does nonfarm job growth encourage or retard soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the...

30
Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil Conservation in Philippine Uplands? AGNES ROLA AND IAN COXHEAD * ABSTRACT If land-degrading agricultural intensification in uplands is driven by labor migration, what will be the effect of nonfarm employ- ment growth? On one hand, a higher opportunity cost of farm labor should reduce labor-intensive cultivation methods. On the other hand, there may also be a reduction in labor-intensive soil conservation practices. We investigate this question using data from an upland watershed in Bukidnon, Philippines. Findings sug- gest that while off-farm employment growth will in general sup- port environmental improvements in the long run, there is a con- tinuing need for agricultural and environmental policies to but- tress this trend. Philippine Journal of Development Number 53, Volume XXIX, No. 1, irst Semester 2002 * Respectively, Professor of the Institute for Strategic Planning and Policy Studies, University of the Philippines-Los Baños, and Associate Professor, University of Wisconsin-Madison, U.S.A, and Regional Project Manager, SANREM CRSP Southeast Asia. The authors gratefully acknowledge the assistance of Isidra Balansag-Bagares in field data collection and Celia Tabien in data processing. Financial support was provided by the U.S. Agency for International Development through the Sustainable Agriculture and Natural Resources Management Collaborative Research Support Program (SANREM CRSP). INTRODUCTION Intensive agriculture in the uplands of tropical countries is observed to cause environmental damage. In the long run, this might jeopardize the resource base and ultimately the capacity of upland households to maintain self-sufficiency in food supplies. There are, in general, two ways to influence farmers’ use of natu- ral resources: direct interventions aimed at altering behavior, and indirect interventions (such as through prices) aimed at altering

Upload: others

Post on 31-Jul-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage orRetard Soil Conservationin Philippine Uplands?

AGNES ROLA AND IAN COXHEAD *

ABSTRACTIf land-degrading agricultural intensification in uplands is drivenby labor migration, what will be the effect of nonfarm employ-ment growth? On one hand, a higher opportunity cost of farmlabor should reduce labor-intensive cultivation methods. On theother hand, there may also be a reduction in labor-intensive soilconservation practices. We investigate this question using datafrom an upland watershed in Bukidnon, Philippines. Findings sug-gest that while off-farm employment growth will in general sup-port environmental improvements in the long run, there is a con-tinuing need for agricultural and environmental policies to but-tress this trend.

�������������� ������������������������� ����������������������������������

* Respectively, Professor of the Institute for Strategic Planning and Policy Studies, Universityof the Philippines-Los Baños, and Associate Professor, University of Wisconsin-Madison,U.S.A, and Regional Project Manager, SANREM CRSP Southeast Asia. The authorsgratefully acknowledge the assistance of Isidra Balansag-Bagares in field data collectionand Celia Tabien in data processing. Financial support was provided by the U.S. Agencyfor International Development through the Sustainable Agriculture and Natural ResourcesManagement Collaborative Research Support Program (SANREM CRSP).

INTRODUCTIONIntensive agriculture in the uplands of tropical countries is

observed to cause environmental damage. In the long run, thismight jeopardize the resource base and ultimately the capacity ofupland households to maintain self-sufficiency in food supplies.There are, in general, two ways to influence farmers’ use of natu-ral resources: direct interventions aimed at altering behavior, andindirect interventions (such as through prices) aimed at altering

Page 2: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

factors that influence farm decisions. In the Philippines, the mostcommon mitigating measure for seemingly unsustainable uplandagricultural practices is the direct approach, especially the intro-duction of soil-conserving methods through extension and farmereducation. For example, Sloping Agricultural Land Technology(SALT), a package of soil management measures for sloping lands,was introduced by the Philippine Department of Agriculture (DA)in the early 1980s to combat soil erosion and land degradation inthe uplands and has been widely promoted in upland develop-ment projects. However, while there is some adoption of conser-vation measures such as hedgerows in high-intensity extensionprojects, there is little evidence of more widespread farmer inter-est in SALT, or of spontaneous adoption (Garrity et al. 1993).Though no systematic evaluation is available, the general impres-sion is one of low and slow adoption rates primarily because farm-ers do not perceive such very labor-intensive technologies to beeconomically profitable (Regmi 1997). Tenure insecurity is also citedas a constraining factor, as with any investment in fixed capital.

On the other hand, the use of indirect policy tools for soilconservation in the uplands is not widespread. This is arguablydue to the perception among policymakers and their advisors thatupland farmers are characteristically subsistence oriented andsomehow beyond the reach of market-based policies. However,the evidence shows that many upland farmers are commerciallyoriented, and respond to output price incentives (Coxhead et al.2001; Coxhead et al. 2002). When output price changes, so doesthe mix of crops produced, and labor demand alters as a conse-quence. Moreover, in adoption decisions on land-clearing or soil-conserving actions, where long-term land productivity and sus-tainable resource management are issues of concern, the reper-cussions of a land use change due to external shocks such as mar-ket price or policy changes will also affect technology decisionsand agricultural labor demand. One type of shock that could havea significant impact on labor allocation decisions in upland agricul-ture is the emergence of rural nonfarm employment opportunities.

Page 3: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

There is a need to explain the link between nonfarm eco-nomic conditions and farmers’ choice of crops and techniques. Ingeneral, the availability of farm household labor is an importantdeterminant of production and land management decisions, in-cluding those affecting soil conservation. The capacity of a farmhousehold to establish and maintain a hedgerow system, for ex-ample, depends in part on the availability of labor and manage-ment skills for the purpose. However, the number of householdmembers available on-farm, and the amount of time they are will-ing to devote to farm labor and management could be influencedby conditions in the nonfarm labor market. In general, greaterearning opportunities in nonfarm employment cause the supplyof family labor on-farm to diminish.

There have been few attempts to examine agricultural house-hold labor supply in the context of the wider rural labor market(Sanchez 1991). One early work was of Lee, Jr. (1965, as cited inSanchez 1991), who provided a theoretical framework to explainthe motivation behind decisions on the allocation of farm resources,particularly labor. The allocation decision between farm and non-farm activities is shown to be consistent with the objective of ahousehold’s welfare maximization and efficiency in the use of farmand household resources. His model suggests that the availabilityof nonfarm employment opportunities, coupled with the aware-ness of farmers of such opportunities, reduces labor input on fam-ily farms.

Experience suggests that some transfer of family labor to non-farm jobs might reduce the level of disguised unemployment andthus promote more efficient use of resources in agriculture, with-out significantly altering the level of farm output. This would bethe case if some labor were initially underemployed on the farm.In the more usual case, however, the withdrawal of some familylabor from the farm requires an adjustment in crops or technolo-gies to reduce labor input.

