industry self-regulation as a solution of reputation commons - usc

35
Chapter 14 Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution to the Reputation Commons Problem: The Case of the New York Clearing House Association Lori Qingyuan Yue Paul Ingram The performance of organizations depends partly on the reputations of their industries. Such reputations are “intangible commons.” Interest in protecting mutual welfare motivates members of an industry to engage in self-regulation. However, the current literature tends to have a pessimistic view of the efficacy of self-regulation in solving the problem of reputational commons. We argue that the obstacles forecasted by such pessimistic reasoning are context- bound and can be overcome if industry self-regulation includes effective sanctions and exclusion strategies. We investigate the case of the New York Clearing House Association, a community- based self-regulatory program, which, by promoting prudence among members, successfully ameliorated the negative spillover effect on market confidence during bank panics. We then identify five conditions that account for the efficacy of this self-regulation. We conclude by

Upload: others

Post on 10-Feb-2022

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

Chapter 14

Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution to the Reputation

Commons Problem: The Case of the New York Clearing

House Association

Lori Qingyuan Yue

Paul Ingram

The performance of organizations depends partly on the reputations of their industries. Such

reputations are “intangible commons.” Interest in protecting mutual welfare motivates members

of an industry to engage in self-regulation. However, the current literature tends to have a

pessimistic view of the efficacy of self-regulation in solving the problem of reputational

commons. We argue that the obstacles forecasted by such pessimistic reasoning are context-

bound and can be overcome if industry self-regulation includes effective sanctions and exclusion

strategies. We investigate the case of the New York Clearing House Association, a community-

based self-regulatory program, which, by promoting prudence among members, successfully

ameliorated the negative spillover effect on market confidence during bank panics. We then

identify five conditions that account for the efficacy of this self-regulation. We conclude by

Page 2: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

showing how research on institutional solutions to the problem of reputation commons can be

extended.

INTRODUCTION

The performance of organizations depends partly on the reputations of their industries. These

reputations are “intangible commons” because organizations share both the penalties and

rewards associated with the reputations of their industries. Interest in protecting mutual welfare

motivates members of an industry to engage in self-regulation. However, current literature tends

to hold a pessimistic view of self-regulation’s ability to solve the problem of industry

reputational commons. This pessimistic view is rooted in three lines of reasoning: (1)

competitive relations within the same industry will undermine the willingness of organizations to

cooperate; (2) a collective solution will suffer from opportunism and is thus unlikely to be

successful; (3) a collective solution is likely to be exploited by a group of organizations in order

to create unfair market competition, which, in turn, will reduce social welfare. Moreover, critics

point out that when it comes to solving the problem of reputation commons, self-regulation is

likely to serve as a smokescreen since reputation can be improved simply by impressing

outsiders without changing the behaviors of organizations. Thus, it is important to investigate

whether self-regulation can solve the problem of reputation commons by disciplining the

behavior of members effectively. We argue that obstacles forecasted by these pessimistic lines of

Page 3: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

reasoning are context-bound and that they can be overcome if industry self-regulation includes

effective sanctions and exclusion strategies.

To justify this claim, we first review the literature on industry reputation commons. We

argue that reputation exists beyond the level of individual organizations and that the problem of

reputation commons originates in the interdependence of outsiders’ perception of an organization

and that of its peers. All organizations within an industry face sanctions from stakeholders when

social expectations are violated. At the same time, all organizations within an industry also enjoy

better access to resources when their industry gains cognitive and social political legitimacy.

Sharing motivates organizations to cooperate, build a good collective reputation, and protect that

reputation from harm. Thus, the emergence of rules and norms to govern the commons is

motivated by the self-interested decisions of organizations, as self-regulatory institutions allow

organizations to gain the benefits of coordinated activity.

We then examine the case of the New York Clearing House Association (NYCHA), a

community-based, self-regulatory program among commercial banking organizations. We show

that the effects of negative spillover on market confidence created a reputation commons for

banks during times of panic, and that the NYCHA was founded as a collective institutional

solution for ameliorating the problem of reputation commons. We have identified five conditions

that result in the NYCHA’s efficacy in solving the commons problem: (1) previous cooperative

experience created a foundation from which self-regulation could take root; (2) a transaction-

based mechanism for measuring contributions and consumption offered incentives for good

performers to contribute and discouraged poor performers from consuming the common good;

Page 4: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

(3) formal mechanisms for inspection, sanction, and exclusion could be enforced to exclude free-

riders; (4) a close-knit community further facilitated monitoring and increased the cost of

defection; and (5) antitrust legislations and the advance of the state constrained the legitimacy of

self-regulation.

We end the chapter by discussing ways to extend research beyond the hurdles that self-

regulation must overcome in order to solve the problem of reputation commons. We suggest that

future research should examine alternative means of enforcement, such as independent third-

party certification, and hybrid forms of regulation that partner with the government. Future

research should also test the efficacy of self-regulation by separating the question as to whether

industry self-regulations can, in theory, be effective, from legal and political contexts that have

inhibited such efforts. Finally, future research should explore the consequence of changes in

community structures and information diffusion mechanisms on self-regulation in order to solve

reputation commons in new industries.

REPUTATION COMMONS: CONCEPT AND TYPE

Corporate reputation is defined as “observers’ collective judgments of a corporation based on

assessments of the financial, social, and environmental impacts attributed to the corporation over

time” (Barnett, Jermier, & Lafferty, 2006: 34). In general, reputation is a judgment that is formed

through the observation of past behaviors, but also shapes future expectations. Reputation

seldom develops in isolation. Since observers can only evaluate the actions of an organization by

Page 5: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

considering those of its peers, reputations of organizations are interdependent. A downward

social comparison can easily boost one’s reputation. Yet standing within a group of dirty peers

can hardly make one look clean if observers perceive every organization as one of the dirty ones.

The thorny interdependence of reputation between an organization and its industry includes both

competitive and communal dimensions. Wade, Swaminathan, and Saxon (1998) have observed

this interdependence in the brewing industry. According to their study, the passage of prohibition

laws in one state resulted in the proliferation of breweries in neighboring states, though too many

prohibitions in neighboring areas dampened the number of local breweries because their

legitimacy was threatened. The communal view of corporations’ reputation argues that the

reputation of an organization depends not only on its actions, but also on the reputation of the

industry in which it occurs. If organizations depend on collective perceptions of their industry,

all of them face sanctions when one severely violates the expectations of stakeholders. Thus,

organizational reputation exists beyond the level of individual organizations and has its roots in

an interorganizational context (Barnett & Hoffman, 2008). In this sense, industry reputation is an

intangible commons (Barnett & King, 2008).

There are at least three reasons why the reputations of organizations share a communal

feature. First of all, organizations within an industry share a reputation because they share similar

attributes. Since organizations within the same industry tend to utilize similar resources, employ

similar technologies, and adopt similar management practices, the actions of one are often

perceived as emblematic of an entire industry. Being tarred by the same brush is not rare. In the

case of the recent Gulf oil spill, for example, while the accident was unique to BP, it put all oil

Page 6: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

companies under public scrutiny because it “caused consumers to question whether a similar

incident could happen to other companies” (Market Strategies International, 2010). As a result,

the market index of the reputation of the energy industry plummeted by 25 percent (Market

Strategies International, 2010). Second, observers use collective reputations to judge an

individual firm due to the problem of information asymmetry. Outsiders may not be equipped

with specialized knowledge to distinguish between the behaviors of the industry’s individual

members. Even if they are, the cost of making an informed judgment may be prohibitively high,

especially when the source of information is distant in terms of geography, culture, and

language. As a result of information asymmetry, newcomers to an industry can still bear the

stigma of their predecessors long after the latter are gone (Tirole, 1996). Third, an individual

organization’s actions can significantly affect the reputation of an entire industry. Research in

psychology has shown that salient events caused by certain group members are represented

disproportionately in impressions of the group formed by observers because the availability

heuristic makes it easier for extremes to be overestimated (Rothbart et al., 1978). As a result,

severe accidents and catastrophes caused by an individual organization can have devastating

effects on the reputation of an entire industry.

Corporate social responsibility is one instance of an industry-reputation common, as the

public has become increasingly concerned about the role of corporations as responsible citizens

in society. Besides pursuing profits, corporations are expected to comply with labor,

environmental, human rights, or other standards of accountability. Researchers have documented

numerous cases in which an entire industry is sanctioned when one or a small group of

Page 7: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

organizations violate the expectations of social responsibility. In the chemical industry, all firms

were punished by shareholders due to one individual firm’s accident (Barnett & King, 2008). In

the coffee, athletic shoes, and apparel industries, sweatshops and other unfair labor practices

have agitated widespread boycotts by consumers (Malkin, 1996; Hornblower, 2000). In the

diamond industry, conflict diamonds mined in African war zones poisoned the glamour linked to

the industry and caused drops in sales (Zoellner, 2006). In the early movie industry, the

excessive portrayal of sex and violence by some producers drew fire from America’s moral

guardians, and incurred a crusade that jeopardized the future of this nascent industry (Walsh,

1996).

To be sure, industry reputation commons is not limited to the domain of social responsibility

or the shared fate occasioned by shared penalties. A good collective reputation can also lead to

shared rewards, such as enlarged growth opportunities or expanded resource space. As a

collective perception, reputation is socially constructed and can be enhanced through a

legitimation process (Rao, 1994). When organizations’ actions are perceived as desirable, proper,

and appropriate to the social system of norms and beliefs, they obtain a good reputation, and lead

to easier resource access. Consider the necessary legitimation process at the early stage of new

industries. Aldrich & Fiol (1994) argue that the essential task of industry pioneers is to construct

a favorable reputation for the industry by demonstrating that it is economically viable,

cognitively cogent, and morally defensible. In the case of French nouvelle cuisine, for example,

endorsement by star chefs ameliorated the pressure of the culinary movement being perceived as

abnormal by traditional food critics (Rao, Monin, & Durand, 2005). Similarly, in the case of

Page 8: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

American hotels, the founding of the Cornell School of Hotel Administration elevated the image

of the hotel industry by presenting it as a profession that attracts talent (Ingram, 1998). When

more and more people follow the steps of pioneers, a fledgling industry not only grows in size

but gradually achieves a taken-for-granted status. In this constitutive legitimation process, each

member contributes by its mere existence.

Another positive effect of sharing an industry reputation is regional industry clusters. The

reputation of industry clusters attracts talent and customers from a wide radius. This

concentration of talent catalyzes innovations that, in turn, benefit all industry members through

the diffusion of learning and knowledge. In the nineteenth century, the reputation of Clyde River

as a shipping capital helped shipbuilders in the area secure orders from all over the world

(Ingram & Lifschitz, 2006). The fair-trade reputation enjoyed by merchants in Champagne

during the Middle Ages helped the region become a trading center in Europe (Milgrom, North, &

Weingast, 1990). Similarly, in the modern age, industry clusters such as Silicon Valley function

as a magnet that attracts entrepreneurs, scientists, and venture capitalists (Saxenian, 1994).

COLLECTIVE SOLUTIONS TO REPUTATION

COMMONS

Central to the problem of reputation commons is the interdependence of the reputation of an

individual organization and that of its industry. If an individual organization can successfully

distinguish itself from the rest of its industry, then no commons problem will arise. However,

Page 9: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

with limited resources, an individual firm may not be able to generate enough differences to

stand out. Empirical evidence has demonstrated that even industry leaders such as Nike, Gap,

and Starbucks are not immune to the backlash against their industries, despite offering superior

working conditions than their peers do (Malkin, 1996; Hornblower, 2000). In fact, firms that

hold high standards of accountability are more likely to be targeted by social activists, who see

responsible firms as soft targets that are likelier to respond to their requests (Barron & Diermeier,

2007). Thus, they prey on these firms to generate momentum for their movements.

