an analysis of u.s. chicken exports to china li zhang …

129
AN ANALYSIS OF U.S. CHICKEN EXPORTS TO CHINA by LI ZHANG (Under the direction of Dr. Lewell F. Gunter) ABSTRACT The United States is the world’s largest poultry producer and exporter. Hong Kong/China has been the second largest market for U.S. poultry products in recent years. The growth potential for chicken exports to this market is great, given China’s large population, relatively low per capita consumption of chicken, expected rising incomes, and the recent inclusion of China in the WTO. In this study, we examined the exports of different frozen chicken parts from the U.S. to Hong Kong/China. Excess supply and demand equations were estimated using three stage least squares, and elasticities were calculated. The results indicate that there may be some differences in income elasticities and price flexibility coefficients of different parts, and suggests that the U.S. may treat Hong Kong/China as a residual market for lower valued parts. INDEX WORDS: Poultry, Chicken parts, Exports, U.S., Hong Kong, China, Excess supply, Excess demand, International trade.

Upload: others

Post on 31-Jan-2022

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

AN ANALYSIS OF U.S. CHICKEN EXPORTS TO CHINA

by

LI ZHANG

(Under the direction of Dr. Lewell F. Gunter)

ABSTRACT

The United States is the world’s largest poultry producer and exporter. Hong Kong/China has been the second largest market for U.S. poultry products in recent years. The growth potential for chicken exports to this market is great, given China’s large population, relatively low per capita consumption of chicken, expected rising incomes, and the recent inclusion of China in the WTO. In this study, we examined the exports of different frozen chicken parts from the U.S. to Hong Kong/China. Excess supply and demand equations were estimated using three stage least squares, and elasticities were calculated. The results indicate that there may be some differences in income elasticities and price flexibility coefficients of different parts, and suggests that the U.S. may treat Hong Kong/China as a residual market for lower valued parts.

INDEX WORDS: Poultry, Chicken parts, Exports, U.S., Hong Kong, China, Excess

supply, Excess demand, International trade.

AN ANALYSIS OF U.S. CHICKEN EXPORTS TO CHINA

by

LI ZHANG

B.Ec., Yangzhou University, P.R. China, 1996

A Thesis Submitted to the Graduate Faculty of The University of Georgia in Partial

Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree

MASTER OF SCIENCE

ATHENS, GEORGIA

2002

© 2002

Li Zhang

All Right Reserved.

AN ANALYSIS OF U.S. CHICKEN EXPORTS TO CHINA

by

LI ZHANG

Major Professor: Lewell F. Gunter Committee: Jack E. Houston Chung L. Huang

Electronic Version Approved:

Gordhan L. Patel Dean of the Graduate School The University of Georgia December 2002

iv

Dedicated to My Parents and My Husband

For Their Love and Support

v

ACKNKOWLEGDMENTS

My deepest and sincere thanks go to Dr. Lewell F. Gunter, my major professor,

for his invaluable guidance and generous encouragement throughout my study. I would

like to express my appreciation to my committee members, Dr. Jack E. Houston and Dr.

Chung L. Huang, for sharing their knowledge, giving me advice and support. I owe

further thanks to Dr. James E. Epperson, for keeping me on track during my thesis

writing.

I am especially indebted to the University of Georgia, and more so to the

Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics for giving me the chance receiving

the professional education and training, and offering me a broader perspective. I wish to

thank my fellow students for encouraging, supporting, and helping me going through

difficult times.

Last, but not least, my deepest gratitude and love goes to my parents and my

husband for their unconditional and unwavering support. Without their support, I don’t

know what I would have accomplished.

vi

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Page

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ...................................................................................................v

LIST OF TABLES............................................................................................................. vi

LIST OF FIGURES .......................................................................................................... vii

CHAPTER

1 INTRODUCTION ..............................................................................................1

Background Information................................................................................1

Problem Statement .........................................................................................4

Objectives ......................................................................................................5

Organization...................................................................................................6

2 THE INTERNATIONAL MARKET FOR CHICKEN AND U.S. CHICKEN

EXPORTS TO HONG KONG/CHINA...............................................................................7

World Poultry Production, Consumption, and Trade ...................................7

U.S. Poultry Production and Exports..........................................................10

Hong Kong/China Poultry Production and Consumption ..........................24

Hong Kong/China Poultry Imports.............................................................31

3 RELATED LITERATURE...............................................................................42

China Poultry Production Issues..................................................................42

China Poultry Consumption and Marketing Issues .....................................45

Poultry Trade Issues.....................................................................................48

vii

Trade Policy Issues ......................................................................................52

Hong Kong-Mainland China Transshipment Issues ....................................55

China Data Problem.....................................................................................57

4 AN ECONOMETRIC MODEL OF U.S. CHICKEN EXPORTS TO HONG

KONG/CHINA ..................................................................................................................59

Theoretical Framework................................................................................59

Empirical Model ..........................................................................................63

Econometric Consideration..........................................................................67

Hypotheses...................................................................................................78

5 ESTIMATED MODELS, DATA, AND RESULTS ........................................80

Estimated Models.........................................................................................80

Data ..............................................................................................................90

Results..........................................................................................................91

6 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION ...............................................................111

Study Summary..........................................................................................111

Conclusion .................................................................................................113

Limitations and Future Research ...............................................................114

REFERENCES ................................................................................................................116

viii

LIST OF TABLES

Page

Table 2.1: Hong Kong Per Capita Consumption Between Fresh and Chilled/Frozen

Chicken ............................................................................................................26

Table 2.2: Volume and Value of Chicken Meat Imports to Hong Kong,

January-November...........................................................................................32

Table 2.3: Hong Kong Imports of Chicken Products ........................................................34

Table 2.4: Percentage of U.S. Chicken Products Imported to Hong Kong being

Re-Exported to China, January-November......................................................38

Table 5.1: Variable Definitions..........................................................................................89

Table 5.2: Estimation Results for U.S. Chicken Feet Exports to HK/CH .........................93

Table 5.3: Estimation Results for U.S. Chicken Wing Exports to HK/CH .......................94

Table 5.4: Estimation Results for U.S. Chicken Leg Exports to HK/CH..........................95

Table 5.5: Estimation Results for U.S. Chicken Offal Exports to HK/CH........................96

Table 5.6: Estimated Elasticities for Chicken Feet Excess Supply and Demand ............104

Table 5.7: Estimated Elasticities for Chicken Wings Excess Supply and Demand.........104

Table 5.8: Estimated Elasticities for Chicken Legs Excess Supply and Demand ...........105

Table 5.9: Estimated Elasticities for Chicken Offal Excess Supply and Demand...........105

ix

LIST OF FIGURES

Page

Figure 2.1: World Broiler Production/Exports ....................................................................9

Figure 2.2: Market Share of Top Five Broiler Export Countries.......................................10

Figure 2.3: U.S. Broiler Production by State .....................................................................12

Figure 2.4: U.S. Chicken and Turkey Exports...................................................................13

Figure 2.5: U.S. Poultry and Products Exports by State....................................................15

Figure 2.6: U.S. Chicken Meat Exports (1997-2002 Total) ..............................................16

Figure 2.7: U.S. Frozen Chicken Parts Exports (1997-2002 Total)...................................18

Figure 2.8: U.S. Frozen Chicken Parts Exports to Hong Kong/China ..............................20

Figure 2.9: Prices of U.S. Frozen Chicken Parts Exports to Hong Kong/China ...............22

Figure 4.1: The Excess Demand of X................................................................................60

Figure 4.2: Supply and Demand Curves of One Product Between Two Trading

Countries ..........................................................................................................61

Figure 4.3: Supply and Demand Curves of One Product Among Three Trading

Countries ..........................................................................................................63

1

CHAPTER 1

INTRODUCTION

1. Background Information

1.1. World Poultry Production, Consumption, and Trade

In the past decade, poultry production has led the growth in global livestock

production, with poultry accounting for nearly 50 percent of meat production gains. As

poultry production units have become more integrated, concentrated, and better managed,

poultry production costs have fallen more than those of competing meats, such as, beef

and pork (USDA, 2002a).

Poultry meat consumption growth has been especially strong in China, Russia,

and Mexico in recent years. Even in the U.S., consumers are buying more poultry. As a

result of the strong and growing world demand for poultry meat, global poultry exports

have advanced at a double-digit pace in the 1990s(Greene and Southand, 1998). World

poultry imports are dominated by two major markets, Russia and Hong Kong/China. In

the recent years, these two markets account for approximately 65 percent of world

imports. Meanwhile, the export side of global poultry trade is driven mainly by the

United States, Brazil, the EU and China (USDA, 1997a).

2

1.2. U.S. Chicken Production and Exports

The U.S. poultry industry is the world’s largest producer and exporter of poultry

meat. U.S. broiler production is concentrated in a group of States: Georgia, Arkansas,

North Carolina, Alabama, and Mississippi. In 2001, these States accounted for over 67

percent of broilers produced in the United States.

U.S. poultry exports are primarily chicken and turkey exports, with chicken

exports being 10 times as large as the volume of turkey exports. During the 1990s,

exports were a major component of the U.S. broiler industry. In 2001, U.S. broiler

exports totaled 5.6 billion pounds (18 percent of total production), valued at $1.8 billion.

The major U.S. markets are Russia and Hong Kong/China. The smaller markets

include Korea, Japan, Canada and Mexico. With about 16 percent of total poultry

production being exported, the U.S. poultry industry is heavily influenced by currency

fluctuations, trade negotiations, and economic growth in its major importing markets.

From 1997 to 2001, the total value of U.S. frozen chicken parts exports to Russia

was $2.2 billion, and $1.72 billion to Hong Kong/China. In the year 2001, the largest two

importers, Russia and China (including Hong Kong), accounted for 59 percent of total

shipments of U.S. broiler products, on a quantity basis.

As markets have opened to increased poultry trade, the United States has

benefited by selling chicken breasts in the domestic market and exporting dark meat and

less valuable cuts to other markets where they are preferred over breast meat.

3

1.3. China/Hong Kong Poultry Production, Consumption and Transshipment

China is among the world’s largest producers and consumers of animal proteins.

As the world’s second largest poultry producer, China shows production increases of

about 3 percent annually. Poultry imports are increasing even more rapidly to meet the

growing domestic demand for protein. China/Hong Kong is the world’s second-largest

poultry meat importer (USDA, 2000a).

The United States is the largest poultry supplier to Hong Kong/China, because of

its abundant supplies and a big variety of product grades. U.S. broiler parts are extremely

competitive in China, accounting for over 60 percent of total imports. Popular U.S. cuts

include drumsticks, chicken feet, mid-joint wings and whole legs. In 2000, The U.S.

remained the leading supplier of poultry products to the Hong Kong market with a market

share of 65 percent, which was far ahead of the second supplier, Brazil (12 percent).

Consumption of poultry products in Hong Kong/China is primarily chicken. For

the past decade, Chinese poultry meat consumption has grown at a double-digit pace.

China promises to be an important and growing market for poultry meat in the future. A

population 10 times as large as Russia, an expanding middle class, and relative low per

capita consumption levels suggest that consumption will continue to grow. The rapid

growth of the fast-food sector, shift in consumer preferences away from pork towards

poultry, and the booming of supermarkets and hypermarkets, will accelerate the growth

of chicken meat demand (USDA, 1998a).

Less than a third of China’s poultry meat imports are direct, with the rest

transshipped through Hong Kong. Hong Kong is a free port and does not levy any

customs tariff on imports, and there is also no tariff quota or surcharge (USDA, 1997b).

4

Brazil is the second largest poultry supplier to Hong Kong/China. Brazil is very

strong in the supply of its 3-joint wings and whole birds. Among the various cuts of

Brazilian poultry exported to Hong Kong, chicken wings were the biggest category.

China became a member of the World Trade Organization (WTO) in December

2001. China’s accession to the WTO will mean a lowering of the poultry import duty

from 20 percent to 10 percent and a more transparent import regime which should also

stimulate imports.

2. Problem Statement

Hong Kong/China (HK/CH) is definitely a big and promising market for U.S.

chicken product. It is also a complex market.

First, the chicken products exported to HK/CH are composed of various chicken

parts, which reflect different consumption preferences between the U.S. and HK/CH.

Some of the chicken parts preferred in HK/CH are less popular in the U.S., thus, trading

between these two countries has benefited both U.S. producers and Chinese consumers,

and the trend is expected to continue. This characteristic of the U.S.-HK/CH poultry trade

has attracted attention from some researchers; however, no econometric study has been

done to examine this phenomenon.

Secondly, in the United States International Trade Commission (USITC) trading

data which we employed in this study, Hong Kong and China were treated as two

markets, and volume and value of chicken exports were recorded monthly. However,

most of Hong Kong’s imports were transshipped to Mainland China, and the volume of

the transshipment is unknown. Without the transshipment data, any study trying to

5

interpret the Hong Kong market and Mainland China market individually would be very

difficult. In this study, we treat them as one market, and use the notation “Hong

Kong/China” (HK/CH) to represent this market hereafter.

Moreover, with its accession to the WTO, China is expected to further lower their

tariff on poultry products, and increase their imports of U.S. poultry. A study that can

help U.S. poultry producers learn more about the China market, and prepare for a more

open market would be very helpful.

As mentioned above, Hong Kong/China is a promising and unique market for

U.S. chicken meat exports, but little systematic research has been done in this area. In the

next section, we will discuss the objectives of this study.

3. Objectives

The major objectives of this study are to examine the HK/CH market for U.S.

chicken products and to model the excess supply and excess demand of U.S. chicken

exported to HK/CH. The specific objectives of this study are:

• To describe the U.S.- HK/CH chicken export market, explore the different

consumption preferences between the U.S. and HK/CH, and assess the potential

of HK/CH market.

• To estimate excess supply and demand equations for different U.S. chicken parts.

• To estimate the elasticities of the HK/CH demand for U.S. chicken parts and to

draw implications based on the estimated results.

6

4. Organization

The remainder of the thesis is divided into five chapters. Chapter 2 describes the

international market for chicken and U.S. chicken exports to HK/CH. Chapter 3 reviews

related literature in the area of China poultry market, trade policy, and transshipment

issues. Chapter 4 presents the theoretical framework and empirical model used in this

study, including general trading theory and econometric considerations. Chapter 5

introduces the estimated models, data description, and the estimation results of the

models. The final chapter, chapter 6, summarizes the study, presents the conclusions,

points out limitations of the study, and gives suggestion for future research.

7

CHAPTER 2

THE INTERNATIONAL MARKET FOR CHICKEN

AND U.S. CHICKEN EXPORTS TO HONG KONG/CHINA

1. World Poultry Production, Consumption, and Trade

In the past decade, growth in global livestock production has been led by the

poultry sector, with poultry contributing nearly 50 percent of meat production. Global

poultry meat production surpassed beef in 1995, and the gap has continued to widen as

beef production has remained stagnant (USDA, 2002a).

Poultry production units have become more integrated, concentrated, and better

managed, allowing poultry meat to be produced at a lower cost than competing meats.

Strong demand for poultry meat and rising product prices, combined with stable input

costs for poultry producers in many countries, pushed up global poultry output 3 percent

in 2001 to 69.4 million MT. With increased output of poultry compensating for

constrained production of beef and pork in 2001, global meat production grew by one

percent to 237.1 million MT.

Global poultry production rose six-fold between 1965 and 2000 to over 65 million

tons. Consumption increases have exceeded population growth, with world per capita

supplies of poultry meat tripling from 3.3 kg in 1965 to more 10 kg in 2000. International

trade has more than kept pace with this industry growth. Global exports of poultry meat

rose from 375,000 tons in 1965 to over 6.5 million tons in 2000. Thus, trade now

accounts for about 10 percent of global consumption (Peterson and Orden, 2002).

8

Poultry meat consumption growth has been especially strong in China, Russia,

and Mexico in recent years. Even in a developed market such as the U.S., consumers are

buying more poultry. Lower prices relative to red meats, the convenience of processed

poultry products, and promotions of poultry products in the fast-food industry have all

contributed to this trend. As a result of the strong and growing world demand for poultry

meat, global poultry exports have advanced at a double-digit pace in the 1990s, while

pork exports have increased at only about 3 percent annually, and beef exports have

actually declined.

Several important events have also shaped demand for poultry trade over the past

years. Animal disease outbreaks shifted consumption and trade demand away from beef

to pork and poultry. In 2001, consumer preferences for poultry prompted global poultry

trade to increase 4 percent in to 7.6 million metric tons, pushing up poultry’s share of

global meat trade to 43 percent, up from 25 percent in 1990. Beef consumption in

2001was estimated 2.6 percent lower while beef production dropped 1 percent and global

trade slid 5 percent.

The U.S. poultry industry is the world’s largest producer and exporter of poultry

meat. Figure 2.1 shows the broiler production and exports of the top four countries: the

United States, EU, Brazil, and China. In 2000, the U.S. exported 2.446 million MT

broilers, and EU, Brazil and China exported 0.764, 0.916, and 0.464 million MT,

respectively. Hong Kong is one of the biggest exports markets for both the U.S. and

Brazil. The largest export destinations for EU broilers are Russia and the Middle East.

9

0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

12000

14000

16000

Production Exports Production Exports Production Exports Production Exports

United States EU Brazil China

Country

Qua

ntity

(1,0

00 M

atric

Ton

s)

1997199819992000

Figure 2.1. World Broiler Production/Exports

Source: “Livestock and Poultry: World Markets and Trade.” Foreign Agricultural Service, USDA (March 2002): 24.

As can be seen from Figure 2.2, in the year 2000, the U.S. supplied about 47

percent of global broiler imports, followed by Brazil, EU, and China, with the market

shares of 17.6 percent, 14.7 percent and 8.9 percent, respectively. U.S.’s share in broiler

exports decreased from 49.36 percent in 1997 to 47.11 percent in 2000, while Brazilian

share increased from 15.49 percent in 1997 to 17.64 percent in 2000.

10

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

1997 1998 1999 2000

Year

Prop

ortio

n in

Exp

orts

Qua

ntity

ThailandChina, (PRC)BrazilEuropean UnionUnited States

Figure 2.2. Market Shares of Top Five Broiler Export Countries

Source: “Livestock and Poultry: World Markets and Trade.” Foreign Agricultural Service, USDA (March 2002): 24.

2. U.S. Poultry Production and Exports

As the world’s largest producer and exporter of poultry meat, U.S. consumption

of poultry meat (broilers, other chicken, and turkey) is considerably higher than either

beef or pork, but less than total red meat consumption. With about 16 percent of total

poultry production being exported, the U.S. poultry industry is heavily influenced by

currency fluctuations, trade negotiations, and economic growth in its major importing

markets.

11

2.1. U.S. Broiler Production

Endowed with a favorable climate, state-of-art production technology, low feed

costs, and advantageous market structures, the U.S. poultry industry is among the most

efficient in the world. In 2001, U.S. poultry meat production valued $19.53 billion, of

which 85.5 percent was broiler meat, 14.3 percent was turkey meat, and 0.2 percent was

other chicken meat. The total farm value of U.S. poultry production in 2001 was $23.97

billion. Broiler production accounts for the majority of the value at $16.69 billion,

followed by eggs at $4.44 billion, turkey at $2.79 billion, and other chicken at $46

million.

Broiler production is concentrated in a group of States stretching from North

Carolina, south along the Atlantic coast to Georgia, then westward through Alabama,

Mississippi, and Arkansas. In 2001, these top five broiler-producing States accounted for

over 67 percent of broilers produced in the United States. As shown in Figure 2.3,

Georgia is the largest broiler production state. In 2001, Georgia’s broiler production was

valued at $ 2.432 billion, with $ 2.237 billion, $ 2.004 billion, $ 1.681 billion, and $

1.492 billion for Arkansas, Alabama, North Carolina, and Mississippi, respectively.

12

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

Alabama Arkansas Georgia Mississippi North Carolina

State

Valu

e (m

illio

n do

llars

)

19971998199920002001

Figure 2.3. U.S. Broiler Production by State Source: “Poultry - Production and Value.” National Agricultural Statistics Service, USDA, various issues, (1997-2002). Note: In the above figure, annual values cover the 12-month period Dec. 1, previous year through Nov. 30.