In this paper, we hypothesize that nonfarm opportunitieswill reduce family labor input in farm operations, even in a rela-

Page 4: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

tively remote upland area. This will occur because rising wages orearnings opportunities make farm work less remunerative relativeto nonfarm work. Households will respond by cultivating less land,mechanizing some tasks, or shifting to crops or techniques thatrequire less management and are less labor-intensive. In wealthycountries, rising nonfarm wages have historically been associatedwith mechanization and the adoption of less labor-intensive crop-ping patterns (Binswanger and Ruttan 1978; Hayami and Ruttan1985). In the uplands of a developing country like the Philippines,rising wages may, under some circumstances, signal a shift fromrelatively labor-intensive annual crops to perennial crops or to lessintensive farming systems, including agroforestry. Depending onits exact nature, such a shift might be characterized as a movetoward a more environment-friendly agricultural development.1

We use the case of the upland community of the SANREM2

project site in Lantapan, Bukidnon, to analyze farmer behavior interms of crop choices and soil conservation technologies in the pres-ence of an emerging rural nonfarm labor market.3 The main ques-tion that we seek to address is whether changes in nonfarm em-ployment opportunities have measurable environmental effectseither directly, through adoption of soil conservation practices, orindirectly, through changes in land use or technology.

In the next section, we discuss the economic developmentand employment trends in the Philippines, and in the Bukidnonand Lantapan labor markets in particular. Then, we analyze inthe section following it the links between nonfarm employment

1 A number of studies conducted in the Philippines and elsewhere in the sloping uplandsof the humid tropics identify the expansion and intensification of annual crop cultivation(primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation,soil erosion, and (in areas where commercial forestry is no longer dominant) deforestation.Unit erosion rates are far higher under annual crops than under agroforestry and otherperennial-based land use systems (David 1988), and the area covered by upland foodcrops is very large in relation to total upland agricultural area. 2 Sustainable Agriculture and Natural Resources Management Collaborative ResearchSupport Program.3 “Rural” here also includes surrounding areas in the province such as the cities ofMalaybalay and Valencia, which are both densely populated.

Page 5: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

and changes in agricultural techniques and activities, includingpractices with direct environmental implications. Then we presentsome empirical analysis of the determinants of adoption of soil-conserving practices. In the penultimate section, we discuss somepolicy scenarios for sustainable resource management. We pro-vide a brief conclusion in the sixth and final section.

Our study makes use of both primary and secondary data.The secondary data are taken from published reports and munici-pal (Lantapan) and provincial (Bukidnon) statistics. The farm andhousehold level data are from farm surveys conducted in the studysite during the dry seasons of 1996, 1998, 1999 and 2000, and inthe wet season of 1998, 1999 and 2000. The sampling and surveymethodology are described in Coxhead (1995). Other demographicstatistics and human capital data have been taken from earlierbenchmark surveys (Rola et al. 1995). Data that characterize la-bor supply consist of the gender of labor market participants, edu-cational attainment, place of residence, and nature of labor par-ticipation.

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND LABOR MARKET TRENDSSINCE THE 1970S

Economic Growth and Employment TrendsA review of Philippine economic performance over recent

decades reveals that as the economy has grown, it has experiencedstructural changes of the kind predicted by development theory,although at a rather slow and fitful pace. The industrial sectorshare of gross domestic product (GDP) has remained roughly steadyat around 35 percent, while the services sector share increasedfrom 38 percent in 1970 to over 45 percent by 1999. The share ofagriculture in GDP has declined somewhat, from 28 percent in1970 to 20 percent in 1999 (Figure 1). The low industrial growthrates have deep historical roots in Philippine macroeconomic con-ditions and trade policy regimes (Bautista et al. 1979; Hill andBalisacan 2002). The relatively rapid growth and structural change

Page 6: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

in the mid-1990s may be attributed to economic and labor policyreforms, strong merchandise export growth, and the double-digitgrowth rate of net factor income from abroad in that period, mainlyin the form of foreign exchange remittances by overseas workers.That period was also marked by a big improvement in productiv-ity and output in the industrial sectors, led by electronics, garments,and other manufactured exports, which ballooned from barely 1percent of exports in 1970 to more than 70 percent by the late1990s. In stark contrast, agricultural exports fell from more than90 percent of the total in 1970 to 28 percent in 1985, and 15 per-cent by 1995 (ILS 1997).

Matching the relatively slow pace of long-run industrialgrowth, most change in the structure of employment has comefrom growth in the service sector. Agriculture’s share in total em-ployment has declined in step with the sector’s GDP share (Figure1). With relatively rapidly growing population and slow overallgrowth, real wages in the Philippines have stagnated since 1980,and present a rather depressing picture (Figure 2). Steeper in-creases in the agricultural wage after 1994—and a compression ofthe sectoral wage ratio—correspond to the decline in the agricul-tural sector share in total employment. This could reflect the ef-fects of the structural change toward growth in more labor-inten-sive manufacturing sectors.

Migration and Agricultural Expansion in Upland and ForestLands

Migration to upland and frontier areas has been a promi-nent feature of modern economic development in the Philippines.In the early postwar years, government programs sponsored mi-grants to convert forest lands for agriculture. Subsequent migra-tion, though spontaneous rather than sponsored, has been moti-vated by the desire to seek out resources which can generate house-hold income when combined with labor. The total population liv-ing in “forest lands” (officially defined as land of slope greaterthan 18 percent, whether forested or not) continued to grow rap-

Page 7: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

idly through the second half of the twentieth century, trebling from6 million in 1950 to nearly 18 million by 1985 (Cruz et al. 1992).The growth rate of the upland population has consistently exceededthat of the population as a whole. Accordingly, a very large frac-tion of Filipinos now resident in “forest lands” (i.e. engaged inupland agriculture) are at most second-generation descendants ofin-migrants.

The motives for migration are not hard to intuit, and havebeen quantified in an excellent empirical study by Cruz and Fran-cisco (1993). These authors used linear regression techniques onmunicipality-level migration data together with economic, geo-graphic, and demographic data from censuses and other officialsources to identify factors associated with migration into forestlands. Their results reveal that per capita income and literacy inlowlands, and population density in uplands, are factors associ-ated with low upland migration rates. Slope, upland urbaniza-tion, and the open access nature of uplands were all associatedwith higher migration rates. Upland incomes were not signifi-cantly associated with migration. As Cruz and Francisco con-clude, the results suggest that “migrants are motivated more bylack of other livelihood options than by the attractiveness of desti-nation lands” (p.26); increases in lowland incomes, and better defi-nition and enforcement of property rights over forest lands couldboth constitute major deterrents to migration.