If individual firms have limited capacity to solve the problem of reputation commons, it is in

the interest of organizations to cooperate, set enforceable standards, and impose a rationalized

system to discipline their actions and those of their competitors. The emergence of a self-

regulatory institution is motivated by the self-interest of organizations, and incentives to

cooperate are grounded in the belief that such an institution will allow organizations to gain the

benefits of coordinated activity. This concept of an institution as a “cooperation-for-collective-

benefits” (Knight, 1992) is a fundamental argument of both institutional economics (North,

1990) and rational-choice institutionalism (Nee & Ingram, 1998). Industry self-regulation

provides a way to solve the problem of reputation commons by providing collective benefits

unattainable through the actions of an individual organization. This is also the strategy that

Barnett & Hoffman (2008) called “teaming up” with peers.

The difficult fact in protecting reputational commons is that it requires many direct

competitors in an industry to cooperate. Organizations that share a common reputation are also

those that researchers and practitioners classify as direct competitors. Yu & Lester (2008) find

Page 10: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

that reputational spillovers occur among structurally equivalent parties. However, structural

equivalence, too, has been used to define competitors because structural equivalents serve as

substitutes for each other. Similarly, Barnett (2006) argues that reputation spillover is stronger

among homogeneous firms. Hannan, Polos, & Carroll (2007) echo this and claim that a

population’s legitimacy is directly tied to the degree of similarity among its members. Yet the

more similar an organization is to its rivals, the more competitive is their relationship due to

overlap in shared resources (McPherson, 1983). In addition, when competition is localized,

staying close to an industrial center means staying close to many competitors. Sorensen & Audia

(2000) have shown that proximity to competitors significantly increases the chances of an

individual organization’s mortality.

The dark shadow of competition is the first obstacle in the formation of a collective solution

to industry reputation commons. Competition dampens mutual trust. Without trust, institutional

initiators are hesitant to act because they risk placing themselves at a disadvantage if their rivals

fail to follow them. Furthermore, other organizations may suspect the intentions of rivals that

initiate a regulatory institution and may thus refuse to participate for fear of being trapped in an

institution that favors initiators. For example, after the scandal of the El Monte sweatshop in

1995, apparel firms in California faced a reputation-commons problem. Some of them attempted

to reach out to their primary competitors to establish an anti-sweatshop alliance. But none of

these efforts were productive because competitors suspected that they simply constituted another

sort of “backroom competition” (Bartley, 2007: 29). In addition to reducing trust, competition

also forces organizations to focus on short-term goals such as survival, whereas the improvement

Page 11: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

of industry reputation takes time. Organizations, uncertain as to whether they will still be in

business the following year, are unwilling to make long-term investments in improving industry

reputation.

The second obstacle facing self-regulation lies in the legitimacy of cooperation among

competitors. Inherent in the theory of perfect competition is the Darwinian notion that purely

competitive markets are good for society because they force firms to reach maximum efficiency.

Beyond the calculation of total social welfare, another aspect of the legitimacy of self-regulation

involves distributional justice, that is, whether self-regulation serves private at the expense of

public interests. Some critics claim that self-regulation is simply a means by which to fend off

government regulation. They criticize self-regulation for its weak standards, ineffective

enforcement, and secret and mild punishments (Waguespack & Sorenson, 2010). Howard, Nash,

& Ehrenfeld (2000) also contend that self-regulation is a smokescreen aimed more at improving

public image than at generating real improvement, much as the globe’s worst human rights

violators are the most likely to sign treaties that protect human rights (Hafner-Burton & Tsutsui,

2005). Supporting such critiques, King & Lenox (2000) report that Responsible Care, a self-

regulatory program established after the Bhopal accident in order to mend the reputation of the

chemical industry, was incapable of reducing its members’ pollution emissions.

Researchers have also expressed concern over the distributional justice of benefits for direct

participants of self-regulation. For example, Barnett (forthcoming) finds that large firms exert

control over industry communal organizations to advance their own interests rather than those of

an entire industry. A related problem is that access to a self-regulation program is controlled by

Page 12: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

institutional incumbents who can deploy self-regulation to disadvantage their economic rivals by

denying them equal rights of participation.

Besides legitimacy concerns, scholars have also been skeptical of the viability of self-

regulation, specifically whether self-regulation can overcome the free-rider problem. The key to

providing any common good is to induce contributions or protect it from being exploited by

those who do not contribute. At least since the publication of Mancur Olson’s The Logic of

Collective Action in 1965, social scientists have been dubious of the idea that voluntary

associations tend to form and take collective action whenever members jointly benefit. The

reasoning behind Olson’s idea is similar in structure to the dilemma of an n-person game

(Hardin, 1971): if each individual can access benefits of the public good that are funded by

others’ contributions without payment, then in a finite number of rounds a rational actor will

contribute zero. If participation in a private cooperation is voluntary and unenforced by a central

authority, then each actor has an incentive to defect from agreements and to free-ride on the

efforts of others.

Another concern related to the free-rider problem is the situation of adverse selection. Since

organizations with lower levels of performance benefit more from an improvement in industry

reputation, they have more incentives to join in coordinated action. Moreover, bad performers

may use participation in industry self-regulation to disguise their poor performance. Without

effective mechanisms to exclude these bad apples, self-regulation may be downgraded in a way

similar to that of the market for lemons (Akerlof ,1970). King & Lenox (2000) observed the

Page 13: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

adverse selection problem in the Responsible Care program and found that firms in heavy

pollution sectors were more likely to join the self-regulation program.

These obstacles have recently been re-evaluated through a series of investigations of real-

life voluntary associations. Based on her research of private institutions that help pool common

resources such as fisheries, forests, and water resources, Ostrom (2000) argued that when a small

group of actors makes a credible commitment, engages in effective monitoring, and sanctions

against deviations, self-organized cooperative institutions can protect participants’ common

interests, and the benefits derived from such collective action can spur efforts to create and

maintain these private institutions. Can the conditions that Ostrom applied to the governance of

physical commons be extended to govern reputation commons?

The depletion of physical commons such as clean water, shared fisheries, and stable climate

has a direct impact on the welfare of relevant parties. The conditions of these physical commons

can hardly be improved if relevant parties do not reduce water pollution, promote sustainable

fisheries, or curb carbon dioxide emissions. However, reputation commons differs from physical

commons in that reputation is a set of perceptions that can be decoupled from actual behavior.

