lee hansen

Upload: tzwtzw25

Post on 02-Jun-2018

228 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    1/28

    Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1856644

    Economics of the Military DraftAuthor(s): W. Lee Hansen and Burton A. WeisbrodSource: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 81, No. 3 (Aug., 1967), pp. 395-421Published by: Oxford University PressStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1884808.

    Accessed: 01/06/2011 13:39

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at.http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless

    you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you

    may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

    Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at.http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=oup..

    Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed

    page of such transmission.

    JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of

    content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms

    of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    Oxford University Pressis collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Quarterly

    Journal of Economics.

    http://www.jstor.org

    http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ouphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/1884808?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ouphttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ouphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/1884808?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=oup
  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    2/28

    Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1856644

    ECONOMICS

    OF

    THE

    MILITARY

    DRAFT

    *

    W.

    LEE HANSEN

    AND

    BURTON

    A.

    WEISBROD

    I.

    The

    conceptual

    framework,

    396.-II.

    The

    model,

    402.--III.

    Empiri-

    cal

    application,

    406.--IV. Some

    extensions

    of

    the

    analysis,

    411.-V.

    Conclusion,

    421.

    This

    paper

    investigates

    two

    important

    consequences

    of

    the

    present military

    draft

    system.

    They

    are distributive

    effects-the

    impact

    on

    the

    distribution of

    real

    output,

    and allocative

    costs

    -

    the

    impact

    on the

    size

    of

    that

    output.

    The

    distributive

    effects

    result

    from the

    relatively

    low

    rate of

    pay

    to draft-affected men -what

    we refer to as the

    implicit

    income

    tax.

    The

    allocative

    costs result

    from

    the

    effects of

    the

    military

    personnel

    system

    on the

    efficiency

    with which

    a

    given

    level

    of resources

    is allocated

    among

    alternative

    uses.

    In

    analyzing

    the

    consequences

    of the

    draft

    system,

    a standard

    for

    comparison

    is

    necessary.

    For this

    standard

    we have

    selected

    a

    free-market, voluntary system,

    but

    in

    so

    doing

    we

    do

    not

    intend to

    suggest

    either

    that

    this

    is the

    only

    alternative

    worthy

    of considera-

    tion,

    or

    that,

    all

    things

    considered,

    it

    is

    preferable

    to

    the

    existing

    draft

    system.

    Whether

    a

    voluntary

    system

    is

    preferable

    under

    present

    or

    any

    other

    conditions

    is not the

    issue;

    rather,

    we

    wish to

    point

    out certain

    consequences

    of

    existing

    arrangements.'

    These

    consequences

    of

    the

    draft

    system

    stem

    directly

    from

    several

    key

    features of that

    system,

    including:

    (1) The compulsion to serve; the individual,

    if

    called,

    has

    no

    choice

    as to

    whether

    or

    not

    he

    serves.

    (2)

    The

    nature

    of

    the

    selection

    procedure;

    as

    long

    as the size

    of the

    draft-age

    pool

    substantially

    exceeds

    military

    requirements,

    rather

    arbitrary

    decisions

    must

    be

    made

    concerning

    draft

    eligibility,

    i.e.,

    which

    segments

    of

    the

    population

    will

    be

    exempted

    or

    rejected,

    and

    which selected.

    *

    We wish

    to

    acknowledge

    the

    comments

    of A.

    Holtmann,

    S.

    Altman,

    and

    others,

    the

    research assistance

    of

    E.

    Fenlon,

    and

    the financial

    assistance

    pro-

    vided

    by

    the Graduate School of The

    University

    of Wisconsin. Much of the

    work

    on this

    paper

    was done

    in

    1965

    in

    connection

    with then-current

    in-

    vestigations

    of the

    draft.

    Subsequent

    to

    the

    writing

    of

    this

    paper,

    several other

    papers

    on this

    subject

    have

    been

    circulated.

    See

    for

    example,

    Walter

    Y.

    Oi,

    The Economic

    Cost of

    the

    Draft,

    and

    Stuart

    H. Altman

    and

    Alan

    E.

    Fechter,

    The

    Supply

    of

    Military

    Personnel

    in

    the

    Absence

    of a

    Draft,

    papers pre-

    sented at

    the

    American

    Economic

    Association

    meetings,

    December

    1966.

    1. In

    considering

    these

    alternatives

    in a

    comparative-statics

    framework

    we

    ignore

    any

    and all

    transition

    costs

    involved

    in

    shifting

    from one

    system

    to

    another.

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    3/28

    QUARTERLY

    JOURNAL

    OF ECONOMICS

    (3) Following

    from

    (2),

    the

    uncertainty

    for

    men

    of

    draftable

    age

    as

    to

    whether,

    when,

    and

    for

    how

    long

    they

    might

    be

    required

    to

    serve.

    (4)

    The

    generally

    below-market

    wage

    paid;

    draft

    systems

    are

    customarily

    (though

    not

    necessarily)

    characterized

    by

    rates

    of

    pay

    that

    are below

    those

    available

    to

    comparable

    men in

    the civilian

    sector.

    This

    study

    has

    limited

    scope.

    It is limited

    to

    the

    analysis and,

    where

    feasible,

    the

    estimation of

    the

    effects of

    the

    military

    draft

    system

    on the

    size

    and distribution of

    real

    output,

    holding

    constant

    the level of aggregate resource use. It does not consider the effects

    of

    the draft

    system

    on

    such extra-economic variables

    as

    the

    quality

    of

    good

    citizenship,

    or the

    bringing

    together

    of men from

    diverse

    regions

    and

    backgrounds,

    or the ethical

    issues

    relevant

    to

    how the

    risk

    of

    death in

    combat

    -which

    has

    increased

    with the

    expansion

    of

    the

    Vietnam

    war

    -should be

    shared.

    Neither

    does

    it

    consider

    the

    desirability

    of

    altering

    the size

    of

    the

    armed

    forces;

    that

    is

    taken

    as

    given.

    Rather,

    we

    concentrate

    on

    the

    economic

    effects

    of the

    system by which a given level and quality of military manpower is

    secured.2

    However,

    toward the close of

    the

    paper

    we do

    show

    how

    the

    draft

    system

    tends to

    increase the

    number of

    men

    in

    uniform

    (at

    any point

    in

    time)

    above that

    necessary

    to

    provide

    a

    given

    military

    capability.

    The

    plan

    of

    the

    paper

    is as

    follows:

    in

    Section

    I

    the

    income-

    distributive effects

    and

    the

    allocative-efficiency

    costs

    of

    the

    present

    draft

    system

    are examined

    at

    the

    conceptual

    level.

    In

    Section

    II

    the model underlying the empirical analysis is presented, and in

    Section

    III an

    empirical

    version

    of

    the

    model

    is

    developed

    and

    some

    quantitative

    estimates

    are

    derived.

    Finally,

    Section

    IV

    explores

    some

    ramifications

    of the

    analysis.

    I. THE CONCEPTUAL

    RAMEWORK

    A.

    Distributive

    Effects

    The current draft system imposes an implicit income tax on

    draftees,

    collected in

    the

    form

    of

    reduced

    rates

    of

    pay,

    i.e.,

    the

    difference

    between their

    civilian

    opportunity

    cost and their

    military

    remuneration--in

    cash and

    in

    kind.

    This

    implicit

    tax

    currently

    redounds

    to

    the

    advantage

    of

    taxpayers

    in

    general, who,

    as

    a

    con-

    2.

    For

    an

    extensive

    bibliographic

    urvey

    of

    the literatureon

    military

    manpower

    policy,

    see

    Military Manpower

    Policy:

    A

    Bibliographic

    Survey,

    Adjutant

    General

    Department

    f the

    Army,Department

    of

    Defense,

    June

    1,

    1965.

    396

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    4/28

    ECONOMICS

    OF THE MILITARY DRAFT

    sequence,

    pay

    smaller

    explicit

    taxes

    than

    they

    would

    if

    draftees

    were

    not

    thus

    taxed.

    This

    implicit

    tax

    on

    servicemen-which

    involves

    a

    redistribution

    of

    income

    between servicemen

    and civilians

    -

    is

    what we

    mean

    by

    distributive effects.

    To observe

    that the choice

    between

    a draft

    and

    a

    voluntary

    system

    involves

    a

    different

    distribution

    of income

    and

    output

    in

    the

    economy

    does not

    imply

    the

    superiority

    of

    either

    system.

    For

    taxpayers

    in

    general,

    the draft

    provides

    an

    inexpensive

    method

    of

    maintaining

    a

    desired

    level of

    defense

    capability.

