comp survey 08-02-10

Upload: mitesh-patel

Post on 03-Jun-2018

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    1/47

    CEOCompensation

    CarolaFrydman1

    Dirk

    Jenter2

    1Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology,

    Cambridge,Massachusetts02142;email:[email protected]

    2Graduate SchoolofBusiness, StanfordUniversity, Stanford,California94305;

    email:[email protected]

    KeyWords

    Executivecompensation,managerialincentives,incentivecompensation,equity

    compensation,optioncompensation,corporategovernance

    Abstract

    ThispapersurveystherecentliteratureonCEOcompensation. Therapidrisein

    CEOpay

    over

    the

    last

    30

    years

    has

    sparked

    an

    intense

    debate

    about

    the

    nature

    of thepaysettingprocess. Manyviewthehigh levelofCEOcompensationas

    the resultofpowerfulmanagers setting theirownpay. Others interprethigh

    payastheresultofoptimalcontractinginacompetitivemarketformanagerial

    talent. WedescribeanddiscusstheempiricalevidenceontheevolutionofCEO

    payandontherelationshipbetweenpayandfirmperformancesincethe1930s.

    Ourreviewsuggeststhatbothmanagerialpowerandcompetitivemarketforces

    are important determinants of CEO pay, but that neither approach is fully

    consistentwiththeavailableevidence. Webrieflydiscusspromisingdirections

    forfutureresearch.

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    2/47

    TableofContents:

    Introduction

    Section1:ThelevelandstructureofCEOcompensation

    1.1

    The

    level

    of

    CEO

    compensation

    1.2ThemaincomponentsofCEOpay

    1.3Otherformsofpay

    1.4Briefsummary

    Section2:ThesensitivityofCEOwealthtofirmperformance

    2.1Quantifyingmanagerialincentives

    2.2Whatistherightmeasureofthewealthperformancerelationship?

    2.3Areincentivessetoptimally?

    2.4Briefsummary

    Section3:ExplainingCEOcompensation:Rentextractionorcompetitivepay?

    3.1TheoreticalexplanationsfortheriseinCEOpay

    3.2Theempiricalevidence

    3.2.1Evidenceforandagainstthemanagerialpowerhypothesis

    3.2.2Evidenceforandagainstcompetitivepay

    3.3Briefsummary

    Section4:

    The

    effect

    of

    compensation

    on

    CEO

    behavior

    and

    firm

    value

    4.1:TherelationbetweenCEOincentivesandfirmvalue

    4.2TherelationbetweenCEOincentivesandfirmbehavior

    4.3Incentivecompensationandmanipulation

    4.4Briefsummary

    Conclusion

    1

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    3/47

    Introduction

    Executivecompensation isacomplexandcontentioussubject.Thehigh levelofCEOpay in the

    U.S.hasspurredanintensedebateaboutthenatureofthepaysettingprocessandtheoutcomes

    itproduces.Somearguethat largeexecutivepaypackagesaretheresultofpowerfulmanagers

    settingtheirownpayandextractingrentsfromfirms.Othersinterpretthesameevidenceasthe

    result of optimal contracting in a competitive market for managerial talent. This survey

    summarizestheresearchonCEOcompensationandassessestheevidenceforandagainstthese

    explanations.

    Our review suggests thatbothmanagerialpowerand competitivemarket forcesare important

    determinantsofCEOpay,but thatneitherapproachalone is fullyconsistentwith theavailable

    evidence.TheevolutionofCEOcompensationsinceWWIIcanbebroadlydividedintotwodistinct

    periods.Priortothe1970s,weobserve low levelsofpay, littledispersionacrosstopmanagers,

    and moderate payperformance sensitivities. From the mid1970s to the early 2000s,

    compensationlevelsgrowdramatically,differencesinpayacrossmanagersandfirmswiden,and

    equity incentivestiemanagerswealthclosertofirmperformance.Noneoftheexistingtheories

    offers a fully convincing explanation for the apparent regime change thatoccurredduring the

    1970s, and all theories have trouble explaining some of the crosssectional and timeseries

    patternsinthedata.

    Many of the theoretical studies we review explore how various characteristics of realworld

    compensation contracts can be consistent with either rent extraction or optimal contracting.

    Whileobviouslyuseful,demonstratingthatagivencompensationfeaturecanariseinanoptimal

    contracting(orrentextraction)frameworkprovideslittleevidencethatthefeatureisinfactused

    forefficiencyreasons(ortoextractrents).Partlyasaresult,thereisnoconsensusontherelative

    2

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    4/47

    importanceofrentextractionandoptimalcontractingindeterminingthepayofthetypicalCEO.

    Tohelpanswerthisquestion,modelsofCEOpaywillhavetoproduce testablepredictionsthat

    differbetweenthetwoapproaches.

    WeexpectthattherenewedinterestintheoreticalworkonCEOpayandtheemergenceofnew

    datawilldeliverboththepredictionsandthetestingopportunitiesneededtoresolvethisdebate.

    Promising recent contributions have examined the effects of exogenous changes in the

    contracting environment on CEO compensation, firm behavior, and firm performance. For

    example, industryderegulationshavebeen linked tohigherCEOcompensation,suggestingthat

    increased demand for CEO talent raises pay levels. On the other hand, declines in CEO

    compensationfollowingregulationsthatstrengthenboardoversightsuggestrentextraction.

    The literature on CEO compensation is vast, and this survey makes no attempt to be

    comprehensive. Instead,weemphasize recentcontributions,andespeciallycontributionsmade

    since the comprehensive reviewbyMurphy (1999).Our focus isonempiricalworkmore than

    theory,on

    U.S.

    rather

    than

    foreign

    evidence,

    and

    on

    public

    instead

    of

    private

    firms.

    The

    large

    segmentsoftheliteratureweignorehavebeenablycoveredinothersurveys,startingwithRosen

    (1992)and followedby,amongothers,Finkelstein&Hambrick (1996),Abowd&Kaplan (1999),

    Murphy (1999),Core,Guay&Larcker (2003),Aggarwal (2008),Bertrand (2009),andEdmans&

    Gabaix(2009).

    Thepaper

    is

    organized

    as

    follows.

    Section

    1describes

    the

    evidence

    on

    the

    level

    and

    structure

    of

    CEOcompensation.Section2examinestherelationshipbetweenCEOpayandfirmperformance

    anddiscusses themeritsofdifferentpayforperformancemeasures.Section3summarizesand

    3

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    5/47

    critiquesexplanationsfortherise inCEOpay.Section4discussestheeffectsofCEOpayonfirm

    behaviorandvalue.Thefinalsectionconcludes.

    Section1:ThelevelandstructureofCEOcompensation

    1.1ThelevelofCEOcompensation

    The increase in CEOpay over the last 30 years, and in particular its rapid acceleration in the

    1990s,hasbeenwidelydocumentedandanalyzed.Figure1providesalongerrunperspectiveon

    theevolution

    of

    annual

    compensation

    for

    the

    three

    highest

    paid

    executives

    in

    large

    U.S.

    firms

    from1936to2005.Thedata is fromFrydman&Saks (2010),who identify the50 largestpublic

    firms in 1940, 1960, and 1990 (for a total of 101 firms) and collect information on executive

    compensationinthesefirmsforallavailableyearsfrom1936to2005.Totalcompensationisthe

    sumoftheexecutivessalary,currentbonusesandpayoutsfrom longtermincentiveplans(paid

    incashorstock),andtheBlackScholesvalueofstockoptiongrants.1

    Figure 1 reveals a Jshaped pattern in executive compensation over the 1936 2005 period.

    FollowingasharpdeclineduringWorldWar IIanda furtherslowdecline in the late1940s,the

    realvalueoftopexecutivepayincreasedslowlyfromtheearly1950stothemid1970s(averaging

    about0.8%growthperyear).Therapidgrowthinexecutivepayonlystartedinthemid1970sand

    continuedalmostuntiltheendofthesample in2005. The increase incompensationwasmost

    dramaticin

    the

    1990s,

    with

    annual

    growth

    rates

    that

    reached

    more

    than

    10%

    by

    the

    end

    of

    the

    decade.Figure1alsoshowsthatCEOpaygrewmorerapidlythanthepayofothertopexecutives

    1BlackScholesvaluesarelikelytooverstateboththecostofoptioncompensationtothefirmanditsvalue

    to the executive (Lambert et al.1991,Carpenter1998,Meulbroek2001,Hall&Murphy2002, Ingersoll

    2006,Klein&Maug2009,Carpenteretal.2010).

    4

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    6/47

    during thepast30years,butnotbefore.ThemedianratioofCEOcompensationto thatof the

    otherhighestpaidexecutiveswas stableatabout1.4prior to1980buthas since then risen to

    almost2.6by200005.

    The surge inexecutivepay in the last30 yearshasbeen replicated in larger crosssectionsby

    manyotherstudies.2Table1zoomsinontheevolutionofcompensationlevelsfrom1992to2008

    forCEOsandothertopexecutivesinS&P500firms,inasampleofmidcapfirms,andinasample

    ofsmallcap firms.Executivecompensationhas increased for firmsofallsizes.ForCEOsofS&P

    500firms,themedianlevelofpayclimbedrapidlyfrom$2.3min1992toapeakof$7.2min2001.

    CEOpaydidnotresumeitsriseafter2001,andmedianpayintheS&P500hasremainedstableat

    levelsbetween$6mand$7mthroughoutthe2000s.

    Beyondtheoverallriseinpay,Table1revealsthreeimportantfacts.First,changesinCEOpayare

    amplifiedwhenfocusingonaverageinsteadofmediancompensation,becausethedistributionof

    compensationhasbecomemoreskewedovertime.Forexample,medianCEOpayintheS&P500

    grewby

    213

    percent

    from

    1992

    to

    its

    peak

    in

    2001,

    while

    the

    increase

    in

    average

    pay

    was

    amuch

    steeper 310 percent. Focusingonmedians is therefore important if the goal is to analyze the

    experienceofatypicalCEO.Second,comparingexecutivepayinlargecap,midcap,andsmallcap

    firmsrevealsinterestingdifferences.Althoughexecutivepayhasincreasedacrosstheboard,the

    growth has been much steeper in larger firms. As a result, the compensation premium for

    managingalargerfirmhasincreased.Finally,thegrowthinpayhasbeenlargerforCEOsthanfor

    othertopexecutives,raisingthecompensationpremiumforCEOs.

    1.2ThemaincomponentsofCEOpay

    2 See, for example, Jensen&Murphy (1990a),Hall& Liebman (1998),Murphy (1999), and Bebchuk&

    Grinstein(2005).

    5

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    7/47

    Despitesubstantialheterogeneityinpaypracticesacrossfirms,mostCEOcompensationpackages

    contain five basic components: salary, annual bonus, payouts from longterm incentive plans,

    restrictedoptiongrants,andrestrictedstockgrants.Inaddition,CEOsoftenreceivecontributions

    todefinedbenefitpensionplans,variousperquisites,and, incaseoftheirdeparture,severance

    payments. The relative importanceof these compensation elementshas changed considerably

    overtime.

    PanelAofFigure2illustratestheimportanceofthemajorpaycomponentsforCEOsoflargefirms

    from1936 to2005,usingagain theFrydman&Saks (2010)data.From1936 tothe1950s,CEO

    compensationwas composedmainly of salaries and annual bonuses. As today, bonuseswere

    typicallynondiscretionary,tiedtooneormoremeasuresofannualaccountingperformance,and

    paid in either cashor stock. Payments from longterm incentive plans,which arebonusplans

    basedonmultiyearperformance,startedtomakeanoticeableimpactonCEOpayinthe1960s.

