+++opitz_tellmann_global_territories-libre

23
This article was downloaded by: [University of Hamburg] On: 13 December 2012, At: 05:28 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http:/ / www.tandfonline.com/ loi/ rdis20 Global territories: zones of economic and legal dis/ connectivity Sven Opitz a & Ut e Tellmann a a Inst it ut e of Sociology, Universit y of Hamburg, Hamburg, Germany Version of record first published: 13 Dec 2012. To cite this article: Sven Opit z & Ut e Tellmann (2012): Global t errit ories: zones of economic and legal dis/ connect ivit y, Dist inkt ion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory, 13:3, 261-282 To link to this article: ht t p: / / dx. doi. org/ 10. 1080/ 1600910X. 2012. 724432 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and- conditions This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae, and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.

Upload: tamer-elshayal

Post on 17-Dec-2015

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

+++Opitz_Tellmann_Global_Territories-libre

TRANSCRIPT

  • This art icle was downloaded by: [ University of Hamburg]On: 13 December 2012, At : 05: 28Publisher: Rout ledgeI nforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registeredoffice: Mort imer House, 37-41 Mort imer St reet , London W1T 3JH, UK

    Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal ofSocial TheoryPublicat ion details, including inst ruct ions for authors andsubscript ion informat ion:ht tp:/ / www.tandfonline.com/ loi/ rdis20

    Global territories: zones of economicand legal dis/connectivitySven Opitz a & Ute Tellmann aa Inst itute of Sociology, University of Hamburg, Hamburg,

    GermanyVersion of record f irst published: 13 Dec 2012.

    To cite this article: Sven Opitz & Ute Tellmann (2012): Global territories: zones of economic andlegal dis/ connect ivity, Dist inkt ion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory, 13:3, 261-282

    To link to this article: ht tp:/ / dx.doi.org/ 10.1080/ 1600910X.2012.724432

    PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTI CLE

    Full terms and condit ions of use: ht tp: / / www.tandfonline.com/ page/ terms-and-condit ions

    This art icle may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Anysubstant ial or systemat ic reproduct ion, redist r ibut ion, reselling, loan, sub- licensing,systemat ic supply, or dist r ibut ion in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden.

    The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representat ionthat the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of anyinst ruct ions, formulae, and drug doses should be independent ly verified with pr imarysources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, act ions, claims, proceedings,demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising direct ly orindirect ly in connect ion with or ar ising out of the use of this material.

  • RESEARCH ARTICLE

    Global territories: zones of economic and legal dis/connectivity

    Sven Opitz and Ute Tellmann*

    Institute of Sociology, University of Hamburg, Hamburg, Germany

    This article develops a notion of global territoriality for understanding theproliferation of special oshore zones in the context of globalization. It furnishesan account of how political territoriality is used for shaping global dis/connectivity. The argument is developed through the exploration of two distinctcases of oshore zones that are usually not theorized as a common phenomenon:one case is the nancial oshore center on the Cayman Islands, the other case isthe Australian oshore center for processing refugee claims on Christmas Island.Whereas the one site deals with non-resident money, the other one administersnon-resident subjects. The article shows that despite the dierent aims that thesesites serve, they are homologous in how they employ territorial strategies formodulating connectivity. We focus on three dimensions: the topological enfoldingof inside/outside relations, the bifurcation between legal and physical presence,and a politics of visibility. By studying how these uses of territoriality entail arecalibration of the obligations and accountability tied to monetary and legalrelations, this article develops a dierent notion of the global. Instead ofunderstanding the global in terms of scale, it suggests an understanding of theglobal in terms of a politics of connectivity.

    Keywords: connectivity; exception; global law; globalization; money; oshore;territory; topology

    Christmas Island is a small isle lost in the Indian Ocean. Tugged away from the

    Australian mainland, surrounded by steep reefs, it can be reached only by a four-

    hour ight or by a supply ship that docks every ve to six weeks (Onishi 2009). It is

    an island full of natural wonders; two-thirds of it is declared a national park. The

    Cayman Islands are about 20 hours by plane from Christmas Island. It has equally

    beautiful natural sites to oer for tourists. But it is unlikely that someone would ever

    try to make that trip. These islands belong to very dierent types of global

    circulation: one is known for handling non-resident money, the other is known for

    processing non-resident subjects. Christmas Island has become infamous for its

    asylum seeker detention center, instituted by the Australian government with the aim

    of creating a hub for the oshore processing of refugees. The Cayman Islands are

    infamous for their status as an oshore nancial center, oering a hub for migrant

    money. They are both small islands and specic places. At the same time, they are

    intimately tied to what has been described as the global space of ows from which

    *Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]

    Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory

    Vol. 13, No. 3, December 2012, 261282

    ISSN 1600-910X print/ISSN 2159-9149 online

    2012 Taylor & Francis

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1600910X.2012.724432

    http://www.tandfonline.com

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • they gain their signicance. As we want to argue in this paper, they are both shaped

    by what we call global territoriality.

    The term global territoriality appears at rst sight to be an oxymoron. It links

    two terms that have been taken to mark opposites. The global is often associated

    with transcending the xity of territoriality. It has been linked to expansion and

    planetary reach. Territory, by contrast, is often associated with the sovereignty of the

    nation-state and the pacication of global movements. It is linked to tying people

    and things to the ground. This common-sense dichotomy between the global and the

    territorial is deeply rooted in political liberalism and also in early sociological

    accounts of globalization. Both tend to understand the emergence of the global in

    terms of a decline of the territorial. From this angle an oshore place like the

    Cayman Islands must appear either as economically insignicant or as a sheer

    anomaly. It does not t the understanding of money as a placeless medium (OBrien

    1992; Simmel 1990). Likewise, Christmas Island must appear as an aberration to the

    human rights regime, which was set up after the Second World War and came into

    full force with the onset of globalization during the 1970s (Moyn 2010). This regime

    aspires to protect individuals by the law irrespective of their location and political

    aliation (Galli 2010, 11720). Consequently, an oshore processing regime on a

    territory such as Christmas Island can only be an anomaly of global law. Taken in

    sum, the talk of global territoriality runs against deeply rooted assumptions and

    expectations about the universalism of law and money.

    However, during the last decade the globalist (Tsing 2000) image with its sharp

    dichotomies between the uid and the xed, the unbound and the bound, the global

    whole and the territorially fragmented parts has also been subject to criticism by

    anthropologists (Ferguson 2006; Ong 2006), political geographers (Elden 2005; Paasi

    1998), and sociologists (Brighenti 2010b; Sassen 2006). Territoriality, according to

    the general argument to be found in this literature, has not waned in its importance

    but if anything has become more important as part and parcel of doing

    globalization. In this light, oshore places such as Christmas Island and the

    Cayman Islands are not anomalies of globalization but are at the heart of it. By

    putting the global and the territorial into one conceptual coinage, this article intends

    to further this line of research by studying oshore zones as a very specic link

    between the territorial and the global (Tellmann 2009). We want to take the

    heterogeneous insular sites of Christmas Island and the Cayman Islands as

    exemplary cases for exploring two related conceptual questions: What kind of

    form does territoriality assume in the context of producing and imagining global

    circulation? And how do we have to modify our understanding both of the global

    and the territorial when we are confronted with spaces that are both at once?

    Following the recent methodological debates about socio-spatial investigations,

    we study these questions by focusing on historically specic geographies as simple

    entry points into a more complex inquiry on how networks and territories intersect

    (Jessop, Brenner, and Jones 2008, 392). By looking at two dierent oshore zones as

    a type of global territory, this article allows us to question the conceptual opposition

    between topology and topography. This conceptual opposition imagines space either

    to be constituted by networks and relations or to be demarcated by an older

    topography in which territoriality was dominant (Amin, Massey, and Thrift 2003, 6).

    In this understanding the notion of the network is juxtaposed to territory framed as

    something more xed. But as Jones has recently argued, we should [. . .] not be

    forced to adopt a network versus territories scenario (2009, 494; Painter 2010).

    262 S. Opitz and U. Tellmann

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • The phenomenon of the oshore zone supports this view. It very much demonstrates

    that territories and networks, topology and topography are linked. But how are we

    to understand this interaction? How exactly is this link forged?

    Christmas Island and the Cayman Islands might appear as a very specic

    and rather peculiar choice for a comparative inquiry of global territoriality. While

    the Cayman Islands are among the most well-known nancial oshore centers

    since the 1970s, Christmas Island has only recently been picked by the Australian

    government as a geographical location for managing what is considered to be a

    threatening inux of refugees. Both territorial constructs have very dierent

    histories. But despite their dierence, both can be looked at as paradigmatic cases

    of global zones: they have both been established either in light of global ows of

    money that one sought to attract or global ows of subjects that one hoped to

    deter. They both belong to the phenomena of zoning strategies that have

    commenced with the start of globalization and proliferated since the last decades.

