hansen 1951

Upload: vishnu-girish

Post on 06-Jul-2018

222 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/17/2019 Hansen 1951

    1/5

    Classical, Loanable-Fund, and Keynesian Interest TheoriesAuthor(s): Alvin H. HansenSource: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 65, No. 3 (Aug., 1951), pp. 429-432Published by: Oxford University PressStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1882223 .

    Accessed: 18/06/2014 22:41

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

     .JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of 

    content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms

    of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

     .

    Oxford University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Quarterly

     Journal of Economics.

    http://www.jstor.org

    This content downloaded from 195.78.109.96 on Wed, 18 Jun 2014 22:41:42 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=ouphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/1882223?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/1882223?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=oup

  • 8/17/2019 Hansen 1951

    2/5

    CLASSICAL,

    LOANABLE-FUND,

    AND KEYNESIAN INTEREST THEORIES

    By

    ALVIN

    H. HANSEN

    Keynes

    attacked

    the classical theory f interest n the

    ground

    that it is

    indeterminate.According

    o

    classical

    theorythe rate is

    determined

    y the intersection f

    the investment

    emand-schedule

    and thesaving-schedule

    schedulesdisclosing

    herelation f nvest-

    ment and

    saving

    to the

    rate

    of interest. No solution,

    however, s

    possiblebecause the positionof the saving-schedulewill vary with

    the

    level of real income.

    As income

    rises,

    the schedule will

    shift o

    the

    right.

    Thus we cannotknow what the rate

    of interestwill

    be

    unless

    we

    already

    know

    the

    income evel. And we cannot know the

    income evel without

    already

    knowing he rate of interest,

    ince a

    lower

    nterest ate

    willmean a largervolume

    of investment,

    nd so,

    via

    the

    multiplier,

    higher

    evel of real ncome.The classicalanalysis,

    therefore

    ffers

    o

    solution.

    Now exactly he same criticismppliesto the Keynesiantheory.

    According

    o the Keynesian

    theory he rate of

    nterest s

    determined

    by the ntersection f

    the supply-schedule

    f

    money perhaps

    nterest

    inelastic,

    f

    rigorously

    ixed by

    the monetaryauthority)

    and the

    demand-schedule

    ormoney the

    iquidity-preference

    chedule).

    This

    analysis

    also

    is

    indeterminate

    ecause the

    liquidity-preference

    ched-

    ule

    will shift

    p

    or down with

    changes

    n

    the income

    evel. Here

    we

    are

    concerned

    with the total

    liquidity-preference

    chedule

    ncluding

    both the transactions demandand the asset demandformoney.

    If

    we separate

    the total demand schedule

    for

    money

    into

    its

    two

    component

    arts,

    we could

    perhaps

    argue

    that the

    pure

    liquidity-

    preference

    chedule

    is independentof the

    level of income.'

    But

    this does

    not

    help

    matters,

    ince

    we cannot

    know,given

    the

    total

    money upply,

    how much

    money

    will

    be available

    to

    hold

    as an asset

    unlesswe

    first

    nowthe evel of

    ncome. Thus

    the

    Keynesian

    theory,

    like the classical,

    s

    indeterminate.

    n the Keynesian

    case the money

    supplyand demand-schedulesannotgivethe rateof nterest nless

    we

    already

    know the

    income evel;

    in

    the classical

    case

    the

    demand

    and

    supply

    schedulesfor aving

    offer

    o

    solutionuntil

    the

    income

    s

    known.

    Keynes' criticism f the

    classical theory

    pplies equally

    to

    his

    own

    theory.

    1.

    In fact since expectations are

    influenced by

    the

    level

    of income

    this

    is

    not a permissible assumption.

    The

    liquidity preference case

    is therefore ven

    weaker

    than

    here

    indicated.

