cigarette strength and smoking behavior · 2 cigarette strength and smoking behavior in june 2009,...

37
Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior Esteban Petruzzello * Abstract This paper analyzes the link between cigarette strength and smoking behavior. I es- timate state dependence demand models that capture two main features of addiction: reinforcement and the existence of withdrawal costs. I find that demand for lights is more price sensitive than for regulars, and that lights are less addictive. Addition- ally, I find that while smoking restrictions are ineffective in reducing regular cigarette smoking, they reduce light cigarette purchases by about half a pack per month. I also find that the quitting behavior of regular and light smokers is similar, though there is some evidence that switching to lights contributes to quitting. These findings support the idea that an establishment of maximum nicotine levels could be helpful to curtail smoking. JEL Codes: D03, D12, I18, L66. * Department of Economics, University of Miami - [email protected]. I would like to thank Aviv Nevo, Igal Hendel, and Robert Porter for their support and guidance. I would also like to thank Germ´ an Bet, Ignacio Franceschelli, Melissa Gray, Frank Limbrock, Lee Lockwood, Fernando Luco, Guillermo Marshall, Cecilia Peluffo, Tiago Pires, and Ana Reynoso for their valuable comments, and the seminar participants at Northwestern University. This research was funded in part by a cooperative agreement between the USDA/ERS and Northwestern University, but the views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the U.S. Department of Agriculture.

Upload: others

Post on 19-Aug-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior

Esteban Petruzzello∗

Abstract

This paper analyzes the link between cigarette strength and smoking behavior. I es-

timate state dependence demand models that capture two main features of addiction:

reinforcement and the existence of withdrawal costs. I find that demand for lights is

more price sensitive than for regulars, and that lights are less addictive. Addition-

ally, I find that while smoking restrictions are ineffective in reducing regular cigarette

smoking, they reduce light cigarette purchases by about half a pack per month. I also

find that the quitting behavior of regular and light smokers is similar, though there is

some evidence that switching to lights contributes to quitting. These findings support

the idea that an establishment of maximum nicotine levels could be helpful to curtail

smoking.

JEL Codes: D03, D12, I18, L66.

∗Department of Economics, University of Miami - [email protected]. I would like to thank Aviv Nevo,Igal Hendel, and Robert Porter for their support and guidance. I would also like to thank German Bet,Ignacio Franceschelli, Melissa Gray, Frank Limbrock, Lee Lockwood, Fernando Luco, Guillermo Marshall,Cecilia Peluffo, Tiago Pires, and Ana Reynoso for their valuable comments, and the seminar participantsat Northwestern University. This research was funded in part by a cooperative agreement between theUSDA/ERS and Northwestern University, but the views expressed herein are those of the author and donot necessarily reflect the views of the U.S. Department of Agriculture.

Page 2: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

1 Introduction

Tobacco smoking is the leading cause of preventable death in the United States. Given that

tobacco kills nearly half a million Americans each year (Surgeon General’s 2014 Report)

and is responsible for substantial health-related economic losses, regulations at all levels of

government have been made to address this public health issue. At the Federal level, the

2009 Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Control Act gave the Food and Drug Ad-

ministration (FDA) the power to regulate maximum levels of nicotine, the main psychoac-

tive substance in tobacco and the key causative agent of cigarette addiction. Moreover,

in 2011 tobacco products labeled or advertised with reduced harm claims, such as “light”

or “mild,” were banned by the FDA in an attempt to deter consumers from associating

such products with any health benefits. Light cigarettes have lower machine-measured

nicotine levels than regular strength cigarettes, but the actual levels provided by a light

cigarette vary from smoker to smoker and may even be equivalent to regular cigarettes in

some cases. It is, therefore, an empirical question to determine if light cigarettes are less

addictive than regular strength cigarettes, and if light cigarette smokers behave differently.

This paper contributes to the policy debate by analyzing the link between cigarette

strength and smoking behavior. I use detailed, high-frequency household level purchase

data for the 2006-2010 period to estimate demand models that take into account the ad-

dictive nature of smoking. My baseline set-up consists of a cigarette demand model that

captures one of the main features of addiction, reinforcement : greater past consumption

of an addictive good raises current consumption. I also incorporate a second feature of

addiction: the existence of withdrawal costs. When smokers’ nicotine levels in a given

period are zero (or substantially lower than the habitual levels), they can experience a

physical discomfort that affects their purchase decisions. I analyze this cost by estimating

a specification of the model that captures the effect of temporary smoking cessation on the

purchases of the following period. Additionally, I incorporate the establishment of public

smoking restrictions as a determinant of the purchased quantities.

I estimate the model for both regular and light cigarettes and find the following

results. First, demand for light cigarettes is more price sensitive than for regulars. On

average, a price increase of one dollar reduces regular cigarettes consumption by about

0.3 packs per month, while it reduces light cigarette consumption by more than a pack

per month. Second, light cigarettes are less addictive than regulars, as evidenced by the

2

Page 3: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

estimations of the two features of addiction in terms of packs smoked. The reinforcement

effect for regulars is 30% (i.e., a pack smoked in the past month accounts for 0.3 packs

smoked in the current one), while it is only 21% for lights. Moreover, for regular smokers,

the withdrawal cost is responsible for the purchase of 0.8 packs on the month following

the temporary cessation, while that figure is 0.5 for light smokers. Third, public smoking

restrictions are ineffective in reducing regular cigarette smoking, though notably smoking

restrictions reduce average light cigarette purchases by about half a pack per month.

Additionally, I examine the determinants of smoking cessation. I estimate a

discrete-time hazard model of the probability of cessation that includes both time-invariant

household characteristics and time-varying determinants, controlling for duration depen-

dence. I find that higher prices are associated with a higher probability of quitting, and

that smoking restrictions do not affect the likelihood of quitting. There are no signif-

icant differences between regular and light smokers; both groups present similar rates

of quitting successfully and relapsing, though there is some evidence that switching to

lights contributes to quitting for some smokers. Overall, this paper’s findings support the

idea that an establishment of maximum nicotine levels could be helpful to curtail smoking.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents some history

on the regulation of cigarette nicotine strength, and a description of smoking behaviors

among consumers of light cigarettes. In Section 3, there is a brief description of the data

and a descriptive analysis of the main variables, including an analysis of switching behav-

ior and of smoking cessation. Section 4 presents the methodology and the main results,

while Section 5 concludes.

3

Page 4: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior

In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-

trol Act into law. The main provision of this Act was to give the Food and Drug Ad-

ministration (FDA) the power to regulate the manufacture, distribution, and marketing

of tobacco products in order to protect public health. In particular, the FDA can require

standards for tobacco products, such as maximum tar and nicotine levels, though it cannot

reduce the nicotine levels to zero. Given that nicotine is the main psychoactive substance

in tobacco and the primary causative agent in terms of addiction, it is important to un-

derstand the role of cigarette strength in smoking behavior and addiction.