    Zones are here understood as specic juridico-territorial constructs that emerge by

    parceling o a bounded area as a specic regulatory space. They are creatures of

    political decree, and they have become ubiquitous in governmental rationalities

    that hope to address a planetary horizon of circulation (Foucault 2008, 5175;

    Elden 2007, 577). Jonathan Bach (2011) and Keller Easterling (2007) have recently

    pointed out that although the zone is a key location for understanding processes

    of globalization, it is generally an under-theorized and under-researched

    phenomenon (Bach 2011, 116).

    Drawing on and hoping to contribute to the existing scholarship on global

    zones and territory, we propose to study the specic territoriality of global zones

    in further depth. We seek to analyze what these territories do to the money and

    subjects entering them, what kind of form they have, and how they are tied to the

    imaginary of global circulations. We look at territoriality as a political technology

    in the sense that Foucault (2007) has given this term, meaning that it belongs to

    a strategic ensemble of governmental rationalities and practices. Specically, we

    are interested in understanding how the phenomenon of creating spaces o the

    map while in itself not a historical novelty belongs to negotiating the global

    (Ruggie 1993). Our vantage point is the observation that the territorial strategy of

    constructing such zones has proliferated in the era of globalization, surging from

    a mere handful in the 1960s to over 5000 barely a lifetime later (Bach 2011, 100).

    Zones can host very dierent practices: they can be about production regimes

    aimed at export, as much as they can be about logistical hubs, knowledge, and

    technology centers. They constitute border sites that control immigrants as well as

    money they range, as Saskia Sassen (2005, 530) has put it, from banks to

    bodies. These zones are constructed, maintained, and championed in light of a

    liberal planetary horizon of circulation that they intend to serve. While not

    exclusive to it, they seem to belong to our contemporary global assemblages in

    particular ways (Ong and Collier 2004). Could it be that these zones help us

    understand that the global might not be simply larger in scale than the nation-

    state, but is a dimension that is broken, poorly formed, [. . .] comes in patches

    (Law 2004, 18) and, as such, is not about scale but more about dierent types of

    connectivity?

    It is important to note that the notion of the zone as a global form does not imply

    a strict uniformity of the phenomenon. As the following exploration of the dierent

    cases will bring into view, zones are versatile technologies, serving dierent aims and

    Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory 263

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • having dierent eects. But they also share common traits. By asking what the zone

    does to the money or the subjects entering it, we are able to show that the

    phenomenology of the zone is characterized by the following dimensions: it consists

    rstly in a peculiar folding of inside and outside, secondly in the disjunction between

    physical and legal presence, and thirdly in a politics of visibility. In each case, the zone

    eects a modulation of relations, for example, between money and political space, or

    between subjects and rights: they mark and unmark bodies as bearers of rights or

    money as bearer of obligations. Using the notion of modulation, as coined by Deleuze

    (1992, 47; 2003, 1167), helps to bring into focus that these spaces are mainly about

    calibrating, undoing, or modifying relations, instead of being merely about

    disciplining the subjects or objects that have come into its reach.

    The remainder of this article proceeds as follows. The next section situates the

    concept of global territoriality in the recent debate on territoriality and the global. It

    claries what it means to look at territory as a political technology and introduces

    the zone as a specic territorial form as part of what Aiwha Ong has called

    graduated sovereignty. Drawing critically on the debate in human geography, we

    want to argue that the territorial operation of zoning is not primarily about

    demarcating possessions or bordering an exclusive polity and requires a more

    topological approach to territoriality. The subsequent sections explore the meaning

    of global territoriality by comparing the territorial form of Christmas Island and the

    Cayman Islands, respectively. The following questions will be addressed: How

    precisely does oshoring operate as a territorial strategy of zoning? How do the

    oshores for processing non-resident money and non-resident subjects belong to the

    same global form? And how do they articulate dierent entanglements of the global

    and the territorial?

    Territoriality, zones, and the global

    The rst waves of globalization theory have today acquired a status of classics that

    share the same mistaken presumption: they framed the global dimension mainly in

    terms of spatial expansion and as an overcoming of the narrow bounds of the

    territorial state. The global world appeared as a smooth space (Hardt and Negri

    2000), a boundless space of ows (Castells 1996; Shields 1997), or a supraterritor-

    ial (Scholte 2005) domain that had overcome the narrow bounds of adjacent, clearly

    demarcated states. The global implied that the only location was about being

    situated on the planet earth (Scholte 1996, 1968). Undoubtedly, this aspiration to

    think the global beyond the state was often linked to a well-founded critique of what

    had been termed the territorial trap (Agnew 1994; Ruggie 1993). The global

    dimension allowed questioning the geographically bounded, territorially demarcated

    state as the basic unit of analysis. In hindsight it looks as if the laudable attempt of

    leaving behind such methodological territorialism (Jessop, Brenner, and Jones

    2008, 391) implied throwing out the baby with the bath-water. Since these early

    accounts of globalization, the suspicion has grown that overcoming the territorial

    trap only meant to fall into a non-territorial trap (Jones 2009, 494) in which

    territoriality was wrongly thought to be irrelevant.

    Today it is widely recognized that theories of globalization have been ill-served

    by an implicit understanding of space that only oers the choice of thinking

    internally contiguous, xed, and somehow pre-given territories on the one hand and

    an image of the globe as if seen from outer space on the other hand: unied,

    264 S. Opitz and U. Tellmann

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • planetary, all-encompassing (Jazeel 2001). In fact, as Neil Brenner (1999a; 1999b)

    has argued already a decade ago, the notion of the global scale in many accounts of

    globalization presupposes a concept of state territoriality simply writ large. His

    argument insinuates that the territorial and the non-territorial trap might suer

    from similar aws. They conceive of global space either as a pre-given geographical

    container or [. . . as] a form of territoriality stretched onto the global scale (Brenner

    1999a, 54). Hence, both traps emerge from the same implicit understanding of space.

    If indeed the early notions of globalization were hampered by their implicit

    commitment to an old notion of bounded space, one has to conclude that rethinking

    the global and rethinking territoriality are co-determined. Avoiding the non-

    territorial trap and the territorial trap alike thus implies that territory has to be

    understood not as isomorphic, self-enclosed blocks of absolute space, but as a

    mosaic that is neither congruent nor contiguous (Brenner 1999a, 53). Re-

    theorizing territory is thus the key for a better understanding of the global, insofar as

    it helps to conceptualize the contemporary multiplication of territories (Brighenti

    2010b, 52). But rethinking territory is not an easy task as it embroils rethinking our

    conceptions of space and the techniques for commanding and calculating it (Elden

    2009, xxvii). Understanding territory has been the challenge a decade ago and still is:

    Territorys time has come, or so it seems (Painter 2010, 1090). But how are we to

    address the complex territorial logics of the present (Elden 2009, xviii, xx)?

    We want to suggest that one fruitful vantage point for thinking the territorial

    anew can paradoxically be found by going back to an old understanding of territory

    as a contingent outcome of territorial practices (Delaney 2005; Paasi 2003). Robert

    Sack had in his classical study on Human Territoriality (1986) dened territory as a

    technology of power that wishes to aect, inuence, and control people,

    phenomena, and relationships, by delimiting and asserting control over a geographic

    area (Sack 1986, 19). According to Sack, territoriality can be used on dierent levels,

    from the personal to the international, and for dierent purposes (1986, 1). As a

    particular technology of power it performs two basic operations: rstly, territory is

    about establish[ing] dierent degrees of access to people, things and relationships

    (Sack 1986, 20). Secondly, its eect is the constitution of inside/outside demarcations

    that can have dierent degrees of xity or depth. Sack emphasizes that territorial

    strategies are never purely geographical. Territory always requires non-territorial

    actions to back it up (Sack 1986, 16). Marking a territory might employ legal,

    symbolic, military, or other means for signaling and parceling out a certain area.

    Sacks notion of territoriality is still instructive, because it does not presume that

    territory always has the same self-enclosed shape; it does not link territory solely to

    the nation-state, nor does it naturalize territorial practices as belonging to a notion

    of Lebensraum (Friedrich Ratzel). Furthermore, it allows understanding territory as

    an eect of highly malleable and versatile strategic practices, which can result in

    dierent forms of inside/outside relations. It enables one to take into view the

    combination of spatial and non-spatial strategies for modulating inside/outside

    relations (Opitz 2012, 11437). Sacks framing of territoriality certainly lacks

    historical specicity, for which it has been rightfully criticized (Elden 2010). But this

    lack can easily be rectied because his notion of territory is dened mainly on a

    formal level. Even though this denition of territoriality oers only a very broad and

    rather thin heuristic, it turns out to be fruitful for analyzing the specicity of global

    territoriality. As can be seen below, particularly the notion of territory as modulating

    access to relationships will be very important for understanding the global territory

    Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory 265

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • as a form that can be articulated as part of dierent assemblages of power (Collier

    2006, 400). Looking at territoriality as a composite of spatial and non-spatial

    practices that engender particular types of boundedness and grant dierential access

    to relationships allows for both sucient focus and openness in understanding the

    phenomenon of oshores. It avoids the simple binary and epochal renderings of the

    two eras of the territorial nation-state and of borderless globalization.