2.2. U.S. Poultry Exports

World trade in meats has grown rapidly since the mid 1980s. In the last 17 years,

U.S. exports of the three major meats—beef, pork, and poultry meat—have grown faster

than other countries’ meat exports, and on a value basis, the U.S. has evolved from

primarily a meat importer to a large exporter of the three major meats, with the export

value of each exceeding $1 billion. During the 1990s, exports were a major component

of the U.S. broiler industry. Between 1993 and 1997, U.S. poultry production expanded

rapidly, largely due to a boom in exports. During this period, exports more than doubled,

averaging about 26 percent annual growth, compared with a 5 percent growth in annual

13

production. About 17 percent of U.S. production was exported in 1997, compared with

only 8 percent in 1993. Since 1997, U.S. meat exports have increased at an average rate

of only about 3 percent, in contrast to double-digits of the previous 10 years.

U.S. poultry exports consist primarily chicken and turkey, with chicken exports

being 10 times as large as the volume of turkey exports. Figure 2.4 compares the two

components of U.S. poultry exports. In 2000, chicken and turkey exports were 2.446 and

0.202 million MT, respectively. Chicken exports increased from 2.116 million MT in

1997 to 2.446 million MT in 2000, while turkey exports decreased from 0.275 million

MT to 0.202 million MT.

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

1997 1998 1999 2000

Year

Expo

rts

(1,0

00 M

etric

Ton

s)

Chicken Turkey

Figure 2.4. U.S. Chicken and Turkey Exports Source: “Livestock and Poultry: World Markets and Trade.” Foreign Agricultural Service, USDA (March 2002): 24.

14

In 2001, U.S. broiler exports totaled 5.6 billion pounds (18 percent of total

production), valued at $1.8 billion. World demand for U.S. broiler products has

fluctuated over the last several years due to changing economic conditions and currency

exchange rates in the major importing countries. In 2001, the largest importers of U.S.

broiler products were Russia (including the Baltic countries) and China (including Hong

Kong). Together, these two markets accounted for 59 percent of total shipments of U.S.

broiler products, on a quantity basis.

As markets have opened to increased poultry trade, the United States has

benefited by selling chicken breasts in the domestic market and exporting dark meat and

less valuable cuts to other markets where they are preferred over breast meat. This

strategy has been especially beneficial for the United States, as large markets have

developed for leg meat in Russia and wings, wing tips, and feet in Hong Kong and China.

U.S. advantages—disease-free status, domestically grown feed, and economies of

size—position the U.S. industry to profit from greater freedom in global meat trade. The

United States will continue to increase its production and exports to help fill global

demand. However, Brazilian poultry production and exports are growing at a faster pace,

as the devaluation of the Brazilian currency “Real” provides an advantage in the export

marketplace.

15

0.0

50.0

100.0

150.0

200.0

250.0

300.0

350.0

400.0

450.0

Alabama Arkansas Georgia Mississippi North Carolina

State

Valu

e (M

illio

n D

ollo

rs)

Year_1997Year_1998Year_1999Year_2000Year_2001

Figure 2.5. U.S. Poultry and Products Exports by State

Source: U.S. Agricultural Trade Update (FAU series), Economic Research Service, USDA. Webpage: http://www.ers.usda.gov/data/FATUS/DATA/16010.xls.

Figure 2.5 shows U.S. poultry exports by state. Georgia, Arkansas, North

Carolina, Alabama, and Mississippi are the largest five poultry export states. Georgia’s

poultry exports in 2001 were valued at $308.8 million. Note that we the chicken exports

data by state are not available, but the poultry data should be representative of chicken

exports because U.S. poultry exports are primarily chicken meat.

2.3. Category of Chicken Meat in Trade

In the Harmonized Tariff Schedule (HTS) code system, chicken meat is divided

into four categories: fresh/chilled whole chicken (HTS code: 020711), frozen whole

16

chicken (HTS code: 020712), fresh/chilled chicken parts (HTS code: 020713), and frozen

chicken parts (HTS code: 020714).

Wholechicken(fresh,chilled)

Wholechicken(frozen)

Chickencuts

(fresh,chilled)

Chickencuts

(frozen)

Canada

China

Hong KongJapan

KoreaMexico

Russia

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

Million Dollar

Canada China Hong Kong Japan Korea Mexico Russia

Figure 2.6. U.S. Chicken Meat Exports (1997-2001 Total)

Source: USITC (The United States International Trade Commission) Interactive Tariff and Trade Dataweb. Webpage: http://dataweb.usitc.gov/.

Figure 2.6 shows the total value of exports of U.S. chicken meat. The highest

valued chicken meat export category is frozen chicken parts (HTS code: 020714) for all

the top import countries listed in the graph, except for Canada. In this study, we will

17

focus on the trade of frozen chicken parts. From 1997 to 2001, the total value of Russia’s

frozen chicken parts imports was $ 2.2 billion, followed by Hong Kong/China at $1.72

billion. These two markets accounted more than 60 percent of the world imports of U.S.

frozen chicken parts.

Under category 020714, frozen chicken parts are further divided into five

categories: chicken leg quarters (HTS code: 0207140010), chicken legs excluding leg

quarters (HTS code: 0207140025), chicken wings (HTS code: 0207140030), chicken feet

(HTS code: 0207140045), chicken offal (HTS code: 02071450), and others (HTS code:

0207140090).

Figure 2.7 shows the total value of exports of U.S. frozen chicken by part and

country for the period 1997-2001. Russia’s imports are mostly chicken leg quarters and

“others”, and Hong Kong/China’s top imports are chicken feet and “others”, but the

composition of “other” chicken parts is not clearly defined in the data documentation.

Note that HK is the leading importer of chicken feet, legs, wings, and offal, and this

makes Hong Kong the second largest importer of U.S. chicken, trailing only Russia.

Comparing the exports to Hong Kong and those to Russia, we can see that Hong Kong’s

chicken imports are of more variety, and in general, the parts exported to Hong Kong are

different from those exported to Russia, thus, these two biggest importers are occupying

different U.S. chicken part markets.

18

LegQuarters Legs Wings

FeetOffal

Others

Canada

China

Hong KongJapan

KoreaMexico

Russia

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

Billion Dollar

Canada China Hong Kong Japan Korea Mexico Russia

Figure 2.7. U.S. Frozen Chicken Parts Exports (1997-2001 Total) Source: USITC (The United States International Trade Commission) Interactive Tariff and Trade Dataweb. Webpage: http://dataweb.usitc.gov/.

2.4. U.S. Chicken Meat Exports to Hong Kong/China

Hong Kong is the world’s second-largest poultry meat importer. However, the

majority of poultry meat imports to Hong Kong are transshipped to Mainland China, with

re-exports accounting for about 70 percent of Hong Kong’s imports. Less than a third of

China’s poultry meat imports are direct, with the rest transshipped through Hong Kong.

19

Because Hong Kong re-exports large quantities of poultry meat to the rest of China,

while also importing meat from Mainland China, the markets are tightly linked.

The US has been a major supplier of poultry products to Hong Kong/China

because of abundant supplies and a big variety of product grades. Popular US cuts

include mid-joint wings and whole legs for Hong Kong, and drumsticks and chicken feet

for China. The exported products from the U.S. do not conflict much with China’s

domestic supply due to Chinese consumption habits. More than 70 percent of U.S.

chicken products exported to China are chicken feet, offal, wingtips and gizzards, and

Chinese domestic producers cannot satisfy the demand for these chicken parts without

imports.

Figure 2.8 shows that chicken feet has been a major component of U.S. chicken

parts exports, and its export volume increased from 0.118 million MT in 1997 to 0.280

million MT in 2001. Chicken legs, wings, and offal exports also increased markedly since

1997. Note that due to Russia’s economic crisis in 1999, Hong Kong imported

significantly more chicken leg quarters in 1999, and decreased its imports after Russia’s

economic recovery in 2000.

The Hong Kong/China market grew rapidly during the 1990s. From 1992 to 1996,

U.S. poultry meat exports to HK/CH more than tripled, reaching nearly 600,000 tons.

The Asian financial crisis began in July 1997. A wave of currency devaluations,

stock market plunges, and business failures severely battered the economies of Indonesia,

Malaysia, the Philippines, Thailand, and Korea, and quickly affected the economies of

Hong Kong/China, although the currencies of China and Hong Kong are pegged to U.S.

20

dollar. The Asian financial crisis has not depressed U.S. broiler exports, although it has

had negative effects on shipments of other poultry exports.

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

Year

Qua

ntity

(1,0

00 M

T) leg quarterslegswingsfeetoffalothers

Figure 2.8. U.S. Frozen Chicken Parts Exports to Hong Kong/China Source: USITC (The United States International Trade Commission) Interactive Tariff and Trade Dataweb. Webpage: http://dataweb.usitc.gov/.

At the beginning of 1998, U.S. broiler exports to Hong Kong/China fell

significantly as consumers avoided all chicken products following a scare that Avian

influenza might be able to pass from poultry to humans. By the early spring of 1998,

however, exports of broilers to Hong Kong/China rebounded to levels above the previous

year, and through September were 2 percent above the same period in 1997.

In 2000, while renewed Russian demand for U.S. leg quarters reduced the volume

of this product going through Hong Kong, shipments of feet and wings were up. Vibrant

21

demand in Mainland China for feet and wings sparked an increase in re-exports. The U.S.

remained the leading supplier of poultry products for the Hong Kong market by

occupying a market share of 65 percent, which was far ahead of the second supplier,

Brazil (12 percent). However, U.S. chicken exports to Hong Kong dropped about 5

percent in the year 2000. Conversely, Brazilian chicken exports rose about 41 percent.

One possible reason is that prices of Brazilian products dropped almost 12 percent in

2000. Nonetheless, the U.S. has a big variety of product cuts at different product grades.

This distinct advantage enables the U.S. to continue to remain as the largest supplier of

chicken products for the Hong Kong market.

In 2001, as the Russian market for US poultry products was open again, the US

supplies to the Hong Kong/China market were relatively less and average C.I.F. prices

were higher when compared to previous years when US has reduced access to the

Russian market. Due to the higher world prices, China chicken imports were down in

2001.

While growth in exports to the Hong Kong/China market has benefited the U.S.

broiler industry, the trend has not strengthened prices as dramatically as it would in other

markets. The reason lies in the composition of products shipped to Hong Kong/China.

More than 20 percent of all broiler products exported there consist of chicken feet.

Without this market, almost all of these parts would go to renderers for eventual use as

feedstuff. These exports represent a definite gain to broiler processors, but their absence

from the U.S. domestic market does not affect prices for broiler parts traditionally

consumed in the U.S. (Harvey, 2000).

22

Figure 2.9 shows the prices (value per unit) of U.S. chicken parts exports to Hong

Kong/China. Overall, the prices decreased over the years. Comparing the prices of

different chicken parts. Chicken feet price is the lowest, with average of $0.51/kg. Note

that the prices shown in the graph are 3-month moving average smoothed prices.

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

1.1

1.2

1.3

1 4 7 10 13 16 19 22 25 28 31 34 37 40 43 46

Time Period

Valu

e pe

r Uni

t (D

olla

r/Kg)

legs wings feet offal others

Figure 2.9. Prices of U.S. Frozen Chicken Parts Exports to Hong Kong/China (January 1997-December 2000) Source: USITC (The United States International Trade Commission) Interactive Tariff and Trade Dataweb. Webpage: http://dataweb.usitc.gov/.

While price may be the deciding factor in purchasing decisions by Chinese

wholesalers, quality, specifications, and packaging are becoming increasingly important.

Hong Kong traders always hope that U.S. products can improve their packaging which is

strong enough to survive after long transportation to inland China.

23

Chinese retailers do not know about U.S. poultry because of the lack of

production origin label. Once frozen chicken parts are shipped to China, they are loaded

on non-refrigerated trucks. Smaller packages go directly to large retail stores, while large

packages are defrosted for sale in smaller retail stores or local wet markets, which leaves

the consumer unaware of origin. As the market liberalizes, U.S. exporters will need to

sell a branded product to be competitive. Already in wholesale and retail markets, the

domestic product is sold in well-packaged, branded form (Morgan, 1997).

Import channels to the wholesale and wet markets are well established but not to

supermarkets. Also, U.S. processors do not package consumer-sized portions for

supermarkets. Small package food products are preferred because of the limited living

space in Chinese urban area.

2.5. U.S. Exports to Other Countries

2.5.1. Russia

The financial crisis in Russia affected the trade in poultry parts in 1998. Extreme

currency fluctuations, difficulties in getting letters of credit and overall price uncertainties

stopped trade temporarily. Following the August 1998 devaluation of the ruble, exports to

Russia during the first eight months of 1999 were more than 80 percent below the level

for the same period in 1998 (USDA, 1999).

Until the ruble devaluation in August 1998, broiler exports had proceeded at a

record pace and prices had been fairly strong. After devaluation, exports fell

dramatically, and prices for most parts declined. By December 1998, the drop in exports

to Russia sent U.S. Northeast prices for leg quarters plunging to 18 cents, a 50-percent

24

decline from 36 cents in August. U.S. poultry meat exports continued to suffer from the

near total collapse of the Russia commercial import market.

In 2000, while Russian poultry production was recovering slowly, commercial

imports of poultry meat had strengthened due to higher prices domestically, and

improved Russian economy, and a stabilization of the rules governing imports. As the

Russian market for U.S. poultry products was open again, the U.S. supplies to the Hong

Kong/China market were also affected. With the higher demand for U.S. chicken

products in the Russia market, U.S. shipments to HK/CH were less and average C.I.F.

prices were higher. Traders revealed that the prices of leg quarters around August 2001

was as high as $0.40/lb when demand in the Russian market was extremely keen before

the winter season. The market in China cannot afford to buy products at such a high

price, leading to decreased imports.

3. Hong Kong/China Poultry Production and Consumption

3.1. Hong Kong Production and Consumption

Hong Kong’s poultry supply is primarily from imports. Hong Kong’s local

production only contributed 18 percent of its chicken meat consumption. Poultry meat

production in Hong Kong is comprised mainly of live poultry imported from China and

slaughtered locally (USDA, 2000b).

Consumption of poultry products in Hong Kong is primarily chicken. In 2001,

Hong Kong consumed about 353,000 MT of poultry products, 86 percent of which were

chicken products. Turkey only constituted about 7,000 MT, with ducks, geese and quail

occupying the rest of the market share. Out of the 303,000 MT of chicken products

25

consumed annually in Hong Kong, live chickens took up a share of 22 percent. Hong

Kong is a mature market for meat consumption, which will likely not experience any

drastic changes (USDA, 2002b).

Hong Kong consumers’ consumption pattern has gradually changed over the past

few years. Low international prices make imported product attractive, and there is a

growing local acceptance of chilled and frozen poultry versus freshly slaughtered. As

shown in Table 2.1, Hong Kong people are more receptive to chilled/frozen products and

consuming more chilled/frozen poultry products at the expense of live chickens resulting

from changes in eating and shopping habits. This trend is expected to deepen in the

future (USDA, 2002b).

The drastic changes in Table 2.1 for 1998 figures were caused by the bird flu

crisis, which served as a catalyst encouraging consumers to buy frozen products when

fresh products were in short supply. The total consumption of fresh chickens has

rebounded significantly since 1999. For chilled/frozen products, consumption has

consistently increased, except in 1999 after a significant jump in 1998. In the very long

term, the market share of live chicken is expected to shrink gradually while the

consumption of chilled/frozen products will rise.

26

Table 2.1. Hong Kong Per Capita Consumption Between Fresh and Chilled/Frozen chicken

Per capita consumption Total consumption Year Product Kg 1,000 MT

Fresh 11 67 1996

Chilled/frozen 32 204

Fresh 10 67 1997 Chilled/frozen 35 226

Fresh 8 53

1998 Chilled/frozen 45 299

Fresh 9 63 1999 Chilled/frozen 43 292

Fresh 9 65 2000 Chilled/frozen 44 308

Source: “Attaché Report: Hong Kong Poultry and Products Semi-Annual, 2001”, Foreign Agricultural Service, (February 2001): 25.

3.1.1. Bird Flu

Hong Kong suffered its first “bird flu” virus in late1997. The effect of the flu

scare was devastating for poultry consumption. Even though trade representatives were

able to point out that frozen poultry parts from the United States did not have avian

influenza, consumers in Hong Kong were reluctant to trust any poultry product. The

poultry consumption rebounded somewhat in January 1998 but only to around 40 percent

of pre-avian flu crisis levels. By the time the crisis was over the government had

destroyed more than a million chickens in Hong Kong.

As a result of the influenza scare, the government banned imports of live birds

from China from late December 1997 through February 7, 1998 and adopted more

stringent sanitary requirements for licensing of chicken farms. Hong Kong did not have

27

live chicken supplies for months, which allowed the consumption of frozen chicken and

red meats to surge. Red meat consumption reportedly jumped 30-40 percent, as

consumers substituted beef or pork for chicken. In China, the “bird flu” resulted in lower

prices and constrained import demand as Hong Kong restricted access for live birds

coming from southern China (USDA, 1998a).

In the year 2001, Hong Kong suffered its second bird flu. In May the Hong Kong

government destroyed over 1.3 million chickens following the death of many chickens in

various wet markets throughout Hong Kong. Retail sales of live chickens resumed on

June 16, 2001 after one-month suspension. Since the second bird flu crisis, both Hong

Kong and Mainland Chinese governments have been very strict in observing the safety

surveillance program, and this perhaps explains why Hong Kong’s importation of live

chicken dropped from 100,000 birds a day to around 80,000 birds a day. Retail sales of

frozen chicken dropped about 20 percent during the crisis, and frozen chicken imports

were affected to some extent.

None of the bird flu incidents caused any long term effect on U.S. chicken

exports. In Hong Kong, chicken consumption and imports resumes only after one

months’ recovery. But the long term effect of the live chicken scare on Hong Kong

consumption patterns may persist. Hong Kong consumers are shifting some of their

consumption from live chicken to frozen chicken.

28

3.2. China Poultry Production, Consumption, and Exports

With 1.3 billion people and a GDP growing about 7 percent a year, China is a

major market with significant growth potential. The United States is the largest

agricultural supplier to China, but there is a lot of competition.

China’s livestock (pork, beef, and poultry) output played an important role in

global meat production over the last decade. China’s meat production has increased 10

percent annually since 1988. When China’s production is excluded, global production of

meat has risen only about one-half percent each year (Greene and Southard, 1998).

3.2.1. China Poultry Production

China’s broiler industry is focusing on the huge domestic market as well as

foreign markets. Moving into position as the world’s second largest poultry meat

producer, China remains a pivotal component of the world poultry meat complex. Indeed,

the longer term outlook of world trade hinges on China’s ability to expand production to

meet its consumption requirements (USDA, 1997a).

China’s poultry production increased rapidly after 1980, although data on poultry

meat and egg production are less reliable than other livestock data because such a large

proportion of the birds are produced by individual farm households, rather than in

specialized operations.

Lower feed prices in 1997 have supported significant production increase in

China, slowing demand for imports. Expansion in domestic poultry meat output in China

and lower prices have made it more difficult for broiler imports to compete against

domestically produced product. In recent years, poultry production growth in China has

29

been modest, around 2 percent, as low feed prices are offset by low product prices. Low

prices are forcing many small-scale poultry operations to close, but as the industry

consolidates, production is expected to climb to meet the growing demand for low-priced

protein (USDA, 2000b).

Grain price policy reforms, implemented in April 1998, have led to a clampdown

on private sales of grains. All buyers are now required to purchase feed inputs from grain

bureaus at prices considerably higher than world prices. This implies a higher cost, less

efficient poultry meat industry in the future. Poultry meat (which includes duck and

goose meat) output in China during 2001 is 12.7 million tons, up by 2 percent from 2000.

3.2.2. China Poultry Consumption

Although current per capita consumption of animal proteins is lower in China

than that in wealthier nations, it is increasing rapidly as China’s economy and personal

incomes grow. China has the potential to become a growing market for animal protein

imports, as demand for meats, fish, eggs, and milk is expected to outgrow domestic feed

grain supplies. For the past decade, Chinese poultry meat consumption has grown at a

double-digit pace.

