paper 4 communal areas prelims proof 2 - kubatana.net

64
Zimbabwe Working Paper 4 The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas DALE DORÉ United Nations Development Programme Comprehensive Economic Recovery in Zimbabwe Working Paper Series 2009

Upload: others

Post on 06-Feb-2022

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Zimbabwe

Working Paper 4

The Recovery and Transformationof Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

DALE DORÉ

United Nations Development Programme

Comprehensive Economic Recovery in ZimbabweWorking Paper Series

2009

Working Paper 4

The Recovery and Transformation ofZimbabwe’s Communal Areas

DALE DORÉ

Copyright © UNDP [2009]

All rights reserved

Layout and Design: Fontline International

The views expressed in this publication are those of the authorsand do not necessarily represent those of the United Nations or UNDP

iii

Team Members of UNDPs Working Paper Series v

Foreword vi

Executive Summary vii

Acronyms viii

Section 1: Introduction 11.1 The Creation of the Communal Lands 11.2 Constraints to Smallholder Agricultural Production in the Communal Areas 11.3 Outline of Paper 2

PART I

STRATEGIES, CRISIS AND RECOVERY

Section 2: An Overview of Performance After Independence (1980–1997) 52.1 Development Strategies: Intensification, Resettlement and Migration 52.2 Fading Hopes for Sustainable Smallholder Development 72.3 Economic Liberalization (1990–1997) 10

Section 3: The Deepening Crisis (1997–2009) 123.1 The Onset of Political and Economic Instability (1997–2000) 123.2 Zimbabwe’s Crisis Years (2000–2007) 133.3 Impact on Smallholders in the Communal Areas 143.4 Zimbabwe’s Rapid Regression (2008–2009) 18

Section 4: Policy Recommendations for Recovery 194.1 Prerequisites for Agricultural Recovery and Growth 194.2 Re-engagement with the International Donor Community 204.3 Emergency Food Aid and Household Food Security 204.4 Recovery Policies for Rebuilding Smallholder Agriculture 224.5 Rethinking Social Protection Measures 23

PART II

COMMERCIALIZATION AND TRANSFORMATIONECONOMIC THEORY, INTERNATIONAL EXPERIENCE AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS

Section 5: Reconceptualizing the Binding Constraints 265.1 Agriculture’s Role in Pro-poor Growth 265.2 Land Tenure in the Communal Areas 265.3 Agricultural Extensification and Environmental Degradation 28

Section 6: Land Tenure Reform 306.1 Transforming Subsistence Agriculture 306.2 Policy Principles and Options 316.3 Farm Size and Commercialization 336.4 The Land Reform Implementation Process 34

Table of Contents

iv

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

Section 7: Policy Support for Smallholder Agriculture 367.1 Investment in Public Goods 367.2 A Growth and Poverty Reduction Model 397.3 Agricultural Markets, Food Security and Price Volatility 40

Section 8: Structural Transformation 428.1 The Process of Structural Transformation 428.2 China’s Transformation 428.3 A Transformation Scenario for Zimbabwe 438.4 Spatial Structure and Urban Development 458.5 An Evolving Unimodal Agrarian Structure 46

Section 9: Concluding Remarks 48

Bibliography 49

v

Dr Dale Doré is the Director of Shanduko in Harare, a non-profit research institute on agrarian andenvironmental issues in Zimbabwe. After an undergraduate degree in Business Adminstration, hecompleted his M.Sc in Regional and Urban Planning at the University of Zimbabwe, and his D.Phil inAgricultural Economics at the University of Oxford. Prior to joining the UNDP recovery strategyresearch team, he was the coordinator of a WWF and IUCN community-based natural resourcemanagement programme in five Southern Africa countries, and later a land tenure specialist for afour country study in S.E.Asia on behalf of the Center for International Forestry Research and theFAO.

Professor Tony Hawkins is currently Professor of Economics at the Graduate School of Managementat the University of Zimbabwe, an institution which he founded. Professor Hawkins received hisB.A. in Economics from the University of Zimbabwe, was a Rhodes Scholar at Oxford where heread for a B.Litt in Economics, and a Fulbright Fellow at Harvard. He has written extensively on theZimbabwean economy with a special focus on the private sector, and consulted for a range ofinternational organizations including the World Bank, UNIDO, UNDP, UNCTAD and SADC.

Dr Godfrey Kanyenze is the Director of the Labour and Economic Development Research Institute ofZimbabwe (LEDRIZ). Prior to this he was an economist with the Zimbabwe Congress of TradeUnions (ZCTU) and statistician with the Central Statistical Office (CSO) in Harare. He currentlyalso serves as a member of the Technical Committee of the Tripartite Negotiating Forum (TNF) andthe Tripartite Wages and Salaries Advisory Board. He received his B.Sc in Economics at the Universityof Zimbabwe, his Masters at the University of Kent, and completed his Ph.D in Labour Economics atthe Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex (UK).

Professor Daniel Makina is currently Professor of Finance and Banking at the University of SouthAfrica in Pretoria. Following his B.Acc at the University of Zimbabwe, Professor Makina completedhis M.Sc in Financial Economics at the School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London,and his Ph.D. at the University of the Witwatersrand in Johannesburg. He has also taught at theGraduate School of Management at the University of Zimbabwe, and conducted training programmesfor public servants from Sudan and South Africa in public financial management.

Dr Daniel Ndlela is a Director of Zimconsult, a consultancy firm in Harare. He completed hisundergraduate degree at the Higher Institute of Economics in Sofia, Bulgaria, and his Ph.D at theUniversity of Lund, Sweden. After serving as Principal Economist at the Ministry of Planning andDevelopment in the early 1980s, he lectured at the Department of Economics at the University ofZimbabwe. He briefly served as Deputy Dean of the Faculty of Social Studies at the University ofZimbabwe before becoming a Senior Regional Advisor at the United Nations Economic Commissionfor Africa (UNECA). He has consulted extensively for, amongst others, the World Bank, COMESA,SADC, UNIDO and UNCTAD.

UNDP Chief Technical Adviser

Dr Mark Simpson completed his B.Sc (Econ) and Ph.D at the London School of Economics, and hisMasters at the School of Oriental and African Studies, University of London. Prior to his posting toUNDP Zimbabwe, Dr. Simpson served with the UN’s Department of Peace-Keeping Operations inmissions in Angola and East Timor, and with UNDP in Mozambique.

Team Members of UNDPs Comprehensive EconomicRecovery in Zimbabwe Working Paper Series

vi

This UNDP working paper on Zimbabwe's communal areas seeks to build on some of the insights andanalyses contained in the UNDPs Comprehensive Economic Recovery in Zimbabwe – A DiscussionDocument which was launched in 2008. Many of the ideas and suggestions it contains are not thereforeentirely new, but the policy-relevant analysis and recommendations it puts forward have been buttressedboth by more detailed work in the field of agricultural economics as well as by drawing on comparativecase studies which were seen by the author to have some relevance to the Zimbabwe context.

Given UNDPs global mandate in the area of poverty reduction, and the currently prevailing high rates ofpoverty in Zimbabwe's communal areas, the need to ensure that future recovery in Zimbabwe is broad-based and equitable is foremost in the minds of the UNDP country office. This specific working paper istherefore offered as a contribution to an ongoing public debate as to how to overcome the variousconstraints affecting that segment of the Zimbabwean population which currently reside in those areas inorder to trigger sustainable growth and poverty reduction.

Dr Agostinho ZacariasUNDP Resident Representative

Mr Lare SisayUNDP Deputy Resident Representative

Dr Mark SimpsonChief Technical Adviser, Recovery StudyUNDP

Foreword

vii

At independence in 1980 Zimbabwe inherited a dual agrarian structure that had seen white commercialfarmers prosper in good farming areas while hundreds of thousands of poor black families struggled tosubsist on smallholdings in the communal areas, much of it in semi-arid areas with poor soils. It wasestimated that there were nearly three times more people living in the communal areas than the landcould sustain. The Zimbabwe Government therefore prioritized the communal areas for development byintensifying agriculture and initiating a programme of resettlement and migration to decongest them.

The smallholder sector made significant gains, surpassing the commercial sector in maize and cottonproduction in the mid-1980s. Ambitious plans were laid to intensify production by land-use reorganizationand establishing consolidated villages in which to concentrate physical and social infrastructure. Theresettlement programme aimed to resettle 162,000 families, while over 300,000 families were expectedto migrate to towns and cities. But these hopes faded by the end of the 1980s. Output declined, villageplanning stalled, the rate of resettlement slowed to a trickle, and the expected migration of households tourban centres failed to materialize. In the meantime, the communal area population had swelled to aboutone million households.

In 1994 the Land Tenure Commission made far-reaching recommendations for addressing the underlyingproblems facing the communal lands, but the government's attentions had turned to land redistribution.After the government launched its fast track land resettlement programme in 2000, it poured huge resourcesinto sustaining newly resettled farmers, but did little to assist communal smallholders. As the governmenttook control over domestic food supplies, communal families became increasingly dependent oninternational humanitarian and food aid.

Since the formation of the inclusive government, the emphasis has been on maintaining the requiredlevels of international humanitarian assistance through food aid, smallholder cropping packs, seed fairsand vouchers to improve household food security. As soon as Zimbabwe's government re-engages fullywith the donor community, it should reduce dependence on such handouts and stimulate smallholderproduction by opening up agricultural credit, input and commodity markets. It then needs to address theunderlying and pervasive constraints that make smallholder agricultural production untenable in mostcommunal areas.

The pressure of population, under a traditional farming system that provides cost-free access to land,results in the continual subdivision of household plots that are too small to sustain livelihoods based onagricultural production, especially in the semi-arid regions. By enabling some farmers to consolidate theirholdings into more viable units, while facilitating the transfer of others into alternative non-farm livelihoods,both the remaining farmers and those engaged in higher productivity non-farm activities will benefitsignificantly. The basic mechanism for this process of commercialization, migration and poverty reductionis a land rental and sales market. The second necessary condition to enable this structural transformationof the rural economy is rapid economic growth in the manufacturing and service sectors of the economy.Over time, as development proceeds, commercialization and transformation will dissolve the existingdual agrarian structure, intensify agricultural production and decongest the communal areas.

Executive Summary

viii

Acronyms

AFC Agricultural Finance Corporation (now Agribank)Agritex Agricultural and Technical Extension ServicesARDA Agricultural and Rural Development AuthorityC-SAFE Consortium for Southern Africa Food EmergencyDFID Department for International Development (UK)DRSS Department of Research and Specialist ServicesFAO Food and Agricultural OrganizationFTLRP Fast Track Land Reform ProgrammeGDP Gross Domestic ProductGMB Grain Marketing BoardICG International Crisis GroupOECD Organization for Economic Co-operation and DevelopmentRBZ Reserve Bank of ZimbabweSADC Southern African Development CommunitySTERP Short Term Economic Recovery ProgrammeUNDP United Nations Development ProgrammeUSAID United States Agency for International DevelopmentWFP World Food ProgrammeZIMCORD Zimbabwe Conference on Reconstruction and Development

1

1.1 THE CREATION OF THECOMMUNAL LANDS

On account of the British Colonial Office’smisgivings about the conduct of the BSA Company,the 1898 Southern Rhodesia Order-in-Councilrequired the Company to ensure that sufficientsuitable land was set aside as reserves for theAfricans’ traditional agricultural requirements‘within which the life of the natives might becontinued under protection and control’. Under itsprovisions, a patchwork of 108 reserves wasdemarcated. After 1900, a succession of landcommissions progressively entrenched the divisionof land between Europeans and Africans, creatingstaggering differences in the size of land holdingsbetween black subsistence smallholders and whitecommercial farmers. Writing in 1962, Floyd wasto observe that ‘although modifications havecertainly been made over the intervening years,the basic pattern of land allocation has persistedwithout radical change from the turn of the centurydown to the present time’ (1962: 231).

By independence in 1980, about 5,600 whitecommercial farmers had access to 15.5 millionhectares of the more productive farmland heldunder freehold tenure, while over 760,000smallholders had to earn their livelihoods from 16.4million hectares of communal land held undercustomary tenure, much of it in arid areas with

poor soils. This dual economy – an impoverishedtraditional sector, the other a thriving modern sector– was the single most enduring feature ofZimbabwe’s agrarian structure (Ndlela, 1981).After 2000, the Fast Track Land ReformProgramme (FTLRP) saw the settlement of about135,000 new farmers on former commercial farms.Although this partially broke the mould of the dualeconomy, the constraints inherent within thecommunal farming system remain daunting(Zimbabwe, 2003).

1.2 CONSTRAINTS TOSMALLHOLDER AGRICULTURALPRODUCTION IN THECOMMUNAL AREAS

One of the defining features of Zimbabwe’scommunal sector is its relatively poor agriculturalpotential. At independence, as Table 1 shows, themost productive land in Natural Regions I and IIwas held by large scale commercial farmers, whilemost of the communal farming areas fell into NaturalRegions IV and V, with very limited agriculturalpotential (Vincent and Thomas, 1961).1

Relatively high and reliable rainfall defines NaturalRegions I and II. Although they only cover 17.2percent of the total land area, the exploitation oftheir high agricultural potential, mainly by

Section 1

Introduction

Table 1: Natural Regions and land classification (1980)

LAND CATEGORYNATURAL (FARMING) REGIONS

I II III IV V

Large-scale commercial farms 71 69 45 28 26Communal areas 13 21 39 50 49Small-scale farming areas – 4 4 4 2State land 16 6 12 18 23

TOTAL PERCENTAGE 100 100 100 100 100

Percentage of total area 1.8 15.4 17.5 36.4 28.9

Source: Zimbabwe Communal Lands Development Plan (1986a: p.96, Table 4)

1 Vincent and Thomas (1961) used rainfall patterns and soil characteristics to define five Natural Regions (I–V), which correspondto different zones of agricultural potential in Zimbabwe.

2

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

commercial farmers, made them the mostproductive farming areas in Zimbabwe. In NaturalRegions III rainfall diminishes and becomes lessreliable. As this reduces their potential for cropproduction, farming systems based on crops andlivestock production are recommended. The dryconditions in Natural Region IV allow a farmingsystem based largely on livestock production withsome drought resistant crops as a sideline. InNatural Region V rainfall is so low and erratic thatthe only viable farming system is one based onextensive cattle or game ranching. In sum, risk anduncertainty are endemic to dryland farming systemson which hundreds of thousands of rural householdsdepend for their livelihoods (Campbell et al., 2002).

A second distinguishing feature of the communalareas is a burgeoning population operating withina traditional system of agriculture dominated byland tenure arrangements whereby local leadersallocate arable land to households and their familieson a usufruct basis.2 Effectively this means thatland cannot be officially rented, bought and sold.Another drawback is the continual subdivision ofland into smaller and less viable holdings as thepopulation grows. In the absence of a land market,this tenure system has no mechanism to consolidatesmall plots into more viable farm sizes. As thepopulation builds up households must access landin more marginal farming areas unsuitable forcultivation, setting in motion a debilitating processof extensive and shifting cultivation (Lele andStone, 1989).

A third defining feature of the communal areas’farming system is the household’s entitlement tocommon property resources, such as water forhousehold use and irrigation, woodlands forfirewood and building, and pastures for grazingcattle and other livestock. Although there is anextensive literature on the management of commonproperty resources (see, for example, DanielBromley’s Making the Commons Work and NilsChristoffsen’s Natural Resource Management inSouthern Africa), the translation of institutionaltheory into the sustainable management of commonproperty resources has been floundering. Theproblem lies in communities trying to devise rules– that involve high transaction costs and which are

continually buffeted by the vagaries of humannature – to counter powerful but perverse economicincentives for individuals to benefit by theirunsustainable use of natural resources. Despitefour decades of critiques of Hardin’s Tragedy ofthe Commons (1968), the basic tenets of hisargument still hold true today. Deforestation,overgrazing, and the silting of dams in the communalareas bear witness to the externalization ofenvironmental costs as individuals benefit fromusing a public resource but bear few of the costs.

The fourth and last main defining feature ofZimbabwe’s communal areas is their stunted urbangrowth coupled with very poor infrastructure andservices. Typically, the communal settlementpattern consists of tiny scattered farms, punctuatedevery few kilometres with small ramshackle ruralcentres that serve the immediately surroundingcommunities. A study by Heath (1978) that rankedthe size of urban centres in Zimbabwe found thatthe largest centre in the communal areas wasMurewa, ranked 34th. All the other 33 larger urbancentres were located in the commercial areas.

1.3 OUTLINE OF PAPER

This paper is broadly divided into two parts. Part Iexamines the economic trajectory of Zimbabwefrom independence to the present. The mainstrategies for the development of the communalareas – intensification, resettlement and migration– and their eventual demise are explored in Sections2 and 3. In Section 4 the basic requisites foragricultural recovery are outlined. It suggestsimmediate humanitarian measures that are requiredto relieve the plight of the poor, and those short-term policy measures required for smallholderagricultural recovery in the communal areas.

Part II looks beyond short-term agriculturalrecovery measures towards the long-term policiesrequired for sustainable poverty reduction throughthe commercialization and structural transformationof the communal areas. Section 5 sets out thebinding constraints faced by smallholders,especially how, under population pressure, thetenure system sub-divides land into countless, small

2 Although the Communal Areas Act (1982) grants authority of land allocation to the rural district council, the power to allocateland often remains vested in traditional leaders.

3

Section 1 – Introduction

and unviable holdings, and how capital is graduallysqueezed out of the traditional agricultural system.A closer look is taken in Section 6 at the need totranscend standard agricultural interventions thataddress the symptoms of poverty, and start dealingwith the underlying causes of poverty. It is arguedthat land tenure reform is the lynch-pin that enablesfactor markets to operate efficiently; and moreover,that this is a pre-condition for allocative efficiency,increased factor productivity, commercializationand transformation. It also suggests how commonproperty resources can be managed better. With

these insights, Section 7 examines smallholderagricultural policies, and public and private sectorinvestment in agriculture – especially infrastructure,research and extension – that support tenurereforms, commercialization and poverty reduction.Part II closes with Section 8 which shows howthe process of structural transformation couldcreate pathways out of poverty by decongestingthe communal areas through migration, and howrural centres could become the focal points in thetransformation process. Section 9 contains someconcluding remarks.

4

PART I

STRATEGIES, CRISIS AND RECOVERY

5

2.1 DEVELOPMENT STRATEGIES:INTENSIFICATION,RESETTLEMENT ANDMIGRATION

After independence, the new Zimbabwe Govern-ment tasked itself with reconstructing a war-torneconomy and building a more egalitarian society.In March 1981 the Zimbabwe Conference onReconstruction and Development (ZIMCORD)was held to garner donor support. The ZIMCORDdocument recounted what were by then familiarproblems in the communal areas:

‘Because of the relatively small area of landallocated and the consequent populationpressure, the poor quality of land, andtraditional farming practices, the productivityof the land is rapidly declining. Landallocations to heads of households are nowoften smaller than the minimum size requiredto support a family. As the number ofcultivators grows, more and more grazing landis converted to crop use and the rate ofdeterioration of the soils accelerates. It isestimated that, given the right ecologicalconditions, the traditional areas should becapable of supporting about 275,000cultivators with present technology. However,in 1977 there were 2,5 times that number.’(Zimbabwe, 1981b: 37)

The key development objective was therefore toreduce poverty by relieving the pressure ofpopulation and livestock on communal land andnatural resources. The conference documenttherefore reiterated the government’s three keypolicy objectives for the communal areas:

• To intensify agriculture in the communal areasby making the ‘priority objective to transformand develop the rural peasant sector’(Zimbabwe, 1981b: 3);

• To resettle communal area farmers on formercommercial farms to decongest the communalareas;

• To encourage ‘non-farming’ family to migrateto urban centres where family breadwinnerslived and where employment opportunitieswould be created’ (ibid: 40).

Intensification

To signal its intent to uplift smallholder agriculture,the government appointed the former president ofthe Commercial Farmers Union, Dennis Norman,as the new agriculture minister. The governmentalso appointed a Commission of Inquiry into theAgricultural Industry under the chairmanship ofProfessor Gordon Chavunduka at the time of theZIMCORD conference, in March 1981. TheCommission’s report noted, ‘At the heart of theproblem lies the issue of improving smallholderproduction, particularly in the communal areas’(Zimbabwe, 1982a: 7). It specifically avoided theuse of the term ‘commercial farmer’ because itbelieved that the prime objective of agriculturalpolicy should be to encourage all farmers to becomecommercial farmers. The assumption that communalfarmers would remain at subsistence productionlevels, it added, was no longer appropriate.