    Theselongtermrewardsareoftenpaidoutoverseveralyears,againwithpaymentineithercash

    orstock.

    Themost strikingpattern inFigure2 is the surge in stockoption compensation starting in the

    early1980s.Thepurposeofoptioncompensation istotieremunerationdirectlytoshareprices

    andthusgiveexecutivesanincentivetoincreaseshareholdervalue.Theuseofstockoptionswas

    negligibleuntil1950,whenataxreformpermittedcertainoptionpayoffstobetaxedatthemuch

    lower capital gains rate rather than as labor income. Although many firms responded by

    institutingstockoptionplans,thefrequencyofoptiongrantsremainedtoosmalltohavemuchof

    animpactonmedianpaylevelsuntilthelate1970s.

    6

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    8/47

    During the 1980s and especially the 1990s, stock options surged to become the largest

    componentof topexecutivepay.PanelBof Figure2 illustrates thisdevelopment for S&P500

    CEOsfrom1992to2008.3Optioncompensationcomprisedonly20%ofCEOpayin1992butrose

    toastaggering49%in2000.Thus,asignificantportionoftheoverallriseinCEOpayisdrivenby

    theincreaseinoptioncompensation,andanytheorythatattemptstoexplainthegrowthinCEO

    payneeds toaccount for this important change in the structureofpay aswell.Thegrowth in

    stockoptionusedidnotoccurattheexpenseofothercomponentsofpay;mediansalariesrose

    from$0.8to$0.9million,andshort andlongtermbonusesfrom$0.6to$1millionoverthesame

    period.Afterthestockmarketdeclineof200001,stockoptionsseemtohavelostsomeoftheir

    luster,bothinrelativeandabsoluteterms,andrestrictedstockgrantshavereplacedthemasthe

    mostpopularformofequitycompensationby2006.

    Explainingthestarkchanges inthestructureofcompensationsincethe1980sremainsanopen

    challenge.It ispossiblethattheexplosioninoptionusewaspromptedbytaxpoliciesthatmade

    performancebased pay advantageous, and by accounting rules that downplayed the cost of

    optioncompensationtothefirm(Murphy2002,Hall&Murphy2003).Moreover, itis likelythat

    both the prior decline in the stockmarket and the advent of option expensing in 2004 have

    contributedtothedecliningpopularityofstockoptionsinrecentyears.4 Thisintriguingshiftaway

    from options has not yet attracted much attention in the academic literature, and further

    researchisneededtodetermineitscausesandconsequences.

    1.3Otherformsofpay

    3TheevolutionwassimilarforothertopexecutivesinS&P500firmsandforS&PMidCapandS&PSmallCap

    firms.4Hall&Murphy (2003) and Bergman& Jenter (2007) argue thatmanagers aremorewilling to accept

    optionsafterstockmarketbooms.

    7

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    9/47

    Three important components of CEO compensation that have received less attention in the

    literatureareperquisites,pensions,andseverancepay.Obtainingcomprehensiveinformationon

    these formsofpayhasbeendifficultuntil recent years.Becauseof the insufficientdisclosure,

    perquisites,pensions and severancepayhaveoftenbeen labeled stealth compensation that

    may allow executives to surreptitiously extract rents (Jensen &Meckling 1976, Jensen 1986,

    Bebchuk& Fried 2004).However, these forms of paymay also arise as the result of optimal

    contracting.Forexample,perksmaybeoptimal if thecostofacquiringgoodsandservices that

    themanagerdesiresislowerforthefirm(Fama1980),oriftheyaidmanagerialproductivityand

    therebyincreaseshareholdervalue(Rajan&Wulf2006).Definedbenefitpensionscanbejustified

    asaformofinsidedebtthatmitigatesriskshiftingproblemsbyaligningexecutives incentives

    withthoseoflenders(Sundaram&Yermack2007,Edmans&Liu2010).5

    The evidence on the size of perquisites is limited, and empirical work on their effects and

    determinants has foundmixed results. Perks encompass awide varietyof goods and services

    providedtotheexecutive,includingthepersonaluseofcompanyaircraft,clubmemberships,and

    loansatbelowmarket rates.Consistentwith the rentextractionhypothesis,shareholders react

    negativelywhen firms firstdisclose thepersonaluseofcompanyaircraftby theCEO (Yermack

    2006a).Averagedisclosedperquisites increasedby190%followingan improvement intheSECs

    disclosurerulesinDecember2006,suggestingthatfirmspreviouslyfoundwaystoobfuscatethe

    reporting of perks (Grinstein et al. 2009). Perks appear to be amore general signal ofweak

    corporate

    governance,

    as

    reductions

    in

    firm

    value

    upon

    the

    revelation

    of

    perks

    substantially

    exceed their actual cost (Yermack 2006a, Grinstein et al. 2009). Thus, the available evidence

    indicates thatat leastsomeperkconsumption isa reflectionofmanagerialexcessand reduces

    5 Defined benefit pensions are inside debt becausemost executive pensions are unsecured, unfunded

    claimsagainstthefirm. Thus,executiveswouldstandinlinewithotherunsecuredcreditorsinbankruptcy

    (Sundaram&Yermack2007).

    8

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    10/47

    shareholdervalue.Ontheotherhand,Rajan&Wulf(2006)provideevidencethatperksareused

    consistentlywith theirproductivityenhancementhypothesis,e.g., tohelp themostproductive

    employees save time. The extent to which perks are justified by the efficient mechanisms

    proposedbyFama(1980)orRajan&Wulf(2006)remainsanopenquestion.

    Theempiricalevidenceonpensionsisevensparserthanforperquisites.PriortoDecember2006,

    SECdisclosurerulesdidnotrequirefirmstoreporttheactuarialvaluesofexecutivepensions.In

    their absence, Sundaram and Yermack (2007) use their own calculations and estimate annual

    increasesinpensionvaluestobeabout10%oftotalpayforFortune500CEOs.Similarly,Bebchuk

    & Jackson (2005) find largepension claims ina small sampleofS&P500CEOs.Conditionalon

    having a pension plan, themedian actuarial value at retirement is around $15million,which

    corresponds to roughly 35% of the CEOs total compensation throughout her tenure. These

    findings suggest that ignoringpensions can result ina significantunderestimationof totalCEO

    pay.

    Alack

    of

    readily

    available

    data

    has

    also

    hampered

    the

    study

    of

    severance

    pay.

    Researchers

    have

    collected information fromemploymentcontracts, separationagreements,andothercorporate

    filingsforusuallysmallsamplesoffirms.Yermack(2006b)findsthatgoldenhandshakes(that is,

    separationpay that isawarded to retiringor firedCEOs)arecommon,butusuallymoderate in

    value.Rusticus(2006)showsthatexanteseparationagreementssignedwhenCEOsarehiredare

    also common, and equivalent to two years of cash compensation for the typical CEO. Finally,

    manyCEOsreceiveasubstantialspecialseverancepayment,calledagoldenparachute,ifthey

    losetheirjobduetotheirfirmbeingacquired.Thestockmarkettendstoreactpositivelytothe

    adoptionofgoldenparachuteprovisions(Lambert&Larcker1985),andsuchprovisionsbecame

    widespreadduringthe1980sand90s(Hartzelletal.2004).Aswithperksandpensions,research

    9

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    11/47

    hasnotyetconclusivelydeterminedwhetherseverancepayisaformofrentextractionorpartof

    anoptimalcontract.6

    1.4Brief

    summary

    Boththe leveland thecompositionofCEOpayhavechangeddramaticallyovertime.Thepost

    WWIIera canbedivided intoat least twodistinctperiods.Prior to the1970s,weobserve low

    levels of pay, little dispersion across top managers, and only moderate levels of equity

    compensation.Fromthemid1970stotheendofthe1990s,allcompensationcomponentsgrow

    dramatically,anddifferencesinpayacrossexecutivesandfirmswiden.Byfarthelargestincrease

    comesintheformofstockoptions,whichbecomethesinglelargestcomponentofCEOpayinthe

    1990s. Finally, averageCEOpaydeclined from 2000 to 2008, and restricted stock grantshave

    replacedstockoptionsasthemostpopularformofequitycompensation.Itisarguablytooearly

    tojudgewhetherthepost2001periodconstitutesathirdregimeinCEOcompensation,orjusta

    temporaryanomalycausedbythetechnologybustof200001andthefinancialcrisisof2008.

    Section2:ThesensitivityofCEOwealthtofirmperformance

    Theprincipalagentproblembetween shareholders and executiveshasbeen a central concern

    ever since the separation of corporate ownership from corporate control at the turn of the

    twentieth century (Berle &Means 1932). Ifmanagers are selfinterested and if shareholders

    cannotperfectly

    monitor

    them

    (or

    do

    not

    know

    the

    best

    course

    of

    action),

    executives

    are

    likely

    to

    pursue their ownwellbeing at the expense of shareholder value. Anecdotal and quantitative

    evidenceonexecutivesperquisiteconsumption,empirebuilding,andpreferenceforaquite life

    6 See Almazan & Suarez (2003), Manso (2009), and Inderst & Mueller (2009) for models of optimal

    severancepay.

    10

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    12/47

    suggeststhattheprincipalagentproblem ispotentiallyhighlydetrimentaltofirmvalues(Jensen

    &Meckling1976,Jensen1986,Morcketal.1990,Bertrand&Mullainathan2003).

    Executivecompensation

    can

    be

    used

    to

    partly

    alleviate

    the

    agency

    problem

    by

    aligning

    managers

    interestswith thoseof shareholders (Jensen&Meckling1976). Inprinciple,anexecutivespay

    shouldbebasedonthemostinformativeindicator(s)forwhethertheexecutivehastakenactions

    thatmaximize shareholder value (Holmstrm1979,1982). In reality,because shareholders are

    unlikelytoknowwhichactionsarevaluemaximizing,incentivecontractsareoftendirectlybased

    ontheprincipalsultimateobjective,i.e.,shareholdervalue.7Byeffectivelygrantingtheexecutive

    anownershipstakeinherfirm,equitylinkedcompensationcreatesincentivestotakeactionsthat

    benefitshareholders.Theoptimalcontractbalancestheprovisionof incentivesagainstexposing

    riskaversemanagerstotoomuchvolatility intheirpay.Thedatareviewed inthissectionshow

    thatthesensitivityofCEOwealthtofirmperformancesurgedinthe1990s,mostlyduetorapidly

    growingoptionholdings.Atthesametime,mostCEOsfractionalequityownershipremainslow,

    whichsuggeststhatmoralhazardproblemsremainrelevant.

    2.1Quantifyingmanagerialincentives

    Measuring the incentiveeffectsofCEO compensationhasbeen a centralgoalof the literature

    since at least the 1950s. Early studies focused on identifying the measure of firm scale or

    performance (e.g., sales,profits,ormarket capitalization) thatbest explainsdifferences in the

    level of pay across firms (Roberts 1956, Lewellen&Huntsman 1970). The next generation of

    studiestriedtoquantifymanagerialincentivesbyrelatingchangesinexecutivepaytostockprice

    performance (Murphy 1985, Coughlan & Schmidt 1985). Although these studies found the

    7Inpractice,CEOcompensationislinkedtobothstockpricesandaccountingperformance.Becausestock

    pricesareanoisymeasureofCEOperformance,itcanbeoptimaltosupplementthemwithothervariables

    thatinformaboutCEOactions(Holmstrm1979,Lambert&Larker1987,Baker1992).

