output dynamics in the long run: issues of economic growth

100
Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth Mausumi Das Lecture Notes, DSE April 17-27; 2017 Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 1 / 100

Upload: others

Post on 02-Jan-2022

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of EconomicGrowth

Mausumi Das

Lecture Notes, DSE

April 17-27; 2017

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 1 / 100

Page 2: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Output Dynamics: Short Run to Long Run

In the first module of the course, we have seen how output andemployment are determined in the short run.

In the Classical system (and its various extensions), these aredetermined by the supply side factors (production conditions); role ofdemand is limited to the detemination of the equilibrium price level.

In the Keynesian system (and its various extensions), aggregatedemand plays a direct role in determining equilibrium output andemployment in the short run.

As discussed before, both these systems are based on aggregativebehavioural equations.

One could provide micro-founded justifications for some of theseequations, but they may not necessarily be consistent with oneanother.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 2 / 100

Page 3: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Output Dynamics: Short Run to Long Run (Contd.)

Alternatively, one could build an internally consistent, dynamicgeneral equilibrium (DGE) framework, where forward-looking agentsmake their optimal decisions, taking both current and future variablesinto account.

But this would entail dynamic equations involving today’s andtomorrow’s consumption; today’s and tomorrow’s capital stock etc.

In other words this would bring us directly into the realm of outputdyamics over time, i.e., economic growth.

In the third module, we are going to explore issues pertaining to theoutput dynamics over time.

In particular, we shall examine how the period-by-period outputdynamics generate a growth path for the economy and what happensto this growth trajectory in the long run:

Does the economy reach a long run equilibrium with a constant growthrate, or does growth fizzle out in the long run?

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 3 / 100

Page 4: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Definition of Long Run: Steady State vis-a-vis BalancedGrowth Path

Before we proceed further, it is important to define the concept of‘long run equilibrium’in the context of growth models.

Long run equilibrium in a growth model is typically defined as abalanced growth path, where all endogeneous variables grow atsome constant rate.

This constant growth rate may differ from variable to variable.

More importantly, this constant growth rate could even be zero forsome variables.

The latter case is typically identified as the steady state in theconventional dynamic analysis (which is a special case of a balancedgrowth path).

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 4 / 100

Page 5: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Output Dynamics: Short Run to Long Run (Contd.)

Must growth dynamics be necessarily based on the DGE framework?

In other words, can the aggregative behavioural equations of theKeynesian or the Classical system also throw up some growthtrajectories for the economy?

If yes, how would they differ from the growth trajectories predicted bythe DGE framework?

Indeed, one can develop growth models based on the short run(static) characterization of the macroeconomy in either the Keynesiansystem or the Classical system.

And the long run charateristics of these growth models may differsubstantially from that of the DGE framework.

We start our discussion by analysing the dynamic versions of one ofthese aggregative models - namely the Classical one.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 5 / 100

Page 6: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Dynamic Extension of the Classical System: theNeoclassical Growth Model

The reason why we focus on the dynamic extension of the Classicalsytem only and not the Keynesian one is because we want to discusslong run growth, not short/medium run business fluctuations.

It is generally believed that in the long run, it is the supply sidefactors which are crucial in determining the output dynamics, not thedemand side factors.

We are also going to abstract away from price dynamics and indeedabstract from all nominal variables, including money itself.

Moreover, unless stated otherwise, we shall generally assume thatgovernment is passive in the sense that it does not intervene in thefunctioning of the market economy via fiscal policies.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 6 / 100

Page 7: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Neoclassical Growth Model: Solow

Solow (QJE, 1956) extends the static Classical system to a dynamic‘growth’framework where both factors of production - capital andlabour - grow over time.

Capital stock grows due to the savings-cum-investment decisions ofthe households (all capital is owned by the households; there is noindependent investment decisions taken by the firms).

Labour supply grows due to the population growth (at an exogenousrate n).

Growth of these two factors generates a growth rate of output in thiseconomy.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 7 / 100

Page 8: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Neoclassical Growth Model: Solow (Contd.)

The questions that we are interested in are as follows:

What is the rate of growth of aggregate as well as per capita output inthis economy?Does the economy attain a balanced growth path in the long run?What is the welfare level attained by the households in the long run?Is there any role of the government in the growth process - either interms of augmenting growth or in terms of ensuring maximum welfare?

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 8 / 100

Page 9: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Solow Growth Model: The Economic Environment

Consider a closed economy producing a single final commodity whichis used for consumption as well as for investment purposes (i.e, ascapital.)At the beginning of any time period t, the economy starts with agiven total endowment of labour (Nt) and a given aggregate capitalstock (Kt).There are H identical households in the economy and the labour andcapital ownership is equally distributed across all these households.At the beginning of any time period t, the households offer theirlabour and capital (inelastically) to the firms.The competitive firms then carry out the production and distributethe total output produced as factor incomes to the households at theend of the periodThe households consume a constant fraction of their total income andsave the rest.The savings propensity is exogenously fixed, denoted by s ∈ (0, 1).

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 9 / 100

Page 10: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Solow Growth Model: (Contd.)

A Crucial Assumption: All savings are automatically invested,which augments the capital stock in the next period.

As we had noted earlier, this asumption implies that:

it is the households who make the investment decisions; not firms.Firms simply rent in the capital from the households for production anddistributes the output as wage and rental income to the households atthe end of the period.

In other words, this asuumption rules out the existence of anindependent investment function - a fundamental assumption in theKeynesian system!

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 10 / 100

Page 11: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Solow Growth Model: Production Side Story

The economy is characterized by S idenical firms.Since all firms are identical, we can talk in terms of a representativefirm.The representative firm i is endowed with a standard ‘Neoclassical’production technology

Yit = F (Nit ,Kit )

which satisfies all the standard properties e.g., diminishing marginalproduct of each factor (or law of diminishing returns), CRS and theInada conditions.In addition, F (0,Kit ) = F (Nit , 0) = 0, i.e., both inputs are essentialin the production process.The firms operate in a competitive market structure and take themarket wage rate (w) and rental rate for capital (r) in real terms asgiven.The firm maximises its current profit:Πit = F (Nit ,Kit )− wNit − rKit .

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 11 / 100

Page 12: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Production Side Story (Contd.)

Static (period by period) optimization by the firm yields the followingFONCs:

(i) FN (Nit ,Kit ) = w .

(ii) FK (Nit ,Kit ) = r .

Recall (from our previous analysis) that identical firms and CRStechnology imply that firm-specific marginal products andeconomy-wide (social) marginal products (derived from thecorresponding aggregate production function) of both labour andcapital would be the same. Thus

FN (Nit ,Kit ) = FN (Nt ,Kt );

FK (Nit ,Kit ) = FK (Nt ,Kt ).

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 12 / 100

Page 13: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Production Side Story (Contd.)

Thus we get the familiar demand for labour schedule for theaggreagte economy at time t, and a similarly defined demand forcapital schedule at time t as:

ND : FN (Nt ,Kt ) = wt ;

KD : FK (Nt ,Kt ) = rt .

Recall that the supply of labour and that of capital at any point oftime t is historically given at Nt and Kt respectively.

Assumption: The market wage rate and the rental rate for capital,wt and rt , adjust so that the labour market and the capital marketclear in every time period.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 13 / 100

Page 14: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Determination of Market Wage Rate & Rental Rate ofCapital at time t:

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 14 / 100

Page 15: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Distribution of Aggregate Output:

Recall that the firm-specific production function is CRS; hence so isthe aggregate production function.

We know that for any constant returns to scale (i.e., linearlyhomogeneous) function, by Euler’s theorem:

F (Nt ,Kt ) = FN (Nt ,Kt )Nt + FK (Nt ,Kt )Kt= wtNt + rtKt .

This implies that after paying all the factors their respective marginalproducts, the entire output gets exhausted, confirming that firmsindeed earn zero profit.

