mobility and labour market outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/fulltext01.pdflabour mobility into...

55
Employment in New Firms: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes Gulzat Zhetibaeva Elvung Doctoral Thesis 2016 Division of Economics Department of Industrial Economics and Management School of Industrial Engineering and Management KTH Royal Institute of Technology Stockholm, Sweden

Upload: others

Post on 18-Oct-2019

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

Employment in New Firms: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes

Gulzat Zhetibaeva Elvung

Doctoral Thesis 2016

Division of Economics

Department of Industrial Economics and Management

School of Industrial Engineering and Management

KTH Royal Institute of Technology

Stockholm, Sweden

Page 2: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

TRITA IEO-R 2016:10

ISSN 1100-7982

ISRN KTH/IEO/R-16:10-SE

ISBN 978-91-7729-099-5

©Gulzat Zhetibaeva Elvung 2016

[email protected]

This doctoral thesis, with the approval of KTH in Stockholm, will be presented to

public examination for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy, on Wednesday, 5th of

October, at 10:00 in Room F3, KTH, Lindstedtsvägen 26, Stockholm.

Printed in Sweden, Universitetsservice US-AB

Page 3: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

Abstract

This thesis studies the role of new firms in the labour market and

uses Swedish data to analyze labour mobility in new firms,

including both transitions of workers into and from new firms. In

particular, it focuses on employees’ wages in new firms and post-

new firm employment labour market outcomes as transitions into

long-term employment and entrepreneurship.

This thesis consists of four essays. The first two essays concern

labour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-

new firm employment mobility.

The first essay explores the role of new firms as an entry point

into the labour market for individuals with little (or no) labour

market experience. The findings show that the wage penalty found

in previous research, which includes more heterogeneous groups

of employees, decreases once the focus is solely on labour market

entrants.

The second essay investigates whether there is a wage penalty

for being employed at a new firm if the individual employee’s

experience and status in the labour market are taken into account;

this essay focuses on individuals who decide to switch jobs. The

findings show that there is a wage penalty for being employed at a

new firm; however, considering a random selection into new firms

may underestimate the wage differentials.

The third essay studies the role that new firms play for the

career path of their employees. In particular, this paper analyzes

whether short-term employment in new firms (employment lasting

less than one year) may serve as a stepping stone toward long-term

employment (at least two years of employment with the same

employer) for non-employed individuals. The findings indicate

that short-term employment in new firms may serve as a stepping

stone toward long-term employment.

Page 4: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

The fourth paper examines the new firm effect on

entrepreneurship, which the findings indicate is positive and

statistically significant; this effect remains even after controlling

for a worker's ability and shows that employees with both high and

low levels of ability may transition to entrepreneurship.

Keywords

New firms, labour market entrants, wage penalty, job switchers,

employment, long-term employment, stepping stone hypothesis,

entrepreneurship, self-employment.

JEL-codes

E24; J21; J31; J62; L26; M13

Page 5: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

Sammanfattning

Denna avhandling studerar betydelsen av nya företag för

arbetsmarknaden och använder svensk data för att analysera

arbetskraftens rörlighet till och från nya företag. Framförallt

fokuserar avhandlingen på de anställdas löner i nya företag samt

deras fortsatta karriär på arbetsmarknaden i form av övergång till

långsiktig sysselsättning och entreprenörskap.

Denna avhandling består av fyra uppsatser. De två första

uppsatserna berör arbetskraftens rörlighet till nya företag. De sista

två uppsatserna fokuserar på rörlighet efter att anställningen i det

nya företaget avslutats.

Den första uppsatsen undersöker betydelsen av nya företag för

inträde på arbetsmarknaden för personer med liten (eller ingen)

arbetsmarknadserfarenhet. Tidigare forskning, baserad på mer

heterogena grupper av anställda, visar att nya företag tenderar att

betala lägre löner. Resultaten i denna studie visar att denna

löneskillnad är lägre när man jämför lönerna för enbart för

anställda som gör sitt inträde på arbetsmarknaden.

Den andra uppsatsen undersöker om lönen för anställda i ett

nytt företag är lägre om den enskilde medarbetarens erfarenhet

och status på arbetsmarknaden beaktas. Denna uppsats fokuserar

på individer som väljer att byta jobb. Resultaten visar att lönerna

för anställda i ett nytt företag är lägre. Om ett slumpmässigt urval

beaktas kan löneskillnaderna underskattas.

Den tredje uppsatsen studerar vilken roll nya företag spelar för

de anställdas fortsatta karriär. Mer specifikt studeras om en

kortare tids anställning i ett nytt företag (sysselsättning som varar

mindre än ett år) kan fungera som en språngbräda till en långsiktig

sysselsättning (minst två års anställning hos samma arbetsgivare)

för personer som inte har någon anställning. Resultaten tyder på

att kort tids anställning i ett nytt företag kan vara en språngbräda

mot en mer långsiktig sysselsättning.

Page 6: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

Den fjärde uppsatsen undersöker om anställning i ett nytt

företag ökar sannolikheten att bli entreprenör. Resultaten visar

på en positiv och statistiskt signifikans effekt. Denna effekt

kvarstår även efter vi kontrollerar för arbetstagarens förmåga och

visar att anställda med både hög och låg förmåga blir

entreprenörer efter sin anställning i ett nytt företag.

Nyckelord

Nya företag, inträde på arbetsmarknaden, löneskillnader,

jobbytare, sysselsättning, långsiktig sysselsättning, språngbräda på

arbetsmarknaden, entreprenörskap, egenföretagande.

JEL-kod

E24; J21; J31; J62; L26; M13

Page 7: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

Acknowledgements

Today is the day, after an intensive period of several years, full of

learning and experience, finishing my PhD thesis and writing this

note of thanks to all who in one way or another have contributed to

the completion of the thesis work.

Foremost, I would like to express my deepest gratitude to my

supervisor Kristina Nyström for her patient guidance,

encouragement and constant support throughout my PhD studies.

Her willingness to give her time and advice so generously has been

very much appreciated. She has been a great mentor for me.

Kristina is also the co-author of two essays included in this thesis.

Also, I would like to offer my special thanks to my co-supervisor

Anders Broström for his support and valuable advices.

My special thanks go to the discussant of my thesis at the final

seminar, Pernilla Andersson Joona from the Swedish Institute for

Social Research, Stockholm University, for providing valuable and

constructive comments and suggestions which contributed to the

improvement of the quality of the thesis. I also want to thank my

colleagues Hans Lööf, for reviewing the manuscript at its final

stage, and Gregg Vanourek for giving advice on language matters.

Valuable comments on the second essay of the thesis given by

Michael S. Dahl from Aarhus University in Denmark has been a

great help.

My special thanks are extended to all my present and past

colleagues and fellow PhD students at the Divisions of Economics,

and Entrepreneurship and Innovation for providing not only a

professional support but a pleasant and friendly work environment.

I thank my friends and colleagues Monia, Pardis and Ingrid for

their companionship, friendship and time taken to discuss

different issues related to the thesis work.

The completion of the thesis would not have been possible

without encouragement and support from my family. I am

Page 8: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

indebted to my father Toktomush and mother Aliman for their love

and unconditional support throughout my life. Also, I am grateful

to my brothers and sisters for their moral support and always

believing in me. Finally, I would like to express appreciation to my

beloved husband Claes for his love and constant support, and to

my son Henning for being a source of inspiration and joy.

Thank you very much everyone!

Stockholm, August 2016 Gulzat Zhetibaeva Elvung

Page 9: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

List of appended papers

Paper I

Nyström, K. and Zhetibaeva Elvung, G. (2014), New firms and labor market entrants: Is there a wage penalty for employment in new firms? Small Business Economics, 43:399–410.

Paper II

Nyström, K. and Zhetibaeva Elvung, G. (2015), New firms as

employers: The wage penalty for voluntary and involuntary job

switchers, LABOUR, 29 (4): 348–366.

Paper III

Zhetibaeva Elvung, G. The effect of employment in new firms on a career path: Is it a stepping stone toward long-term employment?

Paper IV

Zhetibaeva Elvung, G. The new firm effect on entrepreneurship.