    429

    This content downloaded from 195.78.109.96 on Wed, 18 Jun 2014 22:41:42 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/17/2019 Hansen 1951

    3/5

    430

    QUARTERLY JOURNAL

    OF ECONOMICS

    Precisely

    he same s trueof

    the oanable-fundheory.According

    to the loanable-fund

    nalysis, the rate of interest

    s determined

    y

    the intersectionf the demand-schedule or oanable fundswith the

    supply-schedule.

    Now the supply-schedule

    f loanable funds is

    compounded f

    saving in the Robertsonian

    ense) plus net additions

    to loanable funds from new

    money and the

    dishoarding of

    idle

    balances. But since the savings

    portion of the

    schedule varies

    with he evel

    of disposable income,2t follows hat

    the total supply-

    schedule of oanable

    funds lso

    varies with ncome.

    Thus this theory

    is also indeterminate.

    In the loanable-fund heory,the relevant supply-schedules

    conceivedof

    n terms f oanable

    funds i.e., voluntary

    aving plus

    new money).

    In the neo-classical

    theory of Pigou, however, the

    relevant upply-schedules conceived

    n terms f aving

    out ofcurrent

    income. Saving

    is defined s

    the excess of total income received

    over income

    received for services n providing

    for consumption. '

    Again, in the

    same vein, aggregatemoney saving

    is defined

    s

    the excess of

    money

    income over expenditures n consumption

    goods. 4 Here income, consumption, nd saving,all apply to the

    same

    period. Money savings are

    that part of current

    ncomewhich

    is not consumed. Now current

    ncome is derived

    from current

    expenditures.

    Whether r not

    current ncome s fed n part from

    he

    injection f newmoney r from

    he activationof dle

    balances, makes

    no difference

    hatever rom he

    standpoint f the

    Pigouvian or neo-

    classical definition.5

    ncome is income whether

    t springs

    rom

    he

    spending of

    funds borrowed frombanks or from

    the spending

    of

    prior ncome;and saving from uch income s saving even though

    bank credit

    played

    a

    role

    n

    the process

    of

    ncome

    creation.6

    Accord-

    ingly,

    n

    Pigouvianor neo-classical

    heory, saving

    is

    in

    effect

    he

    same

    thing

    s

    loanable

    funds.

    In

    Robertsonian

    anguage,however,

    loanable funds consist of voluntary

    saving

    (i.e., saving

    out

    of

    disposable

    income) plus borrowed

    bank fundsand

    activated

    idle

    balances.

    In

    Pigouvian anguage, aving out

    of current

    ncome

    may

    well exceed

    voluntary or Robertsonian) aving

    n so far

    s

    current

    income s increasedby bank loans or the injectionof idle balances.

    2. Disposable income

    is here used in the Robertsonian sense,

    i.e.,

    yesterday's income.

    3. See A. C. Pigou, Employment nd Equilibrium, p. 30.

    4. Ibid, p. 31.

    5. It is important to be clear about the implications

    of

    these

    definitions

    when

    people or governments borrow

    from the banks. Everybody

    agrees that

    money so borrowedonly becomes

    income when t is paid out, for ervices

    rendered,

    to factors of production (ibid,

    p. 30).

    6.

    Ibid, p. 30.

    This content downloaded from 195.78.109.96 on Wed, 18 Jun 2014 22:41:42 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/17/2019 Hansen 1951

    4/5

    INTEREST

    THEORIES

    431

    Thus the

    Pigouviansupply-schedule

    f savings

    amounts

    to the same

    thing as

    the Robertsonian

    or Swedish

    supply-schedule

    f loanable

    funds. It is therefore ot necessary o distinguish urther etween

    them,

    nd hereafter

    shall refer nly

    to

    the neo-classical7

    heory

    n

    theone side,

    and

    theKeynesian

    on

    the other.

    The neo-classical

    formulation

    nd the

    Keynesian

    formulation,

    takentogether,

    o supply

    us with

    an adequate

    theory f the

    rate

    of

    interest.

    From

    the neo-classical

    formulation

    we get

    a family

    of

    saving-schedules

    t various

    income

    evels. These

    together

    with the

    investment-demand

    chedule8

    give

    us the Hicksian

    IS curve.

