protecting employer investment in training

Upload: comixster

Post on 03-Jun-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    1/27

    Duke University School of Lawis collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Duke Law Journal.

    http://www.jstor.org

    uke University School of Law

    Protecting Employer Investment in Training: Noncompetes vs. Repayment AgreementsAuthor(s): Brandon S. LongSource: Duke Law Journal, Vol. 54, No. 5 (Mar., 2005), pp. 1295-1320Published by: Duke University School of LawStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/40040471

    Accessed: 09-08-2014 08:01 UTC

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available athttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

    JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of contentin a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=duslhttp://www.jstor.org/stable/40040471http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/40040471http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=duslhttp://www.jstor.org/
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    2/27

    PROTECTING EMPLOYER

    INVESTMENT

    IN TRAINING:

    NONCOMPETES

    VS.

    REPAYMENT

    AGREEMENTS

    Brandon S. Long

    Introduction

    In

    an

    economy

    withmore nd more

    opportunities

    or

    workers

    who

    possess sophisticated

    kills nd technical

    ptitude,

    American

    companies

    must

    ight

    o

    recruit,rain,

    nd retain he market's

    most

    talented

    mployees.1

    addled

    with he

    hallenge

    f

    competing

    or

    op

    talent,

    employers

    frequently

    use

    noncompetition

    lauses

    ( noncompetes )2

    n

    employment

    greements

    o

    guard against

    employee

    efections.

    hese lauses

    havebecome

    ncreasinglyopular

    in recent decades

    and have

    been the

    subject

    of considerable

    controversynd debate.At this ebate's ore s often hequestionf

    what

    specific

    mployer

    nterests hould

    noncompetes rotect.

    n

    response

    o

    shifting

    arket

    onditionshat ffect

    mployer-employee

    relationships,3

    tates

    ontinually

    eevaluate

    he

    degree

    o which

    hey

    choose

    o

    uphold

    hese

    oncompetes.4

    To take

    an

    example,

    ouisiana

    has

    recently

    e-assessed

    hich

    employer

    nterests

    houldbe

    protectable.

    istorically,

    ouisiana

    law

    rejected

    ll contracts

    estrainingnyone

    from

    xercising

    lawful

    profession,

    rade r

    business

    f

    ny

    kind, 5

    ut

    made n

    exception

    or

    agreementsyanemployeeto refrainromarryingn orengaging

    in a business

    n

    competition

    ith is

    employer

    i.e.,

    noncompetes).6

    Copyright

    2005

    by

    Brandon S.

    Long.

    1. See

    Peter

    Cappelli,

    The New

    Deal at

    Work

    1-16

    (1999)

    (discussing

    conomic

    factors

    riving

    hange

    n

    employer-employee

    elations).

    2.

    Traditionally, oncompete

    greements

    estrictedn

    employee

    from

    ompeting

    with n

    employer

    within

    specified

    eographic

    egion

    nd

    for finite erm fter

    he

    employment eriod

    ended. See

    generally

    Harlan

    M.

    Blake,

    Employee Agreements

    ot to

    Compete,

    73

    Harv. L.

    Rev.

    625

    (1960) (defining

    oncompetition

    greements

    nd

    tracing

    he

    legal

    enforceability

    f

    noncompetes

    hroughout

    nglish

    ndAmerican

    aw).

    3.

    See

    infra

    otes 3-43

    and

    accompanying

    ext.

    4.

    See

    infra

    art

    I.B.

    5.

    La. Rev. Stat.

    Ann.

    23:921

    A)(l) (West 2003).

    6.

    M23:921(C).

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    3/27

    1296

    DUKE LAW JOURNAL

    [Vol.

    54:1295

    In

    2001,

    n ts

    ontroversialwat

    41

    ecision,

    heLouisiana

    upreme

    Courtnterpretedhis xceptionarrowly,oldinghat noncompete

    will

    be

    unenforceable

    f

    t restrictsn

    employee

    rom

    working

    or

    business

    competitor.8

    n

    contrast,

    he court

    agreed

    to

    uphold

    noncompetes

    hat

    prevent

    n

    employee

    from

    tarting

    is

    own

    business.9

    hus,

    under

    Swat

    24,

    companies

    ould not

    restrictn

    employee

    rom

    working

    or n

    existingompetitor

    utcould

    prevent

    an

    employee

    rom

    pening shop

    across he treet.10

    his

    ruling

    eft

    Louisiana

    mployers

    ithmuch

    ess

    protectiongainst

    heir oss

    of

    investment

    n

    employees.

    n

    dissent,

    ustice

    het

    Traylor

    mentioned

    this concern,arguingthat without broader enforcement f

    noncompetes

    employers

    an not

    sic]

    afford o invest

    ptimally

    n

    product

    evelopment

    r n

    their

    mployees. 11

    In

    reaction o

    this

    holding,

    he Louisiana

    egislature

    tatutorily

    overruled

    wat

    4 in

    June 003.To

    do

    so,

    t enacted

    provision

    hat

    permitted

    nforceability

    f

    noncompetesgainst mployees

    ho are

    employed y

    competing

    usiness,

    egardless

    fwhetherr not hat

    person

    s

    an

    owner or

    equity

    nterest older of that

    competing

    business . . . 12 n

    other

    words,

    he

    enforceability

    f

    noncompetes

    wasexpandedo allow estrictionsoth rom orkings anemployee

    of

    competing

    usiness

    ndfrom

    pening

    ne's ownbusiness.13

    7.

    Swat 24

    Shreveport

    ossier,

    nc. v.

    Bond,

    808 So.2d 294

    (La. 2001).

    8.

    See

    Jennifer .

    Faroldi,

    What's till

    Brewing

    n

    the 003

    Legislative

    ession?,

    La. Emp.

    L.

    Letter,

    June

    003,

    t 4

    ( [Y]ou currently

    an't

    prevent

    ormer

    mployees

    rom

    working

    or

    competing

    usiness. ).

    9.

    Swat

    24,

    808

    So.2d at 296.

    The facts f

    the case are

    fairly traightforward.

    he

    employee

    had been promotedby the employer, constructionompany, o the positionof production

    manager,

    a

    status that

    required

    him to

    sign

    a

    noncompete agreement.

    The

    noncompete

    agreement

    ad

    stipulated

    hat

    he

    employee

    would not serve as an

    officer,

    mployee,

    director,

    agent

    or

    consultantof

    any

    business,

    which is in direct or

    indirect

    ompetition

    with the

    employer.

    d.

    at

    296-97. In

    striking

    own

    this

    contract,

    he

    court examined

    the

    legislative

    records

    behind

    ection

    23:921

    and

    concluded that he

    statute's

    egislative

    ntent

    emanded that

    the

    exception

    n

    subsection

    C)

    only

    applied

    to

    employees

    who establish

    heir

    wn

    competing

    businesses,

    ot

    to

    employees

    who

    chose to

    workfor

    lready-existingompetitors.

    d.

    at 302-07.

    10.

    Id.

    11.

    Id. at

    313

    (Traylor,

    .,

    dissenting).

    12.

    2003 La.

    Sess. Law

    Serv.428

    (West).

    13. This tension between the legislatureand the courts is common in the area of

    noncompete

    aw. In

    the ate

    1980s and

    early

    1990s,

    he state of

    Texas endured similar

    onflict.

    The Texas

    Supreme

    Court had

    interpreted

    he

    state's

    noncompete

    tatute

    narrowly, efusing

    o

    enforce

    noncompetes

    gainst

    at-will

    mployees.

    The Texas

    legislature

    ollowed this decision

    with

    law

    specifically

    ncluding

    t-will

    mployees

    under

    he

    purview

    f the

    noncompete

    tatute.

    For a

    detailed

    description

    f this

    conflict,

    ee Katherine

    V.W.

    Stone,

    Knowledge

    at Work:

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    4/27

    2005]

    REPAYMENT

    AGREEMENTS

    1297

    In

    the LouisianaHouse of

    Representatives

    ebates

    regarding

    thisprovision,numberfargumentseremade nsupport f the

    bill.14

    House

    Representative

    Jack Smith

    justified

    broader

    enforceability

    f

    noncompetes y cautioninggainst

    he risk

    of an

    unrestricted

    mployee

    haring

    rade ecrets

    nd customerists.15

    number

    f

    representatives

    lso

    expressed

    oncern

    hat

    employer

    investment

    n

    employee

    raining ight

    e

    squandered

    f

    companies

    could

    not enforce

    oncompetes.16

    hus,

    they rgued,

    ouisiana

    aw

    should

    be

    expanded

    o

    allow businesses o

    protect

    nvestment

    n

    employee

    trainingthrough

    the enforcement

    f

    noncompete

    agreements.17his desire oprotectmployernvestmentntraining

    marks

    considerable

    eparture

    rom he urrent

    aw

    n

    many

    tates.18

    Louisiana

    s correct

    n

    recognizing

    he

    mportance

    f

    protecting

    an

    employer's

    nvestment

    n

    training.

    et,

    thisNote

    argues

    hat

    sing

    a

    per

    e

    enforceability

    tandard

    or raditional

    oncompetes

    o

    effect

    this

    goal

    limits

    employees'

    post-employment

    ob prospects

    disproportionately

    ompared

    o

    what

    mployers

    eedto

    protect

    heir

    training

    nvestment.

    n contrast

    to traditional

    noncompetes,

    repayment

    greements

    ffer

    sensible

    alternative

    whereby

    n

    employer'sevelofprotection ovesn ockstep ith he ostof, nd

    value

    derived

    rom,

    he

    raining.

    hat

    s,

    repayment

    greements

    ore

    closely pproximate

    he

    degree

    f

    protection

    equired

    o

    encourage

    employer

    nvestment

    n

    training.