Prior to 2011, cigarettes were labeled “full” or “light” depending on their nicotine

strength. Light cigarettes, though now not explicitly labelled as such, are fitted with a

porous filter to diffuse the smoke with clean air. When tested by machine, these cigarettes

register lower levels of nicotine, tar, and carbon monoxide than regular cigarettes. How-

ever, health advocates argue that the machine measurements do not represent human

smoking behavior. Various studies have found that many smokers compensate for the low

strength of light cigarettes by changing their pattern of inhalation. This behavior is often

unconscious rather than deliberate, and includes actions such as increasing the drag time,

blocking the filter holes, inhaling deeper, and consuming more cigarettes (Sutton et al.,

1982; Benowitz et al., 1983). The actual nicotine levels provided by a light cigarette thus

vary from smoker to smoker and may even be equivalent to a regular strength cigarette in

some cases. It is, therefore, an empirical question to determine if light cigarettes are less

addictive than regular strength cigarettes.

Smokers choose light cigarettes for a variety of reasons. Some simply prefer the

flavor, which is less harsh than regular strength cigarettes. Others may switch from regu-

lars to lights in an attempt at the “switch down” method of cessation, in which smokers

switch to a lighter brand every three weeks to gradually decrease their nicotine consump-

tion. Interestingly, one study found that switching to lights was associated with a 58%

increase in cessation attempts, but a 60% lower chance of successfully quitting (Tindle et

al., 2010).

Other smokers may use light cigarettes as an alternative to cessation. Light

cigarettes were initially marketed as being healthier than regular strength cigarettes and

4

Page 5: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

there is evidence that many smokers perceive them to be less harmful. However, numerous

studies have shown that regular and light cigarettes deliver similar amounts of tar and

nicotine and there are no health advantages to smoking lights instead of regulars (2004

Surgeon General’s Report). For this reason, in 2011 the FDA banned tobacco products

labeled or advertised with reduced harm claims, including “low,” “light,” “mild,” and

similar, misleading descriptors. In response, the tobacco industry replaced the labels with

colors; Marlboro Lights are now Marlboro Gold Pack, for example.

This research is especially relevant to the increased market for electronic cigarettes,

which are not currently regulated by the FDA. The nicotine levels in the cartridges of these

cigarettes can be controlled even more precisely than traditional cigarettes and many

brands already offer the option of no nicotine.

3 Data and descriptive analysis

The main data source for this paper is the Nielsen Homescan Data Set. This database

contains a national panel of households that register their purchases of several product

categories, including cigarettes, on a daily basis from 2006 to 2010. Households in this

panel use a barcode scanner provided by Nielsen to input information about their pur-

chases. Each record in the data shows the date and store where the transaction took

place, how much was purchased of each product (universal product code level), and the

price that was paid. There is also detailed information about product characteristics and

household demographics, both of which are updated annually.

If the transaction takes place at a store for which Nielsen already has store-

level price data, Nielsen obtains the price directly from store data. If the store is not

part of the Nielsen database, the household is asked to enter the price. Households have

incentives provided by Nielsen to join the panel and remain active in reporting their trans-

actions (such as monthly prize drawings and gift points).1 Einav et al. (2010) provide

a quality check for these data by comparing them with data from cash registers. The

authors conclude that the magnitude of the reporting error is similar to other commonly

used databases.

1In order to preserve the quality of the data, Nielsen filters households that do not report their trans-actions regularly, and periodically adds new households to replace the ones who leave (trying to keep thesample representative of national demographics).

5

Page 6: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

It is important to emphasize that every cigarette transaction can be recorded, be

it from a big chain store (like Walmart), a small tobacco shop, or a gas station. Even mail

order, online shopping, and vending machines transactions are recorded.2 These data are

quite unique and to the best of my knowledge there is only one paper (Harding et al.,

2012) that makes use of two years of these cigarette data (2006 and 2007) to analyze how

cigarette taxes are passed through to consumer prices.

There are 26,630 households that purchase cigarettes during the 2006-2010 pe-

riod. Analyzing the total sample and the cigarette smokers subsample by year, I find that

about 20% of the households make cigarette purchases, a number consistent with national

figures. Data are observed at the household level; my baseline assumption is that there is

only one smoker per household.

There are four main categories of cigarettes according to their strength: reg-

ular, medium, light, and ultra-light. The two categories that comprise most of the market

are regular and light. For the purposes of this paper, I group the medium, light, and ultra-

light categories under the label “light”. Table A1 in the Appendix shows the nicotine, tar,

and carbon monoxide levels of the top 40 brands in terms of sales.

Most of the households in the sample (about 65%) purchase only regular cigarettes

or light cigarettes. The rest of the households purchase both, but generally with a clear

preference for one of the two. For the purposes of this paper, a household is identified as

a lights smoker if most of its cigarette expenditure is on light cigarettes, while the rest of

the households are considered regular cigarette smokers.

Table 1 presents descriptive statistics.3 Column (1) of Table 1 shows information

for the cigarette smokers sample. Columns (2) and (3) of Table 1 show the results splitting

the sample between regular smokers and light smokers.

2Impersonal sales have been almost entirely prohibited since June 2010 (FDA Consumer Fact Sheet).3Detailed descriptions of the variables can be found in the Appendix. I aggregate data by month of

purchase and weight prices according to the purchased volume. Therefore, a data point is a household-month observation. Also, all the products are standardized at the level of a pack (20 cigarettes), with acigarette length of 85mm (known as King size).

6

Page 7: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Table 1: Descriptive statistics

Entire Sample Regular Smokers Light Smokers

Number of Households 26,630 11,257 15,373

Income $51,894 $48,609 $54,300

Household Size 2.5 2.6 2.5

Income per HH Member $24,387 $22,511 $25,761

Age 49.9 50.0 49.9

Minority 18% 23% 15%

Some College 74% 72% 75%

Unemployed or Retired 24% 27% 22%

Packs per Month 8.3 7.6 8.7

Price per Pack $3.8 $3.8 $3.8

Source: Nielsen Homescan data.

The table displays some differences in characteristics; households that smoke light

cigarettes are wealthier and have a higher employment rate. Light smokers also smoke on

average one more pack per month than regular smokers. Table A2 in the Appendix shows

the expenditure shares across demographics of each type of cigarette according to their

strength.