    However, during

    the

    early

    1960's

    society

    became

    increasingly

    concerned

    with

    the

    growing inequity

    of the

    implicit

    tax on

    draftees,

    as an ever-smaller

    fraction

    of

    the

    potential

    manpower pool

    became

    subject

    to

    the

    tax.

    This

    occurred as

    the number of

    men of

    draftable

    age

    grew,

    while

    concurrently

    military

    manpower

    requirements

    were

    declin-

    ing.

    Even with the

    heightened

    military

    manpower

    requirements

    produced

    by

    the Vietnam

    war,

    it

    remains true

    that a substantial

    fraction of

    young

    men

    are

    not

    serving

    and will

    not serve because

    they

    are

    rejected

    or

    exempted,

    or

    because

    deferments

    carry

    them

    beyond the established upper age limit. Thus, the Universal Military

    Training

    Act is even now not

    universal,

    and the

    tax

    which

    it

    imposes

    remains selective

    and

    discriminatory.3

    This

    brief

    discussion

    has

    recognized

    the effects

    of

    the

    draft

    system

    on

    the

    distribution

    of

    a

    given

    level of

    real

    income.

    But,

    the

    draft

    system, by

    constraining

    the allocation

    of

    resources,

    also

    effects

    -

    and

    adversely

    -

    the size of

    real income.

    The next

    section

    considers

    these allocative costs.

    B.

    Allocative-Efficiency

    Costs

    A

    draft

    system replaces

    the

    price

    mechanism

    of the

    market

    place

    with a direct-control

    mechanism

    for

    allocating

    labor

    resources

    between the

    military

    and civilian

    sectors

    of

    the

    economy.

    In the

    3. There are a number of

    dimensions to

    the

    redistributional

    effects

    of the

    draft.

    To the

    extent that

    military personnel,

    who

    are

    presently

    arrayed

    toward

    the lower end of the income

    distribution,

    would

    receive

    income

    increases

    under

    a

    voluntary

    system,

    there would

    tend

    to

    be

    greater equality

    in

    the

    overall

    income-size distribution if a voluntary system were introduced. Distribu-

    tional

    changes

    would occur

    not

    only by

    income

    size,

    but

    also

    by age,

    geo-

    graphic area,

    and

    industry

    or

    occupational

    affiliation.

    For

    example,

    since the

    military

    offers

    a

    uniform

    wage throughout

    the

    country,

    the

    existence

    of

    in-

    terregional wage

    difference in the

    nonmilitary

    sector tends

    to

    make

    military

    service

    relatively

    more attractive

    in

    some

    regions

    than

    in others.

    Similarily,

    the

    drawing

    power

    of

    the

    military

    for men

    in

    some

    occupations

    or

    industry

    groups

    is

    stronger

    than

    in

    others.

    In

    addition,

    the

    attractiveness of the

    military

    services

    varies

    with

    respect

    to one's

    age.

    The net

    impact

    of these

    illustrative distributional effects

    of

    a

    voluntary

    system

    would

    be

    to

    accentuate

    labor

    market and

    related

    pressures

    in

    some areas or sectors

    of

    the

    economy

    and to relieve them

    in

    others.

    397

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    5/28

    QUARTERLY

    JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

    process,

    the

    draft

    system

    tends to

    produce

    a

    variety

    of

    economic

    costs

    by:

    (1) Restricting

    labor

    mobility through its compulsory aspects,

    thereby

    leading

    to

    substitution effects within

    the

    military.

    These

    latter tend

    to favor

    production

    techniques using

    relatively

    large

    amounts

    of

    labor

    in

    general

    and skilled labor

    in

    particular,

    given

    the

    cheapness

    of

    manpower

    to

    the

    services and the

    absence

    of

    price

    differentials

    between

    manpower

    at various

    skill

    levels.

    (2)

    Creating

    incentive

    effects

    and increased

    uncertainty

    for

    employers

    and

    employees,

    through

    its

    eligibility

    criteria and its

    induction scheduling arrangements.

    (3)

    Increasing

    turnover

    rates,

    thereby

    adding

    to the

    organiza-

    tional,

    training,

    and

    administrative costs

    of

    meeting

    military

    man-

    power

    needs.

    These three

    types

    of

    costs

    are

    not

    independent

    of each

    other,

    and

    the

    distinction

    among

    them

    is not

    always clear,

    but this

    division

    provides

    a useful

    basis

    for

    analyzing

    the

    principal

    allocative

    costs

    of a

    draft

    system.

    While

    the

    impact

    of each

    type

    of cost

    appears

    in

    both the civilian and military sectors of the economy, the first of

    these

    costs--labor

    mobility

    costs -has its

    major

    effect on the

    allocation

    of

    resources between the

    civilian

    and

    military

    sectors,

    while

    costs of the

    second and

    third

    types

    are

    confined

    largely

    to

    resource

    allocations within

    the

    civilian

    and the

    military

    sectors,

    respectively.

    1.

    Constraints

    on labor

    mobility.

    The existence of

    a

    draft

    system together

    with

    its

    corollary

    -

    a

    wage

    level

    inadequate

    to

    attract the number and quality of military personnel required

    -

    inevitably

    determines

    which

    people

    are

    in

    the

    military

    service at

    any

    point

    in

    time

    and which are

    not.

    If

    manpower

    requirements

    are

    met

    through

    a

    voluntary

    enlistment

    system,

    with

    wage

    and other

    incentives

    adequate

    to

    generate

    the

    required

    number of

    enlistments,

    the

    specific

    individuals

    volunteering

    for

    military

    service

    would

    not

    be the

    same

    as those called into

    the armed forces under

    a

    draft

    system.

    The

    draft

    system,

    through

    its

    coercive

    power,

    restricts

    opportunities for labor resources to move into uses where their net

    productivity

    is

    greatest, given

    individual

    utility

    functions,4

    and

    thereby

    reduces

    real national

    product

    below

    the

    level

    which

    could

    be

    attained with

    any

    given

    level

    of

    aggregate

    resource

    use.

    This

    reallocation occurs

    in

    the

    following

    way.

    Under a

    draft

    system

    of

    the

    present

    type,

    a considerable

    degree

    of

    randomness

    4.

    Utility

    functions

    will,

    of

    course,

    reflect

    any preferences

    for

    or

    aversion

    to

    military

    service,

    with

    all that these

    entail.

    398

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    6/28

    ECONOMICS OF

    THE

    MILITARY

    DRAFT

    exists

    with

    respect

    to

    the

    civilian

    productivity

    of

    men

    drafted for

    service.

    Optimally,

    from

    the

    standpoint

    of

    efficiency

    in the

    use of

    manpower

    resources,

    the

    services

    should be staffed

    by

    those

    men

    who,

    for the

    given

    level

    and

    quality

    of

    manpower required,

    have

    the

    lowest civilian

    opportunity

    cost

    (productivity.)

    5

    The

    draft

    system

    does

    this

    very

    imperfectly,

    at

    best,

    since

    among

    eligible

    men,

    the

    great

    variations

    in

    their

    civilian

    productivity

    are

    given

    scant

    consideration in

    making

    selections

    for

    the

    draft.6

    The

    opportunity

    costs

    imposed

    on

    the

    civilian

    economy by

    this

    largely

    random

    process

    of selection

    tend to be

    greater

    than

    the

    costs

    necessary

    to

    secure

    the needed

    quantity

    and

    quality

    of men.

    To

    the

    extent that men who are

    drafted

    have

    greater

    civilian

    produc-

    tivity

    than some

    who

    are

    not drafted

    but

    who would be

    equally

    acceptable

    to the

    military

    services,

    the

    draft

    system

    unnecessarily

    depresses

    real

    output

    in

    the civilian sector

    of

    the

    economy.

    By

    contrast,

    under a

    voluntary

    system

    in which

    military

    wage

    rates

    were

    sufficiently

    high

    to

    attract

    the

    personnel required,

    men

    would

    offer

    their

    labor

    services

    to

    the armed forces

    only

    to

    the extent

    that

    their value to the armed forces exceeded their value (productivity)

    outside,

    as

    conditioned

    by

    individual

    preferences.

    Thus,

    the

    composition

    of

    military

    personnel

    with

    respect

    to

    their

    civilian

    productivity

    would differ

    from that

    produced by

    a

    draft;

    the con-

    sequence

    would

    be

    an increase in

    aggregate

    real

    output

    in the

    rest

    of

    the

    economy,

    with no

    decrease

    in

    the

    capability

    of

    the

    military

    sector.7

    2.

    Incentive

    and

    uncertainty effects.

    The draft

    system

    pro-

    duces a variety of incentive and uncertainty effects for both private

    5.