    Part

    of

    this

    Note discusses

    he

    ncreased

    mportance

    f

    training

    investment

    n

    today's

    workforce

    nd

    the

    need

    for

    udicial

    protection

    of that

    investment.

    art

    II

    traces

    both

    the

    policy

    arguments

    supporting

    nd

    condemning

    oncompetition

    greements

    nd

    the

    ests

    courts

    ommonly

    se

    to

    evaluate

    nforceability.

    art

    II.A

    analyzes

    trainingnvestmentn the contextof traditional oncompete

    Disputes

    over

    the

    Ownership

    of

    Human

    Capital

    in the

    Changing

    Workplace,

    34 CONN.

    L.

    REV.

    721,

    744-46

    2002).

    14.

    La.

    House Chamber

    Proceedings

    Day

    20,

    Discussion

    of House

    Bill

    1770

    May

    7,

    2003)

    (statement

    of

    Rep.

    Jack

    Smith),

    available

    at

    http://house.louisiana.gov/rmarchive/2003/

    May2003.htm.

    15.

    Id.

    16.

    Id.

    17. See

    id.

    ( Look

    at

    the

    company.

    hey're

    going

    o

    make

    an investment

    n that

    ndividual,

    they're oing

    o

    give

    him

    n

    education,

    hey're oing

    o

    train

    him

    . . and

    all

    they

    want

    n return

    is don't

    compete

    gainst

    me for

    wo

    years'

    I think

    t's a fair

    rade. ).

    18. See

    infra

    art II.A.

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    5/27

    1298

    DUKE LAW JOURNAL

    [Vol.

    54:1295

    agreements,

    nd

    Part II.B

    argues

    hat

    epayment

    greements

    re

    a

    more ensible lternativeo traditionaloncompetes.

    I. Training Investment n Today's Economy

    In

    theAmerican

    orkplace,

    nvestment

    n

    training

    s essential

    f

    businesses

    hope

    to

    keep pace

    with

    competition.

    ccording

    o

    Department

    f Labor research n the

    changing ynamics

    f theU.S.

    job

    market,19

    echnologicalmprovements

    ontinue o transformhe

    American

    orkplace

    n

    dramatic ashion.20

    mployers

    re

    constantly

    lookingfor more efficient ays to managetheirbusinesses s

    technology

    nd

    speed

    become critical o business uccess.21 s a

    result,

    ompanies

    emand

    mployees

    hat re

    equipped

    o contribute

    meaningfully

    n

    a

    fast-paced

    usiness

    etting.22

    ith

    technological

    innovation

    ccelerating

    n

    the

    twenty-firstentury,obs

    will

    require

    more

    ophisticated

    orkers;

    [t]he

    demand or

    knowledge'

    orkers

    across wide

    spectrum

    f

    occupations

    s forecastedo

    increase. 23

    Economic

    nnovation

    ill

    affect ll

    jobs;

    certain

    echnology-related

    jobs,

    namely

    omputer

    oftware nd

    support pecialists,

    etwork

    systemsnalysts,nd databaseadministrators,illbecome more

    abundant

    during

    he

    twenty-firstentury

    nd

    will

    be

    especially

    affected.24

    19.

    See

    generally

    .S.

    Dep't

    of

    Labor,

    Strategic

    lan FY

    2003-FY 2008

    (2003)

    [hereinafter

    U.S. Dep't ofLabor Plan] (describing hechangingAmericanworkforce nd theDepartment's

    goals

    for

    mproving

    abor

    conditions),

    vailable at

    http://www.dol.gov/_sec/tratplan/main.htm.

    20.

    See U.S.

    Dep't

    of

    Labor,

    Report

    on the

    American

    Workforce

    (2001)

    [hereinafter

    .S.

    Dep't

    of

    Labor

    Report]

    (describing

    he

    twentieth-century

    nnovations hat

    have transformed

    the

    American

    workplace,

    ncluding [communication

    devices,

    measuring

    devices,

    computer

    controlled

    equipment,

    [and]

    the

    x-ray ),

    available

    at

    http://www.bls.gov/opub/rtaw/

    rtawhome.htm.

    21.

    Id.

    22.

    See id.

    at 6

    (providing

    hat

    men and

    womenwith

    ollege

    degrees

    arn

    almost wo-thirds

    percent

    more than

    those

    with

    nly

    high

    chool

    degrees).

    This

    study

    lso

    reports

    hat n the

    year

    2000

    the

    unemployment

    ate

    for

    individualswith

    only

    a

    high

    school

    degree

    approached

    4

    percent,

    whereas

    herate for

    ollege graduates pproximated nly

    1.5

    percent.

    d. at 193.

    23.

    U.S.

    Dep't

    of Labor

    Plan,

    supra

    note

    19,

    at

    3;

    see also

    U.S.

    Dep't

    of

    Labor

    Report,

    supra

    note

    20,

    at

    3

    ( Over

    the

    course of the

    20th

    century,

    he

    composition

    f the

    labor force

    shifted rom

    ndustries

    ominated

    by

    primary

    roduction

    occupations,

    uch as

    farmers nd

    foresters,

    o

    those

    dominated

    y

    professional,

    echnical,

    nd

    service

    workers. ).

    24.

    U.S.

    Dep't

    of

    Labor

    Plan,

    upra

    note

    19,

    at 4.

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    6/27

    2005]

    REPAYMENT

    AGREEMENTS 1299

    Just

    s the need

    for

    technology-sawy

    mployeesgrows,

    o does

    the need forformalob training.25ew woulddenythatthe twentieth

    century

    aw

    [e]ducationplay[]

    an

    important

    ole

    n

    the advancement

    of

    the individual

    worker,

    the

    workforce,

    nd

    the

    economy. 26

    Employees

    rely

    on

    training pportunities

    s

    incentives or

    hoosing

    particular

    ine of work

    or a

    particular

    mployer.27

    ccording

    to one

    study,

    30

    percent

    of those

    surveyed

    claimed that

    training

    opportunities

    ere an

    extremelymportant

    actor

    n

    choosing

    heir

    careers.28

    ikewise,

    many arge professional

    ervices

    firms dvertise

    their

    raining pportunities

    o

    help

    recruit

    op

    talent.29ust

    y visiting

    a company'sWeb site,one can discover hevastarray f educational

    courses

    available

    to its

    employees.

    One law

    firm,

    ing

    &

    Spalding,

    boasts

    K&S

    University,

    formal ducational

    curriculum

    esigned

    to offer

    ttorneys rofessional

    evelopment pportunities

    t all

    stages

    of their

    careers.30

    Broadly

    speaking,

    employees

    recognize

    that

    education

    eads

    to

    marketability,

    arketability

    eads

    to

    professional

    advancement,

    and

    professional

    advancement

    leads

    to

    personal

    satisfaction.

    With

    training

    becoming

    a

    necessity

    for

    anyone

    looking

    to

    succeed in today'sworkforce, ow does one become trained?More

    specifically,

    who

    should

    pay

    for

    this

    training?

    Obviously,

    formal

    education

    plays

    a

    major

    role

    in

    helping

    ndividuals

    evelop

    skills hat

    25. See

    id. at 3

    ( Increasingly,

    he

    majority

    f

    obs

    will need

    workers

    who have

    acquired

    knowledge

    nd skills

    via

    two-year

    olleges,

    vocational

    training,

    moderate

    to

    long-term

    n-the-

    job

    training,

    nd

    real world

    xperience. ).

    26.

    U.S.

    Dep't

    of

    Labor

    Report,

    upra

    note

    20,

    at 6. See also U.S.

    Dep

    t of Labor

    Plan,

    supra

    note

    19,

    at

    41

    ( Knowledge

    workers

    ow

    account

    for third

    f

    the

    American

    workforce,

    outnumberingactory orkers ytwotoone. ).

    27. See

    Stone,

    upra

    note

    13,

    at

    722

    ( Employees

    see

    the

    growth

    f their

    human

    apital

    and

    the enhancement

    f

    their abor

    market

    pportunities

    s one of the

    benefits

    f the

    ob.

    Jobs

    re

    often valuated

    and

    selected on

    the

    basis

    of whether

    nd how

    much

    opportunity

    or

    earning

    and skill

    nhancement

    re

    provided. ).

    28.

    CAPPELLI,

    upra

    note

    1,

    at 24.

    The same

    study

    found

    that

    47

    percent

    of workers

    characterize

    heir

    nterest

    n

    professional

    evelopment

    s

    important.

    d.

    29.

