regional economics george horváth department of environmental economics [email protected]

51
Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics [email protected]

Upload: sheryl-norman

Post on 17-Dec-2015

228 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Regional Economics

George HorváthDepartment of Environmental [email protected]

Page 2: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

The origins of Regional Economics• Spatial development and settlement theory

did not form part of early Political Economy• Early economic theory focused on a „one-

point economy”• Most significant problems were value,

distribution issues and taxation• First efforts in regional economics were

taken by economically trained industrialists, agriculturalists and transport professionals

• They encountered the rules and decision-making problems of regional economics during their professional work

• This original interdisciplinarity is still present1

Page 3: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Formulating regional economic theoryFormulation of Economic Theory follows a historical logic:

1. First: agricultural issues, second: locating industry, third: locating all other sectors. Transportation as the means of bridging distances has also been treated in regional economics from the early days.

2. Regional economics first dealt with locating individual businesses, i.e.: microeconomic approach. Only later did it start focusing on locating several businesses, i.e.: macroeconomic approach.

3. Regional economics treated competitive scenarios first, later it dealt with monopolistic situations too, eventually dealing with the problem of externalities. 2

Page 4: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Properties of spatiality and its relationship to spatial developmentAspects of the spatial dimension

3

Spatial and geographic adjacency

Spatial and geographic dissimilarity

Spatial and geographic distance and mobility

Spatial and geographic extent and fragmentation

}}}

Urban and Spatial planning

Spatial development, Regional policy

Spatial and Territorial administration

Page 5: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Comparing the „one-point economy and the spatially extensive economy

4

categories one-point spatially extensive

Market Uniform, homogenous (same prices)

Structured and dissimilar in space

Input (costs) Near-average Spatially dissimilar (local)

Competition Perfect (on both Input and Product markets)

Imperfect (geographic monopoly)

Economic reactions Identical Different (local culture and particularities)

Market information Perfect Spatially asymmetricMarket behaviour Rational Spatially restricted

rationalConsumer preferences

Homogenous Spatially inhomogenous

Substitutability Unlimited Limited by spatial allocation of resources

Economic equilibrium

Equilibrium is the standard state

Disequilibrium is the standard state

Page 6: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Regional economics among sciences

5

Economic Sciences

Regional Economics

Geographic, technical and legal sciences

Page 7: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

The elements of Regional Economics• Location theory• Theory of Economic

Space (spatial structures, city and settlement networks, markets in space, agglomerations)

• Regions, regional economic growth and development in space

6

}

}

Microeconomics

Macroeconomics

Page 8: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Location theories and locating factors• Theory of agricultural location (von

Thünen)• Theory of industrial location (Weber)• Location of commerce• Location of services• Theory of choosing a habitation

location (Alonso)

7

Page 9: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Different interpretations of LocationNational level:• Tax regime, customs, tariffs and duties• Economic and legal regulations• Economic and population growth• Political and economic stability• EU membership

Regional level• Quantity and qualification of workforce• Proximity and access to motorways• Vicinity of national frontier• Economic structure

Local level• Price and appropriateness of the real estate (land)• Accessibility of utilities• Local taxes and subventions• Local industry• Cooperative opportunities• Schools, universities and training facilities 8

Page 10: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Weber’s theory of Industrial Location• Logically speaking, the first regional

economic theories were on Industrial Locations (historically speaking, though, the first ones were on agricultural locations.)

• The founder of the Economic Theories of Industrial Location was Alfred Weber

• His magnum opus was published in 1909: „On the Locations of the Industries” (Über den Standort der Industrien)

9

Page 11: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Locative factors in Weber’s theory• Such factors which transform the

conditions of productions favourably to producers (agglomerative factors)

• Benefits arising from the proximity of either resources (raw materials) or markets (transportation costs)

10

Page 12: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Effects and benefits in Weber’s Theory• Agglomerative benefits and transport

costs act in opposing directions• Their equilibrium determines the

optimal location• The agglomerative effect acts towards

the highest concentration of activity…• …but the requirement that locations

should be in the proximity of resources and labour, as well as consumers and markets, acts in the opposing direction.