    11

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    13/47

    predictedpositive relationshipbetweenexecutive compensation and shareholder returns, they

    systematicallyunderestimatedthe levelof incentivesbyfocusingoncurrentpay(Benston1985,

    Murphy1985).Mostexecutiveshaveconsiderablestockandoptionholdings in theiremployer,

    which directly tie their wealth to their employers stock price performance. For the typical

    executive, thedirectwealthchangescausedbystockpricemovementsareseveraltimes larger

    thanthecorrespondingchangesintheirannualpay.

    Acomprehensivemeasureof incentivesshouldtakeallpossible linksbetweenfirmperformance

    andCEOwealth intoaccount.These links includetheeffectsofcurrentperformanceoncurrent

    and future compensation,on the valuesof stock andoptionholdings,on changes innonfirm

    wealth,andontheprobabilitythattheCEOisdismissed.Jensen&Murphy(1990a)arethefirstto

    integratemost of these effects in a study of large publiclytradedU.S. firms for the 197486

    period.TheyfindanincreaseinCEOwealthofonly$3.25forevery$1,000increaseinfirmvalue,

    andconcludethatcorporateAmericapaysitsCEOslikebureaucrats(Jensen&Murphy1990b).

    Table2reproduces

    the

    Jensen

    &

    Murphy

    result

    using

    data

    from

    1936

    to

    2005

    for

    the

    top

    3

    executivesinlargeU.S.firms. TocalculatetheJensenMurphymeasureofincentives(thedollar

    changeinwealthforadollarchangeinfirmvalue,orsimplythefractionalequityownership),we

    follow the literatureanduse twoapproximations:First,we consideronly changes inexecutive

    wealth thataredrivenby revaluationsofstockandoptionholdings.Thischannelhasswamped

    the incentives provided by annual changes in pay formost of the twentieth century (Hall &

    Liebman 1998, Frydman & Saks 2010). Second, we follow Core & Guay (2002a) and use an

    approximationtomeasurethesensitivityofexecutivesoptionportfoliostothestockprice.

    12

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    14/47

    Column1showsthatthefractionalequityownershipofthemedianexecutivedeclinedsharplyin

    the 1940s, recovered in thenext two decades, and shrank again in the 1970s. Although this

    measureof incentiveshas increasedrapidlysincethe1980s, its levelhasyettorecover itspre

    WorldWarIIvalue.Figure3zoomsinonthemorerecentevolutionofmedianCEOincentivesin

    S&P 500 firms from 1992 to 2005. Consistent with the longrun sample, the JensenMurphy

    fractional ownership statistic has steadily increased: in 1992, a typical S&P 500 CEO receives

    about$3.70fora$1,000increaseinfirmvalue;by2005,hergainwouldbealmost$6.40.

    In contrast to Jensen & Murphy (1990a), Hall & Liebman (1998) dispute the view that CEO

    incentivesarewidelyinefficientontwogrounds.First,theincreaseinstockoptioncompensation

    since the1980shas substantially strengthened the linkbetweenCEOwealthandperformance.

    Second,theyarguethatthechangesinwealthcausedbytypicalchangesinfirmvalueareinfact

    large. Even though executives fractional equity holdings are small, the dollar values of their

    equitystakesarenot.Asaresult,thetypicalexecutivestandstogainmillionsfromimprovingfirm

    performance.Hall&Liebmanpropose thedollarchange inwealth forapercentagechange in

    firmvalue,i.e.,thevalueofequityatstake,asmeasureofCEO incentives.Column2ofTable2

    reportsthemedianequityatstakestatisticforthetop3executivesinlargeU.S.firmsfrom1936

    to2005.WhileHallLiebmansequityatstakefollowsasimilarpatternofupsanddownsasthe

    JensenMurphymeasureovertime,itpaintsaverydifferentpictureofthestrengthofincentives

    towardstheendofthesampleperiod.Basedonequityatstake,incentiveshavebeenhigherthan

    their

    1930s

    level

    in

    every

    decade

    since

    the

    1960s,

    reaching

    a

    peak

    in

    the

    2000

    05

    period

    at

    12

    timestheir level inthe193640period. Thesharpest increase in incentivesoccurredduringthe

    1990sand2000s. ForS&P500firms,Figure3showsthatthevalueofequityatstakeforatypical

    13

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    15/47

    CEO increasedmore than fourfold, from $144,000 per 1% increase in firm value in 1992 to

    $683,000in2005.

    Thejuxtaposition

    of

    the

    Jensen

    Murphy

    (1990a)

    and

    Hall

    Liebman

    (1998)

    findings

    highlights

    that

    alternativemeasures of payperformance sensitivities can lead to very different views on the

    magnitudeof incentives.Thedivergence in the levelof these two incentivemeasures in recent

    years ismostly due to the growth in firm values over time: Executives tend to own smaller

    percentage (and largerdollar) stakes in larger firms,with the result that firm growth leads to

    lowerfractionalownershipincentivesbuthigherequityatstakeincentives(Garen1994,Schaefer

    1998,Baker&Hall2004,Edmansetal.2009).8Nevertheless,bothmeasuresrosefromthe1970s

    to the 2000s despite further increases in firm size, mostly due to rapidly increasing option

    holdings. By 200005, themedian largefirm executive holds stock optionsworth $7.2million,

    significantlylargerthanherstockholdingsof$5million,andalmost30timesheroptionholdings

    in197079(columns3and4ofTable2).

    Tosummarize,

    executives

    monetary

    gains

    from

    atypical

    improvement

    in

    firm

    value

    were

    sizeable

    formostofthetwentiethcenturyand increasedrapidly inthe lastthreedecades.Ontheother

    hand,executivesfractionalequityownershiphasalwaysbeenlow,andisevenlowertodaythan

    in the1930s.Becauseof theseconflicting signalsaboutexecutives incentives,weexamine the

    meritsofthedifferentincentivemeasuresinmoredetailnext.

    2.2What

    is

    the

    right

    measure

    of

    the

    wealth

    performance

    relationship?

    8Controllingforfirmsize leadstoan increasingpattern inboth incentivemeasuresovertime(Hadlock&

    Lumer1997,Frydman&Saks2010).

    14

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    16/47

    The rightmeasureofCEO incentiveshasbeen the subjectof a longdebate in the academic

    literature.9 In recent theoreticalwork, Baker&Hall (2004) show that the correctmeasure of

    incentives depends on howCEO behavior affects firm value. In amodified agencymodel that

    allowsthemarginalproductofCEOactionstovarywiththevalue(orsize)ofthefirm,thelevelof

    CEOincentivesdependsonthetypeofCEOactivityconsidered.TheJensenMurphystatisticisthe

    rightmeasureofincentivesforactivitieswhosedollarimpactisthesameregardlessofthesizeof

    the firm, such as acquiring an unnecessary corporate jet or overpaying for an acquisition.

    Conversely,thevalueofequityatstakeistherightmeasureofincentivesforactionswhoseeffect

    scaleswith firm size, such as a corporate reorganization. Since CEOs engage in both types of

    activities,bothmeasuresof incentivesare importantand shouldbe lookedat independently.10

    ThehighvaluesofequityatstakeandthelowfractionalownershiplevelsinFigure3suggestthat

    todaysCEOsarewellmotivatedtooptimallyreorganizetheirfirm,butmaystillfinditoptimalto

    wastemoneyoncorporatejets.

    2.3Areincentivessetoptimally?

    9 See, among others, Jensen&Murphy (1990a), Joskow& Rose (1994),Garen (1994), Hall& Liebman

    (1998),Murphy(1999),Baker&Hall(2004),andEdmansetal.(2009).Measuringoptionincentivesasthe

    sensitivityofwealthtoperformanceisproblematicforriskaverseCEOs.Optionstendtopayoffinstatesin

    whichmarginalutilityisalreadylow,whichmeansthattheactualincentivescreatedforagivensensitivity

    aremuchsmallerforoptionsthanforstock(Jenter2002).10

    Athird incentivemeasure istheelasticityofCEOwealthtoperformance(i.e.,thepercentagechange in

    wealthfor

    aone

    percent

    improvement

    in

    firm

    value).

    This

    statistic

    has

    the

    attractive

    feature

    of

    not

    being

    sensitivetochangesinfirmsize(Murphy1985,Rosen1992),andisthecorrectmeasureofincentiveswhen

    theeffortchoiceof theCEOhasamultiplicativeeffectonbothCEOutilityand firmvalue (Edmansetal.

    2009).WithCEOsnonfirmwealthunobservable,theelasticityhasthedisadvantageofbeingmechanically

    closetoonewhenonlyconsideringtherevaluationsofstockandstockoptionholdingsassourcesofchange

    inCEOwealth. Intheextreme,thismeasureiszeroforanexecutivewithnoequityholdings,andequalto

    one (or theoptiondelta) if theexecutiveholdsat leastone share (oneoption). Inpractice, researchers

    resorttoapproximationstothiselasticitybyscalingtheabsolutechangeinwealthbyannualpay(Edmans

    etal.2009)orbythesumofpayandtheequityportfolioheld(Hall&Liebman1998,Frydman&Saks2010).

    15

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    17/47

    Determining whether observed compensation contracts optimally address the moral hazard

    problembetweenshareholdersandCEOsisdifficult.11Theoptimalincentivestrengthdependson

    parameters that areunobservable, such as themarginalproduct of CEO effort, the CEOs risk

    aversion,theCEOscostofeffort,andtheCEOsoutsidewealth.Thesefreevariablesmakeiteasy

    to develop versions of the principalagent model that are consistent with a wide range of

    empiricalpatterns.Forexample,Garen(1994)andHaubrich(1994)showthatthe lowfractional

    ownershipstakeslamentedbyJensen&Murphy(1990a)areconsistentwithoptimalcontracting

    if CEOs are sufficiently risk averse. Given the flexibility of the agencymodel,most empirical

    studiesfocusinsteadontestingpredictionsaboutcrosssectionaldeterminantsofCEOincentives

    oraboutthemodelscomparativestatics.

    In the basic principalagent model, the optimal level of incentives declines with the cost of

    managerialeffort,thenoisetosignalratiooftheperformancemeasure,andtheexecutivesrisk

    aversion.Consistentwiththesecomparativestatics,thevariation inCEO incentivesacross firms

    appearstobepartlyexplainedbythevarianceinstockreturns,arguablyaproxyforthenoisein

    the outcomemeasure (Garen 1994, Aggarwal& Samwick 1999a, Himmelberg et al. 1999, Jin

    2002,Garvey&Milbourn2003).12 Also,wealthierCEOs,whoarelikelytobelessriskaverse,have

    higherpoweredincentives(Garen1994,Becker2006).

    EmpiricalevidenceonotherpredicteddeterminantsofCEOincentivesisinconclusive.Lambert&

    Larcker (1987) argue that compensation should be more closely tied to stock prices when

    accountingperformanceisrelativelynoisier.Eventhoughthereisconsistentevidenceforsalaries

    11 The determination is made more difficult by the fact that executive pay may be linked to firm

    performanceforotherreasons, includingsortingofexecutives(Lazear2004)andefficientbargainingover

    profits(Blanchfloweretal.1996).12

    In contrast, Core & Guay (2002b) find a positive correlation between stockprice variance and pay

    performancesensitivity,contrarytothepredictionsofthebasicmodel.