Of course, the migration decision is undoubtedly driven inpart by changes in expected income in the uplands relative to thatin the location of origin, and this feature of the economic calculusof migrants may not have been well captured in the census dataon average household income used by Cruz and Francisco. Inparticular, changes in the relative profitability of lowland andupland agricultural production are likely to have influencedintrarural migration decisions. The peak years of the Green Revo-lution, which enabled lowland irrigated rice farms to increase fac-tor productivity by very large margins during the 1970s, were ac-companied by downslope migration from neighboring upland ar-

Page 8: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

eas (Kikuchi and Hayami 2001). In subsequent decades, however,the rate of technical progress has slowed, and the thrust of Philip-pine agricultural policy has generally delivered relatively largeprofitability gains to crops grown in uplands rather than in irri-gated lowlands. The implicit and effective protection rates on corn,the largest upland crop by area sown, increased dramatically fromthe 1970s to the end of the century, with the nominal protectioncoefficient (the ratio of domestic wholesale to world market prices)rising from near zero to 100 percent and more (David 2003). Simi-larly high protective rates prevailed throughout the period for otherupland crops such as temperate-climate vegetables (Coxhead 1997).The rise in price of these upland crops relative to rice, in a contextof generally static real wages and slow growth in nonagriculturalincomes, must also have been a factor in encouraging migration touplands. We may therefore expect to observe that late-twentieth-century migration rates to areas in the Philippines that combinedboth open access to land and agronomic conditions suitable forcorn and vegetable cultivation were very high. This was indeedthe case in the upland areas of Bukidnon province.

N u ev a E ci ja

L a g u n a

C av ite

M o u n tain P ro vin ce

M is am is O ccid en tal

B u kid n o n

P ro v in ce

F em a leM ale

0 .1 2 3

0 .0 7 5

0 .0 0 5

-0 .0 0 3-

-0 .0 1 7-

-0 .0 1 0-

0 .0 4 6

0 .0 5 9

0 .0 0 8

-0 .0 1 5-

-0 .0 3 4-

-0 .0 1 8-

0 .0 2 5

0 .0 5 9

0 .0 1 1

-0 .0 1 9-

-0 .0 6 4-

-0 .0 3 2-

0 .1 2 1

0 .1 1 8

0 .0 2 0

-0 .0 0 5-

-0 .0 1 4-

-0 .0 1 0-

0 .0 4 2

0 .0 5 7

0 .0 1 7

-0 .0 1 1-

-0 .0 2 8-

-0 .0 1 5-

0 .0 2 2

0 .0 6 1

0 .0 1 5

-0 .0 1 9-

-0 .0 5 6-

-0 .0 2 3-

2 00 5 – 2 01 01

–1 98 5 –1 99 0–1 97 5 – 1 98 0–2 00 5 – 2 01 01

–1 98 5 – 1 99 0–1 97 5 – 1 98 0–

Table 1. Net migration rates by gender, selected provinces, 1975–1990

Source: 1995 Census-based National Region and Provincial Population Projection, NSO, Manila.1Projection by NSO.

Page 9: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� �������

The Labor Market in Bukidnon Province and LantapanMunicipality

Labor force growth in Bukidnon province is strongly influ-enced by in-migration. In the 1995 Philippine Census projectionsof interregional and interprovincial migration patterns, Bukidnonwas projected to have positive net migration rates (NMR), for bothmales and females (Table 1).4

Why has Bukidnon been such an attractive area for migrants?Surveys and local histories show that migrants came from otherparts of the country. Attracted by the opportunity to colonize landand convert it for intensive agricultural production, they came tothe cool highlands and began to cultivate temperate crops. In re-cent years, the high migration rate also reflects strong job growthin the province, compared with other provinces in Northern

4 The migration projection assumptions include the differentials in the levels of developmentof the provinces as well as the presence or absence of a growth center. The basic indicatorof change in the level and direction of net migration was the percentage change over thetwo migration intervals (1975-1980 and 1985-1990). In both periods, the computed netmigration rate (NMR)for Bukidnon is positive. This is in contrast with other upland areasin the Philippines like Misamis Occidental and Mountain Province, which have negativeNMRs, meaning, outmigration trends.

Table 2. Population and employment status, selected provinces of Region X, 1996-1999

Source: Integrated Survey of Households Bulletin, 1998.1LFPR - Percent of people in the labor force population over 15 years old. People in the labor force are those peoplewho are working plus people who are looking for work during the reference period.2Number of people employed / number of people in the labor force.3Visible underemployment rate - working for less than 8 hours a day.

C ag ayan de O ro

M isam is O riental

M isam is O ccidenta l

C am ig uin

Buk idn on

4.4

10.5

5 .5

5 .3

25.2

16.1

3 .3

20.2

3 .1

5

22.3

15.4

89.9

92.3

91.5

96.3

96.7

94.1

91.5

94.1

94.2

95.2

95

92.7

63

65.4

64.2

57.6

88

73

60.2

65.3

64.1

50.0

78.7

69.8

295

743

340

43

623

1,7 09

274

701

323

42

588

2,6 02R eg ion X

19981996199819961998199619981996

V isible u n der -em ploy m en t rate 3

Em ploym ent rate2

Labo r fo rce p artic ipa tion rate1

To tal 15 years old and ov er (000)

Page 10: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ �

Mindanao (Table 2). Nonfarm employment opportunities haveincreased rapidly in the urban areas of Bukidnon’s major towns,Malaybalay and Valencia, and province-wide data show nominaland real nonagricultural wages to be slightly higher than planta-tion wages, but significantly higher than the nonplantation (i.e.farm) wages since the mid-1990s. However, Bukidnon also hasthe highest visible underemployment rate, i.e., those employed arenot necessarily fully employed. This may reflect in-migration byworkers hoping to find full-time work, and willing to endure aperiod of unemployment or underemployment in the course of theirsearch—a provincial version of the well-known Harris-Todaromigration model (Harris and Todaro 1970).

Rapid growth of the provincial economy also affects the la-bor supply decisions of long-term Bukidnon residents. For manyfarm families in the province, distances and travel times to urbanareas are now small enough to allow for daily (or at least weekly)commuting. Because of the proximity to alternative employmentopportunities, rural household members can decide whether toseek farm, off-farm, or nonfarm jobs. Naturally, nonagriculturallabor demand favors workers with more education or experience,so the degree of intersectoral labor mobility is likely to be influ-enced by factors on both the demand and supply sides of the mar-ket as well as the transactions costs of moving between markets.

Compared with other Philippine upland communities,Lantapan farmers practice highly commercialized agriculture, thusproviding for year-round agricultural employment. A number offarm activities have remuneration on a daily wage rate basis.5

5 Agricultural wage labor is usually called upon in times of plowing, planting, weeding,and harvesting. Farm labor remuneration in Lantapan includes both cash and noncashpayments. Cash payment may be daily per individual, or on a contractual basis, i.e., perhectare of land worked, per bag of fertilizer applied, or per unit of crop harvested. Noncashpayments are observed in the harvesting of some crops, when harvesters get a share ofoutput as payment. Exchange labor agreements (hunglos) among farmers are sometimesobserved, specifically for planting and weeding. Daily wage rates vary depending onlocation, type of farm operation, sex and age of the laborer. Gender discrepancies are notdistinct in corn areas, although some farmers have reported paying higher female wagesin vegetable cultivation (Rola et al. 1995).