    Other

    goals

    than economic

    efficiency

    should

    influence

    military

    man-

    power

    policy,

    of

    course,

    but

    noneconomic considerations

    are

    beyond

    the

    scope

    of this

    analysis.

    6. One

    exception,

    of

    course,

    is

    the deferment of men

    in

    occupations

    deem-

    ed

    essential

    for

    national

    defense.

    Another

    involves

    deferments of

    graduate

    and

    professional

    school

    students-deferments

    which

    may

    in

    effect become

    exemptions

    as

    students

    pass

    the

    draftable

    age.

    7.

    Foregone

    productivity

    in

    the

    civilian

    sector, occurring

    because of the

    draft

    system, may

    also take the

    form of

    foregone

    future

    output.

    The latter

    involves

    foregone,

    or

    at least

    postponed,

    training

    and

    educational

    services,

    insofar as the availability of such services to members of the armed forces

    falls short of

    their

    availability

    in

    the

    civilian

    economy.

    (Training

    and

    educational activities are

    less

    likely

    to

    be

    foregone

    if similar

    post-service

    op-

    portunities

    are

    available

    through,

    for

    example,

    a

    GI

    Bill. Of

    course,

    the

    pro-

    vision

    of

    such

    opportunities

    amounts to a

    constrained

    increase

    in

    compen-

    sation.)

    If

    education

    and

    training

    of the

    types

    having

    nonmilitary

    value

    are

    less

    readily

    available

    in

    the

    military sector,

    the draft

    system

    involves

    fore-

    gone

    current

    capital

    formation via education

    and

    training

    and

    hence fore-

    gone

    future

    productivity.

    The

    extent of

    such loss is

    mitigated

    insofar as the

    education

    and

    training programs provided

    by

    the

    military

    services

    produce

    skills

    having

    transferable value to the rest

    of the

    economy.

    However,

    this

    aspect

    is

    not

    dealt with

    here.

    399

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    7/28

    QUARTERLY

    JOURNAL OF

    ECONOMICS

    employers

    and

    potential

    draftees.

    Incentive effects

    are

    necessary

    consequences

    of the existence of the

    draft.

    Uncertainty

    effects are

    results

    of

    the

    particular eligibility

    and selection

    procedures

    cur-

    rently

    employed.

    The

    very

    existence of a draft

    gives

    rise

    to

    incentive

    effects

    regardless

    of the

    degree

    of

    uncertainty

    that it

    may

    or

    may

    not

    produce.

    If,

    for

    example,

    all men

    were to be

    drafted

    for, say,

    two

    years

    at

    age

    eighteen,

    both

    employers

    and

    potential

    draftees

    might

    be

    expected

    to

    behave

    differently

    than

    they

    would

    otherwise.

    Employers might

    not

    contemplate hiring young

    people

    until

    after

    their

    military service,

    and

    young people

    would

    have

    to

    defer

    their

    post-high

    school education and

    training.

    Or

    if

    some

    men

    were

    to

    be

    automatically exempted

    from

    the

    draft,

    their

    hiring

    and

    educa-

    tional

    possibilities

    would

    be

    enhanced

    relative

    to

    draft-eligible

    men.

    The draft

    also

    gives

    rise to increased

    uncertainty

    so

    long

    as

    the

    draft-eligible

    population

    exceeds

    military

    personnel

    require-

    ments.

    This

    uncertainty

    operates

    at both the

    group

    and

    individual

    levels.

    Uncertainty

    exists at

    the

    group

    level insofar

    as

    the

    total

    number of persons who will be drafted is not known, or as the future

    dimensions of the

    draft-eligible

    pool

    are

    not

    specified

    (i.e.,

    draft

    exemption categories

    may

    be

    changed).

    But

    even

    if

    it

    were

    known

    with

    certainty

    what the total number of

    draftees will be

    and

    what

    the

    duration of

    military

    service

    for

    each

    draftee will

    be,

    there

    may

    remain

    considerable

    uncertainty

    with

    respect

    to

    precisely

    which in-

    dividuals

    will

    be

    selected for

    the

    draft.8

    Thus,

    for

    the

    individual

    worker,

    there is

    uncertainty

    regarding

    whether

    and when he

    might

    be drafted, and for the individual employer, there is uncertainty

    regarding

    the wisdom of

    hiring

    any

    draft-eligible

    man.

    Even

    if

    no

    men

    are to be drafted

    during

    some

    period,

    the

    very

    existence

    of

    a

    draft law

    automatically

    gives

    rise to

    these

    economic

    costs.

    Even

    if,

    ex

    post,

    the

    number

    of

    draftees

    during

    some

    period

    were

    actually zero,

    it

    may

    not have been at

    all

    clear

    in

    advance that

    this

    would

    be the

    case.

    And

    since

    employers

    as well

    as

    employees

    must

    plan

    for the

    future,

    their

    decisions will be

    affected

    by

    anticipa-

    tions about the workings of the draft system, quite apart from what

    does,

    in

    fact,

    happen.

    As

    pointed

    out

    earlier,

    not

    only

    are

    employers'

    decisions

    likely

    to

    be

    affected

    by

    the

    draft,

    but the same

    is true of

    decisions

    by

    draft-eligible

    young

    men.

    In

    general,

    the draft

    system

    establishes

    incentives

    for

    avoiding

    draft

    eligibility,

    and

    this

    alters

    individual

    8.

    For

    some

    categories

    of

    people exempted

    from

    the draft

    there

    will

    be

    no

    uncertainty

    regarding

    their

    draft status so

    long

    as

    the rules are not

    changed.

    400

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    8/28

    ECONOMICS

    OF

    THE MILITARY

    DRAFT

    decisions

    regarding employment,

    occupational

    choice,

    and invest-

    ment

    in

    training.

    For

    example, young

    people,

    recognizing

    their

    eligibility,

    might

    be

    encouraged

    to avoid

    the

    draft

    by

    placing

    them-

    selves in a deferred or excluded

    group,

    either

    by

    enrolling

    in

    college

    9

    or

    by

    marrying

    and

    having

    children,

    which

    they

    might

    not other-

    wise have

    done

    at

    the

    time.1

    Or,

    recognizing

    that

    induction is

    imminent,

    they

    might

    be

    disposed

    to take

    temporary

    jobs

    that

    have

    no

    real

    career future.

    Or,

    they

    might

    not bother to seek

    any

    em-

    ployment

    at

    all.

    The

    draft-created cost

    of increased

    uncertainty

    in

    the

    civilian

    sector of the

    economy

    is the

    inverse

    of

    the

    benefits,

    in

    terms

    of

    both

    flexibility

    and

    certainty,

    which

    a

    draft

    system

    provides

    for the

    military

    sector.

    With

    a draft the

    military

    is

    readily

    able

    to

    secure

    whatever

    men are

    needed,

    whenever

    they

    are needed. But

    under

    a

    voluntary

    system

    the

    military

    services

    would

    need

    to

    possess

    considerable

    flexibility

    in

    establishing

    pay

    schedules

    in

    order to

    adjust

    to

    changing

    supply

    and

    demand

    conditions

    in

    the

    interrelated

    military

    and civilian

    segments

    of

    the

    economy.

    In

    the

    absence

    of

    such flexibility a voluntary system might well impose intolerable

    burdens

    on

    the

    national defense

    effort,

    particularly

    in times

    of

    crisis,

    when

    sharp

    increases

    in

    the

    number

    of

    personnel

    are

    required.

    Thus,

    whereas a

    voluntary

    system

    would

    reduce

    uncertainty

    in

    the

    civilian

    sector,

    this

    might

    well come

    at the

    expense

    of

    greater

    un-

    certainty

    and

    diminished

    flexibility

    in

    the

    military

    sector.

    It could

    be

    argued,

    of

    course,

    that

    in

    periods

    of crisis

    a

    draft

    system

    could

    be

    reinstituted.

    However,

    to the extent

    that

    the

    draft

    were to be reinstituted frequently, uncertainty in the nonmilitary

    sector

    would

    be increased.

    Consequently,

    standby

    authority

    to

    reinstitute

    the

    draft would

    have

    to

    be used

    judiciously-and

    only

    in

    clear

    emergency

    cases

    -

    lest the civilian sector

    of

    the

    economy

    be

    adversely

    effected.

    Vacillation

    between a

    voluntary

    and a draft

    system

    might

    well

    have more

    serious economic effects than

    the

    con-

    sistent

    use

    of

    a draft

    system.

    3.

    Organizational

    and administrative

    costs.

    The draft

    produces

    several types of resource-allocative changes within the military sec-

    tor.