    16

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    18/47

    andbonuses(Lambert&Larcker1987)andoptionpay(Yermack1995,Bryanetal.2000),Core,

    Guay&Verrecchia (2003) find theopposite result for totalCEOpay.Gibbons&Murphy (1992)

    predictthatincentivesshouldbestrongestforCEOsclosetoretirementtosubstitutefordeclining

    careerconcerns,andfindconsistentevidenceforcashcompensation.Yermack(1995)andBryan

    etal.(2000),ontheotherhand,findnoevidencethatCEOsnearretirementreceiveorholdmore

    stockoptions.John& John (1993)predictanegative relationbetweenexecutive incentivesand

    leverageasfirmstrytoavoidagencycostsofdebt,butYermack(1995)findsnoempiricalrelation

    betweenstockoptiongrantsand leverage.Finally,somestudiesreportevidenceconsistentwith

    theconjecturethat incentives,andespeciallyequity incentives,shouldbestronger infirmswith

    greatergrowthopportunities (Smith&Watts1992,Gaver&Gaver1995),whileothers reporta

    negativecorrelationbetweenthesetwovariables(Bizjaketal.1993,Yermack1995).

    Finally, a central prediction of the principalagent model is the use of relative performance

    evaluation forCEOs.Holmstrm (1982)andDiamond&Verrecchia (1982)argue that contracts

    shouldfilteroutanysystematic(e.g.,marketorindustry)componentsinmeasuredperformance,

    as executives cannot affect these components but suffer from bearing the associated risk.

    Consistentwiththisprescription,bonusplansfrequentlylinktheirpayoutstotheperformanceof

    thefirmrelativetoanindustrybenchmark.However,theoverallevidencefortheeffectiveuseof

    relativeperformanceevaluationisweak.13Thereasonisthatwealthperformancesensitivitiesare

    drivenby revaluationsof (nonindexed) stockandoptionholdings.14Asa result,CEOwealth is

    strongly

    and

    seemingly

    unnecessarily

    affected

    by

    aggregate

    performance

    shocks.

    Several

    recent

    13See,amongothers,Murphy(1985),Coughlan&Schmidt(1985),Antle&Smith(1986),Gibbons&Murphy

    (1990),Janakiramanetal.(1992),Garen(1994),Aggarwal&Samwick(1999a,b),andMurphy(1999).14

    Recentevidenceshowsthatsomefirmslinkthevestingofoptionandstockawardstofirmperformance

    relativetoapeergroup(Bettisetal.2010a).

    17

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    19/47

    papers,however,haveproposed theories thatexplain the lackofbenchmarkingasanefficient

    contractingoutcome.15

    2.4Brief

    summary

    Since Jensen&Murphy (1990a),ourunderstandingof the linkbetween firmperformance and

    CEOcompensationhas improvedsubstantially.The longrunevidenceshowsthatcompensation

    arrangementshaveserved totiethewealthofmanagersto firmperformanceandperhaps to

    alignmanagerswith shareholders interestsformost of the twentieth century.Much of the

    effectofperformanceonCEOwealthworks through revaluationsofstockandoptionholdings,

    ratherthanthroughchangesinannualpay.ThesensitivityofCEOwealthtoperformancesurged

    in the 1990s, mostly due to rapidly growing option portfolios. In contrast, the typical CEOs

    fractionalequityownership remains low, suggestinga continuedneed fordirectmonitoringby

    boardsandinvestors.

    Section3:

    Explaining

    CEO

    compensation:

    Rent

    extraction

    or

    competitive

    pay?

    The rapid rise in CEO pay over the past 30 years has sparked a lively debate about the

    determinantsofexecutivecompensation.Atoneendofthespectrum,thehighlevelsofCEOpay

    areseenastheresultofexecutivesabilitytosettheirownpayandextractrentsfromthefirms

    theymanage.Attheotherendofthespectrum,CEOpayisviewedastheefficientoutcomeofa

    labormarket

    in

    which

    firms

    optimally

    compete

    for

    managerial

    talent.

    Many

    other

    explanations

    for

    theriseinCEOpayhaveemergedinrecentyears,andthedebateistooextensivetodoitjustice

    15 Aggarwal& Samwick (1999b), Himmelberg& Hubbard (2000), and Gopalan et al. (2009) argue that

    benchmarkingmaynotbeoptimal,andJin(2002),Jenter(2002),andGarvey&Milbourn(2003)thatitmay

    beunnecessary.

    18

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    20/47

    inthisreview.Instead,wedividethetheoriesintothosethatviewrisingcompensationasarent

    extractionproblem,andthosethatview itastheefficientoutcomeofamarketmechanism.We

    briefly summarize themain theoretical arguments for these two views and then discuss the

    empiricalevidence.

    3.1TheoreticalexplanationsfortheriseinCEOpay

    The rentextractionviewposits thatweak corporategovernanceandacquiescentboardsallow

    CEOs to (at least partly) determine their own pay, resulting in inefficiently high levels of

    compensation. This theory, summarized as the managerial power hypothesis by Bebchuk&

    Fried(2004),alsopredictsthatmuchoftherentextractionoccursthroughformsofpaythatare

    less observable or more difficult to value, such as stock options, perquisites, pensions, and

    severancepay.Whilethisargument is intuitive,recenttheoreticalworkexploreshow inefficient

    compensationcanbesustainedinmarketequilibrium.Kuhnen&Zwiebel(2009)modelCEOswho

    settheirownpay,withbothobservableandunobservablecomponents,subjecttotheconstraint

    that too much rent extraction will get them ousted. Rent extraction survives in equilibrium

    because firing is costly and because a replacement CEO can also extract rents. Others have

    explored how CEO compensation is determined if there are both firmswith strong andweak

    governanceintheeconomy.Acharya&Volpin(2010)andDicks(2010)showthatfirmswithweak

    governance (and therefore higher compensation) impose a negative externality on better

    governedfirmsthroughthecompetitionformanagers,inducing inefficientlyhighlevelsofpayin

    all

    firms.

    Incontrast to themanagerialpowerhypothesis,agrowing literatureargues that thegrowth in

    CEOpay is theefficient resultof increasingdemand forCEOeffortorscarcemanagerial talent.

    Onesetof theories in thisveinattributes the rise inCEOpay to increasing firm sizesand scale

    19

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    21/47

    effects.IfhigherCEOtalentismorevaluableinlargerfirms,thenlargerfirmsshouldofferhigher

    levelsofpay andbematchedwithmore ableCEOsby an efficient labormarket (Rosen1981,

    1982).SmallincrementsinCEOtalentcanimplylargeincrementsinfirmvalueandcompensation

    duetothescaleofoperationsundertheCEOscontrol(Himmelberg&Hubbard2000).Gabaix&

    Landier(2008)andTervi(2008)developthisideafurtherbysolvingcompetitiveandfrictionless

    assignmentmodels forCEOsunder the assumption thatmanagerial talenthas amultiplicative

    effectonfirmoutput.Inthisframework,andusingspecificassumptionsaboutthedistributionof

    CEOtalent,Gabaix&LandiershowthatCEOpayshouldmoveoneforonewithchanges inthe

    sizeof the typical firm.Thus, theyargue thatthesixfold increase inaverageCEOpaybetween

    1980and2003canbefullyexplainedbythesixfoldincreaseinaveragemarketcapitalizationover

    thatperiod.

    Asecondsetoftheoriesproposesthatchangesinfirmscharacteristics,technologies,andproduct

    marketsoverthe last30yearshave increasedtheeffectofCEOeffortandtalentonfirmvalue,

    andthereforealsotheoptimallevelsofincentivesandpay.Forexample,anincreaseinfirmsize

    raisestheoptimal levelofCEOeffort,andthus incentives, ifthemarginalproductofCEOeffort

    increases with the size of the firm (Himmelberg & Hubbard 2000, Baker & Hall 2004).

    Alternatively, the productivity ofmanagerial effort and talentmay have increased because of

    more intensecompetitionduetoderegulationorentryby foreignfirms (Hubbard&Palia1995,

    Cuat&Guadalupe2009a,b),becauseofimprovementsinthecommunicationstechnologiesused

    by

    managers

    (Garicano

    &

    Rossi

    Hansberg

    2006),

    or

    because

    of

    higher

    volatility

    in

    the

    business

    environment(Dow&Raposo2005,Campbelletal.2001).Finally,moralhazardproblemsmaybe

    moresevereinlargerfirms,resultinginstrongerincentivesforCEOsasfirmsgrow(Gayle&Miller

    20

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    22/47

    2009). Independently of their cause, higherpowered incentives have to be accompanied by

    higherlevelsofexpectedpaytocompensatemanagersforthegreaterriskintheircompensation.

    Athird

    market

    based

    explanation

    for

    the

    growth

    in

    CEO

    pay

    is

    ashift

    in

    the

    type

    of

    skills

    demanded by firms from firmspecific to generalmanagerial skills. Such a shift intensifies the

    competition for talent, improves the outside options of executives, and allows managers to

    capturealargerfractionoftheirfirmsrents(Murphy&Zbojnk2004,2007,Frydman2007).This

    theorypredictsanincreaseinthelevelofCEOpay,risinginequalityamongexecutiveswithinand

    acrossfirms,andahigherfractionofCEOshiredfromoutsidethefirm.

    Finally,a fourthmarketbasedexplanationproposes that thegrowth inCEOpay istheresultof

    stricter corporate governance and improved monitoring of CEOs by boards and large

    shareholders.Hermalin(2005)showsthat,ifCEOjobstabilityisnegativelyaffectedbyanincrease

    inmonitoring intensity,firmsoptimallyrespondby increasingthe levelofCEOpay.Accordingto

    this theory, theobserved rise inpayshouldbeaccompaniedbymoreCEO turnover,astronger

    linkbetween

    CEO

    turnover

    and

    firm

    performance,

    and

    more

    external

    CEO

    hires.

    However,

    an

    economywide strengthening of governancemay not lead to higher pay in equilibrium if the

    change also causes CEOs outside opportunities to become less appealing (Edmans & Gabaix

    2010).

    3.2Theempiricalevidence

    Manyof

    the

    theories

    described

    above

    have

    been

    developed

    to

    explain

    the

    rise

    in

    CEO

    compensationandtheuseofequitylinkedpaysincethe1970s.Itisthereforenotsurprisingthat

    manyofthemdoagoodjobfittingsomeofthemajorstylizedfactsandcrosssectionalpatterns.

    21

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    23/47

    However,asweargueinthissection,thesetheorieshavetroubleexplainingCEOcompensationin

    earlierdecades,aswellasrecentcrosssectionalpatternstheywerenotdesignedtomatch.

    3.2.1Evidence

    for

    and

    against

    the

    managerial

    power

    hypothesis

    ThemanagerialpowerviewofCEOcompensationissupportedbyseveralpiecesofanecdotaland

    systematicevidence.Forexample, thewidespreaduseof stealth compensation isdifficult to

    explain ifcompensationweresimply theefficientoutcomeofanoptimalcontract.Even though

    perks, pensions, and severance pay can be part of optimal compensation, hiding these

    compensationelementsfromshareholdersissuggestiveofrentextraction(Bebchuk&Fried2004,

    Kuhnen&Zwiebel2009).Similarly, thewidespreadpracticeofexecutiveshedgingexposures to

    theirown firm, againwithminimal disclosure, isdifficult tojustify (Bettis et al. 2001, 2010b).

    RentextractionisalsosuggestedbytheobservationthatCEOsarefrequentlyrewardedforlucky

    eventsthatarenotundertheircontrol(suchasanimprovingeconomy)butnotequallypenalized

    forunluckyevents (Bertrand&Mullainathan2001,Garvey&Milbourn2006).16Finally,CEOpay

    increasesfollowingexogenousreductionsintakeoverthreats(Bertrand&Mullainathan1998)and

    decreases following regulatory changes that strengthen board oversight (Chhaochharia &

    Grinstein2009).

    A furthersuggestivepieceofevidence forthemanagerialpowerhypothesis istherevelationof

    widespread options backdating and spring loading. Yermack (1997) observes that stock prices

    tend to rise subsequent tooption grants, suggesting thatpowerfulCEOs are awardedoptions

    rightbeforethereleaseofpositivenews(socalledspringloading).Recentevidenceshowsthat

    spring loading alone isnot sufficient toexplain the stockpricepatterns aroundoption grants.