Page 11: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

Are there other opportunities for employment in Lantapanaside from agriculture? From a 1996 survey of 120 households, 66percent of all labor is mainly on own-farm, 7 percent mainly inoff-farm, and 27 percent mainly in nonfarm activities. Eighty-sixpercent of the nonfarm workers are females.6 The results of subse-quent surveys of the same set of households also suggest higherwage rates per day for nonfarm incomes obtained by householdsthan farm incomes (Table 3). In 1998, two banana plantationswere established in the town. With these in operation, off-farmemployment became more widespread. Banana plantation wagesare higher than farm and even nonfarm wages.

Several factors influence entry to nonfarm work, includingeducation and the willingness to pay for transport and transac-tions costs, and sometimes, the cost of migration. Our data showthat most farm workers reside in their own place of work, whilesome nonfarm workers reside outside Lantapan, and that the pro-

6 The reason for the high proportion of females engaged in nonfarm work is that better-educated members of the population do more nonfarm work, and more females thanmales complete high school and college degrees (Rola et al. 1995).

Table 3. Average daily wages by occupation and location (P/day), Lantapan, 1998-2000

Source: SANREM survey data.

F arm A v era ge

N on farm A v era g e

S ales la d y/ help er

H ou s ehold help

C on stru ction w ork

9 4

1 48

1 25

1 36

7 4

-

1 11

1 82

7 9

1 28

1 01

1 14

4 5

6 9

9 3

1 82

4 9

1 11

1 37

6 2

1 75

3 2

1 48

6 8

1 48

6 3

6 3

5 3

4 0

9 6

-

7 8

1 28

8 3

6 1

5 0

6 0

1 10

1 36

5 9

1 02

7 0

5 5

1 50

9 4

1 41O ff ice E m p loym en t

N on farm w ork

2 00 01 99 91 99 82 00 01 99 91 99 8

L o w er W a te rshed V illag esU p p er W a ters hed V illa g esT yp e o f E m p lo ym ent

O ff-fa rm A v era g e-

S m a ll-sca le enterp rise-

Page 12: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

portion of latter has increased somewhat since the mid-1990s (Rolaand Coxhead 2001).

Determinants of Labor Allocation and Soil Conservation:A Theoretical Model

Clarke (1992) presents a model of dynamic optimization byfarmers in which investments in soil conservation are chosen so asto produce an optimal amount of soil “quality”, used as an inputto production. With some amendments, this model yields a struc-ture that, while highly stylized, captures the main features of thelabor allocation problem. We extend the Clarke model to includethe possibility of nonfarm employment by farm household mem-bers, with the expected nonfarm wage assumed to depend on thelabor market characteristics of the worker. Soil conservation alsouses family labor, so the household labor endowment must be al-located between crop production, soil-conserving investments, andnonfarm employment. Optimizing farmers also make land usechoices, increasing or reducing the area planted in response to soilproductivity and economic incentives. The model characterizessoil-conserving investment decisions in terms of input and outputprices, expected wages, implicit land rental values, and the pa-rameters governing rates of soil quality depletion and recovery.

Farmers allocate land and other resources to produce cropsusing as inputs soil quality Q, land N, and family labor LC, as wellas other inputs (including hired labor), with production technol-ogy F(Q, N, LC, X). We assume that labor inputs to current cropproduction are complementary with soil-conserving investments,so that an increase in the quantity of one raises the marginal pro-ductivity of the other. Soil quality depends on the intensity of landuse and on the effects of soil-conserving investments. Soil-con-serving investments use family labor as the sole input; the mar-ginal product of labor is assumed constant, so we have I(t) = LI.7

7 This is not necessarily the best assumption, especially where major investments suchas hedgerows and terraces are concerned, as these have large fixed-cost components(Shively 1997).

Page 13: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

Using a dot over a variable to denote the time derivative dQ/dt, the dynamics of soil quality are given by the state equation:

(1)

where γ denotes soil quality-depleting characteristics of crop pro-duction The parameter η governs the rate of natural increase ordecline in soil quality in the absence of human intervention.

The farmer chooses the time paths for current inputs of land,and the allocation of labor to current production, investments, andoff-farm employment so as to maximize the discounted value ofreturns to the combined farm and nonfarm enterprise. Define δ tobe the rate of time discount, q the unit price of purchased currentinputs, r the nonfarm wage, and s the rental value of land. Poten-tial labor market participants face an expected wage ρr, where ρreflects the match of a labor market participant’s skills and abilitywith that demanded in the market. This parameter is bounded byzero and one, with values close to 1 indicating a good match andvalues close to zero a poor one. Using vector notation, and drop-ping time indexes, the farmer’s problem is:

(2)

subject to the family labor constraint. Problem (2) is an optimalcontrol problem, solvable with the current-value Hamiltonian:

(3)

where w is the co-state variable, or shadow price of soil quality.

maxN, LC , LI ,X

e− δt pF(Q, N,LC ,X) + ρrLN − qX − sN{ }0

∫ dt

H = pF(Q, N, LC ,X) + ρr(L − LC + LI ) − qX − sN

+ w αLI − ηQ − γF(Q, N , Lc , X)[ ]

•Q ( t ) = αL I( t ) - ηQ ( t ) - γF Q ( t ), N ( t ), Lc

( t ), X ( t )( )Q (0 ) = Q 0

Page 14: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

Assuming that an interior solution exists, the first-order nec-essary conditions for a solution are given by the equations:

(4)

(5)(6)(7)

(8)

In the steady state = 0, and (8) can be rewritten as w(δ + η) =(p – wγ)FQ. The term (p – wg) that appears in these conditionsrepresents the net value of each factor’s marginal contribution onceeffects on land productivity are taken into account, and is positiveas long as δ + η > 0.8 Since in the steady state we can define w =ρr/α from (5), define:

from which it can be seen that value marginal product exceeds theconventional Fi = wi/p when γ is large, ρ is large, r is large, and/orα is small. Assuming that the second-order conditions for a maxi-mum are met, these first-order conditions describe the optimal al-location of labor to current crop production, soil-conserving in-vestments, and nonfarm work, as well as the optimal quantity ofland farmed (or conversely, fallowed), and the quantities of otherinputs used as functions of output prices, input prices, wages andlabor market characteristics, the family labor endowment, the vari-ous soil quality parameters, and the discount rate. Thus in thesteady state, Lj = Lj(p, q, r, s, L, α, β, γ, δ, η, ρ), and similarly for Nand each Xi.

Deriving and signing comparative static results from theserelations requires a great many assumptions on the nature of the

E = (p − γρr / α)

8 Since d > 0 (the rate of time preference must be positive), this condition requires onlythat h > –d, i.e., that if soil quality naturally degenerates rather than regenerates, it doesso at a rate less than –d.