    First,

    as

    noted

    above,

    one

    potentially

    important

    allocative

    effect

    of a

    draft

    system

    results

    from the

    availability

    of

    military

    man-

    power

    at

    wage

    rates that

    fail

    to reflect

    opportunity

    costs.

    Among

    the

    9. Such

    incentives

    to

    increase

    purchases

    of

    education tend

    to

    offset

    forces such

    as

    capital-market

    mperfections

    and the lack of income-tax

    depreciability

    f educational

    expenditures

    f

    a human-investment

    ype.

    1.

    Of

    course,

    n

    designating

    ertain

    groups

    as eitherdeferred

    r

    exempted,

    the Selective Service

    System

    presumably

    does

    not intend to stimulate the

    marriage

    ate

    or

    encourage

    poor

    students o

    pursue

    higher

    education.

    401

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    9/28

    QUARTERLY

    JOURNAL

    OF ECONOMICS

    decisions which the

    military

    services must

    make are

    choices

    between

    the

    degree

    of

    manpower

    utilization

    and the

    degree

    of

    hardware

    (capital)

    utilization.

    Since

    the latter is

    generally

    bought

    in

    private,

    uncontrolled

    markets,

    while the former is obtained at below market

    prices

    through

    the

    draft,

    an

    incentive exists

    for the

    services to sub-

    stitute labor

    for

    capital equipment

    to

    a

    superoptimal extent,2

    or

    at

    least

    to

    substitute

    highly

    skilled,

    highly

    trained

    labor--having

    large

    amounts

    of

    human

    capital

    -

    for less skilled labor.

    Second,

    and

    again

    in

    large

    part

    as

    a

    result

    of the low

    wage

    level

    existing

    under the familiar

    type

    of

    draft

    arrangement,

    the

    system

    tends

    to

    cause an

    excessive

    rate

    of

    manpower

    turnover.

    This

    re-

    sults in an

    unnecessarily

    large

    quantity

    of resources

    devoted to

    training

    new

    inductees.

    That

    is,

    an

    unnecessarily

    large

    fraction

    of

    servicemen are not

    combat-ready, being

    involved

    in

    training

    ac-

    tivities

    either

    as

    trainees

    or

    as instructors or administrators.

    As a

    consequence,

    to have a

    given

    number

    of

    ready

    men

    at

    any

    point

    in

    time,

    the total

    number

    of

    men

    in

    uniform must

    be

    larger

    than

    if

    turnover rates

    were

    not

    pushed up

    by

    the

    submarket

    wage

    level

    associated with the draft.3

    At the same

    time,

    even

    under a

    voluntary system

    some

    ad-

    ministrative

    costs

    associated

    with

    the Selective

    Service

    System

    would

    continue,

    since the draft

    machinery

    would

    probably

    have to

    be

    retained

    for

    possible

    emergency

    use.

    Moreover,

    a

    voluntary

    sys-

    tem

    would entail certain

    additional

    costs

    not

    incurred

    with the

    draft. There

    might

    be need

    for intensified

    study

    of the

    price-

    elasticity

    of the

    military

    labor

    supply

    function,

    and

    recruiting

    (ad-

    vertising) efforts might have to be stepped up, depending upon the

    attractiveness

    of

    the

    financial

    inducements.

    In

    summary,

    any

    ad-

    ministrative-cost

    savings

    that resulted from the

    inactivation

    of the

    Selective

    Service

    System

    might

    be

    more than offset

    by

    the

    costs of

    more intensive

    recruiting

    and of additional

    labor

    market

    analyses.

    II.

    THE MODEL

    Our model for estimating the magnitude of the distributive

    effects and allocative costs

    (except

    for

    the incentive and

    uncertainty

    2.

    As a

    result,

    the civilian

    economy

    tends to have too low a

    labor/

    capital

    ratio,

    for

    a

    given

    level of

    aggregate employment

    in

    the total

    economy

    (including

    the

    military).

    Offsetting

    this

    tendency

    perhaps,

    is the

    desire

    of

    military

    officials to court

    public

    favor

    by

    holding

    down

    the

    size of the draft

    call.

    3.

    A

    relatively high

    rate of

    turnover

    is

    not inherent

    in

    the

    draft

    system,

    since,

    obviously,

    men could be

    drafted

    for

    any

    desired

    period. However,

    our

    society

    has

    chosen

    to make

    the

    period

    of

    compulsory

    duty

    rather

    brief,

    in

    part,

    no

    doubt,

    to offset

    the

    loss of

    job

    freedom and income

    imposed

    on draftees.

    402

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    10/28

    ECONOMICS

    OF

    THE

    MILITARY

    DRAFT

    costs with

    which

    we are unable

    to

    deal)

    is

    most

    easily

    understood

    by

    reference

    to

    Figure

    I.

    At

    this

    point

    the

    model is

    set forth

    at

    the

    conceptual level,

    while

    in Part

    III

    its

    empirical counterparts

    are

    presented.

    We

    turn

    first to

    the use

    of the

    model

    for

    estimating

    the

    draft

    system's

    labor

    mobility

    costs

    which

    are a

    major

    portion

    of

    total

    allocative

    costs.

    As

    noted

    in

    Section

    I,

    the

    efficient

    allocation

    of

    labor

    between

    the

    military

    services

    and

    the

    civilian

    sector

    requires

    that civilian

    opportunity

    costs

    be

    minimized, given

    the number

    and

    quality

    of

    men taken

    into

    the

    services.

    The cumulative

    distribution

    of values of such civilian opportunities (marginal productivities)

    for

    men

    of the

    specified

    quality,

    y,

    is

    given

    by S,

    in

    Figure

    I. The

    number

    of

    draft-affected

    men

    required

    by

    the

    military

    services is

    N

    4.

    In

    Figure

    I

    the

    marginal

    opportunity

    cost

    of ON

    men

    is

    NB

    ;$/Yr

    iSy

    W

    E

    v

    ,oD

    A

    O

    N T

    Number

    of

    Men

    FIGURE

    A

    Model

    of Allocative

    Costs

    and Distributive

    Effects

    of

    the

    Draft

    and

    the

    total

    opportunity

    cost

    is

    OABN

    or

    fSydN.

    OABN

    is

    the

    minimum

    total

    foregone

    civilian

    output

    consistent

    with

    acquisition

    by

    the

    military

    services

    of N

    men of

    quality

    y,

    given

    the stock

    of

    4. We

    retain

    the

    assumption,

    from

    Section

    I,

    that

    manpower

    needs

    are

    a

    given

    -

    that

    is,

    they

    are

    determined

    exogenously.

    403

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    11/28

    QUARTERLY

    JOURNAL

    OF

    ECONOMICS

    resources,

    the

    state

    of

    technology,

    and

    individual

    preferences

    -

    in-

    cluding preferences

    between civilian

    and

    military

    service

    employ-

    ment.

    OV

    (=

    OABN

    -

    ON)

    is

    the

    corresponding

    minimum

    average

    foregone

    civilian

    output.

    The distance OV

    may

    also be viewed as

    an

    estimate

    of the

    average

    civilian

    output

    that

    would

    be

    foregone

    if

    there were a

    voluntary

    system

    of

    military

    manpower

    procurement.

    Thus,

    if this

    minimum

    foregone

    civilian

    output

    is

    compared

    with

    actual

    foregone

    civilian

    output

    under

    the

    draft

    system,

    the

    differ-

    ence

    represents

    an

    estimate

    of the cost

    of labor

    misallocation

    between

    the

    military

    and civilian

    sectors

    of

    the

    economy--what

    we have

    termed the labor-mobility

    allocative

    cost

    of

    the draft.5

    Actual

    foregone

    civilian

    output may

    be

    derived

    from

    Figure

    I

    with

    the

    aid

    of an

    additional

    assumption,

    namely,

    that the

    existing

    draft

    system

    makes selections

    among

    eligible

    men without

    reference,

    in

    general,

    to

    their

    civilian

    productivity

    -

    at

    least with

    respect

    to

    men within

    each

    quality

    class.6

    That

    is,

    the

    selection

    may

    be

    thought

    of

    as

    essentially

    a

    random

    drawing

    from

    the distribution

    of

    civilian

    labor

    productivities.7

    If the N men selected are assumed to constitute a random selec-

    tion

    from

    the

    group

    of

    T men

    (T

    >

    V)

    of

    quality

    y

    in the

    popula-

    tion,

    their

    average

    foregone

    civilian

    productivity,

    OM,

    will exceed

    OV

    per

    man,

    as

    long

    as

    Ty

    >

    Ny

    and

    Sy

    is

    not

    infinitely

    elastic

    throughout

    its

    range.