11

Page 13: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Agglomerative benefits1. Benefits arising from an increase in

size of a particular plant (economies of scale)

2. Benefits arising from the increase in the number of businesses in the same economic sector (specialised suppliers, qualified work force, availability of management and technical know-how), known as „localisation benefits”

3. Urbanisational benefits arising from the infrastructure and size of a big city 12

Page 14: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Agglomerative drawbacks1. Increased price of work force and

required land2. Drawbacks of congestion (noise,

pollution, criminality, social problems)

3. As concentration increases, some of the markets will become more distant, thus increasing transportation costs

13

Page 15: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Main groups of Industrial Location Theories

Cost Minimising theories• Price is a given factor, producers have no

influence• Location of competitive companies does

not affect sales• An increase in profit can only be

achieved by cutting production and transport costs

Weber’s Theory is a cost minimising theory 14

Page 16: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Main groups of Industrial Location Theories

Profit Maximising theories• Price is not a given factor; it depends

on– The location of customers– The location of producers– The location of competitive firms– The strategy of competitive firms

• Demand is not focussed in a single point, but rather, it is spatially distributed 15

Page 17: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Examining factors: transportation• Some raw materials are to be

transported, others are not (air, water, etc.)

• Non-transport cost differences exist in raw materials, intermediary and end-products, e.g.:

– Depth of mines– Quality of raw materials

• All non-transport cost differences are converted into transport costs

• This is a „reverse iceberg” model 16

Page 18: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Suppositions in Weber’s model

• Demand for a product exists at a single point in space

• Two kinds of raw materials exist, in two points, removed from both the market and each other

• The market is perfectly competitive• The sale price of the product is given

and inelastic• All possible locations implement the

same technology, therefore costs incurred must be the same everywhere17

Page 19: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Question: where to settle industry?• Weber’s Theory deals with the

problem of finding an optimal location for industry.

• What are the scenarios?– Locating the industry near the market– Locating it near the raw material– Find an intermediary „compromise”

location

18

Page 20: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Scenario I: locating near the market• An industry will settle near the consumer

market, if– The final product is heavier than the aggregate

weight of the raw materials, energy sources and intermediary products, or otherwise, if

– The final product is not heavier than the aggregate weight, but transportation costs of the final product are so high that they would over-compensate the difference in weight.

• Typical examples:– Beverages (high water demand)– Paints, thinners, etc. (again, high water demand)– Perishable goods (foods, etc.) 19

Page 21: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Scenario 2: locating near raw materials• An industry will settle near the raw materials

or sources of energy, if the industry is heavily dependent on these.

• Examples:– Construction materials– Oil refining– Smelting (blast furnaces)– Alimentation (flour milling, sugar and canning

industry)

20

Page 22: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Scenario 3: other locations?

• What if the industry does not produce for a single market only, and/or requires more than just a few raw materials and energy sources?

• If there is no single item (either on the input or output side) that would dominate the production, where should we locate the industry?

• The solution: finding a compromise location!• How do we define such a location?

21

Page 23: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Defining a compromise location

• Weber uses a formula to define a locative criterion• He defines material indices:

– For each tonne of product, an amount of each component (raw material, energy, etc.) is needed

– These quantities must be put in during the process– One tonne of final product is the output

– a1, a2, a3, a4, etc.

• Aggregate amount of „quantities” to be moved: ∑ai+1

• This amount is called the „weight of the location” (T)

• Using these indices, defining a location becomes more straight forward 22

Page 24: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Three possible locations

1. An industry will be located near an input material if there exists a material index ai, which exceeds half the sum of all input weights (i.e.: half of the weight of location, T), such that ai> T∕2

2. The industry will be located near the product markets if the weight of the product exceeds half the sum of all input weights (ie.: half of the weight of location, T), such that 1> T∕2 , or T<2.