∂H ∂LC = 0 ⇒ FL ( p −w γ) −ρr = 0

∂H ∂LI = 0 ⇒ρ r −w α = 0

∂H ∂N =0 ⇒ FN p −wγ − s = 0

∂H ∂X i = 0 ⇒ Fi p −w γ −q = 0 ∀ i =1,..., n

=δw −∂H ∂Q ⇒ = δ +η+ γ FQ − p FQwww

w

Page 15: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

substitution or complementarity relationships among variables, andwe do not attempt this. Rather, our goal has been to identify theexplanatory variables that will appear in any theoretically consis-tent empirical estimation of the allocation of labor and land re-sources to production, conservation, fallow (for land), or nonfarmemployment (for labor). Nevertheless it can be seen from (4) - (8)that higher nonfarm wages, more productive soil-conserving tech-nologies, or less soil quality-depleting crop production technolo-gies all raise the value of marginal product of land and of laborused in cropping or conservation. Moreover, a close fit betweenthe characteristics of the family labor endowment and those de-manded in the nonfarm labor market (i.e., a value of r close to 1)raises the opportunity cost of labor used on-farm, whether for crop-ping or conservation. From this we can state intuitively that in-creases in the demand for labor in nonfarm sectors will result insubstantial reductions in farm labor use for crops as well as con-servation, and a decline in total area planted among farm house-holds where , and conversely little or no change in land orlabor use in households where . In the former case, a greatdeal will depend on the extent to which other inputs (includinghired labor) can be used as substitutes for family labor, and on theextent to which land can easily be brought into or out of produc-tion.

The reality of the land and labor allocation problem is, ofcourse, much more complex than described by the model. In par-ticular, the choice of crops is an integral part of the labor alloca-tion decision; if hired and family labor are poor substitutes, as isarguably the case in vegetable production and soil-conserving in-vestments, which both require management skills in addition to‘raw’ labor input, then rising nonfarm employment may see house-holds switching to less management-intensive crops such as cornand trees as part of their overall response. Embedded in this is adecision among types of soil-conserving investments; some (suchas contour plowing and hedgerows) are labor-intensive, while oth-

ρ →1

ρ →0

Page 16: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

ers (such as fallowing or planting perennials) are relatively labor-saving. Clarke (1992) offers an extension to his basic model toinclude fallowing; another augmentation would be to allow fordifferent crops, in effect writing F(•) as a vector and permittingland to be reallocated among crops. Yet another extension wouldbe to recognize the role of fixed costs for some soil conserving tech-nologies, so that I(LI) = L0 + βLI. We leave these as subjects forfuture research.

Finally, it should be noted that the model sketched abovelends itself to a variety of policy analyses. Changes in cropproduction technology, and in the efficacy of soil conservationtechniques (for example, through extension or on-farm re-search), can be captured through alterations in the values of γand α respectively. Taxation schemes that discriminate amongland uses or technologies can be introduced via market-basedmeasures (affecting p, q, or s) or command-and-control mea-sures such as land use regulations. More broadly, interven-tions that alter the demand for nonfarm labor, or the quality ofthe household labor resource in relation to nonfarm demandthrough education and training, can also be assessed for theireffects on the uses of land and for soil-conserving investments.

NONFARM EMPLOYMENT AND AGRICULTURALTECHNIQUES

Crop Choices and Soil Conservation DecisionsFor given nonfarm conditions, the level of farm employment

in Lantapan is largely influenced by technology and crop choices.Farm labor intensity differs by crop. Hired (or paid) labor is highwhen external input use is high (Rola and Tagarino 1996); it isthus lowest in coffee and highest in vegetable systems. A shift fromcorn to vegetable cultivation, for example, would involve increaseddemand for both and management, as would the shift from pe-rennials to annuals (e.g., coffee to corn) (Rola 1995; Coxhead et al.

Page 17: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

2002). Less labor available for farm work could then shift cropchoices to perennial (and potentially more environment-friendly)crops such as coffee or even agroforestry.

However, less labor on the farm may also discourage labor-using soil conservation technologies, the promotion of which hasbeen a focus of efforts to encourage environmentally sustainableupland agricultural practices. Our data do not show a clear pat-tern, with adoption rates of both labor-intensive and labor-savingtechnologies varying substantially from year to year and season toseason (Table 4). The percentage of sample plots with labor-inten-sive conservation methods such as contour plowing and hedgerowsdeclined from 16 percent in 1996 to barely 10 percent in 1999, butincreased to 34 percent in dry season of 2000. On the other hand,the proportion of plots with trees and fallow, or labor-saving con-servation measures, increased from 25 percent in 1996 to 34 per-cent in 1999, but declined to 29 percent in 2000 for the dry season.During the wet season, the proportion of plots with labor-savingsoil conservation techniques is normally higher; this is because corn

Table 4. Number and frequency of plots with soil conservation measures, Lantapan,1996-2000

Source: SANREM survey data.

4 72 0 00 –2

5 21 9 99 –2

5 21 9 98 –2

W et Sea so n

3 42 0 00 –1

4 21 9 99 –1

3 21 9 98 –1

5 0 .5 4

4 4 .1 0

4 0 .3 1

2 9 .3 1

3 4 .1 5

2 4 .2 4

2 5 .0 05 6

2 2 .5 8

1 5 .3 0

2 1 .7 1

3 3 .6 2

1 0 .5 7

2 8 .7 9

1 6 .5 2

2 1

1 8

2 8

3 9

1 3

3 8

3 7

9 3

1 1 8

1 2 9

1 1 6

1 2 3

1 3 2

2 2 41 9 96 –1

D ry S ea son

%n%n

P lots w ith T rees / F a llo wP lots w ith C on tou r H ed g erow sT ota l P lo ts Y ea r

Page 18: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

plots are often fallowed when corn prices are low.9 Increased off-farm employment opportunities reinforce all these motivations forfallowing, by raising the opportunity cost of farm labor and relax-ing the need to grow corn year-round for subsistence.

As the model in the previous section suggests, there are sev-eral additional factors that should be considered, such as farm pricesand the influence of public policies or project interventions. Anincrease in the number of plots using soil-conserving measures ofboth types in 2000 may be due to a soil conservation ordinancepassed by the municipality early in that year. There is also sub-stantial variation related to crop choices, with vegetable farms typi-cally exhibiting lower in-field soil conservation measures (Rola andCoxhead 2001).10 Finally, weather conditions may also play a role.

Nonfarm Opportunities and Soil Conservation Practicesin Lantapan

Our data show that farm household members in Lantapanare increasingly participating in nonfarm work, and that more ofthe households in vegetable areas engage in both off-farm and non-farm work (Table 5). Participation in off-farm jobs fluctuates fromyear to year as well as according to crop choice. The El Niñodrought of 1998 saw a big increase in nonfarm employment sharesas upland crops failed. This shift was more prominent in corn ar-eas. Movements to off-farm work in 1999 and 2000 were a conse-quence of the establishment of two large banana plantations inthe study area. But later trends suggest that these jobs are not stablesources of income as most require skilled work.