    Many company

    Web

    sites,

    nd

    especially

    hose

    of

    professional

    ervice

    firms,

    out

    their

    emphasis

    on

    employee

    training

    o

    help

    attract

    talented workers.

    See,

    e.g.,

    AIG,

    Career

    Development,

    at

    http://www.aig.com/careers/about_dev_frameset.htm

    last

    visited

    June

    19,

    2005)

    (on

    file

    with he

    Duke

    Law

    Journal);

    Bank of

    America,

    Team

    Bank of

    America,

    t

    http://

    www.bankofamerica.com/teambank/index.cfm?template=tb_leaddevlast

    visitedJune

    19,2005)

    (on

    filewith

    he Duke

    Law

    Journal);

    McKinsey

    &

    Company,

    Broaden

    Your Career

    Options,

    t

    http://www.mckinsey.com/aboutus/careers/undergraduates/broadencareeroptions/index.asp

    last

    visitedJune

    19,

    2005) (on

    file

    with he

    Duke

    Law

    Journal).

    30.

    King

    &

    Spalding

    LLP,

    K&S

    University,

    t

    http://www.kslaw.com/training/training.asp

    (last

    visitedJune

    19,

    2005) (on

    filewith

    he Duke

    Law

    Journal).

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    7/27

    1300

    DUKE LAW JOURNAL

    [Vol.

    54:1295

    will

    translate nto success

    throughout

    heircareers.

    Universities,

    communityolleges,nd vocationalchools, ll typicallyaidforby

    the

    mployee/worker,rovide

    foundationf

    necessary

    ccupational

    competencies.

    Government

    programs

    also

    help support

    the

    cultivation f the Americanworkforce.31

    elfare

    programs

    nd

    subsidies created

    through egislation

    uch as the Workforce

    Investmentct32llocate

    government

    ollars o assist

    rimarily

    ow-

    income

    workers

    n

    attaining

    he

    ob

    skills

    required

    o

    compete

    n

    today's

    workplace.

    Most

    often, owever,

    merican

    ompanies ccept

    heburden f

    educatingheir wnemployees.33hisarrangementeems to work

    wellfor

    oth

    mployee

    nd

    employer.

    ew

    employees

    ould

    isagree

    that

    formal ducation

    provides

    he framework ithinwhichone

    builds the

    expertise

    necessary

    o sustain a

    living.

    Marketable

    professional

    kills,

    uch s howto

    interpretcompany

    alance heet

    or how

    to weld

    together

    wo

    pieces

    of

    iron,

    can be

    taught

    nd

    understood

    n

    the

    lassroom;ften, owever,

    n

    employee's

    kills

    will

    fully

    lourish

    nly

    within

    heir

    professional

    ontext.34s Aristotle

    stated:

    Forthe

    hings

    hichwe have o earn

    eforewe can do

    them,

    we learnby doing. 35urther,rom n employer's erspective,

    business

    will

    ften

    otrealize he

    full

    alueof an

    employee

    ntil he

    learns

    the

    employer's

    methods,

    echniques,

    nd

    systems.

    n

    those

    situations,

    ormal

    raining

    s

    only

    a

    jumping-offoint.

    On-the-job

    31.

    See,

    e.g.,

    Workforce

    nvestmentAct

    of

    1998,

    Pub. L. No.

    105-220,

    112 Stat. 936

    (codified

    n

    scattered ections f

    20 U.S.C. and 29

    U.S.C.).

    32. Id. In its tatement f

    purpose,

    heWorkforcenvestment ct

    proclaims

    he

    following:

    The

    purpose

    of

    this

    ubchapter

    s

    to

    provide

    workforcenvestment

    ctivities,

    hrough

    statewide and

    local

    workforce nvestment

    ystems,

    hat increase the

    employment,

    retention,

    nd

    earnings

    f

    participants,

    nd increase

    occupational

    kill

    ttainment

    y

    participants,

    nd,

    as a

    result,

    mprove

    he

    quality

    of

    the

    workforce,

    educe welfare

    dependency,

    nd enhance the

    productivity

    nd

    competitiveness

    f the

    Nation.

    29

    U.S.C.

    2811

    (2000).

    33.

    Gary

    Becker

    argues

    that

    mployer

    nvestmentn

    training

    s,

    n

    actuality,

    n

    employee

    investment,

    ince

    the

    employee

    presumably grees

    to a

    lower

    alary

    n

    payment

    or he

    acquired

    skills.

    Gary S.

    Becker,

    Human Capital: A

    Theoretical

    and

    Empirical

    Analysis,

    with

    Special

    Reference

    to

    Education

    33-51

    (3d

    ed.

    1993)

    (discussing pecific

    nd

    general

    training

    f

    employeesby

    their

    mployers).

    34.

    Daron

    Acemoglu

    &

    Jorn-Steffen

    ischke,

    Beyond

    Becker:

    Training

    n

    mperfect

    abor

    Markets,

    109

    ECON. J. 112

    (Feb. 1999)

    (noting

    the

    advantages

    of

    investment n

    workplace

    training

    nstead of

    general

    education,

    because

    on-the-job

    raining

    llows

    employers

    o

    target

    specific

    kill

    ets

    required

    o

    keep

    the business

    n

    pace

    with

    echnological

    rogress).

    35.

    Aristotle,

    Nicomachean

    Ethics 34

    (Martin

    Ostwald

    trans.,

    962).

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    8/27

    2005]

    REPAYMENT

    AGREEMENTS

    1301

    training

    urthers ducation

    by merging

    lassroom

    study

    with

    real-

    world xperience.

    Employer

    investment

    n

    such

    training

    an take

    many

    forms:

    proprietary

    raining

    urricula

    uilt

    by

    the

    employer pecifically

    or

    ts

    employees,

    funding

    ommitments

    or

    employees

    to attend classes

    taught

    by

    a third

    party,

    nd

    informal

    pprenticeship rograms

    re

    examples

    of

    a few of the more common

    methods.36 o meet the

    financial

    demands

    of

    training

    nd

    retaining

    n

    adequate

    workforce,

    an

    employer

    must llocate

    an enormous

    portion

    f its annual

    budget

    to

    employee

    development.

    According

    to one

    report,

    American

    companiesspend moremoneyon education thando all the public

    school

    systems

    n

    the United States.37

    Further,

    nce an

    employer

    has

    paid

    for

    training,

    n

    employee

    forever

    etains

    monopolypower

    over

    his

    skills,

    which

    an be used to

    obtain

    additional

    compensation

    from

    competing

    businesses.38 uch

    like

    any

    other

    nvestment,

    mployers

    will invest

    n

    training nly

    if

    they

    an

    recoup

    that

    nvestment

    y

    exploiting

    he skillsof those

    who

    receive

    the

    training.39

    n that

    sense,

    human

    capital

    is

    indistinct rom

    nonhuman

    apital:

    employers

    weigh

    the

    costs of investments

    made

    in worker kills gainst he stream fbenefitshey xpectfrom aving

    more

    skilled

    employees. 40

    f the costs

    of investment

    re

    enlargedby

    the

    risk that

    an

    employee

    can receive

    the

    training

    without

    any

    contract

    r commitment

    o remain

    with

    he

    employer

    ong enough

    to

    provide

    an

    investment

    eturn,

    n

    employer's

    incentive

    to

    invest

    optimally

    n

    training

    diminishes.41

    his risk

    is

    heightened

    if

    an

    36. In-housetraining as becomeless common s companies truggle o assesswhat skills

    are

    required

    n an

    ever-changing

    conomy.

    CAPPELLI,

    upra

    note

    1,

    at 198-220.

    Rather,

    s new

    degree-specific

    chools

    like

    the

    University

    f

    Phoenix

    grow

    in

    popularity,

    mployers

    find

    t

    more

    cost

    effective

    o outsource

    training

    o third

    parties.

    n those

    cases,

    employers

    might ay

    for

    raining

    n a

    specific

    iscipline

    with

    hopes

    of

    building

    narrower

    nowledge

    base within he

    company.

    By Cappelli's

    account,

    72

    percent

    of the

    University

    f

    Phoenix's

    tuition evenue

    s

    derived

    from

    mployers

    ubsidizing

    heir

    mployees'

    chooling.

    d. at 209.

    37.

    David

    Lange,

    Guest

    Commentary,

    raining rograms

    hould

    Be

    Seen

    as

    Investment,

    Not

    Expense,

    NASHVILLE

    Bus.

    J.,

    Sept.

    15,

    2003,

    available

    at

    http://www.bizjournals.com/

    nashviUe/stories/2003/09/15/smallb5.html?t=printable.

    38. See

    Stewart

    E.

    Sterk,

    Restraints

    n

    Alienation

    f

    Human

    Capital,

    79

    Va. L.

    Rev.

    383,

    392-93

    (1993)

    (discussing

    he risk

    of

    employer

    nvestment

    n

    training

    f

    ong-term

    mployment

    contractsre not

    upheld).

    39.

    CAPPELLI,

    upra

    note

    1,

    at 46.

    40. Id.

    41. The

    growing

    number

    of

    opportunities

    waiting

    those

    who choose

    to leave their

    employer

    fter

    eing

    trained

    xacerbates

    his

    problem.

    ee

    id. at 182-S7

    providing

    xamples

    of

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    9/27

    1302

    DUKE

    LAW

    JOURNAL

    [Vol.