    As already indicated above, this article focuses on the oshore zone as a

    particular case of global territoriality (Bach 2011; Easterling 2007; 2008). We dene

    the zone as a strategic construction or deployment of juridico-political territories.

    These juridico-territorial enclaves have been linked to a notion of extrastatecraft,

    meaning a type of infrastructure that disassembles the contiguous territory of the

    state (Easterling 2008). Zones are bounded spaces, which are exempt from their

    surrounding jurisdiction and constitute dierential regulatory spaces. They belong to

    changing practices of sovereignty that create what we might call nested

    exceptionalisms (Bach 2011, 99). Understanding the zone as a space of exception

    highlights a crucial feature of the zone that consists in the juridical dierence that

    exists between the onshore and the oshore zone. A zone is a space that is marked

    o from its surroundings, either through a sovereign act of enclosure or through

    using a given political territory as such dierential space (Brown 2010, 52). It is tied

    to sovereignty as a border concept, insofar as the zone is dened by organizing the

    space both inside and outside the entity (Brown 2010, 52).

    Nevertheless, the notion of exception needs some clarication in this context,

    given that the denition, which Giorgio Agamben (1998; 2005; Opitz 2011, 10511)

    has given this notion, has been very prevalent in the recent years. Agamben refers to

    the exception as a state in which the protection of law is suspended; he claims that

    this situation of fundamental exposure to sovereign power without protection

    irreducibly belongs to the making of territorial-sovereign law. But as Aiwha Ong has

    already remarked, if one seeks to use the notion of exception for understanding the

    strategic deployment of territoriality as part of always contested neoliberal

    calculations, Agambens stark opposition between bare life and protected life

    needs to be dierentiated (Ong 2006, 20). As we will show below, it would be

    misleading to describe the oshore-processing zone on Christmas Island in terms of

    a total absence of legal procedures as Agambens notion of exception would imply.

    While abrogating the status of the legal subject, it upholds so-called global

    standards, yet delinking them from political space and visibility. The case of the

    Cayman Islands is an even more complicated case to t into the current debate on

    legal and political exceptions as inspired by Agambens work. Money, while being

    oshore, is never subjected to what Agamben calls the ban, describing a relation

    without legal-political protection; quite the contrary, it enjoys a heightened status of

    legal safety. Furthermore, cases such as the Cayman Islands require us to broaden

    the understanding of the emergence of such zones: they are often the outcome of a

    strategic deployment of a geopolitical position within a system of sovereign

    territories, instead of being the internal shadow of an inward foundation of

    sovereignty, as Agamben would have it.

    Following Aiwha Ong, we suggest the conditional use of the notion of exception

    for understanding the fragmentation of human territoriality in the interest of

    forging variable and contingent connections to global circuits (2006, 19). We seek to

    supplement her reading of neoliberalism as exception by focusing on other zones

    than she does. The zones we are looking at are not mainly about techniques of

    266 S. Opitz and U. Tellmann

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • optimization, which aim at subjects and productions. As we want to suggest, the

    Cayman Islands and Christmas Island are about the dis/connectivity of law and

    money itself. We look at these zones in terms of how they modulate what relations of

    money or law are about. Our aim is to deepen the understanding of the very

    phenomenology of the zone by asking: what kind of territorial bounds constitute the

    phenomenon oshore? How are they linked to non-territorial demarcations? What

    happens to legal and monetary relations when entering the zone?

    By suggesting studying the zone as a particularly instructive case of global

    territory, given that this modular form proliferated in this context, we do not want to

    presume the meaning of global circuits or global networks that it belongs to. There

    is no doubt that the liberal political imaginary of today thinks itself in terms of

    networks and ows that are supposed to be molded and served by such territories of

    exemption. Zones are consciously set up as super-corridors of nomadic capital or as

    necessary spaces for managing allegedly global oods of migration. The metaphors

    of uidity, water, and ows are conspicuous in the understanding of globalization and

    often mislead us to imagine a continuous stream that is somehow pre-given (Ferguson

    2006; Pryke 2006, 7). In analyzing those zones and their relations to the global, how

    are we to avoid tapping unconsciously into such an imaginary of smooth liquidity?

    Instead of presuming the world of global ows and nomadic capital, to which the

    zone is perfectly tting, we argue that one has to analyze the constitutive role of these

    territories for managing, establishing, or operating what we term global dis/

    connectivity. The notion of connectivity takes up the question of circulation and

    ow, but re-articulates it as a contingent and multidirectional relationality (see the

    Introduction of this issue). There are no ows that precede the zone. Instead, we are

    dealing with the making and unmaking of connectivity: between money, law, subjects,

    spaces, obligations, and accountability. The modulation of relations and the access to

    them is crucial for dening the role of global territories, as the following cases will

    demonstrate.

    Offshore finance and monetary connectivity

    Monetary ows are often taken as the paradigmatic example for understanding

    issues of globalization. No other aspect of globalization is so deeply tied to the

    imaginary of globalism than the common-sense understanding of monetary ows.

    Money is classically understood as de-territorialized, quickly changing hands and

    spaces, eeing regulation, undermining boundaries, movable like quicksilver

    (Simmel 1990). Yet, in contradistinction to this imaginary of money, global money

    also occupies specic spaces (Clark 2005; Leyshon and Thrift 1997; Tickell 2000).

    These spaces are not just the big stock exchanges and the big cities where

    globalization is managed (Pryke 1991; Sassen 1991). These spaces of ows are also

    found in the territorial enclaves and sovereign spaces that are known under the name

    of oshore (Hudson 1996; Maurer 2005; Palan 2003; Roberts 1995). The attribute of

    oshore conjures up a plethora of images, which range over exotic landscapes, brass

    plates, beaches, nefarious business, and dirty money (Baker 2005). But while the

    cases of dirty money have occupied the minds of government ocials, tax

    departments, and non-governmental organizations, it is important not to forget

    that oshore is a rather signicant site for what is considered global money (Palan

    2003). As the International Monetary Fund (IMF) puts it, nancial oshore centers

    have captured a signicant proportion of global nancial ows (IMF 2007, 3).

    Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory 267

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • The Cayman Islands are one of the oldest and well-established nancial oshore

    centers. It is the fth largest nancial center in the world, the largest oshore mutual

    fund registration center in the world and the second largest oshore insurance

    center (Moodys 2010). It hosts at least a third of globally operating hedge funds. In

    total, there are 72,994 oshore corporations registered at the Cayman Islands; the

    islands are the domicile of 2 trillion dollars of banking assets (Cayman Islands

    Government 2011a; GAO 2008; Sharman 2010). Oshore sites like the Cayman

    Islands are used by multinational corporations but also by pension funds and

    university endowments to handle cross-border relations of money. Oshores

    facilitate combining investment streams from dierent countries in a single portfolio.

    They make it easy to leverage more capital as the corporations licensed there are not

    subjected to high capital requirements. Oshores have also become laboratories for

    inventing and putting to work complex nancial instruments. The complexity of

    international nancial services, their increasing cross-sectoral and cross-border

    integration, and the sharing and transferring of risks across sectors and agents that

    they allow nd their abode in oshore centers such as the Cayman Islands (IMF

    2006, 9).

    The Ugland House on 201 Church Street in George Town on the Grand Cayman

    island has achieved some fame for being the registered home of 18,857 nancial

    institutions (GAO 2008, 11). They t into this small building only because of the fact

    that most of them have no physical presence there. These entities registered at

    Ugland House are legally present, but not physically, and they are not allowed to

    oer their service to those that are their neighbors in the physical space they inhabit.

    These corporations pay a premium to reside somewhere other than where they are

    actually located (Palan 2003, 4). They are there and not there at the same time. Their

    legal personality is divided among dierent jurisdictions (Palan 2003, 106). The

    very recombinatory possibility that the oshore allows between physical and legal

    presence has been recognized to be at the core of the oshore phenomenon (Picciotto

    1999): it allows negotiating degrees of being there. The inside/outside demarcation is

    thereby modulated in a specic way. In order to understand the oshore as a general

    global form one has to inquire more deeply into how precisely this complex and

    elastic demarcation between the inside and the outside works.

    Oshore places look on the surface like geographical places, but they are not.