Thus collective solutions for improving reputation commons can work indirectly by influencing

perception without touching the real problem. In support of this view, Barnett & King (2008)

have found that rather than acting as a means of disciplining the actions of members, self-

regulation deploys impression management practices to forestall industry-wide sanctions. The

difference between physical and reputation commons raises the question about the efficacy of

self-regulation in solving real problems that concern outside stakeholders. If self-regulation is

Page 14: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

simply an effort to manipulate impressions, its efficacy is greatly reduced. It thus remains an

important task to investigate whether, and under what conditions, self-regulation can effectively

discipline the behavior of participants in solving the problem of reputation commons. We

address these problems by illustrating the case of the New York Clearing House Association

(NYCHA), an industry self-regulatory institution that solved the problem of reputation commons

in the banking industry before the founding of the Federal Reserve.

THE CASE OF THE NEW YORK CLEARING HOUSE

ASSOCIATION

Banks are professionally managed. Ordinary depositors cannot easily judge the health of an

individual bank. Due to information asymmetry, depositors use information revealed about

certain banks to evaluate the soundness of others. As a result, negative investment news about a

few banks or some isolated bank failures can damage confidence in a banking market. If

depositors worry that their own banks are, or might become, insolvent, they will rush to

withdraw their deposits, leading to runs on many banks at the same time. Bank runs can make

originally solvent banks fail. To satisfy depositors’ demand for cash, these banks may be forced

to liquidate their assets in a short time period, often at steep discounts. When discounted assets

are inadequate to compensate for debts, a bank becomes insolvent and is likely to fail. Thus,

bank runs are contagious, and the problem of reputation commons is at the center of bank panics

(Calomiris & Gorton, 1991).

Page 15: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

In the US, before deregulation in the late 1970s and early 1980s, banks in most states could

only branch within their headquarter state or within the area of their headquarter cities. Localized

operation made the effect of reputation spillover especially strong because banks were not

diversified geographically. One cooperative arrangement through which banks could unite their

actions was the clearing house. The first clearing house in the country was the New York

Clearing House Association founded in 1853. Before the Federal Reserve was founded in 1914,

there were more than 200 clearing houses in the country. The clearing house was a city-based

voluntary association among banks. The function of the clearing house can be broken down into

two categories, clearing and regulation (Cannon, 1910). To fulfill the clearing function, the

clearing house provided centralized clearing services for its members over notes, drafts, checks,

and bills of exchange. To fulfill the regulation function, the clearing house prescribed rules and

norms for the control of its members, through which the clearing house ameliorated the problem

of reputation commons. It is important to note that the clearing function preceded the regulation

function. Cooperation in the clearing process brought bankers together and created a forum in

which innovative self-regulation took root.

Early in its operation, the clearing house adopted a strategy of pooling the reserves of

members. Pooling was not popular, however, because more conservatively managed banks had

no rewards to contribute to this reserve pool, while opportunistic banks were allowed to pursue

high-risk and high-return operations. From the 1870s on, the clearing house abandoned the

practice of pooling reserves and adopted transaction-based loan certificates. Once a bank panic

struck, member banks could borrow loan certificates from the clearing house and use them in

Page 16: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

place of currency in the clearing process. They could thus inflate the adequacy of cash that they

needed to satisfy depositors’ demands. These loan certificates were interest-based, and

borrowing banks paid lending banks interest rates ranging from 6 to 10 percent—high enough to

encourage reserve-abundant banks to share their bounty and to discourage reserve-deficient

banks from borrowing more frequently than when absolutely necessary. In this way, the clearing

house provided a selective incentive for banks to contribute to collective solvency, and to refrain

from threatening that solvency. Serving as a credit intermediary, the clearing house enabled a

more efficient use of resources during panics, when banks hoarded money.

Was the clearing house an effective regulatory institution? Yue, Luo, & Ingram (2009) have

studied the efficacy of the New York Clearing House Association—the largest clearing house in

the nation—in reducing the failure rate and operational risk of member banks. They found that

the NYCHA reduced the failure rate of member banks by 56 percent after controlling the

endogeneity of self-selection in membership. Moreover, they found that NYCHA member banks

were relatively prudent and avoided highly risky operations. Yue, Luo, & Ingram (2009) also

show that the NYCHA was successful in imposing self-regulation and organizing cooperative

arrangements. What, however, was the welfare implication? As Yue, Luo, & Ingram (2009)

demonstrate, survival benefits did not remain solely with NYCHA members but spread to all

Manhattan commercial banks. The overall failure rate of this population during the regulation of

the NYCHA was significantly lower than in the previous period, which had had no private

regulation. Moreover, the overall failure rate of this population under the regulation of the

NYCHA was no higher than that under the government regulation after 1914. Although the

Page 17: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

NYCHA only rescued its members, its efforts at dampening waves of bank panics stabilized the

market and allowed the whole bank population to flourish. The number of commercial banks

located in Manhattan increased from 51 in 1853, when the NYCHA was founded, to about 100 in

1913, when the NYCHA ceased to regulate the market. More impressively, the total assets of

these banks grew 1,400 percent during this period. Contrary to what antitrust proponents might

predict, under the regulation of the NYCHA, New York developed into the most competitive and

vibrant banking market in the country. It is hard to exaggerate the role that the NYCHA played,

and in an era without a central bank, the NYCHA was regarded as “a most important and

beneficial part in the general economic health of the nation” (Gilpin & Wallace, 1905: 5).

The success of the NYCHA in mitigating panics was a result of the system of loan

certificates, and, most importantly, of the monitoring and sanctioning regime that backed the

system. First of all, the clearing house provided club goods, accessible only to clearing house

members. Key to the provision of club goods was that free-riders had to be excluded from the

club (Potoski & Prakash, 2009). The clearing house had a special committee in charge of

member admission. In addition, new members had to be approved by the majority of existing

members. The clearing house also adopted an exclusion strategy. Banks that refused to share the

burden of other members during a financial crisis were suspended from the privileges of the

clearing house or were even expelled (Cannon, 1910). Second, to prevent the moral hazard

problem, the clearing house required banks to keep a high level of reserves (Hammond, 1957).