    54:1295

    employee

    as the

    opportunity

    ot

    only

    o

    leave

    with kills

    hat he

    employerubsidized,ut lso to use those kills gainsthe mployer

    byworking

    or

    competitor

    usiness.42

    Other ationales lso

    support

    he

    need to

    protect

    nvestment

    n

    training.

    lack of

    protectiongainst mployee

    mobility

    cts

    as a

    double

    hit to the

    employer,

    hichnot

    only

    oses

    its

    monetary

    investment

    n

    developing

    he

    employee's

    kill et but

    also sacrifices

    potential

    market

    dvantage

    o the

    ompetitor

    ho s able to enlist

    he

    recently

    eparted

    mployee.43

    aking

    matters orse s that he

    ossof

    trained

    mployees

    eaves the

    employer

    withno residual

    nterest,

    unlikemany raditionalorms f businessnvestment.he free-rider

    principle rovides

    n

    additional ationale:

    f

    he

    mployer

    as no

    way

    to

    protect

    ts

    nvestment,

    ompetitors

    eluctanto

    invest n

    training

    can

    recruit

    ell-trained

    mployees

    ithout

    aving

    o assume he ost

    ofthe

    raining.

    Thus,

    employers

    eeking

    to recruit

    top

    talent

    and

    stay

    competitive

    ithin

    oday's

    workforce ave a

    significant

    nterest

    n

    protecting

    heir nvestmentsn

    training.

    s discussed

    n Part

    II,

    traditional

    oncompetes

    re an ineffective eansof

    doing

    o,

    and

    better lternatives,uch as repaymentgreements,xist.But to

    appreciate

    these

    alternatives,

    ne must first understand

    he

    traditional

    ationales for

    noncompetes,

    he current tate

    of

    noncompete

    aw,

    and

    how

    regularly

    courts have enforced

    noncompetes

    o

    protect

    n

    employer's

    raining

    nvestment.

    II.

    Noncompete

    Agreements

    A.

    Public

    Policy

    Rationales

    Numerous

    ublic

    policy

    considerationsave led

    to

    divergent

    opinions

    egarding

    he

    degree

    o which

    noncompete

    lausebetween

    an

    employer

    nd an

    employee

    hould e

    upheld.

    or

    instance,

    ome

    courts

    have

    found that

    freedom

    f contract

    rinciples upport

    the

    widespread

    use of

    golden

    handcuffs nd

    signing

    bonuses as methods of

    poaching

    top

    talent

    way

    from

    ompeting usinesses).

    42.

    See

    Rachel S.

    Arnow-Richman, argainingfor Loyalty

    n the

    Information ge:

    A

    Reconsideration

    f

    the

    Role

    of

    Substantive

    airness n

    Enforcing mployeeNoncompetes,

    0

    OR.

    L. Rev.

    1163,

    1203-04

    2001)

    ( [D]espite

    the

    strategicmportance

    f

    cultivating

    nternal

    alent,

    employers

    may

    not make

    such

    investments

    or fear that their

    efforts

    will

    merely

    aid the

    competition. ).

    43. Id.

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    10/27

    2005]

    REPAYMENT

    AGREEMENTS 1303

    enforcing

    ll contracts

    ade

    between

    ompetent arties,

    o

    long

    as

    those ontractsre neitherllegalnorunconscionable.44oncompete

    agreements

    etween

    mployer

    nd

    employee,

    t has been

    argued,

    all

    under this

    general

    rule.45

    oncompete

    dvocates lso

    argue

    that

    restrictionsre

    necessary

    o subvert

    ttemptsyrogue mployees

    o

    poach

    trade ecrets

    nd customer

    ists,

    which ould be used to

    gain

    advantage

    ver

    former

    mployers.46

    his

    seems to follow

    naturally

    from he

    contentionhat

    an

    employer

    eserves

    right

    o

    protect

    investment

    n ts wnbusiness.47

    If

    noncompetes

    re not

    enforced,

    mployers

    will

    lack the

    incentiveospendmoney reatingrade ecrets nd customerists.48

    Such

    investment

    urthersusiness

    goals,

    creates

    ompetition,

    nd

    contributes

    o theoverallwelfare

    f the

    economy.

    ome

    proponents

    of strict

    nforcement

    o

    even furthernd

    argue

    that n

    employer

    should

    have a

    right

    o

    use

    noncompetes

    o

    protect

    ny

    nvestment

    n

    its

    business,

    ncludingmployee

    raining.49ecognizing

    he

    ignificant

    outlay

    n

    training

    osts,

    hose

    proponents

    upport

    he

    protection

    f

    training

    nvestment

    hould he

    beneficiary

    f the

    training

    erminate

    employment.50

    44.

    See,

    e.g.,

    UniCredito

    taliano SPA

    v.

    JPMorgan

    Chase

    Bank,

    288 F.

    Supp.

    2d

    485,

    499

    (S.D.N.Y.

    2003)

    ( Sophisticated

    parties

    .. are held

    to the terms

    f

    their

    ontracts. );

    Wiard v.

    Liberty

    Northwest

    ns.

    Corp.,

    79 P.3d

    281,

    285

    (Mont. 2003) ( [T]he parties

    o a contract

    may

    agree

    to

    anything

    hat

    s not

    llegal,

    riminal,

    r

    immoral

    ).

    But see Maureen B.

    Callahan,

    Comment,

    ost-Employment

    estraint

    greements:

    Reassessment,

    2

    U.

    CHI.

    L. REV.

    703,

    704

    (1985) (suggesting

    hat

    although

    American

    law

    generally

    upholds agreements

    rrived at

    by

    competent

    arties,

    ost-employment

    estraints o

    not share this

    presumption

    f

    validity).

    45. See Stone, supra note 13, at 740 ( When an employment elationship ncludes a

    covenant

    not to

    compete

    .. it is reasonable

    to

    assume that the

    employee

    has consented to

    restrictions

    n his

    or her

    post-employment

    ctivities.

    ccordingly,

    here s a

    strong

    rgument

    or

    courts

    o enforce

    he covenant

    ).

    46.

    See,

    e.g.,

    Water

    Servs.,

    nc.

    v. Tesco

    Chems.,

    nc.,

    410

    F.2d

    163,

    170

    (5th

    Cir.

    1969)

    ( Although

    ovenants

    not to

    compete

    are

    proper

    o

    protect

    rade ecrets

    heymay

    also be valid

    simply

    o

    prevent

    former

    mployee's

    using

    his

    expertise

    gainst

    his former

    mployer. );

    ee

    also

    Blake,

    supra

    note

    2,

    at 627

    ( From

    the

    point

    of

    view of the

    employer,

    ostemployment

    restraints

    re

    regarded

    as

    perhaps

    the

    only

    effective

    method of

    preventing nscrupulous

    competitors

    or

    employees

    from

    appropriating

    valuable trade information

    nd customer

    relationships

    or heir

    wn

    benefit. ).

    47. See

    Arnow-Richman,

    upra

    note

    42,

    at 1170

    [N]oncompetes

    an

    be seen as

    legal

    tools

    necessary

    o

    preserve

    ey

    business nterestsndrelationships. ).

    48. See

    Blake,

    supra

    note

    2,

    at

    627

    (suggesting

    hat

    employersmight

    equire

    covenants o

    protect

    nvestment

    n

    research

    nd

    development).

    49. See

    infra

    art

    II.A.

    50. See

    infra

    art II.A.

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    11/27

    1304

    DUKE

    LAW

    JOURNAL

    [Vol.

    54:1295

    On

    the other

    hand,

    those

    decrying

    mployment

    oncompetes

    generallydvancefour olicy ationales.51irst, omescholars ave

    expressed

    oncern hat estrictiveovenants

    re

    anticompetitive.52

    f

    employees

    re hindered rom

    moving

    aterally

    etween

    ompanies,

    firms

    an tie

    up

    valuablehuman

    apital

    nd create

    monopoly

    n

    market alent.53

    ccording

    o

    Professor

    arlan

    Blake,

    noncompetes

    diminish

    ompetitiony

    ntimidating

    otential

    ompetitors

    nd

    by

    slowing

    own hedisseminationf

    deas,

    rocesses,

    ndmethods. 54

    Second,

    pponents

    ave criticized

    oncompetes

    or

    hindering

    worker's

    ability

    to earn a

    living. Geographic

    and durational

    noncompetes,fenforced,ould imit n employee'sbilityo take

    advantage

    f her

    talents nd

    provide

    ustenance

    orher

    family.55

    o

    the same

    extent hat n

    employermight

    e reluctanto invest

    n

    employee

    raining

    f

    employment

    oncompetes

    ere

    unenforceable,

    an

    employee

    who

    values

    ob transferabilityight

    e ambivalent

    o

    generalob

    training

    f

    restrictive

    ovenant

    bstructedhat

    mployee

    from

    tilizing

    he

    newly

    cquired

    knowledge

    utside f her current

    employment.

    uch

    a

    result

    could

    stunt he

    development

    f the

    American

    orkforce.56

    The final woprimaryolicy onsiderationsre invoked ess

    frequently.

    ome courts

    have

    rejected noncompetes

    hat allow

    employers

    o

    take

    advantage

    f

    superior argainingositions

    o the

    detrimentf

    their

    mployees.57

    ssuming paternalistic

    ole,

    ourts

    51.