    They are regulatory spaces. Oshores are dened by a constitutive split or inner

    cleavage, which is already signied in the very name oshore: oshores are o some

    shore. But which shore (Hudson 1996, 107; 1998)? It is easy to underestimate the

    complexity of what it means to be o some shore. All too often, oshore is only

    understood as a relation between a major industrialized nation, considered onshore,

    and a small island, understood as oshore. The relation between on- and oshore is

    then described by the dierence of the density of regulation and tax regime that exist

    at these two places. Onshore and oshore are competing in this account for a

    presumed global ow of money to domicile in their territories and to generate

    revenue for the state. While there is certainly truth to this narrative, its analytical

    framing underestimates the internal cleavage that oshore is about. Oshore centers

    like the Cayman Islands are not simply o the shore of the USA, for example. They

    are in a sense also oshore to the Cayman Islands themselves: the foreign nancial

    institutions registered at the Cayman Islands have mostly the status of being exempt

    or are licensed in such a way that they are prohibited from trading with or providing

    services to the Cayman Islanders themselves. Hence, we are dealing with combined

    268 S. Opitz and U. Tellmann

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • splitting between countries and jurisdictions that thrive upon internal divisions, as

    much as external ones.

    The most recent Special Economic Zones Order from 2011 that instituted Cayman

    Enterprise City is a case in point for the proliferation of shoring something o

    internally. Not only insurance, pension funds, and hedge funds have their exempt

    zone, but also a Media Park, an Internet and Technology Park, a Commodities and

    Derivatives Park, an International Academic Park, as well as an Outsource Park, the

    last-mentioned being designed as a small dedicated unit to facilitate the production

    and manufacturing for SEZ-based businesses of products in other jurisdictions.

    Each of these parks invites business to operate globally out of Cayman (Cayman

    Islands Government 2012, 4, 8). Being onshore and oshore at the Cayman Islands

    at the same time, while aiming at businesses that conduct oshore operations on

    other shores this complex layering makes oshore an elusive category regardless of

    whether it applies to nancial or to other economic practices. It comes not as a

    surprise that dening a nancial oshore center is a dicult undertaking. Each

    article on the phenomenon of oshore starts with a comment on the troublesome

    eort to say what it is. The condition of oshore might be very much in the eye of

    the beholder (Sharman 2010). This diculty of denition, one might say, resides in

    the complex relationality of the oshore that is about internal and external cleavages

    at once.

    The complex enfolding of the inside and the outside also pertains to the

    jurisdictional status of the Cayman Islands. At rst sight, the Cayman Islands

    appear as a straightforward sovereign political space. The Cayman Islands employ

    the conventions of political sovereignty, understood here as the fundamental right of

    self-governing, for creating a regulatory space on a territory. But already this

    seemingly clear starting-point has to be qualied: the Cayman Islands, just as some

    other Caribbean islands in the net (Maurer 2001), are not an absolute independent

    sovereign state, but a British Overseas Territory, which means that the nal executive

    authority is vested in the British Crown. While assuming independence as a

    territorial jurisdiction, the sovereign prerogative of making laws is restricted by the

    constitutional bounds that are issued for the Islands by Great Britain. At the same

    time, the constitution is geared towards political independence. Hence, it is neither

    totally outside of Great Britain, nor inside of its jurisdiction. This simultaneity of

    inside/outside paradoxically heightens the stability and exclusivity of this territorial

    jurisdiction. It oers the guarantee that the tradition of common law will be

    respected at the Cayman Islands and will not be undone by a radical political

    change. As Moodys credit rating report nds, The Cayman Islands status as a

    British overseas territory has contributed to its strong legal and accounting systems

    (Moodys 2010). At the same time, the degree of jurisdictional independence also

    oers a shield against the regulations of British law. The territorial construction of

    this jurisdiction is of importance in this context as can be demonstrated in

    comparison to the attempts to construct oshore on purely legal terms. There have

    been eorts in the US during the 1980s to copy the oshore onto its own shore

    simply by declaring some monetary deals to belong to a dierentiated set of rules.

    But these oshore facilities, located geographically onshore, were suspected not to

    oer sucient protection. Being part of a dierent jurisdictional territorial space

    oers a trust of place that law itself does not achieve on its own (Hudson 1998, 23).

    The enfolded quality of the inside/outside bifurcation is a crucial part of what

    oshore is and where it is done (IMF 2007). It organizes certain kinds of distances

    Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory 269

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • and connectivity of money; it molds the type of relation that money is about. As the

    most recent attempt to achieve an operational denition of oshore by the IMF

    makes clear, it is exactly the relation between money and its context that is at stake in

    oshore. The denition is relational itself as it designates oshore as a country or

    jurisdiction that provides nancial services to nonresidents on a scale that is

    incommensurate with the size and the nancing of its domestic economy (IMF 2007,

    7). This denition points us towards the status of the money handled there: it is from

    non-residents to non-residents, leading to an understanding of oshore that includes

    the Cayman Islands, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom inter alia in one list

    (IMF 2007, 15). In essence, oshore is thus about a modied relation between money

    to a place: money is supposed only to ow through these sites, to be sent to and

    recovered from non-residents, only acquiring a temporary and legal regulatory

    presence oshore. As one fund manager explains, most customers do not understand

    that the money never is literally there (Hudson 1996, 103). Oshore is a jurisdiction

    that produces a distance between the money and its ocial domicile: it allows

    modulating what moneys relation to space, to accountability, to obligation, to

    visibility is about.

    The distance that oshore constitutes to other jurisdictions does not only reside

    in the formality of being subjected to a dierent set of laws. The regulatory space

    itself is molded in a specic way: it grants money a specic anonymity through its

    privacy or secrecy laws and thus institutes a distance from the sources that

    money comes from. Switzerland is said to have invented this regulatory principle

    that puts the condentiality between a banker and his client on par with the

    relation between a patient and a doctor, while at the same time rendering it a crime

    to convey information to a third party. Monetary privacy turns into a key issue

    for constituting and contesting oshore (Palan 2003, 103; Donaghy 2002, 117).

    Interestingly, the very specic privacy granted to money turns money into the

    very anonymous medium that classical sociology assumed it to be in the rst

    place: money becomes through such laws what it supposedly was all along

    depersonalized and unmarked from any specic and restricted circulation (Zelizer

    1989). While the relation of ownership is absolutely secured, the relations to where

    money stems from, are loosened or hidden. The oshore nance industry proved

    so successful at repackaging debt and diusing risk that no one could be quite sure

    who owed what to whom (Sharman 2010, 2). It becomes almost impossible to

    locate the money as part of a relation, such as income earned, gain accrued, or

    revenue enforced.

    While these relations of revenue and return are at the heart of why money ows

    through the oshore-site after all it is about investments, gains, and keeping the

    gain these whereabouts are invisible. Money gains uidity and is channeled

    through the site of the oshore, regardless of where it comes from and where it goes

    to and if it is a gain or a loss, an obligation, or the undoing of an obligation. What

    oshore does and does not becomes visible if one takes into account that money

    belongs to relations of payment, as Bill Maurer (2007; 2008, 171) suggested, meaning

    that money belongs to a specic relation that determines obligations and returns.

    Putting it dierently, and using Vivianne Zelizers (1989) phrase, one might say,

    money is usually marked more than we expect. The oshore site makes it possible

    through its jurisdictional set-up and the secrecy to undo this marking or negotiate

    this marking. Money is channeled through a space that unmarks money from the

    relations it comes from and where it goes through.

    270 S. Opitz and U. Tellmann

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • The oshore site very much enhances moneys connectivity and anonymity

    through the complex enfolding of inside/outside relations that it is about. The

    imaginary of money as a pre-given ow does not account for how such global

    territories partake in constituting this ow (Tellmann 2011). Instead of taking the

    global ow of money as an analytical shortcut for understanding globalization, one

    is better advised to look at how this imaginary takes part in constituting what it

    describes. It is in this context instructive to take into view how the government of the

    Cayman Islands looks at non-resident money. One might say that the governmental

    agencies of the Cayman Islands treat money as such ow, insofar as they dispense

    with rendering money visible in terms of the relations that it stems from. They do not

    dierentiate according to the relations of income or gain that it enters into. While the

    nancial institutions that are domiciled at the Cayman Islands are there precisely

    because they use money as capital that is, for the pooling of investment funds, the

    combination of dierent investors and cross-border investment, the making of new

    breadths, depths, and amounts of investments and returns the Cayman Islands

    frame money like a cash ow that runs through its pipes. Accordingly, no taxes on

    salary or prot are due. As the Cayman Islands Government website states:

    Following the abolition in 1985 of an annual head tax of CI$10 on all adult maleresidents up to 60 years, there are no direct taxes in the Cayman Islands. There is noincome tax, company or corporation tax, inheritance tax, capital gains or gift tax.(Cayman Islands Government 2011b)

    The governmental revenue for the Cayman Islands comes instead from fees

    mainly: from customs on imported goods, from fees for working permits, from fees

    for company registration and licensing of banks and other nancial institutions, and

    from stamp duty on property. Hence, for using the Cayman Islands as a conduit for

    ones money and for employing those specialists and lawyers that handle this conduit

    one pays a fee but no taxes on prot. Money is not looked at as belonging to certain

    circuits of income, but treated as a pure and naked medium, like a ow of water.