    The difference

    between

    the actual

    and

    mini-

    mum

    foregone

    productivity

    per

    man,

    OM

    -

    OV,

    is

    the

    average,

    the

    per

    man

    labor-mobility

    cost

    which

    results

    from

    the draft

    system's

    compulsory

    selection

    process,

    combined

    with

    its

    lack

    of

    regard

    for

    opportunity costs. The corresponding total labor mobility cost is

    OMCN-OVDN.

    At

    this

    stage

    we

    turn

    to

    the

    model's

    use

    in

    estimating

    the

    in-

    come-distributive

    effect

    of the

    draft

    system,

    in the form

    of

    the

    implicit

    income

    tax

    on

    draftees.

    We

    have

    already

    derived

    OMCN

    as

    the

    total

    foregone

    civilian

    productivity

    of

    draft-affected

    men.

    If

    we assume

    that

    wages

    in

    the

    civilian

    economy

    are

    equated

    with

    the value

    of

    marginal productivity,8

    then

    OMCN

    also

    represents

    gross

    foregone

    earnings

    of draftees. The difference between these

    gross

    foregone

    earnings

    and

    real

    earnings

    in service

    is

    the

    net

    fore-

    5.

    This assumes

    implicitly

    that

    the value

    of

    on-the-job

    training provided

    to

    servicemen

    is

    approximately

    the

    same

    as that

    which

    they

    would

    have

    re-

    ceived

    in

    the

    civilian

    economy.

    6.

    Operational

    measures

    of

    quality

    are

    discussed

    in

    Part III.

    7.

    This is

    not

    to

    argue

    that

    the

    selection

    process

    is

    actually

    random,

    even within

    education

    classes,

    but

    only

    that

    such

    an

    assumption

    seems

    to

    be

    a useful and

    reasonable

    approximation.

    8.

    Because

    of market

    imperfections,

    the

    assumption

    is not

    entirely

    valid.

    404

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    12/28

    ECONOMICS OF

    THE

    MILITARY

    DRAFT

    gone

    earnings

    of

    draftees--their

    implicit

    income tax.

    In

    Figure

    I

    the

    value

    of

    draftee's

    earnings

    in

    service-including

    income

    in

    kind (not only food, shelter, etc., but also the civilian value of

    military

    training

    programs),

    as well

    as

    in

    cash-is

    denoted

    by

    W;

    W

    is

    assumed

    to

    be

    the same

    for

    all

    draftees,

    regardless

    of

    their

    civilian

    earnings

    opportunities.

    The

    difference,

    OM

    -

    OW,

    is

    the

    implicit

    annual income

    tax

    per

    draftee,

    and,

    of

    course,

    OMCN

    -

    OWEN

    is the

    total

    implicit

    tax

    on

    all

    draftees.9

    Thus far we

    have

    shown

    how,

    in

    principle,

    the

    labor-mobility

    costs and certain

    income-redistributive

    effects

    of

    the

    draft can

    be

    estimated, taking military manpower needs as given. Now let us

    modify

    somewhat our

    assumption

    that

    military

    manpower

    needs

    are determined

    exogenously.

    Presumably,

    military

    manpower

    requirements

    relate to

    the number

    of

    ready

    men

    (hereinafter

    denoted

    as

    R),

    not

    merely

    the number

    in

    uniform

    (N).

    That

    is,

    men

    involved

    in

    training

    -

    either as

    new recruits

    or as

    instructors

    or administrators

    of

    these

    new

    recruits

    -

    are not

    ready,

    although

    the

    instructor-administrator

    cadre

    could

    be

    withdrawn

    from

    those

    activities.

    The

    importance

    of

    the

    distinction

    between

    ready

    and

    nonready

    men

    is that

    the

    higher

    the

    rate

    of

    manpower

    turnover

    in

    the

    services,

    the smaller

    will

    be

    the

    fraction

    of

    men

    in

    uniform

    (N)

    who

    are

    ready,

    and,

    hence,

    the

    greater

    N will have

    to

    be

    to

    provide

    a

    given

    R.

    The

    presence

    of

    an

    implicit

    tax on draftees

    causes

    a

    higher

    turn-

    over

    rate

    than

    would

    result

    from

    a

    voluntary

    system

    with

    competi-

    tive wage rates, and thus the current type of draft system causes

    N to

    be

    greater

    than

    it would

    be

    under

    a

    voluntary

    system,

    for

    a

    given

    R.

    This

    means that

    total

    labor-mobility

    costs,

    as well

    as the

    total

    implicit

    income tax--both

    of which

    are

    functions

    of

    N-

    would

    be

    lower

    under a

    voluntary system.1

    The

    relationship

    between

    R

    and

    N can

    be

    stated

    as follows:

    1

    1

    N

    =

    -pN

    +-pkN+R,

    or

    S

    S

    9.

    In

    principle,

    W

    could

    exceed

    M,

    in

    which

    case

    there

    would

    be

    an

    implicit

    negative

    ncometax

    on,

    or

    positive

    income

    transfer

    o,

    draftees.

    1.

    Insofar as

    there are

    political

    concerns

    about

    the

    dangers

    of

    a

    per-

    manent

    and

    completely

    professional

    military

    system,

    t

    would

    not be desirable

    to reduce

    the

    turnover

    rates to

    zero.

    However,

    the alternatives

    are not

    simply

    a

    zero

    rate or the

    high

    current

    rate;

    rather,

    there are

    many

    inter-

    mediate

    possibilities.

    The

    optimal

    rate

    would

    require

    a

    balancing

    of

    the

    political

    and the cost

    considerations.

    t would

    be

    possible

    o

    rely

    entirely

    upon

    a

    voluntary ystem

    and still

    avoid

    the

    political

    dangers

    of

    a

    professional

    ys-

    tem

    by

    simply

    requiring

    he vast

    majority

    of

    servicemen

    o retire

    after,

    say,

    ten years.

    405

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    13/28

    QUARTERLY

    JOURNAL OF

    ECONOMICS

    R

    N=

    R

    1-- (1

    + k)

    8

    where:

    s

    is

    the

    average

    period

    of

    service

    of

    draftees,

    in

    months

    (1/s

    is

    the

    turnover

    rate);

    p

    is the

    training

    period

    for

    draftees,

    in

    months;

    k

    is the ratio of

    training

    personnel

    to

    trainees;

    and

    N

    and

    R are as

    previously

    defined.

    The

    first term on

    the

    right-hand

    side

    of the first

    expression

    above

    indicates the

    number

    of men

    in

    uniform who are

    in

    training

    at a

    given

    point

    of

    time;

    the

    second

    term indicates

    the

    number

    of

    instructors and

    administrators,

    which is assumed

    to

    be

    a

    fixed frac-

    tion

    of

    trainees;

    and the final term

    indicates

    the

    number

    of

    ready

    men.

    It is

    clear

    from the

    equation

    that

    if

    the turnover

    rate

    (1/s)

    were

    reduced,

    then N could be

    reduced

    for a

    given R.

    Or,

    if

    N were

    held

    constant,

    R,

    k,

    or

    p

    could be

    increased

    -together

    or

    indi-

    vidually

    -

    thereby raising the quantity or quality of ready military

    personnel.

    Thus,

    additional

    savings

    would result from a

    voluntary

    system,

    if

    the

    average

    duration

    of

    service could be

    lengthened.

    III.

    EMPIRICALAPPLICATION

    In

    this section

    we estimate the

    distributive effects and the

    allocative costs

    of

    the

    draft,

    employing

    the

    model

    just

    described.

    The estimates are based on three alternative sets of assumptions, in

    order to

    test

    the

    sensitivity

    of the

    estimates to

    a

    wide

    range

    of

    pos-

    sibilities. Each

    assumption,

    hereinafter

    referred to as a

    case,

    in-

    volves

    a

    different

    interpretation

    of

    the

    quality

    of

    military

    man-

    power

    required,

    but

    in

    all

    cases

    a

    constant

    number of

    ready

    men is

    assumed.

    The

    three

    cases are described

    below.

    Throughout,

    the

    potential

    manpower

    pool

    is

    regarded

    as restricted

    to those men

    aged

    eighteen

    to twenty-four who are capable of meeting the physical and mental

    standards established

    by

    the

    military

    services.2

    Such

    men

    are

    referred

    to

    as

    eligibles

    or

    eligible

    men.

    Case

    1: This

    case

    assumes

    that the

    military

    productivity

    of

    men

    differs

    according

    to their

    quality

    characteristics,

    quality being

    2.

    This

    age range

    is used

    only

    to facilitate

    the

    empirical

    work;

    census

    data

    are

    reported

    for

    this

    age

    bracket.