3. A compromise location will be chosen if none of the above conditions hold true, i.e.: ai< T∕2 , and 1< T∕2 or T>2. 23

Page 25: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Working with a compromise location• If there is only a single raw material and a single

product market, there cannot exist a third, „intermediary” or „compromise” location, since one of the material weights will probably exceed half the location weight.

• Should they be exactly equal, choosing an „intermediary” location is still unlikely to be beneficial, as the costs of loading and unloading between the two end points (raw material or the market) will increase costs. Even randomly choosing one will be cheaper.

• Compromise locations can only be defined when there are at least two raw materials and one market, or one raw material and two markets. 24

Page 26: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Finding a compromise location

Let’s suppose we have…• Two raw materials (A and B)• One market (C)…located geographically as shown below:

25B

A

C

Page 27: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Finding a compromise location

• We need to find a point P inside the bounding triangle with the smallest possible associated „import” and „export” costs.

• We’re looking for a certain „centre of mass” of the triangle, but not the geometric centre of mass.

26B

A

C

P

Page 28: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Finding a compromise location• We’re after a point where the product of the transport

tariffs and the import and export costsw1t1s1+ w2t2s2 + w3t3s3→min

wi = point-specific import & export weights (material&product index)

ti = transport tariffs of materials and productssi = distances from the end points, defining the distance

from P

27B

A

C

P

Page 29: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

A possible compromise location

28

B

A

C

P

Page 30: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Compromise locations in real Compromise locations in real lifelife

29

Let’s suppose that we have two raw Let’s suppose that we have two raw materials and one market, just like before,materials and one market, just like before,

A

here,here,

B

here,here, Cand here.and here.

Page 31: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

A possible compromise location

30

We do the maths again, and we identify our compromise location.

Let’s see this on our map now.

A

B

CP

Page 32: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

31

And here it is.And here it is.

A

B

CP

Can we spot any problems?Can we spot any problems?

Page 33: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

32

Our „optimal” compromise location Our „optimal” compromise location is in the middle of nowhere!is in the middle of nowhere!

A

B

CP

So can this be „optimal”?So can this be „optimal”?

• No roads.No roads.• No railroads.No railroads.• There aren’t even any towns close by!There aren’t even any towns close by!

Page 34: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

33

Wouldn’t it be more practical to Wouldn’t it be more practical to have our location elsewhere?have our location elsewhere?

A

B

CP

Weber’s model can give some strange results.Weber’s model can give some strange results.

Here, because Here, because it’s near a town?it’s near a town?

Here, because Here, because there’s a road?there’s a road?

Here, because it’s Here, because it’s close to the river?close to the river?

Here, because Here, because of the railroad?of the railroad?

Page 35: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

34

C

B

A

Where will we find a compromise location?Where will we find a compromise location?

Let’s take a scenario just like Let’s take a scenario just like before:before:

Page 36: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

35

C

B

A

P

Surely, this can’t be a feasible location.Surely, this can’t be a feasible location.

Weber’s model offers this Weber’s model offers this solution:solution:

Page 37: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Associated mathematical problems• There is no simple „one-step solution”

for determining a compromise location• An iterative process needs to be carried

out, which takes several additional steps• There is no single guideline iteration for

solving the problem• Possible solutions have been published

(such as Harold Kuhn and Robert Kuenne’s solution)

• Even if a compromise location is found, it may not be practical in real life

36

Page 38: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

On the issue of workers• We need to take into consideration the

issue of workers as well• We need workers for the factory (obviously)• Workers tend to „live somewhere”• At the time of the formulation of the

theorem, commuting was not an everyday phenomenon, so a given workforce was only available locally

• From Weber’s point of view, the advantages and disadvantages arising from the level of training of the workforce would only be reflected in their wages

37

Page 39: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Weber’s formulation of this question• Let’s suppose that there exists another

city, where wages are lower compared to the optimal (compromise) location (which was determined through transport costs), then

• Considering possible savings in costs and expenses, would it be worthwhile for the industry to locate nearer to where the workforce lives (and bear the additional transport costs on both input and output side)?