A promising start was made in 1981. For the firsttime smallholders were included in negotiatingagricultural commodity prices betweengovernment and the farmers unions. A huge 40percent increase in the price of maize, from Z$85to Z$120 per tonne, was agreed for the 1981/82agricultural season. In the wake of an exceptionallygood season, the supply response to this pricingpolicy was dramatic, both on output, whichincreased from 1.6 million tonnes to 2.9 milliontonnes, and on farmers’ real returns (Herbst, 1990).To bring in the anticipated harvests, the GrainMarketing Board (GMB) penetrated deep into thecommunal areas by opening up an extensive

Section 2

An Overview of Performance After Independence(1980–1997)

6

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

network of grain silos, collection points and feederdepots. The number of grain collection depots inthe communal areas was expanded from threebefore independence to 60 by 1988 (Zimbabwe,1988).

In addition, there was a massive expansion in farmcredit. The number of Agricultural FinanceCorporation (AFC) loans to smallholders grew fromnearly 24,000 in 1981 to a peak of over 95,000 in1986 (Chimedza, 1994). To circumvent theconstraint imposed by the lack of collateral underthe traditional agricultural system, the governmentextended loans to communal farmers on the basisof stop orders3 that the GMB held over theirdeliveries to its depots. The injection of smallholdercredit into communal areas also enabled the privatesector, especially the fertilizer and seed companies,to explore their own marketing opportunities. Thedevelopment of small seed packs by the Seed Co-op, for example, saw a 90 percent adoption ofhybrid maize seed in the communal areas(Tattersfield and Havazvidi, 1994).

Another key component of intensifying smallholderagricultural lay with research. Despite an enviablerecord of agricultural research beforeindependence, it had focused primarily on high-inputtechnologies that mainly benefitted commercialproducers. After independence, agriculturalresearch focused more on the smallholder sector,while attempting to maintain the technology gainsin the commercial sector. Cognisant of the need toimplement its post-independence mandate, a jointcommittee of the Department of Research andSpecialist Services (DRSS) and the Departmentof Agricultural Extension and Technical Services(Agritex) was established to strengthen planningand setting priorities for on-farm research andextension (Tawonezvi and Hikwa, 2006).

In an effort to consolidate the gains from its pricing,marketing and research policies, the governmentunveiled its 15-year Communal LandsDevelopment Plan in 1986. The Plan waspresented as an agrarian reform strategy whosecentral concept was the creation of ‘consolidated

villages’ based on ‘clearly defined land-usepatterns, more intensive use of land, thus resultingin higher productivity’ (Zimbabwe, 1986: 54). Onthe one hand, the restructuring and reorganizing ofdispersed and isolated settlements into plannedvillages was expected to make the provision ofinfrastructure more cost-effective, while on theother, land-use reorganization by the cleardemarcation of villages into residential, croppingand common property areas would releaseadditional land for more intensive agriculturalproduction. It also suggested ‘a more appropriateland tenure system’ that allowed for theconsolidation of fragmented holdings and theintroduction of improved land-use management andconservation measures (ibid.: 45).

Zimbabwe’s agricultural intensification programmeseemed to be vindicated when the dramaticincreases in national smallholder maize and cottonproduction surpassed commercial production in1985 and 1986 respectively. Zimbabwe attractedinternational media coverage and won internationalacclaim,4 its achievement being crowned in 1989when Prime Minister Robert Mugabe was awardedthe Africa Prize for Leadership by the US-basedHunger Project. Rukuni and Eicher (1994) dubbedthe country’s success ‘Zimbabwe’s secondagricultural revolution’, noting proudly that between1970 and 1992 Zimbabwe had exported food for20 of the 22 years. One of the objectives of theirbook, they said, was to examine whether some ofZimbabwe’s approaches could be replicated inother southern African countries.

Resettlement

One of the main objectives of the resettlementprogramme was to alleviate population pressure incommunal areas where human overcrowding andovergrazing were so evident. An ‘intensive’resettlement programme was launched in 1980 toresettle 18,000 households from the overcrowdedcommunal areas onto 1.1 million hectares of formercommercial farmland over three years (Kinsey,1984). This programme was superseded in 1982by an ‘accelerated’ resettlement programme,

3 Stop orders are deductions made by the GMB from the proceeds of maize deliveries to repay the AFC for loans made tosmallholders for the supply of farm inputs.

4 The Guardian Weekly’s caption to its article read: Zimbabwe works a ‘farming miracle’ (May 7, 1985), while a sub-heading of PaulHarrison’s The Greening of Africa (1987) was entitled ‘Zimbabwe’s maize miracle’.

7

Section 2 – An Overview of Performance After Independence

initiated as part of the Transitional NationalDevelopment Plan (1982/83–1984/85). This calledfor the resettlement of 162,000 families on 9 millionhectares of underutilized commercial farmland overthree years. Although some way off the target,1.8 million hectares of land had been acquired forresettlement and over 30,000 families actuallysettled by June 1984 (Zimbabwe, 1985).

Migration

A third development strategy was to furtherdecongest the communal lands by encouragingmigration to towns and cities. In a bid to reducethe number of households in the communal areasto their estimated ‘carrying capacity’ (now revisedupwards to 325,000 households), 235,000communal families were expected to join theirfamily breadwinner who was working and living inan urban centre (Zimbabwe, 1981a).5

The 1981 ZIMCORD proposals detailed howmigration and urbanization strategies should reducepopulation pressure in the communal areas. Theywere:

• To develop a network of urban places toprovide farm input facilities, produce markets,shops, and services with employmentopportunities;

• To encourage ‘non-farming’ families in thetraditional areas, whose heads werepermanently employed outside the communalareas, to go and live with their breadwinners;and

• Create employment in the modern sector toattract more non-farmers to the urban centres.(Zimbabwe, 1981b: 40)

2.2 FADING HOPES FORSUSTAINABLE SMALLHOLDERDEVELOPMENT

Intensification

By the close of the 1980s, the underlying costs ofthe smallholder agricultural revolution were beingcounted. As early as 1986 the government’s over-generous pricing policies had already created anoversupply of maize at a time when the maizeexport market had shrunk, thus adding hugehandling and storage costs to the Grain MarketingBoard’s (GMB) already growing deficit. Apart fromhaving to pay smallholders above the market pricefor their produce, the GMB had to absorb the heavycosts of expanding its network of maize depotsand collection points into areas where it was noteconomically viable. To make matters worse, thegovernment’s decision to subsidize urban maizeconsumption left the GMB with a burgeoning andunsustainable budget deficit (Figure 1).

Source: Doré (1993)

Figure 1: Agricultural marketing losses during the 1980s

5 The ‘carrying capacity’ of the communal areas was the estimated number of families whose livelihoods could be sustained throughagriculture within the communal areas.

200

180

160

140

120

100

80

60

40

20

01981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990

Z$ (m

illio

ns)

8

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

In an effort to reduce the maize stockpile and bringdown its budget deficit, the government loweredits incentive price and encouraged commercialfarmers to move into oilseeds and high valueexporting crops, especially horticulture and tobacco,which had regained their lost markets.

Smallholder production levels, which peaked in1985 at 1.7 million tonnes, declined during thefollowing four years to below 1.35 million metrictonnes. The returns on maize, according to an indexproduced by Herbst (1990) had dropped from 88.0in 1985/86 to 65.1 by the 1987/88 season.6

The government’s pricing and subsidy policy,despite its pro-poor intentions, were oftendetrimental to the welfare of the poor. As farmerspreferred to sell their maize to the GMB and tobuy the subsidized maize meal from the urbancentres, the subsidies contributed to the closure ofan estimated 200 rural mills with significantnegative knock-on effects for rural employment.Conversely, the subsidies that benefited urbanconsumers did not reach out to the remote ruralareas, where the poorest households had to grindtheir own maize. Muir-Leresche and Muchopaestimated that marketing controls implicitly taxedthe poorest rural farmers by some 20 to 30 percentof the potential producer prices in most years,noting that, ‘Despite the objectives of promotinggrowth with equity, the policies were inimical toboth’ (2006: 300).

Nor did it appear that the benefits of the agriculturalrevolution were equitably shared. Rohrbach’ssurvey data suggested that 10 percent ofsmallholder producers, that were concentrated inthe high potential areas (Natural Regions II andIII), accounted for three-quarters of all smallholdermaize sales. In drought years this percentageincreased. His analysis indicated that:

‘... producers facing the smallest food securityrisks are the greatest beneficiaries ofgovernment policy changes andinfrastructural investments designed topromote smallholder production. Producersfacing frequent and or consistent productionshortfalls have benefitted least.’ (1988: 320)

Such findings applied equally to the beneficiariesof credit. In 1985, at the height of smallholderagricultural production, only 8 percent of farmersreceived agricultural credit from the AFC. Evenso, the initial enthusiasm for expanding credit tosmallholders wore off as the rate of loanrepayments declined sharply. Only 44,000 small-scale farmers received loans during the 1989/90cropping season; a drop of over 40 percent fromthe peak 1985 levels (Rohrbach et al.,1990) andfertilizer sales lay 15 percent below their 1985levels.

Research, another key plank in the drive to improvesmallholder livelihoods, was also floundering.Despite progress, the joint committee set upbetween DRSS and Agritex for on-farm small-holder agricultural research and extension wasscrapped in 1990 due to a lack of funding(Tawonezvi and Hikwa, 2006). For all the planning,restructuring and the technical research thatfocused on the smallholder sector there was littledata to show the extent to which research resultswere adopted or whether research improvedsmallholder productivity, livelihoods and incomes.The available evidence suggested that the growthin smallholder maize and cotton production wasbased more on expanding the area cultivated ratherthan greater intensification and productivity throughtechnical innovation (World Bank, 1995).

Without understating the achievement of the‘second’ agricultural revolution, it did not benefitfarmers equally, nor was it sustainable. Inretrospect it seems that the short-lived miracle ofsmallholder production – including a slight increasein intensification with average yields above 1 tonneper hectare – was achieved on the back of unpaidAFC loans, producer subsidies and the huge deficitsincurred by the GMB. The World Bank’s countryassessment in 1995 summed up Zimbabwe’sagricultural performance as follows:

‘While agricultural output grew rapidly in theearly-to-mid 1980s as a result of expandedplantings and yields of maize, cotton, andseveral other crops, underpinned by heavypublic sector support in marketinginfrastructure and credit, it has been stagnant

6 Index of return per dollar of variable cost with base year given as agricultural season 1980/81.

9

Section 2 – An Overview of Performance After Independence

since then, with smallholder agricultureexperiencing declines in output andproductivity. Although an important reasonfor this mediocre performance is thevariability of rainfall which has resulted infrequent droughts of varying degrees ofintensity, the more fundamental causes forpoor performance have been decliningproducer prices in real terms, reducedavailability of formal sector credit, decliningeffectiveness of research and extensionservices, and a contraction of public sectormarketing services.’ (1995: 3)

Smallholder agricultural intensification under theCommunal Land Development Plan fared littlebetter. When the plan was initiated in 1986, Agritexwas issued with a directive to implement the landreorganization programme. It was explicitlyinstructed that the preparation of village plans wasto take precedence over all its other tasks, includingagricultural extension. Yet, by 1990, one study foundthat during the five years between 1986 and 1991,plans had been prepared for only 4 out of 90 villagesin the UMP district7 and that government fundinghad not yet been made available for theimplementation of any projects (Doré, 1993). Itbecame increasingly apparent that the problem laywith a stagnating economy as well as the state’scommand approach and reliance on centralizedforms of decision-making and programmeimplementation. When assessing why the plan wasfailing, the Land Tenure Commission found that:

‘The main reason is the over-centralizationof government with the relevant technicalministries using top-down methods ofplanning and implementation. The secondproblem is the poor coordination of thetechnical ministries who continue to exhibitterritorial behaviour with no evidence of awell thought-out coordinated strategy.’(Zimbabwe, 1994: 35)

As the 1980s drew to a close, less and less washeard of the programme until, by the mid-1990s, itappeared to have been shelved.

Resettlement

The flagship of the government’s agrarian reformprogramme proceeded satisfactorily until 1985, atwhich point nearly 3,3 million hectares ofcommercial farmland had been acquired and about41,000 families resettled (Mhishi, 1995). Thereafter,progress slowed considerably. By 1990 only 15,000more families had been settled. With the expiry ofthe land acquisition restrictions imposed by theLancaster House Constitution, the governmentdecided to shelve the ‘willing buyer-willing seller’principle and opt for the compulsory acquisition ofcommercial farms, as embodied in the LandAcquisition Act of 1992. Even so, the number offamilies resettled by 1997 had risen to only 71,000.

What became evident was that the resettlementprogramme could not be a vehicle for decongestingthe communal areas. Even if it was assumed thatall 71,000 resettled households had originated fromthe communal areas, population growth – duringthe 18 years from 1980 to 1997 – would have addedabout 350,000 households to the communal areapopulation. And even if the government hadmanaged to meet its target of resettling 162,000families from the communal areas, the increase incommunal households would have been double thisnumber by 1997.

As early as 1988, Cusworth and Walker’sevaluation of the resettlement programme foundthat it ‘had little or no impact on the plight of thecommunal areas of Zimbabwe that still suffer fromaccelerating land degradation due to populationpressure’ (1988: ii). In their view, futureresettlement should also have involved directinvestment in the communal areas.

Migration

The expectation that over 300,000 or more familieswould uproot and migrate to live with theirbreadwinners in the main urban centres nevermaterialized because the primary prerequisite formigration – strong economic growth to generate

7 UMP stands for the names of the communal areas – Uzumba, Maramba and Pfungwe – that constitute the district.

10

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

employment – was not met. Although Zimbabwe’saverage economic growth rate in the 1980s was4.3 percent, formal employment grew by only 1.9percent per annum over the period. The averageeconomic growth rate fell to just 0.8 percent from1991 to 1995. Overall, the elasticity of employmentfor Zimbabwe’s manufacturing sector was a mere0.06 from 1980 to 1996 (UNDP, 2008).

Worsening conditions in urban centres, especiallyhousing shortages, exacerbated the difficulty ofmigrating to towns and cities. While the number offamilies waiting to be allocated houses by Harare’smunicipal authorities grew from about 36,000 in1983 to over 50,000 in 1989, the number of familiesactually allocated houses dropped by half from over3,000 to about 1,500 families over the same period(Auret, 1995). By 1996 the number of householdson the Harare municipal housing list had risen toover 100,000. By the mid-1990s there were anestimated 100,000 people living in squattersettlements in and around Harare (ibid.).

When the expected level of resettlement andmigration failed to materialize, the number offamilies living in the communal areas had risen toabout 1.2 million by 1997, nearly 4 times theirestimated carrying capacity. Although thegovernment still occasionally referred to the needto decongest the communal areas, any realexpectation of families voluntarily migrating to ruraland urban centres gradually disappeared.

2.3 ECONOMIC LIBERALIZATION(1991–1997)

While Zimbabweans were celebrating theachievements of smallholder agriculture, the costsof excessive government expenditure, includinggrowing parastatal deficits, were felt. As the first5-year National Development Plan pointed out,employment in the productive sectors was decliningby 1.2 percent annually, but still growing by 2.9percent in the social sectors (Zimbabwe, 1986b).On the advice of the World Bank, Zimbabwetherefore decided to accept a package of market-oriented economic policies with the publication ofA Framework for Economic Reform in January1991 (Zimbabwe, 1991). This was ESAP –Zimbabwe’s Economic Structural AdjustmentProgramme.

The Dairy Marketing Board and the CottonMarketing Board were privatized and the domesticmonopolies of the Cold Storage Commission andthe GMB were overturned. Maize marketing andprices were completely decontrolled, all subsidieswere removed, and the trading of maize waspermitted throughout the country. Crucially forhousehold food security, maize was allowed tomove freely between communal areas in the semi-arid regions. Rural producers gained by the reformslargely because the GMB was still designated asthe buyer of last resort at a set floor price for maize.Thus, in a good agricultural season, when a largeharvest depressed the market price below the floorprice, producers could sell to the GMB rather thanto private buyers. Conversely, during a pooragricultural season when market prices rose abovethe GMB’s floor price, they benefited from salesto private buyers.

There were, however, inherent dangers in settingfloor prices to protect smallholder producers thathad unforeseen and harmful side effects. In goodagricultural years, such as the 1993/94 season, theGMB was required to purchase a massive harvestthat resulted in losses estimated at Z$1.4 billion, orroughly 4.6 percent of GDP, that had to beabsorbed by the Treasury at taxpayers’ expense(Ndlela and Robinson, 2006).

Another success was the privatization of the CottonMarketing Board (CMB). In 1991, the CMB wasgranted formal managerial autonomy and had itsmonopoly in purchasing, ginning, marketing andexporting cotton removed. In 1994, The CottonCompany of Zimbabwe (Cottco) was launched toreplace the CMB. It was eventually privatized in1997. New competitors, such as Cargill (anAmerican-based multinational) and the CottonProducers Association (a cooperative of large-scale commercial cotton producers) competed topurchase smallholders’ cotton through contractfarming. The companies would providesmallholders with credit for inputs and extensionadvice in order to maximize cotton production,which the companies guaranteed to buy at acontracted price. In the wake of this competition,smallholder cotton growers benefited significantly,receiving between 80 to 90 percent of the worldprice between 1994 and 1997 (Muir-Leresche andMuchopa, 2006).

11

Section 2 – An Overview of Performance After Independence

Figure 2 shows how smallholder cotton productionregistered a steady increase in production,overtaking commercial farm production in the mid-1980s. Thereafter smallholder production wassustained – even after the onset of the currentcrisis – through the corporate-smallholder

contracting model. The liberalization of agriculturalmarketing in the 1990s gave a glimpse of the hugepotential of contract farming for smallholderagriculture that goes beyond cotton to other highervalue export commodities, such as horticulture andanimal products.

Source: UNDP (2008)

Figure 2: Cotton production: commercial and communal sectors

300

250

200

150

100

50

01980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

Tonn

es (t

hous

ands

)

Communal

Commercial

12

3.1 THE ONSET OF POLITICALAND ECONOMIC INSTABILITY(1997–2000)

The crash of the Zimbabwe dollar on 14 November1997 on ‘Black Friday’ marked the onset of thecrisis. The government’s threat to acquire 1,500commercial farms, mounting public debt,accusations of corruption, job layoffs, anddisenchantment with rising prices had alreadydestabilized the economy. The trigger for thedollar’s collapse, which lost half its value in a singleday, was the massive unbudgeted paymentsawarded to war veterans (ICG, 2004). Theeconomic reforms unravelled and the governmentgradually re-imposed economic controls.

The GMB saga is a case in point. It had incurredhuge and unsustainable losses between 1993 and1995 amounting to Z$2.9 billion (US$376 million)mainly due to trading losses and finance chargeson borrowed funds. Because the GMBs deficitswere not fully recovered from the government eachyear, it had borrowed heavily both domestically andexternally to cover its debt servicing and operatingcosts. By 1994, its outstanding debt reached overZ$3.1 billion8 with interest charges running atZ$900 million monthly (Larson and Swire-Thompson, 1999). The GMBs unsustainablefinancial position finally galvanized the governmentinto clearing the GMBs debts on condition that itundertook reforms to operate commercially. TheGMB initiated numerous changes in structure andorganization and cut its staff by about 1,000employees by 1997.

While the GMB was planning furtherimprovements in efficiency and customer service,it ran into the core problem of the government’slack of fiscal restraint that had jeopardized

macroeconomic stability and saw inflation runningabove 20 percent from 1991 through to 1996. Atthe same time, in an effort to curb inflation, theReserve Bank of Zimbabwe (RBZ) had raised thebank rate, which stood at 23.5 percent in February1997.9 Faced with these punishing interest rates,the private sector curbed investment whichhampered employment creation. The urbanpopulation was therefore caught between spirallinginflation and falling employment and wages –exactly the opposite of what the economic reformsintended.