    During

    the

    period

    of the

    early

    sixties,

    as well

    as at the

    time

    of

    this

    writing,

    the

    actual

    manpower

    pool

    was

    from

    age

    181/2

    to

    26,

    except

    for

    physicians,

    whose

    eligibility

    continued

    to

    age

    35.

    406

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    14/28

    ECONOMICS OF

    THE MILITARY

    DRAFT

    measured here

    solely by

    years

    of

    educational

    attainment.

    It

    as-

    sumes

    further that all

    men of

    a

    given

    educational

    level are

    equally

    adequate

    to meet the needs

    of the

    services, provided they

    are

    eligible

    men.

    Finally,

    it

    assumes that

    the

    current

    education-age

    distribution

    of

    military

    manpower

    is to

    be

    maintained.

    Case 2: An

    objection

    to Case

    1

    is

    that

    all

    eligible

    men of

    a

    given

    age

    and educational

    level

    may

    not be

    equally productive

    in

    service.

    Thus,

    whereas

    Case

    1 assumed that

    educational attainment

    alone

    was

    an

    adequate

    measure of

    military-manpower

    quality

    for

    all

    men needed

    by

    the

    services,

    Case

    2

    assumes that

    it is

    an

    adequate

    measure

    for only 75 per cent of them. For the other 25 per cent,

    civilian

    income

    potential

    is also

    regarded

    as

    an

    indicator

    of

    quality,

    i.e.,

    those

    men

    with

    higher

    income

    potential

    are assumed

    to

    have

    higher

    productivity

    in

    the

    service.

    And,

    as

    in

    Case

    1,

    the

    current

    education-age

    distribution

    of

    military

    manpower

    is

    held constant.

    Case

    3: For

    contrast,

    a much

    less

    stringent

    case

    is

    examined.

    This

    case

    assumes

    that the

    military

    services

    find all

    eligibles

    equally

    acceptable,

    irrespective

    of

    differences

    in

    level

    of

    education

    and

    civilian incomes.3 We therefore relax the assumption that the cur-

    rent

    education-age

    distribution

    of

    servicemen is

    held

    constant,

    though

    the

    number of

    men is

    still

    maintained.

    For

    each

    of these

    cases

    -

    that

    is,

    for

    each

    set

    of

    assumptions

    about

    military-manpower

    quality

    requirements-the

    distributive

    effects

    and the

    (labor-mobility)

    allocative costs

    are estimated.

    The

    manner in

    which

    this

    is

    done is summarized

    below,4

    by

    presenting

    empirical

    counterparts

    to

    the

    concepts

    presented

    in

    Section

    II

    and

    Figure I. The Sy curve in Figure I is now represented by the

    cumulative

    distribution of

    actual civilian

    incomes

    of

    males

    aged

    18-24

    in

    1959,

    as obtained from

    Census

    publications,

    but

    adjusted

    to

    full-year

    bases.

    Actually,

    five such

    distributions,

    S,

    curves,

    were

    utilized,

    one for each of five

    level-of-education

    groups:

    0-8

    years,

    9-11

    years,

    12

    years,

    13-15

    years,

    and

    16

    or more

    years.

    The

    positive intercept,

    OA,

    reflects

    the

    assumption

    that

    men with in-

    comes below

    that level

    are

    rejected

    for

    military

    service. This

    results

    from the obviously simplifying assumption that those men unable

    to

    meet

    physical

    and mental

    standards have the lowest

    civilian

    in-

    come

    opportunities

    among

    men

    in

    their

    age

    and

    educational

    group.5

    3.

    While

    the

    need for some

    high quality

    personnel

    is

    recognized,

    it

    may

    be

    assumed

    that

    such

    personnel

    are obtained

    through

    normal

    enlistment

    channels.

    4.

    Additional details

    are

    presented

    in an

    appendix,

    available on

    request

    from

    the

    authors.

    5.

    The

    education-specific

    rejection

    rates are:

    grade

    school

    graduates

    or

    less-70

    per

    cent;

    1-3

    years high

    school-32

    per

    cent; high

    school

    gradu-

    407

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    15/28

    QUARTERLY

    JOURNAL OF

    ECONOMICS

    The

    number of

    men of each

    quality,

    y,

    required,

    ON

    in

    Figure

    I,

    is

    the

    difference between

    the number of

    draft-age

    men in

    the

    services

    and the

    number

    who

    have

    voluntarily

    enlisted.

    Since

    such

    volunteers

    are

    presumably

    better

    off because

    of

    their

    choices,

    we are

    concerned

    only

    with the

    remaining

    group

    when

    estimating

    the

    distributive

    effects

    and

    allocative costs

    of

    the draft

    system.

    This

    remaining

    group, numbering 650,000

    in

    fiscal

    year

    1963,

    consists

    of

    182,000

    draftees,

    plus

    an

    estimated

    468,000

    draft-affected

    en-

    listees

    who would

    not have enlisted but

    for

    the existence of

    the

    draft.

    Draft-affected enlistees

    have

    been estimated

    to constitute 40

    per

    cent of total first enlistees.6

    Let us

    now

    present

    the

    empirical

    values

    for

    the

    key

    variables

    shown

    in

    Figure

    I.

    In

    doing

    this,

    we

    shall

    give

    only

    the

    values

    ag-

    gregated

    over all

    education

    groups; thus,

    for

    purposes

    of the en-

    suing

    discussion,

    the

    AS,

    curve

    of

    Figure

    I

    should

    be

    interpreted

    as

    a

    summation of

    the five

    AS,

    curves.

    It

    should

    be

    noted that our

    empirical

    method abstracts

    from

    any disutility

    associated

    with

    employment

    in

    the

    military

    services. This

    point

    is

    discussed further

    in Section IV.

    The

    distance

    OW, average

    annual

    compensation

    (including

    in-

    come

    in

    kind)

    of

    draft-affected

    men,

    is

    estimated at

    $2400

    in

    1959.7

    OV,

    the mean

    annual minimum

    civilian income

    per

    male

    aged

    18-

    24,

    varies

    with

    educational

    level,

    but

    averages

    almost

    $2100.

    OM,

    the mean

    annual

    gross foregone

    income

    per

    draft-affected

    man

    currently

    in

    service,

    also

    varies

    with educational

    level,

    but

    averages

    around

    $3900.

    Given the quality assumptions of Case 1, OABN, the smallest

    total

    foregone

    civilian

    productivity

    at which ON

    men

    can

    be

    ob-

    tained,

    is

    some

    $1.3

    billion

    per year. Then,

    assuming

    that the

    draft

    system

    takes

    men

    randomly

    from within each of

    the

    five

    distribu-

    tions, ASy,

    the

    actual

    foregone

    civilian

    productivity,

    OMCN,

    is

    in

    excess of

    $2.5

    billion

    per year.

    The

    difference,

    VMCD

    (=

    AMCB),

    ates-

    26

    per

    cent;

    1-3

    years

    college--18 per

    cent;

    college graduates--16

    per

    cent;

    overall

    average-36

    per

    cent.

    (Source:

    unpublished

    Defense De-

    partmentdata.)

    6. For a

    full discussion

    f

    the

    method

    used

    to

    estimate the numberof

    draft-affected

    nlistees,

    ee the

    appendix

    eferred

    o

    in

    fn.

    4,

    p.

    407.

    7. The

    $2,400

    igure

    appears

    o have been

    reasonably

    onstant

    between

    1959

    and

    1962,

    he

    period

    o whichour various

    data

    apply.

    It

    shouldbe noted

    that the

    $2,400

    igure,

    while

    quite comprehensive,

    oes

    not

    include

    any

    valuationof

    training

    received

    in

    service.

    However,

    to

    the

    extent that

    draft-affected

    men are

    in

    service

    for

    only

    a rathershort

    period,

    any training-of

    the sort that has value

    in

    the

    civilian

    economy-that

    they

    do

    receive

    may

    not be

    significantly

    reater

    han

    the

    on-the-job

    raining

    and

    experience

    eceived

    by

    civilian

    workers. It is

    only

    this

    difference

    hat

    shouldbe

    addedto the

    $2,400 igure.

    408

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    16/28

    409

    CONOMICS

    OF THE

    MILITARY

    DRAFT

    the estimated

    excess allocative burden

    of the

    draft,

    is

    nearly

    $1.2

    billion

    per

    year,

    as shown

    in Table

    I.

    In Case 1 the distributive effect of the draft, the difference

    between

    actual service

    income and

    foregone

    gross

    civilian income

    for

    all

    education

    groups,

    is OMCN

    -

    OWEN,

    or

    roughly

    $2.5

    bil-

    lion

    minus

    $1.5

    billion-

    slightly

    below

    $1

    billion

    per year.