I closely examined the purchasing behavior of about 100 households that switch

from smoking regular cigarettes to smoking lights. There are two patterns that emerge

with higher frequency. One of them is supportive of the “switch down” method of ces-

sation: these households switch to lights and gradually reduce the purchased amounts,

sometimes stopping afterwards. The other one is supportive of the “compensatory smok-

ing” phenomena: these households switch from regulars to lights and start buying more

cigarettes, potentially to compensate for the nicotine loss. Figures A1 and A3 in the Ap-

pendix show those patterns for selected households.

There is strong persistence in purchased brands; more than half of the house-

holds purchase only one brand, and for about 80% of the households the top brand has a

share higher than 70% of the total cigarette purchases. Additionally, cigarette purchases

are very heterogeneous across households. The median monthly purchase in the sample is

about two packs per month, while the 75th percentile is more than 10 packs.

7

Page 8: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Monthly household purchases present a fairly constant pattern. Figure A5 in the

Appendix shows the coefficient of variation (standard deviation - mean ratio) of monthly

purchases for each of the 26,630 households that make purchases in the 2006-2010 period,

with households in ascending order according to total purchases. Most of the sample has

a coefficient of variation lower than 1, with this phenomenon being starker for households

that purchase greater amounts.

For the purposes of this paper, I consider that purchases and consumption are

equal at the month level. This is unlikely to cause interpretation problems for two reasons.

First, cigarettes do not store well and are known to dry out and have a bad flavor after

some weeks. Second, there is evidence that many smokers try to only purchase the amount

they will consume in a relatively short time period as a way of exerting self-control. Hav-

ing an excess stock of cigarettes could tempt the smoker into smoking more, thus many

smokers opt for frequent, small purchases to regulate their consumption (Kim et al., 2006).

In my data, a household makes on average 2.7 cigarette transactions per month, while the

median is about 2 transactions; these figures support the aggregation by month of pur-

chase.

Data on the various increases in state cigarette excise taxes from 2006-2010

come from the Federation of American Tax Administrators. Information about state-

level restrictions comes from the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. During the

2006-2010 period, several U.S. states (and the District of Columbia, which I treat as a

state for the purposes of this paper) established smoking restrictions in public places such

as bars, restaurants, and workplaces. Table 2 shows the timing of such restrictions.

8

Page 9: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Table 2: List of state smoking restrictions, 2006-2010

Month Year State Month Year State

April 2006 New Jersey October 2007 Minnesota

July 2006 Arkansas January 2008 Illinois

July 2006 Colorado February 2008 Maryland

November 2006 Hawaii July 2008 Iowa

November 2006 Nevada September 2008 Pennsylvania

December 2006 Ohio January 2009 Oregon

January 2007 District of Columbia June 2009 Nebraska

January 2007 Louisiana November 2009 South Dakota

January 2007 Utah December 2009 Virginia

May 2007 Arizona January 2010 North Carolina

June 2007 New Mexico May 2010 Michigan

July 2007 Tennessee July 2010 Kansas

September 2007 New Hampshire July 2010 Wisconsin

Source: Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. There are fourteen states with smoking

restrictions established before 2006: California, Delaware, Connecticut, Florida, Idaho, New York,

Maine, Massachusetts, Georgia, Montana, North Dakota, Rhode Island, Vermont, and Washington.

The state of Indiana established a restriction on 2012. The remaining ten states have no statewide

smoking restriction as of May 2015: Alabama, Alaska, Kentucky, Mississippi, Missouri, Oklahoma,

South Carolina, Texas, West Virginia, and Wyoming.

3.1 Smoking cessation

More than half of the adult smoking population tried to quit smoking in 2010 (Behavioral

Risk Factor Surveillance System Survey Data, 2011). Although the health benefits are

greater for people who stop at earlier ages, cessation has major health benefits at all ages

(Centers for Disease Control and Prevention Fact Sheet, 2012). Quitting is difficult and

relapse rates are high; several attempts are usually required to stop smoking.

3.1.1 Quitting

I consider that households have ceased to smoke in month t if they made their last cigarette

purchase in month t− 1 and have been otherwise active on the Nielsen panel for at least

three more months. A rationale for the choice of three months as the minimum threshold

is that it has been shown that it takes between 1.5 and 3 months after quitting before

9

Page 10: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

the number of nicotinic receptors in the brain of a smoker normalizes to non-smoker levels

(Cosgrove et al., 2009). Obviously, I have no way of confirming if this is in fact a per-

manent quitting situation, but this offers a reasonable approximation. According to this

definition of quitting, 51% of the households in the sample make a potentially successful

quitting attempt. This figure is virtually the same when comparing regular and light

smokers (51% and 50%, respectively).

3.1.2 Temporary quitting

Table A3 in the Appendix shows the number of quitting attempts of more than two months

per household, splitting the sample between regular smokers and light smokers. We can

see that there are no significant differences between the number of attempts made by those

two types of smokers.

3.1.3 Relapsing

I consider that a household has relapsed if:

• they were active in the panel for at least three consecutive months in which they did

not purchase cigarettes; and

• they purchased cigarettes sometime after that.

According to this definition, 63% of the households relapse at least once. This figure is

consistent with survey data. Splitting the sample by regular and light smokers, I find that

64% of regular smokers relapse, while 62% of light smokers do so.

4 Methodology and results

4.1 Baseline reinforcement model

I am interested in estimating the role of state dependence in the demand for cigarettes. I

do so by estimating the following equation:

qit = γ · pit + β · qi,t−1 + αi + µt + εit (1)

where qit are the packs purchased by household i in month t; pit is the average price per

pack that was paid for that amount; αi is household i’s fixed effect; µt is a month effect

10

Page 11: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

common to all households; and εit is the error term, assumed to be independent across

households and serially uncorrelated.4

This equation is consistent with a boundedly-rational model of addiction in which

individuals recognize the impact of past decisions but can only choose their current con-

sumption based on current prices. I test the validity of this assumption in Petruzzello

(2015).5 State dependence is captured by adding a lag of the dependent variable as a re-

gressor. I analyze if, after controlling for time-invariant systematic differences (the αi’s),

the previous consumption helps to explain the current one. More specifically, β is a mea-

sure of the extent of reinforcement, one of the main features of addiction: the fact that

greater past consumption of an addictive good raises current demand. Thus, if a good is

addictive, we would expect β to be positive; the degree of reinforcement is greater when

the coefficient β is larger.