Our data further suggest that households with more mem-bers working on-farm practice soil conservation measures more.

9 Fallowing is also a disease prevention measure for those who can afford to leave theirlands idle10 These differences may be related to cultivation practices, such as that of plowingvegetable fields up and down the slope to prevent waterlogging in the root zone, ratherthan contour plowing to conserve soil.

Page 19: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� �������

Households reporting contour plowing and hedgerows—the rela-tively labor-intensive measures—have a lower proportion of fam-ily members with nonfarm incomes as compared to those report-ing less labor-intensive measures such as trees and fallow. Thegrowth of off-farm incomes among families practising contourplowing and hedgerows is also evident.

Do Labor Market Trends Influence Adoption of Soil Conserva-tion Measures?

The foregoing discussion suggests that labor market changescould influence farmers’ choice of crop and possibly technique. Ifso, what effect does nonfarm job growth have on farm-level deci-sions that affect soil erosion and related environmental phenom-ena? Even the relatively simple model presented in the precedingsection indicated that the answer may depend on a wide varietyof factors, many of which are unobservable. Nevertheless, thisexploratory analysis may at least uncover some economic and othercorrelates of the adoption decision.

Table 5. Distribution of dry season employment by household members over 15years old, 1996-2000

Source: SANREM survey data.

4 41 44 21 172 00 0

4 12 93 01 421 99 9

3 01 75 21 211 99 8

2 956 61 581 99 6

M ain ly v eg eta ble-g row ing a rea s

4 12 53 31 262 00 0

5 12 12 71 131 99 9

4 52 03 51 031 99 8

2 02 06 01 201 99 6

M ain ly co rn-g row ing a rea s

N on farmO ff-fa rmO nfa rm

P rim ary em p loy m ent s ecto r (p ercen t o f ob serv a tions )

O b serv a tionsY ea r

Page 20: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ �

We explore these questions by means of an empirical exer-cise with data from our surveys of Lantapan farmers. We firstestimate a supply function for nonfarm labor from the sample farms,then examine ways in which nonfarm employment and wagesaffect on-farm decisions.

The labor supply function depends, in theory, on the oppor-tunity cost of household labor as measured by its earning power inthe most productive alternative activity. This cannot be observeddirectly; we have information on the nonfarm earnings only ofthat subset of the farm labor force that is employed off-farm. More-over, there is a great deal of unexplained variation in reportednonfarm wages, with some reported rates substantially (and im-plausibly) lower than farm wages. For this reason, we computean expected wage for each observation according to the followingformula:

expwage = max(reported nonfarm wage, average farmwage).

This definition is based on the assumption that those who are notworking in nonfarm jobs can earn at least as much as the farmwage by working on other farms, and those apparently reportingnonfarm wages less than farm wages would not in reality be earn-ing such low sums.

Define the quantity of nonfarm labor supplied by E, the ex-pected wage by W, and a vector Z, where Z contains variablesrepresenting land tenure, the age of the household head (and itssquared value), the education of the household head, and binarydummy variables for season (dry season = 1, wet season = 0) andyear (1998 = 0, other years = 1). The labor supply equation is ex-pressed as follows:

ln(E) = ƒ(ln(W), Z) (9)

Theory indicates that δln(E)/δln(W) > 0; this is the elasticity oflabor supply with respect to the nonfarm wage. The age variable

Page 21: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

is hypothesized to have a nonlinear relationship with nonfarm em-ployment (NFE), as most jobs in the rural areas would require skillsand a certain age level. Older members of the family are not asemployable as the younger members, especially in plantation work.Education is expected to have a positive influence on nonfarm la-bor supply, with a more highly educated person having greaterlikelihood of obtaining nonfarm work. The season dummy cap-tures seasonal aspects of the labor market. The year dummy isintended to capture the labor market impact of abnormal timesduring the 1998 phenomenon of an El Niño drought and the Asiancrisis, when it was observed that more rural household memberswent to in search of nonfarm work; with many staying on afterthe crisis and drought were over (Table 5).

In the second part of the analysis, we estimate the probabil-ity that a farmer will adopt soil conservation measures on a givenplot (parcel). Define a binary variable C, taking a value of 1 if theparcel has a soil conservation measure, and 0 otherwise. The adop-tion decision is modelled in two alternate ways:

C = ƒ(W, P, Z′) (10)

and

C = ƒ(E, P, Z′) (11)

where Z′ = Z as previously defined, plus a variable representingthe slope of the parcel.1 1

The theory in the preceding section indicates that land useand conservation decisions are functions of nonagricultural wages,among other variables, as in equation (10). When nonfarm wagesare high, there is a tendency to get out of the farm and the scarcityof the farm workers will now diminish the propensity to adopt soil

11 Slope is measured by a discrete variable, where 1 stands for flat land and 3 for thesteepest slope.

Page 22: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

conservation measures. Our use of equation (11) is intended tocompensate for imperfect observation of nonfarm wage data; thequantity of nonfarm employment, E, may serve as a proxy for W.

For each parcel, higher slope and more secure tenure areboth expected to have a positive association with the adoption ofconservation practices (Rola and Coxhead 2001). In addition, ex-pected output price was defined as a variable in the model. If oneexpects higher output price in the future, then there is an incen-tive to adopt soil conservation measures where these promisehigher yields. The demographic variables in Z′ are intended tocapture what we have referred to as the ‘match’ between the char-acteristics of family labor and those demanded by the off-farmand nonfarm labor markets, particularly age and education. Wehypothesize that earnings potential rises with each of these; how-ever, as age captures both experience and capacity, we expectalso that earning potential increases with age at a declining rate.Therefore, we include a term for the square of age as well. On thefarm, it is often observed that older persons know more about soilconservation and that their indigenous knowledge leads to moresustainable practices. It could also be that younger farmers havemore nonfarm opportunities through higher educational attain-ment, and thus tend less readily to adopt labor-using practices.12

Our data indicate that farmers adopting no conservation prac-tices at all have an average age of about 30, while those adoptingaverage about 35 years.

With the data available to us, the main testable hypothesis isthat greater nonfarm employment opportunities will be associatedwith lower adoption rates of soil conservation measures. Estima-tion of (9) – (11), augmented by the appropriate stochastic errorstructures, uses the SHAZAM package (White 1993).

12 Further work on the logit analysis should try to capture life cycle effects and possiblyeducation as a way of better separating incentives for various types of soil conservation.

Page 23: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

Table 6. Labor supply function estimates and propensity to adopt soil conservationmeasures, Lantapan, Bukidnon, 1996-2000

Note: Figures in parentheses are standard errors.* Significant at p < 0.10.** Significant at p < 0.05.*** Significant at p < 0.01.