In January 1998, a 21 percent increase in maizemeal sparked food riots in Harare, which thegovernment blamed on the IMF and the WorldBank-sponsored structural adjustment programme.The government then reinstated maize pricecontrols, thus signalling the end of agriculturalmarketing reforms.10 Privileged urban millers, butnot small-scale millers, could once again procuretheir maize requirements from the GMB atsubsidized prices. Thereafter the GMB wouldcontinue to absorb the increased cost of grainimports, importing maize at a far higher cost thanthe GMBs government-authorized selling price(Larson and Swire-Thompson, 1999).

Research and extension services also suffered.The DRSS had embarked on a consultationprocess with stakeholders in the private sector,universities and the commercial sector to developa policy framework for consolidating, guiding andfocusing resources in strategic research areas.At the same time, the Agricultural ResearchCouncil drew up a five-year rolling strategic plan(1999–2004) to fund agricultural research that fellinto key thematic areas. Restructuring, however,could not disguise the intractable problems thathad set in. As government funding became

Section 3

The Deepening Crisis (1997–2009)

8 To put this in perspective, GMB debt amounted to about US$380 million, which was equivalent to 7.8 percent of GDP. (Estimatesbased on the GDP and exchange rates derived from Economist Intelligence Unit’s Country report on Zimbabwe for 3rd quarterof 1996).

9 Finhold Zimbabwe Economic Review, January 2000.10 The Independent (UK), 22 January 1998.

13

Section 3 – The Deepening Crisis

increasingly constrained, the real earnings ofresearchers declined. Eventually ‘the proportionof the recurrent expenditure committed to salariesand overheads increased to 91 percent, leavingonly 9 percent devoted to actual researchactivities’ (Tawonezvi and Hikwa, 2006: 208).Similarly, capital development, which fell to just 5percent of the department’s requirements, wasfar less than the rate of depreciation of theinfrastructural research base.

3.2 ZIMBABWE’S CRISIS YEARS(2000–2007)

In February 2000, the Government sponsoredconstitutional proposals were rejected in areferendum. A process of occupation of white-owned commercial farms began, and in June 2001the Fast Track Land Reform Programme waslaunched (Zimbabwe, 2001).

In July 2001 the government decided to resumecontrol over food supplies. Maize and wheat weredeclared controlled products, making it illegal tobuy, sell or move them within Zimbabwe other thanto the GMB. The Zimbabwe AgriculturalCommodity Exchange (ZIMACE) was officiallysuspended. In December 2001, further restrictionscompelled farmers to deliver their maize and grainstocks to the GMB within 14 days of harvesting.By 2002, the holding of all grain stocks by farmerswas banned and grain supplies were seized, leavingthe livestock industry and farm workers facing acrisis.

Economic Meltdown

The appointment of a new Governor of the ReserveBank of Zimbabwe (RBZ) in 2003 signalled amajor shift in economic policy. The RBZ begandeparting further from orthodox central bankingpractice and its legal mandate over monetarypolicy. On the advice of the executive arm of

government, it started functioning more as adevelopment bank, usurping the fiscal function ofthe Ministry of Finance as well as taking policyand funding decisions for other ministries, especiallyagriculture. From 2004 the RBZ began printingmore and more money to fund its quasi-fiscal (off-budget) activities in order to provide loans to certaineconomic actors. As these loans were granted atderisorily low interest rates in a hyper-inflationaryenvironment, they were little more than subsidies.According to one estimate, these massive subsidiesto newly resettled farmers were equivalent, in 2004,to 19 percent of GDP (Ndlela and Robinson, 2006).

In May 2005, the RBZ introduced the AgricultureSector Productivity Enhancement Facility (ASPEF)to finance agriculture through Agribank, theGMB, commercial banks, ministries, parastatalorganizations and boards.11 It charged interest atthe rate of 20 percent per annum at a time wheninflation was running, according to officialestimates, at 586 percent. Such bizarre pricingdistortions were evident throughout the economy,including government controls and subsidies onfood. In September 2006, for example, thegovernment had fixed the producer price of maizeat Z$33,000 per tonne, which the GMB, as the solelawful dealer in maize, sold to millers at a mereZ$600 per tonne, representing a 98 percent subsidy.Resettled farmers could profit more by selling their1,000 litre fuel allocation – purchased at thesubsided rate of Z$600 per litre and sold to thepublic at Z$30,000 per litre – than by filling theirtractors to plough their fields (FAO/WFP, 2007).

The FTLRP, high subsidies and skewed pricingpolicies predictably caused a rapid decline in percapita agricultural output (Figure 3), incomes andGDP. Real average earnings were lower than in1960, and by 2004 they had collapsed to just 10percent of average earnings in 1990 (UNDP,2008). Zimbabwe’s GDP between 1998 and 2006had declined by 37 percent (Zimbabwe Institute,2007: 37).

11 <www.rbz.co.zw/inc/publications/legaldept/rbzpdfs/Supplement5.pdf>

14

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

Price Control and Shortages

Rather than rein in fiscal expenditure or theprinting of money to reduce inflationary pressures,the government launched Operation DzikisaMutengo (Reduce Prices) in June 2007. Adirective was issued to manufacturers, whole-salers and retailers to reduce their prices by halfwhen inflation was running at 4,500 percent. Theimpact of this policy was heard at a ParliamentaryLand and Agricultural Portfolio Committeemeeting called in September 2007 to access thecountry’s preparedness for the forthcomingagricultural season (2007/08).

The three major fertilizer manufacturers had closedbecause their capacity to produce had beencrippled by a lack of raw materials. The Dorowamine which produced phosphate rock concentrate,a key component in making fertilizer, ceasedoperations due to persistent power cuts and a lackof foreign exchange to import mining materials.As a result, fertilizer firms had produced just 16,000tonnes against a target of 600,000 tonnes for theforthcoming season.12 The costs of producingfertilizer were running at six to ten times thegovernment controlled selling price. A seniorfertilizer company official said that fertilizer hadbeen sold at a fifth of the cost of production as a

result of the government price controls imposed inJune 2007.

A representative of a major seed companyexplained the difficulty in inducing farmers todeliver their seed maize to meet nationalrequirements. Although the government hadapproved a selling price of Z$29 million per tonnein June 2007, a month later the government hadunilaterally reduced it to Z$15 million per tonne. Inthe meantime seed producers had increased theirnominal asking price to between Z$20 million andZ$40 million per tonne. At that time the cost ofimporting seed maize was between Z$48 millionto Z$54 million per tonne at the official exchangerate13 (i.e., five times higher than the government’scontrolled price), but Z$448 million to Z$504 millionper tonne at the parallel exchange rate, about 45times the controlled price paid to local producers.14

3.3 IMPACT ON SMALLHOLDERS INTHE COMMUNAL AREAS

Intensification

The government’s determination to demonstratethe success of its resettlement programme foundthe bulk of RBZ’s massive subsidies being

Source: Central Statistical Office, Harare; National Accounts (various editions)

Figure 3: Agricultural value added per head (constant 1990 prices)

450

400

350

300

250

200

150

100

50

01980 1985 1990 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006

12 Mail & Guardian (SA), 27 August 2007.13 The cost was between US$1,600 and US$1,800 per tonne.14 These prices have not been converted to US dollars, as it is the relative prices in Zimbabwe dollars that matter.

Z$

15

Section 3 – The Deepening Crisis

channelled primarily to new A1 and A2 farmers.15

Although the RBZ claimed to have made someinputs available to communal farmers through theGMB, there is a dearth of data surrounding howmany communal smallholders actually benefitted,on what basis they were selected, how much theyreceived, or what production benefits resulted fromthe inputs.16

Early indications were that the reduction in maizearea (8 percent) and production (12 percent) inthe communal areas was largely due to delays inpayments by the GMB to smallholders for graindeliveries (FAO/WFP, 2001). Later, the generalmeltdown of the economy impacted heavily on fuelsupplies, the availability of transport and theconditions of roads, making the delivery of inputsto farmers as well as commodities to marketsproblematic. There were also the perennialproblems of organizational inefficiencies that

resulted in the late delivery of farm inputs providedby government. As a result, the late plantings ofmaize and the necessity of communal farmers touse retained seed reduced yields significantly, whilelate applications of fertilizer were often a wasteand needless cost (FAO/WFP, 2007).

Figure 4 not only shows a general decline in maizeproduction from 1980 to 2006, but also its volatilitybecause yields are highly dependent on rainfallpatterns. Output in 2002 was reduced significantlyby drought, while the production spike in 2004 waslargely due to good rains.17 The decline in foodproduction may have been steeper in the absenceof the RBZ’s huge input subsidies to farmers,including Operation Maguta,18 involving themilitary. However, the economic damage inflictedby the RBZ’s quasi-fiscal activities that supportedthese subsidies proved economically disastrous.

15 Model A1 is a ‘decongestion’ model (for landless people) that comes in two versions. The ‘villagised’ type allocates settlers aresidential and an arable plot, but has shared grazing areas. The ‘self-contained’ type allocates the households one consolidatedfarm unit. Settlers are allocated 12 to 70 hectares depending on the Natural Region. Model A2 is an ‘indigenisation’ model basedon full cost recovery and a 99-year year lease with an option to purchase a small, medium or large commercial farm (Zimbabwe,2001). In reality: ‘The contrasts between A1 and A2, small- and large-scale, smallholder and commercial are rather arbitrary andmisleading. There is much blurring between these different models’ (Scoones, 2008:1).

16 Donors involved in food distribution from the GMB were frustrated by the absence of data on the GMB’s imports and distribution,making estimated needs and relief planning and coordination difficult (HRW, 2003).

17 The sudden jump in resettlement production and a slump in commercial production is a function of the FTLRP and the blurringof statistical data between the two sub-sectors.

18 Operation Maguta, meaning ‘I am full’, was an agricultural programme implemented by the military in November 2005 toincrease maize production on underutilized commercial farmland. It also provided farm inputs with RBZ funds.

Figure 4: Maize production by sector (1980–2006)

Source: UNDP (2008)

2.0

1.8

1.6

1.4

1.2

1.0

0.8

0.6

0.4

0.2

0.01980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

tonn

es (m

illio

ns)

Commercial

Communal

Resettlement

16

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

Whilst historically the communal areas have beenthe major sources of national maize production, thepicture changes markedly with regards to yields.Average yields in the commercial sector wereabout 4 tonnes per hectare in a normal season(without drought), but these dropped off sharplysince commercial farms were taken over in 2000(Figure 5).19 The communal areas generallyproduce less than one tonne per hectare, andproduced even less after 2001.

The data suggest that a lack of inputs and theirlate delivery have probably been responsible forreduced communal area yields. On the researchand extension front, Agritex was merged withDRSS in 2002 to create the Department ofAgricultural Research and Extension (AREX). Inthe aftermath of the FTLRP, however, anymeaningful research into smallholder productionvirtually ceased. In sum, there is no evidence ofintensification in smallholder agriculture.

Resettlement

In its original conception, the resettlementprogramme was to have specifically benefittedcommunal households (i.e., those who wereeffectively landless, the unemployed and destitute)

in order to alleviate population pressure andimprove livelihoods (Zimbabwe, 1985). This pro-poor focus changed significantly with the FTLRP.A key objective of the new programme had become‘empowerment’, making all black Zimbabweanseligible for resettlement. Applicants were no longerrequired to demonstrate training, experience orcompetence in farming, but only that they hadsufficient resources (Zimbabwe, 2001). How muchtherefore did communal smallholders’ benefit fromthe fast track land distribution process and wasthe original programme objective to decongest thecommunal areas met?

A study by Marongwe (2003) suggests thatopportunism was the principal driving force behindoccupations. He found, for example, that mostoccupiers were from communal and resettlementareas who had simply settled on the nearestcommercial farms. He also observed that farmsbordering urban areas were mainly occupied bypeople from towns and cities who wantedresidential plots. Another category of occupierswere former farm workers, who had nowhere elseto go (Zimbabwe, 2003; Nyakopoto, 2004). A morerecent study by Scoones (2008) bundles thesedifferent types of new A1 settlers together, whomhe numbers at about 60 percent, and refers to them

Figure 5: Maize productivity by sector (1980–2006)

Source: UNDP (2008)

19 The production of maize by commercial farmers in 2007 of 160,000 tonnes was less than one-third of its 1998 production levelsof 521,000 tonnes. Commercial production had dropped to 23 percent of total output, with smallholders producing over three-quarters of national output (UNDP, 2008: p.155, Table 9.3).

6

5

4

3

2

1

01980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

tonn

es (m

illio

ns)

Commercial

Communal

Resettlement

17

Section 3 – The Deepening Crisis

as ‘ordinary farmers’. Scoones also notes that theremaining occupiers, particularly in the A2 schemes,included a significant numbers of civil servants (14percent), business people (5 percent), and membersof the security services (3 percent). If we includeMarongwe’s estimate that war veterans comprisedabout 20 percent of occupiers, a picture emergesof the general composition of the full contingent ofsettlers.

If it were assumed that about 55 percent of the A1settlers originated from the communal areas, thiswould translate,20 using land allocation data fromthe Utete Committee Report (Zimbabwe, 2003),into the resettlement of about 75,000 communalhouseholds.21 Although this represents about 5percent of households in the communal areas, it isunlikely to decongest them for four reasons. Thefirst is that population growth would have made upfor the numbers settled within 4 or 5 years.22 Thesecond is that the resettlement option has beenlargely exhausted because most of the availablefarmland has been allocated for resettlement or isstill contested by the original owners. Third, a largeproportion of displaced farm workers and theirfamilies will probably have found refuge in thecommunal areas. And, fourth, many of thoseresettled have not relinquished their communalhomes.

Migration

It seems likely that instead of a movement ofhouseholds out of the communal areas, thecombination of the economic meltdown and various‘operations’ have seen a net increase of migrantsinto the communal areas. The first wave of in-migrants came in the aftermath of the FTLRP whenabout 200,000 farm workers lost their jobs oncommercial farms (Sachikonye, 2003). While somefarm workers tried their hand at gold-panning,brick-making and craftwork, others brewed illicitliquor or became vendors in towns and cities. The

aged, less resourceful and destitute crowded intomake-shift shelters in squatter camps. Second andthird-generation descendants of migrants fromneighbouring countries, which constituted about 26percent of the farm workers, did not have homesin communal areas to fall back on (ibid.). However,it is likely that at least half the farm workersdisplaced – probably in excess of 100,000households – would have returned to their familyhomes, swelling the numbers already in theovercrowded communal areas.

Those that made their way into cities to findemployment would soon find themselves and otherinformal traders affected by another governmentinitiative in May 2005, Operation Murambatsvina.This was a campaign to remove ‘illegal structures’in towns and cities across the country. The UNSpecial Envoy on Human Settlement Issues inZimbabwe estimated that some 700,000 people hadeither lost their homes, their source of livelihood,or both. Indirectly, a further 2.4 million people wereaffected (Tibaijuka, 2005). With the loss of theirlivelihoods and homes, as well as little prospect offinding employment in urban centres, anecdotalevidence suggests that many households tookrefuge in their communal homes, if only to findtemporary shelter with relatives before chartingtheir next move.

When account is also taken of the those fleeingpolitical violence in the communal areas during therun-up to the June 2008 presidential elections,23

the emerging picture is one of continual internaldisplacement of hundred of thousands of people,often the poorest and most vulnerable, fromcommercial farming areas and mines, towns andcities to rural areas, and from the rural areas backinto urban centres. Though it seems likely thatmany more people found sanctuary in thecommunal areas than were resettled to decongestthem, any estimate of the net balance of peoplenow living in the communal areas is complicatedby thousands more who have fled political violence

20 This takes Scoone’s figure of 60 percent of ‘ordinary farmers’, and discounts (an estimated 5 percent) for farm workers whoremained on commercial farms.

21 Table 2 of the Utete Committee report (Zimbabwe, 2003) shows that 134,452 households were resettled on A1 and A2resettlement schemes.

22 If it is assumed that the population growth rate is 1.2 percent and the existing communal population is 1,5 million households,then the annual increase in the number of households is 18,000.

23 According to USAID Situation Report No.2 (26 June 2008) the UN Office for the Coordination of Humanitarian Affairs (OCHA)estimated that the violence displaced more than 33,400 Zimbabweans.

18

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

and poverty by emigrating to neighbouring countries,mostly South Africa and Botswana (UNDP, 2007);or who, weakened by hunger and destitution, haveperished from diseases such as AIDS or cholera.

Growing Rural Poverty and Vulnerability

As the government moved to control the distributionof food after 2000, the World Food Programmewas appealing for funds from the internationalcommunity to import 447,000 tonnes of maize(FAO/WFP, 2001). Gradually two separate foodprogrammes emerged in Zimbabwe, one run bythe government, and the other by internationalagencies. The international programme consistedof the World Food Programme (WFP) pipeline,which distributed food through NGOs in 49 (of 57)rural districts. The second pipeline was theConsortium for Southern Africa Food Emergency(C-SAFE), a US-funded programme implementedby World Vision, CARE and Catholic ReliefServices.

The general decline in agricultural production wasexacerbated by the 2002/03 drought, leaving nearlyhalf of Zimbabwe’s population – 4.4 million peoplein the rural areas and 1.1 million in the urban areas– in need of food assistance. The report by theFAO and the WFP in 2003 estimated that Zimbabwewould need to import 62 percent of its foodrequirements for the 2003/04 season. By then, lifeexpectancy and incomes had dropped precipitously.In Mashonaland Central Province – arguably themost agriculturally productive in Zimbabwe – lifeexpectancy dropped by 30 percent between 1995and 2003. Over the same period, the mean percapita income of the province fell by an astonishing89 percent (Zimbabwe, 2006).

In a situation of hunger and a high incidence ofHIV, which had reached 24.6 percent of the adultpopulation by 2003, life expectancy rates declinedsharply (UNDP, 2008). According to a report issuedby the United Nations, Zimbabwe’s life expectancyhad dropped to the lowest in the world: 34 yearsfor women and 37 years for men by 2006.24 Whenrains failed again, the household food insecurity

and vulnerability picture for the 2006/07 agriculturalseason once again worsened. One-third of thepopulation, or 4.1 million people, needed food aidthrough to April 2008 (FAO/WFP, 2007).

3.4 ZIMBABWE’S RAPIDREGRESSION (2008–2009)

The economic situation deteriorated further in 2008.The RBZ continued to print bank notes in everhigher denominations, from million to billions totrillions. By July, a single loaf of bread cost nearlyZ$100 billion. As fast as the government printedmoney to pay a diminishing band of civil servants– including teachers, medical staff, the police andthe military – the faster inflation spiralled out ofcontrol, rendering their pay virtually worthless.Without pay, the health and medical servicescollapsed.

Rural schools were deserted by teachers and pupilsalike, while rural clinics were devoid of medicineand most staff. Many teachers and medical staffhad in fact emigrated. Of 140,000 teachers only60,000 reportedly remained, and only around 30percent of government health workers were stillat their posts. In the midst of the collapse in healthservices, a cholera epidemic broke out, claimingover 4,000 lives (ICG, 2009). In January 2009 theepidemic shifted to the rural areas,25 and by Marchit had spread to 56 of the country’s 62 districts.26

Despite government assurances of the timelydelivery of inputs, yet again the delayed delivery ofinputs through Operation Maguta and the GMB wasone of the major factors that reduced agriculturalproductivity during the 2007/08 season (FAO/WFP,2008). For these and other reasons, it was estimatedthat 5.1 million people would require food assistanceduring the ‘hungry season’, between January andMarch 2009; not just cereals, but supplementaryfoods such as oil and beans to augment the needsof the most vulnerable groups (ibid.). In fact, it wasreported that about 7 million people were providedwith food aid to survive to April 2009, forcinghumanitarian agencies to halve cereal rations toextend their food stocks (ICG, 2009).

24 http://www.medicalnewstoday.com/articles/41339.php25 Medecins Sans Frontieres, 22 January 2009.26 Relief Web, 6 March 2009.

19

4.1 PREREQUISITES FORAGRICULTURAL RECOVERYAND GROWTH

The initial steps along Zimbabwe’s path toagricultural recovery do not only lie within thesmallholder agricultural sector itself, but within thebroader context of the government’s relations withits own citizens and the international community:

‘The challenge of improving governance isnot restricted to any field of activity but is asystemic one, requiring a reorientation of thestate, a change in mindset and how it engageswith the economy and society. Any sustainablesocioeconomic recovery over the long term isdependent on this transformation.’ (UNDP,2008: 209)

With the formation of an inclusive government inFebruary 2009, Zimbabwe has signalled its intentto re-engage with the international community byaddressing issues around the rule of law, the rightsto freedom of expression and association, andproperty rights (Simpson and Doré, 2009).