Results for the estimation of Equation (1) are shown in Table 3. Columns (1),

(3), and (5) of Table 3 show the results of OLS fixed-effects estimation. There is a po-

tential endogeneity bias that could arise from regressing the purchased packs of cigarettes

on the price paid. Therefore, I also explore specifications in which I employ state excise

taxes as instruments for the potentially endogenous prices; columns (2), (4), and (6) of

Table 3 show the results of 2SLS estimation.6 State excise taxes vary widely across states;

for example, the excise tax in Missouri is $0.17, while that figure is $4.35 in New York

(the median tax rate is $1.57).7,8 State taxes also vary through time; most of the states

raise their cigarette excise taxes one or more times in the 2006-2010 period, and this is the

key source of exogenous price variation. Gruber and Koszegi (2001) report that state tax

increases are responsible for about 80% of the within state-year variation in prices. Table

A5 in the Appendix shows all the excise tax increases, new rates, and date of application

for any increase between January 2006 and December 2010. Table A6 in the Appendix

shows first stage estimation results.

4I address the validity of this assumption in Petruzzello (2014).5An alternative approach would be to include a lead of the dependent variable; this would be consistent

with the standard rational addiction model specification, which relies on forward-looking behavior.6Cigarette excise taxes have been employed as an instrument for cigarette prices in similar contexts

(Becker et al., 1994; Gruber et al., 2003; Adda and Cornaglia, 2013).7Very few counties and cities in the U.S. establish their own excise taxes.8The federal tax rate had been $0.39 since 2002 until April 2009, when it was raised to $1.01 to provide

funding for the 2009 expansion of the Children’s Health Insurance Program.

11

Page 12: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Table 3: Estimation of the baseline model

Dep. variable: packs purchased per month

All Regular Light

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

OLS 2SLS OLS 2SLS OLS 2SLS

Price -0.1997∗∗∗ -1.2904∗∗∗ -0.1086∗∗∗ -0.8673∗∗∗ -0.7027∗∗∗ -1.1615∗∗∗

(0.0406) (0.2178) (0.0212) (0.2808) (0.0680) (0.2613)

Packs 0.2607∗∗∗ 0.2572∗∗∗ 0.2999∗∗∗ 0.2978∗∗∗ 0.2128∗∗∗ 0.2111∗∗∗

t-1 (0.0111) (0.0112) (0.0249) (0.0248) (0.0058) (0.0058)

F-stat 1639.00 631.14 1355.85

R2 0.6787 0.0549 0.6627 0.0681 0.6880 0.0745

N 300032 300032 139092 134089 194165 189127

Robust standard errors are in parenthesis. All the regressions include month dummies

and household fixed effects. Columns (1), (3), and (5) show the results of OLS estima-

tion, while Columns (2), (4), and (6) present 2SLS estimation results. The R squared

reported for 2SLS estimations is the within R squared. F-stat is the statistic for the first-

stage F test of excluded instruments. *Statistically different from 0 at 10% significance;

**Statistically different from 0 at 5% significance; ***Statistically different from 0 at 1%

significance.

These results show that the demand for light cigarettes is more price sensitive

than for regular cigarettes; this suggests that public intervention in the form of higher

cigarette taxes could be more successful to curb lights smoking. Additionally, light

cigarettes display a lower state dependence than regulars: the reinforcement effect for

regulars is 30% (a pack smoked in the past month accounts for 0.3 packs smoked in the

current one), while that figure is only 21% for lights.

4.1.1 Incorporating withdrawal costs

The specification I have explored incorporates one of the key components of addiction:

reinforcement. I also explore a specification that incorporates withdrawal costs. These

manifest as a physical discomfort that affects the current decision when the levels of nico-

tine in the body are substantially lower than the habitual levels.9 This effect is related to

9These effects have been widely documented; Harris (1993) provides a summary.

12

Page 13: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

past cigarette consumption but is only triggered for individuals that try to reduce their

consumption. Withdrawal costs have an asymmetric nature; they are not triggered by

increases in consumption, only by reductions. As pointed out by Suranovic et al. (1999),

the development of adjustment costs associated with cessation is sufficient to explain why

smoking is habit-forming and is a critical element in making cigarettes addictive.10

I estimate a variation of the baseline model in which I include a withdrawal

cost binary variable, Wit. That variable is equal to 1 in period t for household i if that

household purchased cigarettes on period t − 2 but did not purchase cigarettes in t − 1

(while still purchasing some other product in t−1).11 If withdrawal costs were not a factor,

we would expect that temporary cessation in the past month has no significant effect on

current consumption, holding the rest of the variables fixed. Table A7 in the Appendix

presents the results of the estimation, which show that the withdrawal cost coefficients are

statistically and economically significantly different from zero. Table A8 in the Appendix

shows first stage estimation results.

For regular smokers, the withdrawal cost is responsible for an average of 0.8

packs on the month following the temporary cessation. This figure is 0.5 packs for light

smokers. Therefore, there is evidence of a lower impact of the withdrawal cost for light

smokers. For this specification, there is no significant difference between the reinforcement

effects for regular and light smokers.

4.2 Differential impact of smoking restrictions

I now examine the effectiveness of public smoking restrictions in curbing smoking and

analyze whether the impact is different for lights and regulars. The main purpose be-

hind the enactment of these types of restrictions is to reduce the exposure of non-smokers

to secondhand smoke. Nonetheless, according to the World Health Organization, smok-

ing restrictions may reduce the demand for cigarettes by creating an environment where

smoking becomes increasingly more difficult and also by shifting social norms. By directly

prohibiting smoking in certain areas, these restrictions may deter social smokers by elimi-

nating common smoking settings. Additionally, these restrictions affect habitual smokers

10“An addiction is the compulsive need for and use of a habit-forming substance characterized bytolerance and by well-defined physiological symptoms upon withdrawal” (Merriam-Webster dictionary).

11For this specification it is crucial to consider the months with no cigarette purchases. To define aprice for the months with no purchases, I assign the last price paid and update this value with any increasein state or federal taxes if applicable.

13

Page 14: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

by increasing the hassle cost associated with smoking, as they must move out of restricted

areas in order to smoke.

However, it could be the case that some smokers maintain their cigarette con-

sumption even in the presence of restrictions. Adda and Cornaglia (2010) find some evi-

dence that restrictions simply displace smoking to areas that are not restricted. Owyang

and Vermann (2012) do not find correlation between smoking restrictions and smoking

behavior examining survey data, while Irvine and Nguyen (2011) find that smoking re-

strictions have an effect on individuals at the top of the income distribution (they employ

the 2003 Canadian Community Health Survey).

I benefit from the fact that there are states with no smoking restrictions during

the 2006-2010 period and that the states that established restrictions did so at different

moments of time. This variability is exploited to identify the causal effect of smoking

restrictions on cigarette purchases, controlling for time-invariant household characteristics

and temporary shocks that are common across households. Specifically, households in

states that lack restrictions serve as controls for those in states that have smoking restric-

tions. I define the smoking restriction binary variable Bit, which is equal to 1 in period t

for household i if the state where the household resides established a smoking restriction

on t or before. Table 4 shows the results of incorporating this smoking restriction time-

varying dummy on the specification of Equation (1) (Table A9 in the Appendix presents

first stage results).

14

Page 15: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Table 4: Impact of state smoking restrictions

Dep. variable: packs purchased per month

All Regular Light

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

OLS 2SLS OLS 2SLS OLS 2SLS

Smoking -0.4200∗∗ -0.4572∗∗∗ -0.0529 -0.1660 -0.4958∗∗ -0.3939∗∗

restriction (0.1690) (0.1737) (0.2323) (0.2516) (0.2013) (0.2000)

Price -0.1467∗∗∗ -1.6517∗∗∗ -0.0876∗∗∗ -0.6908 -0.6740∗∗∗ -2.0289∗∗∗

(0.0301) (0.3445) (0.0159) (0.4397) (0.0672) (0.4092)

Packs 0.2874∗∗∗ 0.2835∗∗∗ 0.3432∗∗∗ 0.3415∗∗∗ 0.2249∗∗∗ 0.2213∗∗∗

t-1 (0.0140) (0.0142) (0.0303) (0.0303) (0.0069) (0.0069)

F-stat 712.14 177.64 1255.90

R2 0.6746 0.0169 0.6568 0.1063 0.6868 0.0653

N 217715 217715 99547 96016 142737 139159

Robust standard errors are in parenthesis. All the regressions include month dummies

and household fixed effects. Columns (1), (3), and (5) show the results of OLS estima-

tion, while Columns (2), (4), and (6) present 2SLS estimation results. The R squared

reported for 2SLS estimations is the within R squared. F-stat is the statistic for the first-

stage F test of excluded instruments. *Statistically different from 0 at 10% significance;

**Statistically different from 0 at 5% significance; ***Statistically different from 0 at 1%

significance.

These results show that public smoking restrictions are inadequate to reduce

regular cigarette smoking. Notably, this is not the case for light cigarettes, as smoking

restrictions reduce average light cigarette purchases by about half a pack per month.

4.2.1 Examination of household heterogeneity

In order to examine the role of heterogeneity in addiction, I split the sample by median

age and median income per household member (also splitting the regular and light smok-

ers subsamples). I then estimate the baseline model with the state smoking restrictions

dummy for each of those cells. Table A10 in the Appendix shows the estimations of

15

Page 16: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

the reinforcement coefficient for each cell. We can see that the reinforcement coefficient

for regular smokers is much smaller for younger and for wealthier households, while the

coefficients for light smokers do not present significant differences across cells.

I also investigate heterogeneity in the effects of smoking restrictions. Table A11

in the Appendix shows the coefficients on the state restriction dummy variable for each

cell.12 We can see that the restrictions are effective for younger and wealthier households

that smoke light cigarettes, but not for the rest of the cells.

4.3 Differential cessation and its determinants

In order to analyze the determinants of quitting, I estimate a discrete-time hazard logit

model of the probability of cessation. This model presents both time-invariant household

characteristics (minority status, age, and education level in 2006) and time-varying deter-

minants (the establishment of state smoking restrictions, price, new births, and income),

and it includes a sixth-degree time polynomial to control for duration dependence.13 I

employ the definition of quitting previously stated in Section 3.

Formally,

P (dit = 1) =exp(z)

1 + exp(z)(2)

where dit is the binary survival variable that takes a value of one if household i stops

purchasing in month t and zero otherwise, and

z ≡ a0 + g · Vi,t + h · Fi + P (t) + ιit (3)

where the V ’s are time-varying variables, the F ’s are fixed household demographics, P (t)

is a sixth-order polynomial in time included to control for duration dependence, and ιit is

the error term. The results are reported in Table 5.

12The coefficients from Tables A10 and A11 correspond to 2SLS estimation.13For this model I need to define the price for the quitting month and for previous months when there

were no purchases of cigarettes but the household was active in some other category. For those months Iassign the last price paid and I update this value with any increase in state or federal taxes if applicable.

16

Page 17: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Table 5: Estimation of the cessation hazard model

Dep. variable: survival dummy (cessation)

(1) (2) (3)

All Regular Light

Time-varying :

Smoking restriction 0.0103 -0.0288 0.0265

(0.0228) (0.0353) (0.0300)

Price 0.0025∗ 0.0029∗∗ 0.0089∗∗

(0.0014) (0.0013) (0.0041)

Births 0.4722∗∗∗ 0.4886∗∗∗ 0.4754∗∗∗

(0.0600) (0.0965) (0.0766)

log of Income 0.1677∗∗∗ 0.2001∗∗∗ 0.1521∗∗∗

(0.0153) (0.0230) (0.0208)

Time-invariant :

Age -0.0036∗∗∗ -0.0021 -0.0044∗∗∗

(0.0010) (0.0015) (0.0013)

College 0.0719∗∗∗ 0.1040∗∗∗ 0.0529

(0.0243) (0.0369) (0.0324)

Minority 0.0290 0.0192 0.0114

(0.0276) (0.0389) (0.0400)

R2 0.0122 0.0147 0.0108

N 375420 144933 222679

Standard errors are in parentheses. All the specifications include a sixth-degree time polynomial to

control for duration dependence. *Statistically different from 0 at 10% significance; **Statistically

different from 0 at 5% significance; ***Statistically different from 0 at 1% significance.

The likelihood of quitting is higher when the income is higher and when follow-

ing the birth of a child, as expected. We can also see that younger smokers are more

likely to quit. Education only has a positive impact on the probability of quitting for

regular smokers. In terms of smoking policy variables, higher prices are associated with a

higher probability of quitting for both types. Additionally, the establishment of smoking

restrictions does not have a significant impact on the probability of quitting for either

type.

17

Page 18: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

5 Conclusion

I analyze the link between cigarette strength and smoking behavior by employing house-

hold level purchase data, examining cessation and switching patterns, and estimating state

dependence demand models that take into account the addictive nature of smoking.

The results show that light cigarettes are less addictive than regular cigarettes

and that demand for lights is more price sensitive than for regulars. Moreover, public

smoking restrictions reduce light cigarette purchases by about half a pack per month,

though they are ineffective in reducing regular cigarette smoking. Additionally, higher

prices are associated with a higher probability of quitting successfully, but public smoking

restrictions do not affect the likelihood of cessation for either type of smoker. Lastly, there

is some evidence that switching to lights contributes to quitting for some smokers.

Overall, this paper’s findings support the idea that an establishment of maxi-

mum nicotine levels could be helpful to curtail smoking, with two caveats. First, it could

be the case that the difference in relevant demographics between light and regular cigarette

smokers plays a role in the difference between their behaviors. Second, some of the house-

holds that switch to lights present evidence of compensatory behavior; in those cases, the

establishment of maximum nicotine levels would not generate the desired effect.

18

Page 19: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

References

[1] ADDA, J. and CORNAGLIA, F. (2010): The Effect of Bans and Taxes on Passive Smoking,

American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2: 1-32.

[2] ADDA, J. and CORNAGLIA, F. (2013): Taxes, Cigarette Consumption, and Smoking Inten-

sity: Reply, American Economic Review, 103, 3102-3114.

[3] AHIJEVYCH, K. and GARRETT, B.E. (2004): Menthol Pharmacology and Its Potential

Impact of Cigarette Behavior, Nicotine and Tobacco Research, 6, S17-28.

[4] ALVAREZ, J. and ARELLANO, M. (2003): The Time Series and Cross-Section Asymptotics

of Dynamic Panel Data Estimators, Econometrica, 71, 1121-1159.

[5] ARELLANO, M. and BOND, S. (1991): Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte

Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations, Review of Economic Studies,

58, 277-297.

[6] BECKER, G., GROSSMAN, M., and MURPHY, K. (1994): An Empirical Analysis of

Cigarette Addiction, American Economic Review, 84, 396-418.

[7] BECKER, G. and MURPHY, K. (1988): A Theory of Rational Addiction, Journal of Political

Economy, 96, 675-700.

[8] Behavioral Risk Factor Surveillance System Survey Data, (2011).

[9] BOND, S. Dynamic Panel Data Models: A Guide to Micro Data Methods and Practice The In-

stitute for Fiscal Studies, Department of Economics, UCL cemmap working paper CWP09/02

[10] Centers for Disease Control and Prevention Fact Sheet, (2012).

[11] CHALOUPKA, F.J. (1991): Rational Addictive Behavior and Cigarette Smoking, Journal of

Political Economy, 99, 722-42.

[12] COSGROVE, K.P., BATIS, J., BOIS, F., MACIEJEWSKI, P.K., ESTERLIS, I., KLOCZYN-

SKI, T., STIKLUS, S., KRISHNAN-SARIN, S., O’MALLEY, S., PERRY, E., TAMAGNAN,

G., SEIBYL, J.P., and STALEY, J.K. (2009): Beta2*-Nicotinic Acetylcholine Receptor Avail-

ability during Acute and Prolonged Abstinence from Tobacco Smoking Archives of General

Psychiatry, 66, 666-676.

[13] DELNEVO, C.D., GUNDERSEN, D.A., and HRWYNA, M. (2010): Examining the Relation-

ship Between Menthol Smoking and Cessation Using Data from the 2003 and 2006/7 Tobacco

Use Supplement, submission to the U.S. Food and Drug Administration.

[14] EINAV, L., LEIBTAG, E., and NEVO, A., (2010): Recording Discrepancies in Nielsen Home-

scan Data: Are They Present and Do They Matter? Quantitative Marketing and Economics,

8, 207-239.

19

Page 20: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

[15] FAGAN, P., MOOLCHAN, E.T., HART, A., ROSE, A., LAWRENCE, D., SHAVERS, V.L.,

and GIBSON, J.T. (2010): Nicotine Dependence and Quitting Behaviors among Menthol and

Non-Menthol Smokers with Similar Consumption Patterns Addiction, 105, 55-74.

[16] GRUBER, J. and KOSZEGI, B. (2001): Is Addiction “Rational”? Theory and Evidence,

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 1261-303.

[17] GRUBER, J., SEN, A., and STABILE, M., (2003): Estimating Price Elasticities When There

Is Smuggling: The Sensitivity of Smoking to Price in Canada Journal of Health Conomics, 22,

821-842.

[18] GUL, F. and PESENDORFER, W. (2007): Harmful Addiction, Review of Economic Studies,

74, 147-172.

[19] HARDING, M., LEIBTAG, E., and LOVENHEIM, M.F. (2012): The Heterogeneous Geo-

graphic and Socioeconomic Incidence of Cigarette Taxes: Evidence from Nielsen Homescan

Data, American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 4, 169?198.

[20] HARRIS, J., (1993): Deadly Choices: Coping with Health Risks in Everyday Life. Basic

Books, New York.

[21] HARTMAN, A.M. (2011): What Menthol Smokers Report They Would Do If Menthol

Cigarettes Were No Longer Sold, Presentation to the FDA Tobacco Products Scientific Advi-

sory Committee Meeting.

[22] IRVINE, I.J. and NGUYEN, H.V. (2011): Toxic Choices: The Theory and Impact of Smoking

Bans, Forum for Health Economics and Policy, 14.

[23] KEELER, T.E., HU, T-W., BARNETT, P.G., and MANNING, W.G. (1993): Taxation,

Regulation, and Addiction: A Demand Function for Cigarettes Based on Time-Series Evidence,

Journal of Health Economics, 12, 1-18.

[24] KIM, A.E., RIBISL, K.M., DELNEVO, C.D., and HRYWNA, M. (2006): Smokers’ Beliefs

and Attitudes about Purchasing Cigarettes on the Internet Public Health Rep., 121, 594-602.

[25] LAWRENCE, D., ROSE, A., FAGAN, P., MOOLCHAN, E.T., GIBSON, J.T., and

BACKINGER, C.L. (2010): National Patterns and Correlates of Mentholated Cigarette Use

in the United States Addiction, 105, 13-31.

[26] LEVY, D.T., BLACKMAN, K., TAURAS, J., CHALOUPKA, F.J., VILLANTI, A., and

NIAURA, R.S. (2011): Quit Attempts and Quit Rates among Menthol and Non-Menthol

Smokers in the United States, American Journal of Public Health, 101, 1241-1247.

[27] OWYANG, M.T. and VERMANN, E.K. (2012): Where There‘s a Smoking Ban, There‘s Still

Fire, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 94, 265-86.

[28] PETRUZZELLO, E. (2014): Measuring the Effect of Policy on the Demand for Menthol

Cigarettes: Evidence from Household Level Purchase Data, working paper.

20

Page 21: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

[29] PETRUZZELLO, E. (2015): Testing for Forward-Looking Behavior: Evidence from the En-

actment of Smoking Restrictions, working paper.

[30] Surgeon General’s Report (2014).

[31] SURANOVIC, S.M., GOLDFARB, R.S., and LEONARD, T.C. (1999): An Economic Theory

of Cigarette Addiction Journal of Health Economics, 18, 1-29.

[32] The Industry Menthol Report (2001): Menthol Cigarettes: No Disproportionate Impact on

Public Health.