    TABLE

    I

    ANNUAL

    DISTRIBUTIVE

    EFFECTS

    AND

    ANNUAL ALLOCATIVE COSTS

    *

    OF MILITARY DRAFT

    SYSTEM,

    TOTAL

    AND

    PER

    MAN,

    1959

    (in dollars)

    Total Costs

    (millions)

    Cost Per Man

    Illustrative Case

    Distributive Allocative Distributive Allocative

    Effects Costs

    Effects Costs

    (1) (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    Case 1

    960

    1,180

    1,480 1,820

    Case 2

    960

    870

    1,480 1,350

    Case

    3

    990

    1,120

    1,520

    1,730

    *Includes

    only

    labor-mobility

    effect.

    In

    Case

    2

    the

    distributive

    effects

    are identical

    with

    those in

    Case

    1,

    since

    in

    both

    cases

    the

    rate of

    military pay

    is

    the

    same,

    and it is

    assumed

    that

    the

    draft

    system

    takes

    men

    at

    random

    from

    within

    each

    distribution,

    AS,. However,

    the allocative

    costs

    are

    substan-

    tially

    lower. For

    it

    is assumed

    that

    with

    respect

    to 25

    per

    cent

    of

    the men

    selected,

    the

    difference between their

    civilian and

    military

    productivity

    is

    zero;

    and

    the

    military

    is

    assumed

    to

    require

    this

    fraction of high productivity (high income) men. In Case 1 no such

    requirement

    is

    assumed

    -

    although

    in

    both cases

    some

    high

    income

    men are

    obtained

    through

    the random

    selection

    process.

    We

    turn now to

    Case

    3.

    If

    military

    manpower

    needs were

    simply

    for men

    who

    could

    meet

    the induction

    standards

    of

    1963

    -

    the

    year

    to

    which our

    manpower

    data

    apply-

    then

    qualitative

    characteristics such

    as

    education

    and

    civilian income

    (productivity)

    opportunities

    could

    be

    disregarded.

    In

    this

    case, application

    of our

    model would require only a single distribution of earnings for all

    men

    eighteen

    to

    twenty-four

    and

    an

    aggregate

    rejection

    rate. The

    procedure

    for

    estimating

    labor-mobility

    allocative

    costs

    and

    distri-

    butive

    effects

    is

    then identical with that used

    in

    Case 1.

    Table

    I

    shows,

    somewhat

    surprisingly,

    that these

    costs

    and

    effects

    are

    very

    nearly

    the same for Cases

    1

    and

    3. Two

    forces

    operate

    to

    produce

    this result for the allocative

    costs.

    First,

    be-

    cause the

    educational distribution

    of

    military

    personnel

    does

    not

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    17/28

    QUARTERLY

    JOURNAL

    OF ECONOMICS

    differ

    significantly

    from

    that for all

    males

    in

    the

    draft-age group,

    the

    level

    of

    foregone

    civilian

    earnings

    in

    Case

    3

    is

    very

    close to

    that

    in

    Case

    1.

    Second,

    the fact that

    in

    Case

    3

    the

    minimum-earnings

    cut-

    off

    (NB

    in

    Figure

    I)

    is

    implicitly

    the same for all education

    groups,

    while

    it

    varies

    from

    group

    to

    group

    in Case

    1,8

    gives

    rise to

    only

    a

    small

    change

    in

    the

    minimum

    opportunity

    cost

    of

    the draft.9

    The

    net

    impact

    of

    these

    forces

    causes

    a

    slight

    reduction

    in

    total

    alloca-

    tive

    cost in

    Case 3.

    The distributive

    effect

    differs

    slightly

    in Case

    3

    (relative

    to both Cases

    1 and

    2),

    because

    civilian

    incomes

    (op-

    portunity

    costs)

    change

    as

    a

    result

    of

    dropping

    the

    assumption

    that

    the

    current

    education mix is

    held

    constant.

    In

    reviewing

    the results of

    Table I--the

    range

    of which

    is

    rather modest

    -

    three

    points

    should be

    remembered.

    (1)

    Only

    those

    distributive effects

    of

    the

    military

    draft

    system

    resulting

    from

    the

    implicit

    income

    tax

    which

    the draft

    imposes,

    and

    only

    those

    alloca-

    tive

    costs

    of the

    military

    draft

    system

    stemming

    from restrictions

    on

    labor

    mobility,

    have been considered.

    (2)

    The distributive

    effects

    and allocative

    costs

    shown

    are not

    additive,

    since

    the

    latter

    are real costs, while the former are transfers. (3)

    All

    of

    the

    esti-

    mates

    are

    based

    on 1959

    income

    data,

    even

    though

    the

    1963

    dis-

    tribution

    and mix

    of servicemen

    are

    used.

    In

    deriving

    the results

    presented

    in Table

    I it was

    pointed

    out

    that

    the number

    of men

    required

    for

    the

    services

    was

    held constant.

    However,

    it

    was also

    pointed

    out

    earlier

    in the

    paper

    that if

    we

    assume

    that the

    number

    of

    ready

    men,

    rather

    than

    the total

    number

    of men

    in

    service,

    is

    to

    be held

    constant,

    then

    a smaller

    total num-

    ber of servicemen would be required if the rate of turnover could be

    reduced

    -

    as it would

    be

    under a

    system

    offering

    more attractive

    rates

    of

    compensation.

    At

    this

    point

    we use

    the turnover

    model

    presented

    in

    Section

    II to

    re-estimate the values

    in Table

    I,

    under several

    different

    as-

    sumptions

    about

    the

    relevant

    parameters

    of the

    model.

    If

    in this

    model we hold

    all

    variables

    constant

    at

    their

    current

    values,

    and

    allow

    only

    length

    of

    service,

    r,

    to

    increase

    -

    as it

    would

    if the turn-

    8. The minimum average (per draftee and nonvoluntary enlistee) income

    that would

    have

    to be

    paid,

    or-

    equivalently--the

    minimum civilian

    pro-

    ductivity

    that would have to

    be

    foregone

    in

    order

    to obtain

    the 1963

    num-

    bers

    of men

    with

    the 1963

    educational

    attainments,

    is as follows:

    grade

    school

    -$2,980;

    1 to 3

    years

    of

    high

    school-$2,100;

    high-school

    graduate-

    $2,050;

    1

    to 3

    years

    of

    college--$1,630;

    college graduate-$1,680;

    and a

    weighted

    total--

    $2,060.

    One

    possible

    implication

    of

    differential cutoffs

    is

    discussed

    in

    Section

    IV.

    9.

    The

    minimum

    income cutoff

    for all men is

    $2,010.

    This

    cutoff

    must

    fall

    below the

    $2,060 figure

    referred

    to

    in the

    previous footnote,

    because

    a

    uniform cutoff

    minimizes

    the

    aggregate

    minimum

    foregone

    income

    (opportunity

    costs)

    for the

    given

    level of

    manpower

    obtained.

    410

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    18/28

    ECONOMICS

    OF

    THE MILITARY DRAFT

    411

    over rate

    were

    cut

    -

    then

    the number of

    men

    needed, N,

    is

    reduced

    by

    the amounts indicated in column

    1

    of Table II.

    Columns

    3

    and

    4

    indicate

    how

    much

    the total

    labor-mobility

    allocative costs

    and

    the

    total

    distributive effects

    shown

    in Table

    I

    would

    be

    reduced as

    duration

    of

    service is

    increased. It

    should

    be borne

    in

    mind that

    average

    duration of service

    could

    be

    increased

    in

    various

    ways,

    not

    only by

    enlarging

    rates

    of

    compensation,

    but also

    by

    extending

    the current

    two-year

    draft

    period.

    TABLE II

    ANNUAL ALLOCATIVEAND DISTRIBUTIVE EFFECTS OF. REDUCED

    TURNOVER

    OF

    MILITARY MANPOWER

    Reduction

    in Number of

    Draft-Affected

    Men

    in Annual Reduction

    *

    in

    Service

    (compared

    with

    Average

    Years

    the

    650,000

    in

    service

    Allocative Distributive

    of

    Service

    in

    1963)

    Costs Effects

    (in

    millions (in

    millions

    Total

    Per

    cent

    of

    dollars)

    of

    dollars)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3) (4)

    2

    0 0

    0

    0

    3 36,000 6 66 53

    5

    62,000

    10

    113

    92

    10

    80,000

    12

    146

    118

    20

    86,000

    13

    157

    127

    *

    From

    total amounts

    shown in Table I for

    Case

    1.

    IV.

    SOME

    EXTENSIONS OF

    THE ANALYSIS

    In this section we point out several implications of the con-

    cepts

    and

    findings

    discussed

    in

    this

    paper.