Zimbabwe, through its short-term economicrecovery programme (STERP), also looks set tomeet the second prerequisite for agriculturalgrowth: macroeconomic stability (Zimbabwe,2009). Price stability is particularly importantbecause farmers make their annual productiondecisions based on both the current costs of farminputs and the future prices they expect to receivefor their produce. Stable prices therefore sendimportant market signals to farmers to optimizetheir allocation of resources – land, capital andlabour – to maximize production within the

production possibilities they face. Farmers mustalso be satisfied that the prices they receive onexport markets – where the income elasticity ofdemand is high, and therefore an important sourceof agricultural growth – are an attractive alternativeto producing for a limited domestic market. Farmerswill therefore have a greater incentive to exportwhen macroeconomic policies maintain anexchange rate that is both relatively stable andcompetitive.

The overarching importance of economic policyfor agricultural growth was demonstrated in aseminal study by Krueger, Schiff, and Valdés(1991). They showed that governments, especiallyin sub-Saharan Africa, implicitly taxed agriculturevia overvalued exchange rates and by taxingagricultural exports, resulting in a 30 percentdecline in agricultural prices and slow agriculturalgrowth. Zimbabwe was no exception. In the 1980s,persistent budget deficits and inflationary pressuressaw its exchange rate appreciate by over 50percent. This implicit tax on agricultural exportersrepresented a net subsidy for consumers of foreignexchange, including most manufacturing enterprisesand the government. Jansen and Rukovo (1992)found that the nominal rate of assistance27 onmaize was -17 percent between 1980 and 1990,while those for cotton and tobacco were over -30percent. High negative nominal rates of assistanceon agricultural commodities in Zimbabwe persistedthroughout the 1990s (Ndlela and Robinson, 2006).

The need for macroeconomic stability supports thethird prerequisite for agricultural recovery: pro-poorgrowth. Maintaining a competitive exchange rateis a powerful tool to generate employment in thetradable goods sector28 because it raises the price

Section 4

Policy Recommendations for Recovery

27 The nominal rate of assistance (NRA) is the degree – expressed as a percentage – to which an agricultural commodity is eithersubsidized or taxed by the state. A positive NRA is therefore a subsidy, while a negative NRA is an implicit tax.

28 The tradable goods sector refers to the production of goods for export. A significant increase in demand for labour by a country’sexporting companies can be derived from the rising global demand for their products. This may be achieved partly through tradeliberalization, but mainly through productivity increases and exchange-rate depreciation that increase a country’s competitiveness(Hawkins and Ndlela, 2009). As competitive exchange rates make the importation of capital relatively more expensive,production will favour more labour intensive techniques, gradually drawing labour into the higher productivity tradable sector ina process of structural transformation.

20

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

of capital relative to labour, providing an incentivefor enterprises to use labour more intensively(Kanyenze, 2009). More generally, the weight ofevidence suggests that broad-based economicgrowth founded on trade liberalization, foreigndirect investment and well-functioning marketshave a significant and sustainable impact on povertyreduction (Gunter et al., 2005; World Bank, 2008).Labour and land productivity gains and marketaccess lie at the core of a more robust agriculturaleconomy and pro-poor growth (OECD, 2006).

Although Zimbabwe has now adopted the US dollarand the rand, the problem facing farmers is thatprevious hyperinflation has left the economy withan elevated and uncompetitive price, wage and coststructure (Hawkins and Ndlela, 2009). Accordingto one economist, many farmers had opted out ofwinter wheat production because ‘the cost ofproducing crops is way above the money they realizeafter selling their produce’.29 As price stability cannotcome at the cost of competitiveness, a combinationof real price and wage reductions, as well asincreased productivity, may be required to reduceproduction costs and improve competitiveness.

4.2 RE-ENGAGEMENT WITH THEINTERNATIONAL DONORCOMMUNITY

The Zimbabwe government needs to re-engagewith the international donor community to accessfunding in order to get basic social servicesfunctioning again and to kick-start the economy.While many of Zimbabwe’s development partnershave indicated their willingness to assist Zimbabwe,they have stated that they are awaiting certainpolicy changes that would give them sufficientconfidence in the inclusive government to re-engage and provide development assistance.

In particular, it will be crucial for the parties to theSeptember 2008 inter-party agreement toimplement Section 5.9 (f) of the agreement which

calls for them to ‘work together for the restorationof full productivity on all agricultural land’. Therecognition by the Zimbabwe government of theSADC Tribunal ruling would also send a clear signalto donors of the government’s commitment to therule of law and its respect for property rights.30

So too would implementation of Clause 107 of thegovernment’s own short-term recovery pro-gramme, which reads:

‘In order to promote confidence, investmentsand other developments on farms, as well asensuring security of farming operations, TheInclusive Government will uphold the rule oflaw as well as enforce law and order on farmsincluding arresting any further farm invasionswhich disrupt farming activities.’ (Zimbabwe,2009)

Apart from allowing commercial farmers toproduce food and earn desperately needed foreignexchange, the implementation of this provisionwould trigger strong donor support for pro-pooragricultural policies that assist smallholders toimprove their household food security and reducepoverty.

4.3 EMERGENCY FOOD AID ANDHOUSEHOLD FOOD SECURITY

The most immediate objective is to continue toprovide safety nets and reduce the risks for thepoorest and most vulnerable members of society.The imperative is therefore to maintain andstrengthen the measures already put in place byinternational humanitarian agencies since 2002. Anetwork of bilateral donor agencies channelsemergency food relief through WFP and C-SAFE,and enables households to improve their foodsecurity through agricultural projects managed byFAO and other NGOs.

WFP requested US$280 million to provide foodduring 2009 to support about 4 million people31

29 IRIN (UN) reporting comments by John Robertson, 22 May 2009.30 The Tribunal found that Constitutional Amendment 17, the basis on which the Zimbabwe Government proposed to evict

commercial farmers, was in breach of Article 4(c) and Article 6(2) of the Treaty, governing the right to a fair hearing in a courtand racial discrimination, respectively. The Tribunal therefore ordered the government not to evict commercial farmers orinterfere with their occupation of their farms.

31 World Food Programme appeal for food support to vulnerable groups from January to December 2009 (Project Code: ZIM-09/F/23505).

21

Section 4 – Policy Recommendations for Recovery

through its cooperating partners.32 Its programmeconsists of vulnerable group feeding, social-basedsafety nets, and health-based safety net activities(that support people infected with HIV and AIDSand their households), mobile and vulnerablepopulations and school-based feeding. In May 2009,Zimbabwe’s emergency food programme fed800,000 highly vulnerable beneficiaries, includingschool-children. USAID, through its Office ofForeign Disaster Assistance (OFDA), is probablythe largest contributor of food aid to Zimbabwe.So far this year, its Food for Peace programmehas channelled 106,000 tonnes of emergency foodassistance valued at more than $95.5 millionthrough WFP and C-SAFE.33 The USAID-fundedFamine Early Warning Systems Network(FEWSNET) also plays a vital role in identifyingthose communities most likely to needhumanitarian assistance.

The main contributors towards farm inputs andother types of support for household food securityhave been the Department for InternationalDevelopment (DFID), the European Commission(EC) and the European Commission Humanitarianaid Office (ECHO), which have provided aboutUS$45 million on average since 2003 through 70different implementing organizations. The largestprogramme has been DFID’s Protracted ReliefProgramme (PRP) reaching 1.5 million peoplebetween 2004 and 2007. The PRPs second phaseis now covering livelihoods interventions from 2008to 2013, for an amount of US$100 million with 25implementing partners. The EC has been fundingfood security activities through NGOs and farmers’unions over several 3-year programme phases.ECHO, through successive 12 month programmes,has been contributing about US$15 millions annuallyfor relief food and agricultural activities.34

The FAO estimated that about 350,000 householdswere supplied with seed and fertilizer for the2008/09 season that resulted in 50,000 hectares

being planted to maize (with yields of between 1and 2 tonnes per ha), and 90,000 hectares plantedto small grains (with yields of around 0.8 tonnesper ha). The number of households assistedreached 985,000 in 2003/04, but has generally beenbelow 400,000 since then. This was because theaverage size of fertilizer packs per beneficiary havebecome much bigger.

The government’s recovery programme, STERP,has requested the international donor communityto support its Crop Input Pack Scheme forvulnerable smallholder farmers during the 2009/10farming season. It estimates that each of about800,000 households will require 10 kg of maize/small grains seed packs, 50 kg of Compound Dand 50 kg of Ammonium Nitrate fertilizers. This ismuch higher than the average size of input packsfor the 2008/09 season, which were less than 5 kgfor seed, 20 kg of basal (Compound D) fertilizer,and 35 kg of top dressing (Ammonium Nitrate).The British government has responded byannouncing, in April 2009, that £15 million (aboutUS$21 million) would be made available for foodsecurity and other humanitarian assistance.35

Humanitarian programmes have become morerecovery oriented over the years. Donors initiallyfocused on simply providing basic inputs, but theirprogrammes have graduated into morecomprehensive packages that have includedextension advice to those smallholders who havebeen supplied with seed and fertilizer. These havenow evolved into a wider range of more complexinterventions and integrated practices, such as seedfairs and vouchers, conservation agriculture,garden and micro-irrigation projects, and livestockmanagement. Improved organization andpreparedness has enabled the timely delivery ofinputs to enable smallholders to plant early, whichis crucial for improved yields and household foodsecurity.

32 These include: Africare, Christian Care, Catholic Relief Services, CARE, Concern, GOAL, Help Age Zimbabwe, InternationalOrganization for Migration, International Organisation of the Red Cross and Red Crescent Societies, Mashambanzou Care Trust,Organization of Rural Associations for Progress, Oxfam GB, Plan International, Save the Children UK, World Vision International,and Inter-Country People’s Aid.

33 USAID Zimbabwe: Complex Emergency Report, 13 April 2009.34 Other donors that have contributed significantly include USAID, South Africa, Japan, Sweden, France, Australia, Ireland, Germany

and Spain.35 MSN African News <www.inet.co.za> 24 April 2009.

22

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

Under the current fiscal crisis – where thegovernment is struggling to pay staff salaries foressential social services, such as health andeducation – the government is unlikely to findsufficient resources for civil servants in theagriculture and social services ministries to play ameaningful role in facilitating food aid distributionand agricultural production. However, thegovernment should immediately ensure that thereis much closer cooperation between the GMB andinternational agencies to ensure the coordinateddistribution of food aid to the most needy.

According to the government’s short-termrecovery programme, the GMB’s monopoly as agrain purchaser has been removed.36 Presumablythis means liberalizing the domestic grain market,making it possible for producers to sell directly tomillers, both large and small, as well as facilitatingthe trade and barter of food from surplus productionareas to deficit areas. This important step inimproving household food security and reducingtransport costs should be followed by liftingrestrictions on the importation of cereals by privatetraders. Increasing domestic supplies and allowingcommodity markets to operate competitively willbring food prices down and ensure that householdswith the purchasing power can access food throughthe markets (FAO/WFP, 2008).

4.4 RECOVERY POLICIES FORREBUILDING SMALLHOLDERAGRICULTURE

Once re-engagement with the international donorcommunity and recovery is well underway,government ministries should strengthen theirpartnership and coordination with internationalimplementing agencies. Gradually, as recoverytakes hold, the government should wind down theemergency food aid programme and gear up forimproved household food security throughagricultural production and other livelihoodstrategies, including rural non-farm incomegeneration. Over time, the ministries of agriculture

and social services should assume full responsibilityfor emergency relief and smallholder production,incorporating the experience and innovations ofinternational agencies into their programmes.

As part of its agricultural recovery programme,the government is relying on commercial bankdeposits in hard currency to finance short- andmedium-term loans for farmers to rebuildagriculture (Zimbabwe, 2009). This approachseems unduly optimistic because most commercialfarms have been nationalized, and resettlement andcommunal smallholder farmers do not havetransferrable rights to their property, so they cannotbe used as collateral for loans. A possiblealternative, mooted by the government’s recoveryplan, is for banks to transfer the risk to agro-processing corporations who are keen to fundproduction by entering into contracts with farmers,especially smallholders. The contracting companiesadvance credit and inputs to the smallholder farmer,which are recouped by the company when thefarmer’s harvest is marketed.

Contract farming has a number of advantages. Thefirst is that capital can be provided to smallholdersfor inputs to increase yields and household incomes.It is the private sector which bears the risk (usuallyfrom ‘side marketing’37) as well as the benefits(profits) from the contract. Contracting companiesalso often offer smallholders extension advice,which not only benefits the smallholder, but alsoreduces the risk of the company, i.e., theexpectation that the farmer’s yields will cover thecosts of inputs. With the inputs also come bio-technological advances in the form of new seedvarieties that improve farmers’ yields. Anotheradvantage is that it offers smallholders anopportunity to produce higher value commercialcrops without requiring the capital for processingor the management expertise to operate insophisticated markets. In the absence ofgovernment initiatives for smallholder finance,contract farming offers a viable alternative thatcomplements the food security programmes runby government and international agencies.

36 See Clause 111 of STERP (Zimbabwe, 2009).37 Side marketing often arises when a gap opens between the market and contract price. Smallholders have an incentive to sell their

produce for a higher market price to third parties rather than to the contracting company at the agreed contract price.

23

Section 4 – Policy Recommendations for Recovery

For smallholders that do not qualify for donorassistance or who are not contracted, thegovernment is committed to reviving the fertilizerindustries and making all inputs available throughthe open market. Similarly, it is intent on deregulatingmarketing and the pricing of commodities, allowingfarmers to sell their produce freely at marketdetermined prices. Accordingly, the government hasdone away with the announcement of pre-plantingprices.38 However, it might reconsider this policy,at least for the first year or two, in order to providesmallholder maize producers with a strong incentiveto boost food supplies. Apart from this initial surgeto boost stocks of the national granaries, it wouldput money in the pockets of rural households, wheremultiplier effects would help stimulate economicactivity in the communal areas. It would also takepressure off the international donor agencies todistribute food and allow them to focus more onpromoting food security through agricultural and non-farm livelihood strategies. This would bring thegovernment a step closer to realising its objective ofreducing dependency on food handouts.39 Theseefforts should be complemented by the gradualorganization of farmers into commodity associationsand unions to provide smallholders with a forum thatoffers mutual support for marketing as well asresearch, technical and extension services.40

4.5 RETHINKING SOCIALPROTECTION MEASURES

Paradoxically, it has been the on-going anddeepening crisis in Zimbabwe that has enabledinternational humanitarian agencies to hone theirapproaches to food security. While food handoutsstill play an important role in their efforts, donorsare moving towards providing inputs for foodsecurity, including innovations such as the use ofvouchers and seed fairs. While these newapproaches are an improvement on food handouts,they represent an intermediate form of social

protection. More recently, the notion of cashtransfers41 has been gaining more acceptance(Ferguson, 2007; Standing, 2007).

Standing (2007) assessed different type of socialprotection methods – from food aid and vouchersto cash and capital transfers – according to anumber of principles. Broadly, he evaluates whetherthese methods were economically efficient in termsof administrative burdens, price distortions and theireffectiveness in reaching the poor. He argues thatmeans testing, conditionality and targeting that areinvolved in most social protection programmes maynot just be difficult, costly and inefficient, but areoften intrusive and demeaning. Rather than thepoor having to plead in times of need and only beinggranted assistance at the discretion of statebureaucrats or aid officials – everyone, arguesStanding, should have a minimum basic entitlementthat grants them the dignity and the opportunity tomake decisions for themselves.

The question is whether social protection schemesin poor countries can be designed to be affordable,efficient, effective and unconditional. In SouthAfrica, the Taylor Committee’s report in 2002recommended a far-reaching social protectionscheme based on a small Basic Income Grantpayable to all South Africans with a simple swipeof their national identity cards at an ATM (SouthAfrica, 2002; Ferguson, 2007).42 The Committeeargued that;

‘... by providing a minimum level of incomesupport people will be empowered to take therisks needed to break out of the poverty cycle.Rather than serving as a disincentive toengage in higher return activities, such aminimum (and irrevocable) grant couldencourage risk taking and self-reliance. Suchan income grant could thus become aspringboard for development.’ (South Africa,Department of Social Development, 2002: 61)

38 See Clauses 92, 109, 100, 126 and 127 of STERP (Zimbabwe, 2009).39 See Clause 99 of STERP (Zimbabwe, 2009).40 See Clauses 126 and 127 of STERP (Zimbabwe, 2009).41 Cash transfer programmes were first introduced in the 1990s when Brazil’s Bolsa familia and Mexico’s Opportunidades made

cash payments to poor families on condition that they ensured their children attended school or clinics regularly. By 2006 theBrazilian programme reached over 11 million households and Mexico’s scheme has become a central part of the country’s socialprotection system (Standing, 2007).

42 Better off South Africans would also receive the grant, but these funds would be recuperated through the tax system.

24

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

Despite its promise, the scheme has not beenimplemented so it provides no vindication of itsprofessed practicality or effectiveness. Anyevidence must be sought elsewhere.

Evaluations of a number of projects in Ethiopia43

found cash grants allowed beneficiaries to makestrategic decisions and prioritize their needs, suchas controlling their debt and investing in landproductivity (Standing, 2007). One interestingfinding was that the cost of implementing theschemes was much less than food aid and that thetransaction costs of beneficiaries were reducedconsiderably. In Zambia’s Kalomo Social TransferScheme a local community welfare assistancecommittee used participatory methods to identifythe poorest 10 percent of households, mostly theelderly, AIDS-effected adults and orphans. Ifscaled up to cover the whole country, it wouldamount to just 5 percent of the total currentdevelopment assistance to the country, or about0.5 percent of GDP. In Mozambique, an evaluationof USAID-funded cash grants to families affected

by floods found that most of the money was spenton local goods and services, regenerating livelihoodsand stimulating the local economy.

It is probably premature to declare these cashtransfer schemes an unqualified success, but theydo warrant rethinking how Zimbabwe mightredesign its social protection measures to ensurethat everyone has a bare minimum to live on witha modicum of dignity. These schemes may havethe best chance of success where local marketsare also encouraged to operate freely, so thatmultiplier effects stimulate growth in ruralenterprises and labour markets. Working with itsinternational partners and the private sector,Zimbabwe should experiment with cash transferswith clearly identifiable vulnerable groups such asthe elderly or those with HIV and AIDS. Basedon careful monitoring of their effectiveness andaffordability, such programmes could be extendedto cover other sub-sets of the chronically poor togradually replace more costly and less effectivemethods of delivering aid.

43 These include the USAID funded project, Cash for Relief Programme, Save the Children projects in two districts, and the MeketLivelihood Development Pilot Project.

25

PART II

COMMERCIALIZATION AND TRANSFORMATION

ECONOMIC THEORY, INTERNATIONAL EXPERIENCE

AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS

26

5.1 AGRICULTURE’S ROLE IN PRO-POOR GROWTH

As smallholder agriculture in Zimbabwe is the mainsource of livelihood for hundreds of thousands ofpoor households in the communal areas, raising theiragricultural productivity therefore has the potentialto become a primary source of pro-poor growthand poverty reduction. This optimism is born outby cross-country econometric evidence that showsthat GDP growth generated in agriculture hasconsistently had large benefits for the poor, and isat least twice as effective in reducing poverty asgrowth generated by other sectors (Mellor, 2000;Thirtle et al., 2001; Bravo-Ortega and Leaderman,2005).

However, unless the government starts to formulatea long term strategy that addresses the underlyinghistorical constraints faced by the communal areas,households will remain locked in a social and agro-economic system that perpetuates poverty andsocial distress. Foremost amongst these constraints,this paper argues, is the land tenure system andfactor market failure. Under the pressure ofpopulation, the tenure system has resulted in thesubdivision of farms into uneconomic sizes,squeezed out efficiency-enhancing capital, reducedcultivation to hand-labour, and seen the ecologicaldecline of the communal areas. Put in more humanterms:

‘... in a developed country, the farmer’s sonwho wishes to follow in his father’s footstepscan keep the farm by buying out his morecommercially minded siblings. Farmers inmany developing countries have no suchoption and must continually subdivide theirfarms for each generation until the parcelsare too small to farm profitably, leaving thedescendants with too alternatives: starvingor stealing.’ (De Soto, 2000: 49)

Although households receiving internationalassistance in Zimbabwe may neither starve norsteal, it is virtually impossible today for families toextricate themselves from chronic poverty anddependency when they have only a few hectaresof land, when rainfall is uncertain, and their soilsare poor.