The clearing house closely monitored the balance sheets of member banks and required them to

report their condition every week. Moreover, the clearing house had the authority to audit

Page 18: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

members’ books at any moment, which it could do in response to rumors about the state of a

particular member.

Third, as a form of local self-regulation, the clearing house was relatively small, but its

modest size made close monitoring feasible and coordination relatively easy. Due to prohibitions

on bank branching, banks were locally based. Even the largest clearing houses, such as the

NYCHA, maintained a size of 50–60 members during the years they regulated the market.

Moreover, a shared market made mutual monitoring relatively easy. Gorton & Mulleaux (1987)

argue that monitoring within the clearing house was especially effective because member banks

had the specialized knowledge to value each other’s assets.

Fourth, besides formal strategies, the embeddedness of the clearing house in a close-knit

community also offered informal mechanisms for excluding free-riders. Geographical proximity

facilitated the diffusion of information and increased the stake of sanctions. Within a small

geographical region, monitoring was strong because information could easily be transferred and

defectors easily identified. Moreover, actors were less likely to defect because the stake of losing

various types of connections was too high. Geographical proximity also facilitated social

interactions between community members. Bankers within such dense community networks

faced strong peer pressure to act responsibly. Informal constraints thus significantly reduced the

cost of coordination within the clearing house.

It is useful to compare the clearing house with Responsible Care, an industry self-regulation

program aimed at solving the problem of reputation commons in the modern chemical industry.

In terms of formal control, the clearing house had a set of inspection, sanction, and exclusion

Page 19: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

strategies to control risk-taking activities among its members. As King & Leonx (2000) have

pointed out, however, the Responsible Care program is unable to expel any of its members who

fail to meet the standards and has only limited power to monitor members’ implementation of the

codes. In addition, the Responsible Care program does not inspect members’ adherence but relies

on their self-reporting. Having no “iron fist,” this program is, not surprisingly, more attractive to

bad performers and has no effect disciplining the behaviors of its members. In terms of informal

control, industry self-regulation can create a code of responsible behavior to discipline members

by forming and diffusing norms within the moral community of organizational peers. However,

the formation of norms requires community-wide consensus, while the diffusion of norms

requires dense networks. A small close-knit community did exist among commercial banks in

Manhattan in the 1800s, but is obviously absent in many modern industries. Instead, a modern

industry, such as the chemical industry, is composed of multinational corporations, the

operations of which are globally dispersed. It is nearly impossible for these corporations to

monitor each other. Finally, if members cannot identify with a moral community, informal

coercion simply does not work.

If the clearing house was so successful, why did it eventually fail? The internal operation of

the clearing house never really failed. Before the panic of 1907, the NYCHA issued loan

certificates eight times and not a dollar was lost (Gilpin & Wallace, 1905). For the clearing

houses in the rest of the US, “the losses from all the various note issues, spurious and otherwise,

were negligible! The only loss reported in any of the accounts here considered was $170,000 in

Page 20: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

Philadelphia in 1890 out of an issue of 9.7 million—1.8 percent of that total” (Timberlake, 1993:

210; italics in original).

To understand the final episode of the clearing house as a private regulation program, we

must take into account changes in economic and political contexts. From the end of the 1890s on,

more and more trust companies, originally chartered to manage the wealth of the affluent, began

to compete with banks in the deposit and loan market. Market competition intensified the rivalry

between banks and trust companies, and trust companies were excluded from the NYCHA.

During the panic of 1907, the NYCHA—as a self-regulation program for banks—refused to

extend assistance to trust companies. This deepened the market crisis significantly. The serious

consequences of the panic revealed the limitations of the NYCHA as a market regulator and

created political opportunities for other social and political interest groups to initiate banking

regulation reform.

The political environment also changed. The clearing house as industry self-regulation

flourished in an era of laissez-faire. Before the founding of the Federal Reserve, the government

supplied few institutional solutions to bank panics. The clearing house was founded in the Era of

Free Banking (1837–1862). During this time, states were the sole authority to charter and

regulate banks. The Michigan Act passed in 1837 automatized the chartering of banks, reduced

state supervision, and created shakier banks. Relaxed regulation caused market chaos; the

average lifespan of a bank in this era was five years; about half of the banks failed—a third

because they could not redeem their notes. Many banks in this era earned the reputation of being

wildcat banks. Although the National Banking Act of 1863 created a system of national banks

Page 21: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

that required higher standards of reserves than state banks, the government still offered no

solution to the problem of reputation spillovers during panics. The rise of clearing houses was

the banking industry’s spontaneous response to the need for restoring market confidence and

constructing an ordered market. Instead of being founded to fend off public regulation, the

clearing house played an important role in filling the institutional vacuum created by the

government.

The legitimacy of the clearing house in regulating the market was not challenged until the

1890s, especially after loan certificates of small denomination were circulated in place of

currency during panics. The debate focused on whether loan certificates were loans or currency.

Populists accused the clearing house of issuing illegal money and infringing the authority of the

federal government. By 1907, a large portion of the clearing house issues had become

recognizably illegal (Timberlake, 1993). Seeking to restrain big business and perceiving the

institutions designed by business as serving their own interests, the progressive movement

advanced the state as a legitimate market regulator allegedly for egalitarian reasons. The creation

of the Federal Reserve in 1914 marked the end of the era of the clearing house as a regulator of

commercial banks.

Despite its limitation in regulating an entire market, the NYCHA does prove that self-

regulation can solve the problem of reputation commons by disciplining the behavior of

organizations effectively. We have identified five conditions critical to the clearing house’s

success. First, cooperation within the non-regulatory function of clearing created a foundation in

which self-regulation took root. Previous cooperation had enabled banks to leave the shadow of

Page 22: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

competition and explore opportunities that protected their common interests. Second, interest-

bearing loan certificates created a transaction-based mechanism that encouraged contribution and

discouraged opportunism. Third, the clearing house adopted a set of formal strategies based on

inspection, sanction, and exclusion to prevent banks from taking high risks. Fourth, a close-knit

community further facilitated monitoring and increased the cost of defection. Such a social

structure also formed a moral community that encouraged banks to act responsibly. Fifth, the

economic and political atmosphere outside the clearing house constrained the legitimacy of self-

regulation. While the institutional vacuum left by the government provided fertile ground for

self-regulation to flourish, the subsequent advance of progressive legislation legitimatized the

state rather than private actors as regulator.

These conditions also set up boundaries for self-regulation to discipline the behavior of

members effectively. For example, one limitation of the clearing house was that when the scale

of the economy exceeded the boundaries of local communities, the means of exerting control

were weakened. In this respect, the success of local clearing houses stood in sharp contrast to the

failure of the emergence of a nationwide clearing house. Another limitation that arises when

applying clearing house principles to modern industry self-regulation is the barrier set up by

antitrust laws. Below we discuss ways to extend research beyond the constraints of self-

regulation’s efficacy in solving the problem of reputation commons.

Page 23: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

IMPLICATIONS AND DIRECTIONS FOR FUTURE

STUDY

Our review has two goals. One is to point out that a firm’s reputation is affected by factors

beyond its control. The interdependence of organization and industry reputations creates a

challenging problem of commons. The other is to suggest that given the communal nature of

industry reputation commons, collective strategies such as industry self-regulation provide a

solution to reputation commons. The case of the clearing house clearly illustrates that the

reputation of an individual organization depends on that of its residing industry, and that under

certain conditions self-regulation can be organized effectively to discipline industry peers’

behaviors. We list the literature reviewed in this chapter regarding the concept and management

of industry reputation commons in the summary table at the end of the chapter.

Regarding our first goal, the current literature can be expanded in at least three ways. First,

despite growing scholarly interest in corporate reputation, most research has treated

organizations as autonomous entities and ignored their mutual dependence. Future research

should pay more attention to the externality between organizations and, in their analysis of

organizational outcomes, take into account the commons problem. Second, the current literature

on reputation commons has focused mostly on the negative interdependence between

organizations. Future research should look more carefully at positive externality between

organizations. As our review of the literature reveals, organizations can also benefit from the

positive reputation attributed to their peers’ legitimation efforts or to the effect of industry

Page 24: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

clustering. In fact, a good industry reputation can serve as a unique competitive advantage for an

industry as well as for its members. It may be fruitful for future researchers to reveal how

organizations create and maintain their positive industry reputation. Finally, future research can

also benefit from investigating how the boundaries of reputation commons are defined.

Organizations can be grouped by means other than industries. They can be grouped by

geographies or other common features. Within each group or category, there are subgroups and

subcategories. The interdependence of organizational reputation degenerates with the expansion

of category scope. Thus effective definitions of the borders of reputation commons have

important implications for the success of collective mobilization aimed at addressing problems of

commons. In addition, different audiences may pick up different cognitive cues when defining a

category. Future research on reputation commons should address questions such as who are the

key stakeholders and from whose perspective is corporate reputation addressed.

Regarding our second goal—how to resolve the problem of reputation commons—we

suggest that in order to discipline the behavior of members effectively, any self-regulation

program has to be equipped with an “iron fist” that allows it to monitor and sanction. But modern

antitrust laws prevent self-regulation from directly controlling and sanctioning the behavior of

members. Future research should explore alternative means that self-regulation could adopt to

resolve the problem of reputation commons. One direction to take is to put intra-industry efforts

such as the NYCHA in context with third-party-led private regulation, of which a typical form is

certification. Non-governmental organizations (NGOs) codify standards of action and certify

organizations’ adherence to these standards through independent inspections. An early example

Page 25: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

of such third-party certification is the Motion Picture Association of America (MPAA), which

solved the reputation commons in the movie industry by certifying films according to five

different categories. In the last few decades, concerns over corporate social responsibility such as

sweatshops, child labor, blood diamonds, food safety, environmental sustainability, and other

issues have spurred the foundation of dozens of non-governmental certification institutes

(Bartley, 2007).

Certification is essentially a signaling strategy. By conferring certification, certifiers endorse

a signal that those who are certified are superior to others who are unable or uninterested in

obtaining certification. But certification is limited in its ability to sanction, and thus it may be a

weak solution for reputation commons. When norms are breached, a certifier’s response is often

limited to withdrawing or downgrading certification. This type of sanctioning has limited power

because outsiders may or may not observe the change of signal. Another issue that adds to the

weak sanction is fragmentation within the field of certifiers themselves. Field fragmentation

makes it difficult for outsiders to follow any single certifiers closely. Moreover, the proliferation

of certifiers and the differentiation strategies they pursue enable opportunistic organizations to

shop for certifiers. Competition within the field of certifiers speaks to another problem that arises

from relying on a third party to regulate, namely, how to motivate those independent regulators

who do not have a direct interest in the results of regulation. When certifiers adopt a for-profit

model, competition may lead regulatory standards and enforcement to evolve along a different

trajectory. When facing conflicts of interest, certifiers intentionally create ambiguities in

evaluating categories (Fleischer, 2009). Similarly, when certifiers begin to receive payment for

Page 26: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

their work, it is difficult for them to remain impartial while issuing certification, as was the case

with bond-rating agencies in the recent subprime mortgage crisis (Lucchetti, Ng, & Hitt, 2010).

Future research should investigate how to motivate independent third parties and how to protect

their reputation (see also Gilad and Yogev, Chapter 24, this volume).

The other direction that researchers have taken is towards a hybrid form of public and

private institutions in which private regulators produce the standards of regulation but outsource

enforcement to the government. In the nuclear industry in the US, the Institute of Nuclear Power

Operations (INPO), a trade association, sponsors industry standards, and a state-run regulatory

body, the Nuclear Regulatory Commission (NRC), enforces these standards. Rees (1994) found

confirmative evidence of the efficacy of this type of hybrid form. While it raises questions about

the blurriness of the boundary between public and private regulation, it does touch on one key

issue concerning the success of regulation: an effective regulator must have good knowledge of

an industry. Along this line of reasoning, researchers can also explore other ways in which public

and private regulations can be connected.

The trend of globalization in recent decades offers new opportunities for studying industry

self-governance as a solution for reputation commons. One reason is that antitrust laws may have

limited application within the global market. An obvious case of this is the US antitrust law

which does not apply to any activities of American companies that affect only foreign markets.

The other reason is that the increased flow of capital across national borders creates a demand for

global regulatory schemes that transcend the sovereignty of any single nation. However,

international conflicts add barriers to intergovernmental agreements and consequently afford

Page 27: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

private actors with unique opportunities to act as institutional entrepreneurs (Bartley, 2007).

Researchers have noted that transnational regulatory programs have emerged in manufacturing

and natural resource-extracting industries to manage reputation problems in environmental

protection and labor disputes.

Finally, advances in information technology have profoundly changed the way people

communicate and have seeded various new forms of communities. When the boundaries of

online communities move beyond the constraint of geography, the expanded space offers

opportunities for organizing self-regulation in new domains. In addition, information technology

industries offer new opportunities for investigating collective solutions for reputation commons.

For example, the popularity of online social media has created a US$23 billion-a-year online-

advertising industry that tracks consumers’ web-surfing habits for ad targeting. But this industry

is fiercely attacked by advocates of consumer privacy. To protect the reputation of the industry

as well as to ward off potential public regulations, a coalition representing advertisers and

Internet companies released a set of voluntary guidelines in July 2009, calling for voluntary

disclosure of tracking and data use. Without an enforcement authority, this coalition encourages

adherence only through peer pressure and the threat of public exposure (Steel, 2010). Future

research should investigate whether advances in monitoring technology in cyberspace and

amplified public exposure due to networking online can deter opportunism.

REFERENCE

Akerlof, George A. (1970). “The market for ‘lemons’: Quality uncertainty and the market

mechanism.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3): 488–500.

Page 28: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

Aldrich, Howard E. and Fiol, C. Marlene (1994). “Fools Rush In? The Institutional Context of

Industry Creation.” Academy of Management Review, 19/4: 645–70.

Barnett, Michael L. (Forthcoming). “One Voice, But Whose Voice? Exploring What Drives

Trade Association Activity.” Business & Society.

Barnett, Michael L. and Hoffman, Andrew J. (2008). “Beyond Corporate Reputation:

Managing Reputational Interdependence.” Corporate Reputation Review, 11: 1–9.

Barnett, Michael L. and King, Andrew (2008). “Good Fences Make Good Neighbors: A

Longitudinal Analysis of an Industry Self-regulatory Institution.” Academy of Management

Journal, 51/6: 1150–70.

Barnett, Michael L., Jermier, John, M., and Lafferty, Barbara, A.

(2006). “Corporate Reputation: The Definitional Landscape. Corporate Reputation Review,

9/1: 26–38.

Barnett, Michael L. (2006). “Finding a Working Balance Between Competitive and Communal

Strategies.” Journal of Management Studies, 43/8: 1752–73.

Baron, David P. and Diermeier, Daniel (2007). “Strategic Activism and Nonmarket Strategy.”

Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 16/3: 599–634.

Bartley, Tim (2007). “How Foundations Shape Social Movements: The Construction of an

Organizational Field and the Rise of Forest Certification.” Social Problems, 54/3: 229–55.

Calomiris, Charles W. and Gorton, Gary (1991). “Origins of Banking Panics: Models, Facts,

and Bank Regulation,” in Glenn Hubbard (ed.), Financial Markets and Financial Crises.

Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 93–163.

Page 29: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

Cannon, James G. (1910). Clearing House. U.S. National Monetary Commission. Washington:

Government Print Office.

Fleischer, Anne (2009). “Ambiguity and the Equity of Rating Systems: United States

Brokerage Firms, 1995–2000. Administrative Science Quarterly, 54: 555–74.

Gilad, Sharon and Yogev, Tamar (2011). “How Reputation Regulates Regulators: Illustrations

from the Regulation of Retail Finance,” in Michael Barnett and Timothy Pollock (eds.), The

Oxford Handbook of Corporate Reputation. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press

Gilpin, William J. and Wallace, Henry E. (1905), New York Clearing House Association,

1854–1905. New York: Moses King.

Gorton, Gary and Mullineaux, Don (1987), “The Joint Production of Confidence: Endogenous

Regulation and Nineteenth Century Commercial Bank Clearing houses,” Journal of Money,

Credit and Banking, 19/4: 458–68.

Hafner-Burton, Emilie M. and Tsutsui, Kiyo (2005). “Human Rights Practices in a Globalizing

World: The Paradox of Empty Promises.” American Journal of Sociology, 110/5: 1373–411.

Hammond, Bray (1957). Banks and politics in America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Hannan, Michael T., Pólos, László, and Carroll, Glenn R. (2007). Logics of Organization

Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Hardin, Russell (1971). “Collective Action as an Agreeable n-Prisoners’ Dilemma.” Science,

16: 472–81.

Hornblower, Margot (2000). “Wake Up and Smell the Protest.” Time, 155/15: 58.

Page 30: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

Howard, Jennifer, Nash, Jennifer, and Ehrenfeld, John (2000), “Standard of Smokescreen?

Implementation of a Voluntary Environmental Code.” California Management Review, 42/2:

63–82.

Ingram, Paul and Lifschitz, Arik (2006). “Kinship in the Shadow of the Corporation: The Inter-

Builder Network in Clyde River Shipbuilding, 1711–1990.” American Sociological Review,

71: 334–52.

Ingram, Paul (1998). “Changing the rules: Interests, organizations and institutional change in

the U.S. hospitality industry,” in Mary Brinton and Victor Nee (eds.), The New

Institutionalism in Sociology. New York: Russell Sage Foundation: 258–76.

Ingram, Paul and Yue, Lori Qingyuan (2008). “Structure, Affect and Identity as Bases of

Organizational Competition and Cooperation.” Academy of Management Annals, 2: 275–

303.

King, Andrew A. and Lenox, Michael J. (2000). “Industry Self-Regulation without Sanctions:

The Chemical Industry’s Responsible Care Program.” Academy of Management Journal,

43/4: 698–716.

Knight, Jack (1992). Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Lucchetti, Aaron, Ng, Serena, and Hitt, Greg (2010). “Rating Agencies Face Curbs.” Wall

Street Journal, May 12.

McPherson, Miller (1983). “An Ecology of Affiliation.” American Sociological Review, 48:

519–32.

Page 31: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

Malkin, Elisabeth (1996). “Pangs of Conscience: Sweatshops Haunt U.S. Consumers.”

Business Week, July 29: 46.

Market Strategies International (2010). “Oil Industry Reputation Hit by Gulf Oil Spill, Survey

Shows.” Available at: http://www.marketoracle.co.uk/Article20709.html (accessed 26 May

2011).

Milgrom, Paul R., North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R. (1990). “The Role of

Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne

Fairs.” Economics and Politics, 2/1: 1–23.

Nee, Victor and Ingram, Paul (1998). “Embeddedness and Beyond: Institutions, Exchange, and

Social Structure,” in Mary C. Brinton and Victor Nee (eds.), The New Institutionalism in

Sociology. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press: 19–45.

North, Douglass C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Olson, Mancur (1965). Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and The Theory of Groups.

Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective

Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Ostrom, Elinor (2000). “Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms.” Journal of

Economic Perspectives, 14/3: 137–58.

Page 32: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

Potoski, Matthew and Prakash, Aseem (2009). “A Club Theory Approach to Voluntary

Programs,” in Matthew Potoski and Aseem Prakash (eds.), Voluntary Programs. Boston:

MIT Press: 17–39.

Rao, Hayagreeva (1994). “The Social Construction of Reputation: Certification Contests,

Legitimation, and the Survival of Organizations in the American Automobile Industry:

1895–1912.” Strategic Management Journal, 15: 29–44.

Rao, H., Monin, P., and Durand, R. (2005). “Border Crossing: Bricolage and the Erosion of

Categorical Boundaries in French.” American Sociological Review, 70/9: 868–991.

Rees, Joseph V (1994), Three Mile Island. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Rothbart, M, et al. (1978). “From individual to group impressions: Availability heuristics in

stereotype formation.” Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 14: 237–55.

Saxenian, Annalee (1994). Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and

Route 128. Cambridge: Havard University Press.

Steel, Emily (2010). “To Stem Privacy Abuses, Industry Groups Will Track Web Trackers,”

Wall Street Journal, June 24, 2010.

Sorenson, Olav and Audia, Pino G. (2000), “The Social Structure of Entrepreneurial Activity:

Geographic Concentration of Footwear Production in the United States, 1940–1989.”

American Journal of Sociology, 106/2: 424–62.

Timberlake, Richard H. (1993). Monetary Policy in the United States. Chicago: University of

Chicago Press.

Page 33: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

Tirole, Jean (1996). “A Theory of Collective Reputations (With Applications to the Persistence

of Corruption and to Firm Quality).” Review of Economic Studies, 1996, 63: 1–22.

Wade, James B., Swaminathan, Anand, and Saxon, Michael Scott (1998). “Normative and

Resource Flow Consequences of Local Regulations in the American Brewing Industry,

1845–1918.” Administrative Science Quarterly, 43: 905–35.

Waguespack, David M. and Sorensen, Olav (2010). “The Ratings Game: Asymmetry in

Classification.” Organization Science, 22: 541–53.

Walsh, Frank (1996). Sin and Censorship: The Catholic Church and the Motion Picture

Industry. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Yu, Tieying and Lester, Richard H. (2008)., “Moving Beyond Firm Boundaries: A Social

Network Perspective on Reputation Spillover,” Corporate Reputation Review, 11/1: 94–108.

Yue, Lori Qingyuan, Luo, Jiao, and Ingram, Paul (2009). “The Strength of a Weak Institution:

Clearing House, Federal Reserve, and Manhattan Banks.” Best Paper Proceedings of the

Academy of Management Meeting. Chicago.

Zoellner, Tom (2006). The Heartless Stone: A Journey Through the World of Diamonds,

Deceit, and Desire. New York, NY: St. Martin’s Press.

Summary Table. Literature Review of the Concept and Management of Industry

Reputation Commons

Reference Key Constructs & Findings

Barnett & Hoffman

(2008)

This article argues that organizations’ reputations and performance

are not solely determined by their individual behaviors but also by

Page 34: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

interorganizational dependence.

Barnett & King (2008) This article develops the key definition of reputation commons to

describe the interdependence in organizational reputation.

Organizations in an industry share sanctions thanks to shared

reputation.

Wade, Swaminathan, &

Saxon (1998)

There are both competitive and communal interdependences between

an organization’s reputation and that of its peers.

Bartley (2007); Barnett

& King (2008); Malkin,

(1996); Hornblower

(2000); Zoellner (2006);

Walsh (1996)

These articles study industry reputation commons in the domain of

corporate social responsibility. The violation of social accountability

by an individual organization can result in penalties for an entire

industry.

Aldrich & Fiol (1994);

Rao, Monin, & Durand

(2005); Ingram (1998);

These articles study industry reputation commons in the domain of

legitimation. There are three types of legitimation: cognitive

legitimation, social-political legitimation, and constitutive

legitimation. A good reputation helps all organizations within an

industry to acquire resources.

Ingram & Lifschitz

(2006); Milgrom, North,

& Weingast (1990);

Saxenian (1994)

These articles study industry reputation commons in the domain of

industry clusters and regional advantage. Good reputation of an

industry cluster benefits all organizations by attracting talent and

customers from a wide radius.

Page 35: Industry Self-Regulation as a Solution of Reputation Commons - Usc

Barnett (2006); Ingram

& Yue (2008)

These articles study the collective strategy that firms can adopt to

enhance their competitive positions through cooperation with their

industry peers. These articles suggest that collective strategy can

serve as a means of managing the communal problems, such as

reputation commons, that face an entire industry.

Ostrom (1990); Ostrom

(2000)

Ostrom’s work shatters the belief that government regulation or pure

market transaction (i.e., property rights) is the only solution to the

problem of commons. Ostrom proposes that self-regulation programs

can serve as a viable alternative.

Potoski & Prakash

(2009)

This article proposes private clubs as a solution to the problem of

commons. Clubs can mitigate the reputation commons problem by

conferring a signaling benefit to firms and allowing their stakeholders

to reward them for producing the social externality that club

membership requires.