Poultry is a staple food for the Chinese consumers. Consumers are very sensitive

to prices. Popular cuts for Chinese consumer include chicken feet, leg quarters and 3-

joint wings. In comparison, the more expensive mid-joint wings from the U.S. have little

market in China except in some higher income areas like Shanghai.

30

3.2.3. China Chicken Product Exports

China is a major player in the world poultry meat market, both on the import and

export side of the trade equation. China remains a net importer of poultry on a volume

basis, and a net exporter on a value basis.

China’s largest target export market is the Japanese market. Benefiting from

lower labor and transportation costs, China has aggressively challenged Thailand, Brazil,

and the United States in the Japanese market. China exports higher valued products to

Japan while keeping lower valued products for domestic consumption. This segmentation

dovetails with the traditional tastes of Chinese consumers, who prefer dark meat parts,

wings and feet.

Historically, China has exported not only domestically produced product to Japan

but also imported poultry meat that has been processed to Japanese specifications and re-

packaged in smaller containers. Chinese poultry meat exports to Japan has dropped since

1998. A depressed Japanese economy and weak currency has led to relatively stagnant

demand for imported product. This combined with strong competition from more cheaply

priced Thai broiler meat has damped demand for Chinese product. This resulted in

constrained demand in China for imported chicken. Poultry prices in China dropped

about 30 percent due to the oversupply situation. Hong Kong traders dealing with

transshipment did not foresee the situation. They accumulated large inventories and

incurred big losses due to storage costs (USDA, 1998a).

China is also the largest supplier of whole birds to Hong Kong market. The

Chinese government has announced that effective January 1, 2002, chilled/frozen chicken

products can be exported to Hong Kong without going through any sole agent. They have

31

also lifted their export quotas on chilled and frozen beef, pork and chicken to Hong

Kong. Poultry exports to Hong Kong, particularly whole chickens, are expected to rise. It

will not be in direct competition with the U.S., because Hong Kong’s imports from U.S.

are mainly frozen chicken parts, not whole chicken.

In May 2001, the EU lifted a five-year ban on imports of frozen chicken from

China. The ban had been imposed in 1996 due to hygiene concerns. Prior to the ban,

China’s average annual exports of poultry meat to the EU amounted to 50,000 MT,

roughly one sixth of China’s total poultry exports. It is expected this policy change will

allow more exports to EU, but the progress will be slow, and the exports volume will not

reach previous levels.

4. Hong Kong/China Poultry Imports

4.1. Hong Kong Chicken Meat Imports Overview

Because Hong Kong is a major transshipment point for poultry meat to China, and

the majority of poultry imports by China pass through Hong Kong, Hong Kong has

become a leading poultry meat importer.

Hong Kong local demand, reflected by retained imports, was basically constant

over the years and it has not been a factor contributing to Hong Kong’s fluctuation of

imports, except for the whole bird category. Hong Kong’s chicken meat re-exports to

Mainland China is the real factor that causes the changes of Hong Kong’s total imports.

Because almost 70 percent of Hong Kong’s imports are re-exported to China, and

China’s direct imports are of very little volume compared to Hong Kong’s imports, it’s

32

informative to focus on Hong Kong’s chicken meat imports as well as combined Hong

Kong/China imports.

Table 2.2. Volume and Value of Chicken Meat Imports to Hong Kong, January - November Volume (MT) Value ($ million)

Country 2000 2001 Change 2000 2001 Change United States 658,451 550,709 -16 % 426 373 -12 % Brazil 124,750 119,971 -4 % 99 96 -2 % China 21,567 30,374 41 % 38 48 28 % United Kingdom 30,051 23,072 -23 % 24 18 -25 % Canada 32,428 19,897 -39 % 23 14 -39 % Thailand 17,629 19,546 11 % 22 24 9 % Netherlands 27,884 18,837 -32 % 23 15 -35 % The World 967,298 836,874 -13 % 695 628 -10 % Source: “Attaché Report: Hong Kong Poultry and Products Semi-Annual, 2002”, Foreign Agricultural Service, (Feb 2002): 8.

Table 2.2 shows the U.S. is still the largest chicken meat exporter to Hong Kong,

with a market share of 66 percent in 2001 on value base. Brazil occupied 14 percent of

this market, followed by Mainland China, UK, Canada, Thailand and Netherlands. The

lower imports in 2001 can be explained by the expected China’s accession to the WTO.

Hong Kong importers believed that it became more difficult for their products to get into

China after China became a WTO member because the Chinese authorities issued less

import licenses and allowed less import volume (USDA, 2002c). In the first ten months

of 2001, Hong Kong’s imports of chicken products decreased about 10 percent mainly

because of the decrease in Hong Kong’s chicken re-exports to China (-18 percent). The

import of major re-export categories decreased: chicken feet (-5 percent); chicken wings

(-4 percent); chicken frozen cuts (-37 percent). Hong Kong’s import of chicken frozen

33

cuts dropped remarkably by 37 percent as a result of U.S.’ reduced supply of leg quarters

to Hong Kong, much of the supplies of U.S. leg quarter have been diverted back to the

Russian market (USDA, 2002b).

4.2. Hong Kong/China Imports from Brazil

Brazil is the world’s second largest broiler exporter. Brazil experienced all time

records in production, exports and profit margins in 2001. Broiler production was up 10

percent due to record exports, devaluation of the Brazilian currency, increase in average

slaughter weight, low cost of production and improved productive capacity. A strong

U.S. dollar would maintain Brazil’s competitiveness in world markets even with

increased production cost in 2002.

Traditionally, Brazilians had been whole bird exporters, however in 2001 chicken

parts exports surpassed whole bird levels. The devaluation of the Brazilian Real made

Brazil more competitive on the world market. Brazil significantly increased chicken cut

exports to the world. Although U.S. keeps its dominant role in Hong Kong imports,

Brazil has been increasing its market share from 8 percent in 1996 to 14 percent in 2001.

The merits of Brazilian products, according to Hong Kong importers, are their

consistent product quality and good packaging. Their distinct packing method, solid layer

packing, offers great convenience for users.

Brazil is very strong in the supply of its 3-joint wings and whole birds. Among the

various cuts of Brazilian poultry exported to Hong Kong, chicken wings were the biggest

category. Besides 3-joint wings, Brazil is also very strong in the supply of whole birds.

34

Brazil increased its supply of whole chickens to Hong Kong in response to the rising

demand locally.

Table 2.3. Hong Kong Imports of Chicken Products

Country 1996 1997 1998 1999 (Jan-Oct)

2000 (Jan-Nov)

2001 (Jan-Nov)

MT U.S. 507,633 539,816 538,756 631,629 658,451 550,709 U.S. Share 68 % 66 % 64 % 70 % 68 % 66 % Brazil 58,192 76,507 73,844 82,547 124,705 119,971 Brazil share 8 % 9 % 9 % 9 % 13 % 14 % World 746,063 814,746 839,432 896,176 967,298 836,874 Source: “Attaché Report: Hong Kong Poultry and Products Semi-Annual,” “Attaché Report: Hong Kong Poultry Annual,” Foreign Agricultural Service, various issues, 1996-2002.

Unlike the U.S., Brazil is not able to supply a wide product range to the Hong

Kong market. Another disadvantage of Brazil in terms of its exports to Hong Kong is

expensive freight costs, which currently stand at $5,500 - 5,800 for a 40ft container with

a load of 25 tons. In comparison, the freight between the West Coast of the U.S. and

Hong Kong costs around $ 2,500 (USDA, 2001a).

4.3. Hong Kong-China Transshipment

4.3.1. General Description

Hong Kong is a free market, imposing no tariffs on food imports. There are no

price regulations or import controls. Hong Kong is the world’s largest container port.

Many U.S. agricultural exports make their way into China through Hong Kong. Its duty-

free status and proximity to China have allowed Hong Kong to become the eighth-largest

35

destination for U.S. agricultural exports, and fourth-largest for U.S. consumer-ready

products.

Before July 1997, Hong Kong was a British colony. On July 1, 1997, Hong Kong

was assimilated into China, concern abounded about the status of Hong Kong as a

transshipment point into China. According to Chinese law, Hong Kong’s trade policy

following the integration is to remain unchanged. As such, import regulations and Hong

Kong’s status as a free port which does not levy import tariffs on poultry products

remains unchanged.

Hong Kong retains its own import system. Most re-exports from Hong Kong to

China are handled by Hong Kong transport companies that provide freight forwarding

services to Hong Kong importers, moving their goods into China, taking care of

documents and paying tariffs. These companies’ fees reflect shipping conditions at

Mainland China ports, and they typically rise when the Chinese government institutes

crackdown measures, such as more stringent sanitary standards. The periodic crackdowns

contribute to uncertainty about dependable access to China, thereby inhibited the trade

environment.

In 2001, 47 percent of Hong Kong’s agricultural imports from the United States

were re-exported to China. Direct U.S. exports of broilers to China, the seventh largest

market for the United States, were valued at $33 million. However, U.S. broiler exports

to Hong Kong, for direct consumption there and re-exports to China, accounted for an

additional $335 million. Many observers believe that in the next three or four years,

China’s import liberalization will result in the rechanneling of an increasing share of

imports directly to Chinese destinations. While Hong Kong’s share of this trade will

36

likely decline as China becomes further integrated into the WTO, the absolute volume of

China’s imports should climb (USDA, 2001b).

4.3.2. Poultry Transshipment

Most of the poultry products re-exported to China from Hong Kong are handled

by transport companies. As China’s improved transportation systems allow more

imported poultry products to reach inland markets, re-exports to China are also

increasing.

Consumer preferences in Hong Kong and China differ significantly given the

large gap in living standards. While approximately 65 percent of Hong Kong’s imports

are redirected to China, most of the more expensive chicken parts such as mid-joints,

wings, and legs stay in Hong Kong. The less expensive parts, such as offal, gizzards, low-

priced mid-joints, and particularly feet and paws, are the best selling items in the Chinese

market (USDA, 1997b).

In principle, China is able to absorb large volumes of Hong Kong’s re-exports

provided that products are cheap. However, there are two potential unfavorable factors

for increased re-exports: Lower prices of domestic products and higher transportation

costs. Agricultural production in China has increased and prices have become lower

because of increased supplies. The transport cost of Hong Kong’s poultry re-export to

China has increased. The transport fees charged to handle this trade have several

components: import duties, customs valuation of container loads, and profit margin.

Industry sources pointed out that transport prices have been increasing in recent years,

mainly because of more accurate valuation of goods in containers by Chinese custom

37

officials, who have far better knowledge of product prices than in the past (USDA,

2001a).

There is a growing trend for U.S. products to be re-exported to China, de-boned in

Mainland China and then re-imported into Hong Kong for consumption. Table 2.4 shows

the latest report on U.S. chicken parts re-exports. The share of Hong Kong’s poultry re-

exports to China decreased from 85 percent in January - October 1999 to 82 percent in

January - October 2000. Comparing figures for the first 10 months of 1999 and 2000, the

share of re-exports of chicken feet to China remained the same, and chicken wings

increased from 73 percent to 75 percent and chicken frozen cuts dropped from 85 percent

to 73 percent.

38

Table 2.4. Percentage of U.S. Chicken Products Imported to HK being Re-Exported to China, January - November

MT, 2000 MT, 2001

U.S. chicken product imports to HK 658,451 550,709

U.S. chicken product import to HK being re-exported to China

558,778 451,875

% of US chicken product imports to HK being re-exported to China

85 % 82 %

U.S. chicken feet imports to HK 294,269 286,591

U.S. chicken feet imports to HK being re-exported to China

260,472 255,977

% of US chicken feet imports to HK being re-exported to China

89 % 89 %

U.S. chicken wings imports to HK 114,209 114,189

U.S. chicken wings imports to HK being re-exported to China

83,282 85,307

% of U.S. chicken wings imports to HK being re-exported to China

73 % 75 %

U.S. chicken frozen cuts imports to HK 228,453 134,127

U.S. chicken frozen cuts imports to HK being re-exported to China

194,110 97,930

% of U.S. chicken frozen cuts imports to HK being re-exported to China

85 % 73 %

Source: “Attaché Report: Hong Kong Poultry and Products Semi-Annual, 2002”, Foreign Agricultural Service, (Feb 2002): 8

4.4. Trade Policies and Regulations

Since most of Hong Kong’s poultry imports were re-exported to China, China’s

trade policies could have a significant impact on Hong Kong’s poultry trade. China

reduced import duties on a variety of products including poultry products effctive

October 1, 1997. Import duties were reduced from 45 percent to 20 percent. The effect on

imports was limited, however, with traders stating that it was more cost effective to move

product through “transportation companies” operating near the Guangdong border.

39

Southern China (Guangdong) ports are the primary entry points for imported poultry. The

cost for moving product through these transportation companies (around $180/ton) was

still less than paying the 20-percent tariff. Since the effective rate through “unofficial

channels” is still about 13 percent, the reduction in import duty had little effect on Hong

Kong’s re-export trade to China (USDA, 1998a).

China became a member of the World Trade Organization (WTO) on December

11, 2001 (source: the WTO Internet site). China’s accession to the World Trade

Organization will mean a lowering of the poultry import duty from 20 Percent to 10

percent and a more transparent import regime which should also stimulate imports. After

entering the WTO, China reduced the tariff rate on frozen broiler products, but the

reduction still did not fully meet China’s WTO commitments.

China’s accession to the WTO would also mean that U.S. exporters could look

forward to lower tariffs for poultry meat imports. An ensuing transparent import regime

would provide for more price stability and less risks for both exporter and importer. After

its reunification with China, Hong Kong maintains separate representation to several

international organizations, including the WTO, the World Customs Organization and the

Asian Development Bank.

Now that China has entered the WTO, reductions of duties and the easing of

improper import restrictions will make Shanghai, Dalian, Tianjin and other mainland

ports attractive entry points. For the foreseeable future, trade will continue through Hong

Kong.

The eventual implementation of the U.S.-China Agricultural Cooperation

Agreement could also reduce the role of Hong Kong as a transshipment point. But the

40

Chinese Government must change many of its entry and inspection procedures to comply

with the agreement, and it is still in the process of being implemented.

4.5. Hong Kong/China: Chicken Imports Potential

China promises to be an important and growing market for poultry meat in the

future. A population 10 times as large as Russia, an expanding middle class, and relative

low per capita consumption levels suggest that consumption will continue to grow.

Poultry meat accounts for only 18 percent of China’s meat market, compared to

30 percent in many developed countries and 37 percent in the United States. A shift in

consumer preferences as consumers diversify away from pork towards poultry and

seafood will accelerate the growth in demand for chicken meat, supporting growth in the

domestic industry as well as imports.

The rapid growth of the fast-food sector and the development of a food processing

industry will add to the steady increase in poultry consumption, which has been rising 14

percent annually over the past decade. Kentucky Fried Chicken (KFC) has opened over

150 outlets in China. Additionally, McDonald’s, Pizza Hut and other food chain stores

are prolific in China.

During the past decade, the supermarket has made impressive progress in China.

Consisting first of local chains, and joined by foreign hypermarkets, these large stores

offer incentives and opportunities for increased market access to trade.

Consumption patterns are moving gradually away from the preference for live

chickens to frozen chickens. The change in preference will also increase the demand for

U.S. frozen chicken parts. Chinese consumers used to shop for food daily because of

41

preference for fresh food, however, some Hong Kong/China consumers, especially the

younger generation, have become accustomed to buying chilled and frozen chickens from

supermarkets. There has been growing popularity of frozen food stuff because that many

working women cannot afford the time to do grocery shopping daily, that ready-to-cook

frozen food has become more popular, and that consumers care more about food safety

and nutrition.

42

CHAPTER 3

RELATED LITERATURE

1. China Poultry Production Issues

Despite a long history of livestock-raising activities, China’s livestock industry

did not begin to develop rapidly until the mid-1980s (Tuan, Cao, and Peng, 2001).

Production growth was stimulated not only by general market-oriented policy reforms,

but also by direct government support for specialized poultry breeding operations

(USDA, 1998b). “Official estimates indicate that output more than doubled from 1.5

million tons in 1984 to 3.2 million in 1990. During the 1990’s, China’s poultry meat

production accelerated at an annual rate of 22 percent, reaching 11.5 million tons in

1997” (Crook and Harvey, 1998).

Some research categorized Chinese poultry production units into three groups of

different scales: specialized production, traditional backyard production, and large-scale

production. Statistical sources in China define specialized poultry producing households

as those that devote most of their labor and receive most of their income from poultry

operations. The number of specialized households increased rapidly after rural reforms

were initiated in the early 1980s. Typically, a specialized household will raise five

batches of broilers in a year with 1,000 to 2,000 birds in a batch. In some areas, the

specialized households serve as contract growers for large integrated poultry operations.

43

Researchers estimate that specialized households produce about 40 percent of China’s

poultry output (Crook and Harvey, 1998).

Households specializing in livestock-production activities as their principal

occupation now account for an increasing share of production. However, most meat is

still produced with traditional “backyard” methods—that is, rural households raise

animals on a small scale to supplement their farm income. (Tuan, Cao, and Peng, 2001).

Tuan, Cao, and Peng (2001) compared the price responsiveness of specialized households

and traditional backyard operations, and they concluded that, these specialized

households rely far less on homegrown grain and farm by-products and are more

responsive to grain prices than traditional backyard operations.

Crook and Harvey (1998) reported, “Many traditional farm households keep a

flock of poultry around the farmstead to forage in the fields for whatever they can eat,

supplemented by some feed. Researchers estimate that this traditional method accounts

for about half of total poultry output.”

In the 1990s, many large-scale integrated poultry operations began to emerge.

Currently, there are many large-scale poultry facilities in China, mostly located around

large urban areas and near east coast ports. Some are wholly domestic facilities, but many

are joint ventures with firms from the United States, Singapore, Thailand, Hong Kong,

Taiwan, and Japan. These facilities typically are either near major urban population

centers, or near low-cost transportation routes, where poultry products are sold both to

local urban consumers and to the export market. Modern facilities produce about 10

percent of poultry output. They supply a large share of poultry for urban consumers. For

44

many of these joint venture operations the purpose was to serve not only the domestic

market, but also to export poultry products, primarily to Japan (Crook and Harvey, 1998).

Fuller and Fang (1999) studied the price responsiveness of feed demand by

traditional and specialized household producers of pork and poultry in China and

simulated the impact of changes in the structure of Chinese livestock production on world

feed grain trade. Their feed demand estimation reveals that traditional backyard

producers have very inelastic demands for feed grains. For the traditional producers, the

per capita quantity of grain the household produces and regional differences are

significant determinants of feed grain use. For the specialized household producers, feed

grain demand is roughly twice as responsive to feed prices changes as demands by

traditional households. The larger response to prices reflects that greater dependence of

specialized household producers on markets for their feed inputs. Their results also

suggest that the modernization of China’s livestock sector will not place unmanageable

strains on the international grain market, nor will it greatly increase China’s dependence

on imported grain.

Pork and chicken meat are China’s major livestock products. Some researchers

projected the future production/consumption of these meats, and examined the poultry

production growth rate. Crook and Colby (1998) state that pork still remains the preferred

meat in China, but the price for pork may rise relative to other meats (including chicken

meat) unless China is able to increase grain and oilseed production to meet domestic feed

requirements. They added that a relative increase in the pork price vis-à-vis other animal

protein products will induce consumers to switch to other products.

45

Crook and Colby’s statements are further confirmed by Tuan, Cao, and Peng

(2001), “Poultry production, with its high feed-conversion ratio, has made more efficient

use of China’s feed supply. Poultry’s share of China’s total meat production grew from

11 percent in 1990 to near 19 percent in 1999.”

China is world’s largest producer and consumer of most livestock meat

products, but trade accounts for very small share of the livestock

economy. Government policies have severely limited the exposure to

world markets. In the past decade, a strategy of grain self-sufficiency

limited the growth of domestic livestock production, while a strategy of

meat self-sufficiency restricted imports of livestock products (USDA,

1998b).

The challenge for China is that the country must achieve this consumption growth

with only seven percent of the world’s arable land. China must feed 5.2 people for each

acre of arable land in the country, whereas Europe feeds 1.64, the United States feeds

0.56, and the Russian Federation feeds only 0.44 people per arable acre. It has become

obvious to most experts that China will need to import feed grains or livestock products

to achieve consumer diets similar to those of the developed countries. Most experts

believe China will need to import feed grains of livestock products as its income rises

(Hayes, 1997).