    Fees are due for using the pipes.

    The oshore site for money is a construction that goes beyond the certainly

    important issue of tax evasion. It raises much broader issues of how money is

    constituted as a global ow, what kind of relation it is made to have, and which of

    them are visible to whom. While money is easily understood to have the quality of

    being de-territorialized and boundless just by itself, the foregoing discussion showed

    that this quality is produced by the recombinatory possibilities opened up through

    the oshore. Money is not everywhere the same. Its globality consists in a particular

    marking and unmarking of circulations; it is entailed by the specic visibility and

    invisibility of these relations. If oshore is the global economy (Maurer 2008, 160,

    emphasis in original), this quality might precisely reside in the particular

    recombination of ownership, liability, and visibility.

    Offshore processing and legal connectivity

    Just like money, law has been recently captured by the imaginary of globalism. This

    is in many ways surprising, given that law has been traditionally linked to the

    territory of the state and not to the image of the borderless world. According to the

    Westphalian model, national laws validity ends where the next states legal order

    claims its space. However, today a new form of global law is said to emerge,

    Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory 271

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • reaching beyond the connes of classical international law. Looking at the globe

    through conceptual prisms such as transnational law (Zumbansen 2012) or global

    constitutionalism (Peters 2009), dierent authors concur in the diagnosis of a

    general trend towards legal de-territorialization. Human rights law is a case in point:

    in sentencing crimes such as genocide or torture occurring anywhere on the globe,

    courts apply principles such as ius cogens (i.e. that certain norms are binding on all

    states) and erga omnes (i.e. that certain norms are owed to the entire world

    community) to instantiate laws borderless scope (Sassen 2008; de Wet 2006).

    Consequently, some legal scholars have fully abandoned the concept of territory in

    order to delineate a global law without the state (Fischer-Lescano and Teubner

    2004, 1008 f.). But even where territory is kept as a category, it is seen to be a

    remainder of a fading world order, somehow continuing to play a legal role, but with

    minor, diminished signicance (Raustiala 2006).

    It is against this background of successive legal de-territorialization and universal

    legal expansion that we would like to look at a specic case of oshore processing

    that seems at rst sight very dierent from the case of nancial oshore: the zoning

    strategies used for modulating the accessibility of basic rights for non-resident

    subjects in search of protection. Our case for exploring this specic type of oshore is

    the Australian immigration policy of the last decade. This policy had been adopted

    after a series of maritime refugee incidents in 2001 most notably the case of the MV

    Tampa, where 433 people rescued on the Norwegian container ship were blocked

    from disembarking on Australian land (Crock 2003). At the heart of the package of

    legislation that soon became known as the Pacic Strategy was the exemption of

    coastal areas from the Australian onshore in order to facilitate oshore processing of

    refugee claimants arriving by boat. In an amendment of the Migration Act 1958

    Australia declared parts of its territory to be excised oshore places. These places

    were legally split o from the migration zone as the Australian mainland was newly

    called. According to section 5 of the Act, to enter Australia means in relation to a

    person [. . . to] enter the migration zone. Conversely, to enter the excised places

    would mean to enter a zone that is not Australia. But where is this zone instead?

    Where does a person land who enters an excised place? And what does this place do

    with the person entering it?

    The two last-mentioned questions are, indeed, interconnected. The excision of

    oshore places coincided with the creation of a distinct legal persona: the oshore

    entry person who possessed limited rights in comparison to the regular onshore

    claimant. Whereas people who reach the migration zone were still allowed to apply

    for protection visa, unauthorized arrivals in the excised oshore places, sometimes

    only a few kilometers away from the mainland, were subjected to a dierent legal

    procedure. They could at best hope for the discretion of the Australian Minister for

    Immigration and Citizenship for allowing them to enter and apply for a visa, but it

    was not their unconditional right. Hence, the legally inferior status of the oshore

    entry person became intimately tied to the territorial creation of a paradoxical not-

    Australia, i.e. a place that is not exactly Australia but that, at the same time, does

    not belong to any other country (Budz 2009, 23). In fact, the excised territories

    entertain a rather vexed relation of inside/outside to the mainland. On the one hand,

    the act of legal excision makes them appear to be clearly separated from Australia.

    On the other hand, they remain tied to Australia not only because Australia used

    its territorial jurisdiction to create these zones, but also because persons that nd

    themselves in these territories were regarded as having trespassed onto Australian

    272 S. Opitz and U. Tellmann

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • territory without being entitled to do so, that is, without a valid visa. For this reason

    the Migration Act denes them in section 46A as unlawful non-citizens. This means

    that people who enter one of the 4891 islands (The Senate 2002, 13) that have been

    removed from the migration zone might be, in a certain sense, both physically

    present in Australia and, at the same time, legally absent (Basaran 2008, 345).

    The bifurcation between the paradoxical not-Australia and the main Australia

    was deepened by complementary regulation that allowed for sending applicants for

    asylum from the excised territories to a so-called declared country, where their

    claims were processed. In other words, they were shifted to a dierent jurisdiction.

    Australia signed a Memorandum of Understanding both with Nauru (not a

    signatory to the UN Refugee Convention and, interestingly, also a very shady

    nancial oshore place) and Papua New Guinea (a signatory, but subject to

    signicant reservations) in order to establish processing facilities for the refugee

    status determination. The oshore entry persons, thus, found themselves not simply

    only outside of the Australian migration zone, but in a camp within the borders of a

    former colony. While Australia provided nancial aid and police assistance to both

    countries and Australian immigration ocials conducted the refugee status

    determination, Australian law was not the basis of their procedures. Being in a

    declared country, the UNHCR processing regime was said to be applied, while the

    camps were run by the intergovernmental International Organization for Migration

    (IOM), itself not part of the UN System (Penovic and Dastyari 2007, 35, 51). Being

    o-the-shore from Australia, but not fully in another jurisdiction, the oshore entry

    persons were simply treated as if they were located in an overseas refugee camp

    (Basaran 2011, 97). This included, in particular, a lack of legal assistance and no

    provisions for judicial review of rejected asylum claims. Finally, even a successful

    refugee application did not entitle a claimant to settlement in Australia, with the

    consequence that recognized refugees were kept for lengthy periods, in some extreme

    cases for years, in detention.

    With a new government coming into power in 2007, the detention centers on

    Nauru and Papua New Guinea were closed down, and oshore processing has been

    redirected to the excised territories. Since 2002 around $400 million had been spent

    on building a high-tech detention facility on Christmas Island, which is run by the

    private contractor Global Solution Ltd and holds a capacity between 800 and 1,200

    people:

    It has electric fences and microwave probes for detecting movement; there are camerasystems posted under eaves, on roofs and in every room; and the whole camp is linkedby CCTV to a remote control room in Canberra. The detainees [. . .] wear electronicidentication tags which identify them wherever they are in the center by locatorbeacons. (Grewcock 2008, 364)1

    In 2008 the refugee status determination has been mainly transferred to the

    excised territory of Christmas Island which is legally designed as a space in-between:

    the determination process is supposed to be non-statutory but compliant with

    Australias international legal obligations.

    As Foster and Pobjoy (2011, 58999) outline in their extensive analysis, the

    oshore processing on Christmas Island constitutes a ghostly double of the

    counterparts on the mainland. Law itself becomes thereby equivocal. To begin with,

    neither the form of legal assistance available to oshore entry persons via the

    Immigration Advice and Application Assistance Scheme (IAAAS) nor the form of

    Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory 273

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • review oered by the Refugee Status Assessment Review Panel (RSARP) meets the

    standards established in the onshore system. Both the legal qualication and the

    independence of the providers are highly questionable. For example, IAAAS agents

    are not supposed to be lawyers, while reviewers do not necessarily hold a statuary

    oce. Moreover, denite and non-ambiguous criteria for decision-making are

    lacking. Immigration ocers and reviewers operate on the basis of draft Manuals

    that claim to provide only guidance, but no enforceable rules. Hence, although they

    refer to the Refugee Convention, UNHCR documents, the Australian Migration

    Act, and Australian case law, the norms laid down in these documents are not

    considered to be binding. Consequently, decision-making exhibits a highly

    discretionary character. In fact, the decisions by immigration ocers and reviewers

    ocially merely count as recommendations. For oshore entry persons being nally

    able to apply for (not: to receive) protection visas, they depend on a retroactive act of

    Ministerial discretion under section 46A of the Migration Act. This discretionary act

    is considered to be non-compellable and non-reviewable. Thus, the creation of

    oshore zones allow for normatively unrestrained and in this sense truly sovereign

    decision-making.