L o g lik e lih o o d

R 2

C o n stan t

Y ea r d u m m y(1 9 98 = 0 , O th e rw is e = 1)

S e as o n d u m m y (W et= 0 , D ry = 1 )

E d u c a tio n o f h o u s eh o ld h ea d

E x p . o u tp u t p ric e

E (n o n fa rm em p lo ym en t)

ln (W )

(A g e)2

A g e o f h o u se h o ld H e a d

T en u re

S lo p e

N o n fa rm lab o r su p p ly (O L S ).

In d ep e n d en t V a ria b le

2

)

M o d el 2 (E q . 11 )M o d el 1 (E q . 10 )

-4 14 .64

-6 .5 6 ***(1 .5 2 )

-0 .5 2 ***(0 .1 9 )

-0 .1 5 **(0 .0 7 )

-0 .0 4(0 .0 3 )

-0 .0 0 1***(0 .0 0 1 )

0 .1 8 ***(0 .0 6 )

1 .2 4 ***(0 .2 1 )

0 .7 0 ***(0 .1 1 )

-

-

-

-

-

-

-2 55 .43

-4 .9 2 ***(1 .8 7 )

-0 .5 8 *(0 .3 0 )

-0 .1 8 *(0 .0 9 )

-0 .0 0 4(0 .1 4 )

-0 .0 0 7*(0 .0 0 4 )

-0 .0 0 1*(0 .0 0 1 )

0 .1 3 *(0 .0 8 )

0 .9 3 ***(0 .2 6 )

0 .7 6 ***(0 .1 5 )

-

-

-

-

-

-

-2

-2 87 .02

0 .3 2 8

1 .2 9(2 .9 2 )

-2 .9 4 ***(0 .4 2 )

-5 .6 2 ***(0 .3 9 )

-0 .0 0 2(0 .1 5 )

0 .1 9 ***(0 .0 6 )

-0 .0 0 2*(0 .0 0 1 )

0 .2 3 **(0 .1 2 )

0 .2 0(0 .3 8 )

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

C o n serv a tio n a d o p tio n (lo g it )1 = So il co n se rv atio n o n p lo t,

0 = N o c o n serv a tio n

lo g it )

(E q . 9 )(

Econometric Results and DiscussionTable 6 shows the results of the econometric estimation for

the labor supply function (9), and the conservation adoption rela-tionships (10)-(11). In the former, the log of the wage is a statisti-

Page 24: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

cally significant predictor of NFE, with an elasticity of about 0.2.While this elasticity value seems low, it may not be entirely im-plausible if there is a lot of management content in family labor onown farms. Education does not have a significant relationshipwith NFE; its effects may be captured by the age variable, as youngerworkers are generally better educated. The regression also showsthat the labor supply-age relationship is nonlinear. The negativevalue of the season dummy coefficient supports the contention thathousehold members engage more in nonfarm employment duringthe wet season than the dry. The year dummy also reflects a moreelastic supply of nonfarm labor in 1998, the El Nino year.

The dependent variable in equations (10) and (11) is binary,so the appropriate estimation method is logit (Greene 1993). Theresults are generally as expected. The results for tenure, slope,age, age squared, and education are all unchanged in the two mod-els. Slope and tenure are as expected; higher values (indicatinggreater slope and more secure tenure) increase the likelihood ofsoil conservation. The expected crop price is not a significant de-terminant of the soil conservation decision. The probability of con-servation adoption increases with age, but at a diminishing rate(the age squared coefficient estimate is negative). The coefficientof education is negative, despite the lack of a direct relationshipbetween education and NFE in (9); some aspect of the nonfarmlabor market is being picked up indirectly in (10) and (11). This isan appropriate subject for further research.

The coefficient of the labor market variable (whether quan-tity, E, or wage, W) is always negative, although the wage rela-tionship is not statistically significant (Model 2). While nonfarmemployment opportunities clearly influence labor allocation be-tween farm and nonfarm (the finding from the supply functionestimates), the link from that to the adoption or nonadoption ofsoil conservation practices is not so clear, possibly because responsesare heterogeneous, with some farm households switching crops orhiring in labor or using some other strategy to compensate for the

Page 25: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

reduction in family labor. Nevertheless, the negative sign on ex-pected NF wages indicates a tentative policy conclusion, that solong as land is not to be taken out of production altogether, thegrowth of nonfarm employment opportunities should perhaps bematched by incentives for farmers to adopt soil-conserving strate-gies to reduce family labor on-farm, rather than alternatives thatmight worsen erosion. For example, subsidies or tax breaks forfarmers reallocating their labor to nonfarm employment and wish-ing to convert their farms to agroforestry or other perennial cropsmight be justified on the grounds that by doing so, the offsite ef-fects of soil erosion are diminished.

POLICIES FOR SUSTAINABLE RESOURCE MANAGEMENTIN UPLAND AGRICULTURE

In spite of slowing rates of population growth in uplands,agricultural growth will continue in the short term and will re-main associated with intensive cultivation of profitable annualssuch as corn and vegetables. This is because prevailing economicand technology policies that create substantial incentives to plantthese crops are unlikely to change dramatically in the near term(Coxhead 2000; Coxhead et al. 2001). In Lantapan, two recentdevelopments are currently affecting farmers’ land use and soilconservation decisions. One is the recently adopted municipal or-dinance stipulating that if farmers practice soil conservation mea-sures, they will be favored as participants in government programs,specifically those of the Department of Agriculture. The second isthe increasing availability of nonfarm jobs, especially for youngerworkers, in new agribusiness ventures such as banana plantationsand commercial-scale livestock feedlots, recently initiated in themunicipality. Initial impacts of these local policies, as shown byour data, are that more of the farmers remaining in farm produc-tion are actively investing in soil conservation, while for those inoff-farm work, conservation takes the form mainly of fallowing.Wives who may have remained working in the vegetable plots do

Page 26: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

not do the terracing or contours and just plant a small patch of theplot with cabbage or other vegetables.

In the long term, continued growth and structural change inthe Philippine economy can be expected to further raise the op-portunity cost of farm labor. Employment and wage policies, andother measures (such as trade and investment policies) that affectlabor markets indirectly, can all thus serve as instruments affect-ing upland resource management. In this setting, nonfarm em-ployment growth can be expected to reduce incentives to expandcultivated area in uplands, in spite of technical progress in crops.13

However, the labor-using soil conservation technologies promotedwith rather limited success by some development projects and thePhilippine government in the past are likely to become even lessattractive to farmers. How then can one reconcile the aim of achiev-ing higher incomes in commercial upland agriculture with that ofsustaining the productivity of the resource base?