2. China Poultry Consumption and Marketing Issues

“Over the past two decades, both rural and urban per capita meat consumption

has increased. Rural households (nearly 70 percent of China’s consumers) raised their per

46

capita consumption of meat and fish from 12.4 kg in 1983 to 20 kg in 1999, an increase

of over 60 percent. Urban households consumed more than twice as much meat and fish

per capita as did rural households in 1983 (30.6 kg)” (Tuan, Cao, and Peng, 2001).

Wang et al. (1998) suggested that China’s demand for animal products will

continue to grow as income increases. “Chinese meat consumption will continue to be

sensitive to per capita incomes. Continued growth in incomes at levels close to those seen

recently will cause large increases in demand for meat products”( Wang et al., 1998).

They further addressed that, if markets are allowed to decide where these additional

supplies should originate, U.S. exports of poultry and pork should increase dramatically.

A U.S. Department of Agriculture Economic Research Service analysis based on

China’s price and income statistics since the early 1980s found that poultry demand was

more sensitive to income growth than pork demand and that rural meat demand

responded more to income growth than urban demand. (Cao and Huang, 2000)

Wang et al. (1998) used two common demand systems, the almost ideal demand

system and the translog demand system to estimate the demand elasticities for six animal

products: pork, beef and mutton, poultry, eggs, fish, and milk in urban China. The

estimated poultry demand expenditure elasticity for Chinese urban household is 1.4895,

which is the highest among the five animal products. Their estimated poultry demand

own (Marshallian) price elasticity is -1.3362, which is also the highest among the five

animal products. Both the expenditure and price responsiveness on poultry demand is

elastic. The second highest expenditure and own price elasticity is for fish, with 1.1909 as

its expenditure elasticity, and –1.0253 as its own price elasticity. With Chinese

consumers’ increasing income/expenditure, and low poultry meat price, both income and

47

price effects suggest that consumers will be very likely to increase poultry consumption,

and that poultry consumption will increase faster than pork consumption, provided that

poultry production is more cost-efficient.

The USDA Broiler Team visited China in 1997 under the USDA, Ministry of

Agriculture Science and Technology Exchange Program. The team concluded that most

spent hens from traditional and specialized households, and most likely also those from

modern facilities, still are marketed through local food markets. Generally these birds are

slaughtered and consumed on the same day, reducing the requirements of cold storage.

They also noted in their trip report that birds from farm families typically are sold in local

food markets. Consumers pick out a live chicken and the vendor kills the bird, scalds it,

picks off the feathers, eviscerates it and hands the white dressed chicken to the consumer.

The team witnessed these operations in both small towns and in large metropolitan areas.

On the other hand, broilers from specialized households and from large modern

broiler operations are sold to state-owned or joint venture slaughter facilities. The fresh,

chilled, or frozen meat is sold in local food markets equipped with freezer bins, in food

stores, and in newly emerging supermarkets. Most of the frozen chicken parts the team

saw throughout China came from domestic slaughter houses. Crook and Harvey (1998)

found that frozen paws (feet) and wings from foreign countries were found mostly in

traditional local open markets (wet markets).

“As China moves from outdoor markets to supermarkets in the cities, the United

States is falling behind domestic producers. It would be best to build U.S. brand

recognition with small packages with Chinese labeling,” says Zhihong (Agricultural

Trade Office, Shanghai officer). “There are no small pre-packaged U.S. poultry products

48

available in the Chinese market, but this could possibly be done for certain chicken parts

through partnerships with well-connected Chinese firms.”

(http://www.meatingplace.com/articles/p1153.asp, 1998)

To help U.S. poultry exporters better develop China import markets, Ferris (2002)

pointed out that, Hong Kong consumers are a leading indicator of potential consumer

demand in China. With the similar ethnic makeup as its huge neighbor, Mainland China,

a healthy average disposable income ($24,000 in 2000), demanding tastes, and years of

exposure to western products, Hong Kong should be viewed as an incubator or

microcosm for long-term export projects in China and easy-entry, exporter-friendly

laboratory for the world’s most populous country.

3. Poultry Trade Issues

World trade in meats has grown rapidly since mid-1980s. The trade primarily

involves shipping cuts of meats and edible offal rather than carcasses or live animals.

Emerging patterns of trade are due only partially to relative advantages in countries’

production costs. Dyck and Nelson (2000) suggested that the disparities in preferences

among trading partners for particular meat cuts has also influenced trade patterns.

As the bulk of world poultry trade has moved from whole birds to parts,

producers have had to expand the scope of their marketing worldwide to find markets for

all the various parts of the bird. By taking into account differing income levels and the

specific consumer preferences of various regions, processors can target parts to specific

markets, and sometimes receive a better price than they could domestically. The key to

expansion for these countries will be to maintain their status as low-cost producers, while

49

simultaneously developing worldwide markets for the wide array of products that they

produce (USDA, 1998c).

Exports of broiler feet from the United States to China are a prime example. Q.

Wang et al. (1998) reported that Chinese consumers tend to discount those cuts most in

demand in the U.S. and to favor those cuts that are less desired in the U.S. and European

market.

The difference in preferences provides a marketing opportunity for U.S.

poultry meat exports. U.S. firms export wings, feet, other dark meat, and

offal to China and Hong Kong; legs to Japan; and dark meat and offal to

Mexico. These export markets pay more for such cuts than U.S.

consumers. In addition, low U.S. prices of chicken-leg quarters make them

affordable to Russian consumers, who also generally prefer dark meat.

The U.S. industry, with its ability to supply large amounts of most kinds of

meat, is likely to find new international markets where U.S. meat has a

cost advantage and /or where product preferences complement those of

U.S. consumers (Dyck and Nelson, 2000).

Dyck and Nelson (2000) reported that U.S. poultry meat and offal (hearts, livers,

feet, etc.) exports growth exceeded that of beef and pork exports since mid 1980s. They

explained that these meat trade flows are strongly influenced by factors other than costs

of supplying a market. The wide differences in U.S. and foreign consumer preferences for

broiler cuts and offal are a likely reason.

Vicente, Allen, and Reeves (1998) called this kind of trade flow “transaction

oriented.” Poultry exporters tend to offer in domestic markets products that reflect

50

national preferences. They are then challenged to find a destination where excess product

in the form of “rejected” product categories would be acceptable in order to complete the

transaction. This type of commercial operation tends to be “transaction oriented.” A

common practice is to sell surplus U.S. chicken parts in the foreign market to fulfill the

increased demand for breast meat in the U.S. market to a profitable level.

In the U.S. market, chicken breast meat is the most favorable chicken part, and the

price of chicken breast meat is also the highest among all the chicken parts. During

March to August 2002, the average price is $2.19/lb for chicken breast, $1.08/lb for

whole chicken, and $1.29 /lb for chicken legs. Price of chicken breast meat is more than

twice the price of whole chicken, and it is almost $1 higher than the price of chicken legs

(Poultry and Eggs/Online Briefing Room, USDA).

In China market, the price differences are reversed. Wang et al. (1998) states that

the internal organs typically sell at a price that is equal to or greater than muscle meat

prices in the same markets in China. Also, bone-in chicken feet are generally sold at

premium price as compared to chicken breast meat.

However, this strategy (risen from different chicken meat consumption

preferences) could be adopted in reverse by other producing countries. In

this case the processors would sell the cheaper cuts and parts on the

domestic market and more expensive cuts to higher income countries.

China has been adopting this strategy and been exporting de-boned meat

and other value-added products to the Japanese and Korean markets

(International Agricultural Baseline Projections to 2007/AER-767, 1998).

51

China’s livestock product trade has developed very slowly over the last 20

years. Currently, China exports only about 5 percent of its poultry meat

output and 1 percent of its pork and beef output. Export markets are very

localized, with most shipments going to China’s closet neighbors—Hong

Kong, Japan, and Russia. Poultry meat trade has grown rapidly over the

last 10 years. China poultry meat exports are primarily chicken thighs,

chicken breasts, and whole chickens, while imports are primarily wings,

feet and giblets (Tuan, Colby, and Cao, 2000).

As the world’s largest poultry meat exporter, the U.S. is interested in prospects

for its products in the Chinese market. According to Crook and Harvey (1998), Hong

Kong/China market is currently the second largest destination for U.S. exports of poultry

and egg products. Although China is expected to continue its broiler output, it will remain

a large market for poultry imports.

Wailes, Fang, and Tuan (1998) stated that:

Broiler imports have exceeded exports in Mainland China since 1990, and

for greater China (mainland China and Hong Kong), net imports have

increased six-fold since 1990. China’s share of U.S. farm exports, in

general, is small, but the upward trend is strong. One of the most

successful market developments for U.S. trade into China has been poultry

meat. The southern region of the U.S. has become an important supplier of

U.S. food and agricultural exports to China, especially poultry, soybeans,

wheat, and cotton. Therefore the growth experienced in these markets

52

should be, and is, reflected in the significance of export shipments from

the southern states.

Growth potential is based on China’s fundamental demand forces including the

world’s largest population, a high real-income growth rate, an emerging urban middle

class, and accession to the World Trade Organization. It’s believed that rapidly rising

consumer incomes and the increase in the number of hotels and joint-venture firms in

China’s more developed cities (such as Shanghai, Beijing, and Guangzhou) are the other

main sources of higher import demand for meat and value-added food (Wailes, Fang, and

Tuan, 1998).

However, the United States and its poultry export development agencies may

need to emphasize product differentiation promotions to try to regain some of the market

(including Chinese import market) shares captured by Brazil (Costa, 2001). The

preliminary data in his study suggests that Brazil increased market shares in the world

poultry market after the devaluation of the Brazilian Real, and the simulations suggest

that these increases in market shares may be even larger in the long run. He argued,

“Given the first year change in market shares and the longer term projections from

GTAP, major losses can result for the United States poultry export market and industry.”

4. Trade Policy Issues

“China is one of the world’s largest agricultural economies, and its accession to

the WTO and further integration into the world economy will lead to a wealthier and

more stable international food system. Under the terms of accession, China’s agricultural

trade regime will be more open and responsive to global markets. Farms in the U.S. are

53

particularly well positioned to benefit from China’s accession to the WTO because the

farming systems and underlying resource endowments in China and the U.S. complement

each other, providing opportunities for mutually beneficial trade” (Lohmar et al. 2002).

Constraints on U.S.-China agricultural trade include tariffs, food security policies,

and other non-tariff barriers (Wailes, Fang, and Tuan, 1998). The Chinese government

reduced the tariffs on pork and poultry meat imports from 45 percent to 20 percent in

1997. In addition to the import tariff, the government collects a 17 percent value-added

tax on all imported meat products, making the new effective tariff rate of 40.4 percent.

Despite these changes to diminish the barriers to meat imports, official trade in meat

products has not grown significantly after the tariff reduction. The industry perception in

the U.S. is that, even at the reduced tariff rates, it is still too costly to import meat

products through official channels. Unofficial transshipments and smuggling of pork

products into China through Hong Kong is estimated to be as much as seven times

greater than official imports. These “gray channels” are a viable, less expensive

alternative to direct imports (Wang et al. 1998).

Using a partial equilibrium model of China’s livestock and grain sectors, Wang et

al. (1998) examined the impact of a 100 percent reduction in the official tariff rate on

Chinese pork and poultry imports. The 17 percent value-added tax is assumed to remain

in place, making the effective tariff rate in the scenario 17 percent. The results for their

scenario analysis suggest that liberalization of China’s pork and poultry markets will

cause a relatively large change in world trade levels without causing any serious price

disruptions. The U.S. is in a good position to capture much of the benefits of such

liberalization because it already dominates world trade in unsubsidized poultry products.

54

So long as the trade increases generated by market liberalization are close to the levels

projected in this study, the price impact in U.S. and Chinese markets will be relatively

small, according to their estimated results.

Peterson and Orden (2002) constructed a perfectly competitive spatial partial

equilibrium model to evaluate some the policy effects on world poultry trade. The model

simulates the trade flows among six key exporting and importing countries (U.S., Brazil,

EU, Japan, China, and Russia.) and two aggregate rest-of-world regions (a rest-of-world

poultry exporting region, and a rest-of-world poultry importing region.). Effects of

removal of restrictions based on tariffs, tariff-rate quotas (TRQs) and sanitary regulations

are evaluated maintaining a distinction between “high-value” (mostly white meat: breast

meat and wings) and “low-value” (mostly dark meat: drumsticks and thighs of chicken

and turkey) poultry products. Because white and dark meats are produced in fixed

amounts per bird, they are treated as jointly produced goods in the model (Peterson and

Orden, 2002). Their results suggest that removal of sanitary barriers alone has relatively

little effect compared to removal of tariffs and TRQs, but has more effect if sanitary and

other barriers are removed simultaneously.

First, they removed all tariffs and TRQ’s but left any SPS (Sanitary and

Phytosantiary) barriers in place. This would substantially increase trade in poultry

products. The U.S. would experience about a ten times larger increase in low-value

exports (530,000 MT) compared to its increase in high-value exports (57,000 MT). The

removal of Chinese tariffs on low-value poultry would result in a 922,000 MT (103.6

percent) increase in low-value imports.

55

Second, they removed only the SPS barriers. “Because removing these trade

barriers alone does not really improve the potential for increased trade, there is little

change between the base case (with both tariffs, TRQ’s and SPS barriers.) and the results

for this scenario.”

Third, they removed all trade barriers, a true free trade scenario. This would lead

to substantial increases in high-value exports for both the U.S. and China (470,000 MT

and 310,000 MT, respectively), which displaces a greater amount of EU poultry

production than in the tariffs and TRQ’s removal case.

5. Hong Kong-Mainland China Transshipment Issues

One of the problems in understanding the potential of China’s market has been

the re-exportation and smuggling that has been significantly hidden in Hong Kong trade

data. Livestock trade is significantly affected by Hong Kong’s markets. Many products

are re-exported to China through Hong Kong, which is not reflected in China’s import

data reported by China’s customs statistics. High levels of net imports by Hong Kong in

livestock products are believed to be explained by re-exports into Mainland China

(Wailes, Fang, and Tuan, 1998).

The exact figures for transshipments through Hong Kong are not always

available, as some shipments are sent in ways to avoid China’s import duties. Because

Hong Kong re-exports large quantities to the rest of China, while also importing meat

from China, the markets are tightly linked. As the economic ties between Hong Kong and

China become even closer, it likely will become necessary to look at them as one market,

with Hong Kong as the chief port in southern China (Crook, and Harvey, 1998).

56

After China’s accession to the WTO, Hong Kong importers are seeking to

convince U.S. exporters to continue doing business through the existing channels; on the

other hand, potential partners in China could offer innovative pricing and distribution

plans that deserve serious consideration. Ferris (2002) stated, “Other than China’s

accession to WTO, there are many other factors that will also influence trade flows

among the United States, Hong Kong and China. One major consideration is ‘Financing

Considerations’. ”

Ferris (2002) concluded that Hong Kong will likely continue in its current

financial role for at least another five years, for several reasons:

• It remains difficult for private companies in China to obtain letters of credit.

• Although larger Chinese importers may be able to pay in U.S. dollars, the

majority cannot. Moreover, Chinese currency is not fully convertible outside

China.

• With Hong Kong companies, U.S. exporters are reasonably assured of getting

paid.

• Hong Kong has a Western-style legal system with the rule of law and enforceable

contracts.

As the world’s largest container port, Hong Kong can accommodate the very

largest ships. Its size and location will keep Hong Kong involved in Southern China’s

trade, regardless of import policy changes. Ferris (2002) forecasted that Hong Kong will

continue to offer significant advantages as a trade entrepot. He quoted some veteran

Hong Kong traders’ rough estimation: the share of China’s agricultural imports coming

through Hong Kong could drop from 60 percent to 30 percent. In years to come, more

57

U.S. shipments will go directly to China. However, China’s total import volume will

likely expand so much that Hong Kong’s absolute volume of re-exports to China would

remain near the current high levels for many years. “Although the trade patterns will

likely change markedly, the pace of change will be much slower than most expect, at

least 10 years” (Ferris, 2002).

6. China Data Problem

Gale (2002) reported:

Analysis of China’s economy is made more challenging by the uncertain

accuracy of the country’s official statistics. The politicization of statistics,

reliance on bottom-up administrative reporting, use of nonstandard

definitions, and parallel reporting systems in multiple agencies often make

Chinese statistics confusing and potentially misleading. Many analysts

believe that the macroeconomic statistics overstate economic growth and

understate unemployment.

Over the past decade, researchers at USDA’s Economic Research Service have

identified a number of analytical issues and anomalies associated with China’s animal

protein economy that make it difficult to assess the current situation as well as future

trends in either livestock inventories or feed grain demand. Most researchers agree that

some animals slaughtered have been double counted and that in some cases, local cadres

inflated output statistics to earn better performance evaluations (USDA, 1998d).

“Researchers in China and the U.S. have observed that per capita meat availability

as measured by government production and population statistics is roughly 50 percent

58

larger in 1996 than per capita meat consumption as measured by the State Statistical

Bureau (SSB) urban and rural household income and expenditure surveys. Scholars in

China have questioned this growing gap” (USDA, 1998d).

The data on poultry meat and egg production are less reliable than other livestock

data because such a large proportion of the birds are produced by individual farm

households, rather than in specialized operations (USDA, 1998d).

“Despite the uncertainties, however, there is no doubt that livestock product

markets in China are significant to world markets, and their importance is likely to

become much greater in the future” (USDA, 1998d).

59

CHAPTER 4

AN ECONOMETRIC MODEL OF U.S. CHICKEN EXPORTS

TO HONG KONG/CHINA

1. Theoretical Framework

1.1. General Trade Theory: Excess Supply and Excess Demand

The most important concepts in economics are market supply and demand. Excess

supply and excess demand are tools that simplify the analysis of international markets.

The difference between quantity supplied and quantity demanded at prices above the

autarky equilibrium price is called excess supply (ES). The difference between quantity

demanded and quantity supplied at prices below the autarky equilibrium price is called

excess demand (ED). Excess supply shows the quantity of a good a country wants to

export and excess demand shows the quantity of a good a country wants to import at

relevant prices. The interaction of international excess supply and excess demand

determines the quantity traded and the price of the traded good.

Figure 4.1 depicts an excess demand curve for good X for a country. The excess

demand curve for X is labeled Ex, which is much like a conventional demand curve,

except that the quantity demanded may be either positive or negative. A negative excess

demand is simply a desire to supply (export) the good to the world market at that price

ratio. At autarky price ratio Pa, there’s zero excess demand. Excess demand for X

becomes increasingly negative (exports of X becomes increasing positive) as the world

60

0

Pa

P*2

P*1

price ratio increases above Pa. Excess demand becomes increasingly positive (imports of

X become increasingly positive) as the world price ratio falls below Pa. (Markusen et al.

1995).

Figure 4.1. The Excess Demand for X

1.2. Excess Supply and Demand: One Product and Two Countries

Supply and demand curves can be used to show the gains from trade. Figure 4.2

shows trade between the U.S. and foreign countries, given the domestic demand and

supply curves in the U.S. and the rest of the world (ROW) taken as an aggregate entity.

The supply of U.S. exports is the amount by which domestic supply exceeds domestic

demand at all prices above the U.S. autarky price Pus, shown as the excess supply curve

ES in the middle panel of Figure 4.2. The demand for U.S. exports is the amount by

which foreign demand exceeds foreign supply at all prices below the ROW autarky price

Excess Demand

Price

Ex

61

Pr, shown as the excess demand curve ED. Export supply and demand intersect at an

equilibrium price Pe where qe is the quantity exported by the U.S. and imported by ROW.

The exports from the U.S. are qs – qd, the same quantity as qe, and foreign imports Qd –

Qs (Tweeten, 1992).

P

Q

P

Q

P

Q

The U.S. World Market HK/CH

S

D

ES

ED

S

D

0 0

VX

W Y

RPe

Pr

qd q qs Qs Q Qd

Figure 4.2. Supply and Demand Curves of One Product Between Two Trading Countries

Export markets raise the domestic price of the commodity in the U.S. to Pe from

the equilibrium price Pus in market isolation. The price Pe is lower than the market-

isolated price Pr in the foreign market. With trade, the gain in producer R + V+ X exceeds

the loss in consumer surplus R + V in the U.S. by the net social gain represented by the

triangle X in Figure 4.2. In the foreign market, the gain in consumer surplus W + Y

exceeds the loss in producer surplus w by the net social gain represented by the area Y.

Thus the public (made up of consumers and producers) in each trading area realizes a

positive net gain from trade (Tweeten, 1992).

62

1.3. Excess Supply and Demand: One Product and Three Countries

In the general discussion of trade theory with two countries and one product, it

was noted that the excess supply of a product is determined by product price and supply

and demand relationships in the exporting country, since HK/CH is only one of the

possible destinations for U.S. chicken part exports, we need to expand the two country

model to include two destination markets for U.S. chicken exports – Hong Kong/China

and the ROW. Figure 4.3 shows U.S. domestic demand and ROW excess demand in the

left panel. The U.S. excess supply of chicken to HK/CH is U.S. supply minus the sum of

U.S. domestic demand and ROW excess demand for U.S. chicken, as shown in the

middle panel of Figure 4.3.

In the left panel, U.S. domestic demand (DD) and ROW excess demand for U.S.

goods were aggregated horizontally to form a new demand curve, DDus + EDROW, which

is named total demand (TD). The kink on the TD curve implies that ROW will start

importing at prices lower than this point. In the right panel, HK/CH domestic supply (DS)

and ROW excess supply to HK/CH were aggregated to form a new supply curve named

total supply (TS). The kink on TS implies that ROW will start exporting to HK/CH at

prices higher than this point. Comparing Figure 4.3 with Figure 4.2, all the differences in

the middle panel are derived from the TD curve in the left panel and TS curve in the right

panel. Similar to the one good and two countries case, we derived the curve ED (HK/CH

excess demand for U.S. chicken parts) and ES (U.S. excess supply to HK/CH). Thus

HK/CH excess demand and supply not only depend on the supply, demand and prices in

U.S. and China markets, but are also related to the supply, demand and price in ROW.

63

P

Q

P

Q

P

QThe U.S. World Market HK/CH

S

DD

ES

ED

DS

D

TS

TD

qe0 0

Figure 4.3: Supply and Demand Curves of One Product Among Three Trading Countries

The following analysis will focus on two aspects of the market: the excess supply

of U.S. product to HK/CH, and the excess demand for U.S. frozen chicken parts in

HK/CH market. To analyze excess supply and demand, it is necessary to develop a model

incorporating the elements that could affect the supply/demand. The goal is to derive

supply and demand equations in which most of the relevant factors are included. Section

2 will present the development of the excess supply and demand equations.

2. Empirical Model

Four chicken products were analyzed in the empirical model. They are: frozen

chicken legs, frozen chicken wings, frozen chicken feet, and frozen chicken offal. As

indicated in Chapter 2, Hong Kong/China is the largest market for U.S. exports of these

chicken parts during the period 1997 - 2001. Hong Kong/China frozen chicken leg

64

quarter equations were not estimated in this analysis because Russia is the dominant

market for U.S. chicken leg quarters. U.S. leg quarter exports to Russia were over ten

times as great as those to Hong Kong/China during the period from 1997 – 2001.

However, before specifying factors affecting excess supply and demand in the relevant

countries, the joint product nature of the production of different chicken parts must be

considered.

2.1. Joint Production of Chicken Parts

As mentioned in Chapter 3, U.S. excess production of chicken parts may be

influenced by the domestic demand for chicken breast meat. According to the latest price

spread released from USDA, price per pound of chicken breast meat was more than twice

of the price of whole chicken during March to August 2002. Because chicken parts are

produced in fixed proportion per bird, more chicken feet, offal, legs, wings, etc. may be

produced than needed in the U.S. domestic market, and U.S. producers may have to find

foreign markets to clear these parts. In other words, some of the chicken parts would be

wasted if no other distribution channels were found. These low valued chicken parts

could be classified as “by-products” that are produced together with the “primary

product,” in this case, high priced chicken breast meat. We may call the market for by-

products the “residual market.”

The market for the highest valued primary products will have a greater influence

on production decisions than the residual markets for lower valued by-products. Hence,

the production of U.S. chicken parts is determined by production of whole birds which is

largely determined by domestic demand for chicken breast meat. Some markets for

65

residuals from primary chicken product have become well established over the years.

Before residual markets were developed, certain chicken parts (e.g. chicken feet, offal,

and so on) were wasted. They were sold as feedstuff, almost without any return to the

producers. Obviously, producers in the broiler industry have real interest in finding ways

to use as much of the chicken as possible. Hong Kong/China is by far the largest user of

these residual chicken parts. The estimation of the trade models that examine and test the

“by-product” and other hypotheses will be presented in Chapter 5.

2.2. General Form of Excess Supply and Excess Demand Functions

It is assumed that U.S. chicken meat is distributed to: the U.S., HK/CH, and

ROW. It is also assumed that chicken consumed in HK/CH is produced domestically,

imported from the U.S., or imported from ROW. Thus, the excess supply of frozen

chicken part j from U.S. to HK/CH, where j is one of the parts which is produced in fixed

proportion per bird, can be specified as a function of U.S. chickens produced and prices

of part j in alternate markets,

(4.1a) QsjUS-HK/CH, t = f(QUS, t, Pj

US, t, PjUS-HK/CH, t, Pj

US-ROW, t)

where

QsjUS-HK/CH, t = Quantity of U.S. frozen chicken part j exported to HK/CH in period t.

QUS, t = Number of chickens slaughtered in the U.S in period t.

PjUS, t = U.S. domestic price of chicken part j in period t.

PjUS-HK/CH, t = Value per unit of U.S. frozen chicken part j exported to HK/CH in period t.

66

PjUS-ROW, t = Value per unit of U.S. frozen chicken part j exported to ROW in period t.

The excess demand for U.S. frozen chicken part j in HK/CH is specified as a

function of own-price, HK/CH income, and prices of related goods (including part j from

other countries). Specifically,

(4.1b) QdjUS-HK/CH, t = f(Pj

US-HK/CH, t, PjHK/CH, t, Palt

HK/CH, t, IncomeHK/CH, t, PjROW-HK/CH, t )

where

QdjUS-HK/CH, t = Quantity of frozen chicken part j imported by HK/CH in period t.

PjUS-HK/CH, t = Price of U.S. frozen chicken part j imported by HK/CH in period t.

PjHK/CH, t = Price of chicken part j produced in Hong Kong/China in period t.

PaltHK/CH, t = Price of alternative meat product in Hong Kong/China market in period t.

IncomeHK/CH, t = Hong Kong/China income level in period t.

PjROW-HK/CH, t = Price of ROW frozen chicken part j imported by HK/CH in period t.

By definition, the excess supply of U.S. chicken part j exported to HK/CH in

period t equals the excess demand for HK/CH imports of U.S. chicken part j in period t.

QsjUS-HK/CH, t = Qdj

US-HK/CH , t = QjUS-HK/CH, t.

Usually, exchange rates are included in trade models. However, both the Hong

Kong dollar and the China RMB are pegged to the US dollar, and the exchange rates of

67

the Hong Kong dollar and China RMB to the U.S. dollar are almost fixed during the

study period. Because of the absence of variation in US to HK/CH exchange rates, these

exchange rates were not included in the model.

In this study, we have a set of ES and ED equations for each chicken part, and

there are four chicken parts of interest. In total, we have eight equations. The price and

quantity of chicken parts traded are to be determined jointly in the market. Therefore,

Pjus-HK/CH and Qj

us-HK/CH are the endogenous variables to be explained by the model.

The US chicken production, chicken prices in the U.S. and ROW, HK/CH

income, and prices of related goods in HK/CH, on the other hand, are exogenous

variables that affect the ES and ED of the chicken parts. In other words, the value of the

variables QUS, PUS, PjUS-ROW, IncomeHK/CH, Pj

HK/CH, PjROW-HK/CH, and Palt

HK/CH are assumed

to be completely determined outside the system under consideration.

3. Econometric Considerations

3.1. Simultaneous Equation System and Variables

A model is said to constitute a system of simultaneous equations if all the

relationships involved are needed for determining the value of at least one of the

endogenous variables included in the model. This implies that at least one of the

relationships includes more that one endogenous variable (Kmenta, 1986). In this study, a

simple model of the market for each chicken part involves an excess supply and an

excess demand equation. For instance, in the ES (4.1a) and ED (4.1b) equations for

chicken part j, QsjUS-HK/CH and Psj

US-HK/CH are endogenous variables. Note that both

68

equations are needed for determining the values of these two endogenous variables, so

that the system is one of the simultaneous equations.

The classification of variables as endogenous and exogenous is very important as

far as economic theory is concerned since a necessary condition for the completeness of

theory is that the number of endogenous variables is equal to the number of independent

equations in the system (Kmenta, 1986). In this study, there are two independent

equations, (4.1a) and (4.1b), and two endogenous variables, PjUS-HK/CH and Qj

US-HK/CH for

each chicken part, so that the system contains a total of eight independent equations and

eight endogenous variables. The system satisfies the necessary condition for the

completeness.

The definition of a simultaneous equation system can be given a rigorous

interpretation when an economic model has been specifically formulated as a set of well-

defined stochastic relationships, that is, when it has been turned into what is generally

called an econometric model. Typically, economic theory tells us which relations make

up the model, which variables are to be included in each of the relations, and what is the

sign of some of the partial derivatives. As a rule, economic theory has very little to say

about the functional form of the relations and the values of the parameters. In order to put

an economic model into the form of a testable proposition, it is necessary to specify the

functional form of the relations. The end result is an econometric model that is ready for

estimation or testing of hypotheses (Kmenta, 1986).

69

The econometric model representing these relations (4.1a) and (4.1b) can be

defined as:

(4.2a) ES: QjUS-HK/CH, t = a0 + a1Qj

US, t + a2PjUS-HK/CH, t + a3Pj

US, t + a4PjUS-ROW, t + ε1jt,

(4.2b) ED: PjUS-HK/CH, t = b0 + b1Qj

US-HK/CH, t + b2 PjHK/CH, t + b3 Palt

HK/CH, t

+ b4 incomeHK/CH, t + b5PjROW-HK/CH, t + ε2jt.

Where ED represents the inverse excess demand equation, a’s and b’s are

parameters, and ε’s are random disturbances. Each disturbance is characterized by the

assumptions of the classical normal linear regression model (Kmenta, 1986). The

assumptions on each disturbance εkt are:

εkt ~ i.i.d. (0, σkk), k=1, 2

E (εkt εks) = 0, t, s = 1, 2, … , T; t ≠ s.

Where σkk is the variance of εkt, and T is the number of observations.

Equations (4.2a) and (4.2b) are called the structural form of the model. They are

structural equations in the sense that they are derived from the economic theory and each

purports to describe a particular aspect of the economy.

In general, the structural form of the system of equations can be written in matrix

form (Kmenta, 1986) as:

(4.3) B yt + Γ xt = ut

70

where yt =

Gt

t

t

y

yy

M

2

1

, xt =

Kt

t

t

x

xx

M

2

1

, ut =

Gt

t

t

u

uu

M

2

1

,

B =

GGGG

G

G

βββ

ββββββ

L

MOMM

L

L

21

22221

11211

, and Γ =

KKKK

K

K

γγγ

γγγγγγ

L

MOMM

L

L

21

22221

11211

.

Where yt is a vector of endogenous variables, xt is a vector of exogenous

variables, ut is a vector of stochastic disturbances, and t = 1, 2, …, T. The βs and the γs

are known as the structural coefficients. There are G endogenous and K exogenous

variables in the system.

A matrix representation of all T observations is (Kmenta, 1986):

(4.4) Y B′ + X Γ′ = U,

where Y is a (T x G) matrix of observations on the G endogenous variables, X is a (T x

K) matrix of observations on the K exogenous variables, and U is a (T x G) matrix of the

values of the G disturbances.

With respect to the stochastic disturbances, we stipulate that each disturbance

satisfies the assumptions of the classical normal linear regression model, i.e.,

ugt ~ i.i.d. (0, σgg), g = 1, 2, …, G;

E (ugt ugs) = 0, t, s = 1, 2, … , T; t ≠ s.

71

However, we do not rule out the possibility that the disturbances are correlated across

equations, i.e. that

E (ugt uhs) = σgh, g, h = 1, 2, …, G;

The reduced form of the system is obtained by solving the structural form

equations for the values of the endogenous variables, that is, by expressing the Ys in

terms of the Xs and Us. Using matrix notation, we may write the reduce form as

(Kmenta, 1986):

(4.5) yt = П xt + vt,

where П =

GKGG

K

K

πππ

ππππππ

L

MOMM

L

L

21

22221

11211

, and vt =

Gt

t

t

v

vv

M

2

1

,

Where the πs represent the reduced form coefficients and the vs the reduced form

disturbances. In general, each reduced form disturbance is a linear function of all

structural disturbances.

The relationship between the structural form and the reduced form can be

described as (Kmenta, 1986):

(4.6) П = - B-1Γ, and

(4.7) vt = B-1ut.

72

In this study, the reduced form equations for each chicken part j showing

explicitly how the endogenous variables are jointly dependent on the exogenous variables

and the disturbances of the system can be expressed as:

(4.8a) QjUS-HK/CH, t = g1(Qj

US, t, PjUS, t, Pj

US-ROW, IncomeHK/CH, t, PjHK/CH, t, Pj

ROW-HK/CH, t,

PaltHK/CH, t) + ξ1t,

(4.8b) PjUS-HK/CH, t = g2(Qj

US, t, PjUS, t, Pj

US-ROW, t, IncomeHK/CH, t, PjHK/CH, t, Pj

ROW-HK/CH, t,

PaltHK/CH, t) + ξ2 t.

where ξ1t and ξ2t are the reduced form disturbances, which represent the linear

combination of all structural disturbances.

Because there are endogenous variables among the explanatory variables in

simultaneous equations, ordinary least squares (OLS) estimators of the structural

coefficients are not consistent, at least in general. However, the reduced from equations

are represented by the exogenous variables of the system, so that OLS estimators of the

reduced form coefficients are consistent. The question then is whether we can derive

estimates of the structural coefficients from the consistent estimates of the reduced form

coefficients. This problem is called the identification problem (Kmenta, 1986).

3.2. The Identification Problem

A necessary condition for identification of a given structural equation is that the

number of exogenous variables excluded from the given equation is at least as large as

the number of endogenous variables included in the equation less one This is called the

73

order condition for identifiability. Note that this is only a necessary and not a sufficient

condition for identification. The relation used in determining the identification status of

the equations (Kmenta, 1986) is:

(4.9) B П = - Γ.

To satisfy the sufficient condition for identification, another condition is needed, and it is

called the rank condition for identifiability (Kmenta, 1986). Specifically,

Rank (П∆**) = G∆ - 1,

where П∆** is a sub-matrix of П. The order and rank conditions enable us to set up the

following general rules for determining the identification status of a structural equation.

• If K** > G∆ - 1 and Rank (П∆**) = G∆ - 1, we have overidentification.

• If K** = G∆ - 1 and Rank (П∆**) = G∆ - 1, we have exact identification.

• If K** ≥ G∆ - 1 and Rank (П∆**) = G∆ - 1, the structural equation is

underidentified.

• If K** < G∆ - 1, the structural equation is underidentified.

Where

K** = number of exogenous variables excluded from the equation.

G∆ = number of endogenous variables that appear in the equation.

In this study, all the estimated ES and ED equations meet the order condition. Adding

that the rank condition is satisfied, the equations are overidentified (or exact identified).

74

3.3. Different Estimation Methods for System Equations

Economic models frequently involve a set of relationships designed to explain the

behavior of certain variables. In particular, when a relation is a part of a system, some

regressors are typically stochastic and correlated with the regression disturbance. In this

case, the OLS estimators of the regression coefficients are inconsistent and other methods

must be derived to provide consistent estimates (Kmenta, 1986). In estimating an

overidentified (or exactly identified) structural equation belonging to a general

interdependent system of equations, there are several methods leading to consistent

estimation that can be used. Probably the best-known single equation method is that of

two-stage least squares (2sls) (Kmenta, 1986).

The two-stage least squares estimator, although consistent, is in general not

asymptotically efficient. The reason for the lack of asymptotic efficiency is the disregard

of correlation of the disturbances across equations. An alternative explanation for the lack

of asymptotic efficiency is that single equation estimators do not take into account prior

restrictions on the other equations in the model. This parallels the situation in which a

regression equation belonging to a set of seemingly unrelated regressions (SUR) is

estimated by ordinary least squares method. If we do not take into account the correlation

between the disturbances of different structural equations, we are not using all the

available information about each equation and therefore, do not attain asymptotic

efficiency. This deficiency can be overcome, as in the case of seemingly unrelated

regressions, by estimating all equations of the system simultaneously. For this purpose,

we can use one of the so-called system methods, such as three-stage least squares (3sls)

75

estimation. Three-stage least squares is the simplest system method, which involves a

straightforward application of the Aitken generalized estimation (Aitken, 1934-35) to the

system of structural equations (Kmenta, 1986).

Regression of supply (or demand) functions for various commodities with

observations made over time is one of the typical cases where covariance represents links

between different equations. In this study, a system of ES and ED functions were

constructed for each chicken part. Suppose that we cannot rule out the possibility that the

regression disturbances in the eight different equations are mutually correlated. Its

variance-covariance matrix can be shown as:

E (εk εj) = σkj IT, k, j = 1, 2, … , 8; k ≠ j,

where IT is an identity matrix of order (T x T), σkj is the covariance of the disturbances of

the kth and jth equation, which is assumed to be constant over all observations. These

considerations led to a 3sls estimation method for system of equations in this study.

Generally, suppose the overidentified (or exact identified) structural equation is

the first equation of the system, such that

(4.10) y1 = Y1β1 + X1γ1 + u1, and Y1 = [y2, y3,…,yG∆],

where y1 is a (T x 1) vector of the endogenous variable whose coefficient in the first

equation is one, Y1 is a T x (G∆ - 1) matrix of the remaining endogenous variables in the

76

first equation, X1 is a (T x K*) matrix of the predetermined variables in the first equation,

and u1 is a (T x1) vector of the disturbances in this equation.

The two-stage least squares estimation process may be viewed as consisting of

two successive applications of the ordinary least squares method. In the first stage the

reduced form equations for y2, y3, … ,yG∆ are estimated, and the fitted values of these

variables are calculated. In the second stage, the least squares method is applied to (4.11)

where the fitted values of y2, y3, … ,yG∆ are used as explanatory variables (Kmenta,

1986).

(4.11) y1 = Y1(hat)β1 + X1γ1 + u1*

where Y1(hat) is the vector of fitted values of y2, y3, … ,yG∆.

In the case of three-stage least square (3sls) estimation, Aiken generalized

estimation is applied straightforwardly to the system of structural equations. The system

can be rewritten as

(4.12) y1 = Y1(hat) β1 + X1 γ1 + u1*

y2 = Y2(hat) β2 + X2 γ2 + u2*

yG = YG(hat) βG + XG γG + uG*

Where yg is a (T x 1) vector of the endogenous variable in the gth equation, which is to be

estimated by the model. Yg(hat) is a T x (Gg∆ - 1) matrix of the remaining endogenous

77

variables in the gth equation, Xg is a (T x Kg*) matrix of the predetermined variables in

the gth equation, and ug* is a (T x1) vector of the disturbances in the gth equation.

The underlying idea of this Aiken generalized estimation in (4.12) is to take into

account the correlation of the disturbances across equations by treating (4.12) as a set of

seemingly unrelated equations (Kmenta, 1986). Under the assumptions stated at the

beginning of this section, the three-stage least squares estimates of the structural

coefficients are consistent and asymptotically efficient. The exactly identified equations

add no information that is relevant for estimation of the overidentified equations of the

system (Kmenta, 1986).

It should be noted that the residuals from the estimated three-stage least squares

equations can be used to obtain new estimates of the variances and covariances of the

structural disturbances. These can then replace the previous estimates in the three-stage

least squares formula, thus leading to new estimates of the structural coefficients. The

process could be repeated until there is no change in the estimated structural coefficients.