Page 10: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first
Page 11: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

Table of contents

1. Introduction ................................................................... 13

2. The role of new firms in the economy ......................... 15

2.1 New firms as employers ............................................................. 15

2. 2 New firms and their employees in Sweden ............................. 17

3. Economic theory on labour market outcomes ........... 25

3.1 Search and matching theory ...................................................... 25

3.2 Stepping stone-hypothesis ........................................................ 27

3.3 The new firm effect on entrepreneurship ................................. 28

4. Previous empirical literature ........................................ 30

4.1 Employment in new firms ........................................................... 30

4.2 Wage differentials in new firms and post new firm-employment

labour market outcomes .................................................................. 31

5. Data ................................................................................ 35

5.1 Unique Swedish data .................................................................. 35

5.2 Data for the analysis ................................................................... 36

6. Defining new firms and measuring labour market

outcomes ........................................................................... 37

6.1 New firms ..................................................................................... 37

6.2 Labour market outcomes ........................................................... 38

7. Outline of the study and summary of the main findings

............................................................................................ 39

7.1 Essay 1. New firms and labor market entrants: Is there a wage

penalty for employment in new firms? ........................................... 40

7.2 Essay 2. New firms as employers: The wage penalty for

voluntary and involuntary job switchers ........................................ 41

Page 12: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

7.3 Essay 3. The effect of employment in new firms on a career

path: Is it a stepping stone toward long-term employment? ........ 42

7.4 Essay 4. The new firm effect on entrepreneurship .................. 44

8 Conclusions and suggestions for future research ...... 46

References ......................................................................... 49

Page 13: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

13

1. Introduction

This thesis is motivated by the ongoing debate about the

importance of new firms in the economy, and studies the role of

new firms as employers in the labour market by focusing on

mobility of new firm employees and their labour market outcomes.

It consists of two parts, a cover essay and four appended essays

that aim to contribute to the discussion and empirical literature on

the role of new firms in the labour market.

The significance of entrepreneurship as an economic engine of

growth is emphasized in the creation of new jobs that contribute to

aggregate employment growth. A popular perception about small

businesses creating the most private sector jobs supported by early

research (see e.g. Birch 1981) has changed following by new

insights on the job creation power of firms (Haltiwanger et al.

2013)1. Although small and medium-sized businesses account for

majority of gross job creation, a closer look at the age profile of

firms reveals a different picture. For instance, as Criscuolo et al.

(2014) find in OECD2 countries, not all small businesses are net job

creators, but only young businesses create a disproportionate

number of jobs. Similarly, Haltiwanger et al. (2013) find that job

creation is negatively associated with firms’ age and conclude that

the firm age effect, rather than its size, is very important for

understanding entrepreneurship and for policies aimed at

fostering entrepreneurship. Hence, in regard to job-creating power,

the relevance of the age profile of small businesses is important; it

is not the size of the business that matters as much as the firm age.

Given the importance for economic development the

phenomenon of entrepreneurship has attracted considerable

1 See Haltiwanger et al. (2013) for a detailed discussion. 2The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

Page 14: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

14

interest among policymakers and researchers, which has led to

research in the field from different levels and perspectives;

research has focused on questions such as determinants of new

firm formation, their role in economic dynamics and policies

stimulating new firm formation (see e.g. Ferris and Voia 2012,

Thai and Turkina 2013, Valdez and Richardson 2013, Barreneche

García 2014).

On the other hand, there is an ongoing debate about the role of

new firms in the labour market with respect to the quality of the

jobs they provide (e.g. Shane 2009), as well as their role as

employers of individuals they decide to hire (see e.g. Nyström

2011). Most of new jobs created by start-ups are of low quality, and

their impact on the economic growth is minimal (Litwin and Phan

2012). This is due to the fact that new employers often operate on a

small scale with constrained resources (Litwin and Phan 2013).

Furthermore, employees of new firms differ from employees of

incumbent firms. For instance new firms employ disproportionally

more immigrants and recent graduates (Nyström 2011), and youth

(Ouimet and Zarutskie 2014), than incumbent firms. Finally,

studies on new firms as organizations find that new firms provide a

different working environment to their employees than incumbent

firms, such as less bureaucracy (Sørensen 2007) and opportunities

to work alongside managers (Wagner 2004).

In sum, although new firms may offer jobs of lower quality

compared to incumbent firms, they have attractive features to offer

and are important as employers, especially for individuals with

weaker status on the labour market. This therefore indicates the

importance of new firms as an object of study, and this research

aims to investigate the role of new firms as employers in the labour

market.

The thesis addresses employment in new firms and post-new

firm employment labour market outcomes by analysing labour

mobility in new firms, including both transitions of workers into

Page 15: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

15

and from new firms. This thesis aims to provide new insights

regarding employee mobility in new firms. In particular, it focuses

on the wages of employees in new firms and on post-employment

transition of new firm employees into long-term employment and

entrepreneurship.

This cover essay consists of eight sections. Section 2 provides a

brief overview on new firms’ role in the economy, on the

relationship between new firms and economic growth, and on the

role of new firms in the labour market. In addition, an overview of

the dynamic of new firms and their employees in Sweden is

presented in this section. Section 3 presents several economic

theories related to the labour market. In section 4, the previous

empirical literature is discussed, and Section 5 presents the dataset

used in this thesis. Section 6 presents the definition of new firms

and the measurement of labour market outcomes. Section 7

summarises the four essays included in the thesis, and the main

findings of each essay are highlighted. Finally, conclusions and

suggestions for further research are presented in section 8.

2. The role of new firms in the economy

2.1 New firms as employers

Joseph Schumpeter viewed entrepreneurs as introducing novelty

through new combinations of existing knowledge and development

of a new organizational form (Schumpeter 1934). Historically,

entrepreneurship is one of the oldest activities and it includes

discovering and exploiting new business opportunities in new

ventures for economic gain (Landstrom 2007).

From a macroeconomic perspective, the importance of new

firms for economic growth is emphasized in the creation of new

jobs and contributions to aggregate employment growth. Through

their job creating power new firms affect economic growth at both

Page 16: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

16

the national and regional levels (Audretsch and Keilbach 2004).

Furthermore, new firm formation is also found to have an

important influence on the development of regional economic

well-being (Davidsson et al. 1994). Hence, new firms are important

in job creation and in stimulating economic growth.

At the microeconomic level jobs created by new firms have been

studied in terms of their quality. On the labour market quality of

jobs is usually measured in pecuniary terms, such as wages, as well

as in non-pecuniary terms, such as job security, fringe benefits and

employee protection (see e.g. Wagner 1997). Most new jobs created

by start-ups are of low quality and their impact on economic

growth is minimal (Litwin and Phan 2012). New firms are less

likely to offer high-quality jobs even after controlling for numerous

sources of variation (Litwin and Phan 2013). Jobs in new firms are

usually associated with lower wages (Brixy et al. 2007). New firms

tend to offer less stable jobs since there is a high probability of job

destruction during the first five years (se e.g. e.g., Geroski 1995,

Shane 2009); they also provide fewer fringe benefits than

incumbent firms (Wagner 1997).

On the other hand, new firms are heterogeneous, and as Dahl

and Klepper (2015) find, productive new firms hire more talented

employees already from the time of entry, and these firms

consistently pay higher wages to their new hires. Although new

firms offer fewer fringe benefits, for instance health insurance,

once a new firm survives and grows it is as likely to offer work

benefits as established businesses (Litwin and Phan 2012). These

findings highlight the particular importance of more productive

high-growth new firms in the economy.

Economists study not only the quality of jobs provided by new

firms but the role of new firms as employers regarding the

individuals they employ. The empirical literature shows that new

firms disproportionally employ certain group of individuals, for

instance immigrants and recent graduates (Nyström 2011), and

Page 17: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

17

youth (Ouimet and Zarutskie 2014). This highlights the

importance of new firms as employers, especially for individuals

with weaker status on the labour market. Hence, new firms may

play a role for their integration into the labour market.

Finally, studies on new firms as organizations find that new

firms provide a different environment to their employees than

incumbent firms, which may attract a certain group of individuals.

Unlike older firms, new firms provide a workplace with a higher

level of freedom with less bureaucracy (Sørensen 2007) and

possibility to work alongside managers (Wagner 2004). Hence,

these features may attract more individuals who prefer such firm

attributes.

2. 2 New firms and their employees in Sweden

This subsection presents a general overview of the dynamics of

new firms and their employees in Sweden. Data for the tables and

figures are accessed through MONA (Microdata Online Access).3

Table 1 presents statistics on new firms4 in Sweden’s private sector

for the period 1998-2010. As one can see, the number of new firms

varied between 12,784 and 17,7635 and seems to be increasing with

the exception of the period 2001-2002. These new firms seem to

make the largest share of all new firms aged 0-5 years. Figure 1

shows that newly founded firms comprise approximately 3-4

percent of all firms6, while the new firms aged 0-5 years comprise

3 This is a system that provides micro data at Statistics Sweden. 4 Definition of new firms used in the thesis are discussed in Section 6. Here, new firms are defined as independent start-ups and do not include firms with only one employee (they are considered as self-employment), and other types of new firms such as divestures or spin-offs (see Andersson and Klepper 2013). 5These numbers differ from the official statistics, since new firms studied in this thesis include only one type of new firm, independent start-ups. According to Statistics Sweden there were 34,040 new firms established in 1998 and 35,000 new firms in 1999 (SCB 2000), while the number of start-ups in 2009 amounted 59,597 and in 2010 to 66,681 (SCB 2011a). 6 The number of genuine new business in relation to the existing business portfolio in 1999 amounted to 7.3 percent on average for the country (SCB 2000),

Page 18: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

18

approximately 6-10 percent of all firms.