38

Page 40: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Weber’s solution• As previously, Weber projects labour costs

on a quantity of final product (one tonne)• He first calculates the amount of labour

required for the production of a tonne of final product.

• The then divides this quantity by the aggregate weight of all materials going in and out of the factory, i.e.: the weight of the location

• We get an index number, which he calls labour coefficient (Arbeitskoeffizient, A)

• We can now directly work with labour costs

39

Page 41: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

What this means• If A1 is the labour coefficient at the

„optimal” (with the supposedly higher labour costs), and

• A2 is the labour coefficient at the city with the supposedly lower labour costs, then

• The difference A1-A2 will indicate the savings in labour expenditure.

40

Page 42: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Working this out with formulae• If the new location would be at a distance of

S kilometres from the optimal location, and the cost of transportation would be t per tonne, a switch of location would only be worthwhile, if

T∙S∙t < A1-A2

• In such a situation, we would replace some of the labour costs with additional transport costs.

• Hopefully, this would result in a saving.• If not, DON’T do it!• This substitution effect has become a

fundamental part of location theories. 41

Page 43: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

About market effects• When treating labour, it becomes obvious

that Weber does not consider the effect companies have on wages:

• If a new factory locates in a town, this will have an effect on wages (increase) so the calculated savings on wages will not be realised.

• Even though Weber’s Model is considered to be a cost-minimising approach, by disregarding market responses we cannot even calculate cost savings.

42

Page 44: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Agglomeration effectsag· glom· er· ate, vb:

to form or be formed into a mass or cluster

• as firms in related industries cluster together, costs of production may decline significantly

– firms have competing multiple suppliers– greater specialization and division of labour

• Even when competitors agglomerate, benefits may be reaped, as the cluster attracts more suppliers and buyers

• Cities grow because of such effects!• It relates to two main ideas:

– Economies of Scale– Network Effects

43

Page 45: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Advantages of agglomeration• Influx of new information and

practices• This can bring down fixed costs of

production• As fixed costs fall, a stage of

economies of scale is reached

44

Page 46: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Disdvantages of agglomeration• City growth may only be persistent if

advantages constantly outweigh disadvantages

• Adverse effects may appear– Congestion– Pollution– Criminality– Other negative externalities of clustering

• Pricing power of the firms will decrease, as shortage of labour becomes apparent 45

Page 47: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Back to Weber’s ModelAccording to Weber, companies have two alternative paths to take:

1.Establish two separate factories, each near its own suppliers and markets, at optimal distances between the two

2.Establish a single factory with the combined production capacity of the hypothetical two factories, which would be located at a not optimal site, but the additional transport costs would be covered by the savings through economies of scale

Which alternative should one choose?46

Page 48: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Sounds familiar?• It should; the logic of solving this problem is

exactly the same as the problem of labour.• A move away from the optimal location results

in an increase in costs.• However, savings will be realised in some fixed

costs that don’t increase with size:– Administration– Buildings and real estate– Production and development costs– Marketing

• If the benefits of economies of scale outweigh the losses through locating away from the optimum, it’s worthwile to build a larger factory

47

Page 49: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

Working this out with formulae• Let’s consider fixed costs C and the mass

of products from each plant W1 and W2

• As previously, T is the weight of the location, S is the distance from our

• The criterion for building a larger factory is therefore

48

2121

2WW

CWW

CtST

Page 50: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

To wrap up Weber’s Model• Weber considers each factor one after

the other.• If we began by leaving the optimal

location for benefits of cheaper labour, we then start out from this new point when we consider the effects of agglomeration and economies of scale

• Savings have to cover an increase in the cost of labour as well!

49

Page 51: Regional Economics George Horváth Department of Environmental Economics george@eik.bme.hu

To wrap up Weber’s Model• Even though it has a number of known

flaws, Weber’s model remains a cornerstone in regional economics

• It has been a logical guideline for locating industry for several decades

• Even today it has some applications

49