    Mitchelv.

    Reynolds,

    4

    Eng.

    Rep.

    347,

    348-50

    Ch. 1711).

    See

    generally

    allahan,

    upra

    note 44

    (arguing

    hat the

    restraint-of-trade

    ationale,

    he

    employee-protection

    ationale,

    and the

    loss-to-society

    ationaledo not

    sufficiently

    arrant

    nenforceability

    f

    noncompetes).

    52. Blake,supranote2,at627.

    53. Id.

    54.

    Id.

    55.

    See,

    e.g.,

    ABC v.

    Wolf,

    420

    N.E.2d

    363,

    368

    (N.Y. 1981)

    (recognizing

    hat

    despite

    a

    strict

    pproach

    to

    enforcement f

    ..

    covenants,

    public policy

    mandates

    skepticism

    oward

    restrictions

    impairing

    he

    employee's

    bility

    o earn a

    living

    r the

    general

    ompetitive

    mold

    of

    society );

    All-Pak,

    nc. v.

    Johnston,

    94 A.2d

    347,

    351

    (Pa.

    Super.

    Ct.

    1997)

    ( [I]n determining

    whether o

    enforce

    post-employment

    estrictive

    ovenant,

    we must

    balance the interest he

    employer

    eeks to

    protect gainst

    he

    mportant

    nterest f the

    employee

    n

    being

    ble to earn a

    living

    n his

    chosen

    profession. ).

    56.

    See

    Stone,

    upra

    note

    13,

    at

    722

    ( Employees

    see the

    growth

    f

    theirhuman

    apital

    and

    the

    enhancement

    f their

    abor market

    pportunities

    s

    one of the

    benefits f the ob. ); U.S.

    Dep't

    of

    Labor

    Plan,

    supra

    note

    19,

    at 5

    ( The

    fast

    pace

    of

    technological

    hange

    will . .

    require

    that

    workers

    ommit hemselves

    o

    lifelong earning

    f

    [the]

    Nation's

    workforce s to remain

    competitive

    n the21st

    Century. ).

    57.

    See Schmidl v.

    Cent.

    Laundry

    &

    Supply

    Co.,

    13

    N.Y.S.2d

    817,

    823

    (Sup.

    Ct.

    1939)

    (recognizing greater

    differentialn

    bargaining

    ower

    between

    employer

    nd

    employee

    than

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    12/27

    2005]

    REPAYMENT

    AGREEMENTS

    1305

    that

    cite this rationale when

    striking

    own restrictions

    ssume that

    employers, iventheir n-house egal resources and experience, re

    more

    sophisticated argainers

    nd

    likely

    to induce

    employees

    nto

    unnecessarily

    estrictiveovenants.

    Lastly,

    ome courts re

    reluctant

    to enforce

    noncompetes

    that

    deprive

    the

    public

    of an

    employee's

    effort nd

    productivity;58

    escribed

    by

    one commentator s the loss-

    to-society

    rationale,59

    his

    line

    of

    reasoning

    is rare

    in

    today's

    jurisprudence.60

    B.

    Case Law

    Giventhe

    complex

    policy

    onsiderations hat re folded nto the

    analysis,

    t is no

    surprise

    hat

    many

    states have been reluctant o

    establish

    a consistent

    standard for

    analyzing noncompetition

    agreements.

    he American

    case law

    in this

    area has been

    described

    by

    one

    court as

    a sea vast

    and

    vacillating,overlapping

    and

    bewildering. 61

    ithout onsistent

    tandards,

    ourtshave

    struggled

    o

    find olid

    footing

    n a field

    of

    legal uncertainty.62

    ften,

    ourtsuse a

    balancing

    est

    whereby

    he

    various

    policy

    considerations re

    weighed

    to determine

    the outcome

    best

    attuned to

    the interestsof the

    employee,

    mployer,

    nd the

    general

    public.63

    he focusof this test

    between

    two

    corporate

    ntities);

    Arthur

    Murray

    Dance Studios

    v.

    Witter,

    05

    N.E.2d

    685,

    704

    (Ohio

    1952) (expressing

    oncern

    hat

    n

    employee's

    bargaining

    isadvantage

    ould

    produce

    a

    rash,

    mprovident

    romise ).

    But see

    Hilb,

    Rogal,

    & Hamilton

    Agency

    of

    Dayton

    v.

    Reynolds,

    610

    N.E.2d

    1102,

    1107

    (Ohio

    Ct.

    App.

    1992) ( While

    an

    employment

    elationshipmay by

    definition

    esult

    n an

    employer

    having slightly

    etter

    bargaining

    osition

    han

    an

    employee,

    this

    disparity

    n

    bargaining ower

    s

    inherent n the

    relationship

    nd is not sufficient

    o render

    contract nenforceablebsent showing f abuse]. ).

    58.

    See,

    e.g.,

    Tarr

    v.

    Stearman,

    105 N.E.

    957,

    961

    (111.

    914) (finding

    he interests

    f the

    public

    to

    be

    paramount,

    nd

    stressing

    oncern

    fornot

    ust

    the financial

    rofits

    o be

    made

    from

    rades

    r

    professions,

    ut

    theconvenience

    f

    the

    public

    s

    well ).

    59.

    Callahan,

    upra

    note

    44,

    at 712.

    60. See

    Blake,

    supra

    note

    2,

    at

    686

    (recognizing

    hat

    he courts

    usually

    ook at the

    burden

    on the

    employee

    nd

    almost

    never consider

    he

    njury

    o

    society eparately);

    Callahan,

    supra

    note

    44,

    at

    706

    ( [T]hough

    [the

    loss

    to

    society'

    rationale]

    s not much

    relied

    upon

    today,

    hese

    agreements

    were

    once

    considered

    a

    threat to the

    economy

    because

    they

    could remove

    a

    productive

    erson

    from he

    work

    force. ).

    61.

    Arthur

    Murray

    ance

    Studios,

    05 N.E.2d

    at 687.

    62. See Tamara Loomis, Non-Compete

    Pacts: Whether

    These

    Agreements

    Hold

    Up

    Is

    Uncertain,

    .Y.L.J.,

    Aug.

    24,

    2000,

    at 6

    ( At

    the end of the

    day,

    however,

    he one

    thing

    hat s

    certain

    with

    non-compete

    greement

    s that

    nothing

    s

    certain. ).

    63. See

    Bendinger

    v.

    Marshalltown

    rowell

    Co.

    [sic],

    994 S.W.2d

    468,

    472

    (Ark.

    1999)

    ( We

    review

    ases

    involving

    ovenants

    not

    to

    compete

    on a

    case-by-case

    basis. );

    42 AM. JUR.

    2D

    Injunctions

    138

    2003) ( A

    court

    may

    ook

    at the

    equities

    on both ides

    n

    deciding

    whether

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    13/27

    1306

    DUKE

    LAW

    JOURNAL

    [Vol.

    54:1295

    becomes hereasonablenessfthe

    restraint,

    onsidering

    he

    needs

    of

    both mployeendemployer.64hiscase-by-casepproach otonly

    provides

    ittle

    uidance

    orfuture ourt

    roceedings,

    t also

    hinders

    the

    employer's bility

    o

    predict

    which ontracts

    re

    likely

    o be

    upheld

    n

    court.65uch

    uncertainty

    esults

    n

    a vast

    amount

    of

    litigation

    ver the

    validity

    f

    noncompete

    greements,66

    dding

    another

    ostto an

    already-expensivemployer

    nvestment

    n human

    capital.67

    The

    degree

    o which tates

    will

    nforce

    oncompetes

    aries.On

    one

    end,

    a few statesfavor

    rejection

    f all restraints

    f

    trade,

    leaving oom or nly handful fnoncompeteshat re sonarrowly

    defined s to

    have a

    negligible

    ffect n the

    employee's

    ight

    o

    practice

    is trade.68

    n the other

    nd,

    Judge

    Richard

    Posnerhas

    to issue an

    injunction

    rohibiting

    former

    mployee

    from

    ompeting

    withhis or

    her former

    employer ).

    64.

    See,

    e.g.,

    All

    Stainless nc. v.

    Colby,

    308

    N.E.2d

    481,

    485

    (Mass. 1974) (determining

    enforceability y

    weighing

    the reasonable needs of the former

    mployer

    .

    .

    against

    both the

    reasonableness f the restraint

    mposed

    on the former

    mployee

    nd the

    public

    nterest ).

    65. See PeterJ.Whitmore, Statistical nalysis fNoncompetitionlauses nEmployment

    Contracts,

    5 J.

    CORP.

    L.

    483,

    485

    (1990)

    ( [I]t

    still s difficultor

    awyers

    o

    predict

    onfidently

    how a

    courtwill react to

    any

    givennoncompetition

    lause. );

    Greg

    T.

    Lembrich,Note,

    Garden

    Leave: A

    Possible Solution o

    the Uncertain

    nforceabilityf

    Restrictive

    mployment

    ovenants,

    102

    COLUM.

    L.

    REV.

    2291,

    2303

    (2002) ( The

    lack of

    consistency

    hat ourtshave

    demonstrated

    in

    deciding

    hese

    cases has led to an

    atmosphere

    f

    uncertainty,

    hich

    may help

    to

    explain

    why

    lawyers

    ind t

    very

    difficulto advise

    clients. ).

    66.

    See

    Whitmore,

    upra

    note

    65,

    at

    485

    ( [T]he ambiguity urrounding

    he

    enforceability

    of

    these clauses

    has resulted n vastamounts

    f

    itigation

    nd

    reported ppellate

    decisions. )

    67.

    One factor ften

    ndervalued n the

    determination

    f

    noncompete

    nforceability

    s

    the

    degree

    to which

    mployer

    nvestmentmustbe

    protected.

    ut

    simply,

    he

    greater

    he cost of an

    investment,

    he

    higher

    he

    return n

    employer

    xpects.

    ee

    infra

    art II.B.

    Employer

    ncentive

    to trainemployees hingeson seeinga return n that nvestment.ee supra Part I. Likewise,

    employer

    ncentive o establish

    noncompetes

    s

    directly

    elated to the

    ability

    o enforce hem

    without

    ostly itigation.

    iven the

    difficulty

    n

    balancing

    ach of the

    givenpolicy

    onsiderations

    and the

    unpredictability

    f

    udicial

    enforcement,

    his Note

    stipulates

    hat the

    employer

    must

    assume

    greater

    responsibility

    n

    ensuring

    he

    validity

    f

    its

    noncompetes.

    ee

    infra

    Part III.B.

    One

    type

    of

    noncompete

    that

    might

    be more

    consistently

    pheld,

    advocated

    herein

    as

    an

    alternative o

    traditional

    oncompetes,

    s the

    post-employmentepayment

    greement,

    iscussed

    infra

    art

    II.B.

    68.

    California

    law,

    for

    instance,

    stipulates

    that

    every

    contract

    by

    which

    anyone

    is

    restrained rom

    ngaging

    n a

    lawful

    profession,

    rade,

    r

    businessof

    any

    kind s to that xtent

    void.

    Cal. Bus. &

    PROF. Code

    16600

    (West 1997).

    California ourtshave

    interpreted

    his

    statute

    o acceptnot even reasonable restraints f trade.See, e.g.,Metro Traffic ontrolv.

    Shadow

    Traffic

    Network,

    2

    Cal.

    App.

    4th

    853,

    859

    (Cal.

    Ct.

    App.

    1994) ( Section

    16600 has

    specifically

    een

    held to

    invalidate

    employment

    ontractswhich

    prohibit

    n

    employee

    from

    working

    or

    competitor

    when the

    employment

    as

    terminated,

    nless

    necessary

    o

    protect

    he

    employer's

    rade

    ecrets. ).

    Courts

    will,however,

    llow a

    very

    imited

    xception

    f he

    employee

    is barred

    from

    ursuing nly

    small or

    limited

    art

    of the

    business,

    rade or

    profession.

    BM

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    14/27

    2005]

    REPAYMENT

    AGREEMENTS

    1307

    advocated

    per

    se

    enforceability

    f

    noncompetes ubject

    only

    to

    the

    traditional octrines ffraud, uress, r unconscionability.69urther,

    many

    tateseven allow a blue

    pencil

    test,

    whereby

    ortions

    f the

    employment

    ontractdeemed too

    restrictive

    may

    be

    removed from

    the

    agreement,eaving

    he restof the

    noncompete

    nforceable.70

    Despite

    some

    inconsistency

    between

    states,

    common

    frameworkshave

    emerged

    to

    settle issues of

    enforceability.

    s

    previously

    described,

    most courts are

    wary

    of

    upholding

    contracts

    that

    restrict

    n

    individual's

    right

    to

    pursue

    a trade.71n

    addition,

    although

    many

    courts

    disfavor

    noncompetes,72

    ome

    courts find

    v.

    Bajorek,

    191 F.3d

    1033,

    1040

    9th

    Or.

    1999)

    (quoting

    Campbell

    v. Bd.

    of

    Trs. of

    The Leland

    StanfordJunior

    Univ.,

    817 F.2d

    499,

    502

    (9th

    Cir.

    1987)).

    Other

    states,

    uch as

    Alabama and

    North

    Dakota,

    have devised similar

    tatutory rohibitions

    f

    noncompetes.

    ALA.

    CODE

    8-1-

    l(a) (1975);

    N.D.

    CENT. CODE

    9-08-06

    1987)

    (voiding noncompetes,

    nd

    making tatutory

    exceptions

    nly

    for

    he

    sale of

    a

    business r the dissolution f

    a

    partnership).

    69.

    See Outsource

    Intl.,

    Inc.

    v.

    Barton,

    192 F.3d

    662,

    670-71

    (7th

    Cir.

    1999) (Posner,

    J.,

    dissenting) advocating widespread

    enforcement f

    noncompetes

    and the

    application

    of a

    reasonablenesstest

    only

    to

    address

    questions

    of

    fraud,duress,

    or

    unconscionability);

    ee also

    Eraser Co.

    v.

    Kaufman,

    138

    N.Y.S.2d

    743,

    750-51

    (Sup.

    Ct.

    1955)

    ( Negative

    covenants n

    employmentontracts re not presumptivelynvalid and will be enforced n the absence of

    proof

    that

    they

    are

    unconscionable,

    nequitable,

    or in contravention f

    public

    policy. );

    Callahan,

    supra

    note

    44,

    at 725

    ( [T]he

    doctrine f

    unconscionabilityrovides

    n

    appropriately

    limited mechanismfor

    protecting mployees

    in

    those narrow circumstanceswhere

    udicial

    scrutiny

    f contractss

    actually ustified. ).

    70.

    The blue

    pencil

    test

    has

    been

    applied

    in a few variations.Some courts take a

    restrictive

    pproach

    by removing nly

    the unreasonable

    provisions

    f

    a

    contract

    hat

    re

    easily

    severable

    from he valid

    provisions.

    ee,

    e.g.,

    Hahn

    v.

    Drees,

    Perugini

    &

    Co.,

    581 N.E.2d

    457,

    461-62

    (Ind.

    Ct.

    App.

    1991) (eliminating

    n

    easily

    removable

    phrase

    that

    suggested

    an

    employee

    would not

    be allowed to deal with clients

    obtained

    prior

    to his

    employment);

    Bridgestone/Firestone,

    nc.

    v.

    Lockhart,

    F.

    Supp.

    2d

    667,

    683

    (S.D.

    Ind.

    1998)

    (reserving

    he

    right

    o

    remove

    overly

    broad restrictions

    rom he terms f

    a

    contract

    when

    doing

    so does not

    expand the original anguage of the agreement).More commonly,modern courts exercise

    greater

    reedom

    o

    modify

    r rewrite

    nreasonable

    provisions

    hat

    re unenforceable s written.

    See,

    e.g.,

    Nestle Food Co.

    v.

    Miller,

    36 F.

    Supp.

    69,

    78

    (D.R.I.

    1993) (applying

    Rhode Island's

    rule of

    partial

    nforcement

    o

    modify

    he terms

    f a

    noncompete

    when

    necessary

    o

    protect

    the

    employer's

    nterests).

    71.

    Courts

    re

    generally

    more

    ikely

    o

    uphold

    noncompetes

    or ale of businesses hanfor

    employment

    ontracts.

    n the former

    ituation,

    noncompete

    willrestricthe seller

    of a

    business

    from

    ompeting

    with

    the

    buyer

    for a

    particular

    uration fter he

    sale is consummated. he

    sales

    price

    of a business

    will include the value

    of that business'

    goodwill.

    Serena

    L.

    Kafker,

    Golden

    Handcuffs: Enforceability

    f

    Noncompetition

    Clauses in

    Professional Partnership

    Agreements

    f

    Accountants,

    hysicians,

    nd

    Attorneys,

    1 Am.

    BUS.

    L.

    J.

    31,

    33

    (1993).

    72. See, e.g., Amex Distrib. Co. v. Mascari, 724 P.2d 596, 600 (Ariz. Ct. App. 1986)

    ( Restrictive

    ovenantswhich

    tend to

    prevent

    n

    employee

    from

    pursuing

    similarvocation

    after

    termination

    f

    employment

    re

    disfavored. );

    Poole v. Incentives

    Unlimited, nc.,

    548

    S.E.2d

    207,

    209

    (S.C.

    2001)

    ( [Covenants

    will be

    critically

    xamined nd construed

    gainst

    he

    employer. );

    Modern

    Env'ts,

    nc. v.

    Stinnett,

    61 S.E.2d

    694,

    695

    (Va. 2002)

    ( [Covenants

    in

    restraint f trade

    are not

    favored,

    will be

    strictly

    onstrued, nd,

    in the

    event of

    an

    ambiguity,

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    15/27

    1308 DUKE

    LAW

    JOURNAL

    [Vol.

    54:1295

    that

    policy

    interests

    warrant

    enforceability

    nder certain

    circumstances.73

    In

    assessing

    uch

    ircumstances,

    ourts

    ommonly

    se a

    two-part

    test o delineate etween nforceablend unenforceable

    rovisions.74

    First,

    noncompetes

    re

    permitted

    when

    the

    employer

    can

    demonstratehat he

    contracts

    necessary

    o

    protect

    n

    employer's

    legitimate

    business interests.75

    f

    the

    employer

    establishesa

    protectable

    nterest,

    he

    noncompete

    will become

    presumptively

    enforceable

    nd the burden

    will

    hift o

    the

    employee.76

    econd,

    o

    overcome his

    resumption

    nd void he

    ontract,

    he

    mployee

    must

    showthattheagreements unreasonablen itsscope,geographic

    boundaries,

    r

    duration,

    r that t is

    particularlynjurious

    o the

    interests f the

    generalpublic.77

    f these unreasonablenessactors

    sufficientlyutweigh

    the

    employer'sprotectable

    nterests,

    he

    noncompete

    ill

    e

    voided.78

    This

    reasonableness

    est

    enerally

    nvolves

    eighing

    he

    need to

    protect

    he

    employer's

    usiness

    gainst

    he

    agreement's

    ppressive

    effects

    n

    the

    employee.79

    xcessive

    eographic

    nd time

    estrictions

    will

    be

    construed n

    favor of the

    employee. );

    see also Gillian

    Lester,

    Restrictive

    ovenants,

    Employee

    Training,

    nd

    theLimits

    f

    Transaction-Cost

    nalysis,

    6

    IND.

    L.J.

    49,

    54

    (2001) ( As

    a

    presumptive

    matter,

    contracts

    restricting

    postemployment employee mobility

    are

    unenforceable

    t common

    aw. ).

    73.

    See

    supra

    notes61-70.

    74.

    Restatement

    (Second)

    of

    Contracts

    188

    (1981)

    characterizes his test as

    follows:

    (1)

    A

    promise

    o

    refrain rom

    ompetition

    hat

    mposes

    a restrainthat s

    ancillary

    o

    an

    otherwise

    alid transaction r

    relationship

    s

    unreasonably

    n

    restraint f

    trade f

    (a)

    the

    restraints

    greater

    han s needed

    to

    protect

    he

    promisee's

    egitimate

    nterest,

    or (b) the promisee'sneed is outweighedbythehardship o the promisor nd the

    likely

    njury

    o

    the

    public.

    75.

    For

    examples

    of

    cases

    demonstrating

    his

    nalysis,

    ee

    Blake,

    supra

    note

    2,

    at 651-84.

    76.

    Id.

    77.

    Though

    many

    cholars

    gree

    that he

    loss-to-society

    ationale s

    not

    favored

    by

    most

    contemporary

    ourts,

    t least a

    handfulof

    cases have

    employed

    this

    policy argument

    when

    determining

    he

    enforceability

    f

    restrictive

    ovenants

    against

    physicians

    nd

    dentists.

    ee

    Kafker,

    upra

    note

    71,

    at

    37-41

    (discussing

    ases that

    nticipate

    he

    njury

    o

    society

    resulting

    from

    nforceability

    f

    noncompetes gainst

    physicians

    nd

    dentists).

    t is worth

    mentioning

    hat

    the

    public

    interest

    rgument

    works

    both

    ways

    for

    these cases: courts

    might

    trikedown a

    noncompete

    or

    restricting

    doctor's

    ability

    o

    provide

    medical services o a

    particular egion,

    but

    conversely

    ourts

    might phold

    a

    noncompete

    hat

    will distribute

    octors o other

    reas of

    thestate. d

    78.

    Blake,

    supra

    note

    2,

    at

    651-84.

    79.

    Lester,

    upra

    note

    72,

    at

    54-57;

    see

    also,

    e.g.,

    Availability

    nc. v.

    Riley,

    336

    So.

    2d

    668,

    669-70

    (Fla.

    Dist.

    Ct.

    App. 1976)

    (upholding

    a

    noncompete

    restricting

    n

    employee

    from

    working

    within

    one-hundred-mile

    adius

    when the

    employer

    conducted 85

    percent

    of its

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    16/27

    2005]

    REPAYMENT

    AGREEMENTS

    1309

    are

    the

    factors hat

    will most

    often

    result

    n

    unenforceability,80

    ut

    provisionshatunreasonably estrictn employee'srangeofactivities

    may

    also

    be

    invalidated.81

    urther

    onsiderations,

    uch as whether he

    employee

    was

    involuntarily ischarged82

    r

    whetherthe

    employee

    provides

    a

    unique

    service

    to the

    business,83

    ay

    also factor nto the

    reasonableness

    alculus.

    Questions

    arise

    over

    what

    types

    of

    employer

    nterests re

    likely

    to be

    protectable.

    Many

    commentators

    gree

    that the two interests

    most

    n need of

    protection

    re trade secrets nd customer ists.84

    y

    providing

    ompanies

    with rade secret

    protection,

    he Uniform

    rade

    Secrets Act helps companies to guard informationhat derives

    independent

    economic

    value,

    actual

    or

    potential,

    from not

    being

    generally

    nown

    o

    .. other

    persons

    who can obtain

    economicvalue

    from

    ts disclosure

    or

    use,

    and is the

    subject

    of efforts hat

    are

    reasonable

    under

    the circumstances

    to maintain

    its

    secrecy. 85

    However,

    because

    the statute

    does

    not

    fullyprotect

    the

    employer

    from

    disclosure,86

    urther

    protection,

    n

    the

    form of restrictive

    covenants,

    s needed.

    business

    within

    hatradius

    nd when

    the

    employee

    was

    otherwise

    well able to

    support

    himself

    and

    his

    family );

    owa Glass

    Depot,

    Inc. v.

    Jindrich,

    38

    N.W.2d

    376,

    382

    (Iowa

    1983)

    ( Proximity

    o customers

    s

    only

    one

    aspect.

    Other

    aspects,

    ncluding

    he nature

    of the business

    itself,

    ccessibility

    o

    information

    eculiar

    to the

    employer's

    business,

    nd the nature

    of the

    occupation

    which

    s

    restrained,

    must e

    considered

    long

    withmatters f

    basic

    fairness. ).

    80.

    For

    a

    general

    discussion

    of

    time,

    geography,

    nd

    scope

    restrictions,

    ee

    Blake,

    supra

    note

    2,

    at

    674-84.

    81.

    Id.

    82.

    See,

    e.g.,

    Ma &

    Pa,

    Inc. v.

    Kelly,

    342

    N.W.2d

    500,

    502

    (Iowa

    1984) (distinguishing

    he

    discharge

    f an

    employee

    from n

    employee

    resignation

    nd

    finding

    discharge to

    be]

    a factor

    opposing hegrant f an injunction ).

    83.

    Compare

    Ticor

    Title

    ns. Co.

    v.

    Cohen,

    173 F.3d

    63,

    70-72

    (2d

    Cir.

    1999) (applying

    New

    York

    law

    to

    uphold

    a

    noncompete

    when the

    employer

    eeking

    nforcement

    emonstrated

    hat

    the

    employee

    had

    built

    unique

    relationships

    ith

    limited

    roup

    of

    clients

    n the real estate

    title

    insurance

    ndustry

    nd that

    those

    clients

    had been

    developed

    at

    the

    employer's

    xpense)

    with

    Vander

    Werf

    v. Zunica

    Realty

    Co.,

    208

    N.E.2d

    74,

    77

    (111.App.

    Ct.

    1965) (refusing

    njunctive

    relief

    o an

    employer

    when

    there

    was

    no

    showing y

    defendant

    hat

    the

    employer's]

    methods

    of

    doing

    business

    were

    original

    r

    unique ).

    84.

    See,

    e.g.,

    Lester,

    upra

    note

    72,

    at 54-55.

    85.

    Unif.

    Trade Secrets

    Act

    1,

    14 U.L.A.

    433

    (1990).

    86.

    Whereas

    the

    Trade Secrets

    Act

    merelyprovides

    tort

    remedy

    for n

    employer

    nce

    trade secret disclosureoccurs, a restrictive oncompeteideally preventsdisclosurefrom

    occurring

    n the

    first

    lace.

    Also,

    if

    charges

    re

    brought

    gainst

    n

    employee

    for

    breach of

    trade

    secret

    aw,

    the

    employer

    isksdisclosure

    f

    the

    protected

    sset

    n court.

    Lester,

    upra

    note

    72,

    at

    53.

    For

    these

    reasons,

    noncompetes

    fill

    gap

    whereother

    egal

    and

    extra-legal

    mechanisms

    all

    short.

    d. For

    a

    general

    discussion

    f the

    need

    for

    noncompetes

    n trade

    secret

    aw,

    see id.

    at

    52-53.

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    17/27

    1310 DUKE

    LAW

    JOURNAL

    [Vol.