5.2 LAND TENURE IN THECOMMUNAL AREAS

Institutional Failure

According to tradition, the chief was the owner ortrustee of land within his nyika or chiefdom, whichhe allocated to his subjects through his wardheadman and village kraalheads. At the householdlevel, the male head was responsible for allocatingland to members of his family. If a familysubsequently abandoned the land, it reverted to thechief to allocate to another of his subjects. Thesystem thus precluded the sale or renting of landfrom one person to another.

In reality, this system of land allocation was tobecome much messier. As land shortages becamemore acute in the 1960s and 1970s, people beganto cultivate without being granted permission fromtraditional leaders (Scoones and Wilson, 1989).44

Then, in 1982, due to the chiefs’ supposed collusionwith the Rhodesian authorities, their power toallocate land was transferred to district councilsunder the Communal Lands Act. When the PrimeMinister’s directive came in 1984 for the communalareas to be administratively divided into ward andvillage development committees (wardcos andvidcos) – that cut across traditional boundaries – itwas the chairpersons of these committees thatwere granted the authority to allocate land on behalfof councillors. On top of these were the ruling party

Section 5

Reconceptualizing the Binding Constraints

44 This practice was known as kurima madiro which means to plough where one pleases.

27

Section 5 – Reconceptualizing the Binding Constraints

structures, which felt entitled to have a say in anyimportant matters, including the allocation of land(Zimbabwe, 1994).

Although in some areas, such as Seke and Gokwe,the traditional authorities gave way to the new localadministrative committees, in other areas (e.g.,Uzumba) traditional authorities ignored the newlaws and continued to allocate land (Doré, 1993).By the 1990s, the Rukuni Commission found‘overwhelming evidence that the most serious landconflict today are within communal areas’. Theseconflicts, it added, were ‘approaching anarchy insome areas’ (Zimbabwe, 1994: 23,24). TheCommission found that the collapse of the legaland administrative structures in the communal areaslay in the ambiguity of the law, which gave authorityto councillors to allocate land according tocustomary law, thus implying a role for traditionalleaders. In this confusion, those seeking land wouldapproach whoever they believed would grant it tothem, or would simply settle inconspicuously andclear woodland, often cultivating on sloping andinfertile soils (Doré, 1993).

By the onset of the crisis in 1997, the RukuniCommission’s recommendations for communalland tenure reforms had been quietly shelved andthe institutional quagmire in the communal areasremained unresolved. In the absence of any policyor mechanism to integrate the local institutions orbuild consensus on bye-laws or rules, the communalareas were left to muddle along, dogged by a senseof powerlessness and apathy. Any notion that theland allocation system was customary or traditionalhad been lost. What remained was a system oftenure characterized by most of the drawbacks ofthe traditional system, but without the transferrablerights and benefits enjoyed by commercial farmerswho had title to their land.

Population Pressure

Despite this institutional disorder, it is important tounderstand that the system has historically providedfamilies with a safe haven during troubled times.By allowing households access to land on whichto grow crops and use natural resources at no cost,

the system at least provided ‘something foreveryone’. Poor families were thus able to houseand sustain themselves without the costly outlaysfor rent, water and electricity that are necessaryin the towns outside the communal areas. Ineconomic parlance, their cost of living was‘externalised’ onto society, and was thus a form ofsubsidy to rural families.45

The downside, however, was felt when thepopulation grew and land constraints and naturalresource degradation made themselves felt. As theimplicit subsidies and externalized costs provide anincentive for households to remain in communalareas, they tend to bind households to the land andso add further pressure to natural resources. Inaddition, families choose to remain in the communalareas for fear that their absence for any extendedperiod could result in their fields being reallocatedor claimed by others. Given these strong incentivesto maintain a foothold in the communal areas, itwas always unlikely that thousands of rural familieswould voluntarily leave the communal areas to join‘breadwinners’ in towns and cities (Zimbabwe,1981a). As the ZIMCORD document noted,‘Under the traditional system of land tenure thereis no inducement to leave one’s land, whether ornot it is used productively’ (Zimbabwe 1981b: 39).

Inefficiencies of Factor Market Allocationand Substitution

The problem is not just that the communal areasact like a sponge, continually absorbing a growingpopulation, but that the tenure system createseconomic inefficiencies through the distortion offactor markets. One way to illustrate the problem(before delving into the economics of factorallocation efficiency), is to briefly compare thecommunal and commercial tenure systems.

Before 2000, all commercial farms were held underfreehold title, allowing farmers to buy and sell landon the open market, the price of farms beingdetermined by the relative supply and demand forfarmland. As title was transferrable, farmersnegotiated loans with financial institutions forseasonal farm inputs and working capital, medium-

45 An externality is a cost to society, such as environmental degradation, when individuals benefit from using a public good – forexample, communal grazing areas. The cost is internalized when the user rather than society bears all the costs of use.

28

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

term loans for equipment and buildings, and evenlong-term loans to acquire the land itself. It wasthis interplay of factor markets for land, capitaland labour that allowed commercial farmers toallocate their resources to optimize productionefficiency according to the economic principle ofvariable factor proportions.46

It is argued here that the absence of these markets– often referred to as ‘market failure’ byeconomists – has distorted the allocation of factorsof production in communal areas to create aninefficient farming system that perpetuates poverty.At the core of this problem lies the system of tenurethat grants access to land for cultivation that carriesno cost to the user. As it does not reflect thescarcity value of land, it ‘impairs the signals andincentives that are necessary to guide and inducefarmers to use farm land efficiently’ (Schultz, 1964:125). As such, there is no price mechanism ormarket signal to constrain a growing demand forthe limited supply of land.

Inevitably, as the population burgeons and a growingnumber of eligible families claim their right to land,plots have been continually subdivided into smallerand less viable holdings. As farms become smaller,total output and hence incomes decline. With lesssurpluses available to buy yield-enhancing farminputs, outputs fall further and poverty ensues. And,since the tenure system offers no mechanismthrough which more efficient farmers can acquiremore land, better farmers are unable to consolidatetheir holdings into larger, more viable units.Conversely, it ties less efficient smallholders, whoshow little aptitude or enthusiasm for farming, toland that they might otherwise rent or sell.

The tenure system is particularly debilitatingbecause of its detrimental knock-on effects on thelabour and capital markets. During periods of rapidpopulation growth, when a relative scarcity of landdevelops, the expectation is that agriculturalproduction will be intensified by substituting landfor labour. However, in the absence of price signalsfrom a land market (which would show the price

of land increasing relative to labour) householdswill continue to demand more land – even in theface of land shortages. Moreover, since labour itselfis relatively cheap and abundant compared tocapital inputs, the rational household will also havean incentive to apply more labour rather than capitalinputs to land.

5.3 AGRICULTURALEXTENSIFICATION ANDENVIRONMENTALDEGRADATION

The net result of cost-free land is thereforedistortions in capital markets where householdshave a perverse incentive to reduce farm inputs.As they fail to maintain fertility, the soils graduallybecome exhausted and households are compelledto apply their labour to clearing woodland andopening up new land for cultivation, setting inmotion a system that perpetuates extensive orshifting types of cultivation. Reh et al., (1989), forexample, found that all potential arable land – orabout half the total area of Chiweshe communalarea – had been cleared for cultivation over time,yet only 15 percent of it was still in use. Similarly,Bruce (1990) found that between 1980 and 1988the opening up of new areas for cultivation, ratherthan higher per hectare yields, accounted for almostall increased crop production in the communalareas.

As more and more land is used for growing crops,cattle have to survive on dwindling communalpastures. In Chiweshe communal area, Reh et al.,maintained that cultivation had encroached soextensively into available livestock feed resourcesthat the binding constraint to any further expansionof cultivation was the lack of sufficient feedresources to sustain the number of cattle neededto provide draught power. The World Bank (1985)estimated (for the period 1975 to 1984) that grazingareas shrunk by 700,000 hectares as land wasbrought under cultivation, while Kundhlande andMutandi (1989) claimed that persistent

46 Also know as the principle of ‘optimal factor combination’, the criteria of allocative efficiency in farm production requires thatfactor scarcities be reflected in their respective prices and that they are used in such proportions that output is maximized for agiven cost. This condition is met when land, labour and capital are combined in such a way that the ratio between their marginalproductivities and their prices is equal.

29

Section 5 – Reconceptualizing the Binding Constraints

encroachment in Gutu communal land had reducedthe cultivation: grazing ratio from 20:80 in 1953 to51:49 in 1988.

The problem of dwindling livestock feed resourcesis exacerbated because communal grazing land isa free and indivisible public resource that carriesno opportunity cost to the user. As livestock ownerscan externalize the environmental costs of usingthe common pasture, households have a strongincentive to continue adding more livestock toalready degraded grazing areas, thus quickeningthe pace towards environmental decline andundermining the very resource base on which theirlivelihood depends (Hardin, 1968). The constraintto cattle numbers imposed by limited feedresources and the additional number of cattlerequired for draught power result in the cattleparadox: too many for the environment to sustain,but too few for draught power requirements. Cliffe(1986), for example, quoted Drinkwater’sobservation in one area that was 300 percent over-stocked in terms of its environmental carryingcapacity; yet, in terms of draught power needs itwas 53 percent under-stocked. Eventually, cattle– a form of smallholder capital par excellence –are gradually squeezed out of the farming system,

reducing cultivation to toiling with hand-heldimplements.

The foregoing clearly shows that the communalareas had already become pools of poverty wellbefore the current crisis. Rohrbach et al., note,for example, that the international community’scelebration of Zimbabwe’s maize miracle in the1980s ‘deflected attention from the extensive andconsistent reliance of a large proportion ofsmallholders on public food distributionprogrammes’ (1990: 106). Later, Campbell et al.,were to conclude ‘that the current processes ofintensification and diversification are not leadingpeople out of the poverty trap in semi-arid regions’(2002: 125).

In short, the system was neither sustainable thennor now; and the communal areas are looking lesslike safety nets and more like poverty traps. Atsome point, change for more sustainable livelihoodsmust inevitably come. While such reforms mayinvolve greater risks – for which new forms ofsocial protection (discussed earlier) should bedeveloped for the chronically poor – they also bringwith them innovation, opportunities and pathwaysout of poverty.

30

6.1 TRANSFORMING SUBSISTENCEAGRICULTURE

So far, this paper has tried to show that theunderlying problem of the communal areas’subsistence economy has been that neither the valueof land nor natural resources reflect their scarcityvalue because they are available cost-free toindividuals and households. Instead the costs arefelt throughout the farming system, the mostobvious being the externalized costs on societythrough the environment.

Circular and Cumulative Causation: aSynopsis

Cost-free access to land and natural resources actas subsidies and therefore as ‘pull’ factors forhouseholds to remain in the communal areas, whichis exacerbated by households’ fears of losing theirclaim on land. As there is no price mechanism toallocate the limited supply of land and naturalresources, demand is infinitely elastic. As thepopulation has grown, the unlimited demand forland has seen the subdivision of holdings into smallerand less viable parcels of land. This has resulted ina decline in outputs and incomes as well asinvestible surpluses for capital inputs to maintainyields and fertility. In more marginal communalfarming regions, the risk-aversion of smallholdersreduces the yield-enhancing inputs still furtherbecause the cost of fertilizer represents a largeshare of production costs relative to expectedincomes. Rohrbach et al., (1990) found, forexample, that the level of fertilizer use droppeddramatically when the risk of applying expensiveinputs could be wasted if the rains failed. In NaturalRegion V virtually no farmers used fertilizer.

Capital is finally squeezed out of the system, firstby the factor market distortions that make capitalrelatively more expensive than land and labour and,second, by the continual encroachment ofcultivation on common grazing areas, which limitsthe number of draft cattle that the communal areascan support. Finally, because the farming system

does not ascribe an underlying value to land, itcannot be used as collateral to raise loans for farmcapital. It is this combination of smaller holdings,factor market distortion and arid conditions thatdrive a process of agricultural extensification,leaving in its wake exhausted soils, overgrazedpasture, erosion and silted dams.

By any measure, most households will remainchronically poor as the system is unsustainable.They survive only at the expense of theenvironment, international assistance and thetaxpayer. In analysing this process one is remindedof Myrdal’s concept of circular and cumulativecausation which provides an apt description of thesmallholder farming system within the communalareas: a process ‘continuously pressing levelsdownwards, in which one negative factor is, at thesame time, both cause and effect of other negativefactors’ (1957: 11). More recently, this concept wasechoed by Leared: ‘Both the people and theenvironment’, he said, ‘suffer in an incessant spiralof despair’ (2009: 2).

Transcending Standard Interventions

Usually it is necessary to treat the symptoms ofany malady first. In Zimbabwe, internationalorganizations have responded generously to theplight of the hungry with direct food aid. As hungerabates, their attention is turning towards providingseed and fertilizer packs to enable households togrow their own food. As a semblance of normalityreturns, the expectation is that agriculturalists willrespond to the problems of low yields and povertyby recommending a raft of measures that includeimproved access to credit to buy yield-enhancinginputs, such as hybrid seed and fertilizers;extension advice to improve cultivation practices,minimum tillage, early planting and conservationmethods; and integrating the cropping and livestocksystems. More broadly, suggestions also includeimproving market access, promoting farmerorganizations, and managing natural resourcesmore sustainably.

Section 6

Land Tenure Reform

31

Section 6 – Land Tenure Reform

These measures will certainly assist better andmore resourceful farmers with bigger smallholdingsin higher rainfall areas to improve their incomesand reduce poverty. But these interventions canonly be of very marginal benefit to the majority ofsmallholders, especially those in the more aridcommunal areas, whose livelihoods cannot besustained by agriculture. This pessimism is sharedby Campbell et al., (2002), who believe that inthese regions, where output is so dependent on thevagaries of the weather, the likelihood of asustainable credit scheme to support inputs is highlyunlikely. Nonetheless, there is no doubt that thegovernment, with the help of the international donorcommunity, will have to continue treating thesymptoms of this poverty by providing acombination of food aid, input packs, vouchers andcash transfers for the foreseeable future.

Two Transformational Processes

In the meantime, every effort should be made totackle the underlying causes of poverty andenvironmental degradation by initiating twotransformational processes. The first is the gradualtransformation of the communal area farmingsystem to a commercial farming system byreversing the vortex of compounding negativeimpacts and initiating a positive spiral of cumulativecausation.

The remedy lies in internalizing the cost of landand natural resources to reflect their underlyingscarcity value. To do this a price must be attachedto the value of land. But since price is determinedby supply and demand, there must be a market forland. Then again, land can only be rented or soldthrough the market if it is clearly defined bothphysically and legally: it needs to confer secureand enforceable rights on its owner. The logicalconclusion of getting land to reflect its scarcityvalue therefore ends with an institutional andregulatory system of land registration andadministration to create a transparent and efficientland market. Economic theory tells us that whenthis happens the factors of production will becombined to optimize economic efficiency. Thedevelopment of land markets and the gradual

absorption of capital into the farming systemtherefore lies at the core of commercializingtraditional agriculture.

The establishment of a land market is also a crucialstep toward the operation of a secondtransformation process to reduce poverty stillfurther – through structural transformation. Thisis a process whereby the institutional (land tenure)changes in the communal areas are complementedby broad economic growth and productivity gainsin the industrial sector.47 Secure transferrablerights to communal land create incentives for rurallabour to migrate to employment opportunities inurban centres, thereby decongesting the communalareas and reducing poverty (Clarke, 1957, Cheneryand Syrquin, 1975; OECD, 2006; World Bank,2008). Thus, agriculture’s potential to reducepoverty goes far beyond standard agriculturalinterventions and its direct impact on farmers’income. As a DFIDs policy paper makes clear:

‘Over time the “structural transformation”of poor countries’ economies away fromdependence on agriculture lies at the heartof sustained poverty reduction.’ (2005: 8)

In this section we focus on the transformation ofthe farming system. In Section 8 we considerstructural transformation in more detail.

6.2 POLICY PRINCIPLES ANDOPTIONS

Local Institutional Reform

Even as government builds consensus on a policyand regulatory framework to transform the overallfarming system, the starting point must be to reformthe village and local governance institutions. Thefirst principle is to preserve the unity of commandby creating a single village authority that is nestedwithin the ward and district council structures, andthat has a single source of legitimacy and authority.There should also be clear boundaries andresponsibilities for the areas of jurisdiction at eachadministrative level.

47 In the economic theory of structural transformation it is conventional to use a two sector model, agriculture and industry. Inpractice we mean the migration of labour to non-agricultural sectors, including manufacturing and services as well as both formaland informal employment.

32

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

The second principle is that of subsidiarity: thatmatters ought to be handled by the smallest, lowestor least centralized competent authority. Authorityover land issues, for example, should be devolvedto the ward or village level when they have thecompetence to do so.

The third principle is democratic decision-makingand the separation of powers. If higher leveldecisions are to be taken with the prior informedconsent of local residents, decision makers musthave confidence that local community leadersfaithfully represent the majority view. Institutionalchange must necessarily vest legitimate authorityin communities to enable them to take democraticdecisions on their chosen paths towards landreform. The evolution towards more formal typesof tenure in Mexico, for example, allowedcertified plots in ejido communities to becomefully transferable freehold land through a qualifiedvote by the community assembly. But the factthat fewer than 15 percent of ejidos chose fulltitling showed that many smallholders saw thebenefits of maintaining their existing rights (WorldBank, 2008).

One of the sticking points to developing moredemocratic community institutions in Africa hasbeen that traditional leadership is often appointedand paid by the state. Traditional leaders thereforetend to be accountable to party or governmentauthorities rather than to the people they ostensiblyrepresent. Mamdani (1996) has also criticized the‘fused powers’ of traditional leaders, who not onlymake the rules and execute decisions, but judgeoffenders as well. Platteau, sensing the inadequacyof traditional systems, suggested that moderngroupings, where ‘the ideal of internal democracycan well substitute for the former ideal of respectfor the village traditions’, would be an improvementon traditional village associations (1992: 290). ForAlden Wily (2006), the modern community as thearbiter of rules or customs is both logical andnecessary. While it is inclusive of elders and chiefs,it is the majority of members that should decideand open the way to good governance.

Land Registration

Any registration programme must adhere to theprinciple of social legitimacy. Since institutionalchange is path dependent,48 the development ofland markets should evolve from the existing tenuresystem with the understanding and informedconsent of communities. It is they that shouldcontrol both the modifications in the land tenurerules as well as the pace of change within an agreedpolicy and regulatory framework. Unless thelegality of ownership is coupled with sociallegitimacy, formal titling can be problematic. InKenya, for example, foreclosure on small farmerswas legally permissible, but not socially legitimate.Any attempt to take possession of a plot from asmallholder defaulting on a loan was met with localresistance and the reluctance of banks to destroythe livelihood of a poor rural family (Alden Wily,2006).

Another prime consideration is the cost ofregistering, administering and enforcing land rights.Formal title hardly makes sense when theunderlying value of small plots is not sufficientlyhigh to justify the high costs of establishing andenforcing the underlying land rights. Recentadvances in technology have dramatically reducedthe cost of issuing land registration certificates. Thewidespread availability of satellite imagery andhandheld global positioning system (GPS) devices,together with institutional arrangements that putlocal actors in charge of adjudication, can providereasonable accuracy at much lower costs. Ethiopia,for example, embarked on a large scale programmein 2003 to issue land-use certificates to about 6million households. The high survey cost ofconventional methods (of between $20 and $60per stand) were reduced to roughly $1 a plot, largelybecause conflict resolution and surveying werevoluntarily provided by local land-use committees.Adding handheld GPS with accuracy to less thanone metre to record corner coordinates wouldincrease these costs by about 60 cents (Deiningeret al., 2007, World Bank, 2008).

48 Path dependence is a technological concept applied by North (1990) to patterns of institutional evolution. Earlier decisionsbetween alternative options or rules chart the direction of technological or institutional development which persists over timealong a particular path. Any incremental change in design or rules tends to continually narrow the scope of future options orchoices.