Thus the total output currently produced goes to the households asincome (Yt) - of which they consume a fixed proportion and save therest.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 15 / 100

Page 16: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Dynamics of Capital and Labour:

Recall that the capital stock over time gets augmented by thesavings/investment made by the households.Also recall that households are identical and they invest a fixedproportion (s) of their income (which adds up to the aggregateoutput - as we have just seen).Hence aggegate savings (& investment) in the economy is given by :

St ≡ It = sYt ; 0 < s < 1.Let the existing capital depreciate at a constant rate δ : 0 5 δ 5 1.Thus the capital accumulation equation in this economy is given by:

Kt+1 = It + (1− δ)Kt = sYt + (1− δ)Kti.e., Kt+1 = sF (Nt ,Kt ) + (1− δ)Kt , (1)

While labour stock increases due to population growth (at a constantrate n):

Nt+1 = (1+ n)Nt . (2)

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 16 / 100

Page 17: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Dynamics of Capital and Labour (Contd):

Equations (1) and (2) represent a 2× 2 system of differenceequations, which we can directly analyse to determine the time pathsof Nt and Kt , and therefore the corresponding dynamics of Yt .

However, given the properties of the production function, we cantransform the 2× 2 system into a single-variable difference equation -which is easier to analyse.

We shall follow the latter method here.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 17 / 100

Page 18: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Capital-Labour Ratio & Per Capita Production Function:

Using the CRS property, we can write:

yt ≡YtNt=F (Nt ,Kt )

Nt= F

(1,KtNt

)≡ f (kt ),

where yt represents per capita output, and kt represents thecapital-labour ratio (or the per capita capital stock) in the economyat time t.The function f (kt ) is often referred to as the per capita productionfunction.Notice that using the relationship that F (Nt ,Kt ) = Nt f (kt ), we caneasily show that:

FN (Nt ,Kt ) = f (kt )− kt f ′(kt );FK (Nt ,Kt ) = f ′(kt ).

[Derive these two expressions yourselves].

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 18 / 100

Page 19: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Properties of Per Capita Production Function:

Given the properties of the aggregate production function, one canderive the following properties of the per capita production function:

(i) f (0) = 0;

(ii) f ′(k) > 0; f ′′(k) < 0;

(iii) Limk→0

f ′(k) = ∞; Limk→∞

f ′(k) = 0.

Condition (i) indicates that capital is an essential input of production;Condition (ii) indicates diminishing marginal product of capital;Condition (iii) indicates the Inada conditions with respect to capital .Finally, using the definition that kt ≡ Kt

Nt, we can write

kt+1 ≡ Kt+1Nt+1

=sF (Nt ,Kt ) + (1− δ)Kt

(1+ n)Nt

⇒ kt+1 =sf (kt ) + (1− δ)kt

(1+ n)≡ g(kt ). (3)

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 19 / 100

Page 20: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Dynamics of Capital-Labour Ratio:

Equation (3) represents the basic dynamic equation in the discretetime Solow model. (Interpretation?)Notice that Equation (3) represents a single non-linear differenceequation in kt . Once again we use the phase diagram technique toanalyse the dynamic behaviour of kt .Recall that to draw the phase diagram of a single difference equation,we first plot the g(kt ) function with respect to kt . Then we identifyits possible points of intersection with the 45o line - which denote thesteady state points of the system.In plotting the g(kt ) function, note:

g(0) =sf (0) + (1− δ).0

(1+ n)= 0;

g ′(k) =1

(1+ n)

[sf ′(k) + (1− δ)

]> 0;

g ′′(k) =1

(1+ n)sf ′′(k) < 0.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 20 / 100

Page 21: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Dynamics of Capital-Labour Ratio (Contd.):

Moreover,

Limk→0

g ′(k) =1

(1+ n)

[sLimk→0

f ′(k) + (1− δ)

]= ∞;

Limk→∞

g ′(k) =1

(1+ n)

[s Limk→∞

f ′(k) + (1− δ)

]=(1− δ)

(1+ n)< 1.

We can now draw the phase diagram for kt :

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 21 / 100

Page 22: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Dynamics of Capital-Labour Ratio (Contd.):

From the phase diagram we can identify two possible steady states:

(i) k = 0 (Trivial Steady State);

(ii) k = k∗ > 0 (Non-trivial Steady State).

Since an economy is always assumed to start with some positivecapital-labour ratio (however small), we shall ignore the non-trivialsteady state.

The economy has a unique non-trivial steady state, given by k∗,which is globally asymptotically stable: starting from any initialcapital-labour ratio k0 > 0, the economy would always move to k∗ inthe long run.

Implications:

In the long run, per capita output: yt ≡ f (kt ) will be constant atf (k∗) while aggregate output Yt ≡ Nt f (kt ) will be growing at thesame rate as Nt (namely at the exogenously given rate n).

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 22 / 100

Page 23: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Verification of Stability Property: Linearization

Let us now veify the stability property of the non-trivial steady state(k∗) via the linearization technique. (Notice though that thelineraization technique will only tell us about the local stability; notglobal stability).

Recall that the difference equation is given by:

kt+1 =sf (kt ) + (1− δ)kt

(1+ n)≡ g(kt )

Linearizing around the non-trivial steady state:

kt+1 = g(k∗) + g ′(k∗) (kt − k∗)= g ′(k∗)kt + [g(k∗)− g ′(k∗)k∗]

The non-trivial steady state would be locally stable iff

g ′(k∗) =[sf ′(k∗) + (1− δ)

(1+ n)

]< 1.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 23 / 100

Page 24: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Verification of Stability Property: Linearization (Contd.)

To see how the linearization works, let us take a specific productionfunction of the Cobb-Douglas variety:

f (k) = kα; 0 < α < 1.

Then

g(kt ) =s(kt )α + (1− δ)kt

(1+ n)

And the nontrivial steady state is:

k∗ =(

sn+ δ

) 11−α

Verify that at k∗ =( sn+δ

) 11−α , g ′(k∗) =

[sα(k∗)α−1 + (1− δ)

(1+ n)

]< 1.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 24 / 100

Page 25: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Some Long Run Implictions of Solow Growth Model:

Notice that the non-trivial steady state k∗ can be written as:

k∗ =sf (k∗) + (1− δ)k∗

(1+ n)⇒ (1+ n) k∗ = sf (k∗) + (1− δ)k∗

⇒ f (k∗)k∗

=n+ δ

s.

Total differentiating and using the properties of the f (k) function, itis easy to show that,

dk∗

ds> 0;

dk∗

dn< 0;

dk∗

dδ< 0.

A higher savings ratio generates a higher level of per capita output inthe long run;A higher rate of grwoth of population generates a lower level of percapita output in the long run;A higher rate of depreciation generates a lower level of per capitaoutput in the long run.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 25 / 100

Page 26: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Some Long Run Implictions of Solow Growth Model(Contd.):

But these are all level effects. What would be the impact on the longrun growth?It is easy to see that in this Solovian economy the per capita incomedoes not grow in the long run (f (k∗) is a constant).

On the other hand, the long run growth rate of aggregate incomein the Solovian economy is always equal to n (and is independentof other parameters, e.g., s or δ)

Notice there is no role for the government in influencing the long rungrowth rate here. In particular, if the government tries to manipulatethe savings ratio (by imposing an appropriate tax on households’income and investing the tax revenue in capital formation), then sucha policy will have no long run growth effect.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 26 / 100

Page 27: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Solow Model: Long Run vis-a-vis Short/Medium Run

To summarise:

The per capita income does not grow in the long run; it remainsconstatnt at f (k∗) - the exact level being determined by variousparameters (s, n, δ).The aggregate income grows at a constant rate - given by theexogenous rate of growth of population (n).