The number of employees in new firms is approximately

40,000-60,000 7 per year, and again they comprise the largest

share of all employees of the new firms aged 0-5 years, as Table 2

shows. At the same time new firm employees comprise

approximately 2 percent of all employees working in the private

sector, while employees working in new firms aged 0-5 years

comprise approximately 3-5 percent of all employees. Although

new firm employees comprise a small share of all employees, they

hire more employees. For instance, Figure 3 shows that

approximately 22-29 percent of all employees are newly hired

every year, and among the newly hired employees in all firms

approximately 7-8 percent of them are hired by newly founded

firms; new firms aged 0-5 years hire approximately 8-11 percent of

all newly hired employees.

On the other hand, every year approximately 15-17 percent of all

firms close down8 (Figure 4). The number of closed new firms is

approximately 3,000-5,000 per year, while the number of new

firms aged 0-5 years is approximately 6,000-9,000 per year (Table

3). Among all closed firms approximately 5-7 percent are new

firms while 9-13 percent are new firms aged 0-5 years. New firms

seem to comprise the largest share of closed new firms aged 0-5

years. At the same time, the number of employees affected by new

firm closure comprise the largest share of employees of closed new

firms aged 0-5 years (Table 2) and the share of employees affected

by firm closure of new firms is approximately 10-12 percent, while

the share of employees affected by closure of new firms aged 0-5

years comprise approximately 15-19 percent of all employees

while this index was equal to 7.3 percent in 2009 and 8.1 percent in 2010 (SCB 2011a). 7 Newly founded firms employed approximately 56,580 people in 1999 (SCB 2000) and in 2010 employed a total of 117,419 people (SCB 2011a). 8 This category includes all closed firms that are not counted as survivors. Other firm closures due to splitting or merging are excluded from this category.

Page 19: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

19

affected by firm closure (Figure 5).

In sum, new firms as employers are important on the labour

market as they hire a significant share of all newly hired employees,

although the percentage of employment accounted for by new

firms is rather low. Furthermore, new firm closure affects many

employees since up to 20 percent of employees of all closed firms

come from new firms aged 0-5 years.

Page 20: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

20

Table 1 New firms9 in Sweden (1998-2010) Firms Closed firms

Years New firms (0 years)

New firms (0-5 years)

All firms10 New firms (0 years)

New firms (0-5 years)

All firms

1998 14,202 22,984 38,6711 4,508 6,270 65,333

1999 13,807 28,378 38,6447 4,243 6,896 60,468

2000 15,324 34,050 39,2711 4,566 7,829 62,012

2001 13,959 37,212 393,763 4,198 7,750 59,336

2002 12,784 39,355 396,219 3,992 8,029 67,620

2003 13,675 39,209 382,518 3,897 7,783 64,926

2004 13,285 39,084 424,025 4,111 7,729 73,317

2005 15,028 40,894 427,167 4,529 8,386 73,052

2006 16,199 42,442 435,775 4,825 8,948 77,884

2007 17,763 44,873 442,762 5,168 9,427 73,960

2008 16,809 46,104 452,025 4,988 9,626 74,869

2009 14,896 44,995 455,750 4,543 9,125 77,426

2010 17,165 47,026 467,286 5,138 9,943 77,812

9 New firms according to the definition used in the analysis. 10 This category includes all firms in the private sector, including firms with only one employee which are counted as self-employment.

Page 21: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

21

Table 2 Employees in firms, ages 16-64 (1998-2010) Employees Newly hired employees Employees of closed firms11

Years New firms

(0 years)

New firms (0-5

years)

All firms New firms

(0 years)

New firms (0-5

years)

All firms New firms

(0 years)

New firms (0-5

years)

All firms

1998 46,605 73,434 2,336,321 46,605 54,468 636,077 14,348 18,746 118,234

1999 48,396 93,464 2,422,973 48,396 60,675 693,857 15,558 22,579 140,935

2000 55,747 114,806 2,548,910 55,747 71,901 804,575 17,148 25,143 137,247

2001 49,962 124,472 2,559,405 49,962 68,377 719,323 15,400 24,109 126,454

2002 44,354 129,760 2,561,050 44,354 64,275 654,221 14,136 23,470 123,092

2003 46,163 128,021 2,556,259 46,163 65,100 602,027 13,930 22,645 126,688

2004 44,176 128,006 2,619,744 44,176 64,527 694,798 14,317 23,123 133,619

2005 50,557 133,036 2,637,561 50,557 70,279 653,817 15,884 25,156 144,604

2006 55,100 137,609 2,707,486 55,100 75,459 724,503 17,277 27,444 162,322

2007 61,409 146,267 2,807,949 61,409 83,428 803,953 18,412 28,431 151,928

2008 57,681 148,784 2,848,579 57,681 80,022 746,926 17,852 28,237 143,704

2009 49,711 142,112 2,727,325 49,711 70,929 614,311 16,265 26,980 146,186

2010 57,313 149,731 2,821,653 57,313 80,329 735,025 18,169 29,208 171,033

11 This number shows the total number of employees who worked at firms closed down in the year prior to the closure.

Page 22: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

22

0,0%

2,0%

4,0%

6,0%

8,0%

10,0%

12,0%

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012

Figure 1 New firms

New firms (0 years) (% of all firms)

New firms (0-5 years) (% of all firms)

0,0%

1,0%

2,0%

3,0%

4,0%

5,0%

6,0%

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012

Figure 2 Employment in new firms, ages 16-64

New firm (0 years) employees (% of all employees)

New firm (0-5 years) employees (% of all employees)

Page 23: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

23

0,0%

5,0%

10,0%

15,0%

20,0%

25,0%

30,0%

35,0%

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012

Figure 3 Newly hired employees, ages 16-64

Newly hired employees in new firms (0 years) (% of all new hires)

Newly hired employees in new firms (0-5 years) (% of all new hires)

Newly hired employees (% of all employees)

0,0%

5,0%

10,0%

15,0%

20,0%

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012

Figure 4 Closed firms

Closed new firms (0 years) (% of all closed firms)

Closed new firms (0-5 years) (% of all closed firms)

Closed firms (% of all firms)

Page 24: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

24

0,0%

5,0%

10,0%

15,0%

20,0%

25,0%

1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012

Figure 5 Employees affected by firm closure, ages 16-64

Employees of closed new firms (0 years) (% of employees of all closedfirms)

Employees of closed new firms (0-5 years) (% of employees of all closedfirms)

Employees of all closed firms (% of all employees)

Page 25: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

25

3. Economic theory on labour market outcomes

3.1 Search and matching theory

The matching model 12 of the labour market describes a

relationship between agents on the labour market, in particular job

seekers and employers. The labour market acts as a matching

process in which an individual worker searches for a job while a

firm chooses the right worker for a position. Employee recruitment

by firms is a matching process between prospective employees and

employers, depending on the characteristics of employees and

employers. Individuals and firms face both firm and individual

constraints in this process.

On the job search theory 13 individuals know only the

distribution of wages existing in the economy and they search for

employers who will make a definite wage offer. The optimal

strategy for a job seeker is to accept any wage offer higher than his

or her reservation wage. However, the reservation wage depends

on the set of parameters affecting the labour market, in particular

the job destruction rate, the arrival rate of job offers, and

unemployment insurance benefits. The impact on the

unemployment benefits for the reservation wages also depends on

an individual’s eligibility for unemployment benefits.

Furthermore, wages are not only determined by job seekers, but

by the strategic behavior of firms; this makes the distribution of

wages endogenous. Wage formation in firms14 also depends on a

number of factors. Under perfect competition workers receive

wages equal to their marginal productivity. The differences in wage

settings between individuals then account for the level of hard

12 See e.g., Jovanovic (1979) and Cahuc and Zylberberg (2004). 13 See Cahuc and Zylberberg (2004) pp. 103-165 14 See Cahuc and Zylberberg (2004) pp. 246-298

Page 26: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

26

working and individual productivity, which is explained by the

human capital theory. However, in reality, markets are not perfect.

Employment in new firms is also a matching process and a

number of factors make new firms less attractive on the labour

market as employers compared to incumbent firms. First, new

firms are associated with risks. Since the vast majority of new firms

are short-lived (Geroski 1995, Shane 2009) and face a high risk of

closing down (Persson 2004), it is a risky decision for an individual

to accept an offer of employment in a new firm. Furthermore, new

firms may offer jobs of lower quality such that they pay lower

wages (Brixy et al. 2007), provide worse conditions in terms of

fringe benefits and skill enhancement (Wagner 1997). Under these

circumstances, new firms may have a limited pool of applicants

available to them.

On the other hand, even if entering a new firm as an employee is

a risky project, new firms may offer other attractive factors. New

firms provide attractive features such as higher level of freedom

and less bureaucracy (Sørensen 2007), as well as the opportunity

to work alongside managers and learn (Wagner 2004). These

features may attract more individuals who prefer such firm

attributes. Furthermore, young and small firms attract relatively

more individuals with a weaker position on the labour market

compared to incumbent firms; such individuals include

immigrants, recent graduates (Nyström 2011), labour market

entrants (Nyström and Elvung 2014), involuntary job switchers

(Nyström and Zhetibaeva Elvung 2015), and individuals who have

been unemployed (Schnabel et al. 2011).