    One can clearly see from this brief reconstruction that Australian immigration

    policy has relied upon a complex set of territorial operations of zoning during the

    last decade. For understanding the production of excised territory one has rst to

    acknowledge how this territory works within, between, and against existing

    territorial frames (Elden 2009, xx; Vaughan-Williams 2008). One has to address,

    just as in the case of nancial oshore centers, the complex layering of inside/

    outside. The excised territory confuses the distinction between the modern world

    order of territorial segments and its contemporary, mostly liberal counter-vision of a

    de-territorialized new world order with disaggregating sovereignty (Slaughter

    2004). Such a distinction leaves no space for conceptualizing the territorial folding

    that turns the inside out but keeps it within its reach which is exactly the

    topological twist performed by the oshore territory. Furthermore, what might seem

    as an anomaly both within a Westphalian and a post-Westphalian frame could in

    fact be a paradigmatic phenomenon of the present logics of territory that nd their

    visible expression in the proliferation of dierent types of zones. As a space in-

    between, oshore simultaneously constitutes and secures a zone of legal ambiguities

    (Basaran 2011, 102). The territorial enclosure gives way to blurred responsibilities, a

    lack of binding criteria, and discretionary powers that deny the protection of law to

    the subject.

    Just as the nancial oshore changes the type of relation that money enters into,

    the territorial construction of the oshore zone for processing refugee claims is about

    a changed and modulated relation of the subject to law. Usually, at least within the

    liberal framework, the connection between subject and law is paradigmatically

    enshrined in the possibility to appeal to a court and in the guarantee of due process.

    Oshoring subjects to remote and dierential regulatory spaces challenges this

    relation. The territorial strategy of oshoring diminishes the access to the circuits of

    legal connectivity by both physical and legal means (Opitz 2012, 129). It restricts

    access to rights through restricting the opportunities for articulating a legal claim. To

    use a spatial metaphor, the territorial strategy distances the subject from the legal

    centers. At the same time, it also executes a partition of the legal sphere. In allowing

    for connections to administrative processes designed to comply with abridged forms

    of refugee law, it disconnects at the same time from more substantial legal

    274 S. Opitz and U. Tellmann

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • provisions. The global law is in this case a weakened and ambiguous execution

    of global conventions, with extremely limited possibilities to hold this executive

    accountable in practice. In the case of oshore processing, territory, thus, constitutes

    a legal technology for modulating the relation between subjects and law in a deeply

    restrictive manner. It results in producing a subject that is physically abducted,

    exposed to an executive power that is only loosely bound by its legal obligations,

    while the subject is lacking substantive means to appeal to a law that might hold

    these powers accountable.

    This analysis clearly demonstrates that the widespread metaphors of the legal

    hole or the ban as well as the vocabulary of legal exceptionalism do not fully

    capture the complexity of the territorial strategy (Johns 2005). First and foremost,

    a lot of legal reasoning and legal expertise has owed into the construction of the

    oshore territory. In this sense, oshore places are places not emptied of but

    suused with law. Moreover, even though explicit strategies of judicial exemption

    and territorial division are involved, these strategies of fragmentation do not

    produce clear-cut boundaries. As Eyal Weizman (2007, 4) has remarked in a

    dierent context, the territories of eective control currently become fragmented,

    dynamic, and thus unchartable by conventional mapping techniques. At the same,

    the elasticity and ambiguity of these spaces also allow for contestation. Australia,

    to begin with, has never denied its international legal obligations. Unsurprisingly,

    competing interpretations of international law and especially human rights law

    have soon emerged, together with the competing evaluation of Australias state

    practice as illegal (Doussa 2007). Furthermore, the relocation of the oshore

    processing from third countries to excised territories has brought refugee status

    determination closer to constitutional litigation. The struggles about these

    territorial zones are on-going.2

    In any case, territory itself plays an active role for how these contestations will

    unfold. Territorial strategies rely on the remoteness and inaccessibility of the

    location of these zones. Christmas Island is so small and secluded that it is certainly

    out of sight. A 17-year-old boy from Afghanistan who has been detained on the

    island puts it as follows: When we studied geography our teachers never showed us

    Christmas Island [. . .] if we look at a world map, Christmas Island is hiding in the

    map. Its so small (cited in Chambers 2011, 19). Geography itself oers a veil of

    secrecy, since the territorial enclosure controls both people entering and people

    leaving. Restraining access to law is coupled with restraining movements across

    territorial borders (Brighenti 2010a). Hence, oshores are technologies to shield a

    certain conguration of legal connectivity from the permanently on-going struggle

    for law. How far the dream of a global cosmopolitan law will come true depends on

    such struggles. But the global will never be about a law that exists beyond territory.

    Instead, it revolves around the question about who will be able to achieve legal

    presence and political voice in particular situations by particular means. If the

    oshore is the global, then this quality might lie for both cases precisely in the

    particular recombination of space, obligation, and visibility.

    Conclusion the zone as a global form

    Christmas Island and the Cayman Islands are both juridico-political zones that

    disrupt the conventions of the Westphalian model of political territory. They are

    jurisdictions of a specic sort. Trying to come to grips with the phenomenon of

    Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory 275

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • nancial oshore site, the IMF denes with surprising acuity such jurisdictions as a

    territorial entity that is not a country or a state as commonly understood by

    international law and practice but an overseas territory under the sovereignty of

    another state (typically a former colony or dependency) or an enclave (2007, 4).

    As such they deploy territoriality in a way that dees the mapping strategies of the

    Westphalian world, without necessarily dissolving national space. They are post-

    Westphalian, if one understands, as Wendy Brown has suggested, the prex post as

    signaling a very particular condition of afterness in which what is past is not left

    behind, but gives way to a present that nevertheless also breaks in some way with

    this past (Brown 2010, 21). Zones exist in the interstices of this system and act as

    laboratories for recalibrating what legal and monetary relations are about and how

    they are tied to political space. Territory is in both cases a crucial political

    technology, but its role shifts. Territoriality works in one case to weaken legal

    protection and in the other case to strengthen it. The zone is in one case about

    enhancing moneys uidity and recombinatory powers and in the other case

    about undoing the possibilities of subjects to negotiate their legitimate modes of

    movement.

    Even though the oshore zones that we have compared are very dierent in their

    eects and purpose, they both exhibit a structural analogy. The analysis presented

    above has sought to lay bare such common structure. This commonality consists in

    three dimensions: a complex enfolding of the inside with the outside, a bifurcation

    between physical and legal presence, and a politics of visibility. In this conclusion, we

    want to discuss these three dimensions in a comparative fashion. We want to clarify

    in which ways we can talk about the oshore zone as a global form, meaning that

    we have to specify both what its form is and in which sense it is global.

    It is striking to see that the operations of unmarking of money and unmarking of

    bodies as rights holders are procedures that both rely on installing a discontinuity of

    legal and physical presence.3 Palan (2003, 106) has noted for the case of economic

    oshores that oshore starts with questioning the legal unity of the subject, hence

    allowing the separation of physical presence and the dierential interpretation of

    legal presence. But the meaning of this separation diers widely if we compare

    nancial oshores with oshores for processing refugee claims. In the one case,

    money is legally present in these places, but physically absent. Moneys legal

    presence is clearly circumscribed and dened. The legal address, so to speak, of the

    monetary account in the jurisdiction allows the relation of ownership to be secured

    and clearly denes the courts and procedures of appeal. For subjects brought to the

    oshore processing zone, the opposite holds true. They are physically present at the

    oshore, forcefully brought there and bound by techniques of incarceration, while

    their legal presence is far from unequivocal. If the term virtual applies, it does less

    so to money with its clearly dened and protected legal oshore address than to the

    oshore entry person who nds herself confronted with an ambiguous set of rules

    and the inability to appeal properly to the courts or communicate with lawyers. The

    subject is bound to space while unhinged from appealing to law in a guaranteed and

    reliable way. While nancial oshores amplify the connectivity of money, asylum-

    processing oshores stall legal connectivity. Splitting the legal and physical presence

    can have opposite eects, depending on at which end one nds oneself.

    Each of the oshore territories is dened by peculiar inside/outside relations. The

    inside/outside relation between onshore and oshore is refracted. In the case of

    oshore nance, it is remarkable that oshore places often emerge in former colonies

    276 S. Opitz and U. Tellmann

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • and dependent territories. These are not completely independent and sovereign

    states. The Cayman Islands bind their sovereign powers to make law to a long

    tradition of common law of the British Empire. By undoing full sovereignty, the

    restrictions of common law are enhanced. Territorial jurisdictions are here safe

    havens of legal procedures, oering a place from where monetary connectivity can

    safely be sought. The opposite is true for the subjects that nd themselves in the

    territorial enclaves of oshore asylum procedures. They are captured in territorial

    connes that also have a refracted relation to territorial sovereignty. But this

    time such refracted relation does not enhance the guarantees of legal procedure; it

    does not bind sovereign discretion. On the contrary, being outside of Australias

    jurisdiction means here to be within the reach of executive power but outside of the

    full domain of rights. In this territory that is neither inside nor outside of the

    sovereign state, the law ceases to work as a means of guaranteeing protection,

    oering anything but a safe haven to the subject in its reach.

    As we have argued before, territory is more than a geographical and even more

    than a juridical construct. The case of oshore zones makes that abundantly clear.

    While being about both geography and legal technique, they are also prominently

    tied to a modulation of visibility and invisibility. In the case of monetary oshores

    the issue of visibility is of highest concern. It is part of constructing the boundaries of

    this territory: the oshore is a truly protected zone, only insofar as the privacy of

    monetary relations is guaranteed by a penal code and hence ensured against any

    curiosity from the outside. It only fullls its functions in the circulation of money

    because it links territory to such informational protection. Struggles to penetrate this

    invisibility and protect it signal the importance of secrecy. Secrecy allows enhancing

    moneys potentiality for disconnecting from the marked circulations it stems from. It

    turns money into an anonymous medium that is unmarked and hence multiplies its

    connectivity. Visibility implies traceability: it enables one to link money to the

    circulations it stems from and is obliged to.

    For the case of asylum-processing oshores, visibility and invisibility have a

    similar eect but are dierently produced. Whereas the invisibility of money is

    constituted by a legal code, the invisibility of the refugee as a legal subject is a by-

    product of the geographical territory itself. Far away from the mainland on an island

    that is not even on every map of the world, the geographical location of this territory

    makes sure that those incarcerated are out of sight. Political strategies to undo such

    invisibility usually consist in using social media to produce visibility that is otherwise

    suppressed. However, the territorial distancing also complicates such political

    counter-strategies (Bailey 2011). For money as for these subjects, the invisibility

    undercuts the problematization of political accountability and responsibility. The

    means and ways of executive power that are shielded from public scrutiny and legal

    control have always been regarded as a threat to democracy. In this sense, the

    oshore can be linked to the general rise of government secrecy that is tied to

    making the global dimension within the state, as Saskia Sassen has argued (2006,

    179).

    However, the very distribution of what is private and secret takes dierent forms.

    For the case of money, the privacy of its whereabouts is granted, whereas non-

    resident subjects are exposed to governmental scrutiny and the executive power is

    not. Looking at this rather dierent use to which the construction of the zone is put,

    this comparison nevertheless brings out the odd commonality of its form. Across all

    dierences, there seems to be a tendency to assort secrecy and privacy in a way that

    Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory 277

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • shifts the role of law away from being an instrument of democratic protection and

    contestation. The zone, it seems, is a modulator. It shifts accountability and

    visibility, it re-arranges the relations between inside and outside, it organizes

    monetary and legal dis/connectivity. It enhances or stalls the recombinatory powers

    of money, it frames who can connect to legal protection, it changes the type of

    relation that money and law have to political space. The zone is about relations and

    the access to them: that between subjects and law, between money and marked

    circulation, between executive power and democratic control, between spaces of

    control and political contestation. Is the global anything but such modulation?

    The zone, thus, belongs in specic ways to the forging of global connectivities. As

    Jonathan Bach has noted, the zone is a liminal space insofar as it functions as key

    node [ . . . in a] materially heterogeneous network a network that generates a

    particular depiction of space emerging from an interaction between linear spaces and

    network spaces (Bach 2011, 115). But how are we to understand this interaction? If

    we frame this interaction in terms of global ows that are larger in scale than these

    territorial hubs and that hit these spaces from the outside, one already deploys a

    certain understanding of the global in terms of scale and uidity. While the

    metaphors of uidity, ow, and oods sweeping the globe as a territorial unit are

    conspicuously present when issues of globalization are discussed be it in terms of

    nancial tsunamis, oods of immigrants, or the slippery nature of money in general

    these metaphors should not unconsciously delimit the analytical imagination. The

    comparative analysis of the zone as a specic territorial form allows us to go beyond

    this globalist imaginary. The global might be less a scale larger than a territorial

    space but consists of types of relations and recombinations of relations: who and

    what is allowed to recombine and gain speed and uidity; what forms of

    accountability are put into practice; and what types of enfolding between the inside

    and the outside enhance or diminish the control of executive power all these aspects

    are modulated in the zone, but the zone does not predetermine what kind of

    modulation will take place.

    Notes

    1. For further details see also the entry on the website of the Global Detention Project:http://www.globaldetentionproject.org/countries/asia-pacic/australia/introduction.html.

    2. By the end of 2010 the High Court rejected the view held by the government that oshoreprocessing on Christmas Island was non-statutory. The government reaction has beentwofold: On the one hand, it declared its intention to continue oshore processing onexcised territories, yet promised to introduce some procedural changes in compliance withthe courts decision. On the other hand, plans about a new regional solution resurfaced,this time including arrangements with Malaysia.

    3. This phrase stems from one our anonymous reviewers. We found it so apt and beautifullyrendered that we allow ourselves to use it even though we can only acknowledge theauthor anonymously.

    Notes on contributors

    Sven Opitz (Dr.) is lecturer in sociology at the University of Hamburg. He teaches socialtheory with a focus on the linkages between classical sociologies and post-structuralistapproaches. In his research he investigates the intersections of law and security, combiningsystems theorys process ontology with de- and post-constructivist approaches. His currentresearch explores processes of norm generation in emergencies and logics of epidemiccontagion as a mode of connectivity. Recent publications include: An der Grenze des Rechts:Inklusion/Exklusion im Zeichen der Sicherheit (Velbruck 2012), and Government unlimited:

    278 S. Opitz and U. Tellmann

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • The security dispositif of illiberal governmentality in Governmentality: Current Issues andFuture Challenges, ed. U. Brockling, S. Krasmann, and T. Lemke (Routledge 2011).

    Ute Tellmann (PhD) is currently Lecturer in Sociology at the University of Hamburg. Sheteaches social theory and political theory with a focus on cultural economy and historicalepistemology. Her research addresses the cultural and political underpinnings of economicdiscourses, economic temporality, and collectivity. She is currently working on the question ofdebt and infrastructure as a hybrid economic connectivity. Most recent publications includeCatastrophic populations and the fear of the future: Malthus and the genealogy of liberaleconomy in Theory, Culture, Society (forthcoming).

    References

    Agamben, G. 1998. Homo sacer: Sovereign power and bare life. Stanford: Stanford UniversityPress.

    Agamben, G. 2005. State of exception. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Agnew, J. 1994. The territorial trap: The geographical assumptions of international relations

    theory. Review of International Political Economy 1, no. 1: 5380.Amin, A., D. Massey, and N. Thrift. 2003. Decentering the national: A radical approach to

    regional inequality. London: Catalyst.Bach, J. 2011. Modernity and the urban imagination in economic zones. Theory, Culture &

    Society 28, no. 5: 98122.Bailey, R. 2011. Transitory persons, precarious lives: Irregular migrants in Australian law.

    Critical Legal Thinking Law & the Political. http://www.criticallegalthinking.com.Baker, R. 2005. Capitalisms Achilles heel. Dirty money and how to renew the free-market

    system. Hoboken: John Wiley.Basaran, T. 2008. Security, law, borders: Spaces of exclusion. International Political Sociology

    2, no. 4: 33954.Basaran, T. 2011. Security, law and borders. At the limits of liberties. London: Routledge.Brenner, N. 1999a. Beyond state-centrism? Space, territoriality, and geographical scale in

    globalization studies. Theory and Society 28, no. 1: 3978.Brenner, N. 1999b. Globalisation as reterritorialisation. The re-scaling of urban governance in

    the European Union. Urban Studies 36, no. 3: 43151.Brighenti, A.M. 2010a. Lines, barred lines. Movement, territory and the law. International

    Journal of Law in Context 6, no. 3: 21727.Brighenti, A.M. 2010b. On territorology. Towards a general science of territory. Theory,

    Culture & Society 29, no. 2: 5272.Brown, W. 2010. Walled states, waning sovereignty. New York: Zone Books.Budz, M. 2009. A heterotopian analysis of maritime refugee incidents. International Political

    Sociology 3, no. 1: 1835.Castells, M. 1996. The information age I. The rise of the network society. Oxford: Blackwell.Cayman Islands Government. 2011a. 2010 Compendium of Statistics. Grand Cayman:

    Economics and Statistics Oce. http://www.eso.ky/docum1/docum137.pdf.Cayman Islands Government. 2011b. About Cayman. Taxes. http://www.gov.ky/portal/

    page?_pageid1142,1481212&_dadportal&_schema PORTAL.Cayman Islands Government. 2012. Special economic zones law (Law 22 of 2011) 2011.