But all these happen only in the long run, i.e., as t → ∞.Starting from a given initial capital-labour ratio k0 ( 6= k∗), it willobviously take the economy some time before it reaches k∗.

What happens during these transitional periods?

In particular, what would be the rate of growth of per capita incomeand that of aggregate income in the short run - when the economy isyet to reach its steady state?

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 27 / 100

Page 28: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Transitional Dynamics in Solow Growth Model:

When the economy is out of steady state, the rate of growth ofcapital-labour ratio is given by:

γk ≡kt+1 − kt

kt=

sf (kt )+(1−δ)kt(1+n) − kt

kt

=sf (kt )− (n+ δ)kt

(1+ n)ktT 0 according as kt S k∗.

Moreover,dγkdk

=−s(1+ n) [f (k)− kf ′(k)]

[(1+ n)k ]2< 0.

In other words, during transition, the higher is the capital-labour ratioof the economy, the lower is its (short run) growth rate.

This last result has important implications for cross country growthcomparisons.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 28 / 100

Page 29: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Further Implictions of Solow Growth Model: Absolutevis-a-vis Conditional Convergence

The above result implies that the transitional growth rate of percapita income in the poorer countries (with low k0) will be higherthan that of the rich countries (with high k0); and eventually they willconverge to the same level of per capita income (AbsoluteConvergence).This proposition however has been strongly rejected by data. In factempirical studies show the opposite: richers countries have remainedrich and poorer countries have remained poor and there is nosignificant tendencies towards convergence - even when one looks atlong run time series data.

The proposition of absolute convergence of course pre-supposes thatthe underlying parameters for all economies (rich and poor alike) arethe same.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 29 / 100

Page 30: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Absolute vis-a-vis Conditional Convergence (Contd.)

If we allow rich and poor countries to have different values of s, δ, netc. (which is plausible), then the Solow model generates a muchweaker prediction of Conditional Convergence.Conditional Convergence states that a country grows faster - thefurther away it is from its own steady state.

An alternative (and more useful) statement of ConditionalConvergence runs as follows: Among a group of countries which aresimilar (similar values of s, δ, n etc.), the relatively poorer ones willgrow faster and eventually the per capita income of all these countrieswill converge.

This weaker hypothesis in generally supported by data.

However, Conditional Convergence Hypothesis is not very helpful inexplaining the persistent differences in per capita income amongst therich and the poor countries.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 30 / 100

Page 31: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Solow Model: Golden Rule & Dynamic Ineffi ciency

Let us now get back from short run to long run (steady state).Recall that for given values of δ and n, the savings rate in theeconomy uniquely pins down the corresponding steady statecapital-labour ratio:

k∗(s) :f (k∗)k∗

=n+ δ

s.

We have already seen that a higher value of s is associated with ahigher k∗, and therefore, a higher level of steady state per capitaincome (f (k∗)).So it seems that a higher savings ratio - though has no growth effect- may still be welcome because it generates higher standard of living(as reflected by a higher per capita income) at the steady state.But welfare of agents do not depend on just income; it depends onthe level of consumption. So what is the corresponding level ofconsumption associated with the steady state k∗(s)?

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 31 / 100

Page 32: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Solow Model: Golden Rule & Dynamic Ineffi ciency(Contd.)

Notice that in this model, per capita consumption is defined as:

CtNt

≡ Yt − StNt

⇒ ct = f (kt )− sf (kt )Accordingly, for given values of δ and n, steady state level of percapita consumption is related to the savings ratio of the economy inthe following way:

c∗(s) = f (k∗(s))− sf (k∗(s))= f (k∗(s))− (n+ δ) k∗(s). [Using the definition of k∗]

We have already noted that if the government tries to manipulate thesavings ratio (by imposing an appropriate tax on household’s incomeand using the tax proceeds for capital formation), then such a policywould have no long run growth effect.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 32 / 100

Page 33: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Golden Rule & Dynamic Ineffi ciency in Solow Model(Contd.)

But can such a policy still generate a higher level of steady state percapita consumption at least?If yes, then such a policy would still be desirable, even if it does notimpact on growth.Taking derivative of c∗(s) with respect to s :

dc∗(s)ds

=[f ′(k∗(s))− (n+ δ)

] dk∗(s)ds

.

Sincedk∗

ds> 0,

dc∗(s)ds

T 0 according as f ′(k∗(s)) T (n+ δ).

In other words, steady state value of per capita consumption, c∗(s),is maximised at that level of savings ratio and associated k∗(s) where

f ′(k∗) = (n+ δ).Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 33 / 100

Page 34: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Digrammatic Representation of the Golden Rule SteadyState:

We shall denote this savings ratio as sg and the corresponding steadystate capital-labour ratio as k∗g - where the subscript ‘g’stand forgolden rule.

The point (k∗g , c∗g ) in some sense represents the ‘best’or the ‘most

desirable’steady state point (although in the absence of an explicitutility function, such qualifications remain somewhat vague).

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 34 / 100

Page 35: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Alternative Digrammatic Representation of the GoldenRule Steady State:

There are many possible steady states to the left and to the right ofk∗g - associated with various other savings ratios.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 35 / 100

Page 36: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Golden Rule & the Concept of ‘Dynamic Ineffi ciency’

Importantly, all the steady states to the right of k∗g are called‘dynamically ineffi cient’steady states.From any such point one can ‘costlessly’move to the left - to alower steady state point - and in the process enjoy a higher level ofcurrent consumption as well as higher levels of future consumption atall subsequent dates. (How?)Notice however that the steady states to the left of k∗g are not‘dynamically ineffi cient’. (Why not?)

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 36 / 100

Page 37: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Cause of ‘Dynamic Ineffi ciency’in Solow Model

Dynamic ineffi ciency occurs because people oversave.

This possibility arises in the Solow model because the savings ratiois exogenously given - it is not chosen through households’optimization process.Note that if indeed the steady state of the economy happens to lie inthe dynamically ineffi cient region, then that in itself would justify apro-active, interventionist role of the government in the Solow model- even though government cannot influence the long run rate ofgrowth of the economy.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 37 / 100

Page 38: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Limitations of the Solow Growth Model:

There are two major criticisms of the Solow model.

1 The steady state in the Solow model might be dynamically ineffi cient,because people may oversave. If one allows households to choosetheir savings ratio optimally, then this ineffi cinency should disappear.But this latter possibility is simply not allowed in the Solow model.

2 Even though the Solow model is supposed to be a growth model - itcannot really explain long run growth:

The per capita income does not grow at all in the long run;

The aggregate income grows at an exogenously given rate n, whichthe model does not attempt to explain.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 38 / 100

Page 39: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Extensions of the Solow Growth Model:

The basic Solow growth model has subsequently been extended tocounter some of these critisisms.

We shall look at two such extensions:1 Neoclassical Growth Model with Optimizing Households: Thisextension allows the households to choose their consumption/savingsbehaviour optimally. There are two different characterization of theoptimizing household model:

Households optimize over infinite horizon (TheRamsey-Cass-Koopmans Framework)Households optimize over finite horizon in an overlapping generationsset up (The Samuelson-Diamond Framework).

2 Growth Models with non-Neoclassical Technology: This extensionallows the per capita income to grow in the long run.In this context weshall also discuss why the aggregate production technology may notexhibit all the Neoclassical properties.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 39 / 100

Page 40: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Neoclassical Growth with Optimizing Agents:

Let us start with first extension which allows for optimizingconsumption/savings behaviour by households over infinite horizon:The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Inifinite Horizon Framework(henceforth R-C-K)This framework retains all the production side assuption of theSolovian economy; but households now choose their consumption andsavings decision optimally be maximising their utility defined over aninfinite horizon.

This latter statement should immediately tell you that the underlyingmacro structure would be very similar to the DGE framework that wehave constructed earlier.