The resulting estimates, know as iterative three-stage least squares (i3sls) estimates, have

the same asymptotic properties as the ordinary three-stage least squares estimates

(Kmenta, 1986).

In this study, we used three-stage least squares (3sls) estimation method for

parameter estimations based on the following reasons:

• Since price and quantity are jointly endogenous variables, both supply and

demand equations are necessary to adequately describe the observed values. A critical

assumption of OLS is that the regressors are uncorrelated with the residual. When current

endogenous variables appear as regressors in other equations (endogenous variables

78

depend on each other), this assumption is violated and the OLS parameter estimates are

biased and inconsistent. It is referred to as simultaneous equation bias. Neither the

demand nor supply equation can be estimated consistently by OLS.

• Regression of supply (or demand) functions for various commodities based on

time series observations is one of the typical cases where covariance represents links

between different equations, and an instrumental method such as 3sls or SUR is needed

to overcome the simultaneous equation bias.

4. Hypotheses

In this study, we want to find out:

• Does the quantity of U.S. chicken part j exports to HK/CH respond to its own

export price?

That is, do the U.S. poultry producers determine their chicken parts export

quantity based on the export price, or do they send these chicken excess parts to HK/CH

market just to get rid of these products because there is no domestic market for these

chicken parts?

• Does U.S. whole chicken production level positively affect the quantity of

U.S. chicken parts exported to HK/CH?

As previously stated, because these chicken parts are produced in fixed

proportions, we suspect that more chicken feet, offal, legs, wings, etc. may be produced

than needed in the U.S. domestic market. If the U.S. chicken parts export quantities do

respond positively to U.S. production, but not to their own export prices, it may suggest

that HK/CH is a residual market.

79

• Do U.S. exporters take into account of the prices of U.S. chicken part j in

alternative markets (e.g., prices in U.S. domestic and ROW markets) to

determine the quantity of U.S. chicken part j exported to HK/CH?

• Is the price of U.S. chicken part j exported to HK/CH negatively affected by

its own export quantity?

• Are the prices of U.S. chicken parts exported to HK/CH positively affected by

HK/CH income level?

• Are the prices of U.S. chicken parts exported to HK/CH impacted by the price

of alternative products, or HK/CH import prices from ROW?

80

CHAPTER 5

ESTIMATED MODELS, DATA, AND RESULTS

1. Estimated Models

The system model was estimated using several functional forms to examine the

robustness of the estimates, and four model specifications were estimated in this study.

Each of these specifications studied the excess supply and demand for all the four

chicken products: chicken feet, wings, legs and offal. These model specifications are

presented in sections 1.2 – 1.5. The estimates of structural parameters of each

specification were obtained by estimating these eight equations simultaneously, except

for specification 3, where parameters were estimated for each chicken part separately.

The empirical models estimated are different from the theoretical model (4.2a and 4.2b)

proposed in Chapter 4. Modifications of the theoretical model are discussed in the

following section.

1.1. Model Modifications

1.1.1. Uniqueness of the Market and Data Availability

In the ES equations for chicken feet and chicken offal, the U.S. price, Pjus, was not

included as an explanatory variable. There is no market in the U.S. for chicken feet and

offal consumption and therefore no domestic prices are reported for these chicken parts.

Furthermore, monthly data for, Pjus, U.S. domestic price of frozen legs and wings are

81

unavailable. Instead of omitting these variables, we used data representing U.S. chicken

leg (North East) prices, and chicken wing (North East) prices as proxies.

In the ED equations, the variable, PjHK/CH, price of chicken parts produced in

HK/CH was not included because the monthly data were not available. The Hong Kong

Composite Consumer Price Index for live poultry, PHK_live, was used as a proxy for

PaltHK/CH. This price information was only available for the Hong Kong market, but

commodity prices in Hong Kong and Mainland China markets are closely related.

The price of HK/CH imports from ROW (PjROW-HK/CH) should also be an

important factor that affects HK/CH demand for U.S. chicken, but these data were not

available. In order to account for the impact of HK/CH imports from non-U.S. sources on

the HK/CH demand for U.S. chicken, we included an alternative variable, QBrazil, which

is the quantity of Brazil chicken product exports to the whole world. We chose QBrazil

because Brazil is a major exporter to HK/CH, but monthly bilateral data on Brazil –

HK/CH trade were unavailable. Hong Kong/China income data, IncomeHK/CH, are also

unavailable, so Hong Kong GDP, GDPhk, was used as a proxy for HK/CH income.

1.1.2. Possible Data Problem

It was noticed that U.S.-HK/CH chicken export data changed dramatically since

January 2000. The most apparent changes are the quantity of “other” chicken parts was

only half of the volume before January 2000, and the quantity of chicken offal was ten

times as large as before. We suspect that the changes on the quantity of different chicken

parts exports were caused by the changes on the classification of chicken parts. Thus, we

added the dummy variable, d_y2, with the value 0 for the observations of year 1997-

82

1999, and 1 for the year 2000. Because the magnitude of the data problem was related to

the data of export quantity of “other” chicken part, an interaction term, D1, was defined

by multiplying QothersUS-HK/CH with the dummy variable d_y2. D1 was added to the ES and

ED equations as an adjustment term.

1.1.3. Other Model Modifications

In one of the alternative model specifications, the ES equations were defined

without prices as explanatory variables, because we suspect that the U.S. treats HK/CH as

a place to dispose of surplus chicken parts, and the quantity exported is not responsive to

prices.

Note that a variable representing Chinese chicken production should be in the ED

model, but it is omitted from the empirical specification. As discussed in Chapter 3, the

annual Chinese production data may not be reliable and monthly Chinese poultry

production data are also unavailable. Although China has steadily increased their

production, its per capita consumption level is still very low, and demand for U.S.

imports may be largely unaffected by Chinese production at recent production levels.

Also, the exported products from the U.S. do not compete directly with China’s domestic

supply due to Chinese consumption habits. More than 70 percent of U.S. chicken

products exported to China are chicken feet, offal, wingtips and gizzards, and Chinese

domestic producers cannot satisfy the demand for these chicken parts without imports.

Leaving out Chinese chicken production ia not expected to result in serious bias in the

estimates.

83

The variable, Qleg quarterUS-HK/CH (Qleg qrt

US-HK/CH), was added to the ED equations in

order to capture the influence of leg quarter imports on the demand for other chicken

parts. This variable was treated as an exogenous variable in estimation because the

quantity of chicken leg quarters shipped to HK/CH appears to be largely determined by

the quantity of U.S. leg quarter shipped to Russia. Russia dominates the market for U.S.

leg quarters. The amount of U.S. leg quarter shipments to HK/CH became significant

only for a brief period, largely associated with Russia’s economic difficulties and a steep

devaluation of the Ruble.

1.2. Model Specifications

Several different approaches were employed to specify the ES equations for

empirical estimation. Specifically, linear price, price ratio, and no price approaches were

examined in this study. Each of these approaches related to the specification of the price

variables used in the empirical implementation of the econometric models will be

discussed in the following sections.

1.2.1. Linear Price Approach (Specification 1)

In the linear price approach, the supply of exports is specified as a function of

U.S. chicken production, the HK/CH export price, U.S. price, ROW export price, and an

adjustment term, D1. The equation for the excess supply of U.S. frozen chicken part j

was specified as:

(5.1a) QjUS-HK/CH = a0 + a1 QUS + a2 Pj

US-HK/CH + a3 PjUS+ a4 Pj

US-ROW +a5 D1 + ε1jt.

84

Equation (5.1a) embodies the hypothesis that exports to HK/CH are posited to rise when

there’s an increase in the U.S. production. In addition, as the price of HK/CH exports

rises, exports to HK/CH become more profitable and, hence, exporters will supply more.

As the price in U.S. or the price of exports to ROW rise, exports to HK/CH become

relatively less profitable and, hence, exporters will supply less. We, therefore, expect a1

and a2 to be positive in the results, and a3 and a4 to be negative.

The Hong Kong/China inverse excess demand equation was specified as:

(5.1b) PjUS-HK/CH = b0 + b1 Qj

US-HK/CH+ b2 Qleg quarterUS-HK/CH + b3 PHK_live + b4 GDPHK

+ b5 QBrazil + b6 D1 + ε2jt,

where j = chicken feet, chicken wings, chicken leg, and chicken offal, and

ε1jt, ε2jt = disturbance terms.

The εts were assumed to satisfy the assumptions of the classical normal linear regression

model.

Equation (5.1b) embodies the hypothesis that as the quantity of HK/CH imports

rises, prices of the imports will become lower in order to clear the HK/CH market. In

addition, import prices are posited to rise, when there is an increase in the Hong Kong

GDP. We therefore expect b1 to be negative and b4 to be positive in the results. Since Qleg

quarterUS-HK/CH and QBrazil represent quantities of substitutes for frozen imported parts from

the U.S. We expect b2 and b5 to be negative. Since PHK_live represents the price of a

substitute for U.S. frozen chicken parts, we expect b3 to be positive. ES equations (5.1a)

85

and ED equations (5.1b) comprised the system model for specification 1. The

endogenous variables in ES and ED system models are: QjUS-HK/CH and Pj

US-HK/CH, and the

exogenous variables are: QUS, PjUS, Pj

US-ROW, Qleg quarterUS-HK/CH, PHK_live, GDPHK, QBrazil,

and D1.

1.2.2. Price Ratio Approach (Specifications 2 and 3)

The differences between the price ratio approach and the linear price approach lie

on the specification of the ES equations. In this approach, the relative prices instead of

the linear prices were used in model specification. Two versions of the price ratio

approach are examined in this study.

1.2.2.1.Specification 2

The supply of exports is specified as a function of U.S. chicken production, price

of U.S. exports to HK/CH, the relative prices of exports (i.e., the ratio of the U.S.

domestic price to the HK/CH export price, and the ratio of the ROW export price to the

HK/CH export price), and an adjustment term, D1. The equation for the excess supply of

U.S. frozen chicken part j was specified as:

(5.2a) QjUS-HK/CH = c0 + c1 QUS + c2 Pj

US-HK/CH + c3 PjUS/Pj

US-HK/CH+ c4 PjUS-ROW/Pj

US-HK/CH

+c5 D1 + ε3jt.

Equation (5.2a) postulates that as the price of HK/CH exports rises relative to domestic

price or ROW price, exports to HK/CH become more profitable and, hence, exporters

86

will supply more. In addition, exports are posited to rise, when there is an increase in the

U.S. production. We therefore expect the signs to be positive on c1 and c2, and negative

on c3 and c4.

The Hong Kong/China inverse excess demand equation was specified as:

(5.2b) PjUS-HK/CH= d0 + d1 Qj

US-HK/CH+ d2 Qleg quarterUS-HK/CH + d3 PHK_live + d4 GDPHK

+ d5 QBrazil + d6D1 + ε4jt.

The ED equation (5.2b) is the same as that in specification 1. Equations (5.2a) and

(5.2b) comprise the system model of specification 2. The setting of endogenous variables

and exogenous variables for specification 2 is the same as that in specification 1.

Note that the excess supply equations in specification 2 are nonlinear in variables.

These nonlinear variables are price ratios PUS/PjUS-HK/CH and Pj

US-ROW/PjUS-HK/CH. We need

a method that can estimate simultaneous models with nonlinear equation. Computing

parameter estimates for nonlinear equations requires an iterative process. Here we used

i3sls (iterated three-stage least squares) estimation method. Starting with an initial value

for the parameter values, nonlinear estimation method (e.g., i3sls) tries different

parameter values until the objective function of the estimation method is minimized. This

process does not always succeed (i.e., the nonlinear estimation does not always

converge).

In specification 2, each set of ES and ED equations for a chicken part was

estimated separately, to reduce the convergence problem. Initially, all 8 equations were

estimated simultaneously, but the i3sls estimation did not converge.

87

1.2.2.2.Specification 3

Specification 3 is similar to specification 2 in that they have the same appearance

of excess supply and demand equations, but the model of specification 3 is estimated in

another way. Although the price ratios PjUS / Pj

US-HKCH and PjUS-ROW / Pj

US-HKCH are still

involved in the ES equations, these price ratios were calculated before estimation and

were treated as predetermined. Thus, specification 3 is estimated by 3sls instead of i3sls.

This is the only difference between specifications 2 and 3.

The endogenous variables in this system model are: QjUS-HK/CH and Pj

US-HK/CH. The

exogenous variables are: QUS, PjUS, Pj

US-ROW, Qleg quarterUS-HK/CH, PHK_live, GDPHK, QBrazil,

and D1. We also take the price ratio PjUS/Pj

US-HKCH and PjUS-ROW/Pj

US-HKCH as

predetermined.

1.2.3. No Price Approach (Specification 4)

We wanted to investigate the notion that the U.S. treats HK/CH as a place to

dispose of surplus chicken parts. Thus the quantity exported would not be responsive to

prices. Therefore, we added one more specification which has no prices in the ES

equations. In the absence of PjUS-HKCH, Pj

US and PjUS-ROW in the ES equation, the supply of

exports is specified as a function of the U.S. chicken production and an adjustment term

of D1. The equation for the excess supply of U.S. frozen chicken part j was specified as:

(5.3a) QjUS-HK/CH = e0 + e1 QUS + e2 D1 + ε5t.

88

We assume HK/CH exports are to rise when there is an increase in the U.S. production.

Therefore, a positive e1 coefficient is expected. The excess demand for U.S. chicken part

j is specified in the same way as in specifications 1, 2, and 3. The endogenous variables

in this ES and ED system model are: QjUS-HK/CH and Pj

US-HK/CH. The exogenous variables

are: QUS, PjUS, Pj

US-ROW, Qleg quarterUS-HK/CH, PHK_live, GDPHK, QBrazil, and D1. The 3sls

estimation method was applied on this specification. The estimation results of these

model specifications are presented in section 4. A summary of the variables used in the

various specifications of the econometric model is presented in Table 5.1.

89

Table 5.1. Variable Definitions Variable Definition Qleg

US-HK/CH Quantity of the U.S. domestic exportsa of frozen chicken legs to Hong Kong/China. (In 1,000 MT)

QwingUS-HK/CH Quantity of the U.S. domestic exportsa of frozen chicken wings to

Hong Kong/China. (In 1,000 MT) Qfeet

US-HK/CH Quantity of the U.S. domestic exportsa of frozen chicken feet to Hong Kong/China. (In 1,000 MT)

QoffalUS-HK/CH Quantity of the U.S. domestic exportsa of frozen chicken offal to Hong

Kong/China. (In 1,000 MT) Qother

US-HK/CH Quantity of the U.S. domestic exportsa of other frozen chicken partsd to Hong Kong/China. (In 1,000 MT)

PlegUS-HK/CH Priceb of the U.S. domestic exportsa of frozen chicken legs to Hong

Kong/China. (U.S. dollar/Kg) Pwing

US-HK/CH Priceb of the U.S. domestic exportsa of frozen chicken wings to Hong Kong/China. (U.S. dollar/Kg)

PfeetUS-HK/CH Priceb of the U.S. domestic exportsa of frozen chicken feet to Hong

Kong/China. (U.S. dollar/Kg) Poffal

US-HK/CH Priceb of the U.S. domestic exportsa of frozen chicken offal to Hong Kong/China. (U.S. dollar/Kg)

PotherUS-HK/CH Priceb of the U.S. domestic exportsa of other frozen chicken partsd to

Hong Kong/China. (U.S. dollar/Kg) QUS Number of total chicken slaughtered in U.S. Plegus US chicken leg domestic (North East) price (cents/pound)

Pwingus US chicken wing domestic (North East) price (cents/pound)

Qleg qrt

US-HK/CH Quantity of the U.S. domestic exportsa of frozen chicken leg quarters to Hong Kong/China. (In 1,000 MT)

PHK_live Hong Kong live poultry Composite Consumer Price Index (Oct. 1999-Sep. 2000=100)

GDPHK Hong Kong Seasonal Gross Domestic Product (HK$ million) QBrazil Brazil chicken product exports to the whole world.

d_y2 Dummy variable, with the value equals to 1 for the year 2000, and

equals to 0 otherwise. D1 Interaction term of d_y2 and Qother

US-HK/CH.

Note: a. Domestic Exports: Exports of domestic merchandise include commodities which

are grown, produced, or manufactured in the United States, and commodities of foreign origin which have been changed in the United States, including U.S. Foreign Trade Zones, from the form in which they were imported, or which have been enhanced in value by further manufacture in the United States. (Source: ATPA 1999 Appendix B, Bureau of International Labor Affairs/US department of Labor)

90

b. Price: FASc domestic exports value / domestic exports quantity (Source: USITC web data)

c. FAS Export Value: FAS (Free Alongside Ship) value is the value of exports at the U.S. port, based on the transaction price, including inland freight, insurance, and other charges. The value excludes the cost of loading the merchandise aboard the carrier and also excludes any further costs.

d. Other frozen chicken parts: frozen chicken parts excluding chicken leg quarters, chicken legs, chicken wings, chicken feet, chicken offal. Exports commodity information was collected in terms of the commodity classifications in the Schedule B, Statistical Classification of Domestic and Foreign Commodities Exported from the United States. Schedule B is a U.S. Bureau of the Census publication and is based on the Harmonized Commodity Description and Coding System (Harmonized System). (Source: ATPA 1999 Appendix B, Bureau of International Labor Affairs/US department of Labor)

2. Data

The models in this study employed monthly data from January 1997 through

December 2000. Trade data for the empirical model were obtained from the United States

International Trade Commission. U.S. chicken meat production and U.S. domestic price

data are obtained from Poultry Yearbook, USDA. U.S. chicken parts price data are from

“Economic Time Series Page”, www.economagic.com. Hong Kong live chicken price

and Hong Kong GDP data are from Census & Statistics Department, Hong Kong SAR

Government. Brazil export data are obtained from the Brazilian Poultry Exporters

Association website: http://www.abef.com.br/.

As to the USITC data, its disclaimer (http://dataweb.usitc.gov/disclamer.html)

implies their data may not be accurate. We used d_y2 and QotherUS-HK/CH in the

econometric models to adjust the apparent USITC data problem for the year 2000. It was

also noticed that the last two observations (November and December 2000) of U.S.

chicken wings exported to ROW have apparent data recording errors. For example, in

91

December 2000, the value of chicken wings exported to 17 of the ROW countries were

exactly of the same value, $10.407 million. These two observations were deleted from

the data sample. Because of the similar data problem, we also deleted the first

observation of January 1997. Thus, the total observations in this study are 45. A 3-month

moving average smoothing method was applied to the original data to reduce some of the

abrupt monthly fluctuations in the data.

3. Results

3.1. Overview of Estimation Results

In general, the ED results were much more robust across specifications with more

significant coefficients of expected signs. ES results were more variable across

specifications with more insignificant coefficients or coefficients with unexpected signs

(Tables 5.2-5.5).

In the following discussion, we will focus primarily on those estimated parameters which

are significantly different from zero at the 10 percent level.

The excess supply estimation generally yielded significant coefficient estimates

for U.S. chicken production (QUS) with the expected positive signs, and with the strongest

relationships for chicken feet (Table 5.2) and chicken offal (Table 5.5). This implies that

U.S. production played an important role in determining the quantity of these chicken

parts supplied to Hong Kong/China, especially for the lower-valued products. The more

whole chicken the U.S. produces, the more chicken parts are exported to HK/CH.

Results for the inverse excess demand equations are generally consistent across

specifications. The estimation results indicate that import prices are responsive to the

92

import quantities, except for chicken offal (Table 5.5). The coefficients of HK/CH import

quantity are all negative and significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level

(except for chicken offal), revealing that lower import prices are associated with higher

quantities of U.S. exports. HK/CH prices of these four chicken parts imports are

negatively related to the quantity of HK/CH chicken leg quarter imports (Tables 5.2-5.5),

which is determined by Russia’s leg quarter imports from the U.S. This suggests that leg

quarter imports diverted from Russia significantly influenced HK/CH chicken parts

import prices.

The Hong Kong GDP coefficient estimates are positive and mostly significantly

different from zero at 5 percent level, except for chicken offal. The result suggests that

HK/CH consumers demand more U.S. chicken parts as their income increases. The

coefficients for Hong Kong consumer price index for live poultry are mostly negative and

significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level for chicken feet (Table 5.2) and

wings (Table 5.3). These results do not seem to support the contention that chicken feet

and wings are substitute products for live poultry in Hong Kong.