In the long run, upland agriculture should move away fromintensive cultivation as environmental amenities become morehighly valued. But in the shorter run, policies are needed to influ-ence farmer behaviour. Growth of nonfarm jobs could cause la-bor to be withdrawn from intensive agriculture without sacrific-ing household incomes. A desirable scenario is one in which thereis growth of small- and medium-scale enterprises, together withhigher nonfarm wages, and accompanied by better remunerationfor on-farm employment as the level of employed farm labor de-clines. This is expected to shift farm production to more labor-sav-ing crops, such as perennials, and to labor-saving soil conservingtechnologies. In the Lantapan site, an interesting follow up is astudy of the effect of current and emerging changes in local andnational government environmental policies on income sources,crop choice, household welfare, and the quality of the environ-ment.

13 The slope of upland farms inhibits mechanization as a labor-saving response to wageincrease.

Page 27: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� ��������

REFERENCES

Balisacan, A. and H. Hill, Editors. 2003. The Philippine Economy:Development, Policies and Challenges. Quezon City, Philip-pines: Ateneo de Manila University Press.

Bautista, R. M., J. Power and Associates, 1979. Industrial Promo-tion Policies in the Philippines. Manila: Philippine Institute forDevelopment Studies.

Binswanger, H.P. and V.W. Ruttan. 1978. Induced Innovation: Tech-nology, Institutions, and Development. Baltimore: JohnsHopkins University Press.

BLES (Bureau of Labor and Employment Statistics). 1997. CurrentLabor Statistics. Manila Philippines.

Clarke, H.R. 1992. The Supply of Non-degraded Agricultural Land.Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics 36(1):31-56.

Coxhead, I. 1995. The Agricultural Economy of Lantapan Munici-pality, Bukidnon, Philippines: Results of Baseline Survey.SANREM Social Science Group Working Paper No. 95/1.

—————. 1997. Induced Innovation and Land Degradation inDeveloping Countries. Australian Journal of Agricultural Re-search in Economics 41(3): 305-32.

—————. 2000. The Consequences of Philippine Food Self-suf-ficiency Policies for Economic Welfare and Agricultural LandDegradation. World Development 28(1):111-128.

Coxhead, I., A.C. Rola and K. Kim. 2001. How Do National Mar-kets and Price Policies Affect Land Use at the Forest Mar-gin? Evidence from the Philippines. Land Economics 77(2):250-67.

Coxhead, I., G.E. Shively and X. Shuai. 2002. Development Poli-cies, Resource Constraints and Agricultural Expansion onthe Philippine land frontier. Environment and DevelopmentEconomics 7:341-363.

Cruz, M.C., C.A. Meyer, R. Repetto and R. Woodward. 1992. Popu-lation Growth, Poverty, and Environmental Stress: Frontier Mi-

Page 28: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ ��

gration in the Philippines and Costa Rica. Washington, DC:World Resources Institute.

Cruz, W. and H. Francisco. 1993. Poverty, Population Pressureand Deforestation in the Philippines. Paper presented at aworkshop on Economy-wide Policies and the Environment,World Bank, Washington DC, Dec. 14-15.

David, C. 2003. Agriculture. In The Philippine Economy: Development,Policies and Challenges, edited by A. Balisacan and H. Hill.Quezon City, Philippines: Ateneo de Manila University.

David, W.P. 1988. Soil and Water Conservation Planning: PolicyIssues and Recommendations. Journal of Philippine Develop-ment. 15(1):47-84.

Garrity, D.P., D.M. Kummer and E.S. Guiang.1993. SustainableAgriculture and the Environment in the Humid Tropics: ThePhilippines. Committee on Sustainable Agriculture and theEnvironment in the Humid Tropics. Washington, D.C.: Na-tional Academy Press.

Greene, W.H. 1993. Econometric Analysis. New York, USA:MacMillan Publishing Co.

Harris, R and M. Todaro. 1970. Migration, Unemployment andDevelopment: a Two-Sector Analysis. American Economic Re-view 60:126-142.

Hayami, Y. and V.W. Ruttan. 1985. Agricultural Development: AnInternational Perspective 2nd ed. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Uni-versity Press.

ILS (Institute for Labor Studies). 1997. Efficacy of Selected LaborMarket Reforms in Promoting Globalization with Equity: ThePhilippine Case. Monograph Series No. 6.

Kennedy, P. 1998. A Guide to Econometrics, 4th edition. Cambridge,MA: MIT Press.

Kikuchi, M. and Y. Hayami. 1983. New Rice Technology, IntraruralMigration, and Institutional Innovation in the Philippines.Population and Development Review 9(2):247-57.

Lee, J.E. Jr. 1965. Allocating Farm Resources between Farm and Non-farm Uses. Journal of Farm Economics 47(Feb.1965):83-92.

Page 29: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

�������������� ����������������� �������

National Statistics Office. 1990 Census of Population and Hous-ing. Report No. 3-18J: Socio-economics and DemographicCharacteristics-Bukidnon. Manila: National Statistics Office.

—————. 1995. Highlights of Census of Population. Manila:National Statistics Office.

Regmi, S.P. 1997. Economic Analysis of Adoption of ContourHedgerow Practices by Upland Farmers in Claveria and Cebu,Philippines. Unpublished M.S. thesis, UPLB, College, Laguna.

Rola, A.C. 1995. Profitability and Sustainability of Agricultural Pro-duction Systems in the Lantapan Subwatershed. SANREMSocial Science Group Working paper No. 95/5.

Rola, A.C., D.D. Elazegui, M.M. Paunlagui and E.P. Tagarino. 1995.Socio-Demographic, Economic and Technological Profile ofFarm Households in Lantapan, Bukidnon, Philippines: 1995Survey Statistics. SANREM Research Report. UPLB, College,Laguna.

Rola, A.C. and E.P. Tagarino. 1996. Productivity Analysis of Up-land Corn Systems: The Case of Lantapan, Bukidnon, Phil-ippines. The Philippine Agriculturist 79(3&4):225-238.

Rola, A.C. and I. Coxhead. 2001. Soil Conservation Decisions andNonfarm economic Conditions: A Study of the Rural LaborMarket in the Philippine Uplands of Bukidnon. In SeekingSustainability: Challenges of Agricultural Development and En-vironmental Management in a Philippine Watershed by I.Coxhead and G. Buenavista. Los Baños, Laguna, Philippines:PCARRD.

Sanchez, T.C. 1991. Rural Labor Markets, Rural Nonfarm Enter-prises and Agrarian Reform in the Philippines: A Review ofthe Literature. PIDS Working Paper Series No. 91-17. Ma-nila.

Shively, G.E. 1997. Impact of Contour Hedgerows on UplandMaize Yields in the Philippines. Agroforestry Systems 39(1):59-71.

White, K.J. 1993. SHAZAM, The Econometrics Computer Program,ver. 7.0. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Page 30: Does Nonfarm Job Growth Encourage or Retard Soil ... · (primarily corn and upland rice) as the primary sources of agricultural land degradation, soil erosion, and (in areas where

������� ����� ������������ �

Blank page