33

Section 6 – Land Tenure Reform

6.3 FARM SIZE ANDCOMMERCIALIZATION

As land certification and administration begin toenable land transfers – and thus a rental and salesmarkets to develop – the more efficientsmallholders could consolidate their landholdingsto increase their output and incomes, and producesufficient surpluses to invest in capital inputs thatimprove soil fertility and yields.

As Figure 6 shows, there is a strong and robustrelationship between the amount of land availableto a household and its income from farming. Whenfarms are very small, the household’s priority is to

meet its subsistence requirements by growingmaize. But as farms get bigger (or are consolidated)– towards 10 acres (about 4 hectares) – moreland is available for cash crops, such as cotton.Commercialization begins to emerge as the areaset aside for growing food is minimized andhousehold food security is based on the incomefrom crop sales.

Using a simple recursive regression model Doré(1993) confirmed the intuitively obvious: that asplot sizes increased so did surplus income (profits),which were both positively associated with thelevel of capital inputs (Figure 7). This supports thesupposition that when a land market allows smaller

Figure 7: Capital inputs and surpluses by farm size

Source: Doré (1993)

1600

1400

1200

1000

800

600

400

200

01.2 2.7 4.7 6.6 8.6 10.7 14.6

Farm size (acres)

Z$

Capital inputs

Surpluses

Figure 6: Household maize and cotton production by farm size

Source: Doré (1993)

300

250

200

150

100

50

01.2 2.7 4.7 6.6 8.6 10.7 14.6

Farm size (acres)

Out

put (

Z$)

Maize

Cotton

34

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

holdings to be consolidated, the accumulation ofinvestible capital will be ploughed back into thefarming enterprise, thereby increasing agriculturaloutput.

These larger holdings will also begin to absorbsurplus labour from smaller less viable farms. Solong as the marginal productivity of labour, asreflected in the wage rate, is greater than earningsfrom small parcels of land, labour will continue tobe drawn into larger, more efficient farms. Thismeans that both the farmer and the labourer willbe better off. Allowing the factors of production tobe substituted for one another through a marketmechanism will enable those who wish to moveout of farming to be adequately compensated. Asthe World Bank sees it, policies activating land rentaland sales markets can not only promoteconsolidation, but where ‘consolidation occursthrough the land rental market, win-win situationscan occur’ (2008: 92).

As farms are consolidated, another benefit becomesevident: the costs of registering title to larger plotswill be smaller as a proportion of the underlying valueof the property. A point will be reached when it willpay smallholders to upgrade their property in orderto use it as collateral against loans from formallending institutions. As with other commercialfarmers, the smallholder will be able to negotiateloans for working capital and inputs, as well asmedium- and long-term loans for equipment andbuildings – and for land itself, to consolidate further.There is thus a tremendous need for financialinnovations that can place smallholders on a ladderof ascending financial market access (Makina, 2009;World Bank, 2008). All these measures will furtherimprove productivity and yields and draw in morelabour, so that smallholders begin to make a greatercontribution towards national food security andexports.

6.4 THE LAND REFORMIMPLEMENTATION PROCESS

In 1994 the Rukuni Land Tenure Commission laidthe foundations for communal land tenure reform

by calling for an adjudication, demarcation and landregistration programme through democraticallyelected community assemblies. By taking theCommission’s recommendation a step further itwould be possible to develop a legal and institutionalframework which supports the evolution of a landmarket.

Land Registration

As a first step, the Land Tenure Commissionrecommended that ownership of communal landthat currently vests in the state (the President)should pass to the people who use it, invest in it,and whose livelihoods depend upon it. Communities,for their part, should form themselves intodemocratic village assemblies (dare or inkundla)that could, within a broad regulatory framework,decide for themselves the path and pace of changein land tenure arrangements.49 The next step wouldbe to survey the communal areas, starting with theadjudication and mapping of traditional villages,progressing to all arable and residential land forwhich land registration certificates would be issued.

Here the Commission’s recommendations tail off.The logical next step, however, is to facilitate theoperation of communal land markets. Ascommunities have far better access to localinformation than central government, they can oftenenforce and administer property rights at the locallevel at very low cost:

‘The creation of effective local landadministration institutions is a preconditionfor serious planning for change in landadministration in the communal areas ... Ifthere is no effective implementation in thesenew, lower level institutions, it will do littlegood for central ministries to indulge inexcessive planning. This applies to bothtenure and land use planning.’ (World Bank,1991: 68,69)

This suggests the establishment of a simple, low-cost local administrative system at the ward levelto register transactions electronically. In order tomeet the costs of its administration, the ward

49 While the Commission proposed that the village assembly be chaired by the traditional leader (the kraalhead), a more democraticand accountable option would be to elect a chairperson.

35

Section 6 – Land Tenure Reform

assembly should be empowered to raise revenueby a small land levy or unit (flat) tax on households.Over time, as the market matures, the moreproductive farmers may wish to consolidate theirholdings by buying land that they previously rented.

Common Property Resource Management

Priority for land tenure reform should be given tothose communities that have met certain criteria,such as establishing their own governance andadministration structures; that have reachedagreement on village boundaries; and that havedecided to proceed with a land reform programme.Such a requirement would be both an incentiveand a measure of a community’s commitment andability to embark on the slow and rocky pathtowards land tenure reform.

It should be noted, however, that where there arevast lands and low populations, the cost of enclosureand enforcing property rights are unsustainable anduneconomic. Hardin therefore acknowledged that:‘The commons, if justifiable at all, is justifiable onlyunder conditions of low population density’ (1968:1246).

The Land Tenure Commission recommended thatgrazing and other common land should be surveyed,for which a land registration certificate would beissued. Whilst the Commission recommended thatthe certificate be held in trust by the kraalhead,the more democratic alternative would be to allowthe assembly to decide whether to retain a commonproperty scheme or transform the commons intomore individualized land rights. In this case it wouldbe essential to have clear and transparentmechanisms for making the change (Deininger,

2003). In Mexico, for example, a 75 percentmajority of the ejido assembly could decide whichof the community lands should be parcelled out toindividuals and which should be held in commonproperty (World Bank, 2002).

The medium-term prescription for open access tonatural resources and the internalization of costsis to convert them into ‘common property regimes’.Central to this process is the exclusive control bya relatively small group of users over specific andbounded natural resources to encourage greatercommon responsibility for resource management(Bromley, 1989). The first requirement is todelegate formal authority to a small group of usersto enact, implement and enforce rules overresources within a particular area. Costs can beinternalized by imposing a user fee, such as astumping fee, or by a ‘cap and trade’ mechanismwhereby the number of livestock to be grazed ona particular pasture is limited, and where the rightto graze can be traded.

Unfortunately, these common property resourcemanagement schemes are notoriously difficult toimplement effectively. As there is no mechanismto determine, a priori, whether the ‘correct’(shadow) price has been agreed for user fees – ora low enough cap on livestock numbers as beenset – the inclination is to fix them too liberally. Thismeans that externalities will not be properlyinternalized, and the resource will continue to bedepleted. Despite these problems, the commonproperty regime remains an important first step inthe event that an assembly decides on a moreappropriate system of managing the commons orprivatizing them.

36

Assuming that the markets begin to transform thefarming system; that smaller holdings are graduallyconsolidated; and the communal areas are slowlydecongested as people drift towards non-agricultural employment opportunities, what policieswould best support the conversion of smallholdersinto nascent commercial farmers? What policieswould quicken the pace of sustainable pro-pooragricultural growth and the transformation of thefarming system? This section tries to elaborate themain policy thrusts to achieve these objectives, butthe overriding policy principle is one of partnershipbetween the public and private sectors, where thestate provides a regulatory framework in whichthe private sector can operate most effectively(Stiglitz: 1998).

‘Government and markets should be seen ascomplements rather than substitutes, with therole of the government being to create marketswhere they are missing and to introduce theregulations to make markets functionproperly.’ (DFID, 2005: 30)

In particular, priority should be given to spendingon public goods that support private investment thatmaximizes the impact on productivity growth andthat benefits the poor.

7.1 INVESTMENT IN PUBLIC GOODS

Public spending on agriculture in Zimbabwe hasbeen heavily biased toward subsidizing private goods:seed, fertilizer and machinery. Even under normalcircumstances, subsidies tend to be wasteful andinefficient because they distort factor prices,encouraging farmers to use more of a particularinput than is optimally efficient. For example, farmersin semi-arid regions would be prepared to add moresubsidized fertilizer to crops where the risk of droughtis high because they do not bear the full costs ofcrop losses. But subsidies have been unusually

inefficient and wasteful in Zimbabwe because theyhave been paid for by printing money, thus drivingup inflation, and because inputs have been used formaking arbitrage profits rather than production. Thechannelling of these subsidies to better-offresettlement farmers came at the expense ofdesperately needed long-term investments such asinfrastructure and research that could havebenefitted communal smallholders appreciably.

As far as the World Bank is concerned:

‘The more the state is involved in supplyinginputs, such as fertilizer and credit, and inmarketing agricultural products, the greateris the potential for corruption. That is whyrolling back the state can reduce corruption.’(2008: 254)

Prioritizing Infrastructure

The new Zimbabwe government recognizes thatit can no longer rely on RBZ quasi-fiscal activitiesto fund agriculture, but still sees a significant staterole over the short-term recovery period.50

However:

‘It should be emphasised that after STERP,the State will move away from a regime ofdependency and handouts in a bid to ensurethe independence and strength of all farmactors.’ (Zimbabwe, 2009: Clause 99)

This signals an important departure fromunsustainable public expenditure on agriculture anda determination to move towards more productiveinvestment in core public goods that strengthen the‘critical arteries and enablers in the agricultureproduction value chain’ (Zimbabwe, 2009). Theseinclude the revival of Hwange Colliery coal supply,the restoration of power supplies, the overhaulingof the National Railways freight services and therehabilitation of the irrigation infrastructure.51 In

Section 7

Policy Support for Smallholder Agriculture

50 See Clauses 86 and 112 of STERP (Zimbabwe, 2009).51 See Clause 104 of STERP (Zimbabwe, 2009).

37

Section 7 – Policy Support for Smallholder Agriculture

the absence of state financial resources and theimperative to prioritize expenditure on socialservices, the state should reform these publicenterprises and encourage foreign directinvestments in them. The role of the state wouldbe to manage and regulate the participation of theprivate sector to revamp these public enterprisesby ensuring that a fair, transparent and competitivetendering procedure is followed that boostsZimbabwe’s growth prospects.

In addition, smallholders would benefit significantlythrough public investment in research and extension(discussed below), rural infrastructure (especiallyroads and water supplies), and the improvementof property rights and the enforcement of rulesand contracts. Of particular importance is ensuringa balance between resources allocated to newinfrastructure and the resources allocated for theiroperation and maintenance to ensure theirsustainability.

Increasingly, communications are becomingimportant for improving access to market information,using established means such as radio, as well asnew information technologies such as mobile phones(DFID, 2005). In Uganda, 80 percent of communitieshave mobile phone coverage, and 5 percent ofhouseholds possess them. Broader coverage, morethan the possession of individual mobile phones,induces market participation by reducing transactioncosts in crop marketing, especially for perishablegoods. For example, the Kenya AgriculturalCommodity Exchange and Safaricom Limited collectand disseminate current and reliable commodity priceinformation to Kenyan farmers through a low-costSMS provider (World Bank, 2008).

Research

Developing countries invested 0.56 percent of theiragricultural GDP in agricultural research in 2000(including donor contributions); only about one-ninthof the 5.16 percent that developed countries invest.Part of this disparity is because private investmentmakes up just over half of research spending indeveloped countries but only 6 percent in thedeveloping world. Still, the intensity of public

investment (in relation to agricultural GDP) is fivetimes higher in industrial countries (World Bank,2008).

In the face of acute government financialconstraints to fund research, formal partnershipsbetween research institutions, the private sectorand farmers’ organizations offers an alternativesource of funding as well as an opportunity to bringfarmers’ voices into the research decision-makingprocess. The Zimbabwe government recognizesthe importance of farmers organizing themselvesinto unions and specialized commodity associationsfor research, extension and marketing,52 whileTawonezvi and Hikwa have been strong advocatesof the active participation of farmers who pressfor the type of research and extension from whichthey would benefit most. They also believe that,‘It is necessary now more than ever to involveuniversities, the private sector and farmers in orderfor research to be demand-driven’ (2006: 209).Forming such coalitions between researchinstitutions, producers and the private sector aroundparticular commodities or value chains may be themost effective way to engage the government anddonors to boost research. If government could bepersuaded to contribute its extensive facilities forresearch throughout the country, donors may bewilling to upgrade these facilities to enable theresearch coalitions to meet the recurrent costs ofresearch through levies and other contributions.

Zimbabwe’s commercial farmer associations havetraditionally formed their own researchorganizations, such as the Tobacco ResearchBoard, and forged funding arrangement withgovernment and researchers. For example, theZimbabwe Tobacco Association agreed to pay 63percent of the annual tobacco research budgetraised from a levy on the tobacco sales of itsmembers (Cole and Cole, 2006). Perhaps evenmore extraordinary was the development of theRattray Arnold Research Station by the ZimbabweSeed Maize Association from the levies paid byseed maize producers from the proceeds of theirsales.53 When the Zimbabwe Seed MaizeAssociation subsequently became incorporated asThe Seed Company Ltd a tripartite agreement was

52 See Clauses 126 and 127 of STERP (Zimbabwe, 2009).53 The Zimbabwe Seed Maize Association subsequently became incorporated as The Seed Company Ltd.

38

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

formed between the company, the research stationand government, which allowed the governmentto make extensive use of the research station’sfindings. The government was also assisted inextensive testing by the Agricultural ResearchTrust farm which was established by thecommodity associations of the CommercialFarmers’ Union for independent evaluation ofvarieties used by its members (Havazvidi andTattersfield, 2006).

Members of smallholder organizations should alsostart contributing towards adaptive research, testingand dissemination as they begin to commercialize.In this way they will have a greater say in the typeof research from which they are most likely tobenefit. This research should go further than thetechnical aspects of food production and includeagricultural economics and marketing research.Pro-poor research needs to also examine howfarmers within the communal farming system canbecome more technically efficient, as well asmonitor how the system itself is being transformed.This requires research into evolving land tenurearrangements and market incentives that couldtransform smallholder agriculture into a more pro-poor and commercially sustainable sector.

Extension

The public financing of orthodox methods ofagricultural extension, such as the training and visit(T&V) system, has come under scrutiny andsevere criticism (Anderson et al., 2006). The mainproblem has been the lack of resources andincentives for extension staff, as well as their poorrecord of accountability to farmers. Moreover,extension workers rarely keep abreast withemerging technologies or innovative extensionapproaches. As a result there is little evidence thattheir work has made any meaningful impact onproductivity. Yet the Zimbabwe government hasbeen burdened with the huge cost of maintaining amassive extension system which is not financiallysustainable. Typically, extension staff remainconfined to their offices when funds for fuel andtransport run out early in the financial year.

For reasons not dissimilar to the problems besettingresearch, the private sector has the potential tomake a significant contribution to extension.Whereas Zimbabwe is hamstrung withinnumerable funding priorities but scant resources,agricultural companies are likely to have access toresources as well as strong incentives to reach outto farmers. There are broadly two ways in whichthis may happen: by direct marketing and throughcontract farming.

Companies, eager to market their products – suchas seed, fertilizer, chemicals and equipment – areexcellent extension vehicles for technological changeand innovation diffusion by the supply of theirproducts to communal area farmers. In Mangwendecommunal land, for example, about 42 percent ofmaize producers had adopted maize hybrids in 1975.With the introduction by The Seed Company of arange of smaller pack sizes, the proportion had risento 77 percent by 1980, and by 1985 about 99 percentof growers purchased hybrid seed (Mashingaidze,2006). More recently, cotton and tobacco contractschemes have seen companies advising growers onthe use of new varieties and techniques – from landpreparation and planting dates, to the application ofchemicals and fertilizers and harvesting techniques– to improve yields for the mutual benefit of thecompanies and smallholders alike. As incomesimprove and demand grows, linkages to industry willsee an increasing variety of goods and services beingoffered to farmers.

Extension may still be publicly funded, but thegovernment should move away from its sprawling,costly and inefficient organizational structure anddevelop a more professional, cost-efficient andfocused approach to extension, applying innovativetechniques and working closely with the privatesector and farmer organizations. Public fundingcould, for example, flow through farmerorganizations and commodity associations, whichmay in turn contract out extension services to privateproviders and NGOs, as in Uganda’s NationalAgricultural Advisory Services. Commodityassociations in particular could promote farmerinterest groups around a specific crop and livestockactivity and develop marketing partnerships with theprivate sector (World Bank, 2008).

39

Section 7 – Policy Support for Smallholder Agriculture

7.2 A GROWTH AND POVERTYREDUCTION MODEL

There is increasing evidence that a ‘smallholderagricultural growth and poverty reduction model’is likely to be centred on those commodities withhigh income elasticities and values. Mellor (2000),for example, investigated three major sources ofgrowth in agriculture: yield-enhancing technology;increased land area; and a change in thecomposition of output to high-value commodities.Of these, he finds particular merit in the productionof high-value commodities – especially horticultureand livestock, which he believes can generatestrong growth of between 4 and 6 percent. And,because the agricultural sector in low-incomecountries is so large, it adds immense purchasingpower to small farmers. This, he argues, offershuge potential for poverty reduction because it isthe expenditure of the smallholders’ increasedincome on locally produced, labour-intensive, non-tradable goods and services – expanded housing,personal services, increased primary education,health services and local transport – that drivesemployment creation in the non-farm sector. Withthis spurt in employment growth, labour marketstighten quickly in the local non-farm sector, causingreal wages to stir and rise. That is why, claimsMellor, poverty declines so rapidly with increasedagricultural output.

There is undoubtedly a high-end market opportunityto exploit in order to realize this growth potential inagriculture. Fruits and vegetables are one of thefastest growing agricultural markets in developingcountries, with production increasing by 3.6 percenta year for fruits and 5.5 percent for vegetablesfrom 1980 to 2004. Exports of horticulture,livestock, fish, cut flowers, and organic productsnow make up 47 percent of all developing countryexports, far more than the 21 percent for traditionaltropical products such as coffee, tea, and cotton(World Bank, 2008). Yet, as the opportunities openfor these exports, the sanitary and phytosanitarystandards governing international trade – imposedfor reasons of food safety or to protect domesticagriculture from imported animal or plant diseases– are becoming increasingly stringent.

These grades and standards make it more difficultfor smallholders acting alone to participate in thesemarkets. How then can smallholders with limitedresources and expertise share in the gains of highvalue commodity production? The answer wouldseem to lie in contract farming, discussed earlier,where companies provide the capital, inputs andextension advice to contracted out-growers forproduction. Companies also provide processingfacilities and access to international markets forsmallholders’ produce. Indeed, there are manyexamples of successful corporate-smallholderpartnership in Africa. These vary from dairyprojects in Kenya, forestry projects in South Africa,and tobacco production in Malawi andMozambique. Until recently, Zimbabwe haddeveloped smallholder grower partnerships in suchdiverse areas as horticultural, cotton and tobaccoproduction, and ostrich farming. Of these, cottonremains one of the most successful contractfarming schemes in the country. Some 400,000cotton farmers are aggregated in smallholderfarmer associations across the country by Cottco(Leared, 2009), and the government is pushing foran increase in contract farming.54

Leared (2009) has called for the concentration ofscarce capital, skills and services in agriculturalclusters or ‘agri-hubs’ to create a corporate-smallholder model of production. A commercialfarming operation would form the core of such ahub, which would service a substantial out-growerscheme. The rationale and benefits of agri-hubswould be to reduce transaction costs, achieveeconomies of scale, and link smallholders into theagricultural value chain by providing them withfinancial services, farm inputs, transport andlogistics, processing and marketing, and in somecases storage and post harvest management. Morespecifically, the agri-hub would offer smallholdersthe best chance of success by providing them withaccess to, inter alia:

• Planning, agronomy and extension services,plus in-house training programmes for the long-term transfer of skills;

• Seasonal and developmental finance –implemented and monitored by the scheme;

54 See Clause 117 of STERP (Zimbabwe, 2009).

40

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

• Technological advances (seeds and fertilizers)– at the right price in the right pack sizes andon time – and appropriate mechanization; and

• Basic health and education facilities to farmingfamilies.