Hence, the matching process in the recruitment process of new

firms may differ from the recruitment process in incumbent firms.

Although new firms may have difficulties employing more

productive and highly capable individuals due to their less

attractive features, new firms may attract more individuals who

prefer firm attributes that are more specific to new firms despite

Page 27: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

27

the fact that potential employees are aware of the risks associated

with new firms. At the same time, individuals with a weaker

positon on the labour market may accept employment in new firms

in the absence of other alternatives or employment opportunities,

for instance in larger or older firms.

3.2 Stepping stone-hypothesis

Workers’ decision to transition from one firm to another as an

employee or entrepreneur is dictated not only by the current

labour market conditions but by the characteristics related to

previous employment, such as firm characteristics, occupation and

job characteristics. Moving from less favorable employment to

“better” employment (e.g., in terms of earnings and job stability)

may be partially explained by the stepping-stone hypothesis15 that

was formulated by Sicherman and Galor (1990). This hypothesis is

based on the career mobility theory, which argues that wage

penalties for overeducated workers are compensated by better

promotion prospects.

An individual’s acceptance of the job offered at firms with lower

wages and job instability may be explained by a number of factors.

For instance, overeducated workers for the current low wage job

may accept such positions to avoid the scarring effects of staying

unemployed (Arulampalam 2001). On the other hand, this may be

the shortest pathway to a job that matches the attained educational

level (Baert et al. 2013). This type of mobility can be explained by

the stepping stone hypothesis. Hence, individuals may accept jobs

with lower quality to move to better jobs in the future and treat the

current firm as a temporary place.

Even if employment in new firms is risky and less attractive as

discussed in the previous subsection, many individuals may see the

15 See Baert et al. (2013) for a detailed discussion on the stepping stone hypothesis.

Page 28: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

28

employment in new firms as a good opportunity for human capital

accumulation and a transitory point toward better job options in

terms of earnings and job stability. For instance, non-employed

individuals may accept short-term employment in new firms to

improve their chances of gaining long-term employment. As

discussed by Hagen 2000 and Ichino et al. 2008, the stepping

stone effect may work through several channels and summarised

as follows.16 First, employment in new firms may be seen as an

investment in human capital that can be transferred to the next job.

Second, it may serve as a screening device. For instance, non-

employed individuals accepting employment in new firms make

themselves available for screening to signal about their skills and

productivity to potential employers. Third, temporary jobs may

promote on-the-job search, such that new firm employees taking

short-term jobs start searching for a long-term job earlier. Fourth,

there is the signaling mechanism. Short-term employment may

also be a positive signal to other employers, again, in comparison

to the situation in which the person had remained unemployed.

Finally, employees in new firms may choose to work a short period

of time voluntarily if they are offered attractive outside alternatives

in terms of wages such that new firms may serve as a temporary

point toward a final destination.

3.3 The new firm effect on entrepreneurship

Previous research indicates a link between an individual’s

workplace environment and his or her engagement in

entrepreneurial activity. According to previous research,

16 See a detailed discussion on the mechanisms of the stepping stone hypothesis (Hagen 2003) where he uses German data to investigate whether fixed-term contracts serve as stepping stones for the unemployed towards permanent employment and discusses four explanations of the stepping stone mechanism. Ichino et al. (2008) use Italian data to study whether temporary work agencies can be an effective springboard to permanent employment and discuss two reasons why temporary employment could serve as a springboard to a stable job.

Page 29: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

29

employees of small firms are significantly more likely to quit than

are those at large firms to start new ventures (Hyytinen and

Maliranta 2008, Baltzopoulos 2009). This link shows a negative

relationship between firm size and the likelihood of the employees

becoming entrepreneurs. Elfenbein et al. (2010) call this link the

“small firm effect”.

On the other hand, Haltiwanger et al. (2013) argue that the firm

age effect rather than its size is very important in regard to

understanding entrepreneurship and for policy implications to

promote entrepreneurship. Young firms are small on average but

not all small firms are young. Hence, the small firm effect on

entrepreneurship may not always be the same as the new firm

effect, which makes it necessary to consider the firm age effect on

entrepreneurship separately from the firm size effect. Some

empirical evidence links the firm age to entrepreneurship. For

instance, Wagner (2004) find that work experience in a young and

small firm that are no older than 10 years are important for

entrepreneurship. Similarly, Sorensen (2007) finds a positive

effect of younger firms on entrepreneurship, especially those aged

0-3 years.

In this thesis, this positive link between young and small firms

and entrepreneurship is labeled as the “new firms effect” on

entrepreneurship. The mechanism behind the new firm effect on

entrepreneurship is based on the environment that new firms may

offer to their employees. This impact is driven by the increase of

human capital through accumulation of entrepreneurial knowledge

and skills that are important to start a business. As small firms,

new firms may act as important breeding grounds for

entrepreneurs (Baltzopoulos 2009), providing favourable

conditions to develop entrepreneurial knowledge and skills.

Moreover, new firm employees have an opportunity to gain start-

up experience, which is an important human capital for

Page 30: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

30

entrepreneurship (see Davidsson and Honig 2003) while working

in new firms in their early years of establishment.

4. Previous empirical literature

4.1 Employment in new firms

There is a large body of literature that studies new firms in

general, for example in terms of their performance (Lööf and

Nabavi 2014), job quality (Brixy et al. 2006), survival (Acs and

Armington 2004), and formation (Knoben et al. 2011). Among

other topics, entrepreneurship research studies the role of

entrepreneurial or new firms and there is a debate on the role of

new firm as employers.

A number of researchers also focus on the individuals who new

firms hire when studying employment in new firms. For instance

Nyström (2011) studies employment in new firms by using

Swedish data and finds that the share of employees from so-called

“labour market outsiders”, 17 such as immigrants and recent

graduates, was higher in new firms compared with incumbent

firms. Similarly, Ouimet and Zarutskie (2014) use US data to show

that young firms disproportionately employ and hire young

workers. These findings indicate the importance of new firms,

especially for individuals with a weaker position on the labour

market. On the other hand, new firms are heterogeneous and hire

individuals with different skills. For instance, Dahl and Klepper

(2015) analyse the hiring choices of all new firms that began

operating between 2003 and 2010 by using the matched

employer–employee dataset for Denmark. They find that more

productive firms hire more talented employees from the time of

entry, which suggests that workers are allocated to firms according

to their abilities.

17 See Lindbeck and Snower (2001) for a discussion of the theory.

Page 31: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

31

4.2 Wage differentials in new firms and post new firm-

employment labour market outcomes

The main focus of the thesis is to study the role of new firms as

employers by analysing the new firm employee’s labour market

outcomes, such as earnings, and post new firm employment

transitions to long-term employment or entrepreneurship.

In labour economics, firm characteristics are often studied

when analysing wage differentials. Previous studies on the wage

penalty of employment in entrepreneurial or new firms focus on

the relationship between firm size and wages. Wagner (1997)

provides a literature review covering a number of studies and

concludes that small firms offer worse jobs than large firms

because wages are lower, fringe benefits are lower, job security is

lower and opportunities for skill enhancement are worse. The wage

penalty found in small firms is also confirmed by a number of

other empirical studies (Bayard and Troske 1999, Troske 1999,

Millimet 2006, Waddoups 2007).

One of the most influential studies on the firm age-wage

relationship was carried out by Brown and Medoff (2003). They

find that older firms pay higher wages; however, the relationship is

not monotonic, with wages falling and then rising with years in

business. Another study by Brixy et al. (2007) uses a linked

employer–employee dataset for Germany to analyse wage setting

in newly founded and other firms. They find that on average, wages

in newly founded establishments are 8 percent lower than in

similar incumbent firms. Regarding Swedish studies, Heyman

(2007) uses a matched employer–employee dataset for Sweden

and analyses the link between firm age and wages. The results

indicate that the inclusion of firm age does not affect the impact of

firm size on wages.

Previous studies on firm age-wage differentials have been

unable to control for the possibility that the opportunity costs of

Page 32: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

32

accepting employment at new firms may differ across individuals.

Hence, the first essay in the thesis studies whether the wage

penalty of employment in a new firm persists if one focuses solely

on labour market entrants. Similarly, the second essay investigates

whether a wage penalty for being employed at a new firm exists by

taking the individual employee’s experience and status in the

labour market into consideration by focusing only on individuals

who decide to switch jobs.

