . . . the past devours

the future . . . the consequences are potentially terrifying, etc.”

r > g in the data.

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

0-1000 1000-1500 1500-1700 1700-1820 1820-1913 1913-1950 1950-2012 2012-2050 2050-2100

Ann

ual r

ate

of re

turn

or r

ate

of g

row

th

The rate of return to capital (pre-tax) has always been higher than the world growth rate, but the gap was reduced during the 20th century, and might widen again in the 21st century.

Sources and series: see piketty.pse.ens.fr/capital21c

Figure 10.9. Rate of return vs. growth rate at the world level, from Antiquity until 2100

Pure rate of return to capital r (pre-tax)

Growth rate of world output g

Page 11: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

N�� � T��������, T���, B�� �� E��������� C��������

Recall: K(t+ 1) = [1� �(t)]K(t) + s(t)Y (t). Impose s(t) = s, �(t) = �,

and

Yt = AK✓t [(1 + �)tLt]

1�✓,

where Lt grows at rate n, and � is technical progress.

Normalize: kt ⌘ Kt/Lt(1 + �)t and yt ⌘ Yt/Lt(1 + �)t; then

yt = Ak✓t .

and

(1 + n)(1 + �)kt+1 = (1� �)kt + sAk✓t ,

N�� � T��������, T���, B�� �� E��������� C��������

So far: yt = Ak✓t and (1 + n)(1 + �)kt+1 = (1� �)kt + sAk✓t , so that

kt ! k⇤ '

sA

n+ � + �

�1/(1�✓)

and

yt ! y⇤ ' A1/(1�✓)

s

n+ � + �

�✓/(1�✓)

.

So the overall rate of growth converges to n+ �.

On the other hand, r is given by the marginal product:

rt = ✓A⇥Kt/(1 + �)tLt

⇤✓�1

= ✓Ak✓�1t

! ✓A

sA

n+ � + �

��1

=✓

s[n+ � + �],

Page 12: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

N�� � T��������, T���, B�� �� E��������� C��������

So down to comparing r = ✓s [n+ � + �] with g = n+ �.

) r > g if ✓ � s (surely true empirically, but also for deeper reasons):

s is ine�cient if consumption can be improved in all periods.

Easy example: s = 1, but there are others.

Recall that Yt/Lt converges to

A1/(1�✓)(1 + �)t✓

s

n+ � + �

◆✓/(1�✓)

and per-capita consumption converges to the path

A1/(1�✓)(1 + �)t✓

s

n+ � + �

◆✓/(1�✓)

(1� s).

It follows that if s > ✓, the growth path is ine�cient.

So e�ciency implies r > g, but there is no prediction for inequality.

D����������� S������ R����

The Third Law is really a simple statement about di�erential savings rates.

For instance, assume that the rich earn predominantly capital income

yt = ct + kt

kt = syt, yt+1 = rkt

y(t) = y(0)(1 + sr)t

If initial rich share is x(0), and g is rate of growth, then t periods later:

x(t) = x(0)

✓1 + sr

1 + g

◆t

Can back out r if we know s and {x(t)}:

r =[x(t)/x(0)]1/t(1 + g)� 1

s

Page 13: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

D����������� S������ R����

Do the rich save more than the poor? (lifetime vs current income)

Estimates from Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF):

�-Yr Income Average Instrumented By

Vehicle Consumption

Quintile � �.� �.�

Quintile � �.� ��.�

Quintile � ��.� ��.�

Quintile � ��.� ��.�

Quintile � ��.� ��.�

Top �� ��.� ��.�

Top �� ��.� ��.�

Source: Dynan-Skinner-Zeldes (����), they provide other estimates

r =[x(t)/x(0)]1/t(1 + g)� 1

s

Some quick calculations for top ��� in the US:

x0 = 1/3 in ����, rises to xt = 47/100 in ����.

Estimate for g: �� per year.

Estimate from Dynan et al for s: ��� (optimistic).

Can back out for r: r = 9.7%.

In�ation-adjusted rate of return on US stocks over ��th century: �.��

Much lower in the ����s and ����s, higher in the ����s and ����s.

Page 14: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

r =[x(t)/x(0)]1/t(1 + g)� 1

s

Similar calculations for top �� in the US:

x0 = 8/100 in ����, rises to xt = 18/100 in ����.

Estimate for g: �� per year.

Estimate from Dynan et al for s: ���.

Can back out for r: r = 10.5%.

r =[x(t)/x(0)]1/t(1 + g)� 1

s

Try the top �.�� for the United States:

x0 = 2.2/100 in ����, rises to xt = 8/100 in ����.

Estimate for g: �� per year.

If these guys also save at �.�, then r = 14.4%!

If they save 3/4 of their income, then r = 9.6%.

Page 15: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

r =[x(t)/x(0)]1/t(1 + g)� 1

s

Slightly better job for Europe, but not much. Top ���:

x0 = 29/100 in ����, rises to xt = 35/100 in ����.

Estimate for g: �� per year.

Estimate from Dynan et al for s: ���.

Can back out for r: r = 7.5%.

High relative to r in Europe.

UK the highest at �.�� over ��th century, others appreciably lower.

r =[x(t)/x(0)]1/t(1 + g)� 1

s

Finally, top �� for the UK:

x0 = 6/100 in ����, rises to xt = 15/100 in ����.

Estimate for g: �� per year.

Estimate from Dynan et al for s: ���.

Can back out for r: r = 11.4%.

Summary

Di�erential savings rates explain some of the inequality, but far from all of it.

Page 16: Debraj Ray - New York University30% 35% 40% 45% 50% 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 Figure I.1. Income inequality in the United States, 1910-2010 The top decile

W��� E������� ��� H��� R���� �� R����� �� ��� R���?

Two broad groups of answers:

The rich have information on higher rates of return (see Supplement)

The rich have physical access to higher rates of return.

Better physical access: imperfect capital markets and nonconvexities:

Stocks (no problem)

Hedge funds?

Private unincorporated businesses (moral hazard, adverse selection)

Human capital (inalienability, holding children responsible for debt)