Overall, the results suggest that the changes in the exports of U.S. frozen chicken

parts to HK/CH are attributable to changes in U.S. chicken production. Furthermore,

prices of these exports are negatively impacted by the quantity exported and the diversion

of leg quarters from Russia to HK/CH, and positively impacted by income increases in

Hong Kong.

93

Table 5.2. Estimation Results for U.S. Chicken Feet Exports to HK/CH

Variable Linear Prices Relative Pricesa (i3sls)

Relative Pricesa (3sls) b No Prices

Excess Supply: QfeetUS-HK/CH

Constant -1.174 (11.249)

-25.061* (13.859)

-7.937 (11.762)

-26.029** (10.290)

QUS 31.414** (15.569)

54.538** (18.180)

35.414** (15.940)

55.942** (15.267)

PfeetUS-HK/CH -16.993**

(3.781) -0.583 (5.925)

-11.140** (3.791) ---

PfeetUS ---

--- --- ---

PfeetROW 1.390*

(0.711) 0.221

(0.816) 0.997** (0.423) ---

D1 0.354** (0.090)

0.341** (0.098)

0.377** (0.090)

0.338** (0.092)

Adj-R2 0.604 --- 0.600 0.598 Excess Demand: Pfeet

US-HK/CH

Constant 0.798** (0.205)

0.680** (0.247)

0.783** (0.210)

0.695* (0.250)

QfeetUS-HK/CH -0.020**

(0.003) -0.018** (0.006)

-0.020** (0.003)

-0.017** (0.006)

Qleg qrtUS-HK/CH -0.007**

(0.002) -0.007** (0.002)

-0.007** (0.002)

-0.007** (0.002)

PHK_live -0.004** (0.001)

-0.004** (0.001)

-0.004** (0.001)

-0.004** (0.001)

GDPHK 1.537** (0.428)

1.954** (0.567)

1.634** (0.442)

1.792** (0.600)

QBrazil -0.001 (0.000)

-0.001 (0.001)

-0.001 (0.000)

-0.001 (0.001)

D1 0.007** (0.002)

0.007** (0.003)

0.007** (0.002)

0.005 (0.003)

Adj-R2 0.808 --- 0.807 0.784 a PUS and PROW represent US and ROW price relative to US-HKCH own-price, respectively. b Price ratios calculated before estimation, linear estimation used. c R2 s were calculated at the 2sls stage. *significant at the 10 percent level, ** significant at the 5 percent level. Numbers in parentheses are standard errors of the estimated parameters.

94

Table 5.3. Estimation Results for U.S. Chicken Wing Exports to HK/CH

Variable Linear Prices Relative Pricesa (i3sls)

Relative Pricesa (3sls) b No Prices

Excess Supply: QwingUS-HK/CH

Constant -0.907 (8.219) N/A1 -4.066

(9.778) -0.264 (6.156)

QUS 7.854 (10.205) N/A1 11.452

(10.729) 7.479

(9.133)

PwingUS-HK/CH -0.295

(2.265) N/A1 0.193 (3.219) ---

PwingUS -0.002

(0.029) N/A1 0.010 (0.020) ---

PwingROW 0.372

(1.065) N/A1 -0.003 (0.735) ---

D1 0.156** (0.057) N/A1 0.144**

(0.057) 0.145** (0.055)

Adj-R2 c 0.289 --- 0.291 0.241 Excess Demand: Pwing

US-HK/CH

Constant 1.353** (0.429) N/A1 1.343**

(0.444) 0.896

(0.607)

QwingUS-HK/CH -0.068**

(0.013) N/A1 -0.074** (0.012)

-0.092* (0.046)

Qleg qrtUS-HK/CH 0.023**

(0.003) N/A1 -0.024** (0.003)

-0.021** (0.004)

PHK_live -0.006** (0.002) N/A1 -0.006**

(0.002) -0.005 (0.003)

GDPHK 1.858** (0.865) N/A1 1.869**

(0.907) 3.065** (1.316)

QBrazil -0.002** (0.001) N/A1 -0.001

(0.001) -0.001 (0.002)

D1 0.018** (0.005) N/A1 0.017**

(0.005) 0.018** (0.007)

Adj-R2 c 0.650 --- 0.650 0.621 a PUS and PROW represent US and ROW price relative to US-HKCH own-price, respectively. b Price ratios calculated before estimation, linear estimation used. c R2 s were calculated at the 2sls stage. *significant at the 10 percent level, ** significant at the 5 percent level. Numbers in parentheses are standard errors of the estimated parameters. 1: Estimation didn’t converge.

95

Table 5.4. Estimation Results for U.S. Chicken Leg Exports to HK/CH

Variable Linear Prices Relative Pricesa (i3sls)

Relative Pricesa (3sls) b No Prices

Excess Supply: QlegUS-HK/CH

Constant 0.817 (4.034) N/A1 -4.945

(4.873) -11.229**

(5.494)

QUS 9.493 (5.659) N/A1 11.433*

(6.296) 23.363** (8.151)

PlegUS-HK/CH -9.857**

(1.313) N/A1 -3.060** (1.046) ---

PlegUS 0.054**

(0.023) N/A1 0.035** (0.014) ---

PlegROW 2.513**

(0.626) N/A1 1.613** (0.462) ---

D1 0.082* (0.042) N/A1 0.086*

(0.043) 0.059

(0.049) Adj-R2 c 0.450 --- 0.430 0.307

Excess Demand: PletUS-HK/CH

Constant 0.470 (0.404) N/A1 0.610

(0.444) 0.205

(0.851)

QlegUS-HK/CH -0.099**

(0.014) N/A1 -0.096** (0.013)

-0.092** (0.032)

Qleg qrtUS-HK/CH -0.012**

(0.003) N/A1 -0.014** (0.004)

-0.012* (0.007)

PHK_live -0.002 (0.002) N/A1 -0.002

(0.002) -0.001 (0.003)

GDPHK 2.854** (0.872) N/A1 2.529**

(0.974) 3.321

(1.987)

QBrazil 0.000

(0.001) N/A1 0.001 (0.001)

0.002 (0.002)

D1 0.003 (0.005) N/A1 0.002

(0.005) -0.004 (0.007)

Adj-R2 c 0.626 --- 0.632 0.603 a PUS and PROW represent US and ROW price relative to US-HKCH own-price, respectively. b Price ratios calculated before estimation, linear estimation used. c R2 s were calculated at the 2sls stage. *significant at the 10 percent level, ** significant at the 5 percent level. Numbers in parentheses are standard errors of the estimated parameters. 1: Estimation didn’t converge.

96

Table 5.5. Estimation Results for U.S. Chicken Offal Exports to HK/CH

Variable Linear Prices Relative Pricesa (i3sls)

Relative Pricesa (3sls) b No Prices

Excess Supply: QoffalUS-HK/CH

Constant -24.212** (10.431)

-28.512** (11.786)

-28.358** (9.592)

-34.166** (9.297)

QUS 32.826** (14.572)

40.032** (15.649)

32.227** (13.607)

52.300** (13.793)

PoffalUS-HK/CH -1.138

(2.388) 0.566

(3.302) 4.262* (2.487) ---

PoffalUS ---

--- --- ---

PoffalROW 8.866**

(1.927) 3.635** (1.336)

7.242* (1.365) ---

D1 0.749** (0.088)

0.758** (0.098)

0.656** (0.088)

0.913** (0.083)

Adj-R2 c 0.891 --- 0.901 0.868 Excess Demand: Poffal

US-HK/CH

Constant 1.720** (0.640)

2.015** (0.729)

2.122** (0.587)

2.019** (0.883)

QoffalUS-HK/CH 0.015

(0.012) -0.004 (0.023)

0.002 (0.011)

-0.026 (0.033)

Qleg qrtUS-HK/CH -0.028**

(0.004) -0.025** (0.004)

-0.028** (0.004)

-0.022** (0.004)

PHK_live 0.001

(0.003) -0.001 (0.004)

-0.002 (0.003)

-0.002 (0.004)

GDPHK -2.319* (1.304)

-2.776* (1.513)

-2.943** (1.200)

-2.845 (1.823)

QBrazil -0.003 (0.002)

-0.003 (0.003)

-0.002 (0.002)

-0.000 (0.004)

D1 -0.011 (0.008)

0.006 (0.012)

-0.006 (0.008)

0.016 (0.017)

Adj-R2 c 0.654 --- 0.663 0.482 a PUS and PROW represent US and ROW price relative to US-HKCH own-price, respectively. b Price ratios calculated before estimation, linear estimation used. c R2 s were calculated at the 2sls stage. *significant at the 10 percent level, ** significant at the 5 percent level. Numbers in parentheses are standard errors of the estimated parameters.

97

3.2. Comparison of Results from Different Specifications

On theoretical grounds, the first three specifications are less restrictive in that they

include prices or relative prices in the models. In specification 1, linear prices were

included in ES equations. In specifications 2 and 3, price ratios were incorporated in ES

equations.

In terms of goodness-of-fit, the specifications which include prices in ES

equations seem to perform better, as the system weighted R2s for specifications 1 and 3

are higher than that for specification 4, which has no prices in its ES equations. By

comparing the adjusted R2s which were calculated for each ES and ED equation from the

intermediate stage, 2sls estimation, we note that the values of adjusted R2s in

specification 4 were relatively close to those calculated for specifications 1 and 3 in many

cases.

As far as the estimation results are concerned, the three specifications with prices

in the ES equations generated more coefficient estimates with unexpected signs. For

instance, specification 1 contains the price of HK/CH exports, U.S. domestic price and

ROW price (PjUS-HK/CH, Pj

US, and PjROW) in its ES equations. We expected the coefficient

estimates for PjUS-HK/CH to be positive, and those for Pj

US, and PjROW to be negative.

However, the estimation results often did not give significant estimates with expected

signs for the coefficients including price and relative prices. On the other hand,

specification 4 is more parsimonious and it generated fewer inconsistent or unexpected

coefficient estimates.

98

3.3. Results for Different Chicken Parts

Results vary for different chicken parts, and these differences may provide

insights into Hong Kong/China chicken imports. As pointed out in the previous section,

the performance of QUS (U.S. whole chicken production) is in accordance with the

theory, with the coefficient estimates all being positive for every chicken part. For

chicken feet (Table 5.2) and chicken offal (Table 5.5), the estimates of QUS are positive

and significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level across all four specifications.

This strongly suggests that U.S. chicken feet and offal exports are significantly

influenced by U.S. whole chicken production. Although QUS coefficient estimates for

chicken wings (Table 5.3) and legs (Table 5.4) are all positive, they didn’t show as strong

positive relationships as those for chicken feet and offal. None of the coefficient

estimates for QUS for chicken wing are significantly different from zero at the 10 percent

level. For chicken legs, QUS coefficient estimates were positive and significantly different

from zero at 10 percent level only for specifications 3 and 4.

We did not find the expected positive relationships between export quantity (QjUS-

HK/CH) and export price (PjUS-HK/CH) in excess supply equations, except for chicken offal

(Table 5.5), which has a positive sign in specification 3 at the10 percent significance

level. On the contrary, the coefficient estimate of PjUS-HK/CH was found negative for

chicken feet (Table 5.2) and chicken legs (Table 5.4), with estimates significantly

different from zero at the 5 percent level across specifications. The coefficient estimates

of export price for chicken wings (Table 5.3) were not significant at 10 percent level.

These unexpected results indicate that U.S.-HK/CH parts prices did not positively affect

the volume of exports. Our estimates indicate either the absence of a significant impact of

99

own-price on U.S. supply, or a negative impact, depending on the part and the

specification. No theoretical rational for the estimated negative relationship between

own-price and quantity in the ES equations for feet and legs is obvious. There was a

strong negative correlation between price and quantity of U.S. chicken exports to HK/CH

during the data period, and the estimated equations generally did not isolate a positive

own-price supply response embedded in that relationship.

The U.S. parts price was only available for wings and legs, and was hypothesized

to have a negative impact on ES to HK/CH. The only significant coefficients for Pus

were for specifications 1 and 3 for the legs equation, and the sign of these coefficients

were different from what was expected (Table 5.4). The estimates of PjROW were

significant and positive for chicken offal (Table 5.5), legs (Table 5.4) and feet (Table 5.2)

in contrary to our expectations. In this study, PjROW was assumed to be exogenous, and to

affect the U.S. export quantity to HK/CH. However, this strong positive relationship may

be explained by the dominance of HK/CH in the export market for these chicken parts

(especially for chicken offal and feet). A higher ROW price may be caused by increasing

the supply to the HK/CH market. The fact is in the year 2000 nearly all the U.S. frozen

chicken feet exports, about 73 percent of U.S. frozen chicken offal exports and about half

of U.S. frozen chicken legs went to the HK/CH market. As more exports go to HK/CH

market, less supplies will be sent to ROW, thus the prices in ROW markets will be forced

to be higher.

Turning to the ED results, the estimates of excess demand relationship yield

useful information. If we exclude chicken offal, the overall coefficient estimates for

import quantity (QjUS-HK/CH) are negative. This suggests that as more U.S. chicken feet,

100

wings, and legs are imported to HK/CH, the prices of these imports are likely to decrease.

For chicken offal (Table 5.5), two of the coefficient estimates of QjUS-HK/CH were positive

and the other two were negative, and none of these estimates were significantly different

from zero at 10 percent level, implying that chicken offal price is not affected by quantity

exported to HK/CH, and increasing quantity of chicken offal imports will not

significantly affect the price of the imports.

The coefficient estimates for HK/CH leg quarter imports are uniformly significant

and negative across chicken parts and specifications. The negative relationship between

prices of HK/CH chicken feet, wings, legs, and offal imports and the quantity of HK/CH

leg quarter imports implies that the more chicken leg quarters are imported to HK/CH,

the lower the price these chicken parts will be in the HK/CH market. However, the

HK/CH imports of U.S. leg quarters are determined by Russia’s imports of U.S. leg

quarters, because Russia is the dominant market for U.S. leg quarters. Thus, the prices of

these four chicken parts in HK/CH market are, in turn, affected by Russia’s imports of

leg quarters. As stated in Chapter 2, due to Russia’s economic crisis, Hong Kong

imported significantly more chicken leg quarters in 1999, and prices in HK/CH dropped

dramatically. When the Russia market for U.S. poultry products was open again in 2001,

the U.S. supplies to HK/CH were relatively less and average C.I.F. prices were higher

than several years ago when U.S. supplies did not have access to Russian market.

The estimated coefficients of Hong Kong GDP (GDPHK) are positive and

significantly different from zero at 5 percent level for all chicken parts, except for

chicken offal. This implies that chicken feet, wing and leg demand is positively and

significantly affected by GDPHK. For chicken offal (Table 5.5), the coefficient estimates

101

for GDPHK carry negative signs from all 4 specifications, with 3 out of the 4 estimates

being significantly different from zero at 10 percent level. When people’s income

increases, consumer will buy more chicken feet, wings, and legs; however, chicken offal

consumption will decrease. This suggests that chicken offal is an inferior product in

HK/CH.

The coefficient estimates of Hong Kong live poultry price (PHK_live) appeared with

significant negative signs only for some specifications of chicken feet (Table 5.2) and

wings (Table 5.3). This result suggests live HK/CH poultry may not be a substitute

product for frozen U.S. chicken parts.

Negative and significant relationship between HK/CH import chicken part prices

and Brazil exports was only found in the case of chicken wings (Table 5.3). The

estimates of coefficient for the variable QBrazil were negative but insignificant for chicken

feet (Table 5.2) and offal (Table 5.5), and positive and insignificant for chicken legs

(Table 5.4). This implies that when Brazil increases its worldwide chicken exports, the

price of U.S. chicken wing exports to HK/CH is most likely to decrease. As stated in

Chapter 2, Brazil is a major supplier of chicken wings, and a major competitor of U.S.

chicken wings exports.

As expected, the adjustment term, D1, did show its importance in explaining the

changes in the dependent variables, because most of the equations yielded significant

estimates for the variable, D1 at the 5 percent level, especially in the ES equations. Note

that the estimates of D1 in the ES equations were significantly different from zero at the 5

percent level for chicken feet (Table 5.2), wings (Table 5.3), and offal (Table 5.5) across

specifications, and significant at the 10 percent level for chicken legs (Table 5.4). The

102

estimated coefficients for D1 in ED equations were relatively less significantly different

from 0. The significance shown in ES equations suggests that the substantial decreases in

“other” chicken exports in 2000 were accompanied by significant increases in the

specified parts exports. This may be due to changes in export reporting or classification

in 2000. The lower price response to D1 in ED equations suggests that the export prices

were less affected by the shift in 2000.

Finally, the excess supply estimation results for chicken wings are rather poor,

compared with the ES results for the other three chicken parts. As shown in Table 5.3,

none of the estimates for the explanatory variables in the ES equation are significant at

the 10 percent level, except for the adjustment term D1. This suggests that there are some

important factors affecting U.S. frozen chicken wings exports to HK/CH that were not

included in the ES model. For example, the U.S. not only exports frozen chicken wings,

they also export fresh/chilled chicken wings, and the biggest export market for

fresh/chilled chicken wings is Canada. Canada is the second largest import market for

U.S. frozen chicken wings, trailing only Hong Kong. As can be seen in Figure 2.6 in

Chapter 2, Canada imported considerable amounts of fresh/chilled chicken cuts, and

among them, chicken wings are one of the biggest chicken cuts category. Because we do

not have the monthly data of U.S. fresh/chilled chicken wings exports to Canada, we may

miss some information which is important to explain the quantity of U.S. frozen chicken

wings exported to HK/CH.

103

3.4. Elasticity Estimates

Generally, elasticity (Ej) is calculated by the formula:

)/)(/( YXXYE j ∂∂= ,

where Y is the dependent variable, and X is the independent variable. Elasticities are

commonly calculated at the point of the overall mean of the variables X and Y, and that is

the approach followed here. One elasticity was calculated from the supply equation – the

elasticity of export quantity (QjUS-HK/CH) with respect to U.S. whole chicken production

(QUS). From the excess demand equation, we calculated the elasticities of export price

(PjUS-HK/CH) with respect to own quantity (Qj

US-HK/CH), HK/CH chicken leg quarter imports

(Qleg quarterUS-HK/CH), and Hong Kong GDP (GDPHK). The estimated elasticities for each

chicken part and specification presented in Tables 5.6 - 5.9. Note that the elasticities were

not reported in cases where the coefficient is not significantly different from zero at the10

percent level.

104

Table 5.6. Estimated Elasticities for Chicken Feet Excess Supply and Demand

Elasticity Linear Prices Relative Pricesa (i3sls)

Relative Pricesa (3sls) b No Prices

Excess Supply: QfeetUS-HKCH

QUS 1.680 2.891 1.877 2.965 Excess Demand: Pfeet

US-HKCH Qfeet

US-HK/CH -0.497 -0.448 -0.497 -0.423 Qleg qtr

US-HK/CH -0.073 -0.073 -0.073 -0.073 GDPHK 0.952 1.210 1.011 1.109

a PUS and PROW represent US and ROW price relative to US-HKCH own-price, respectively. b Price ratios calculated before estimation, linear estimation used. 1: Coefficient estimation didn’t converge. 2: Coefficient estimate is not significant at the 10 percent level. Table 5.7. Estimated Elasticities for Chicken Wings Excess Supply and Demand

Elasticity Linear Prices Relative Pricesa (i3sls)

Relative Pricesa (3sls) b No Prices

Excess Supply: QwingUS-HKCH

QUS N/A2 N/A1 N/A2 N/A2 Excess Demand: Pwing

US-HKCH Qwing

US-HK/CH -0.456 N/A1 -0.496 -0.616 Qleg qtr

US-HK/CH 0.159 N/A1 -0.166 -0.146 GDPHK 0.770 N/A1 0.774 1.269

a PUS and PROW represent US and ROW price relative to US-HKCH own-price, respectively. b Price ratios calculated before estimation, linear estimation used. 1: Coefficient estimation didn’t converge. 2: Coefficient estimate is not significant at the 10 percent level.