    Supplement no. 4 published with extraordinary gazette no. 10, dated 31 January 2012.Chambers, P. 2011. Society has been defended: Following the shifting shape of state through

    Australias Christmas Island. International Political Sociology 5, no. 1: 1834.Clark, G.L. 2005. Money ows like mercury. The geography of global nance. Geograska

    Annaler 87, B: 99112.Collier, S. 2006. Global assemblages. Theory, Culture & Society 23, nos. 78: 399401.Crock, M. 2003. In the wake of the Tampa: Conicting visions of International Refugee Law

    in the management of refugee ows. Pacic Rim Journal of Law & Policy 12, no. 1: 4995.De Wet, E. 2006. The international constitutional order. International and Comparative Law

    Quarterly 55, no. 1: 5176.Delaney, D. 2005. Territory a short introduction. Malden: Blackwell.Deleuze, G. 1992. Postscript on the societies of control. October 59, no. 4: 17.

    Distinktion: Scandinavian Journal of Social Theory 279

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • Deleuze, G. 2003. Francis Bacon: The logic of sensation. London: Continuum.Donaghy, M. 2002. Monetary privacy in the information economy. Bank condentiality in

    Monaco. International Sociology 17, no. 1: 11333.Doussa, J.v. 2007. Human rights and oshore processing. UTS Law Review 41, no. 1: 4156.Easterling, K. 2007. Enduring innocence. Global architecture and its political masquerades.

    Cambridge: MIT Press.Easterling, K. 2008. Zone. In Urban transformation, ed. A. Ruby and I. Ruby, 3045. Berlin:

    Ruby Press.Elden, S. 2005. Missing the point: Globalisation, deterritorialization and the space of the

    world. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers 30, no. 1: 819.Elden, S. 2007. Governmentality, calculation, territory. Environment and Planning D 25, no. 3:

    56280.Elden, S. 2009. Terror and territory: The spatial extent of sovereignty. Minneapolis: University

    of Minnesota Press.Elden, S. 2010. Land, terrain, territory. Progress in Human Geography 34, no. 6: 799817.Ferguson, J. 2006. Global shadows. Africa in the neoliberal world order. Durham: Duke

    University Press.Fischer-Lescano, A., and G. Teubner. 2004. Regime-collisions: The vain search for legal

    unity in the fragmentation of global law. Michigan Journal of International Law 29, no. 4:9991046.

    Foster, M., and J. Pobjoy. 2011. A failed case of legal exceptionalism? Refugee statusdetermination in Australias excised territory. International Journal of Refugee Law 23,no. 4: 583631.

    Foucault, M. 2007. Security, territory, population. Lectures at the Colle`ge de France 19771978. New York: Palgrave.

    Foucault, M. 2008. The birth of biopolitics. Lectures at the Colle`ge de France 19781979. NewYork: Palgrave.

    Galli, C. 2010. Political spaces and global war. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.GAO (United States Government Accountability Oce) 2008. Cayman Islands. Business

    and tax advantages attract U.S. persons and enforcement challenges exist. GAO-08-778: 157.

    Grewcock, M. 2008. Systems of exclusion: The Rudd government and the end of the Pacicsolution. Current Issues in Criminal Justice 19, no. 3: 3638.

    Hardt, M., and A. Negri. 2000. Empire. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Hudson, A. 1996. Globalization, regulation and geography: The development of the Bahamas

    and the Cayman Islands oshore nancial centres. A dissertation submitted for the degreeof doctor of philosophy at the Department of Geography, University of Cambridge,Sidney Sussex College. Unpublished manuscript.

    Hudson, A. 1998. Placing trust, trusting place: On the social construction of oshore nancialcentres. Political Geography 17, no. 8: 91537.

    IMF.2006.Oshore nancial centers.The assessment programaprogress report.PreparedbyTheMonetary and Financial Systems Department and approved by Ulrich Baumgartner: 119.

    IMF. 2007. Concept of oshore nancial centers: In search of an operational denition. Workingpaper. Prepared and authorized by A. Zorome and B. Johnston. WP/07/87: 134.

    Jazeel, T. 2011. Spatializing dierence beyond cosmopolitanism: Rethinking planetary futures.Theory, Culture & Society 28, no. 5: 7597.

    Jessop, B., N. Brenner, and M. Jones. 2008. Theorizing socio-spatial relations. Environmentand Planning D 26, no. 3: 389401.

    Johns, F. 2005. Guantanamo Bay and the annihilation of exception. The European Journal ofInternational Law 16, no. 4: 61335.

    Jones, M. 2009. Phase space. Geography, relational thinking, and beyond. Progress in HumanGeography 33, no. 4: 487506.

    Law, J. 2004. And if the global were small and noncoherent? Method, complexity, and theBaroque. Environment and Planning D 22, no. 1: 1326.

    Leyshon, A., and N. Thrift. 1997. Money/space. Geographies of monetary transformation.London: Routledge.

    Maurer, B. 2001. Islands in the net: Rewiring technological and nancial circuits in the oshoreCaribbean. Society for Comparative Study of Society and History 43, no. 3: 467501.

    280 S. Opitz and U. Tellmann

    Dow

    nloa

    ded

    by [U

    nivers

    ity of

    Ham

    burg

    ] at 0

    5:28 1

    3 Dec

    embe

    r 201

    2

  • Maurer, B. 2007. Incalculable payments: Money, scale, and the South African oshore greymoney amnesty. African Studies Review 50, no. 2: 12538.

    Maurer, B. 2008. Re-regulating oshore nance. Geography Compass 2, no. 1: 15575.Moodys Investor Service. 2010. Credit opinion: Cayman Islands, Government of. Global

    credit research. http://www.gov.ky/pls/portal/docs/PAGE/CIGHOME/FIND/ORGANISATIONS/AZAGENCIES/TSY/DOCUMENTS/152269%20RESEARCHDOCUMENT.PDF.

    Moyn, S. 2010. The last Utopia. Human rights in history. Cambridge: Harvard UniversityPress.

    OBrien, R. 1992. Global nancial regulation. The end of geography. London: Pinter.Ong, A. 2006. Neoliberalism as exception. Mutations in citizenship and sovereignty. Durham:

    Duke University Press.Ong, A., and S. Collier, eds. 2004. Global assemblages. Technology, politics, and the ethics of

    anthropological problems. Malden: Blackwell.Onishi, N. 2009. Australia puts its refugee problem on a remote island, behind razor wire. The

    New York Times, November 4. http://www.nytimes.com/2009/11/05/world/asia/05island.html?pagewanted all.

    Opitz, S. 2011. Government unlimited: The security dispositif of illiberal governmentality. InGovernmentality: Current issues and future challenges, ed. U. Brockling, S. Krasmann, andT. Lemke. 93114. New York: Routledge.

    Opitz, S. 2012. An der Grenze des Rechts: Inklusion/Exklusion im Zeichen der Sicherheit.Weilerswist: Velbruck.

    Paasi, A. 1998. Boundaries as social processes: Territoriality in the world of ows. Geopolitics3, no. 1: 6988.

    Paasi, A. 2003. Territory. In A companion to political geography, ed. J. Agnew, 10922.Malden: Blackwell.

    Painter, J. 2010. Rethinking territory. Antipode 42, no. 5: 10901118.Palan, R. 2003. The oshore world: Sovereign markets, virtual places, and nomad millionaires.

    Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Penovic, T., and A. Dastyari. 2007. Boatloads of incongruity: The evolution of Australias

    oshore processing regime. Australian Journal of Human Rights 13, no. 1: 3361.Peters, A. 2009. The merits of global constitutionalism. Indiana Journal of Global Legal Studies

    16, no. 2: 397411.Picciotto, S. 1999. Oshore: The state as legal ction. In Oshore nance centres and tax

    havens. The rise of global capital, ed. M. Hampton and J. Abbott, 4379. London:Macmillan.

    Pryke, M. 1991. An international city going global: Spatial change in the City of London.Environment and Planning D: Society and Space 9, no. 2: 197222.

    Pryke, M. 2006. Speculating on geographies of nance. University of Manchester/OU CRESCWP Series Theme 1, WP 24: 126.

    Raustiala, K. 2006. The evolution of territoriality: I