    16 Jenter&Kanaan (2008) show thatCEOsaremore likely tobe firedafterbad industryorbadmarket

    performance,whichindicatesthatsomeCEOsarepenalizedforbadluck.

    22

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    24/47

    Instead,many grantsmusthavehad their grantdates chosenexpost tominimize the strike

    priceofatthemoneyoptionsandmaximizetheirvaluetoexecutives(Lie2005,Heron&Lie2007,

    Narayanan & Seyhun 2008). Such backdating of options appears to have been widespread,

    affectingabout30%offirmsfrom1996to2005 (Heron&Lie2009),andwasmoreprevalent in

    firmswithweak boards and strong chief executives (Bebchuk et al. 2010). However, option

    backdatingmayalsoariseduetoboardsdesiretoavoidaccountingchargesandearningsdilution.

    ItremainstobeshownthatbackdatingwasinfactassociatedwithrentextractionbyCEOs.

    Apotentcriticismof themanagerialpowerhypothesis is that it isunable toexplain the steady

    increaseinCEOcompensationsincethe1970s.Thereisscantevidencethatcorporategovernance

    has weakened over the last 30 years; instead, most indicators show that governance has

    considerably strengthenedover thisperiod (Holmstrm&Kaplan2001,Hermalin2005,Kaplan

    2008).Moreover,awardingpaybyallowingmanagerstoextractsomerentscanbeoptimal if

    monitoring iscostly.Inequilibrium,rentextractionmaybecompensatedforthroughreductions

    inother formsofpay, thusnot leading tohigher total compensation.Consequently,observing

    that a CEO receives forms of pay usually associatedwith rent extraction does not necessarily

    implythattheCEOscompensationexceedsthecompetitivelevel.

    Indefenseofthemanagerialpowerhypothesis,itispossiblethatthedesireorabilityofmanagers

    toextractrents(and increasetheirtotalpay)onlyemergedassocialnormsagainstunequalpay

    weakened.Piketty&Saez(2003)arguethatsuchashift insocialnormshelpsexplaintherise in

    CEOpayandthewideningincomeinequalityinthepastthreedecades,andLevy&Temin(2007)

    relate this change in norms to the dismantling of institutions and government policies that

    23

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    25/47

    preventedextremepayoutcomesfromWorldWarIItothe1970s.17Alternatively,theincreasing

    popularityofstockoptions,coupledwithboardslimitedunderstandingofoptionvaluation,may

    haveallowedmanagers tocamouflage their rentextractionasefficient incentivecompensation

    (Hall&Murphy2003,Bebchuk&Fried2004).

    3.2.2Evidenceforandagainstcompetitivepay

    Marketbased andoptimal contractingexplanations for the rise inCEOpayhave also received

    considerable empirical support. For example, the stock market tends to react positively to

    announcementsofcompensationplansthatintroducelongtermincentivepayorlinkpaytostock

    prices(Larcker1983,Morgan&Poulsen2001).Consistentwithacompetitivelabormarket,CEOs

    of higher ability (identified through better performance) tend to receive higher compensation

    (Graham et al. 2009). Moreover, changes in product markets appear to have increased the

    demand for managerial talent and raised CEO pay. Hubbard & Palia (1995) and Cuat &

    Guadalupe (2009a) document higher pay levels and payperformance sensitivities following

    industry deregulations, and Cuat & Guadalupe (2009b) show that pay levels and incentives

    increase when firms face more import penetration. While these exogenous changes in the

    contractingenvironmenthavethepredictedeffectsonmanagerialpay,theestimatedmagnitudes

    aremodest,leavingalargefractionofthesharpriseinCEOpayunexplained.

    The idea that firmsdemand forCEO skillshas shifted from firmspecific togeneralmanagerial

    human capitalhas theadvantageofpredictingnotonlyan increase in compensation,butalso

    changes in pay dispersion and managerial mobility that are consistent with the empirical

    evidence.Asdescribed inSection1,thepastthreedecadeshaveseenamarked increase inthe

    17However,FrydmanandMolloy (2010)suggest thatchanges in thehigh tax ratesprevalentduring this

    periodhadatmostmodestshortruneffectsonexecutivepay.

    24

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    26/47

    differences in executive paybetween large and small firms, andbetween CEOs andother top

    executives.Over the sameperiod, the ratioofnewCEOs appointed fromoutside the firmhas

    risensharply,topexecutiveshavebecomemoremobileacrosssectors,theirbusinessexperiences

    havebecomemorediverse,andthefractionofCEOswithanMBAhasrisen(Murphy&Zbojnk

    2007,Frydman2007,Schoar2008).However,thesechangesinmanagersbackgroundsandskills

    appeartohaveoccurredslowlyovertime(Frydman2007),andthemagnitudeandtimingofthe

    changesmaynotbelargeorquickenoughtoexplaintherapidaccelerationinCEOcompensation

    sincethe1980s.

    As detailed in Section 3.1,Hermalin (2005) argues that risingCEOpay is the result of stricter

    monitoringofCEOsbyboards and large shareholders.Thisview isbroadly consistentwith the

    empiricalevidence.Thefractionofoutsidedirectorsonboardsandthelevelofinstitutionalstock

    ownershiphaveincreasedsincethe1970s(Husonetal.2001),whileCEOturnovershavebecome

    morefrequent(Kaplan&Minton2008)andcloselylinkedtofirmperformance(Jenter&Lewellen

    2010).Whilethesetrendsaresuggestive,thereisnodirectevidencethatchangesingovernance

    causedthesurge inCEOpay,orthataddedpressureonCEOscanaccountforthemagnitudeof

    thepayincrease.

    Finally,theoriesbasedontheinteractionoffirmscalewiththedemandforCEOtalentfindtheir

    strongestempiricalsupportinthecorrelatedincreasesinfirmvalueandCEOpaysincethe1970s.

    Gabaix&Landier(2008)calibratetheircompetitivemodelofCEOtalentassignmentandfindthat

    thegrowth inthesizeofthetypicalfirm(measuredbythemarketvalueofthemedianS&P500

    firm)canexplaintheentiregrowthinCEOcompensationfrom1980tothepresent.However,this

    resulthasbeen criticized in several studies.Frydman&Saks (2010) show that the relationship

    betweenfirmsizeandCEOpayishighlysensitivetothetimeperiodchosen,asthiscorrelationis

    25

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    27/47

    almostnonexistent from the1940s to theearly1970s.Moreover, thepost1970s relationship

    maynotberobusttodifferentsampleselectionchoices(Nagel2010).Finally,sinceboththesize

    ofthetypicalfirmandCEOcompensationhavetrendedupwardssincethe1970s,itisdifficultto

    determinewhethertherelationshipbetweenthesetwovariablesiscausal.

    A seconddifficulty formodels of frictionless CEO assignment is the empirical scarcityof CEOs

    movingbetweenfirms.ThemodelsofGabaix&Landier(2008)andTervi(2008)predictthat,at

    anypointintime,amoretalentedCEOshouldrunalargerfirm.Consequently,anychangesinthe

    sizerankoffirmsshouldleadtoCEOsswitchingfirms.Inreality,CEOsstayatonefirmforseveral

    yearsandrarelymovedirectlyfromoneCEOpositiontothenext.Althoughitisstraightforwardto

    augmentacompetitiveassignmentmodelwitha fixedcostofCEO replacement, the fixed cost

    would need to exceed the effects of differences in CEO talent. A large fixed cost of CEO

    replacementcreateslargematchspecificrentsthatapowerfulCEOcouldcapture,fundamentally

    changingtheexplanationforhighlevelsofCEOpaytoonerelatedtomanagerialpower(Bebchuk

    &Fried2004,Kuhnen&Zwiebel2009).

    3.3Briefsummary

    Ourreadingoftheevidencesuggeststhatbothmanagerialpowerandcompetitivemarketforces

    are importantdeterminantsofCEOpay,andthatneitherapproachalone isfullyconsistentwith

    theavailableevidence.Ontheonehand,severalcompensationpractices,aswellasspecificcases

    ofoutrageousandhighlypublicizedpaypackages, indicatethat(at leastsome)CEOsareableto

    extractrentsfromtheirfirms.Ontheotherhand,efficientcontractingexplanationsarearguably

    more successful at explaining differences in pay practices across firms and at explaining the

    evolution of CEO pay since the 1970s. However, none of theories provides a fully convincing

    explanationfortheapparentregimechangeinCEOcompensationthatoccurredduringthe1970s.

    26

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    28/47

    Moreover,bothapproachesfailtoexplaintheexplosivegrowthofoptionsinthe1990sandtheir

    recent decline in favor of restricted stock, which may be in part a response to changes in

    accountingpractices. While it ispossible thatacombinationof theproposedexplanationscan

    explain the changes in CEO pay in recent decades, the relative importance of the different

    theoriesremainsanopenquestion.

    Section4:TheeffectofcompensationonCEObehaviorandfirmvalue

    Thedebate

    about

    the

    nature

    of

    the

    pay

    setting

    process

    and

    the

    recent

    financial

    crisis

    have

    createdrenewedinterestintheeffectsofcompensationonCEObehaviorandfirmperformance.

    Most concerns aboutmanagerial paywould be alleviated if high levels of CEO pay and high

    wealthperformance sensitivities led to better performance and higher firm values. However,

    providingconvincingevidenceontheeffectsofexecutivepayisextraordinarilydifficult.

    Themain

    problem

    with

    measuring

    the

    effects

    of

    compensation

    is

    one

    of

    identification.

    Compensation arrangements are the endogenousoutcomeof a complexprocess involving the

    CEO,thecompensationcommittee,thefullboardofdirectors,compensationconsultants,andthe

    managerial labormarket.As a result, compensation arrangements are correlatedwith a large

    numberofobservable andunobservable firm andCEO characteristics.Thismakes itextremely

    difficult to interpret any observed correlation between executive pay and firm outcomes as

    evidenceof

    acausal

    relationship.

    For

    example,

    CEO

    pay

    and

    firm

    performance

    may

    be

    correlated

    becausecompensationaffectsperformance,becausefirmperformanceaffectspay,orbecausean

    unobservedfirmorCEOcharacteristicaffectsbothvariables.

    27

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    29/47

    4.1:TherelationbetweenCEOincentivesandfirmvalue

    The relationbetweenmanagerial incentivesand firmvalue isoneof the fundamental issues in

    compensationresearch.Moststudies focusonwhethermanagerialequity incentivesaffect firm

    value,oftenmeasuredasTobinsQ. Inan influential study,Morcketal. (1988)document that

    firmvalueincreaseswithmanagerialownershipifmanagersownbetween0and5%ofthefirms

    equity,decreasesifmanagersownbetween5and25%,andincreasesagain(weakly)forholdings

    above25%.Oneinterpretationoftheirfindingsisthattheinitialpositiveeffectreflectsimproving

    incentives,andthesubsequentnegativeeffect increasingmanagerialentrenchmentandactions

    adversetominorityshareholders.Usingtwo largercrosssectionsoffirms,McConnell&Servaes

    (1990) find that firm value increases until the equity ownership by managers and directors

    exceeds40to50%ofsharesoutstanding.