[33] TAURAS, J.A., LEVY, D.T, CHALOUPKA, F.J., VILLANTI, A., NIAURA, R.S., VAL-

LONE, D., and ABRAMS, D.B. (2010): Menthol and Non-menthol Smoking: the Impact of

Prices and Smoke-Free Air Laws, Addiction, 105, 115-123.

[34] Tobacco Products Scientific Advisory Committee (2011): Menthol Cigarettes and Public

Health: Review of the Scientific Evidence and Recommendations.

21

Page 22: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

A Description of the variables

• College dummy : 1 if maximum education level attained in the household is any

college attendance. This includes “Some College,” “Graduated College,” and “Post

College Grad.”

• Age: Age on December 2005 (if more than one adult, average age).

• Minority dummy : 0 if the respondent answered “White” and “No” to the “Race”

and “Hispanic” entries, respectively.

• Income: Mid-point of the corresponding annual income interval (annual income is

categorized in 17 brackets between $5,000 and $200,000).

• Unemployed or Retired : 1 if no household head is employed.

• Births: Birthsit is equal to 1 if there was a birth in household i on month t or before,

but after January 2006; and is equal to 2 if there was a second birth in household i

on month t or before, but after January 2006. It takes the value zero otherwise.

22

Page 23: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

B Characteristics of top brands

Table A1: Top 40 selling brands

Brand Firm Menthol Strength Tar Nicotine COMarlboro PM Light 11 0.9 13Marlboro PM Regular 16 1.2 16Newport L Y Regular 14 1.2 15Marlboro PM Ultra light 5 0.5 8Parliament PM Light 11 0.9 12Camel R Light 9 0.8 10Marlboro PM Medium 13 1 12Winston R Light 11 0.9 13Winston R Regular 16 1.3 15Kool R Y Regular 16 1.1 15Basic PM Light 11 0.8 15Salem R Y Light 8 0.7 10Marlboro PM Y Light 9 0.7 11Camel R Regular 17 1.3 15Basic PM Regular 15 1 18Merit PM Ultra light 5 0.5 7Basic PM Ultra light 5 0.4 8Virginia Slims PM Light 9 0.7 10Virginia Slims PM Y Light 9 0.7 10Salem R Y Regular 17 1.3 16Carlton R Ultra light 1 0.1 1Marlboro PM Y Regular 14 1 13Doral R Light 10 0.8 11Newport L Y Light 12 1 12Merit PM Regular 9 0.8 12Virginia Slims PM Ultra light 6 0.5 6Basic PM Y Light 11 0.8 15Virginia Slims PM Y Ultra light 6 0.5 6Pall Mall R Regular 14 1.2 12Salem R Y Ultra light 6 0.5 9Doral R Ultra light 4 0.4 6Capri R Light 9 0.8 6Virginia Slims PM Regular 14 1 12Virginia Slims PM Y Regular 14 1 12Doral R Regular 14 1.1 13Kool R Y Mild 11 0.9 10Winston R Ultra light 4 0.5 6Misty Slims R Y Light 9 0.7 10Capri R Y Light 9 0.8 6Misty Slims R Light 8 0.7 9

Source: Nielsen Homescan data and Federal Trade Commission. Nicotine,tar, and carbon monoxide are measured in milligrams per cigarette. PMstands for Philip Morris, R for Reynolds, and L for Lorillard.

23

Page 24: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

C Expenditure shares

Table A2: Cigarette expenditure shares by demographics

Race/Ethnicity Regular Medium Light Ultra-light

White 39% 3% 44% 15%

African American 57% 5% 31% 7%

Hispanic 44% 3% 41% 12%

Asian 35% 7% 38% 21%

Income

Lowest fourth 46% 2% 39% 12%

Second fourth 42% 2% 42% 14%

Third fourth 38% 3% 44% 15%

Highest fourth 32% 3% 46% 19%

Education

Grade school 51% 1% 38% 10%

High school 45% 2% 41% 12%

Some college 41% 3% 42% 14%

College grad 34% 3% 45% 18%

Source: Nielsen Homescan data.

24

Page 25: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

D Switching patterns

Figure A1: Switch down behavior examples

Source: Nielsen Homescan data. �: regular cigarettes; ♦: light

cigarettes; ×: no purchase of cigarettes but active in panel

25

Page 26: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Source: Nielsen Homescan data. �: regular cigarettes; ♦: light

cigarettes; ×: no purchase of cigarettes but active in panel

26

Page 27: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Figure A3: Compensatory behavior examples

Source: Nielsen Homescan data. �: regular cigarettes; ♦: light

cigarettes; ×: no purchase of cigarettes but active in panel

27

Page 28: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Source: Nielsen Homescan data. �: regular cigarettes; ♦: light

cigarettes; ×: no purchase of cigarettes but active in panel

28

Page 29: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

E Consumption behavior

Figure A5: Coefficient of variation for monthly purchases of each household

Source: Nielsen Homescan data.

29

Page 30: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

F Quitting attempts

Table A3: Number of quitting attempts of more than two months

# of attempts # of households Regular smokers % Light smokers %

0 6,388 23% 24%

1 6,079 22% 23%

2 7,149 27% 27%

3 3,637 14% 13%

4 1,903 7% 7%

5 937 3% 4%

6 or more 537 2% 2%

26,630 100% 100%

Source: Nielsen Homescan data

30

Page 31: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

G Smoking restrictions

Table A4: States with smoking restrictions and year of enactment

Year States

1995 California

2002 Delaware

2003 Connecticut, Florida, and New York

2004 Indiana, Maine, and Massachusetts

2005 Georgia, Montana, North Dakota, Rhode Island, Vermont, and Washington

2006 Arkansas, Colorado, Hawaii, Nevada, New Jersey, and Ohio

2007 Arizona, District of Columbia, Louisiana, Minnesota, New Hampshire,

New Mexico, Tennessee, and Utah

2008 Illinois, Iowa, Maryland, and Pennsylvania

2009 Nebraska, Oregon, South Dakota, and Virginia

2010 Kansas, Michigan, North Carolina, and Wisconsin

2012 Indiana

Note: there are 10 states with no statewide smoking ban as of May 2015: Alabama, Alaska,

Kentucky, Mississippi, Missouri, Oklahoma, South Carolina, Texas, West Virginia, and Wyoming.