In short, the agri-hub concept would serve to linkland, capital and people in a sustainable, equitableand competitive manner.

Leared seems to have in mind the development ofagri-hubs in the commercial-resettlement areas ofZimbabwe. The challenge therefore is to weighthe prospects and possibilities of projecting these‘beachheads of growth’ into the communal areas.In doing so, agri-hubs have a striking resemblanceto the ‘growth point’ concept developed by theTribal Trust Land Development Corporation(TILCOR) in the 1960s and 1970s, and adoptedby its successor, the Agricultural and RuralDevelopment Authority (ARDA) afterindependence. A growth point consisted of a coreestate located on irrigable soil on which capital andexpertise were concentrated to develop a largescale commercial farming operation in thecommunal areas. Out-growers were located on theperiphery of the core estate, which serviced theirneeds. Growth points were also to serve as top-tier centres of urban growth in the communal areaswhich not only included shopping, administrative,agricultural, health and educational facilities, butalso ‘a variety of small-scale industrial andcommercial enterprises which will provide the basisfor self sustaining growth’ (Zimbabwe, 1981b: 40).

ARDA, which currently consists of 30 estates thatcovers 293,000 hectares of mainly communalfarmland, was described by one official as having‘been reduced to a mere shadow of our formerself’.55 Another report described these estates as‘dormant’.56 ARDA therefore epitomizes theinefficiencies of state farming. Large areas remainunutilized, scarce resources are wasted, and thereare few incentives, risks or accountability toperform effectively. Its losses have been a net drainon the exchequer. An opportunity therefore existsfor the government to convert the ARDA estates

into agri-hubs in communal areas. Once clear plans,transparent processes and competitive tendingprocedures are firmly in place, the ARDA estatescould be sold to commercial agriculturalconsortiums to promote sustainable corporate-smallholder partnerships that produce high valuecrops for export. However, such agri-hubs neednot be limited to ARDA estates, but could beinitiated in any one of the hundreds of rural servicecentres in the communal areas – within theparameters of a well-conceived regulatoryframework and democratic decision-makingprocesses.

7.3 AGRICULTURAL MARKETS,FOOD SECURITY AND PRICEVOLATILITY

Agricultural economic reforms in the 1990s sawthe successful privatization of the Dairy MarketingBoard and the Cotton Marketing Board, but theGMB remained firmly in state hands. Indicationsare that the inclusive government intends to moveaway from the state subsidized inputs and marketcontrols on the purchase and sale of agriculturalcommodities. As part of its recovery programme(STERP), all inputs are to be made availablethrough the market (Clause 92), and thederegulation of marketing will allow farmers tosell their produce on the open market (Clause109). To ensure that farmers receive competitiveprices for their produce, a commodity exchangeis to be established (Clause 128). Whilederegulation removes GMBs monopoly on grainpurchases, it will remain the purchaser of lastresort (Clauses 111).

The notion that the GMB should be the buyer oflast resort appears to be widely accepted, but asargued earlier, there are dangers inherent ingovernments’ racheting up floor prices. Even whenorganizations such as the GMB are tasked withrunning commercial operations to maintain strategicreserves and price stability, their interventions areoften poorly timed, and sometimes subject toinefficiencies, corruption and vested interests,resulting in huge fiscal costs (World Bank, 2008).

55 The Herald, 17 April 2009.56 The Standard, 10 December 2006.

41

Section 7 – Policy Support for Smallholder Agriculture

As liberalizing trade can be a source of ‘quick wins’for reducing price volatility, the government shouldrather consider strengthening regional trade links.South Africa, for example, decided against holdinga food security reserve. Instead, it responds to foodemergencies by buying private stocks and importingfrom the world market (Coulter, 2005). Similarly,during poor seasons when grain is in short supply,high maize prices would be buffered by Zimbabweallowing private imports of maize from South Africaand elsewhere. The government for its part couldassist the most vulnerable groups with vouchersor cash transfers to buy food.

To support trade mechanisms in smoothing outmaize price volatility and to provide a simple floorprice system to protect the poor, Coulter andOnumah (2002) have proposed the setting up of aregulatory framework for a commercially based‘warehouse receipt system’ (WRS) for the storageof maize and other grain crops. Essentially, theWRS works by enabling farmers to store their grainwith warehousing agents when production is highand prices depressed. Once stocks decline andprices rise again, farmers can off-load their grainat a higher price. One of the benefits of the system

is that the farmers’ warehouse receipts of graindeposits can be used as a negotiable instrumentand as collateral with banks for farm loans.Warehouse receipts could also be used for tradingon the new commodity exchange.

Should the government still insist on establishing afood security reserve and act as a buyer-of-lastresort, commercial warehouses could do so onbehalf of government. Coulter (2005) suggests thatwarehouse operators would simply issue a receiptfor grain deposits. The government would then buythe receipts at the floor price, plus carrying costs.The key is to make the reserve as small as possibleand to set the floor price just high enough to allowmost smallholders to break even, but low enoughto avoid it being used frequently. Apart fromsignificantly reducing the cost of managing nationalfood reserves, the warehouse system allows boththe government and international food aid agenciesto manage food stocks using receipts withouthaving to invest substantially in warehousesthemselves. Since there would be little justificationfor retaining the GMB, the Zimbabwe governmentmight consider auctioning off the GMBs assets toprivately operated warehouses.

42

The second transformation process, mentioned inSection 6, is structural transformation. Here weexamine how the process of transformation works,how it worked in China, and how it might work inZimbabwe and, in the long term, how it couldsignificantly reduce poverty. With these changescome the evolution of a more unimodal agrarianstructure that provides a ladder of opportunity forthe poor, as well as changes in spatial patterns thatwould see the emergence of small towns servicinga more prosperous rural hinterland.

8.1 THE PROCESS OF STRUCTURALTRANSFORMATION

The concept of structural transformation, whichColin Clark credited to the observations of 17thcentury economist Sir William Petty, is that ascountries become more economically advanced,‘the numbers engaged in agriculture tend to declinerelative to the numbers in manufacture, which inturn decline relative to the numbers engaged inservices’ (Clark, 1957: 492). The repeatedconfirmation across countries and over time, thatgrowth is associated with a reallocation ofeconomic activity away from agriculture to onepredominantly driven by manufacturing andservices has elevated the concept of structuraltransformation to one of the most robust stylizedfacts of development (Syrquin, 1989, DFID, 2005).

This transformational process is set in motion bytwo economic principles. The first, known as EngelsLaw, holds that agricultural goods have a relativelylower income elasticity than manufactured goods,meaning that as people’s incomes rise, theirdemand for manufactured goods rises relative tofood. Since the demand for labour is derived fromthe demand for goods and services, more and morelabour will be demanded for the production ofmanufactured goods relative to agricultural goods.Over time, as development proceeds, an everincreasing proportion of a country’s population willtherefore be engaged in manufacturing andservices, as opposed to those engaged in

agricultural activities. This process is given addedimpetus by a second economic principle, thepositive relationship between the rate of growth ofindustrial output and the rate of productivity growth,known as Verdoorn’s law. The most likelyexplanation for this phenomenon is the increasingeconomies of scale that are possible within theindustrial sector, the agglomeration effects or‘clustering’ of complementary industries locatedwithin the same town or city, as well as thecompetitive and innovative business environmentof cities.

It is not just that higher demand for manufacturedgoods and the higher levels of productivity in themanufacturing sector enables manufacturing togrow faster than agriculture, but it will drive theoverall growth in an economy. The operation ofthese two economic principles thus draws peopleaway from farms and smallholdings and intofactories, offices and shops. It is for this reasonthat only 6 percent of the work force, on average,in OECD countries is employed in agriculture. Bycontrast, in Zimbabwe – in common with otherdeveloping countries – about 70 percent of thepopulation is still engaged in agricultural production.It also means that although agriculture’s outputincreases in absolute terms, its contribution as aproportion of total GDP declines.

8.2 CHINA’S TRANSFORMATION

Although many countries have been through or aregoing through a process of structuraltransformation, China provides a radicalcontemporary example of how it has worked andits impact on poverty reduction. Its reform, knownas Gai Ge Kai Feng, roughly translates into‘change the system, open the door’, and meanschanging the incentives and ownership to a privateenterprise system and liberalizing trade (Dollar,2008). It therefore welcomed direct foreigninvestment that brought technology andmanagement skills to build capacity for Chineseworkers and firms.

Section 8

Structural Transformation

43

Section 8 – Structural Transformation

When China started to reform its collectiveagriculture, it was largely a rural country in which80 percent of its vast population lived in the ruralareas. Today, only 60 percent do so. It is estimatedthat 200 million people relocated from the rural tothe urban areas. The first lesson from China,therefore, is that the process of structuraltransformation is driven by very high rates ofeconomic growth in the industrial sector of theeconomy. Although agriculture notched upimpressive rates of growth of 6.3 percent annuallybetween 1991 and 2005, it still lagged behindindustry, which grew consistently above 10 percentper annum. It was this large productivity gap thatacted as a centripetal force, pulling rural migrantsinto higher productivity urban employment.Because migrants are now more productive andearn more, they have been an important source ofgrowth and poverty reduction for China. The shareof the population living beneath the poverty line inChina declined from over 60 percent at thebeginning of economic reform in 1978 to just 7percent in 2007, 57 which in global historical termsrepresents the most successful rates of povertyreduction ever.

These powerful pull factors are sometimes seenas sufficient conditions for structuraltransformation, suggesting that policy-makers canignore the need for rural land tenure reform. Here,again, China’s experience is instructive. Althoughthe Chinese government disbanded its agriculturalcollectives by introducing a ‘household responsibilitysystem’, the passage of a new property rights lawin March 2007, limited farmers’ land rights torenewable 30-year land-use leases. Onedisappointed commentator called for smallholdersto be given marketable ownership rights to the landthey farm:

‘If they could sell their land, tens of millionsof underemployed farmers might findproductive work. Those who stay on the farmcould acquire bigger land holdings and usethem more efficiently. Nor will the new lawlet peasants use their land as security onwhich they could borrow and invest to boostproductivity.’58

Indeed, it has been large-scale expropriations offarmland that was acquired for housing and factoryconstruction that rendered millions of farmerslandless, while enriching those who acquired it forvirtually nothing. As a result, land disputes havebecome a leading cause of social unrest, sparkingthousands of protests across China by poor farmersoutraged at the expropriation of their land fornegligible or no compensation. The other lessonfrom China, therefore, is the need to initiate theprocess of granting farmers land rights at theearliest stages of reform in order to protect theirland rights and to allow them to benefit from them– whether they remain farmers or decide tomigrate to work opportunities in cities.

8.3 A TRANSFORMATIONSCENARIO FOR ZIMBABWE

The overarching aim of decongesting the communallands and reducing poverty rests upon a twin-trackstrategy:

• Initiating communal land reforms thatincreases tenure security to facilitate a smoothprocess of migration from the communal areasto non-farm work and job opportunitieselsewhere

• Building a competitive economy throughmacroeconomic reforms, trade liberalizationand an investment-friendly climate that drivesproductivity and economic growth to creatework and jobs in the non-farm sectors.

Push and Pull Factors

In the communal areas, many households do notmake productive use of their land. Although theywould benefit by renting it out, they fear losingtheir claim over it. In these circumstances, therewould clearly be a benefit both to those wantingto rent land and those wanting to rent out theirland if tenure was more secure and the law didnot prevent them from entering into a rent or saleagreement. The process of providing householdsin the communal areas with more secure tenure

57 The World Bank’s ‘cost of basic needs’ poverty line is based on the minimum consumption that a person needs (2,100 caloriesper day) plus other basic necessities of life.

58 The Economist, 8 March 2007. Leader: China’s next revolution (p.11).

44

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

would therefore enable the more resourcefulsmallholders to rent or buy neighbouring plots toconsolidate their smallholding into more viableplots. Because such agreements would enableland to be more productively used, there wouldalso be a boost in national production. Thosesmallholders who are able to find alternative workor employment elsewhere would be able to eitherrent out or sell their communal plots through anemerging communal land market. With the benefitof renting or selling their land, prospectivemigrants could explore alternative non-farmlivelihood options.

‘As opportunities in the non-farm economyincrease, land markets allow households toengage in migration, specialization,investment, and intergenerational landtransfer, thereby improving productivity andparticipants’ earnings. Households with lowagricultural skills are likely to be able toobtain higher incomes from off-farmemployment than from farming, and thus willbe better off if they rent out some or all oftheir land for others to cultivate.’ (Deininger,2003: 86)

The process of creating more secure individualtenure and setting up common property regimeswill also gradually internalize costs and reduce theimplicit subsidies enjoyed by communal households.As the cost of living between the rural areas andtowns begins to narrow, so the incentives forremaining in the communal areas will declinerelative to migrating to urban centres. This ‘push’from the communal areas must be matched by the‘pull’ of work and job opportunities from outsidethe communal areas. The corollary to land tenurereforms, therefore, is broad-based economicgrowth that drives investment and employment.This is a sine qua non for the transformationprocess because it allows urban centres tocontinually absorb the inflow of migrants into higherproductivity jobs that reduce poverty. Without thissolid growth, communal households will simplysubstitute rural for urban poverty in a ‘migrationof despair’ (OECD, 2006). In particular, Zimbabwemust avoid the experience of most sub-Saharancountries over the last 40 years, where the shareof labour in agriculture has declined dramatically,but which have experienced almost no growth in

per capita GDP – which is consistent with theobserved urbanization of poverty (World Bank,2008).

Supporting Policies

Macroeconomic stability and competitive exchangerates should be a central policy plank in thetransformation process, not only becauseexpanding export markets will feed back into anincreased demand for local labour, but also becausecompetitive exchange rates favour labour intensiveproduction. Yet, while sound economic policies area necessary condition to encourage migration tourban areas, they are not sufficient. They must besupported by urban development policies that turnnon-farm activities into sustainable urbanlivelihoods, address the need for secure urban landrights and affordable housing, and provide socialprotection, utilities and services that root familiesin the urban environment.

Another central plank in the transformation processis education. Evidence shows that the younger,wealthier, better educated and more resourcefulmembers of communal households are more likelyto find suitable income earning opportunities inurban areas and generally make a success ofmigrating out of the rural areas. It is the inability ofthe many poor and uneducated to move into skilledor even semi-skilled employment that underlies thepersistence of poverty and the inequality thatemerges when economic growth takes off outsideagriculture (Banerjee and Newman, 1993;Hoddinot, 1994; Jonasson and Helfand, 2008). Thisonly serves to underline the national priority ofeducating and developing the capabilities of allchildren, including the poorest, and equip them toeventually escape their rural poverty.

Research by Jonasson and Helfand (2008)identifies another crucial variable in shaping non-agricultural opportunities: location. Althoughindividual and household characteristics such asgender, education and wealth are significant factorsin explaining the likelihood of engaging in non-farmemployment, locational factors – distance to largermarkets, infrastructure, and the level of localaggregate demand – explained more variance thanhousehold characteristics, and nearly two-thirds asmuch variance as individual characteristics. This

45

Section 8 – Structural Transformation

geographical concentration of economic activitiesassumes even greater importance whenhouseholds are less able to escape poverty thatrelies solely on agricultural income. The authorstherefore recommend that:

‘... promotion of rural non-agriculturalactivities should be an ingredient in strategiesaimed at developing viable rural economiccentres, that is, small and medium sized[centres] that are "growth motors" inthemselves or well connected with the broaderurban economy.’ (2008: 22)

These rural growth motors, they argue, couldprovide an attractive alternative to migration tometropolitan areas. Relative to large cities, theycould also serve as places that offer lower costsof living for their residents and lower costs ofproduction for their businesses.

8.4 SPATIAL STRUCTURE ANDURBAN DEVELOPMENT

The failure of urban development in the communalareas is not simply a lack of infrastructuraldevelopment, but a function of the very limitedpurchasing power of households within the serviceregion of rural centres (Johnson, 1972). Thesubdivision of land into smaller and less viableholdings reduces smallholders’ incomes andpurchasing power, thus weakening their forwardsupply linkages into commodity markets andagricultural processing enterprises, as well as theirbackward demand linkages for consumer goodsand farm capital. In the absence of a market forgoods and services that have a relatively high rangeand threshold59 there is little incentive for businessenterprises to relocate to rural centres. InZimbabwe’s case, businesses are also deterredfrom relocating and investing in rural centres incommunal areas because they cannot securestrong property rights such as freehold title overtheir properties, but have to rely on annual leasespaid to the district administration. Without viablebusinesses and adequately resourced households

to meet the maintenance costs of infrastructureand services, their provision becomes difficult tojustify.

Broadly, then, the very limited purchasing powerof smallholders has inhibited the functionalcomplexity of the many rural centres within thecommunal areas, which remain small and inert.Thus:

‘Despite its intellectual appeal, the markettown concept has, in general, failed becausethe basic strategy of growth did not providethe essential foundation of raising ruralincomes. With a change in the strategy, themarket town can become the cornerstone ofthe development effort.’ (Mellor, 1976: 188)

It is precisely because communal land tenurereform provides the opportunity to raise ruralincomes by the consolidation of holdings into viablefarming units that it is the foundation of a spatialand structural transformation strategy.

As communal farmers begin to consolidate theirholdings and increase production, their earnings andtheir demand for a range of goods and servicesrise. These then strengthen backward economiclinkages for agricultural inputs, such as improvedhybrid seeds, fertilizer and capital equipment toimprove productivity. Smallholders will also beginto demand improved financial services, such asbanking facilities both for savings as well as loans,using their secure property rights to land ascollateral. A growing prosperity among farmerswould also place a demand on improved socialservices and infrastructure: better schools andhealth services, along with communication, roadsand water supplies. Increased local agriculturalproduction would also open up opportunities forstrengthening forward economic linkages. Theprivate sector, for example, could establishmarketing outlets or agro-industrial processingplants, whose size and sophistication could varyfrom small-scale processing plants, such as grindingmills, to more complex processing plants for theexport of high-value goods. In this way rural

59 In the parlance of the geographer – the range of a good is defined as the distance over which people are prepared to travel to buygoods or services, whereas the threshold refers to a certain minimum population with the purchasing power necessary to supportthe supply of a particular good or service.

46

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

centres could become the focal point for suppliesof goods and services for farmers, as marketingand processing centres for their production, andas destinations for migrants to live and work, eitherby finding jobs or by operating micro- and small-scale enterprises: trading, making goods or providingservices.

Supporting Policies

If this transformation scenario is to become areality, certain other fundamental changes withinrural centres are required: secure long termproperty rights, land-use planning, the provision ofinfrastructure and social facilities, and an electedlocal authority to plan, guide and control the centre’sdevelopment as well as facilitate the growth of ademocratic civic culture.

In order to attract businesses that are willing tomake long term investments as well as smallholderswanting to diversify their livelihoods into non-farmactivities, property rights in rural centres should bestrengthened, preferably by converting stands intofreehold title. As more companies and migrantsacquire business and residential stands, asustainable demand would be created for physicalinfrastructure (power, communications, roads andwater) and social infrastructure (clinics andschools) at rural centres. By the same token,improved infrastructure would create a magnet formore businesses and skills to relocate at the centres.Not only would this make for the more efficientand sustainable use of infrastructure, but it wouldprovide a basis for self-sustaining growth.

Agri-hubs could also play a vital role inconcentrating agricultural skills and capital in ruralcentres by establishing a core estate and processingfacilities for the rural hinterland. The notion thatagricultural corporations should bid for and manageARDA estates implies the need for clear policyguidelines and a regulatory framework to providefor private land acquisition in and around ruralcentres that can become the local engine ofinclusive growth.

While the communal plots would be consolidatedinto ever larger holdings, the synergetic effects ofprivate, local authority and government investmentwould concentrate skills and capital in rural centres.

Eventually, the complementary growth linkagesbetween farm and town would result in a spatialmetamorphosis as the distinction between farmsand rural centres becomes more sharply defined.As the development of the symbiotic economicrelationship between centre and hinterlandmatures, farm incomes should continue to rise andhigher order goods demanded. The urban responsewould be to draw in more resources and diversifyits activities, thereby increasing the town’sfunctional complexity and lend it a self-sustainingpolarity. Over time, this process will allow ruralcentres to develop into small towns that have theessential services to support a vibrant farmingcommunity.