    Subsequentstudieshaveexaminedhowdifferentaspectsofexecutivesequity incentivesrelate

    tofirmvalue,withmixedresults.Forexample,Mehran(1995) findsthat firmvalue ispositively

    relatedtomanagersfractionalstockownershipandtothefractionofequitybasedpay.Habib&

    Ljungqvist (2005) observe a positive association of firm valuewith CEO stock holdings, but a

    negativeonewithoptionholdings.Manyotherstudiesfailtofindanyrelationshipbetweenfirm

    value and executives equity stakes (e.g., Agrawal & Knoeber 1996, Himmelberg et al. 1999,

    Demsetz&Villalonga2001).Sinceequityholdingsaremanagersandboardsdecision,noneof

    thesecorrelationscanbeinterpretedascausal.

    Several studies use instrumental variables to address the endogeneity of managers equity

    incentives (e.g.,Hermalin&Weisbach1991,Himmelbergetal.1999,Palia2001).However, as

    pointed out by Himmelberg et al., valid instruments formanagerial ownership are extremely

    difficulttoobtain,becauseallknowndeterminantsofownershiparealso likelydeterminantsof

    28

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    30/47

    Tobins Q.18 Because of the lack of credible instruments, this literature has been unable to

    convincinglyidentifythecausaleffectsofmanagerialincentivesonfirmvalue.

    4.2The

    relation

    between

    CEO

    incentives

    and

    firm

    behavior

    Incentive compensation should motivate managers to make sound business decisions that

    increaseshareholdervalue.Toassesswhetherexistingcompensationarrangementsachievethis

    goal,alargeliteraturestudiestherelationshipbetweenexecutivecompensationandcompanies

    investmentdecisionsandfinancialpolicies.

    Manyof

    the

    early

    studies

    in

    this

    literature

    focus

    on

    accounting

    based

    long

    term

    incentive

    plans.

    Theintroductionofsuchplanshasbeenlinkedto,amongothers,increasesincapitalinvestment

    (Larcker1983)andimprovementsinprofitability(Kumar&Sopariwala1992).Morerecentstudies

    shifttheirfocustomanagersstockandoptionholdings.Equity incentiveshavebeenconnected

    to awide varietyofoutcomes, includingbetteroperatingperformance (Core& Larcker2002),

    moreandbetteracquisitions(Dattaetal.2001,Cai&Vijh2007),largerrestructuringsandlayoffs

    (Dial&

    Murphy

    1995,

    Brookman

    et

    al.

    2007),

    and

    more

    voluntary

    liquidations

    (Mehran

    et

    al.

    1998).Executivestockoptions,whichareusuallynotdividendprotected,havealsobeenlinkedto

    lowerdividends(Lambertetal.1989)andtoashiftfromdividendstosharerepurchases(Fenn&

    Liang2001).Finally,asizeable literaturestudiestherelationshipbetweenmanagerial incentives

    andcorporaterisktaking.Theresultssuggestthatstrongerequityincentivesareassociatedwith

    18Somepaperstrytoaccountfortheendogeneityofmanagerialownershipbyestimatingasimultaneous

    equation system.However, thisapproach requiresat leastasmanyexogenous variablesasendogenous

    variablesinthemodel,leavingthechallengesinfindingvalidinstrumentsunsolved.

    29

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    31/47

    less risk taking,whileconvexity inexecutivesportfoliosdue tooptions iscorrelatedwithmore

    risktaking.19

    4.3Incentive

    compensation

    and

    manipulation

    Any form of incentive compensation entails the danger that managers may manipulate the

    performance measure.20 Consistent with this prediction, several studies link earningsbased

    bonusplanstoearningsmanagement,especiallyifrealizedearningsareclosetofloorsandcapsin

    the bonus schedule (Healy 1985,Holthausen et al. 1995). Firms also seem tomanipulate the

    disclosure of information around CEO option awards, delaying the release of good news and

    accelerating the disclosure of bad news (Aboody & Kasznik 2000). Finally, a series of recent

    studies document a positive correlation between CEOs equity incentives and earnings

    manipulation(Cheng&Warfield2005,Bergstresser&Philippon2006,Burns&Kedia2006,Efendi

    etal.2007,Peng&Rell2008,Johnsonetal.2009).However,thereisdisagreementaboutwhich

    partofCEOsequity incentives is the culprit,with some studies linkingmanipulation tooption

    (butnot stock) incentives, andothers linkingmanipulation to stockholdings (butnotoptions).

    Moreover,theevidenceforaconnectionbetweenequityincentivesandaccountingirregularities

    isnotunanimous.Ericksonetal. (2006) find thatexecutivesequity incentivesareunrelated to

    accusationsofaccounting fraudby theSEC,whileArmstrongetal. (2009) find thatCEOequity

    incentives have, if anything, a modestly negative effect on restatements, SEC enforcement

    releases,andclassactionlawsuits.

    4.4Briefsummary

    19See,forexample,Tufano(1996),Guay(1999),Rajgopal&Shevlin (2002),Lewellen(2006),andColeset

    al.(2006).20

    See Bolton et al. (2006), Goldman & Slezak (2006), and Benmelech et al. (2010) for models of

    performancemanipulation.

    30

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    32/47

    The literature provides ample evidence that CEO compensation and portfolio incentives are

    correlatedwithawidevarietyofcorporatebehaviors, from investmentand financialpoliciesto

    risk takingandmanipulation.Arguably, thewidespreaduseof incentive compensationand the

    largecrosssectionaldifferencesinmanagerialcontractswouldmakelittlesenseifcompensation

    hadnoeffectonCEObehavior.However,becausecompensationarrangementsareendogenous

    and correlatedwithmanyunobservables,measuring their causal effects onbehavior and firm

    value isextremelydifficult and remainsoneof themost important challenges for researchon

    executivepay.

    Conclusion

    Theexecutivecompensation literaturehasexperiencedtremendousgrowth inrecentyears,and

    sohasourunderstandingofpaypractices.Yet,many importantquestions remainunanswered.

    For example, the causes of the apparent regime change in CEO compensation that occurred

    duringthe

    1970s

    remain

    largely

    unknown.

    The

    relative

    importance

    of

    rent

    extraction

    and

    optimal

    contractingindeterminingpayforthetypicalCEOisstilltobedetermined,andevenlessisknown

    about the causal effects of CEO pay on behavior and firm value. Finding answers to these

    questionswill requirea combinationofnew theorypredictions, the creativeuseofexogenous

    changes inthecontractingenvironment,andnewdatafromothercountries,priordecades,and

    differenttypesoffirms.Theprogressmadebyrecentstudiesonallthesedimensionsiscausefor

    optimismandsuggeststhatanswersmaynotbefaroff.

    DisclosureStatement

    31

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    33/47

    Theauthorsarenotawareofany affiliations,memberships, funding,or financialholdings that

    mightbeperceivedasaffectingtheobjectivityofthisreview.

    Acknowledgments

    We thank Jeffrey Coles, Alex Edmans, Eitan Goldman, ToddMilbourn, Kevin J.Murphy, Stew

    Myers,DavidYermack, and Jeff Zwiebel forhelpfuldiscussions and suggestions, and Francisco

    GuedesSantosandYesolHuhforassistanceinpreparingthismanuscript.

    32

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    34/47

    LiteratureCited

    Aboody D, Kasznik R. 2000. CEO stock option awards and the timing of corporate voluntary

    disclosures.J.Acc.Econ.29(1):73100

    AbowdJM,KaplanDS.1999.Executivecompensation:sixquestionsthatneedanswering.J.Econ.

    Perspect.13(4):14568

    AcharyaAV,VolpinPF.2010.Corporategovernanceexternalities.Rev.Finance14(1):133

    AggarwalRK,SamwickAA.1999a.Theothersideofthetradeoff:theimpactofriskonexecutive

    compensation.J.PolitEcon.107(1):65105

    AggarwalRK,SamwickAA.1999b.Executivecompensation,relativeperformanceevaluation,and

    strategiccompetition:theoryandevidence.J.Finance54(6):19992043

    AggarwalRK.2008.Executivecompensationand incentives. InHandbookofCorporateFinance:

    Empirical Corporate Finance, ed. BE Eckbo, pp. 497538. Amsterdam: Elsevier/North

    Holland

    AgrawalA, KnoeberCR. 1996. Firmperformance andmechanisms to control agencyproblems

    betweenmanagers

    and

    shareholders.

    J.

    Financ.

    Quant.

    Anal.

    31(3):377

    97

    AlmazanA,SuarezJ.2003.Entrenchmentandseverancepayinoptimalgovernancestructures.J.

    Finance58(2):51947

    Antle R, Smith A. 1986. An empirical investigation of the relative performance evaluation of

    corporateexecutives.J.Acc.Res.24(1):139

    Armstrong CS, Jagolinzer AD, Larcker DF. 2009. Chief executive officer equity incentives and

    accountingirregularities.Work.Pap.,StanfordUniv.

    BakerGP.1992.Incentivecontractsandperformancemeasurement.J.Polit.Econ.100(3):598614

    BakerGP,HallBJ.2004.CEOincentivesandfirmsize.J.LaborEcon.22(4):76798

    Bebchuk LA, Fried JM. 2004. Pay without Performance: The Unfulfilled Promise of Executive

    Compensation.Cambridge,MA:HarvardUniv.Press

    BebchukLA,GrinsteinY.2005.Thegrowthofexecutivepay.OxfordRev.Econ.Pol.21(2):283303

    BebchukLA,GrinsteinY,PeyerUC.2010.LuckyCEOsandluckydirectors.J.Finance.Forthcoming

    BebchukLA,JacksonRJ.2005.Executivepensions.J.Corp.L.30:82356

    BeckerB.2006.Wealth,riskaversionandCEOcompensation.J.Finance61(1):37997

    BenmelechE,KandelG,VeronesiP.2010.StockbasedcompensationandCEO(dis)incentives.Q.

    J.Econ.Forthcoming

    BenstonG.

    1985.

    The

    self

    serving

    management

    hypothesis:

    some

    evidence.

    J.

    Acc.

    Econ.

    7(1

    3):6783

    BergmanNK,JenterD.2007.Employeesentimentandstockoptioncompensation.J.Financ.Econ.

    84(3):667712

    Bergstresser D, Philippon T. 2006. CEO incentives and earningsmanagement.J. Financ. Econ.

    80(3):51129

    BerleAA,MeansGC.1932.Themoderncorporationandprivateproperty.NewYork:Macmillan

    33

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    35/47

    BertrandM.2009.CEOs.Ann.Rev.Econ.1:12149

    BertrandM,MullainathanS.1998.Executivecompensationandincentives:theimpactoftakeover

    legislation.Work.Pap.,NBER

    BertrandM,MullainathanS.2001.AreCEOsrewardedforluck?Theoneswithoutprincipalsare.

    Q.J.Econ.116(3):90132

    BettisJC,BizjakJM,ColesJL,KalpathyS.2010.Stockandoptiongrantswithperformancebased

    vestingprovisions.Work.Pap.,Ariz.St.Univ.

    Bettis JC,Bizjak JM,KalpathyS.2010a.Whydo insidershedge theirownershipandoptions?An

    empiricalexamination.Work.Pap.,Ariz.St.Univ.

    Bettis JC,Bizjak JM, LemmonML.2001b.Managerialownership, incentivecontracting,and the

    useof zerocost collarsandequity swapsby corporate insiders.J.Financ.Quant.Anal.

    36(3):34570

    Bizjak JM, Brickley JA, Coles JL. 1993. Stockbased incentive compensation and investment

    behavior.J.Acc.Econ.16(13):34972

    BlanchflowerDG,

    Oswald

    AJ,

    Sanfey

    P.

    Wages,

    profits,

    and

    rent

    sharing.

    Quart.

    J.

    Econ.

    111(1):22751

    BoltonP,ScheinkmanJA,XiongW.2006.Executivecompensationandshorttermistbehavior in

    speculativemarkets.Rev.Econ.Stud.73(3):577610

    Brookman JT,ChangS,RennieCG.2007.CEOequityportfolio incentivesand layoffdecisions.J.