31

Page 32: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

H Excise tax increases, 2006-2010

Table A5: Excise tax increases, rates, and date of application

Date State Increase New Rate Date State Increase New Rate

07/01/06 Alaska 0.20 1.80 04/01/09 U.S. (federal rate) 0.62 1.01

07/01/06 New Jersey 0.18 2.58 04/10/09 Rhode Island 1.00 3.46

07/01/06 North Carolina 0.05 0.35 05/15/09 Mississippi 0.50 0.68

09/30/06 Hawaii 0.20 1.60 07/01/09 Delaware 0.45 1.60

12/07/06 Arizona 0.82 2.00 07/01/09 Florida 1.00 1.33

01/01/07 South Dakota 1.00 1.53 07/01/09 Hawaii 0.60 2.60

01/01/07 Texas 1.00 1.41 07/01/09 Kentucky 0.30 0.60

03/15/07 Iowa 1.00 1.36 07/01/09 New Hampshire 0.70 1.78

07/01/07 Alaska 0.20 2.00 07/01/09 New Jersey 0.13 2.70

07/01/07 Connecticut 0.49 2.00 07/01/09 Vermont 0.45 2.24

07/01/07 Indiana 0.44 1.00 07/01/09 Wisconsin 0.75 2.52

07/01/07 New Hampshire 0.28 1.08 09/01/09 North Carolina 0.10 0.45

07/01/07 Tennessee 0.42 0.62 10/01/09 Connecticut 1.00 3.00

08/01/07 Delaware 0.60 1.15 10/01/09 District of Columbia 1.50 2.50

09/30/07 Hawaii 0.20 1.80 11/01/09 Pennsylvania 0.25 1.60

01/01/08 Maryland 1.00 2.00 05/01/10 Washington 1.00 3.03

01/01/08 Wisconsin 1.00 1.77 07/01/10 Hawaii 0.40 3.00

06/03/08 New York 1.25 2.75 07/01/10 New Mexico 0.75 1.66

07/01/08 Massachusetts 1.00 2.51 07/01/10 New York 1.60 4.35

09/30/08 Hawaii 0.20 2.00 07/01/10 South Carolina 0.50 0.57

03/01/09 Arkansas 0.56 1.15 07/01/10 Utah 1.01 1.70

Source: Federation of American Tax Administrators.

32

Page 33: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

I Additional results

Table A6: Baseline model - First stage results

Dep. variable: price paid

All Regular Light

(1) (2) (3)

Tax rate 0.6901∗∗∗ 0.7404∗∗∗ 0.6660∗∗∗

(0.0170) (0.0295) (0.0181)

F-stat 1639.00 631.14 1355.85

χ2-stat 24.34 7.30 2.87

R2 0.0298 0.0160 0.1118

N 293947 134089 189127

Robust standard errors are in parenthesis. All the regressions include month dummies and

the lagged quantity. F-stat is the statistic for the first-stage F test of excluded instruments.

***Statistically different from 0 at 1% significance.

33

Page 34: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Table A7: Estimation of the baseline model with withdrawal costs

Dep. variable: packs purchased per month

All Regular Light

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

OLS 2SLS OLS 2SLS OLS 2SLS

Withdrawal 0.6640∗∗∗ 0.6545∗∗∗ 0.8185∗∗∗ 0.8050∗∗∗ 0.5442∗∗∗ 0.5411∗∗∗

cost effect (0.0820) (0.0843) (0.1514) (0.1563) (0.0824) (0.0826)

Price -0.0682∗∗∗ -0.9854∗∗∗ -0.0389∗∗∗ -0.7880∗∗∗ -0.2972∗∗∗ -1.1154∗∗∗

(0.0068) (0.0842) (0.0046) (0.1322) (0.0151) (0.1080)

Packs 0.3263∗∗∗ 0.3219∗∗∗ 0.3412∗∗∗ 0.3369∗∗∗ 0.3143∗∗∗ 0.3109∗∗∗

t-1 (0.0082) (0.0083) (0.0165) (0.0168) (0.0070) (0.0070)

F-stat 5456.60 1258.19 6325.69

R2 0.6699 0.0829 0.6640 0.0628 0.6743 0.1295

N 713674 713418 293673 293543 420001 419875

Robust standard errors are in parenthesis. All the regressions include month dummies and

household fixed effects. Columns (1), (3), and (5) show the results of OLS estimation, while

Columns (2), (4), and (6) present 2SLS estimation results. The R squared reported for 2SLS

estimations is the within R squared. F-stat is the statistic for the first-stage F test of excluded

instruments. *Statistically different from 0 at 10% significance; **Statistically different from

0 at 5% significance; ***Statistically different from 0 at 1% significance.

34

Page 35: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

Table A8: Withdrawal cost - First stage results

Dep. variable: price paid

All Regular Light

(1) (2) (3)

Tax rate 0.7699∗∗∗ 0.7593∗∗∗ 0.7784∗∗∗

(0.0104) (0.0214) (0.0098)

F-stat 5456.60 1258.19 6325.69

χ2-stat 120.75 33.09 57.89

R2 0.0234 0.0120 0.1060

N 713418 293543 419875

Robust standard errors are in parenthesis. All the regressions include month dummies, the

lagged quantity, and the withdrawal cost dummy. F-stat is the statistic for the first-stage F

test of excluded instruments. ***Statistically different from 0 at 1% significance.

35

Page 36: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

J Impact of smoking restrictions

Table A9: Impact of state restrictions - First stage results

Dep. variable: price paid

All Regular Light

(1) (2) (3)

Tax rate 0.7265∗∗∗ 0.7998∗∗∗ 0.6733∗∗∗

(0.0272) (0.0600) (0.0190)

F-stat 712.14 177.64 1255.90

χ2-stat 19.33 1.90 10.69

R2 0.0215 0.0114 0.1188

N 213470 96016 139159

Robust standard errors are in parenthesis. All the regressions include month dummies, the

lagged quantity, and the state restrictions dummy. F-stat is the statistic for the first-stage F

test of excluded instruments. ***Statistically different from 0 at 1% significance.

36

Page 37: Cigarette Strength and Smoking Behavior · 2 Cigarette strength and smoking behavior In June 2009, President Obama signed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Con-trol Act into

K Household heterogeneity

Table A10: Reinforcement coefficient - split samples

Full Sample Regular smokers Light smokers

Age≤52 0.24∗∗∗ 0.24∗∗∗ 0.25∗∗∗

> 52 0.32∗∗∗ 0.44∗∗∗ 0.21∗∗∗

Income per ≤$21,250 0.32∗∗∗ 0.41∗∗∗ 0.23∗∗∗

HH member >$21,250 0.19∗∗∗ 0.15∗∗∗ 0.21∗∗∗

Note: ***Statistically different from 0 at 1% significance.

Table A11: Impact of smoking restrictions on consumption - split samples

Full Sample Regular smokers Light smokers

Age≤52 -0.55∗∗∗ -0.21 -0.83∗∗∗

> 52 -0.41 0.04 -0.28

Income per ≤$21,250 -0.20 -0.19 -0.16

HH member >$21,250 -0.88∗∗∗ -0.63 -1.03∗∗∗

Note: ***Statistically different from 0 at 1% significance.

37