Labour market outcomes of employees, such as employment or

entrepreneurship as employees transition from one firm to another,

are affected not only by current employment but also by

characteristics related to previous employment. Moving from less

favorable employment to better employment is partially explained

by the stepping-stone hypothesis. Previous research has studied

different employment patterns, such as part-time jobs, temporary

contracts and low-wage jobs, as potential stepping-stones on the

labour market toward better jobs in terms of employment stability,

wages, and contract types. For instance, Mosthaf et al. (2014) finds

that future wage prospects are better for low-paid women than for

unemployed or inactive women. Moreover, for women low-paid

jobs can serve as a stepping stone out of unemployment. Similarly,

Knabe and Plum (2013) find that individuals improve the chance

to obtain a high-wage job by accepting low-paid work, especially

those with lower-skills and longer periods of unemployment. At

the same time, employment in larger firms increases transition to

better employment. Mitchell and Welters (2008) find that casually

employed workers will find it easier to transition to non-casual

employment if they are employed in large firms, as they are more

likely to be exposed to a broader and deeper social network.

Long-term employment that may lead to permanent

employment may be a ‘good transition’ compared to temporary

employment. Permanent employment has some advantages in

terms of job quality, such as higher level of job security, higher

Page 33: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

33

wages, employee education and better labour market opportunities

(Skedinger 2012).

The findings of previous research on temporary employment

provide mixed evidence on the stepping stone hypothesis. For

instance, Ichino et al. (2008) use data for two Italian regions to

show that temporary work agencies can be an effective springboard

into permanent employment. Similar results are found by Guell

and Petrongolo (2007) who use Spanish data and analyse

conversion of temporary employment into permanent employment,

finding that the conversion rate increases with the tenure. Finally,

Cockx and Picchio (2012) find that short-lived jobs are stepping

stones to long-lasting jobs (lasting one year or more) for Belgian

long-term unemployed school-leavers. On the other hand, Svalund

(2013) indicates low mobility from temporary to permanent

employment contracts in Sweden. Similarly, Hveem (2013) uses

Swedish data and estimates the causal effect of temporary work

agency employment on the subsequent probability of employment

in the regular labour market and finds no evidence of a stepping-

stone effect.

Most of the research discussed above aims to determine the

effect of contract type on future employment. Cockx and Picchio

(2012), who test short-lived jobs as stepping stones to long-lasting

jobs, focus solely on short-lived jobs that end involuntarily (ending

in unemployment). This excludes individuals who may accept

employment in a new firm but transition to another firm

voluntarily. Furthermore, most previous research testing the

stepping-stone hypothesis studies whether non-standard jobs

accelerate or delay the transition into a better job match (see e.g.

Esteban-Pretel et al. 2011, Baert et al. 2013). However, the strategy

of accepting non-standard jobs is found to be less beneficial in

terms of long-term consequences. For instance, for unemployed

workers, taking a contingent job does not raise the probability of

having a regular job in the long term (Esteban-Pretel et al. 2011).

Page 34: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

34

Hence, building on previous research the third essay studies the

new firm effect on future employment by investigating short-term

employment in new firms (both voluntary and involuntary) as the

potential stepping stone toward long-term employment, especially

for individuals with previous non-employment status (i.e.,

unemployment and non-participation). Moreover, the study

focuses on the immediate effect of employment in a new firm on

long-term employment.

The small firm effect on entrepreneurship is fairly established in

the literature. Many researchers have supported the small firm

effect empirically. For instance, Hyytinen and Maliranta (2008)

use a large linked employee-employer dataset from Finland and

(Baltzopoulos 2009) employ Swedish employer-employee data;

they find that smaller firms spawn new entrepreneurs more

frequently than larger firms do. From another point of view,

Kacperczyk (2012), using U.S. data, finds that employees in large

and mature organizations are less likely to transition to

entrepreneurship. Young firms are small on average but not all

small firms are young. Hence, the small firm effect on

entrepreneurship is not always the same as the new firm effect,

which necessitates considering the firm-age effect separately from

firm-size effect.

On the other hand, empirical evidence on the effect of firm age

on entrepreneurship is relatively less established. One such work

carried out by Wagner (2004) uses German data and demonstrates

both the positive effect of work experience in a firm that is both

young and small and that is at most 10 years old, even after

controlling for various individual characteristics and attitudes.

Similarly, Sorensen (2007) tests the new firm effect on

entrepreneurial entry by using Danish data and finds a positive

effect of younger firms on entrepreneurship, especially those aged

0—3 years. Furthermore, he finds that the effect of a firm’s age is

more sensitive to the inclusion of industry-fixed effects.

Page 35: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

35

In these studies, new firms have been defined in various ways.

Furthermore, these studies do not differentiate between different

types of new firms. For instance, spin-offs, which are on average

larger, differ from other types of new firms in the quality of their

employees (Andersson and Klepper 2013). Hence, building on the

previous research, the fourth essay studies the new firm effect on

entrepreneurship by analysing the individual’s engagement in

entrepreneurial activity through employment experience in new

firms. Unlike previous studies, this study focuses only on

employees of independent start-ups, thus excluding other new firm

formations resulting from mergers, acquisitions or spin-offs.

5. Data

5.1 Unique Swedish data

All four essays included in the thesis are empirical and use Swedish

data. Data for the entire thesis are derived from a unique matched

individual-firm dataset provided by Statistics Sweden. It is unique

insofar as it covers all individuals in Sweden who are 16 years and

older. These individuals are then linked to family, business and

workplace. Currently, the available dataset covers the period 1986-

2012.18

The datasets used in the thesis are drawn from the database,

which integrates existing data from the labour market, education,

the social sector, business and finance sectors. As a result, the

database consists of extremely detailed information for all

individuals on, for example, age, gender, education, foreign

background, place of birth, place of residence, employment status,

occupation, annual income, and their employers, both at firm or

enterprise and establishment levels together with organizational

18 The dataset is continuously updated with new entries and date coverage. Today it covers the period 1986-2012, although at the time when the thesis work began it covered the period 1986-2008.

Page 36: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

36

and financial data. Firm level data provide basic statistical

information on start-ups, shutdowns, divisions and mergers of

enterprises and establishments.

5.2 Data for the analysis

In each essay, data for the studies are collected based on the study

question and availability of the key variables. A more detailed

description of the data and the data sources for some variables is

found in the data section of each paper. The unit of study in each

paper is an employee connected to his employer at the firm level in

the private sector.

The first essay employs an employer-employee matched dataset

that covers the Swedish population during the period from 1998 to

2008 with labour market entrants as units of study, while the

second essay focuses on individuals who decide to switch jobs

using the data for the period 1998–2010. In essays 3 and 4

individual-firm level data are used, with newly hired employees

being selected as a unit of study from five different cohorts, namely

2001-2005. In essay 3, each newly hired employee is tracked for

the next two years, while in essay 4 newly hired employees are

followed for five years from the time they enter their firms. Table 3

shows the coverage and general description of the data used in the

essays.

Table 3 Overview of the data used in the essays

Essays Period Units of study Type of data

Essay 1 1998-2008

Labour market entrants

Individual level data on demography, wages, employment etc.

Essay 2 1998-2010

Job switchers Individual and firm level data on demography, wages, employment etc.

Essay 3 2001-2007

Newly hired employees

Individual and firm level data on demography, wages, employment, social benefits etc.

Page 37: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

37

Essay 4 2001-2010

Newly hired employees

Individual and firm level data on demography, wages, employment, occupation, entrepreneurship or self-employment etc.

6. Defining new firms and measuring labour

market outcomes

The main purpose of the thesis is to investigate the role of new

firms as employers by analysing the employee mobility and

studying the wages and post-employment labour market outcomes

of employees in new firms. The definition of a new firm used in the

thesis is consistent throughout with the exception of small

differences described in the next subsection. The measurement of

wages and labour market outcomes as long-term employment and

entrepreneurship builds on previous research.

6.1 New firms

In the thesis a new firm is defined as a newly established firm that

is no more than three or five years old and had no more than 10

employees at the time of its establishment. This restriction on firm

size is based on the classification of start-ups by Eriksson and

Kuhn (2006) based on Danish data because new firms with more

than 10 employees are assumed to be divestitures, reorganizations

of activities that previously occurred at an incumbent firm. For

Swedish data, Andersson and Klepper (2013) use similar

classification of start-ups. Furthermore, this category of new firms

excludes new firms categorized as pushed and pulled spin-offs.19

Thus, the new firm category includes all newly established firms

that are at most three or five years old and have at most 10

employees at the time of the establishment.20

19 For definition of the spin-offs see, Andersson and Klepper (2013). 20 In the first essay, the new firm category does not exclude divestures.

Page 38: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

38

The identification of new firms in the dataset is based on a

combination of information on the firm’s id-code (organization

numbers), the status in relation to the previous year and year when

the firm was established.21 Based on this information, new firms

have new id-codes and are not encoded as survivors in relation to

the previous year.

6.2 Labour market outcomes

A person's total wages for a year are measured as total gross salary

including other income (e.g., sickness benefit, sick pay and

compensation for travel between home and workplace, including in

connection with short-term employment and assignments)

according to information from the employers reported to the

Swedish Tax Agency.22 Although this value represents the person’s

annual income, the term wages are used in essays 1 and 2 and this

value is categorized as a person’s annual (labour) income in essays

3 and 4.