Let us revisit the underlying macro framework.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 40 / 100

Page 41: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Neoclassical Growth with Optimizing Agents: The R-C-KModel

The R-C-K model is considered Neoclassical - because it retains allthe assumptions of the Neoclassical production function (includingthe diminishing returns property and the Inada conditions.)

In fact the production side story is exactly identical to Solow.

As before, the economy starts with a given stock of capital (Kt) anda given level of population (Lt) at time t.

These factors are supplied inelastically to the market in every period.This implies that households do not care for leisure.

Population grows at a constant rate n.

Capital stocks grows due to optimal savings (and investment)decisions by the households.

Notice that once again savings and investment are always identical.So just like Solow, this is a supply driven growth model.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 41 / 100

Page 42: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

The R-C-K Model: The Household Side Story

There are H identical households indexed by h.

Each household consists of a single infinitely lived member to beginwith (at t = 0). However population within a household increasesover time at a constant rate n. (And each newly born member isinfinitely lived too!)

At any point of time t, the total capital stock and the total labourforce in the economy are equally distributed across all the households,which they offer inelastically to the market at the market wage ratewt and the market rental rate rt .

Thus total earning of a household at time t: wtNht + rtKht .

Corresponding per member earning: yht = wt + rtkht ,where kht is the per member capital stock in household h,

which is also the per capita capital stock (or the capital-labourratio, kt) in the economy.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 42 / 100

Page 43: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

The Household Side Story (Contd.):

In every time period, the instantaneous utility of the householddepends on its per member consumption:

ut = u(cht); u′ > 0; u′′ < 0; lim

ch→0u′(ch) = ∞; lim

ch→∞u′(ch) = 0.

The household at time 0 chooses its entire consumption profile{cht}∞t=0 so as to maximise the discounted sum of its life-time utility:

Uh0 =∞

∑t=0

βtu(cht)

subject to its period by period budget constraint.

Notice once again that identical households implied that permember consumption (cht ) of any household is also equal to the percapita consumption (ct) in the economy at time t.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 43 / 100

Page 44: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

The R-C-K Model: Centralized Version (Optimal Growth)

There are two version of the R-C-K model:A centralized version - which analyses the problem from the perspectiveof a social planner (who is omniscient, omnipotent and benevolent).A decentralized version - which analyses the problem from theperspective of a perfectly competitive market economy where‘atomistic’households and firms take optimal decisions in theirrespective individual spheres.

The centralized version was developed by Ramsey (way back in 1928)and is often referred to as the ‘optimal growth’problem.In the DGE framework (discussed in Module 1) we have solved theproblem both from the perspective of the social planner as well as forthe perfectly competitive market economy.We have shown that under rational expectations and perfectinformation on the part of the households, the solution paths forthe economy under the two institutional structures are identical.We shall therefore characterise the solution paths for only one ofthem, namely that of the social planner.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 44 / 100

Page 45: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

The R-C-K Model: Centralized Version (Optimal Growth)

From our analysis of the DGE frameowrk, we know that the dynamicoptimization problem of the social planner is:

Max .{ct}∞

t=0,{kt+1}∞t=0

∑t=0

βtu (ct )

subject to

(i) ct 5 f (kt ) + (1− δ)kt for all t = 0;

(ii) kt+1 =f (kt ) + (1− δ)kt − ct

1+ n; kt = 0 for all t = 0; k0 given.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 45 / 100

Page 46: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

R-C-K Model: Centralized Version (Contd.)

In Module 1, we have seen how to solve a dynamic programmingproblem (using the Bellman equation) to arrive at the dynamicequations characterizing the optimal paths for the control and statevariable.

Using this method, we can derive the following two dynamicequations characterizing the solution to the social planner’soptimization problem as:

u′ (ct ) [1+ n] = βu′ (ct+1)[f ′(kt+1) + (1− δ)

]. (4)

kt+1 =f (kt ) + (1− δ)kt − ct

1+ n; k0 given. (5)

These two equations represent a 2X2 system of difference equationswhich implicitly defines the ‘optimal’trajectories of ct and kt .

Of course, we still need two boundary conditons to preciselycharacterise the solution paths for this 2X2 system.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 46 / 100

Page 47: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

R-C-K Model: Centralized Version (Contd.)

One boundary condition is given by the initial condition: k0.

The other boundary condition is provided by the Transversalitycondition:

limt→∞

βt[f ′(kt ) + (1− δ)

].u′(ct )kt = 0

However, the dynamic equations given above are very involved andchracterizing the optimal path is not very easy.

To simplify, let us begin by assuming specific functional forms foru(c) and f (k).

Letu(ct ) = log ct ;

f (kt ) = (kt )α ; 0 < α < 1.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 47 / 100

Page 48: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

R-C-K Model (Centralized Version): Optimal Paths(Contd.)

Given these specific functional forms, the dynamic equations for thecentralized R-C-K model are represented by the following twoequations:

ct+1 =β[α(kt+1)α−1 + (1− δ)

]1+ n

ct ; (6)

kt+1 =(kt )α + (1− δ)kt − ct

1+ n. (7)

The associated boundary conditions are:

k0 given; limt→∞

βt[α(kt )α−1 + (1− δ)

].ktct= 0

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 48 / 100

Page 49: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Characterization of the Optimal Paths:

We are now all set to characterise the dynamic paths of ct and kt ascharted out by the above dynamic system.Before that let us quickly characterize the steady state.Using the steady state condition that ct = ct+1 = c∗ andkt = kt+1 = k∗ in equations (6) and (7), the steady state values aregiven by:

k∗ =

[αβ

1+ n− β(1− δ)

] 11−α

;

c∗ = (k∗)α − (n+ δ)k∗.

Now let us chart out the optimal paths of ct and kt - starting fromany given initial value of k0. (Note that the initial value of c0 is notgiven - it is to be optimally determined).We now construct the phase diagram to qualitatively characterise thesolution paths for these specific functional forms.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 49 / 100

Page 50: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

R-C-K Model (Centralized Version): Phase Diagram

Recall that to construct the phase diagram for this 2× 2 system wehave to plot the two level curves 4c = 0 and 4k = 0 in the (kt , ct )plane.The equations of these two level curves are as follows:

ct+1 − ct ≡ 4c =[

β[α(kt+1)α−1 + (1− δ)

]1+ n

− 1]ct = 0; (8)

kt+1 − kt ≡ 4k = (kt )α − (n+ δ)kt − ct1+ n

= 0. (9)

From (8):

4c = 0⇒ either

[β[α(kt+1)α−1 + (1− δ)

]1+ n

− 1]= 0; or ct = 0

i.e., either kt+1 =

(αβ

(1+ n)− β(1− δ)

) 11−α

= k∗ = kt ; or ct = 0

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 50 / 100

Page 51: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

R-C-K Model (Centralized Version): Phase Diagram(Contd.)

From (9):4k = 0⇒ ct = (kt )α − (n+ δ)kt

Thus along the 4k = 0 locus:dctdkt

∣∣∣∣4k=0

R 0 according as α(kt )α−1 R (n+ δ)

i.e., kt Q(

α

n+ δ

) 11−α

≡ kg

Also, when kt = 0, ct = 0; & when kt =(

1n+ δ

) 11−α

≡ k, ct = 0.

A Comment: Earlier (in the context of the Solow model), we had definedthe ‘golden rule’capital-labour ratio as kg : f ′(k) = n+ δ. Now with theCobb-Douglas production function, f ′(k) = α(kt )α−1. Therefore ‘golden

rule’is suitably defined as: kg =(

αn+δ

) 11−α .

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 51 / 100

Page 52: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

R-C-K Model (Centralized Version): Phase Diagram(Contd.)