    Financ.Res.30(2):25981

    Bryan S, Hwang L, Lilien S. 2000. CEO stockbased compensation: an empirical analysis of

    incentiveintensity,relativemix,andeconomicdeterminants.J.Bus.73(4):66193

    Burns N, Kedia S. 2006. The impact of performancebased compensation on misreporting.J.

    Financ.

    Econ.

    79(1):35

    67

    CaiJ,VijhAM.2007.IncentiveeffectsofstockandoptionholdingsoftargetandacquirerCEOs.J.

    Finance62(4):1891933

    CampbellJY,LettauM,MalkielBG,YexiaoX.2001.Haveindividualstocksbecomemorevolatile?

    Anempiricalexplorationofidiosyncraticrisk.J.Finance56(1):143

    Carpenter JN. 1998. The exercise and valuation of executive stock options. J. Financ. Econ.

    48(2):12758

    Carpenter JN, Stanton R, Wallace N. 2010. Optimal exercise of executive stock options and

    implicationsforfirmcost.J.Financ.Econ.Forthcoming

    ChengQ,WarfieldT.2005.Equityincentivesandearningsmanagement.Acc.Rev.80(2):44176

    ChhaochhariaV,GrinsteinY.2009.CEOcompensationandboardoversight.J.Finance64(1):231

    61

    Coles JL, Daniel ND, Naveen L. 2006. Managerial incentives and risktaking. J. Financ. Econ.

    79(2):43168

    Core JE,GuayWR. 2002a. Estimating the value of employee stock option portfolios and their

    sensitivitiestopriceandvolatility.J.Acc.Res.40(3):61330

    34

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    36/47

    Core JE, Guay WR. 2002b. The other side of the tradeoff: the impact of risk on executive

    compensationarevisedcomment.Work.Pap.,Univ.Penn.

    CoreJE,GuayWR,LarckerDF.2003.Executiveequitycompensationandincentives:asurvey.Fed.

    Res.BankNewYorkEcon.PolicyRev.9(1):2750

    CoreJE,GuayWR,VerrecchiaR.2003.Priceversusnonpriceperformancemeasures inoptimal

    CEOcompensation

    contracts.

    Acc.

    Rev.

    78(4):957

    81

    CoreJE,LarckerDF.2002.Performanceconsequencesofmandatory increases inexecutivestock

    ownership.J.Financ.Econ.64(3):31740

    Coughlan A, Schmidt R. 1985. Executive compensation, management turnover, and firm

    performance:anempiricalinvestigation.J.Acc.Econ.7(13):4366

    Cuat V, Guadalupe M. 2009a. Executive compensation and competition in the banking and

    financialsectors.J.Bank.Finance33(3):495504

    CuatV,GuadalupeM.2009b.Globalizationandtheprovisionof incentives insidethefirm:the

    effectofforeigncompetition.J.LaborEcon.27(2):179212

    DattaS,

    Iskandar

    Datta

    M,

    Raman

    K.

    2001.

    Executive

    compensation

    and

    corporate

    acquisition

    decisions.J.Finance56(6):2299336

    DemsetzH,VillalongaB.2001.Ownershipstructureandcorporateperformance.J.Corp.Finance

    7(3):20933

    DialJ,MurphyKJ.1995.Incentives,downsizing,andvaluecreationatGeneralDynamics.J.Financ.

    Econ.37(3):261314

    DiamondDW,VerrecchiaR.1982.Optimalmanagerialcontractsandequilibriumsecurityprices.J.

    Finance37(2):27587

    Dow J, Raposo CC. 2005. CEO compensation, change, and corporate strategy. J. Finance

    60(6):2701

    27

    EdmansA,Gabaix X. 2009. Is CEO pay really inefficient?A survey of new optimal contracting

    theories.Eur.Financ.Manag.15(3):48696

    EdmansA,GabaixX.2010. TheeffectofriskontheCEOmarket.Work.Pap.NewYorkUniv.

    EdmansA,GabaixX,LandierA.2009.AmultiplicativemodelofoptimalCEOincentivesinmarket

    equilibrium.Rev.Financ.Stud.22(12):4881917

    EdmansA,LiuQ.2010.Insidedebt.Rev.FinanceForthcoming

    Efendi J, Srivastava A, Swanson EP. 2007. Why do corporate managers misstate financial

    statements? The role of option compensation and other factors. J. Financ. Econ.

    85(3):667708

    EricksonM,HanlonM,MaydewEL.2006.Istherealinkbetweenexecutiveequityincentivesand

    accountingfraud?J.Acc.Res.44(1):11343

    FamaE.1980.Agencyproblemsandthetheoryofthefirm.J.Polit.Econ.88(2):288307

    FennGW,LiangN.2001.Corporatepayoutpolicyandmanagerialstockincentives.J.Financ.Econ.

    60(1):4572

    Finkelstein S, Hambrick D. 1996. Strategic Leadership: Top Executives and Their Effects on

    35

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    37/47

    Organizations.Minneapolis:West

    FrydmanC.2007.Risingthroughtheranks:theevolutionofthemarketforcorporateexecutives,

    19362003.Work.Pap.,MIT

    Frydman C, Molloy R. 2010. Does tax policy affect executive compensation? Evidence from

    postwartaxreforms.Work.Pap.,MIT

    FrydmanC,SaksRE.2010.Executive compensation:anewview froma longtermperspective,

    19362005.Rev.Financ.Stud.23(5):2099138

    GabaixX,LandierA.2008.WhyhasCEOpayincreasedsomuch?Q.J.Econ.123(1):49100

    GarenJ.1994.Executivecompensationandprincipalagenttheory.J.PolitEcon.102(6):11751199

    GaricanoL,RossiHansbergE.2006.Organizationand inequality inaknowledgeeconomy.Q.J.

    Econ.121(4):1383435

    GarveyGT,MilbournTT.2003. Incentivecompensationwhenexecutivescanhedge themarket:

    evidenceofrelativeperformanceevaluationinthecrosssection.J.Finance58(4):155781

    Garvey

    GT,

    Milbourn

    TT.

    2006.

    Asymmetric

    benchmarking

    in

    compensation:

    executives

    are

    rewardedforgoodluckbutnotpenalizedforbad.J.Financ.Econ.82(1):197225

    Gaver JJ, Gaver KM. 1995. Compensation policy and the investment opportunity set. Financ.

    Manag.24(1):1932

    Gayle GL,Miller RA. 2009. Hasmoral hazard become amore important factor inmanagerial

    compensation?Am.Econ.Rev.99(5):174069

    GibbonsR,Murphy KJ.1990.Relativeperformance evaluation for chiefexecutiveofficers. Ind.

    LaborRelat.Rev.43(3):30S51S

    Gibbons R,Murphy KJ. 1992.Optimal incentive contracts in the presence of career concerns:

    theoryandevidence.J.Polit.Econ.100(3):468505.

    Goldman E, Slezak SL. 2006. An equilibrium model of incentive contracts in the presence of

    informationmanipulation.J.Financ.Econ.80(3):60326

    Gopalan R,Milbourn T, Song F. 2009. Strategic flexibility and the optimality of pay for sector

    performance.Rev.Financ.Stud.23(5):206098

    GrahamJR,LiS,QiuJ.2009.Managerialattributesandexecutivecompensation.Work.Pap.,Duke

    Univ.

    GrinsteinY,WeinbaumD,YehudaN.2009.Theeconomicconsequencesofperksdisclosure.Work.

    Pap.,CornellUniv.

    GuayWR.1999.The sensitivityofCEOwealth toequity risk:ananalysisof themagnitudeand

    determinants.J.

    Financ.

    Econ.

    53(1):43

    71

    Habib MA, Ljungqvist A. 2005. Firm value and managerial incentives: a stochastic frontier

    approach.J.Bus.78(6):205394

    HadlockC,LumerG.1997.Compensation, turnover,and topmanagement incentives:historical

    evidence.J.Bus.70(2):15387

    HallB,LiebmanJ.1998.AreCEOsreallypaidlikebureaucrats?Q.J.Econ.113(3):65391

    36

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    38/47

    HallB,MurphyKJ.2002.Stockoptionsforundiversifiedexecutives.J.ofAcc.Econ.33(1):342.

    HallB,MurphyKJ.2003.Thetroublewithstockoptions.J.Econ.Perspect.17(3):4970

    Hartzell JC,Ofek E, Yermack,D. 2004.Whats in it forme? Privatebenefitsobtained byCEOs

    whosecompaniesareacquired.Rev.Financ.Stud.17(1):3761.

    HaubrichJG.

    1994.

    Risk

    aversion,

    performance

    pay,

    and

    the

    principal

    agent

    problem.

    J.

    Polit.

    Econ.102(2):25876

    HealyP.1985.Theeffectofbonusschemesonaccountingdecisions.J.Acc.Econ.7(13):85107

    HermalinBE.2005.Trendsincorporategovernance.J.Finance60(5):235184

    HermalinBE,WeisbachMS.1991.Theeffectsofboardcompositionanddirectincentivesonfirm

    performance.Financ.Manag.20(4):10112

    HeronRA, LieE.2007.Doesbackdatingexplain the stockpricepatternaroundexecutive stock

    optiongrants?J.Financ.Econ.83(2):27195

    Heron RA, Lie E. 2009.What fraction of the stock option grants to top executives have been

    backdated

    or

    manipulated?

    Manag.

    Sci.

    55(4):513

    25

    HimmelbergCP,HubbardRG.2000.IncentivepayandthemarketforCEOs:ananalysisofpayfor

    performancesensitivity.Work.Pap.,ColumbiaUniv.

    Himmelberg CP, Hubbard RG, Palia D. 1999. Understanding the determinants of managerial

    ownershipandthelinkbetweenownershipandperformance.J.Financ.Econ.53(3):353

    84

    HolmstrmB.1979.Moralhazardandobservability.BellJ.Econ.10(1):7491

    HolmstrmB.1982.Moralhazardinteams.BellJ.Econ.13(2):32440

    HolmstrmB,KaplanSN.2001.Corporategovernanceandmergeractivity in theUnitedStates:

    makingsenseofthe1980sand1990s.J.Econ.Perspect.15(2):12144

    Holthausen RW, Larcker DF, Sloan RG. 1995. Annual bonus schemes and themanipulation of

    earnings.J.Acc.Econ.19(1):2974

    Hubbard RG, Palia D. 1995. Executive pay and performance: evidence from the US banking

    industry.J.Financ.Econ.39(1):10530

    HusonMR,ParrinoR,StarksLT.2001.InternalmonitoringmechanismsandCEOturnover:along

    termperspective.J.Finance56(6):226597

    Inderst R,Mueller HM. 2009. CEO replacement under private information. Rev. Financ. Stud.

    Forthcoming

    Ingersoll J. 2006. The subjective and objective evaluation of incentive stock options. J. Bus.

    79(2):45387

    Janakiraman S, Lambert RA, Larcker DF. 1992. An empirical investigation of the relative

    performanceevaluationhypothesis.J.Acc.Res.30(1):5369

    JensenMC.1986.Agency costsof free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers.Am.Econ.

    Rev.76(2):32329

    Jensen MC, Meckling WH. 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and

    37

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    39/47

    ownershipstructure.J.Financ.Econ.3(4):30560

    JensenMC,MurphyKJ.1990a.Performancepayandtopmanagement Incentives.J.Polit.Econ.

    98(2):225264

    JensenMC,MurphyKJ.1990b.CEO incentives: itsnothowmuch,buthow.HarvardBus.Rev.