According to Statistics Sweden, short-term employment

statistics are intended to measure the number of employees

quarterly (SCB 2013). The database used for the thesis covers

information on an annual basis only, and there is no official

definition of short-term employment. Hence, in this thesis, short-

term employment in new firms is defined as employment that lasts

a maximum of one year and that is close to the definition of Cockx

and Picchio (2012); while the long-term employment lasts at least

two years with the same employer, which may lead to permanent

employment.23

21 This coding system is based on statistics documentation by Statistics Sweden. See Andersson and Arvidson (2011). 22 See SCB (2011b) p.122 23 According to Swedish labour law, an employee who has worked more than two years on a full-time basis at the same employer has the right to demand permanent employment. In accordance with paragraph 5 of the labour law in Sweden (§ 5 LAS (1982: 80)

Page 39: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

39

The definition of an entrepreneur is based on the definition

provided by the Statistics Sweden. As Minniti and Levesque (2008)

argue, although entrepreneurship and self-employment are not the

same thing, self-employment is often used as a means to

operationalize empirically the contribution of entrepreneurship to

macroeconomic activity. Hence, the terms self-employment and

entrepreneurship are used interchangeably throughout the thesis.

The definition of a self-employed person or an entrepreneur is

based on the variables on professional occupation, wage income

and income from active business activity.24 In the employment

register, an individual is defined as self-employed if the income

received from self-employment is higher than the income received

from paid employment at the workplace chosen as main activity

during November. The choice of workplace is in turn dependent on

which of the two types of income provided the highest November

income. This is given by an individual’s occupation status. In this

thesis entrepreneurs, such as those who are self-employed

according to the definition of Statistics Sweden, are defined by

occupation status. Additionally, those who have any business

income are also included to this category following Andersson

Joona and Wadensjö (2013).

7. Outline of the study and summary of the main

findings

The first two essays focus on employee mobility into new firms and

their labour market outcome in new firms, while the third and

fourth essays study post-new firm employment labour market

outcomes of employees in new firms.

24 See SCB (2011b) pp.78-124

Page 40: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

40

7.1 Essay 1. New firms and labor market entrants: Is

there a wage penalty for employment in new firms?

This essay (co-authored with Kristina Nyström) examines the

role of new firms as an entry point to the labour market. The paper

studies whether the wage penalty of employment in a new firm

persists if we focus solely on labour market entrants and

contributes to the discussion regarding wage penalty for

employment at new firms. According to the ‘‘insider–outsider’’

theory (Lindbeck and Snower 2001), ‘‘insiders’’ are employees who

enjoy protected employment opportunities due to seniority, while

‘‘outsiders’’ are either unemployed or obtain work only temporarily.

When an outsider is employed, he/she becomes a labour market

entrant with the possibility of becoming an insider if he/she

remains in the firm for a sufficient period. The theoretical

framework is based on the job search and matching theory.

The paper uses data for the entire private sector for the period

from 1998 to 2008, where 2008 is the last year of data available to

us. The unit of observation is a labour market entrant. This

category includes all individuals who became employed for the first

time in the observed year on a full-time basis in the private sector

and who are at or below 30 years of age. New firms are classified

into three groups as newly established firms (1-year-old), firms

that are up to 3 years old, and firms that are up to 5 years old.

Incumbent firms in each model are firms not defined as new firms.

The question addressed in this paper aims to estimate the wage

penalty on labour market entrants for employment in a new firm.

An individual is not assigned to a new firm randomly but instead

obtains employment based on many factors, such as abilities, skills,

etc., which might also have an effect on the outcome of the

assignment. The propensity score matching method suggested by

Rosenbaum and Rubin (1983) is used to study the wage differences

between labour market entrants employed in new and incumbent

Page 41: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

41

firms.

The results show that there is a wage penalty associated with

employment in new firms for labour market entrants. However,

the penalty is rather small. The estimated wage penalty varies

across years between 0.6 to 4.9 percent, with an average wage

penalty of 2.9 percent for labour market entrants employed in new

firms over the studied period. There are no observed patterns in

terms of increases or decreases in the wage penalty over time. The

increased wage dispersion observed in the Swedish welfare state

after the economic crisis in the 1990s seems not to have influenced

the wage penalty. Hence, the estimates of the wage penalty are

smaller compared with many other studies that include more

heterogeneous groups of employees in terms of position in the

labour market.

7.2 Essay 2. New firms as employers: The wage penalty

for voluntary and involuntary job switchers

This essay (co-authored with Kristina Nyström) investigates

whether a wage penalty for being employed at a new firm exists if

the individual employee’s experience and status in the labour

market are taken into consideration. In the analysis of the firm

age–wage relationship, both individual and firm heterogeneity are

considered when an individual faces the situation of having to

accept a current job offer.

The paper focuses on individuals who decide to switch jobs and

uses matched employee–employer data in Sweden for the period

1998–2010, focusing on the private sector. The unit of observation

is a job switcher, who is defined as a person who works at the

current and previous periods as employees on a full-time basis and

transitions from one firm to another firm. Finally, the dataset is

restricted to individuals who are between 18 and 60 of age.

The theoretical framework is based on the job search and

matching theory and studies the firm age–wage relationship using

Page 42: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

42

the endogenous switching model. This model sorts workers into

two states, employment in a newly founded firm and employment

in an incumbent firm. Only one state is observed, and there are

controls for possible bias; wage and selection equations are

estimated simultaneously.

The findings are given as follows. First, the share of job

transitions into lower wages are higher for those who switch to new

firms compared with incumbent firms (40 percent and 31 percent,

respectively). There is also evidence of a non-random selection into

new versus incumbent firms. Individuals who switch jobs

involuntarily due to firm closure are more likely to become

employed at new firms. The endogenous wage equation estimates

indicate that being an involuntary job switcher has an equally

negative effect on wages regardless of whether the switch is to a

new or incumbent firm. Hence, the wage penalty caused by an

involuntary job switch is the same at a new firm as it is at an

incumbent firm. However, the positive effect of education on

wages is more pronounced for job switchers selecting into an

incumbent firm. Finally, the results of the analysis of predicted

wage differentials indicate that wage differentials are

underestimated if only random selection into new firms is

considered.

7.3 Essay 3. The effect of employment in new firms on a

career path: Is it a stepping stone toward long-term

employment?

This essay studies the role that new firms play for the career path

of their employees based on the analysis of employee mobility in

new firms. In particular, this paper analyses whether employment

in new firms that lasts at most one year can be a stepping stone for

unemployed individuals toward long-term employment, which

lasts at least two years with the same employer. Previous research

shows that women and men have different employment prospects

Page 43: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

43

and unemployment rates, which affect their outside options and

thus their bargaining power on temporary jobs (Guell and

Petrongolo 2007); there are gender differences in job transitions as

well (D’Addio and Rosholm 2005, Theodossiou and Zangelidis

2009). Hence, in this essay, the analysis is carried out for men and

women separately.

The data used in the analysis are selected from five cohort years

(2001-2005) collected from the Swedish employee-employer

database. The unit of observation is a newly hired employee who

accepted employment in new firms in any years between 2001 and

2005 who are between 25 and 55 years of age. Propensity score

matching (PSM) is used to compare the outcomes of the group of

employees joining new firms with a control group staying non-

employed. The theoretical background is based on the stepping-

stone hypothesis.

The findings show that for women the probability of entering

long-term employment increases by 9.3 percentage points

following short-term employment in new firms compared to

staying non-employed. For men the probability of entering long-

term employment increases by 9.1 percentage points following

short-term employment in new firms. The result supports the view

that new firm employment may serve as a stepping stone to long-

term employment for non-employed individuals. The findings are

consistent with previous research (see e.g. Cockx and Picchio 2012).

For both women and men, this effect is largest for younger

individuals between 25 and 34 years of age, individuals with

tertiary education and who had a student income, while it is the

smallest for individuals with unemployment income and primary

education. Finally, new firm employees who leave the new firms

even after firm closure are also more likely to enter long-term

employment compared to those who remain non-employed. This

suggests that short-term employment in new firms may serve as a

stepping stone to a long-term employment for all new firm

Page 44: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

44

employees who exit firms both voluntarily and involuntarily

through firm closure.

7.4 Essay 4. The new firm effect on entrepreneurship

This paper examines the new firm effect on entrepreneurship. The

question addresses whether employment experience at a new firm

increases the likelihood of its employees becoming entrepreneurs.

Building on previous research the transition of new firm employees

to self-employment is analysed. In addition, the worker's ability

derived from the income residuals are controlled.

The phenomenon known as the small firm effect on

entrepreneurship (Elfenbein et al. 2010), which shows that

employees from small firms are more likely to enter

entrepreneurship than their large firm counterparts, is supported

by a considerable amount of previous research (see e.g., Hyytinen

and Maliranta 2008, Baltzopoulos 2009). On the other hand,

relatively few studies have investigated the link between new firms

and entrepreneurship (see e.g., Wagner 2004, Sorensen 2007).