All these information can be put together in constructing the followingphase diagram:

There exists a unique path (denoted by SS) which will take us to thenon-trivial steady state. This is indeed the optimal path. All other pathsviolate the TVC.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 52 / 100

Page 53: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

R-C-K Model (Centralized Version): Growth Conclusions

In the R-C-K model, for any given k0, the optimal c0 will be chosensuch that the economy is on the SS path.

Along this path, the average capital stock and average consumptionapproach their steady state values (k∗.c∗) in the long run (i.e, ast → ∞).Thus the long run growth conclusions of the Solow model prevails:

The per capita income does not grow in the long run; it remainsconstatnt at f (k∗) - the exact level being determined by variousparameters (s, n, δ).The aggregate income grows at a constant rate - given by theexogenous rate of growth of population (n).

BUT, is the steady state now dynamically effi cient? For that we haveto compare this steady state with the ‘golden rule’.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 53 / 100

Page 54: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

R-C-K Model (Centralized Version): Dynamic Effi ciency

It is easy to verify that for our specific example (with a Cobb-Douglasproduction function):

k∗ =(

αβ

(1+ n)− β(1− δ)

) 11−α

<

n+ δ

) 11−α

= kg

But is it true in general, or is this an artifact of the Cobb-Douglasproduction function?

To answer this question, let us go back to the generalized R-C-Kmodel and examine whether its steady state is dynamically effi cient ornot.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 54 / 100

Page 55: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

R-C-K Model (Centralized Version): Dynamic Effi ciency(Contd.)

Recall that the dynamic equations characterizing the optimal paths ofthe generalized R-C-K model were given by:

u′ (ct ) [1+ n] = βu′ (ct+1)[f ′(kt+1) + (1− δ)

](10)

kt+1 =f (kt ) + (1− δ)kt − ct

1+ n(11)

We know that at steady state, by definition:

ct = ct+1 = c∗;

kt = kt+1 = k∗.

Using this steady state definition in the dyamic equations, the steadystate for this system is given by:

k∗ : f ′(k∗) =(1+ n)− β(1− δ)

β; (12)

c∗ = f (k∗)− (n+ δ)k∗ (13)

Is this steady state dynamically effi cient?Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 55 / 100

Page 56: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

R-C-K Model (Centralized Version): Golden Rule &Dynamic Effi ciency

Recall that the ‘golden rule’capital-labour ratio is defined as:

kg : f ′(kg ) = (n+ δ)

Given that 0 < δ, β < 1, one can again easily verify that

f ′(k∗) =(1+ n)− β(1− δ)

β> (n+ δ) = f ′(kg )

⇒ k∗ < kg .

In other words, the steady state of the R-C-K model necessarily lies inthe dynamically effi cient region.This is true for any n and δ, as long as 0 < β < 1 (i.e., householdsprefer curren consumption to future consumption). Indeed it is onlywhen β = 1 that household will optimally reach the golden rule suchthat:

k∗ = kg .

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 56 / 100

Page 57: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

R-C-K Model (Centralized Version): Golden Rule &Dynamic Effi ciency (Contd.)

Thus we see that in the centralized version of the R-C-K model, whenthe social planner decides on how much to save and how much toleave for households’consumption in order to maximise households’utility over infinite horizon, it ensures that the corresponding steadystate is always dynamically effi cient.Finally, will all these results hold for a decentralized market economyas well?

The answer is: "yes" - because (under rational expectation andcomplete information) the solution path for the social planner isexactly identical to the solution path for the market economy.

Thus the growth path of the decentralized market economy will beexactly identical to the growth path of the planned economy;moreover the steady state of the market economy will be dynamicallyeffi cient too.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 57 / 100

Page 58: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Samuelson-Diamond Overlapping Generations Model

We have so far analysed optimizing savings behaviour by thehouseholds in the context of the inifinite horizon R-C-K framework.We now turn to an alternative framework, where agents optimize overa finite time horizon.This framework was first developed by Samuelson (1958) in thecontext of an exchange economy, which was later extended to aproduction economy by Peter Diamond (1965).Each agent now lives exactly for T periods. For convenience, we shallassume that T = 2.We shall denote these two periods of an agent’s life time by ‘youth’and ‘old-age’respectively.The agent works only in the first period of his life (when young) andis retired in the second period (when old).Thus he has to make provisions for his old-age consumption from hisfirst period wage income itself (through savings).The agent optimally decides about his consumption profile bymaximizing his life-time utility (to be specified later).

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 58 / 100

Page 59: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

OLG Model: Production Side Story

Once again, the production side story in the OLG model is identicalto that of Solow.Thus the economy starts with a given stock of capital (Kt) and agiven stock of labour force (Nt) at time t.Notice that since people do not work during their oldage, the currentlabour force consist only of the current youth.We also assume that all firms have access to an identical productiontechnology - which satisfies all standard neoclassical properties.The firm-specific production functions can be aggregated to generatean aggregate production function such that :

Yt = F (Kt ,Nt ).

At every point of time the market clearing wage rate and the rentalrate of capital are given by:

wt = FN (Kt ,Nt ); rt = FK (Kt ,Nt ).

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 59 / 100

Page 60: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

OLG Model: Household Side Story

There are H households or dynasties in the economy. In everyhousehold, at any point of time t, there are two cohorts of agents -those who are born in period t (‘generation t’- who are currentlyyoung) and those who were born in the previous period (‘generationt − 1’- who are currently old): hence the name ‘overlappinggenerations’.Thus at any point of time t, total population consists of twosuccessive generations of people:

Lt = Nt +Nt−1.

(Notice that although total population is Lt , total labour force attime t in only Nt .)We shall assume that population in successive generations grows at aconstant rate n :

Nt+1 = (1+ n)Nt .

Hence total population in the economy (Lt) also grows at the sameconstant rate n.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 60 / 100

Page 61: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Life Cycle of a Representative Member of Generation t:

All agents within a generation are identical. So we can talk in termsof a representative agent belonging to ‘generation t’.

The agent is born at the beginning of period t with an endowment ofone unit of labour.

All agents in this model are selfish - they care only about their ownconsumption/utility and not about their childrens’utility. Hence theydo not leave any bequest.

No bequest implies that the young agent has only labour endowmentand no capital endowment.

The young agent in period t supplies his labour inelastically to thelabour market in period t to earn a wage income wt .

Out of this wage income, the agent consumes a part and saves therest - which becomes his capital stock in the next period and allowshim to earn a rental income in the next period.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 61 / 100

Page 62: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Representative Agent’s Utility Function:

Notice that since the agent would not be working in the next period,the savings and the consequent ownership of capital is the only sourceof income for him in the next period.

Thus an agent is a worker in the first period of his life and becomes acapitalist (capital-owner) in the second period of his life.

The young agent in period t optimally decides on his currentconsumption (c1t ) and current savings (st) (or equivalently, his currentconsumption (c1t ) and future consumption (c

2t+1)) so as to maximise

his lifetime utility:

U(c1t , c2t+1) ≡ u(c1t ) + βu(c2t+1); 0 < β < 1, (14)

where u′ > 0; u′′ < 0; limc→0

u′(c) = ∞; limc→∞

u′(c) = 0.

β is the standard discount factor which tells us that agents prefercurrent consumption more than future consumption.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 62 / 100

Page 63: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Representative Agent’s Budget Constraints:

The first period budget constraint of the agent:

c1t + st = wt .

The second period budget constraint of the agent:

c2t+1 = (1+ ret+1 − δ)st .

Combining, we get the life-time budget constraint of the agent as:

c1t +c2t+1

(1+ r et+1 − δ)= wt . (15)

The agent decides on his optimal consumption in the two periods bymaximising (1) subject to (2).Since the agent is taking his savings decision in the first period, whensecond period’s market interest rate is not yet known, he mustoptimize on the basis of some expected value of the rt+1.As before, we shall assume that agents have perfectforesight/rational expectations such that r et+1 = rt+1 for all t.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 63 / 100

Page 64: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Representative Agent’s Optimal Consumption & Savings:

From the FONC of the optimization exercise:

u′(c1t )u′(c2t+1)

= β(1+ rt+1 − δ). (16)

From the FONC and the life-time budget constraint, we can derivethe optimal solutions as:

c1t = ψ(wt , rt+1);

c2t+1 = η(wt , rt+1).