105

Table 5.8. Estimated Elasticities for Chicken Legs Excess Supply and Demand

Elasticity Linear Prices Relative Pricesa (i3sls)

Relative Pricesa (3sls) b No Prices

Excess Supply: QlegUS-HKCH

QUS N/A2 N/A1 1.629 3.318 Excess Demand: Pleg

US-HKCH Qleg

US-HK/CH -0.665 N/A1 -0.645 -0.618 Qleg qtr

US-HK/CH -0.090 N/A1 -0.104 -0.090 GDPHK 1.272 N/A1 1.128 N/A2

a PUS and PROW represent US and ROW price relative to US-HKCH own-price, respectively. b Price ratios calculated before estimation, linear estimation used. 1: Coefficient estimation didn’t converge. 2: Coefficient estimate is not significant at the 10 percent level. Table 5.9. Estimated Elasticities for Chicken Offal Excess Supply and Demand

Elasticity Linear Prices Relative Pricesa (i3sls)

Relative Pricesa (3sls) b No Prices

Excess Supply: QoffalUS-HKCH

QUS 6.620 8.086 6.510 10.565 Excess Demand: Poffal

US-HKCH Qoffal

US-HK/CH N/A2 N/A2 N/A2 N/A2 Qleg qtr

US-HK/CH -0.202 -0.181 -0.202 -0.159 GDPHK -1.002 -1.199 -1.271 N/A2

a PUS and PROW represent US and ROW price relative to US-HKCH own-price, respectively. b Price ratios calculated before estimation, linear estimation used. 1: Coefficient estimation didn’t converge. 2: Coefficient estimate is not significant at the 10 percent level.

As to the excess supply elasticity, the calculated elasticities of U.S. chicken part

export quantity (QjUS-HKCH) to US production (QUS) showed some slight variations. The

calculated elasticities for chicken feet vary from 1.680 in specification 1 to 2.965 in

specification 4 (Table 5.6). The calculated elasticity for chicken offal vary from 6.510 in

106

specification 3 to 10.565 in specification 4 (Table 5.9), and those for chicken legs are

1.629 in specification 3 and 3.318 in specification 4 (Table 5.8).

Overall, the calculated excess demand elasticities are consistent across

specifications.

The percentage change of price (PjUS-HKCH) with respect to its own quantity (Qj

US-

HKCH) in the ED equations is called “price flexibility coefficient.” The price flexibility

coefficients were only calculated for chicken feet, legs, and wings, because coefficient

estimates for QoffalUS-HKCH were not significantly different from zero at the 10 percent

level. The magnitude of all the calculated price flexibilities were less than 1, with the

price flexibility ranging from -0.423 to -0.497 for chicken feet (Table 5.6), -0.456 to -

0.616 for chicken wings (Table 5.7), and -0.618 to -0.665 or chicken legs (Table 5.8).

This suggests that the parts prices were not very responsive to own quantity changes.

Chicken feet imports have the lowest price flexibility and chicken leg imports have the

highest price flexibility.

The calculated price flexibility of chicken part import price to HK/CH chicken leg

quarter imports (Qleg qrtUS-HK/CH) carried negative signs for all the four chicken parts, and

are all less than unity. The calculated flexibilities are -0.073 for chicken feet (Table 5.6),

from -0.146 to 0.159 for chicken wings (Table 5.7), from -0.09 to -0.104 for chicken legs

(Table 5.8), and from -0.186 to –0.202 for chicken offal (Table 5.9). With the absolute

value for chicken offal being the highest. This suggests that chicken offal was more

affected by the changes of leg quarter import quantity than other chicken parts.

Except for chicken offal, the estimated flexibilities of import price with respect to

Hong Kong GDP are all positive. The estimated price flexibilities vary from 0.952 to

107

1.210 for chicken feet (Table 5.6), from 0.770 to 1.269 for chicken wings (Table 5.7), and

from 1.128 to 1.272 for chicken legs (Table 5.8). With the values around unity, it implies

that prices were somewhat responsive to changes in GDP growth. In general, the price

responsiveness is more flexible for chicken leg than those for chicken feet and wings.

Negative price flexibilities to Hong Kong GDP were found for chicken offal (Table 5.9),

and the magnitudes are greater than unity. It suggests that a 1 percent increase in Hong

Kong GDP level would decrease the chicken offal price by more than 1 percent.

Unfortunately there are almost no estimates of price responsiveness available in the

literature with which to compare the estimates given in Tables 5.6-5.9. However, if the

inverses of the own-quantity price flexibilities are interpreted as estimates of own-price

demand elasticities, the calculated values for all parts except offal are slightly more

elastic than the elasticity for China poultry demand (-1.336) reported by Wang et al.

(1998).

3.5. Model Estimation Statistics

3.5.1. System-weighted MSE, and system-weighted R2 statistics,

System-weighted mean square error (MSE) and system-weighted R2 statistics

measure the fit of the joint model obtained by stacking all the models together and

performing a single regression with the stacked observations weighted by the inverse of

the model error variances. The system-weighted R2s we obtained for linear 3sls

estimation of specifications 1, 3, 4 are 0.758, 0.806, and 0.702, respectively. It shows that

the estimated models explained approximately 80 percent of the variability of the

dependent variables.

108

The R2 statistics are computed consistently with the calculation of the F statistic.

The ES and ED equations all seem to be quite well specified judging by the values of the

R2s obtained. It is valid for testing hypothesis but may not be a good measure of fit for

models estimated by instrumental variables methods, including 3sls (i.e., R2 may not be a

good measure of the goodness of fit of the model). However, R2 statistic is bounded (-∞,

0), so that values close to unity are still a fairly good indicator of the goodness of fit of

the individual equation.

3.5.2. F-Test

The F-test shown in the 3sls case is a valid test of the no-regression hypothesis

that the true coefficients of all regressors are 0. However, because of the first-stage

projection of the regression mean square, this is asymptotically F but not exactly F-

distributed in finite samples. Thus, for small samples the F-test is only approximate when

instrumental variables are used.

The F-ratio and its significance were obtained from the second stage estimation. It

shows that all the equations we used in 3sls estimation have the F-values with

significance level less than 0.0001, thus leads to the rejection of the null hypothesis that

the true coefficients of all the non-intercept parameters are 0. It implies that each

equation in the models explained most of the variance of its dependent variable.

3.5.3. The t statistics

The t statistic is the parameter estimate divided by the standard error when the

hypothesis is that the true parameter is 0. The t-tests are strictly valid in finite samples

109

only for OLS estimates but are asymptotically valid for the other methods. In the

nonlinear specification, because the model is nonlinear, the standard error of the estimate,

the t value and its significance level are only approximate. These values are computed

using asymptotic formulas that are correct for large sample sizes but only approximately

correct for smaller samples.

The t statistics were not reported in this study, but their significance levels were

presented in Tables 5.2-5.5, by using ** as significant at the 5 percent level, and * at

the10 percent level. The interpretation of these coefficient estimates and their significant

level were discussed in the results section.

3.5.4. Durbin-Watson (DW) test

If the data are time series, it is possible that εt depends on εt-1 or, more generally,

the εts are not identically and independently distributed (i.i.d.). If the errors of a model

system are autocorrelated, the standard error of the estimates of the parameters of the

system will be inflated. However, the parameter estimates will still be unbiased and

consistent.

Note that there are missing values in some of our models. If there are missing

values, the test statistics are calculated according to Savin and White (1978). When the

residual series is interrupted by missing observations, Savin and White (1978) show that

it has the same null distribution as the DW with no gaps in the series and can be used to

test for autocorrelation using the standard tables. The Durbin-Watson statistic is not valid

for models containing lagged endogenous variables.

110

In this study, we obtained Durbin-Wastson (DW) statistics for each equation in

the estimated models, and the results show that there is evidence of positive

autocorrelation in these equations. The autocorrelation can be partially explained by the

data smoothing process. Although we did the test of autocorrelation, the Durbin-Watson

statistic, the properties of these tests are still not clear in simultaneous models when one

is using a 3sls estimator.

111

CHAPTER 6

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION

The U.S. poultry industry is the world’s largest producer and exporter of poultry

meat. Hong Kong/China (HK/CH) is the second largest export market for U.S. poultry

products. As the HK/CH market develops, the U.S. has benefited by exporting less

valuable chicken cuts to HK/CH and selling chicken breast meat in the domestic market.

The China market has great potential to be an important and growing market for poultry

meat in the future, because of its large population, rapid economic growth, relative low

per capita consumption level and its accession to the WTO.

The objective of this study is to examine the exports of U.S. chicken parts to the

HK/CH market, model the excess supply and demand of this trade flow, and report

findings related to HK/CH market responsiveness.

1. Study Summary

First, we discussed the international market for poultry meat and U.S. chicken

exports to Hong Kong/China. We also pointed out that the unique U.S.-HK/CH chicken

export pattern is partially attributed to the different chicken consumption preferences

between U.S. and HK/CH consumers.

A theoretical framework of excess supply (ES) and excess demand (ED) analysis

was then adopted. Four chicken products (chicken feet, chicken wings, chicken legs and

112

chicken offal) were chosen for empirical analysis. Joint production and residual market

concepts were introduced. Based on the ES and ED theoretical framework and joint-

production considerations, general forms of excess supply and excess demand functions

were defined. Finally, the theoretical models were used to develop models for empirical

estimation and estimation results and calculated elasticities were reported. Four model

specifications were estimated in order to check the consistency of the estimation results.

The inverse excess demand (ED) specifications were exactly the same when

combined with the four excess supply specifications, and the estimation results for these

ED equations provided us with consistent results across specifications. In general,

negative relationships were found between HK/CH import price and own import quantity.

Positive relationships were found between import price and Hong Kong GDP level.

Three of the four specifications included prices in their excess supply (ES)

equations, however, the parameters estimated for these prices were not consistent with

expectations. The other primary variable in the ES equations, U.S. whole chicken

production, had positive and significant impacts on U.S. exports to HK/CH for most parts

and specifications. An ES specification, with the U.S. whole chicken production variable

but without any price variables, was constructed to be represent a scenario in which the

U.S. producers treat the chicken parts as by-products and HK/CH as a residual market.

This specification explained ES equations almost as well as those with price

specifications. It produced fewer results that conflicted with theory, and produced ED

parameter estimates that were generally very close to those produced by the other

specifications.

113

Based on the calculated elasticities, we found that quantity of U.S. chicken offal

exports to HK/CH are much more responsive to U.S. production levels than chicken feet

and legs. The flexibilities of import price with respect to import quantity are negative and

inflexible, and the flexibilities of import price to Hong Kong GDP level are near unity,

and positive for chicken wings, legs and feet but negative for chicken offal.

2. Conclusions

Overall, the quantities of U.S. chicken parts exported to HK/CH are positively

impacted by U.S. whole birds production. Coefficients of own price and alternative

market price variables were generally either insignificant or significant but with a sign

contradicting a priori expectations based on theory. Additional work on ES estimation is

needed, but these results may support the view that U.S. producers treat these chicken

parts as by-products of U.S. chicken production and the HK/CH market for these chicken

parts as a residual market. If this is true, U.S. producers may be able to improve profits

by giving more attention to prices in alternative markets if such markets exist.

With the exception of chicken offal, the demand for U.S. chicken parts in the

HK/CH market should continue to grow as HK/CH consumers’ income increases.

Combined with limited domestic chicken production in the HK/CH market, low per

capita poultry consumption, and expected growing income, HK/CH consumer demand

for chicken product will outgrow their domestic production, and their consumption of

U.S. chicken products may go up significantly.

The China market can absorb more chicken feet and offal without lowing prices

much. In the other words, increasing U.S. chicken feet and offal exports to the HK/CH

114

market would not cause its own export price to decrease significantly. According to the

empirical results obtained from this study, a 1 percent increase in HK/CH import quantity

of U.S. chicken feet would only cause a decrease on its own import price ranging from

0.423 percent to 0.497 percent.

The HK/CH chicken leg import price was more responsive to its own import

quantity than the other parts examined here. Even for legs, however, a 1 percent increase

in exports is accompanied with a decrease in price between 0.618 percent and 0.665

percent. This suggests the export revenues from legs would continue to increase with

greater quantities of exports, but the HK/CH market may be less able to absorb increases

in leg shipments than increases of shipments of feet and offal.

Brazil’s worldwide chicken exports did not seem to significantly affect the price

of U.S. chicken parts exported to HK/CH, except for chicken wings. However, with

Brazil’s increasing market share in HK/CH market, U.S. chicken export prices may

eventually be negatively impacted.

3. Limitations and Future Research

The limitations of this study are caused primarily by the data problems. The data

we used in this study is mainly from USITC database, however, these data cannot be

guaranteed to be flawless, and we noticed some apparent data problems occurred in the

year 2000. Although we have attempted to deal with the data problem in this study, the

impact of potentially remaining data problems is not possible to assess.

Because the data for different U.S. chicken parts started only after January 1997,

we have to use the monthly data in the model estimation in order to meet the degree of

115

freedom requirement. The monthly observations may fluctuate widely due to some

sporadic incidents. In this study, we used statistical smoothing methods to reduce the

fluctuation effect, but this may still cause some noise in the estimation.

In this study, we were not able to evaluate the policy effect of China’s accession

to the WTO in December 2001. Because the data did not cover the time period when

policy was changed. Future study may include the 2001 and 2002 data to assess the

policy effect. Given the number of unexpected and insignificant efficient in the excess

supply equations, particular attention should be given to the estimation of excess supply

equations.

116

REFERENCES Aitken, A.C. “On Least Squares and Linear Combination of Observations.” Proceedings

of the Royal Society of Edinburgh, 55 (1934-1935) pp.42-48. Cao, Q., and K.S. Huang. “Urban and Rural Food Demand in China.” Unpublished

Chinese manuscript, November 2000. Costa, E.F. “Brazil’s New Floating Exchange rate Regime and Competitiveness in the

World Poultry Market.” Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics, 33 (August 2001): 367-375.

Crook, F.W., and W.H. Colby. “China’s Livestock Sector Growing Rapidly.”

Agricultural Outlook, Economic Research Service/USDA, November 1998. Crook, F.W., and D.J. Harvey. “China’s Poultry Economy: Production, Marketing,

Foreign Trade and Consumption.” U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, International Agriculture and Trade Reports: China, WRS-98-3, July 1998.

Dyck, J., and K. Nelson. “World Meat Trade Shaped by Regional Preferences and

Reduced Barriers.” Agricultural Outlook, Economic Research Service/USDA, March 2000.

Ferris, G.D. “What change in China Means For Trade in Hong Kong.” AgExporter,

March 2000. Fuller, F., C. Fang. “ The Impact of Structural Change in Chinese Livestock Production

on World Feed Grain Trade.” Paper presented on the American Agricultural Economic Association Meeting, August 1999.

Gale, F. “China’s statistics: Are They Reliable?” China’s Food and Agriculture: Issues

for the 21st Century/AIB-775, Economic Research Service/USDA, (April 2002): 50-53.

Greene, J., and L. Southard. “U.S. Red Meat and Poultry Markets In a Global Setting.”

Agricultural Outlook, (June-July 1998): 10-12. Hayes, D. “The Chinese Market for U.S. Pork Exports.” Center for Agricultural and

Rural Development (CARD) publication, August 1997.

117

Harmonized Tariff Schedule of the United States (2002), United States International Trade Commission, Internet site: http://dataweb.usitc.gov/SCRIPTS/tariff/toc.html (accessed December 4, 2002).

Harvey, D. “Growth in Broiler Production Likely to Slow in 2001”, Agricultural Outlook,

November 2000: 2-3. Kmenta, J. “Elements of Econometrics.” 2nd Edition, Macmillan Publishing Company,

1986. Lohmar, B., J. Hansen, H. Hsu, and R. Seeley. “WTO accession will increase China’s

agricultural imports.” Agricultural Outlook, Economic Research Service/USDA, April 2002.

Luk, M.Y. Consumer Price Index Section, Census and Statistics Department, Hong Kong

SAR, 2002. Markusen, J.R., J.R. Melvin, W.H. Kaempfer, and K.E. Maskus. “International Trade:

Theory and Evidence.” McGraw-Hill, Inc., 1995. Martin, W., and C. Bach. “State Trading in China.” Paper prepared for presentation to the

University of Neuchatel conference on “State Trading and the WTO,” Geneva, Switzerland, September 12-13, 1997.

Morgan, N. “Selling Poultry in China No Longer Chicken Feed.” Agexporter, 1997.

Internet site: http://www.fas.usda.gov/info/agexporter/1997/selling.html (Accessed October, 2002).

N.E. Savin, K.J. White. “Testing for Autocorrelation with Missing Observations.”

Econometrica, volume 46, Issue 1 (Jan. 1978): 59-67. Peterson, E., and D. Orden. “Effects of Tariffs and Technical Barriers on High- and Low-

Value Poultry Trade.” Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Agricultural Economics Association, Long Beach, California, July 28-31, 2002.

The World Trade Organization (WTO), Internet site:

http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/countries_e/china_e.htm (Accessed November 2002).

Thompson, H. “International Economics: Global Markets and International

Competition.” World Scientific Publishing. Co. Pte. Ltd. 2001, ISBN: 981-02-4344-8: 14.

Tuan, F., Q. Cao, and T. Peng. (2001) “Livestock Production competitive, but Exports

Remain Small.” China: Agriculture in Transition, Economic Research Service/USDA (November 2001): 37-47.

118

Tuan, F., H. Colby, and Q. Cao. “ Demand for Livestock products Stalls.” International

Agricultural and Trade Reports: China, March 2000. Tweeten, L. “Agricultural Trade: Principles and Policies.” Wetview Press, 1992: 27-29. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), Livestock and Poultry: World Markets and

Trade, Foreign Agricultural Service, October 1997a. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), Livestock and Poultry: World Markets and

Trade, Foreign Agricultural Service, March 1997b. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), Livestock and Poultry: World Markets and

Trade, Foreign Agricultural Service, March 1998a. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), “China’s Economy Slows; Livestock Sector

Posts Long-Term Growth.” International Agricultural and Trade Reports: China, July 1998b.

U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), “Overview of World Poultry Market.”

International Agricultural Baseline Projections to 2007/AER-767, August 1998c. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), “Problems in Measuring China’s Livestock

Sector.” Agricultural Outlook, November 1998d. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), Livestock and Poultry: World Markets and

Trade, Foreign Agricultural Service, October 1999. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), International Egg and Poultry Review, Vol. 03,

No. 14, April 2000a. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), Livestock and Poultry: World Markets and

Trade, Foreign Agricultural Service, October 2000b. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), “Hong Kong Poultry and Products Semi-

Annual 2001.” GAIN Report, Foreign Agricultural Service, February 2001a. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), “Hong Kong Market Development Reports

China’s Accession to the WTO: What Does It Mean for Hong Kong?” GAIN Report, Foreign Agricultural Service, August 2001b.

U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), International Egg and Poultry Review, Vol. 05,

No. 21, May 2002a. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), “Hong Kong Poultry and Products Semi-

Annual 2002.” GAIN Report, Foreign Agricultural Service, February 2002b.

119

U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), International Egg and Poultry Review, Vol. 05,

No.11, March 2002c. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), Livestock and Poultry: World Markets and

Trade, Foreign Agricultural Service, various issues, 1996-2002. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), “Poultry - Production and Value.” National

Agricultural Statistics Service, various issues, 1997-2002. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), “Poultry and Eggs”, Briefing Room,

http://www.ers.usda.gov/briefing/foodpricespreads/meatpricespreads/cuts.xls. (Accessed October 2002).

Vicente, M.V., A.J. Allen, and J. Reeves. “An Analysis of major Poultry Products

Traders in World markets.” Journal of Food Distribution Research, (29 Jan 1998): 107-108.

Wailes, E.J., C. Fang, and F.C. Tuan. “U.S.-China Agricultural Trade: Constraints and

Potential.” Journal of Agricultural Economics Association, 30, 1 (July 1998): 113-126.

Wang, Q., F. Fuller, D. Hayes, and C. Halbrendt. “Chinese Consumer Demand for

Animal products and Implications for U.S. Pork and Poultry Exports.” Southern Agricultural Economics Association, 30 (July 1998): 127-140.