    68(3):13853

    JenterD.2002.Executivecompensation,incentives,andrisk.Work.Pap.MIT

    JenterD,KanaanF.2008.CEOturnoverandrelativeperformanceevaluation.Work.Pap.,Stanford

    Univ.

    JenterD,LewellenK.2010.PerformanceinducedCEOturnover,Work.Pap.,StanfordUniv.

    JinL.2002.CEOcompensation,diversification,andincentives.J.Financ.Econ.66(1):2963

    JohnT,JohnK.1993.Topmanagementcompensationandcapitalstructure.J.Finance48(3):949

    74

    JohnsonSA,RyanHE,TianYS.2009.Managerial incentivesandcorporate fraud: the sourcesof

    incentives

    matter.

    Rev.

    Finance

    13(1):115

    45

    JoskowP,RoseN.1994.CEOpayandfirmperformance:dynamics,asymmetries,andalternative

    performancemeasures.NBERWork.Pap.No.4976

    KaplanSN.2008.AreU.S.CEOsoverpaid?Acad.Manag.Perspect.22(2):520

    KaplanSN,MintonB.2008.HowhasCEOturnoverchanged? Increasinglyperformancesensitive

    boardsandincreasinglyuneasyCEOs.Work.Pap.,Univ.Chic.

    Klein D, Maug E. 2009. How do executives exercise their stock options? Work. Pap., Univ.

    Mannheim

    KuhnenCM,ZwiebelJ.2009.Executivepay,hiddencompensationandmanagerialentrenchment.

    Work.Pap.,NorthwesternUniv.

    KumarR,SopariwalaPR.1992.Theeffectofadoptionof longtermperformanceplansonstock

    pricesandaccountingnumbers.J.Financ.Quant.Anal.27(4):56173

    LambertRA,LanenWN,LarckerDF.1989.Executive stockoptionplansandcorporatedividend

    policy.J.Financ.Quant.Anal.24(4):40925

    LambertRA, LarckerDF.1985.GoldenParachutes,executivedecisionmaking, and shareholder

    wealth.J.Acc.Econ.7(13):179203

    Lambert RA, LarckerDF. 1987. An analysis of the use of accounting andmarketmeasures of

    performanceinexecutivecompensationcontracts.J.Acc.Res.25:85125

    Lambert RA, Larcker DF, Verrecchia RE. 1991. Portfolio considerations in valuing executive

    compensation.J.

    Acc.

    Res.

    29(1):129

    49

    Larcker DF. 1983. The association between performance plan adoption and corporate capital

    investment.J.Acc.Econ.5(1):330

    LazearEP.2004.Outputbasedpay: incentivesor sorting? InResearch in LaborEconomics, 23,

    AccountingForWorkerWellBeing,ed.SWPolachek,pp.125.Oxford:JAI/Elsevier

    LevyFS,TeminP.2007.Inequalityandinstitutionsin20thcenturyAmerica.Work.Pap.,MIT

    38

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    40/47

    LewellenK.2006.Financingdecisionswhenmanagersareriskaverse.J.Financ.Econ.82(3):551

    89

    LewellenW, Huntsman B. 1970.Managerial pay and corporate performance.Am. Econ. Rev.

    60(4):71020

    LieE.2005.OnthetimingofCEOstockoptionawards.Manag.Sci.51(5):80212

    MansoG.2009. MotivatingInnovation.Work.Pap.MIT

    McConnellJJ,ServaesH.1990.Additionalevidenceonequityownershipandcorporatevalue.J.

    Financ.Econ.27(2):595612

    MehranH.1995.Executivecompensationstructure,ownership,andfirmperformance.J.Financ.

    Econ.38(2):16384

    MehranH,NoglerGE,SchwartzKB.1998.CEOincentiveplansandcorporateliquidationpolicy.J.

    Financ.Econ.50(3):31949

    MeulbroekL.2001.Theefficiencyofequitylinkedcompensation:understandingthe fullcostof

    awardingstockoptions.Financ.Manag.30(2):530

    MorckR,ShleiferA,VishnyRW.1988.Managementownershipandmarketvaluation:anempirical

    analysis.J.Financ.Econ.20(12):293315

    MorckR,ShleiferA,VishnyRW.1990.Domanagerialobjectivesdrivebadacquisitions?J.Finance

    45(1):3148

    MorganAG,PoulsenAB.2001.Linkingpaytoperformancecompensationproposals intheS&P

    500.J.Financ.Econ.62(3):489523

    MurphyKJ.1985.Corporateperformanceandmanagerialremuneration:anempiricalanalysis.J.

    Acc.Econ.7(13):1142

    Murphy KJ. 1999. Executive compensation. In Handbook of Labor Economics Vol.3B, ed. O

    Ashenfelter,D

    Card,

    pp.

    2485

    563.

    Amsterdam:

    Elsevier/North

    Holland

    Murphy KJ. 2002. Explaining executive compensation:managerial power versus the perceived

    costofstockoptions.Univ.Chic.LawRev.69(3):84769

    MurphyKJ,ZbojnkJ.2004.CEOpayandappointments:amarketbasedexplanationforrecent

    trends.Am.Econ.Rev.94(2):19296

    Murphy KJ, Zbojnk J. 2007.Managerial capital and themarketfor CEOs.Work. Pap., Univ.

    South.Cal.

    NagelGL. 2010. The effectof labormarketdemandonU.S.CEOpay since 1980. Financ. Rev.

    Forthcoming

    NarayananMP,

    Seyhun

    HN.

    2008.

    The

    dating

    game:

    do

    managers

    designate

    option

    grant

    dates

    to

    increasetheircompensation?Rev.Financ.Stud.21(5):190745

    PaliaD. 2001. Theendogeneityofmanagerial compensation in firm valuation: a solution.Rev.

    Financ.Stud.14(3):73564

    PengL,RellA.2008.Executivepayandshareholderlitigation.Rev.Finance12(1):14184

    PikettyT,SaezE.2003.IncomeinequalityintheUnitedStates,19131998.Q.J.Econ.118(1):139

    39

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    41/47

    RajanRG,WulfJ.2006.Areperkspurelymanagerialexcess?J.Financ.Econ.79(1):133

    Rajgopal S, Shevlin T. 2002. Empirical evidence on the relation between stock option

    compensationandrisktaking.J.Acc.Econ.33(2):14571

    Roberts DR. 1956. A general theory of executive compensation based on statistically tested

    propositions.Quart.J.Econ.70(2):27094

    RosenS.1981.Theeconomicsofsuperstars.Am.Econ.Rev.71(5):84558

    RosenS.1982.Authority,control,andthedistributionofearnings.BellJ.Econ.13(2):31123

    Rosen S.1992.Contracts and themarket forexecutives. InContractEconomics, ed. LWein,H

    Wijkander.Cambridge:BlackwellPublishers

    RusticusTO.2006.Executiveseveranceagreements.Work.Pap.,Univ.Penn.

    Schaefer S.1998.Thedependenceofpayperformance sensitivityon the sizeof the firm.Rev.

    Econ.Stat.80(3):43643

    SchoarA.2008.CEOcareersandstyle.Work.Pap.,MIT

    SmithCW,

    Watts

    RL.

    1992.

    The

    investment

    opportunity

    set

    and

    corporate

    financing,

    dividend

    and

    compensationpolicies.J.Financ.Econ.32(3):26392

    Sundaram RK, Yermack DL. 2007. Pay me later: inside debt and its role in managerial

    compensation.J.Finance62(4):155188

    TerviM.2008.ThedifferencethatCEOsmake:anassignmentmodelapproach.Am.Econ.Rev.

    98(3):64268

    TufanoP.1996.Whomanagesrisk?Anempiricalexaminationofriskmanagementpracticesinthe

    goldminingindustry.J.Finance51(4):1097137

    YermackD. 1995.Do corporations awardCEO stock options effectively?J. Financ. Econ. 39(2

    3):23769

    YermackD.1997.Goodtiming:CEOstockoptionawardsandcompanynewsannouncements.J.

    Finance52(2):44976

    Yermack D. 2006a. Flights of fancy: corporatejets, CEO perquisites, and inferior shareholder

    returns.J.Financ.Econ.80(1):21142

    YermackD. 2006b.Goldenhandshakes: separationpay for retired anddismissedCEOs.J.Acc.

    Econ.41(3):23756

    40

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    42/47

    Figure1:MedianCompensationofCEOsandOtherTopOfficersfrom1936to2005Figure1shows themedian levelofcompensation inasampleofthe threehighestpaidofficers in the

    largest50firms in1940,1960and1990(foratotalof101firms).Firmsareselectedaccordingtototal

    salesin1960and1990,andaccordingtomarketvaluein1940.Compensationdataishandcollectedfor

    allavailableyearsfrom1936to1992;theS&PExecuCompdatabase isusedtoextendthedatato2005

    (Frydman&Saks2010).Totalcompensationiscomposedofsalary,bonuses,longtermbonuspayments

    (includinggrants

    of

    restricted

    stock),

    and

    stock

    option

    grants

    (valued

    using

    Black

    Scholes).

    The

    CEO

    is

    identifiedasthepresidentofthecompanyinfirmswheretheCEOtitleisnotused.Othertopofficers

    includeanyexecutivesamongthe3highestpaidwhoarenottheCEO.Alldollarvaluesare in inflation

    adjusted2000dollars.

    0.30.40.50.60.70.80.9

    11.11.21.31.41.51.61.71.8

    1.92

    2.12.22.32.42.5

    1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

    CEOs Other top executives

    Executivecompensationin2000d

    ollars(logscale)

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    41

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    43/47

    Figure2:TheStructureofCEOCompensation

    PanelA:ThestructureofCEOcompensationfrom1936to2005Thediagram shows themedian leveland theaveragecompositionofCEOpay in the50 largest firms in

    1940,1960,and1990(foratotalof101firms).Compensationdataishandcollectedfromproxystatements

    forallavailableyearsfrom1936to1992;theS&PExecuCompdatabaseisusedtoextendthedatato2005

    (Frydman&

    Saks

    2010).

    The

    figure

    depicts

    total

    compensation

    and

    the

    three

    main

    components

    that

    can

    be

    separatelytrackedoverthesampleperiod:salariesandcurrentbonuses,payoutsfromlongtermincentive

    plans(includingthevalueofrestrictedstock),andthegrantdatevaluesofoptiongrants(calculatedusing

    BlackScholes).ThecomponentpercentagesarecalculatedbycomputingthepercentagesforaverageCEO

    payineachperiodandthenapplyingthemtomedianCEOpay,asinMurphy(1999).Alldollarvaluesarein

    inflationadjusted2000dollars.Notethattheverticalaxisisonalogscale.

    0.00

    0.50

    1.00

    1.50

    2.00

    2.50

    1936-39 1940-45 1946-49 1950-59 1960-69 1970-79 1980-89 1990-99 2000-05

    Salary &

    Bonus

    LTIP &

    Stock

    Options

    74% 53% 40%

    19%15%

    37%

    $0.9m $1.0m $1.0m

    $1.2m

    $1.8m

    $4.1m

    $9.2m

    23%

    32%

    7%

    84%87%93%99%

    $1.1m

    99%

    $4,000

    $8,000

    $6,000

    $2,000

    $1,000

    $10,000

    $1.1m

    100%

    11%

    CEO

    compensationin2000dollars(log

    scale)

    42

  • 8/12/2019 Comp Survey 08-02-10

    44/47

    PanelB:ThestructureofCEOcompensationfrom1992to2008ThediagramshowsthemedianlevelandtheaveragecompositionofCEOpayinS&P500firmsfrom1992

    to2008andisbasedonExecuCompdata.ExecuCompcollectscompensationdatafromp