Corresponding optimal savings:

st = wt − ψ(wt , rt+1) ≡ φ(wt , rt+1).

Before we proceed further, it is useful to note the signs of the partialderivatives sw and sr .

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 64 / 100

Page 65: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Representative Agent’s Optimal Consumption & Savings(Contd.):

Notice that

sw ≡∂φ(wt , rt+1)

∂wt= 1− ∂ψ(wt , rt+1)

∂wt= 1− ∂c1t

∂wt.

From the life-time budget constraint of the agent:

∂c1t∂wt

+1

(1+ rt+1 − δ)

∂c2t+1∂wt

= 1.

Under the assumption that both c1t and c2t_1 are normal goods, a unit

increase in the wage rate wt ceteris paribus must increase both c1t

and c2t+1. This implies that 0 <∂c1t∂wt

< 1 (since both ∂c2t+1∂wt

and1

(1+rt+1−δ)are positive).

This in turn implies that

0 < sw < 1.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 65 / 100

Page 66: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Representative Agent’s Optimal Consumption & Savings(Contd.):

The sign of sr however is ambiguous.

Notice that

sr ≡∂φ(wt , rt+1)

∂rt+1= −∂ψ(wt , rt+1)

∂rt+1= − ∂c1t

∂rt+1.

So the sign of sr depends on how first period consumption respondsto a unit change in rt+1.

Recall however that1

1+ rt+1 − δis the relative price of c2t+1 in terms

of c1t .

Thus a unit increase in rt+1 ceteris paribus reduces the relative priceof future consumption in terms of current consumption.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 66 / 100

Page 67: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Representative Agent’s Optimal Consumption & Savings(Contd.):

Any such price change will be associated with two effects:a substitution effect (⇒ consumption should move in favour of therelatively cheaper good);an income effect (⇒ the budget set of the consumer expands, whichincreases consumption of both goods)

Thus due to an increase in rt+1 ceteris paribusc1t should decrease due to the substitution effect, whilec1t should increase due to the income effect of a price change.

The sign of∂c1t

∂rt+1depends on which effect dominates.

This in turn implies that

sr R 0

according as, substitution effect R income effect.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 67 / 100

Page 68: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Representative Agent’s Optimal Consumption & Savings(Contd.):

Notice that sr < 0 implies that savings responds negatively to achange in the future rate of interest: a rise in the (expected) rate ofinterest leades to lower savings.

Apriori we have no reason to rule out this case, even though it iscounter-intutive. It depends on the characteristics of the utilityfunction.

However, henceforth we shall assume that the utility function of theagents is such that the substitution effect of a price change dominatesthe income effect so that

sr = 0.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 68 / 100

Page 69: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Aggregate Consumption & Savings:

Let us now turn our attention to the aggregate economy.

Recall that in every period the total output is distributed as wageincome and capital income:

Yt = wtNt + rtKt . (17)

The entire wage income goes to the current young generation. Eachof them saves a part of the wage income (st) and consume the rest.Thus,

wtNt = c1t Nt + stNt .

On the other hand, the entire interest income goes to the current oldgeneration. Each of them consume not only the interest earnings butthe left over capital stock as well. Thus,

c2t Nt−1 = rtKt + (1− δ)Kt .

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 69 / 100

Page 70: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Aggregate Consumption & Savings (Contd.):

Thus aggregate consumption in this economy at time t :

Ct = c1t Nt + c2t Nt−1

= [wtNt − stNt ] + [rtKt + (1− δ)Kt ]

= wtNt + rtKt − [stNt − (1− δ)Kt ]︸ ︷︷ ︸St

(18)

Notice that aggregate savings St has two components:1 The positive savings by the young (stNt );2 The negative savings by the old (−(1− δ)Kt ).

As before, from the Savings-Investment equality for the aggregateeconomy:

It = St , where It ≡ Kt+1 − (1− δ)Kt⇒ Kt+1 = stNt .

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 70 / 100

Page 71: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Dynamics of Capital-Labour Ratio:

Since we know that labour force in this economy is growing at therate n, i.e., Nt+1 = (1+ n)Nt , we can derive the dynamic ofcapital-labour ratio (kt) as:

kt+1 =st

(1+ n)=

φ(wt , rt+1)(1+ n)

. (19)

Again, from the production side of the story, we already know that

wt = f (kt )− kt f ′(kt );rt+1 = f ′(kt+1).

Thus we can write (4) as:

kt+1 =φ(wt (kt ), rt+1(kt+1))

(1+ n)= Φ(kt , kt+1). (20)

Equation (20) is the basic dynamic equation of the OLG model,which implicitly defines kt+1 as a function of kt . Given k0, we shouldbe able to trace the evolution of the capital-labour ratio over time.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 71 / 100

Page 72: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Existence of a Unique Perfect Foresight path:

Let us look at dynamic equation (20). Notice that it is an ‘implicit’difference equation with kt+1 entering on both sides.

In fact this implicit nature of the function arises precisely due toassumption of perfect foresight. For any given kt , the LHS denotesthe kt+1 that will acutally emerge in the economy while thert+1(kt+1) in the RHS captures the kt+1 that people expect to hold.Perfect foresight will hold if and only if there two match with eachother.

This then raises the following question: for every kt do we neceassrilyget a unique kt+1 that satisfy the dynamic equation (20)?In other words, for any given initial value of k0, does a uniqueperfect foresight path exist?Notice that uniqueness is important because otherwise the futuretrajectory of the economy will become indeterminate.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 72 / 100

Page 73: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Existence of a Unique Perfect Foresight Path (Contd.):

Notice that for any given value of kt ,say k, from (20) we shall have aunique solution for kt+1 if and only if the curve representingΦ(k , kt+1) has a unique point of intersection with the 45o line in thepositive quadrant.A suffi cient condition for this to happen is Φ(k , kt+1) is either a flatline or is downward sloping with respect to kt+1, i.e.,

∂Φ(k, kt+1)∂kt+1

5 0 for all k ∈ (0,∞).

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 73 / 100

Page 74: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Existence of a Unique Perfect Foresight Path (Contd.):

Notice that

∂Φ(k, kt+1)∂kt+1

=1

(1+ n)∂φ(wt , rt+1)

∂kt+1

=1

(1+ n)∂φ(wt , rt+1)

∂rt+1

drt+1dkt+1

=1

(1+ n)sr f ′′(kt+1).

Thus a suffi cient condition for the existence of a unique perfectforesight path is: sr = 0.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 74 / 100

Page 75: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Dynamics of Capital-Labour Ratio (Contd.):

Let us now characterise the evolution of kt over time.

Since Φ(kt , kt+1) is a nonlinear function of kt and kt+1, we shallhave to use the phase diagram technique to qualitatively characterisethe dynamics.

In drawing the phase diagram, first note that the slope of the phaseline can be determined by total diffentiating (20):

(1+ n)dkt+1 = swdwtdkt

dkt + srdrt+1dkt+1

dkt+1

i.e.,dkt+1dkt

=sw [−kt f ′′(kt )]

(1+ n)− sr f ′′(kt+1).

Under the assumption that sr = 0, the slope of the phase line isnecessarily positive.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 75 / 100

Page 76: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Dynamics of Capital-Labour Ratio (Contd.):

But even when the slope is positive, the curvature is not necessarilyconcave - since it would involve the third derivative of the utilityfunction and the f (k) function - whose signs are not known.