Moreover, new firms have been defined in various ways. Hence,

building on previous research, this paper studies the new firm

effect on entrepreneurship by analysing the individual’s

engagement in entrepreneurial activity through employment

experience in new firms. Apart from the previous studies the

current work focuses only on employees of independent start-ups,

thus excluding other new firm formations due to mergers,

acquisitions or spin-offs, and also controls for the worker's ability.

The mechanism behind the new firm effect on entrepreneurship is

based on the environment that new firms may offer to their

employees. This impact is driven by the increase in human capital

through accumulation of entrepreneurial knowledge and skills that

are important in starting a business.

The dataset collected from the matched employee-firm database

provided by Statistics Sweden at five different periods (2001-2005)

Page 45: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

45

25 is used for empirical testing, and the competing risk models are

employed. Furthermore, the transition of new firm employees into

entrepreneurship is analysed for men and women separately.

The findings of the paper indicate that the new firm effect is

statistically significant and positive, and this effect remains even

after controlling for the worker's ability. Many covariates in the

analysis seem to affect the self-employment transition for women

and men in the same way; however, many significant differences

across women and men exist. In particular, family status has a

different impact on the self-employment entry for women and men.

Moreover, the model including the ability dummies shows that

employees in the highest and the lowest deciles of the income

residual distribution are more likely to enter entrepreneurship

than those in the middle of the income residual distribution.

The relatively high rate of entrepreneurial entry among workers

in the lowest tail of the income residual distribution may be

explained by the opportunity cost factor such that the lower-ability

workers have the lowest opportunity cost of becoming self-

employed as argued by Elfenbein et al. (2010). On the other hand,

workers in the lowest and the highest income residual distribution

may have different reasons for transitioning to self-employment.

Finally, the analysis of the transition of employees in new and

incumbent firms separately shows that among new firm employees

self-employed women are drawn from the lowest and the next

highest tails of the income residual distribution, while self-

employed men are drawn from the lowest tails of the income

residual distribution only. However, among incumbent firm

employees both self-employed women and men are drawn from

both tails of the income residual distribution, which suggests that

the workers with the lowest and the highest abilities are more

likely to enter entrepreneurship. This may indicate that new and

incumbent firm employees may transition to different types of

25 This is the same dataset used in essay 3

Page 46: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

46

entrepreneurial activities26.

8 Conclusions and suggestions for future

research

This thesis uses Swedish data to address employment in new firms

and post-new firm employment labour market outcomes by

analysing the labour mobility in new firms, including both

transitions of workers into and from new firms. This thesis aims to

fill the research gap related to the labour mobility of employees in

entrepreneurial firms 27 and provide new insights regarding

employee mobility in new firms. In particular, it focuses on wages

of employees in new firms and post-employment transition of new

firm employees into long-term employment and entrepreneurship.

Throughout this thesis highlights the importance of considering

new firms separately from small firms which may not always be

new. All four essays included in this thesis contribute to the

existing literature on the role of new firms as employers and also

make separate contributions. The general contributions may be

summarised as follows.

The first two essays contribute to the empirical literature on

firm age-wage differentials regarding wage penalty for

employment at new firms. In this setting the main contribution lies

in studying the firm age-wage differentials by considering the non-

random selection into new firms and controlling for the status of

individuals on the labour market entering new firms. Furthermore,

the findings underline the importance of new firms, especially for

26 For instance, Andersson Joona and Wadensjö (2013) find that among wage-earners the self-employed starting unincorporated firms (e.g., purely new firms) are drawn from both tails of the income residual distribution, while the self-employed starting an incorporated firm (e.g., spinouts) are only drawn from the top of the income residual distribution. 27 See Nyström (2015) for a detailed discussion of the research gap.

Page 47: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

47

individuals with weaker status, labour market entrants and

involuntary job switchers.

The third and fourth essays provide new insights on employee

mobility in new firms, especially regarding the effect of new firms

on post-new firm employment labour market outcomes. The third

essay contributes to the discussion of firms as stepping stones to

long-term employment. The findings of this essay emphasize the

importance of new firms for labour market integration of non-

employed individuals. Finally, the fourth essay aims to contribute

to the discussion of the firm effect on entrepreneurship and to

extend knowledge about entrepreneurship.

However, this thesis has some limitations that result in other

questions that may be interesting for later analysis. The first and

second essays analyse wage differentials between employees in

new and incumbent firms and focus on a specific type of labour

mobility—labour market entrants and job switchers. The essays

study the pecuniary benefits associated with employment at a

newly created business. However, employment in a small, newly

created venture may bring other benefits that may be

advantageous for an individual’s future career. Hence, it would be

interesting to study whether the fact that the company was newly

created was important to the employee’s decision to accept the job

offer and follow the career paths of employees in newly created

ventures.

The third essay focuses at the transition of new firm employees

to better jobs in terms of job stability only. Although the findings

indicate that new firms may serve as stepping stones toward long-

term employment, this transition may result in jobs of different

quality. Hence, it would also be interesting to see the stepping

stone effect in terms of earnings as well as other occupations for

instance self-employment.

The fourth essay and the thesis study only one type of new firms,

which is the independent start-up. As the descriptive statistics

Page 48: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

48

show this type of new firms are concentrated in specific industry

sectors. Hence, it would be interesting to include other types of

new firms as well. Secondly, the transitions to other firms as

entrepreneurs are not differentiated by different types of

entrepreneurial activity. This limitation could lead to another

question if the new firm effect is different for these different types

of transitions, especially when considering the worker's ability.

Finally, the transitions of new firm employees are not separated

between the voluntary and involuntary exits (e.g., due to firm

closure). Considering these different transitions may explain more

about the new firm effect on entrepreneurship and the underlying

motivation for these individuals to become entrepreneurs.

In general, the findings have important implications. First, new

firms may be important as employers, especially for individuals

with a weaker position on the labour market such that new firms

may help with the labour market integration of these individuals.

At the same time new firms may serve as a transitory point for

their employees toward better employment in terms of job stability.

Furthermore, new firms have a positive impact on entrepreneurial

activity. This has implications for individuals who are considering

starting a business, such that new firm employment experience has

a positive effect on entrepreneurship. At the same time, this

finding may also have implications on policymakers with regard to

encouragement of entrepreneurship. However, this thesis leaves

open the question on the type of new firms started by new firm

employees, which may also have a different effect on policies

stimulating entrepreneurship since given the debate on the types

of entrepreneurship that have the most impact on the economy.

Page 49: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

49

References

Acs, Z.J. and Armington, C., 2004. New firm survival and human capital. The Papers on Entrepreneurship, Growth and Public Policy, (1404).

Andersson Joona, P. and Wadensjö, E., 2013. The best and the brightest or the least successful? Self-employment entry among male wage-earners in Sweden. Small Business Economics, 40 (1), 155–172.

Andersson, J. and Arvidson, G., 2011. ‘Företagens och arbetsställens dynamik’, Statistics documentation document NA/FRS.

Andersson, M. and Klepper, S., 2013. Characteristics and performance of new firms and spinoffs in sweden. Industrial and Corporate Change, 22 (1), 245–280.

Arulampalam, W., 2001. Is unemployment really scarring? Effects of unemployment experiences on wages. The Economic Journal, 111 (475), 585–606.

Audretsch, D. and Keilbach, M., 2004. Entrepreneurship Capital and Economic Performance. Regional Studies, 38 (8), 949–959.

Baert, S., Cockx, B., and Verhaest, D., 2013. Overeducation at the start of the career: Stepping stone or trap? Labour Economics, 25, 123–140.

Baltzopoulos, A., 2009. The firm and the region as breeding grounds for entrepreneurs. CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series Paper, (189), 9–48.

Barreneche García, A., 2014. Analyzing the determinants of entrepreneurship in European cities. Small Business Economics, 42 (1), 77–98.

Bayard, K. and Troske, K.R., 1999. Examining the employer-size wage premium in the manufacturing, retail trade, and service industries using employer-employee matched data. American Economic Review, 89 (2), 99–103.

Birch, D.L., 1981. Who creates jobs? Public Interest, 65, 3–14.

Page 50: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

50

Brixy, U., Kohaut, S., and Schnabel, C., 2006. How fast do newly founded firms mature? Empirical analyses on job quality in start-ups. In: Entrepreneurship in the Region. 95–112.

Brixy, U., Kohaut, S., and Schnabel, C., 2007. Do newly founded firms pay lower wages? First evidence from Germany. Small Business Economics, 29 (1-2), 161–171.

Brown, C. and Medoff, J.L., 2003. Firm Age and Wages. Journal of Labor Economics, 21 (3), 677–697.

Cahuc, P. and Zylberberg, A., 2004. Labor economics. MIT Press.

Cockx, B. and Picchio, M., 2012. Are short-lived jobs stepping stones to long-lasting jobs? Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 74 (5), 646–675.