8.5 An Evolving Unimodal AgrarianStructure

The development of a land market that includescommunal, resettlement and commercial farmlandshould in the long run gradually see the consolidationof small communal plots into more viable andproductive farming units, and the subdivision oflarger underutilized commercial farms. The dualagrarian structure, which had made it virtuallyimpossible for a small communal farmer to buy alarge commercial farm, would gradually dissolve.In its place a more ‘unimodal’ structure shouldemerge made up of a variety of different farmsizes, but which consists mainly of small- tomedium-sized family farms. Indeed, the size offarms would no longer be determined byadministrative fiat, but the allocation of resourcesthat reflects farmers’ skills and their capital base.As John Bruce notes:

‘Through the operation of the land market,agrarian structure changes with othertransformations in the economy asdevelopment proceeds. Sizes of units increaseor decrease, and distributions changedepending on changes in relative factor pricesand other economic changes. Interventionsin land markets are not at all unusual tomanage change. ... But the market is the basicmechanism.’ (1990: 55)

As a national land market develops the distinctionbetween the different types of farming systemswill become more blurred. The many different farm

47

Section 8 – Structural Transformation

sizes will provide a ‘ladder of opportunity’ foraspiring and productive farmers to climb, either byconsolidating their farms or by buying a bigger farmelsewhere. Thus, according to Hayami:

‘... the agrarian structure of developingeconomies will gradually shift from thepresent bifurcated system to a unimodalstructure where the middle class is dominantand in which even the landless labourers havea chance to ascend.’ (1989: 753)

As this new agrarian structure emerges, thegovernment should work towards integrating thevarious tenure systems into a single legal andregulatory framework and land administrationsystem.

48

Two years after the death of Mao Zedong, Chinaembarked on a remarkable journey of growth andtransformation that has amazed the world andwhich saw a precipitous decline in those living inpoverty. Obviously Zimbabwe is not China and mustchart its own course. Although Zimbabwe isunlikely to match China’s heady pace ofdevelopment and modernization, it nonetheless hasthe human, capital and natural resource potentialto grow and develop steadily to reduce povertysignificantly and eventually shed its dependenceon international aid. Equally important, Zimbabwehas the legal, institutional and cultural heritage tomake rapid gains if it chooses to ‘change thesystem, open the door’.

Section 9

Concluding Remarks

This paper has argued that one of the systems thatshould change is the communal land tenure system.Many of these suggestions are not new, but buildon the recommendations of the seminal work ofthe Rukuni Land Tenure Commission that have laindormant for 15 years. Its recommendations offeredthe stepping stones for extending smallholders’property rights and creating land markets to unlockthe value of land. Nor are they new to a countrythat has benefited enormously from a history ofagricultural and urban land markets, but fromwhich the rural poor in the communal areas havebeen excluded. It is these markets, together withsound economic policies that enable rapid growth,that are necessary to decongest the communalareas and provide the foundation for the structuraltransformation of the economy.

49

Alden Wily, L. (2006), Land Rights Reform and Governance in Southern Africa: How to make itwork in the 21st Century? United Nations Development Programme, New York.

Anderson, J.R., G. Feder, and S. Ganguly (2006), The Rise and Fall of Training and Visit Extension: AnAsian Mini-drama with an African Epilogue. In A.W. Van den Ban and R.K. Samanta, (eds.),Changing Roles of Agricultural Extension in Asian Nations. B. R. Publishing Corporation, NewDelhi.

Auret, D. (1995), Urban Housing: A National Crisis? Mambo Press/The Catholic Commission forJustice and Peace in Zimbabwe. Harare, Zimbabwe.

Banerjee, A. and A.F. Newman (1993), Occupational Choice and the Process of Development. Journalof Political Economy. 101(2), pp.274–298.

Bravo-Ortega, C. and D. Lederman (2005), Agriculture and National Welfare around the World:Causality and International Heterogeneity since 1960. World Bank Policy Research WorkingPaper Series 3499, Washington, DC.

Bromley, D.W. (1989), Property Relations and Economic Development: the Other Land Reform. WorldDevelopment. 17(6), pp.867–877.

—— (ed.) (1992), Making the Commons Work: Theory, practice and policy. ICS Press, San Francisco.

Bruce, John W. (1990), Legal Issues in Land Use and Resettlement. Background paper prepared forthe World Bank (1991). Mimeograph, Harare.

Campbell, B., J. Sayer, W. Kozanayi, M. Luckert, M. Mutamba and C. Zindi (2002), Household livelihoodsin semi-arid regions: options and constraints. Centre for International Forestry Research, Bogor.

Chenery, H.B. and M. Syrquin (1975), Patterns of Development, 1950–1970. Oxford University Press,London.

Chimedza, R. (1994), Rural Financial Markets, in M. Rukuni, M. and C.K. Eicher Zimbabwe’s AgriculturalRevolution. University of Zimbabwe Publications, Harare.

Christoffersen, N. (ed.) (1997), Natural Resources Management in Southern Africa. Proceedings ofthe Regional Natural Resource Management Project. Biennial Conference, Victoria Falls.

Clark, C. (1957), Conditions of Economic Progress. (3rd edition) MacMillan, London.

Cliffe, L. (1986), Policy Options for Agrarian Reform in Zimbabwe: A Technical Appraisal. FAOReport, Harare.

Cole, D.L. and J.S. Cole (2006), Tobacco Research and Development, in M. Rukuni, P. Tawonezi and C.Eicher (eds.) Zimbabwe’s Agricultural Revolution Revisited, University of Zimbabwe, Harare.

Coulter, J.P. (2005), Making the transition to a market-based grain marketing system. World Bank/DFID, Washington, DC.

Coulter, J.P. and G.E. Onumah (2002), The role of warehouse receipt systems in enhanced commoditymarketing and rural livelihoods in Africa. Food Policy. 27(4), pp.319-337.

Cusworth, J and J. Walker (1988), Land Resettlement in Zimbabwe: A Preliminary Evaluation. OverseasDevelopment Administration, London.

Bibliography

50

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

Deininger, K. (2003), Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction. A World Bank Policy ResearchReport. The World Bank/Oxford University Press.

Deininger, K., D. Ayalew Ali, S. Holden, and J. Zevenbergen. (2007), Rural Land Certification inEthiopia: Process, Initial Impact, and Implications for Other African Countries. World BankPolicy Research Working Paper 4218. World Bank, Washington, DC.

De Soto, Hernando (2000), The Mystery of Capital, Bantam Press.

DFID (2005), Growth and poverty reduction: the role of agriculture. DFID Policy Paper.

Dollar D. (2008), Lessons from China for Africa. Policy Research Working Paper 4531. The WorldBank.

Doré, D. (1993), Land Tenure and the Economics of Rural Transformation: A Study of Strategies toRelieve Land Pressure and Poverty in the Communal Areas of Zimbabwe. D.Phil, Oxford University.

FAO/WFP (2001), Crop and Food Supply Assessment Mission to Zimbabwe. FAO Global Informationand Early Warning System on Food and Agriculture. World Wide Programme.

—— (2007), Crop and Food Supply Assessment Mission to Zimbabwe. Food and AgriculturalOrganization and World Food Programme, Rome.

—— (2008), Zimbabwe: Crop and Food Supply Assessment. Special Report by the Food and AgricultureOrganization and the World Food Programme, Rome.

Ferguson, J. (2007), Formalities of Poverty: Thinking about Social Assistance in Neoliberal South Africa.African Studies Review, 50(2), pp.71–86.

Floyd, B. (1962), Land Apportionment in Southern Rhodesia, in R. Prothero (ed.) People and Land inAfrica. Oxford University Press, London.

Gunter, B.G., M.J. Cohen and H. Lofgren (2005), Analysing Macro-Poverty Linkages: An Overview.Development Policy Review. 23(3), pp.243-265.

Hardin G. (1968), The Tragedy of the Commons. Science. 162: 1243-4.

Havazvidi, E.K. and R.J. Tattersfield (2006), Development of the Seed Industry, in M. Rukuni, P. Tawoneziand C. Eicher (eds.) Zimbabwe’s Agricultural Revolution Revisited, University of Zimbabwe, Harare.

Hawkins, Tony and Daniel Ndlela (2009), Foreign Trade, Competitiveness, and the Balance ofPayments. Comprehensive Economic Recovery in Zimbabwe, Working Paper Series No.6, UNDP-Zimbabwe, Harare.

Hayami, Y. (1989), Reply to Binswanger and Elgin, in A. Maunder and A. Valdés (eds.) Agriculture andGovernments in an Interdependent World. Dartmouth, Aldershot.

Heath, R. (1978), Rhodesian Service Centres and Service Regions. Unpublished M.Phil. thesis.University of Zimbabwe, Harare.

Herbst, J. (1990), State Politics in Zimbabwe. University of Zimbabwe, Harare.

Hoddinott, J. (1994), A Model of Migration and Remittances Applied to Western Kenya. Oxford EconomicPapers. 46(3), pp.459–76.

HRW (2003), Not Eligible: The Politicisation of Food in Zimbabwe. Human Rights Watch. Vol.15,No.17(A).

ICG (2004), Blood and Soil. International Crisis Group, Brussels.

—— (2009), Zimbabwe: Engaging the Inclusive Government. African Briefing No.59. InternationalCrisis Group, Brussels.

51

Bibliography

Jansen, D.J. and A. Rukovo (1992), Agriculture and Policy Environment: Zambia and Zimbabwe –Political Dreams and Policy Nightmares. OECD Technical Paper No.74. OECD, Paris.

Johnson, J.H. (1972), Urban Geography: An Introductory Analysis. (2nd Edition) Pergamon Press.

Jonasson, E. and S.M. Helfand (2008), Locational Determinants of Rural Non-agriculturalEmployment: Evidence from Brazil. Department of Economics Working Papers, Lund University.

Kanyenze, G. (2009), Labour Markets and the Rebuilding of Human Capital. Comprehensive EconomicRecovery in Zimbabwe, Working Paper Series No.3. UNDP-Zimbabwe, Harare.

Kinsey, B.H. (1984), The Strategy and Tactics of Agrarian Reform: Resettlement and Land Policy inZimbabwe. Discussion Paper 136. University of East Anglia, Norwich.

Krueger, A.O., M. Schiff, and A. Valdés (eds.) (1991), The Political Economy of Agricultural PricingPolicy. World Bank, Washington, DC.

Kundhlande, G. and R. Mutandi (1989), Experience of the CARD Programme in Gutu in relation toimproving livestock and grazing production. In B. Cousins (ed.) People, Land and Livestock. CASS.University of Zimbabwe, Harare.

Larson, D.W. and A. Swire-Thompson (1999), The Effects of Grain Market and Policy Reforms onBusiness Decisions and Competitiveness in Zimbabwe: 1991-1997.<http://www.ifama.org/tamu/iama/conferences/9/1999/1999%20Congress/Forum%20Papers_PROCEEDINGS/Larson_Don.PDF>

Leared, H. (2009), Development Beachheads: The case for agricultural hubs as platforms forgrowth and development in sub-Saharan Africa. A Brenthurst (Draft) Discussion Paper, Harare.

Lele, U. and S. Stone (1989), Population Pressure, the Environment and Agricultural Intensification.MADIA Discussion Paper 4. World Bank, Washington, DC.

Makina, D. (2009), Recovery of the Financial Sector and Building Financial Inclusiveness,Comprehensive Economic Recovery in Zimbabwe, Working Paper Series No.5. UNDP-Zimbabwe,Harare.

Mamdani, M. (1996), Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa and the Legacy of Late Colonialism.Princeton University Press.

Marongwe, N. (2003), Farm occupation and occupiers in the new politics of land in Zimbabwe. In A.Hammer, B. Raftopoulos and S. Jensen. Zimbabwe’s Unfinished Business. Weaver Press, Harare.

Mashingaidze, K. (2006), Maize Research and Development. In M. Rukuni, P. Tawonezi and C. Eicher(eds.) Zimbabwe’s Agricultural Revolution Revisited. University of Zimbabwe, Harare.

Mellor, J. (1976), The New Economics of Growth: A Strategy for India and the Developing World.Cornell University Press, Ithaca, N.Y.

—— (2000), Faster More Equitable Growth: The Relation between Growth in Agriculture andPoverty Reduction. CAER II Discussion Paper No. 70. Harvard Institute for InternationalDevelopment, Cambridge, M.A.

Mhishi, S.G. (1995), A critical analysis of the Resettlement Programme in Zimbabwe. ZimbabweFarmers Union/Friedrich Ebert Foundation, Harare.

Muir-Leresche, K. and C. Muchopa (2006), Agricultural Marketing. In M. Rukuni, M. Tawonezi and C.Eicher (eds.) Zimbabwe’s Agricultural Revolution Revisited, University of Zimbabwe, Harare.

Myrdal, G. (1957), Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Regions. Duckworth, London.

Ndlela, D.B. (1981), Dualism in the Rhodesian National Economy. Lund Economic Series 22.

52

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

Ndlela, D. and P. Robinson (2006), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Zimbabwe. AgriculturalDistortions Research Project Working Paper (Draft). World Bank, Washington DC.

North, D.C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. CambridgeUniversity Press.

Nyakopoto, K. (2004), Dorset: A Survey of new settlers and their needs on a former commercialfarm in the Midland of Zimbabwe. Ruth Hutchinson, Harare

OECD (2006), Promoting Pro-poor growth: Agriculture. DAC Guidelines and Reference Series, Paris.

Platteau, J-P. (1992), Land Reform and Structural Adjustment in sub-Saharan Africa: Controversies andGuidelines. Economic and Social Development Paper 107. Presented at the Regional Workshopon Land Issues in Africa and the Middle East and North Africa Region, Kampala, Uganda. FAO,Rome.

Reh, I., S.A.M. van Oosterhout, B.M. Campbell and R.F. Du Toit (1989), Resource Use and AgriculturalProduction. In B.M. Campbell, R.F. Du Toit and C.A.M. Attwell (eds.) The Save Study. Universityof Zimbabwe, Harare.

Rohrbach, D.D. (1988), The growth of smallholder maize production in Zimbabwe (1979–1985):Implications for Food Security. In M.Rukuni and R.H Bernsten, Southern Africa: Food SecurityPolicy Options. UZ/MSU Food Security Research in Southern Africa, University of Zimbabwe,Harare.

Rohrbach, D.D., J. Stack, B. Heddon-Dunkhorst and J. Govereh (1990), Agricultural Growth and NationalFood Security. Proceedings of the First National Consultative Workshop, Juliasdale. IntegratingFood, Nutrition and Agricultural Policy in Zimbabwe. University of Zimbabwe, Harare.

Rukuni, M. and C.K. Eicher (1994), Zimbabwe’s Agricultural Revolution. University of ZimbabwePublications, Harare.

Sachikonye, L. (2003), Land Reform for Poverty Reduction? Social Exclusion and Farm Workers inZimbabwe. Presented at Conference on Staying Poor: Chronic Poverty and Development Policy,IDMP, Manchester University.

Schultz, T. (1964), Transforming Traditional Agriculture. Yale University Press, New Haven.

Scoones, I. (2008), A New Start for Zimbabwe? Institute for Poverty, Land and Agrarian Studies,University of Western Cape, South Africa.

Scoones, I. and K. Wilson (1989), Households, Lineage Groups and Ecological Dynamics: Issues forlivestock development in Zimbabwe’s communal lands, in B. Cousins (ed.) People, Land andLivestock. CASS. University of Zimbabwe, Harare.

Simpson, M. and D. Doré (2009), International Aid and its Management: Some Insights for Zimbabwein the Context of Re-engagement. Comprehensive Economic Recovery in Zimbabwe, WorkingPaper Series No.2. UNDP-Zimbabwe, Harare.

South Africa (2002), Transforming the Present—Protecting the Future. Report of the Committee ofInquiry into a Comprehensive System of Social Security for South Africa, Department of SocialDevelopment, Government Printer, Pretoria, South Africa.

Standing, G. (2007), How Cash Transfers Boost Work and Economic Security. Working Paper No.58,United Nations Department of Economic and Social Affairs, New York.

Stiglitz, J.E. (1998), An agenda for development in the 21st Century. Annual World Bank Conferenceon Development Economics, April 2021, Washington DC.

53

Bibliography

Syrquin, M. (1989), Sector Proportions and Economic Development: The Evidence since 1950, in J.G.Williamson and V.R. Panchamukhi (eds.) The Balance between Industry and Agriculture inEconomic Development. Vol.2, Part I.

Tattersfield, R. and E.K. Havazvidi (1994), The Development of the Seed Industry. In M. Rukuni, P.Tawonezi and C.K. Eicher (eds.), Zimbabwe’s Agricultural Revolution. University of ZimbabwePublications, Harare.

Tawonezvi P.H. and D. Hikwa (2006), Agricultural Research Policy. In M. Rukuni, P. Tawonezi and C.Eicher (eds.) Zimbabwe’s Agricultural Revolution Revisited, University of Zimbabwe, Harare.

Thirtle, C., X. Irz, L. Lin, MaKenzie-Hill and S. Wiggins (2001), Relationship between Changes inAgricultural Productivity and the Incidence of Poverty in Developing Countries. Reportcommissioned by the Department for International Development, London.

Tibaijuka, A.J. (2005), Scope and Impact of Operation Murambatsvina. Report by the Fact-FindingMission to Zimbabwe by the UN Special Envoy on Human Settlements Issues in Zimbabwe. UnitedNations, New York.

UNDP (2007), The Developmental Potential of the Diaspora. UNDP-Zimbabwe ComprehensiveRecovery Strategy, Harare.

—— (2008), Comprehensive Economic Recovery in Zimbabwe: A Discussion Document. UNDP-Zimbabwe, Harare.

Vincent, V. and R.G. Thomas (1961), Agricultural Survey of Southern Rhodesia, Government Printer,Harare.

World Bank (1985), Zimbabwe: Land Subsector Study. World Bank, Washington DC.

—— (1991), Zimbabwe: Agricultural Sector Memorandum. Report No. 9429-ZIM. Southern AfricanDepartment, Agriculture Operations Division. World Bank, Washington DC.

—— (1995), Zimbabwe: Achieving Shared Growth. Country Economic Memorandum. World Bank,Washington, DC.

—— (2002), Mexico: Land Policy a Decade after the Ejido Reforms. World Bank, Rural Developmentand Natural Resources Sector Unit, Washington, DC.

—— (2008), World Development Report: Agriculture for Development. The World Bank, Washington,DC.

Zimbabwe (1981a), Report of the Commission of Inquiry into Incomes, Prices and Conditions ofService, under the chairmanship of Roger Riddell. Government Printers, Harare.

—— (1981b), Zimbabwe Conference on Reconstruction and Development (ZIMCORD). GovernmentPrinters, Harare.

—— (1982a), Report of the Commission of Inquiry into the Agricultural Industry (ChavundukaCommission). Government Printers, Harare.

—— (1982b), Transitional National Development Plan 1983–1985. Government Printers, Harare.

—— (1985), Intensive Resettlement: Policies and Procedures. Ministry of Lands, Resettlement andRural Development, Harare.

—— (1986a), Communal Land Development Plan: A 15 Year Development Strategy (Draft). Ministryof Lands, Agriculture and Rural Resettlement, Harare.

—— (1986b), First Five Year National Development Plan: 1986–1990. Government Printers, Harare.

—— (1988), Report of the Commission of Inquiry into Parastatals. Under the Chairmanship ofJustice L.G. Smith, Harare.

54

The Recovery and Transformation of Zimbabwe’s Communal Areas

—— (1991), A Framework for Economic Reform (1991–95). Government Printers, Harare.

—— (1994), Report of the Commission of Inquiry into Appropriate Land Tenure Systems, under thechairmanship of Prof. M. Rukuni. Government Printers, Harare.

—— (2001), People First: Zimbabwe’s Land Reform Programme. (June) Government Printers, Harare.

—— (2003), Report of the Presidential Land Review Committee. Vol.1 Main Report. Under thechairmanship of Charles Utete, Harare.

—— (2006), Zimbabwe: 2003 Poverty Assessment Study Survey: Main Report: Ministry of PublicService, Labour and Social Welfare, Harare.

—— (2009), Short Term Emergency Recovery Programme (STERP) – Getting Zimbabwe MovingAgain. Government Printers, Harare.

Zimbabwe Institute (2007), Progressive Zimbabwe: Sustainable Growth and Transformation. ZimbabweInstitute, Cape Town, South Africa.