Hence anything is possible: we may have situations of no steadystate; unique stable steady state; unique unstable steady state;multiple steady states (some stable, some unstable):

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 76 / 100

Page 77: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Stability & Dynamic Effi ciency in the OLG Model:

In other words, the nice result of the Solow model of a unique andglobally stable steady state is no longer gauranteed - despite theproduction function satifying all the standard neoclassicalproperties - including diminishing returns and the Inadaconditions!What about dynamic effi ciency?

Even that is not gauranteed any more!

Below we provide an example - with specific functional forms - toshow that dynamic effi ciency is not necessarily gauranteed under theOLG model - despite optimizing savings behaviour by the agents.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 77 / 100

Page 78: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Golden Rule & Dynamic Effi ciency in the OLG Model:

Before we turn to the specific functional forms, let us first define thegolden rule in the context of the OLG model.

As before let us define the ‘golden rule’as that particular steady statewhich maximises the steady state level of per capita (average)consumption.

Notice however that now there are two sets of people at any point oftime t - current young (Nt) and current old (Nt−1).

Hence per capita (average) consumption at any point of time t wouldbe defined as:

ct =c1t Nt + c

2t Nt−1

Lt=c1t Nt + c

2t Nt−1

Nt +Nt−1=(1+ n)c1t + c

2t

1+ (1+ n).

In other words, the per capita consumption in period t is theweighted average of the consumption of the current young and thatof the current old.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 78 / 100

Page 79: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Characterization of the Steady State in OLG Model:

So what would be the steady state value of per capita consumption?Recall that the basic dynamic equation is the OLG model is given by:

kt+1 =st

(1+ n)=

φ(w(kt ), r(kt+1))(1+ n)

Accordingly, the steady state(s) of the OLG model is defined as:

k∗ =s∗

(1+ n)=

φ(w(k∗), r(k∗))(1+ n)

⇒ s∗ = (1+ n)k∗ (21)

On the other hand, from the optimal solutions of c1 and c2, we knowthat at steady state:(

c1)∗

= ψ(w(k∗), r(k∗)) = w(k∗)− s∗; (22)(c2)∗

= η(w(k∗), r(k∗)) = [1+ r(k∗)− δ] s∗. (23)

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 79 / 100

Page 80: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Steady State Per Capita Consumption in the OLG Model:

Hence from (1), (2) & (3) steady state per capita consumption:

c∗ =(1+ n)

(c1)∗+(c2)∗

1+ (1+ n)

=(1+ n) [w(k∗)− s∗] + [(1+ r(k∗)− δ)] s∗

1+ (1+ n)

=(1+ n)w(k∗) + [r(k∗)− δ− n)] s∗

1+ (1+ n)

=(1+ n) [{w(k∗) + r(k∗)k∗} − (n+ δ)k∗]

1+ (1+ n)

=1+ n

1+ (1+ n)[f (k∗)− (n+ δ)k∗] .

Maximizing c∗ with respect to k∗, we would still get the golden rulecondition as:

kg : f ′(k∗) = (n+ δ)

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 80 / 100

Page 81: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

OLG Model with Specific Functional Forms:

Let us now assume specific functional forms.

LetU(c1t , c

2t+1) ≡ log c1t + β log c2t+1;

f (kt ) = (kt )α ; 0 < α < 1.

Also let the rate of depreciation be 100%, i.e., δ = 1.

Thus the life-time budget constraint of the representative agent ofgeneration t is given by:

c1t +c2t+1rt+1

= wt .

The corresponding FONC:

c2t+1c1t

= βrt+1. (24)

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 81 / 100

Page 82: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

OLG Model: Specific Functional Forms (Contd.)

From the FONC and the life-time budget constraint, we can derivethe optimal solutions as:

c1t =1

1+ βwt ;

st =β

1+ βwt ;

c2t+1 = βrt+1

[1

1+ βwt

].

Corresponding dynamic equation:

kt+1 =st

(1+ n)=

(1

1+ n

) [β

1+ βwt

].

Finally, given the production function,

wt = (1− α) (kt )α

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 82 / 100

Page 83: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

OLG Model: Dynamics with Specific Functional Forms

Thus the dynamics of this specific case is simple:

kt+1 =(

11+ n

)(β

1+ β

)(1− α) (kt )

α .

It is easy to see that the above phase line will generate a uniquenon-trivial steady state which is globally stable.

The corresponding steady state solution is defined as:

k∗ =

(1

1+ n

)(β

1+ β

)(1− α) (k∗)α

i.e., k∗ =

[(1

1+ n

)(β

1+ β

)(1− α)

] 11−α

.

Is this steady state dynamically effi cient? Not necessarily!

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 83 / 100

Page 84: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

OLG Model: Dynamic Ineffi ciency

Notice that given the specific functional form, the ‘golden rule’valueof the capital-labour ratio can be derived as:

kg : f ′(k∗) = (n+ δ)

i.e., kg : α(k∗)α−1 = 1+ n

i.e., kg =

1+ n

] 11−α

.

It is easy to verify that the steady state under this specific examplewill be dynamically ineffi cient whenever

β

1+ β>

α

1− α.

Example: β =12; α =

15.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 84 / 100

Page 85: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Reason for Dynamic Ineffi ciency in the OLG Model:

Thus we see that dynamic ineffi ciency may arise in the OLG model -despite optimizing savings behaviour by households.

This apparently paradoxical result stems from the fact that agents are‘selfish’in the OLG model; they do not care for their children’sutility/consumption.

Thus when they optimise they equate the MRS with (the discountedvalue of) the actual future return (rt+1 + 1− δ):

u′(c1t )u′(c2t+1)

= β(rt+1 + 1− δ).

Now notice that

u′ (ct )u′ (ct+1)

T 1⇒ u′ (ct ) T u′ (ct+1)⇒ ct S ct+1.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 85 / 100

Page 86: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Reason for Dynamic Ineffi ciency in OLG Model (Contd.)

This implies that in the OLG framework, ct S ct+1 i.e, consumptionwould rise, fall or remain unchanged over time if the correspondinggross (future) return, measured by (rt+1 + 1− δ) is greater, equal to

or less than the subjective cost1β, ie. according as

rt+1 + 1− δ R 1β.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 86 / 100

Page 87: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Dynamic Ineffi ciency: OLG vis-a-vis R-C-K Model

Recall that in the R-C-K model the corresponding equation was givenby:

u′ (ct ) [1+ n] = βu′ (ct+1)[f ′(kt+1) + (1− δ)

].

i.e.,u′ (ct )u′ (ct+1)

T 1 according as[f ′(kt+1) + (1− δ)]

1+ nR 1

β

Thus in the R-C-K framework, ct S ct+1 i.e, consumption would rise,fall or remain unchanged over time if the correspondingpopulation-adjusted (future) return, measured by [rt+1+(1−δ)]

1+n isgreater, equal to or less than the subjective cost measured by 1

β .

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 87 / 100

Page 88: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Reason for Dynamic Ineffi ciency in OLG Model (Contd.)

Notice that in both the OLG model and the R-C-K model, householdswill stop saving whenever their percieved return is less than thesubjective cost 1β .But due to presence of intergenerational altrauism, in the R-C-Kmodel the percieved return is adjusted for popultion growth and isgiven by [rt+1+(1−δ)]

1+n , whereas in the OLG model this return is just[rt+1 + (1− δ)] .This implies that in the R-C-K model households will necessarily stopsaving when the (net) marginal product has fallen below thepopulation growth rate [rt+1+(1−δ)]

1+n < 1.But there is no reason why in the OLG model, households would stopsaving in this scenario, because even though the gross marginalproduct [rt+1 + (1− δ)] has fallen below 1+ n - it might still greaterthan the subjective cost 1β .Thus there is a tendency to oversave(compared to the R-C-K model), which persists even when theeconomy has moved into a dynamically ineffi cient region.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 88 / 100

Page 89: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Dynamic Ineffi ciency & Scope for Government Interventionin the OLG Model:

Since under the OLG framework, the steady state of the decentralizedmarket economy may be dynamically ineffi cient (despite rationalexpectations on part of the agents), this again justifies a role ofgovernment in improving effi ciency.