    Our

    objective

    is to be

    provocative

    and to

    suggest

    questions

    for further

    investigation,

    rather

    than to offer definitive conclusions.

    Particular

    caution should be

    exercised

    in

    interpreting

    the

    quantitative

    results in this

    section,

    for

    they

    are

    crude,

    being

    based

    on

    incomplete

    data and

    assump-

    tions that

    may

    require

    reconsideration.

    Nevertheless,

    some

    of

    the

    results

    are indeed

    striking

    and

    may

    warrant

    further

    refinement.

    A.

    The

    Relative Value

    of

    Educated

    Manpower

    to the Civilian

    and

    Military

    Sectors

    If

    it is assumed that

    the

    military

    services have

    the

    educational

    mix

    of men

    that is

    optimal,

    in the

    sense

    of

    equating

    the

    marginal

    military productivities

    of

    men in

    all of the

    educational

    classes,

    then

    the

    findings

    in

    Part

    III

    (including

    footnote

    8,

    p.

    410)

    concerning

    differential

    earnings

    cutoffs

    imply

    that a

    college-educated

    man who

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    19/28

    QUARTERLY

    JOURNAL

    OF ECONOMICS

    can

    earn as

    little

    as

    $1600

    per

    year

    in the civilian

    economy

    is

    just

    as

    valuable

    in the service

    as

    the

    elementary

    school educated

    man

    who

    can

    earn

    as

    much as

    $3000

    in the civilian

    economy.

    Thus,

    formal

    education

    is

    being

    treated

    as

    relatively

    more valuable in the

    military

    service than

    it is

    in

    the

    civilian

    economy.

    In

    a

    modern

    military

    system

    such

    a

    conclusion is not

    implausible,

    if

    it is true

    that the

    technology

    now

    employed by

    the

    military

    is

    more

    demand-

    ing

    of the

    skills

    of well-educated

    men than

    is the

    average technology

    employed

    in

    the

    civilian

    sector.

    Some

    notion as

    to

    whether the

    military

    services

    are

    using

    more

    advanced

    technology

    than

    the

    civilian

    economy

    in

    general might

    be

    obtained

    by

    determining

    whether the

    capital/labor

    ratio

    in the

    military-service

    sector

    is

    higher

    than

    it

    is

    in

    the civilian

    sector

    of

    the

    economy.

    If

    it

    is,

    we would seem

    to have

    found

    a

    justifica-

    tion

    for the observed

    differential

    income cutoffs

    according

    to

    educa-

    tional

    attainment.

    The

    data

    shown

    in Table

    III on

    capital/labor

    ratios

    for the

    military

    versus

    the civilian

    sectors

    of

    the

    economy

    are

    consistent

    with the hypothesis that the ratio of physical capital to labor is

    higher

    in

    the

    military

    sector.

    Measured

    by

    gross

    capital

    stock

    per

    man,

    in

    constant

    dollars,

    the

    military

    capital/labor

    ratio

    is

    double

    that

    for the civilian

    sector.

    Measured

    by

    net

    capital

    stock

    2

    per

    man,

    in

    constant

    dollars,

    the

    military

    capital/labor

    ratio

    slightly

    exceeds

    that

    for the

    civilian sector.3

    Another

    test

    might

    involve

    making

    a

    comparison

    of

    the

    occupa-

    tional

    distribution of

    servicemen

    (and

    particularly

    the

    army)

    with

    that for the labor force as a whole. Unfortunately, the needed data

    are not

    available,

    but

    if

    they

    were,

    we would

    expect

    to

    find a

    higher

    proportion

    of

    military

    personnel

    concentrated

    in

    heavily

    capital-

    using occupations.

    In

    summary,

    the

    available

    data do

    not

    run

    counter to

    the

    notion that

    military

    technology

    is

    more

    capital-using

    and

    thus,

    perhaps,

    more

    demanding

    of

    the

    skills

    of

    at

    least some better

    educated

    men.

    But

    additional work

    is

    required

    to

    give

    this con-

    clusion a firmer basis.

    1.

    Undepreciated apital

    stock;

    for a discussion

    of

    this

    concept

    see

    Raymond

    W.

    Goldsmith,

    The National Wealth

    of

    the

    United

    States

    in

    the

    Postwar

    Period

    (Princeton:

    Princeton

    University

    Press,

    1962).

    2.

    Gross

    capital

    stock

    less

    capital

    consumption

    llowances.

    3. It is

    worth

    pointing

    out that from

    the

    mid-1950's

    ntil

    at least

    1958,

    military

    capital/labor

    atios

    were

    rising

    more

    rapidly

    than were those

    in

    the

    private

    economy.

    For

    example,

    rom

    1955

    to

    1958

    the

    military capital/labor

    ratio

    rose

    by

    about 13

    per

    cent

    on

    a

    net

    capital

    stock basis

    (or

    11

    per

    cent

    on

    a

    gross

    basis),

    as

    contrastedwith

    a

    5

    per

    cent

    rise on a

    net

    basis

    for the

    civilian

    ratio.

    For

    data,

    see

    the source

    or

    Table

    III.

    412

  • 8/10/2019 Lee Hansen

    20/28

    ECONOMICS OF

    THE

    MILITARY DRAFT

    TABLE

    III

    CAPITAL/LABOR

    RATIOS,

    CIVILIAN

    AND

    MILITARY

    ECTORS,

    958

    (in

    constant

    1947-49

    prices)

    Capital

    Stock

    Labor Force

    Sector

    (in

    $

    billions)

    (in

    millions)

    Ratios

    Gross

    Net

    Gross

    (1)/(3)

    Net

    (2)/(3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3) (4)

    (5)

    Military

    130 44 2.6

    50

    17

    Civilian

    1,715

    1,022

    68.6 25 15

    Sources: Capital Stock: Raymond W. Goldsmith The National Wealth of the United

    States

    in

    the Postwar

    Period

    (Princeton:

    Princeton

    University

    Press, 1962).

    Tables

    B-172

    (sum

    of cols.

    1-3)

    and

    B-174

    (sum

    of cols.

    1-3)

    for

    military, gross

    and

    net,

    respectively;

    and

    Tables A-26

    (col.

    1)

    and

    A-28

    (col.

    1),

    for

    civilian,

    gross

    and

    net,

    respectively.

    Labor Force: Economic

    Report of

    the

    President,

    Jan.

    1966,

    Table C-20.

    B.

    The

    Military

    Manpower

    Supply

    Curve

    One of

    the

    analytical

    tools

    developed

    in

    this

    paper

    can be

    used

    to shed

    light

    on the

    nature

    of the

    supply

    curve

    for

    military

    man-

    power

    and

    on

    the

    extent of aversion

    to

    or

    preference

    for

    military

    service

    as

    compared

    with civilian

    employment.

    The

    key

    concept

    is

    the

    opportunity

    cost

    curve

    portrayed by

    AS,

    in

    Figure

    I.

    This

    curve can be

    interpreted

    as

    a

    special

    type

    of

    labor

    supply

    function

    for

    military

    manpower,

    under

    the

    assumption

    that

    men will

    work

    for

    whatever

    employer-military

    or

    civilian-pays

    the most

    (either

    in

    cash or

    in

    kind)

    or,

    in

    other

    words,

    that men

    have neither

    an aversion

    to

    nor

    preference

    for

    military

    employment.

    In

    this

    sec-

    tion we present this type of special labor supply curve based on an

    aggregate

    of

    Sy

    curves

    in

    Figure

    I,

    and

    subsequently

    use it

    to

    de-

    velop

    several estimates

    of actual labor

    supply

    curves.

    The

    first

    problem

    is

    to

    determine the

    shape

    of

    the

    opportunity-

    cost

    (supply)

    curve

    for

    the

    relevant

    range

    -

    namely,

    between

    the

    number

    of enlisted

    men of

    draft

    age

    currently

    in

    the services

    and

    the

    number that

    we estimate would

    be

    in

    the service

    voluntarily

    (i.e.,

    if

    there

    were

    no

    draft).

    This

    range,

    650,000,

    is the number of men

    for whom supply responses to wage increases are important.

    In

    Figure

    II,

    AS*y

    portrays

    this

    opportunity-cost (supply)

    curve. Point

    A

    indicates

    that if additional

    men of

    acceptable

    quality

    are to be

    obtained, they

    will have

    to be obtained at a

    civilian

    op-

    portunity

    cost of at least

    $1800.4

    The

    remainder

    of the

    curve

    AS*y

    4.

    This follows

    from our

    assumption

    that

    rejectees

    have the lowest

    civilian

    income

    opportunities

    i