Criscuolo, C., Gal, P.N., and Menon, C., 2014. The Dynamics of Employment Growth. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers, (14), 96.

D’Addio, A.C. and Rosholm, M., 2005. Exits from temporary jobs in Europe: A competing risks analysis. Labour Economics, 12 (4), 449–468.

Dahl, M.S. and Klepper, S., 2015. Whom do new firms hire? Industrial and Corporate Change, 24 (4), 819–836.

Davidsson, P. and Honig, B., 2003. The role of social and human capital among nascent entrepreneurs. Journal of Business Venturing, 18 (3), 301–331.

Davidsson, P., Lindmarkt, L., and Olofsson, C., 1994. New Firm Formation and Regional Development in Sweden. Regional Studies, 28 (4), 395–410.

Davis, S.J. and Haltiwanger, J., 1999. Gross job flows. In: D. Ashenfelter, O., Card, ed. Handbook of Labour Economics, vol. 3. North-Holland, Amsterdam, 2711–2797.

Page 51: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

51

Elfenbein, D.W., Hamilton, B.H., and Zenger, T.R., 2010. The Small Firm Effect and the Entrepreneurial Spawning of Scientists and Engineers. Management Science, 56 (4), 659–681.

Eriksson, T. and Kuhn, J.M., 2006. Firm spin-offs in Denmark 1981-2000-patterns of entry and exit. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24 (5), 1021–1040.

Esteban-Pretel, J., Nakajima, R., and Tanaka, R., 2011. Are contingent jobs dead ends or stepping stones to regular jobs? Evidence from a structural estimation. Labour Economics, 18 (4), 513–526.

Ferris, J.S. and Voia, M.-C., 2012. What are the significant determinants of entrepreneurship? International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business, 17 (4), 415–454.

Geroski, P.A., 1995. What do we know about entry? International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13, 421–440.

de Graaf-Zijl, M., van den Berg, G.J., and Heyma, A., 2011. Stepping stones for the unemployed: The effect of temporary jobs on the duration until (regular) work. Journal of Population Economics, 24 (1), 107–139.

Guell, M. and Petrongolo, B., 2007. How binding are legal limits? Transitions from temporary to permanent work in Spain. Labour Economics, 14 (2), 153–183.

Hagen, T., 2003. Do Fixed-Term Contracts Increase the Long-Term Employment. Opportunities of the Unemployed ? Discussion Paper No. 03-49.

Haltiwanger, J., Jarmin, R., and Miranda, J., 2013. Who Creates Jobs? Small versus Large versus Young. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 95 (2), 347–361.

Heyman, F., 2007. Firm size or firm age? The effect on wages using matched employer-employee data. Labour, 21 (2), 237–263.

Hveem, J., 2013. Are temporary work agencies stepping stones into

Page 52: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

52

regular employment? IZA Journal of Migration, 2 (1), 21.

Hyytinen, A. and Maliranta, M., 2008. When do employees leave their job for entrepreneurship? Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 110 (1), 1–21.

Ichino, A., Mealli, F., and Nannicini, T., 2008. From temporary help jobs to permanent employment: what can we learn from matching estimators and their sensitivity? Journal of Applied Econometrics, 23 (4), 305–327.

Jovanovic, B., 1979. Firm-specific Capital and Turnover. Journal of Political Economy, 87 (6), 1246.

Kacperczyk, a. J., 2012. Opportunity Structures in Established Firms: Entrepreneurship versus Intrapreneurship in Mutual Funds. Administrative Science Quarterly, 57 (3), 484–521.

Knabe, A. and Plum, A., 2013. Low-wage jobs - springboard to high-paid ones? Labour, 27 (3), 310–330.

Knoben, J., Ponds, R., and van Oort, F., 2011. Employment from new firm formation in the Netherlands: Agglomeration economies and the Knowledge Spillover Theory of Entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 23 (3-4), 135–157.

Landstrom, H., 2007. Pioneers in Entrepreneurship and Small Business Research.

Lindbeck, A. and Snower, D.J., 2001. Insiders versus Outsiders. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15 (1), 165–188.

Litwin, A.S. and Phan, P.H., 2012. The Quality of Jobs Created by Entrepreneurs. Cornell University, ILR school.

Litwin, A.S. and Phan, P.H., 2013. Quality over quantity: Reexamining the link between entrepreneurship and job creation. ILRReview, 66 (4), 833–873.

Lööf, H. and Nabavi, P., 2014. Survival, productivity and growth of new

Page 53: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

53

ventures across locations. Small Business Economics, 43 (2), 477–491.

Millimet, D.L., 2006. Job search skills, employer size and wages. Applied Economics Letters, 12 (2), 95–100.

Minniti, M. and Levesque, M., 2008. Recent developments in the economics of entrepreneurship. Journal of Business Venturing, 23 (6), 603–612.

Mitchell, W. and Welters, R., 2008. Does casual employment provide a ‘stepping stone’ to better work prospects? Center of Full Employment and Equity Working Paper No. 08-11, (08).

Mosthaf, A., Schnabel, C., and Schank, T., 2014. Low-wage employment versus unemployment: Which one provides better prospects for women? IZA Journal of European Labor Studies, 3 (21), 1–17.

Nyström, K., 2011. Labor mobility and entrepreneurship: Who do new firms employ? CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series, (250), 1–18.

Nyström, K., 2015. Pre- and post-entrepreneurship labor mobility of entrepreneurs and employees in entrepreneurial firms. CESIS Electronic Working Paper Series #420.

Nyström, K. and Elvung, G.Z., 2014. New firms and labor market entrants: Is there a wage penalty for employment in new firms? Small Business Economics, 43 (2), 399–410.

Nyström, K. and Elvung, G.Z., 2015. New Firms as Employers: The Wage Penalty for Voluntary and Involuntary Job Switchers. Labour, 29 (4), 348–366.

Ouimet, P. and Zarutskie, R., 2014. Who works for startups? The relation between firm age, employee age, and growth. Journal of Financial Economics, 112 (3), 386–407.

Persson, H., 2004. The survival and growth of new establishments in Sweden, 1987-1995. Small Business Economics, 23 (5), 423–440.

Page 54: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

54

Rosenbaum, B.Y.P.R. and Rubin, D.B., 1983. The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal effects. Biometrika, 70 (1), 41–55.

SCB, 2000. Newly-started enterprises in Sweden 1998 and 1999. Statistics Sweden.

SCB, 2011a. Newly-started enterprises in Sweden 2010. Statistics Sweden.

SCB, 2011b. Background Facts, Labour and Education Statistics. Integrated database for labour market research 1990-2009. Statistics Sweden.

SCB, 2013. Short-term employment statistics. Statistics Sweden.

Schnabel, C., Kohaut, S., and Brixy, U., 2011. Employment stability in newly founded firms: A matching approach using linked employer-employee data from Germany. Small Business Economics, 36 (1), 85–100.

Schumpeter, J.A., 1934. The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Shane, S., 2009. Why encouraging more people to become entrepreneurs is bad public policy. Small Business Economics, 33 (2), 141–149.

Sicherman, N. and Galor, O., 1990. A Theory of Career Mobility. Journal of Political Economy, 98 (1), 169.

Skedinger, P., 2012. Tudelad trygghet. Jobben kommer och går - behovet av trygghet består. Stockholm: Ekerlids förlag., 114–135.

Sorensen, J.B., 2007. Bureaucracy and entrepreneurship: Workplace effects on entrepreneurial entry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52, 387–412.

Svalund, J., 2013. Labor Market Institutions, Mobility, and Dualization in the Nordic Countries. Nordic Journal of Working Life Studies, 3 (1), 123–144.

Page 55: Mobility and Labour Market Outcomes - kth.diva-portal.org970502/FULLTEXT01.pdflabour mobility into new firms. The last two essays focus on post-new firm employment mobility. The first

55

Sørensen, J.B., 2007. Bureaucracy and Entrepreneurship: Workplace Effects on Entrepreneurial Entry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52 (3), 387–412.

Thai, M.T.T. and Turkina, E., 2013. Macro-level determinants of formal entrepreneurship versus informal entrepreneurship. Journal of Business Venturing, 29 (4), 490–510.

Theodossiou, I. and Zangelidis, A., 2009. Should I stay or should I go? The effect of gender, education and unemployment on labour market transitions. Labour Economics, 16 (5), 566–577.

Troske, K.R., 1999. Evidence on the employer size-wage premium from worker-establishment matched data. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 81 (1), 15–26.

Waddoups, C.J., 2007. Employer size-wage effects in Australia. Labour, 21 (4-5), 809–835.

Wagner, J., 1997. Firm size and job quality: A survey of the evidence from Germany. Small Business Economics, 9, 411–425.

Wagner, J., 2004. Are young and small firms hothouses for nascent entrepreneurs? Evidence from German micro data. Applied Economics Quarterly, 50 (4), 379–391.

Valdez, M.E. and Richardson, J., 2013. Institutional determinants of macro-level entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 37 (5), 1149–1175.