Thus the conclusions of the OLG model are diametrically opposite ofthat of the R-C-K model - even though both are based on strictlyneoclassical production function and optimizing agents.

The difference arises primarily due to the absence of parental altruismin the OLG framework.

It can be shown that if we introduce parental altruism in the OLGmodel (by incorporating a bequest term that each parent leaves to hischild at the end of his life time), then the OLG framework will be verysimilar to the R-C-K framework.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 89 / 100

Page 90: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

OLG Model: Summary

Even though the production function is Neoclassical in the OLGmodel, the strong stability result of Solow (as well as R-C-K model)does not hold:

a steady state may not exists;even if it exists it may not be unique;even if it is unique, it may not be stable.

So the growth conclusions of the Solow model do not hold either.

Moreover the dynamic ineffi ciency problem may reappear here- eventhough each agent is optimally determining his savings behaviour.

Thus in this model there is scope for government intervention interms of improving effi ciency.

Since the OLG model does not obey the growth properties of theSolow/R-C-K model, we do not identify this structure with the“Neoclassical Growth Model" (even though the production structurehere is identical to Solow/R-C-K).

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 90 / 100

Page 91: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Long Run Growth of Per Capita?

Recall that in all the growth models discussed so far, thecapital-labour ratio (kt) in the long run becomes a constant. Hencenone of them can explain the steady rise in per capita income that ishistorically observed in almost all economies since the industrialrevolution in Europe in the late 18th century.Such staedy growth is often explained by appealing to exogenoustechnological shocks.Can we have long run growth of per capita income in a Solow-typeeconomy even without such exogenous shocks?The answer is: yes, but only if you allow some of the Neoclassicalproperties of the production function to be relaxed.The long run constancy of the per capita income in the Solow modelarises due to the strong uniqueness and stability property of thesteady state - which in turn depends on two key assumptions: theproperty of diminishing returns and the Inada Conditions. One cangenerate long run growth of per capita income in the Solow model ifwe relax one of these conditions.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 91 / 100

Page 92: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

AK Production Technology: First Step TowardsEndogenous Growth

In particular, steady growth along a balanced growth path is possibleif the production function exhibits non-diminishing returns.A specific example of such non-diminishing returns technology is theAK technology where output is a linear function of capital:

Yt = AKt .

The AK model is the precursor to the latter-day ‘endogenous growththeory’which (unlike Solow) attempts to explain long run growth inper capita income in terms endogenous factors within the economy.

When technology interacts with the factor accumulation, there is noreason why the production function would necessarily exhibitdiminishing returns.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 92 / 100

Page 93: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

AK Technology: Dynamics of Capital and Labour

Let us now replace the Neoclassical production function in the Solowmodel by an AK production function.

As before, capital stock over time gets augmented by thesavings/investment made by the households.

Thus the capital accumulation equation in this economy is given by:

Kt+1 = It + (1− δ)Kt = sYt + (1− δ)Kti.e., Kt+1 = sAKt + (1− δ)Kt , (25)

Labour stock, on the other hand, increases due to population growth(at a constant rate n):

Nt+1 = (1+ n)Nt . (26)

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 93 / 100

Page 94: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

AK Technogy: Dynamics of Capital-Labour Ratio

Using the definition that kt ≡ KtNt, we can write

kt+1 ≡ Kt+1Nt+1

=sAKt + (1− δ)Kt

(1+ n)Nt

⇒ kt+1 =sA+ (1− δ)

(1+ n)kt . (27)

From above, the rate of growth of capital-labour ratio, and hencethat of per capita output, is immediately given by:

kt+1 − ktkt

=sA− (δ+ n)(1+ n)

As long as sA > (δ+ n), per capita output grows at a constant rate -both in short run and long run.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 94 / 100

Page 95: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Justifications for AK Technology:

There are many justifications as to why the ‘aggregate’productiontechnology might be linear. Here we look at two examples - eachproviding a different justification as to why diminishing returns mightnot work:

1 Fixed Coeffi cient Technogy - exhibiting complemetarity between factorsof production;

2 Production Technology with Learning-by-Doing and KnowledgeSpillover (Frankel-Romer).

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 95 / 100

Page 96: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Justification for AK Technology: Leontief ProductionFunction

The first example of an AK technology is of course the FixedCoeffi cient (Leontief) Production Function:

Yt = min [aKt , bNt ] ,

where a and b are the constant coeffi cients representing theproductivity of capital and labour respectively.Suppose the economy starts with a (historically) given stock ofcapital and a given amount of labour force at time t.Then fixed coeffi cient technology implies:

Yt = aKt if aKt < bNt (capital constrained economy);

Yt = bNt if bNt < aKt (labour constrained economy).

In the first case, the production technology would in effect be AK -although notice that labour is still used in the production process.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 96 / 100

Page 97: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

Justification for AK Technology: Learning by Doing &Knowledge Spillover

A more nuanced justification was provided by Frankel (1962), whichwas later exploited by Romer (1986) in developing the first model ofendogenous growth.

This was already discussed in the context of the Micro-foundations.Let us quickly recapitulate.

Consider an economy with S identical firms - each having access toan identical firm-specific technology:

Yi = AtF (Kit ,Nit ) ≡ At (Kit )α (Nit )1−α ; 0 < α < 1.

The firm-specific production function exhibits all the neoclassicalproperties.

At represents the current state of the technology in the economy,which is treated as exogenous by each firm.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 97 / 100

Page 98: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

AK Technology: Frankel-Romer Explanation

The At depends on the aggregate capital labour-ratio in theeconomy - due to ‘learning by doing’. In particular, let us assume

At =(KtNt

; β > 0; where Kt = SKit ; N = SNit .

Corresponding Aggregate Production Function:

Yt = ∑Yit = S[At (Kit )

α (Nit )1−α]

= At (SKit )α (SNit )

1−α

= At (Kt )α (Nt )

1−α .

Replacing the value of At in the aggregate production technology:

Yt = At (Kt )α (Nt )

1−α = (Kt )α+β (Nt )

1−α−β .

In the special case where α+ β = 1, the aggregate productiontechnology is indeed AK.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 98 / 100

Page 99: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

AK Technology: General Insight

Even though the AK models hint at some explanation for thetechnology parameter (e.g., learning by doing in the Frankel-Romermodel), they do not model technological progress explicitly.

The subsequent endogenous growth models explicitly specify aprocess of technological change in terms of R&D, education,improvement in infrastructure etc. They also move away from theCRS technology to allow for IRS - which necessitates a movementaway from competitive market structure.

Even more recent developments in growth theory go beyondtechnology and explain growth in terms of other deeper factors likeinstitutions, political economy, income and wealth distribution etc.

These are however beyond the purview of the current course.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 99 / 100

Page 100: Output Dynamics In the Long Run: Issues of Economic Growth

References:

Reference for Solow Model & Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans OptimalGrowth Model :

D. Acemoglu: Introduction to Modern Economic Growth, Chapter 2,Sections 2.1,2.2, 2.3 & Chapter 5, Sections 5.1,5.2, 5.3, 5.4, 5.5, 5.9.

Reference for the OLG Model:

D. Acemoglu: Introduction to Modern Economic Growth, Chapter 9,Sections 9.2,9.3, 9.4.O.Galor & H. Ryder (1989): "Existence, uniqueness, and stability ofequilibrium in an overlapping-generations model with productivecapital,", Journal of Economic Theory, pp.360—375.

Das (Lecture Notes, DSE) Economic Growth April 17-27; 2017 100 / 100