    54:1295

    Similarly,

    ourts ave been

    willing

    o

    uphold

    noncompetes

    hat

    protectnemployer'snvestmentnprocuringndmaintaininglient

    relationships.87

    ales-intensive

    usinesses,

    ike

    technology

    onsulting

    or

    insurance

    ompanies,

    re driven

    y

    customer

    elationships;

    uch

    businesses ften

    spend huge

    sums

    of

    money

    to

    develop

    these

    relationships. y

    one

    account,

    costs

    of customer

    relationship

    management

    oftware,

    ommonly

    sed

    by

    businesses

    o track ontact

    with

    customers nd

    analyzepurchasing atterns,

    an

    range

    from

    several

    housand

    ollars or

    basic

    ystem

    o

    $50,000

    er

    alesperson

    for

    more

    sophisticated roducts.88

    ecause of this

    significant

    investmentn developingustomer ata, employers o not want

    salespeople

    o

    depart

    with lients hat he

    company pent ignificant

    money

    o

    develop.

    Otherwise,

    ompanies

    have little ncentive

    o

    invest t

    the outset.

    Accepting

    his

    rationale,

    ourts

    have

    upheld

    covenants

    arrowly

    rawn o

    protect

    nvestments

    n

    customer

    ata.89

    Despite

    courts'

    general

    willingness

    o

    protect

    employer

    investment

    n

    trade

    ecrets nd customer

    ists,

    more ontroversial

    question

    s

    whether

    udges

    should

    protect mployer

    nvestment

    n

    employee

    raining.

    Most courts ee investment

    n

    training

    s an

    employee xpense, ot an employerost, he udicialprotectionf

    which s not

    legitimate

    oncern.90 small

    minority

    f

    courts

    llows

    companies

    o

    protect

    nvestments

    n

    training,

    f

    the

    protection

    s

    narrowly

    onstructed.91he

    remainder f thisNote addresses

    he

    issue of

    noncompetes

    s an

    effective eansof

    protectingmployer

    87.

    The

    misappropriation

    f

    customer ists

    generated

    for

    both

    sales of

    services,

    uch as

    accounting

    or

    consulting

    companies,

    and

    sales of

    fungible goods

    have been

    deemed

    as

    protectablenterests. ee, e.g.,Fair Assoc, Inc. v. Baskin,530 S.E.2d 878,881 (N.C. Ct.App.

    2000)

    (finding

    hat

    behavioral

    onsulting

    irm

    ad a

    protectable

    nterestn

    limiting

    he risk f

    client

    misappropriation y

    a

    consultant-employee

    hen

    work

    require

    d]

    that ts Consultants

    develop

    an

    intimate

    elationship

    ith

    ts

    clients );

    Arnow-Richman,

    upra

    note

    42,

    at 1176 n.40

    ( Cases

    which are

    particularly

    onvincing

    o

    courts

    are those in

    which the

    product

    sold is

    fungible

    r

    where

    it is

    easy

    for the

    customerto

    mistake

    the

    sales

    person

    with the actual

    employer. ).

    88.

    See Erika

    Morphy,

    The

    Real Cost

    of

    CRM,

    NEWSFACTOR

    ECHNOLOGY

    NEWS

    (Oct.

    29,

    2001)

    ( [P]er-seat

    costs for

    high-complexityrojects

    that have

    1,000

    users start t

    around

    US$50,000

    and

    slowly

    rop

    to

    about

    $15,000

    s

    the number f users

    ncreases

    o

    5,000. )

    at

    http://www.newsfactor.com/story.xhtml?story_id=14447on

    file

    with

    he Duke Law

    Journal)',

    Emma

    Nash,

    The

    High

    Cost

    ofCRM,

    COMPUTERWEEKLY.COM

    Aug.

    17,

    2001)

    (describing

    he

    rising ost of CRM

    software)

    t

    http://www.computerweekly.com/Articlel05058.htm

    on

    file

    with

    he

    Duke

    Law

    Journal).

    89. See

    supra

    note 87.

    90.

    See

    infra

    art II.A.

    91.

    See

    infra

    art II.A.

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    18/27

    2005]

    REPAYMENT AGREEMENTS 1311

    investment

    n

    training

    nd

    questions

    whether

    epayment greements

    provide more suitable lternative.

    III. NONCOMPETES VS.

    REPAYMENT AGREEMENTS

    With

    employers

    hard-pressed

    o

    protect

    their

    investments

    n

    training,

    hey

    often ook to

    noncompete

    agreements

    s a means

    of

    protection.

    However,

    the area of

    noncompete

    aw is

    in

    a constant

    state

    of

    flux;

    tates,

    ontinually eevaluating

    heir

    noncompete

    aws,

    play

    a

    perennial

    game

    of

    catchup

    as

    market conditions

    revolutionize mployment atterns nd practices.This environment

    has

    resulted

    n

    employer

    onfusion

    n

    predicting

    whether ovenants

    will be

    upheld

    and court

    frustration

    t

    having

    to

    constantly

    evise

    employment

    aw doctrine.92

    epayment

    greements

    ffer

    less

    risky,

    and

    more

    suitable,

    method

    for

    protecting

    employer training

    investment.

    A.

    Traditional

    oncompetes

    re Unsuitable

    rotection

    gainst

    Training

    nvestment

    oss

    The increasingvolume of employee trainingsuggests that

    employers

    will continue

    o use

    noncompete

    greements

    s a

    way

    to

    protect

    heir

    raining

    nvestments.

    owever,

    courts

    have

    historically

    disfavored

    covenants

    designed

    solely

    to

    protect

    an

    employer's

    investment

    n

    training.93

    survey

    of

    105

    noncompete

    cases did not

    even

    find he

    employer's

    nvestment

    n

    training ignificant

    nough

    to

    warrant

    discussion.94

    Although

    some

    contemporary

    ourts have

    occasionally

    held

    these

    nvestments

    o

    be

    protectable

    when the cost

    s

    92.

    See

    CAPPELLI,

    upra

    note

    1,

    at 1-16.

    93.

    See,

    e.g.,

    USAchem,

    Inc.

    v.

    Goldstein,

    12

    F.2d

    163,

    167 n.4

    (2d

    Cir.

    1975) ( [T]he

    fact

    that

    a former

    mployee

    was

    trained

    by

    the

    employer

    s not a basis

    for

    granting

    n

    injunction

    enforcing

    restrictive

    ovenant. );

    Kelsey-Hayes

    Co.

    v.

    Maleki,

    765

    F.

    Supp.

    402,

    407

    (E.D.

    Mich.

    1991),

    vacated,

    889

    F.

    Supp.

    1583

    (E.D.

    Mich.

    1991) (holding

    that

    whatever

    xpertise

    defendant

    eveloped

    as

    a

    computer

    rogrammer

    t

    Kelsey-Hayes,

    with

    he assistance

    f on-the-

    job

    instruction

    nd

    published

    manuals,

    has been

    his

    alone,

    historically,

    nd would

    not fallwithin

    the

    proscription

    f

    contracts

    rotecting

    n

    employer's

    propriety

    r confidential

    nformation );

    Clark

    Paper

    &

    Mfg.

    Co.

    v.

    Stenacher,

    40

    N.E.

    708,

    711-12

    (N.Y.

    1923) (refusing

    o

    protect

    n

    employer's

    nvestment

    n

    the

    generaltraining

    f a

    wrapping apersalesperson);

    Kidde Sales

    &

    Serv.,

    Inc.

    v.

    Peairson,

    493 S.W.2d

    326,

    330

    (Tex.

    Civ.

    App.

    1973) (stating

    the court's

    unwillingness

    o

    enforce

    noncompetes

    o

    protect

    raining

    even

    ifthe

    training

    as

    complex

    nd

    extensive ).

    94.

    Stone,

    supra

    note

    13,

    at 751

    (citing

    Peter J.

    Whitmore,

    A

    Statistical

    Analysis of

    Noncompetition

    lauses

    n

    Employment

    ontracts,

    5 J.CORP.

    L.

    483,

    524-25 & n.243

    1990)).

    This content downloaded from 103.231.241.233 on Sat, 09 Aug 2014 08:01:16 UTCAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 8/11/2019 Protecting Employer Investment in Training

    19/27

    1312

    DUKE LAW

    JOURNAL

    [Vol.

    54:1295

    significant,95

    ourts

    enerally

    avenot ccorded

    nvestment

    n

    training

    the ame protectable tatus rantedo trade ecrets nd customer

    lists.96

    This has

    left cholars o debatewhethernvestment

    n

    training

    should

    e a

    protectable

    nterest.

    erhaps

    he

    most

    ecognized

    heory

    attacking

    ovenants

    rotecting

    mployer

    nvestment

    n

    training

    s

    Professor

    ary

    Becker's

    human

    apital

    model.97ecker

    begins

    with

    the

    premise

    hat

    wodistinct

    ypes

    f

    training

    xist:

    eneral

    raining,

    which

    ncreases n

    employee'smarketability

    o

    many

    firms,98

    nd

    specific

    raining,

    hich

    nhances

    n

    employee's

    alue

    only

    o the

    firm

    providinghetraining.99ccordingo Becker'smodel,neither f

    95.

    See,

    e.g.,

    Borg-

    Warner

    Protective

    erv.

    Corp.

    v.

    Guardsmark, nc.,

    946

    F.

    Supp.

    495,

    501

    (E.D.

    Ky. 1996)

    (finding

    private security

    irm's nvestm