    In

    otherwords,the neoclassical formulationells us what the various

    levels

    of ncome

    will be

    (given

    the

    investment-demand

    cheduleand

    family f

    saving-schedules)

    t different

    ates of

    interest.

    From

    the

    Keynesianformulation

    we get

    a family

    of liquidity

    preference

    chedules

    at various

    income evels.

    These together

    with

    the

    supplyof

    money

    fixedby the

    monetary

    uthority, ive

    us

    the

    Hicksian

    L

    curve (which

    prefer o

    call the

    LM

    curve ).9

    The

    LM curve

    tells us what

    the

    various

    rates of

    interest

    will be (given

    thequantityofmoney nd thefamily f iquidity-preferenceurves)

    at differentevels of

    ncome. But the

    iquidity

    chedule

    lone

    cannot

    tell

    us

    what

    the

    rate of interest

    will be.

    The IS curve

    and the

    LM curve

    are

    functions elating

    he

    two

    variables: (1)

    incomeand

    (2)

    the rateinterest.

    Income

    and the

    rate

    of interest

    re therefore

    etermined

    ogether

    t the

    point

    of

    intersection

    f these two

    curves

    or

    schedules.

    At this

    point

    income

    and the rate of interest

    tand

    in

    a relation

    o

    each other

    uch

    that:

    (1) investmentnd saving re n equilibriumi.e.,actualsavingequals

    desired aving)

    and (2) the

    demand

    formoney

    s

    in

    equilibrium

    with

    the

    supply

    of money

    i.e., the desired

    amountof

    money s

    equal

    to

    the

    actual

    supply

    of

    money).

    Thus

    a determinate

    heory

    f nterest

    s based

    on: (1) the

    nvest-

    ment demand function, 2)

    the saving-function

    or

    conversely

    he

    7. The classical

    theory

    may be said to

    coincide

    with the

    neo-classical

    or

    Pigouvian theory

    n

    the special case

    in which

    no new

    money is- eing created

    by

    the banking systemand in which idle balances are not being dishoarded.

    8.

    Perhaps

    a family

    of

    investment-demand

    schedules,

    one for each

    level

    of income.

    Everyone

    will agree

    that a change

    n the level of income

    affects

    he

    volume

    of investment,but

    not everyone

    will agree that

    the level

    of

    income

    is

    a

    determinant

    of net nvestment.

    9. See

    my Monetary

    heory nd

    Fiscal

    Policy,Chapter5.

    The

    LM

    curve

    represents

    situation

    in which

    L

    =

    M in an equilibrium

    sense, L meaning

    the demand for money,and

    M

    the supply

    of money.

    Similarly

    the

    IS curve

    indicates

    a condition

    n which

    I

    =

    S

    in an equilibrium

    sense

    (i.e., the multiplier

    process has

    fully worked

    itself

    out).

    This content downloaded from 195.78.109.96 on Wed, 18 Jun 2014 22:41:42 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

  • 8/17/2019 Hansen 1951

    5/5

    432

    QUARTERLY

    JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

    consumptionfunction),

    3) the liquidity

    preference unction,

    nd

    (4) the quantity

    of

    money. The

    Keynesiananalysis,

    ooked

    at as a

    whole, nvolvedall of these. But Keynes neverbroughtthemall

    together n

    a comprehensive

    ay to

    formulate n integrated

    nterest

    theory.

    He failed to

    point out specificallyhat

    liquidity

    preference

    plus the

    quantityofmoney can give

    us not the

    rate of interest,

    ut

    only an

    LM

    curve.

    It was left

    forHicks' to supply us

    with the

    tools

    needed

    for comprehensive

    nalysis.

    ALVIN H. HANSEN.

    HARVARD UNIVERSITY

    1.

    Econometrica,

    Volume V, 1937, 147-59.

    This content downloaded from 195.78.109.96 on Wed, 18 Jun 2014 22:41:42 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp