coffee cooperatives and fairtrade certification: a case ...€¦ · and uncle paul to read and...

99
GHENT UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION ACADEMIC YEAR 20132014 Coffee cooperatives and Fairtrade certification: a case study in Burundi Master’s Dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science in Economics Margot Vandorpe Under the guidance of Prof. M. D’Haese + S. Desiere

Upload: others

Post on 15-Feb-2021

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • GHENT UNIVERSITY

    FACULTY OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION

    ACADEMIC YEAR 2013– 2014

    Coffee cooperatives and Fairtrade certification: a case study in Burundi

    Master’s Dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science in Economics

    Margot Vandorpe

    Under the guidance of

    Prof. M. D’Haese + S. Desiere

  • GHENT UNIVERSITY

    FACULTY OF ECONOMICS AND BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION

    ACADEMIC YEAR 2013– 2014

    Coffee cooperatives and Fairtrade certification: a case study in Burundi

    Master’s Dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science in Economics

    Margot Vandorpe

    Under the guidance of

    Prof. M. D’Haese + S. Desiere

  • PERMISSION I declare that the contents of this thesis may be consulted and/or reproduced, provided that the source is acknowledged. Margot Vandorpe

  • Abstract (Dutch) Cococa, consortium des coopératives de café, is een unie van koffie coöperatieven in Burundi en

    regelt de koffie marketing en de export. Van de 13 aangesloten coöperatieven zijn er drie sinds

    maart 2013 Fairtrade gecertificeerd.

    Deze thesis onderzoekt de werkingsproblemen van vier van deze coöperatieven, gerelateerd

    aan de coöperatieve organisatievorm, de aard van de koffiemarkt en de lage socio-

    economische ontwikkeling van Burundi. Vervolgens wordt geanalyseerd of het Fairtrade label

    financiële en/of sociaal-economische voordelen biedt/kan bieden aan de coöperatieven,

    gegeven de specifieke context. Het onderzoek is gebaseerd op de analyse van documenten en

    kwantitatieve data van Cococa en semi-gestructureerde interviews met de voorzitters van de

    coöperatieven, de coördinatoren van Cococa en verantwoordelijken van de ondersteunende

    NGO’s.

    De belangrijkste werkingsproblemen zijn: gebrek aan focus op hun educatieve en sociale rol;

    lage participatie van hun leden in beslissingen; onvoldoende werkingskapitaal en daardoor late

    uitbetaling van de koffieboeren; weinig voordelen van het lidmaatschap; moeilijke

    kwaliteitsverbetering ondanks de betere prijzen voor hogere kwaliteitskoffie; en lage scholing

    en ervaring van management en leden waardoor deze en andere problemen uitvergroot

    worden. Cococa en de non-gouvernementele organisaties nemen echter enkele taken van de

    coöperatieven op zich, wat betreft de ontwikkeling van de coöperatieve, financiële steun en

    opvolging van de certificatie.

    Cococa heeft tot vandaag geen Fairtrade kopers gevonden, waardoor de gecertificeerde

    coöperatieven niet konden genieten van de directe voordelen van het Fairtrade label, zijnde de

    Fairtrade minimum prijs, de sociaal-economische premie en de mogelijkheid tot

    voorfinanciering. Dit is niet verbazingwekkend gezien het grote overaanbod op de Fairtrade

    markt. De Fairtrade certificatiecriteria leveren de coöperatieven echter wel indirecte voordelen

    op inzake organisatieontwikkeling, milieubescherming en veiligheid op de werkplaats. Een

    andere beperking van het certificaat is de kwaliteitsinvariante Fairtrade minimumprijs. De

    coöperatieven met koffie van hogere kwaliteit (en dus hogere marktprijzen) zullen minder

    voordeel halen uit het Fairtrade minimum.

  • I

    Acknowledgement Merci, merci beaucoup to all the people who helped me during the last year. First of all I want

    to thank professor D’Haese for guiding this master thesis. Special thanks to Sam Desiere for the

    excellent tutoring. Many thanks to Stefaan Calmeyn, the legal representative of Broederlijk

    Delen, who helped me in the start-up of the research and brought me in contact with many

    local organizations in Burundi. VLIR-UOS to make the journey financially possible. Sincere

    gratitude for the motivated and highly skilled team of Cococa, to welcome me in their

    organization and explain me with great patience the coffee and certification process of the

    cooperatives. Many thanks to Etienne Bihogo from Inades Formation to spend a lot of time,

    sharing his impressive knowledge on cooperatives and certification. Joseph and the whole team

    of Inades Formation, to help me where possible. Thanks to Abdon from Adisco to devote many

    hours explaining complex accountancy of the cooperatives. To all the coffee related people I

    met in Burundi, from the presidents of the coffee cooperatives and coffee farmers to the coffee

    cuppers of the Cup of Excellence and coffee bars in Bujumbura. Many thanks to my aunt Ann

    and uncle Paul to read and correct this work. Special thanks to my eldest sister Adeline and her

    friend Matthias, for being my best imaginable support team and giving me a house and home in

    Burundi. Thanks to my parents for having a lot of confidence in my studies and me. Thanks to

    my roommates Hanne & Kaat, my sisters and my friends. Thanks to all the coffee bars and

    libraries in Burundi and Belgium to provide a good working atmosphere. Thanks to the many

    cups of coffee that helped me focus during writing.

  • II

  • III

    Table of Content Acknowledgement .......................................................................................... I

    List of abbreviations ...................................................................................... VI

    List of figures ................................................................................................ VII

    List of tables ................................................................................................ VIII

    Introduction ................................................................................................... 1

    Part I: Literature review ................................................................................. 3

    1. Burundi and its coffee sector ................................................................................................... 3

    1.1. Socio-Economic situation of Burundi ................................................................................ 3

    1.1.1. Economic indicators .................................................................................................... 4

    1.1.2. Role of coffee .............................................................................................................. 5

    1.2. History of the Burundian coffee sector ............................................................................. 7

    1.3. Burundian coffee production ............................................................................................ 9

    1.3.1. Production processes ................................................................................................ 10

    1.3.2. Production volatility .................................................................................................. 13

    1.3.3. Burundian coffee quality ........................................................................................... 14

    1.4. International coffee prices .............................................................................................. 15

    2. Cooperatives .......................................................................................................................... 17

    2.1. Definition ......................................................................................................................... 18

    2.2. History of cooperatives in Africa ..................................................................................... 19

    2.3. Advantages of the cooperative organization form ......................................................... 21

    2.3.1. Transaction costs ....................................................................................................... 21

    2.3.2. Scale Economies ........................................................................................................ 22

    2.3.3. Filling up a market vacuum ....................................................................................... 23

    2.4. Operating difficulties inherent in cooperatives............................................................... 23

    2.4.1. Free-rider problem .................................................................................................... 23

    2.4.2. Horizon problem ....................................................................................................... 23

  • IV

    2.4.3. Portfolio problem ...................................................................................................... 24

    2.4.4. Control problem ........................................................................................................ 24

    2.4.5. Influence cost problem ............................................................................................. 24

    3. The Fairtrade label ................................................................................................................. 24

    3.1. Pricing policy .................................................................................................................... 25

    3.2. The certification process ................................................................................................. 27

    3.3. Positive impact ................................................................................................................ 29

    3.4. Criticism ........................................................................................................................... 30

    3.4.1. Impact on poverty reduction .................................................................................... 30

    3.4.2. Stable prices guarantee? ........................................................................................... 32

    3.4.3. Lack of recognition for quality .................................................................................. 33

    3.4.4. Other criticism ........................................................................................................... 34

    Part II Case study: Burundian coffee cooperatives and Fairtrade ................... 35

    1. Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 35

    2. Methodology ......................................................................................................................... 36

    3. Cococa and partner organizations ......................................................................................... 37

    3.1. Cococa ............................................................................................................................. 37

    3.2. Role of NGO’s .................................................................................................................. 39

    4. Internal structure cooperatives ............................................................................................. 41

    4.1. Characteristics of cooperatives ....................................................................................... 41

    4.2. The seven ICA principles .................................................................................................. 45

    4.3. Advantages of the cooperative organization form ......................................................... 47

    5. Operating challenges of the cooperatives ............................................................................. 49

    5.1. Payment of coffee farmers .............................................................................................. 49

    5.2. Pricing and marketing...................................................................................................... 50

    5.3. Member recruitment and compensation ....................................................................... 54

    5.4. Quality improvement ...................................................................................................... 55

    5.5. Low educational level of members and staff .................................................................. 60

  • V

    6. Fairtrade certification: illusion or solution? .......................................................................... 62

    6.1. Certification process ........................................................................................................ 62

    6.2. Opinions ........................................................................................................................... 64

    6.3. Impact .............................................................................................................................. 66

    6.3.1. Conditional advantages ............................................................................................. 66

    6.3.2. Incentives .................................................................................................................. 69

    7. Conclusion: to certify or not to certify? ................................................................................. 70

    Bibliography ................................................................................................. IX

  • VI

    List of abbreviations Adisco Appui au Développement Intégral et la Solidarité

    ARFIC Autorité de Régulation de la Filière Café du Burundi

    BIF Burundian Franc

    CEVAL Centre for Evaluation

    Cococa Consortium des coopératives de café

    Flo-Cert Fairtrade Labeling Organizations International - Certification

    FW Fully Washed

    ICA International Co-operative Alliance

    ICO International Coffee Organization

    ILO International Labour Organization

    IRED Innovations et réseaux pour le développement

    ISTEEBU Institut de statistiques et d’études économiques du Burundi

    ITC International Trade Center

    LIFFO London International Financial Futures and Options Exchange

    NCFC National Council of Farmer Cooperatives

    NGO Non-governmental Organization

    NYBOT New York Board Of Trade

    OHCHR Office of the High Commissioner of Human Rights

    PTD Potato Taste Defect

    SDL Stations de lavage

    SODECO Société de déparchage et de conditionnement

    UN United Nations

    USAID United States Agency for International Development

    USD United States Dollar

  • VII

    List of figures Figure 1: Share of coffee in total export earnings 2005-2010 ........................................................ 5

    Figure 2: Distribution of coffee trees in Burundian provinces ...................................................... 10

    Figure 3: Two main coffee cherries production processes ........................................................... 11

    Figure 4: Green coffee production in Burundi since 1982, for two different processing methods

    ....................................................................................................................................................... 13

    Figure 5: International market prices for Arabica and Robusta coffee (1980-2010) .................... 17

    Figure 6: The Arabica Coffee Market 1989-2010: Comparison of Fairtrade and New York Prices

    ....................................................................................................................................................... 26

    Figure 7: Cococa and partners ...................................................................................................... 36

    Figure 8: Proportion of coffee trees of 30 years and older in Burundian provinces .................... 44

    Figure 9: Relationship price ($/kg) and quantity (kg) of FW15+ green coffee contracts ............. 53

    Figure 10: Price range ($/kg) of Cococa’s contracts in 2012-2013 and 2013-2014 ...................... 54

    Figure 11: Cococa’s average prices of the superior quality grade and inferior quality grade,

    2012-2014 ..................................................................................................................................... 59

    Figure 12: Comparison of three relevant prices, April 2012- March 2014 (USD cents/pound) ... 67

  • VIII

    List of tables Table 1: Economic indicators of Burundi, 1962-2008 ..................................................................... 4

    Table 2: Fairtrade minimum prices and premiums for different varieties of Arabica coffee ...... 27

    Table 3: Characteristics of the four cooperatives ......................................................................... 42

    Table 4: Characteristics of buyers of Cococa ................................................................................ 52

    Table 5: Grading system of Fully Washed coffee .......................................................................... 57

    Table 6: Average prices per grading quality in coffee year 2012-2013 (USD/kg) and number of

    different buyers per quality .......................................................................................................... 58

    Table 7: Results linear regression of price .................................................................................... 60

  • 1

    Introduction This research essentially consists of two parts: a literature review and a case study. The first

    part discusses the relevant literature required to analyze a case study of four coffee

    cooperatives and a second-level cooperative Cococa, Consortium des Cooperatives de Café, in

    Burundi. Cococa is a union created to help 13 cooperatives managing their own washing station

    to commercialize and export their coffee. Two of these cooperatives have recently been

    Fairtrade certified. The purpose of this master thesis is twofold: an analysis of the main

    operating problems of the cooperatives and answering the question: can Fairtrade certification

    be considered as a financial or socio-economic development for these coffee cooperatives? The

    analysis of this question requires careful understanding of different topics. The first topics

    discussed in the literature review are the coffee cultivation and coffee market in Burundi, in

    order to gain a good insight into the core business of the cooperatives. Also important are the

    socio-economic situation of Burundi, the history of coffee cultivation and the recent

    privatization of the coffee sector. The second part of the literature review provides the theory

    on the cooperative organization form by analyzing the International Co-operative Alliance

    principles (ICA), the advantages over other business forms and the operating difficulties. Of

    course the research question demands an analysis of the Fairtrade label, issued by Flo-Cert.

    This third part focuses on the producer’s side: the certification criteria, positive impacts and

    criticism. The criticisms elaborated are those relevant for this case study: poverty reduction,

    stable prices guarantee and the lack of recognition for quality.

    The case study begins with the framework of Cococa and the introduction of the non-

    governmental organizations, which are part of the advisory board. The nature of the coffee

    cooperatives is studied, by applying the ICA principles and looking into the advantages and

    disadvantages. By discussing the main operating challenges of the cooperatives and analyzing if

    the Fairtrade certificate provides a solution, an answer to the research question is formulated.

    The operating challenges discussed here are the late and low payment of the coffee farmers,

    the low and volatile prices, the poor distinction in compensation between members and non-

    members, the difficulties of focusing on quality improvement and the low educational level of

    the management of the cooperative.

  • 2

    The case study is based on semi-structured interviews and document analysis. The time scope

    of the data is limited because Cococa has only been operational since 2012, one year before

    this research started. Moreover, the Fairtrade certificate was obtained in March 2013, only four

    months before the start of the research. Until today, no Fairtrade contract has been concluded

    by Cococa. This means the research lacks quantitative data on Fairtrade sales contracts to

    support conclusions or perform anything like a cost benefit or impact analysis. It is therefore

    mainly a qualitative analysis complemented with quantitative data on the coffee prices,

    quantities and quality. Another limitation of the research is the difficult in data collection: some

    data were incomplete or incorrect. Nevertheless, most of the data received by Cococa is

    trustworthy and carefully maintained.

  • 3

    Part I: Literature review

    1. Burundi and its coffee sector

    Burundi is a small country in Central Africa. Coffee is its main export product and accounts for a

    large share of its foreign exchange earnings (ITC, 2011). In what follows, some economic

    indicators of Burundi and the important economic role of coffee for the government and the

    inhabitants is outlined. Paragraph 1.2 covers the history of the Burundian coffee sector and

    paragraph 1.3 covers the Burundian coffee production, its production processes, volatility and

    quality. Paragraph 1.4 gives a brief introduction to the international coffee prices.

    1.1. Socio-Economic situation of Burundi

    Burundi is a small country in Central-Africa, without access to the sea. It is surrounded by

    Rwanda, Tanzania and Congo. Between 1993 and 2000 Burundi was trapped in an ethnic-based

    civil war between Tutsis and Hutus, which caused severe social and economic damage. In 2000

    the peace agreements of Arusha were signed, and some major challenges lay ahead for the

    unstable country: rebuilding their cities and infrastructure, organizing democratic elections,

    improving the living standard of its population, collecting external funds etc. (Vandenginste,

    2012). Burundi ended up worse than before the civil war: with a GDP per capita of only 600$

    (2012) it is ranked 5th poorest country of the world, after Zimbabwe, Somalia, the Democratic

    Republic of Congo and San Marino (CIA, 2013). Burundi faces many difficulties in modernization

    and development: bad infrastructure and roads, political instability, low agricultural

    productivity, low health and educational level of the population, low electricity supply,

    government corruption etc. The economy is characterized by subsistence farming. Agriculture

    accounts for 30% of the GDP and employs 93.6 % of the population. The primary sector remains

    the main sector, but the secondary and tertiary sectors gain importance (World Bank, 2011).

    Despite its small surface (27,830 km2), Burundi has a population of 10.8 million and a

    population growth rate of 3.08% (CIA, 2013). Rwanda and Burundi comprise one of the most

    densely populated areas of Africa (Isteebu, 2013). Sixty-eight percent of the Burundian

    population lives below the poverty line (CIA, 2013).

  • 4

    1.1.1. Economic indicators

    Table 1 enumerates some economic indicators between 1962, the year of independence, and

    2008. The GDP per capita declined over the 46-year period. This is mainly because of the high

    population growth rate and the sharp decline in GDP per capita during the civil war. We notice

    a spectacular rise in aid per capita. Burundi is extremely dependent of foreign aid, which

    represents 42% of its national income. This is the second highest percentage in Sub-Sahara

    Africa (World Bank, 2011). A declining export share in % GDP and a rising import share in % GDP

    contribute to a deficit in the current account balance.

    Table 1: Economic indicators of Burundi, 1962-2008

    Source: World Bank, 2011, p3

    The financial market of Burundi is clearly underdeveloped. The World Bank showed that only

    2% of the Burundian population had a bank account, 0.42% used bank credits and 4% was

    active in microfinance. Especially in rural areas access to bank accounts is difficult (World Bank,

    2011). The inflation rate is spectacularly high. In June 2013 it reached a maximum of 11.4%.

    This is of course not favorable to a stable investment climate (Isteebu, 2013). Since 2009

    Burundi joined the East African Community, which tries to strengthen the trade relations in the

    region.

    The survey of Bachmann (2009) in the provinces Kayanza, Ngozi, Gitega and Murumvya reveals

    that 55.3% of the households live under the poverty line of one dollar a day. Coffee is the

  • 5

    principal source of revenue for the rural population, followed by bananas and livestock.

    Estimates of the average land holdings are 2.17 hectares per household. Inspecting the

    numbers more closely they reveal that the land is very unequally distributed. 14.7% of the

    households cultivate less than 0.5 hectare and 27.9% cultivate more than 2.5 hectare. The

    shortage of land is a major problem for the poorest.

    1.1.2. Role of coffee

    Coffee is the second largest export commodity in the world after petrol. In the coffee season

    2010/2011 the total coffee production is estimated at 7.8 million tons. Coffee is the main

    export product of Burundi and accounts for 62% of its export value (see figure 1) and 90% of its

    foreign exchange earnings (ITC, 2011).

    Figure 1: Share of coffee in total export earnings 2005-2010

    Source: ITC, 2012, p20

  • 6

    Burundi’s export base is very limited and undiversified mainly because of the stagnation in

    agriculture. Because of the low diversification Burundian export incomes are volatile and

    vulnerable to external shocks such as bad weather, quantity or price shocks (World Bank,

    2011).

    According to a study of the ISTEEBU, Institut des Statistiques et d’études Economiques du

    Burundi (2013), 590.000 farmer families grow coffee, which is 45% of the total population. On

    average a coffee farmer owns 200 coffee trees (Ntimpirangeza, 2010). The income generated

    from coffee, is treated as unique by the farmers because of its seasonal effect and the lump

    sum it generates. Kimonyo & Ntiranyibagira (2007) write that as coffee is a seasonal product,

    revenues from coffee are larger than what the farmer is able to save over the year, and thus

    often used for non-daily expenditures such as construction works, school fees etc.

    Most farmers cultivate more than coffee: food crops (beans, maize, sorghum, potatoes,

    manioc…) and cash crops (bananas, sugar cane, tea…), and some farmers own livestock animals

    (Cochet, 1995). However the same study of Cochet in 1995 reveals that coffee is not the most

    beneficial and profitable crop for most Burundian farmers. The remuneration is low, the

    working conditions are bad and the purchasing power is decreasing. This outdated study of

    Cochet (1995) proves to be still relevant today. The Iwacu1 published on 23 March 2013:

    « Le café n’est plus rentable», se lamentent certains caféiculteurs. Ils menacent de le remplacer

    par d’autres cultures. Côté administration, le café est source de devises pour l’Etat et n’est pas à

    négliger. Des mises en garde viennent de tomber. » (Bukeyeneza, 2013, March 23)

    Until today the coffee culture is under threat due to low profitability. Coffee farmers may

    choose to switch to other cultures, which would pose a serious threat to state income. In the

    article cited, coffee is called a state project. The state imposes penalties of 2 000 BIF for each

    extracted plant and 20 000 BIF for each poorly maintained field.

    1 Iwacu is a national newspaper of Burundi

  • 7

    1.2. History of the Burundian coffee sector

    In 1930, Belgian catholic missionaries introduced coffee in Burundi. It was considered as a cash

    crop and thus an opportunity to acquire a good income for the farmers who were focused

    mainly on subsistence agriculture. The coffee production grew and reached 27.279 tons of

    green coffee in 1959 (Ired, 2011).

    In 1962, the independence of Burundi was celebrated. Coffee reminded the farmers of

    (unhappy) colonial times: production and quality dropped (Broederlijk Delen, 2011; Kimonyo &

    Ntiranyibagira, 2007), which worsened with the fall in prices. However, in 1976 the coffee

    landscape of Burundi changed completely. The government realized coffee could secure

    financial resources for the state and generate an income for the rural areas, where otherwise

    this is scarce. All private operators were nationalized and export related activities were

    regulated by OCIBU, Office du Café du Burundi. The OCIBU paid a fixed amount to the

    Burundian farmers, unrelated to the international price. This meant stability and protection

    from market volatility, but on the downside, farmers did not benefit from price increases

    (Broederlijk Delen, 2011).

    After the nationalization many investments were made in the sector: 133 coffee washing

    stations to produce washed coffee were installed in the countryside and plantation area

    doubled between 1980 and 1993. However due to large population growth and land scarcity in

    Burundi, the sector experienced growing difficulties (Kimonyo & Ntiranyibagira, 2007).

    Despite the investments, reform seemed necessary due to the following reasons: i) the

    expansion of coffee plantations did not lead to an expansion of production, which remained

    relatively stable between 1980 and 1993; ii) a monopoly of the OCIBU on the coffee export

    resulted in inefficient governance and low prices; iii) the price falls led to the build-up of

    significant deficits; iv) coffee farmers earned little while factory workers were well paid etc.

    (Kimonyo & Ntiranyibagira, 2007).

    In 1986 negotiations about privatization of the sector began with the IMF and World Bank.

    Seven years later, a terrible civil war began, which caused a rural exodus, demolition of

    plantations and washing stations, and a neglect of those plantations that survived. Privatization

    plans were postponed until after the peace agreements in 2000. The sector experienced much

  • 8

    material damage and the toll of human life was enormous. After the coup d’état of Pierre

    Buyoya in 1996, neighboring countries imposed an economic embargo on Burundi (Broederlijk

    Delen, 2011; Kimonyo & Ntiranyibagira, 2007).

    The Special Rapporteur on the human rights situation in Burundi reported the embargo was

    having a ‘disastrous effect’ on the Burundian population (Bossuyt, 2012). It also caused severe

    losses and disturbance in the coffee industry. In 1999 the embargo was lifted after progress by

    the government in the peace process. In 2006 the Burundian government opted for a total

    liberalization (Kimonyo & Ntiranyibagira, 2007). Two facts complicated this privatization

    process considerably: Burundi was still recovering from the civil war and the coffee sector was

    one of the most income generating sectors for the state. The privatization required the sale of

    the 133 coffee washing stations owned by the state. Owning a washing station is a very

    strategic possession in the coffee sector: at the washing station the quality of the coffee beans

    can be controlled and the product remains property until the export. In 2009 13 washing

    stations were sold to Webcor, a Swiss Company. In 2011 another 28 were sold to various

    private investors. Ninety-two washing stations remain property of the state today (Broederlijk

    Delen, 2011).

    Although the stakeholders agreed on the need for privatization, there is much criticism of the

    way the reforms have been implemented. The sale of the washing stations does not offer real

    opportunity for Burundian associations and companies. The would-be buyers need to show a

    bank balance of at least one million dollars over a minimum of three years. President Pierre

    Nkurunziza declared in his speech on the 1st of May 2007 that, coffee until exportation, is

    exclusively owned by the farmer, and 25% of the shareholding of the privatized stations de

    lavage (SDLs) would be given to farmer associations. These promises remain unfulfilled

    (Broederlijk Delen, 2011).

    On these reforms the CNAC, Conféderation Nationale des Caféiculteurs, an organization, which

    gives coffee farmers a voice at national level, reacted strongly. They demanded more

    participation and more ownership and blamed the government for not listening to the

    producers (Broederlijk Delen, 2011). Two UN experts, Olivier De Schutter en Cephas Luminas

    wrote on 18 April 2013 that privatization of the coffee sector in Burundi does not pay attention

  • 9

    to the interests of the producers. Meanwhile the reforms caused an ownership shift of those

    operations generating the highest profits to foreign companies (OHCHR, 2013, April 18).

    In 2007 OCIBU was replaced by ARFIC, Autorité Regulatoire du Filière de Café, a state-owned

    control organ of the coffee sector. ARFIC is responsible for statistics of the sector, collecting and

    dispersing data, and controlling and defining quality of the exported coffee. In the beginning of

    the coffee season ARFIC determines a minimum price per kilo to be paid to the producers. This

    price is in function of the market price (Broederlijk Delen, 2011).

    1.3. Burundian coffee production

    The Burundian coffee year starts on the 1st of April and runs until the 31st of March (ITC, 2011).

    In recent years only Arabica coffee has been produced in Burundi. Arabica coffee represents

    60% of the coffee worldwide and is considered the coffee with superior quality and taste. The

    international prices for Arabica coffee are higher than for Robusta, but Arabica is more

    susceptible to diseases. Important geological factors for coffee production are height, climate

    and rainfall. Arabica coffee requires an altitude between 1200 and 2000 meters, a moderate

    climate between 18 and 22°C and yearly rainfall between 1400 and 2000mm (ITC, 2011).

    Figure 2 shows the regional distribution of coffee trees in Burundi. The provinces with an

    important coffee cultivation are Kayanza, Ngozi, Gitega and Muyinga, all situated in Northern

    Burundi. The report of Isteebu (2009) reveals that washing stations are an important link in the

    coffee chain in Burundi. In the provinces with more than 150 001 coffee trees (see figure 2),

    65% to 90% of the coffee farmers sell their coffee to washing stations. In other provinces, with

    low coffee cultivation and probably less washing stations, the percentage of coffee farmers that

    sell their coffee to washing stations is much lower: in the eastern provinces Cankuzo and Ruyigi

    this is only 3.4% to 13% of the coffee farmers.

  • 10

    Figure 2: Distribution of coffee trees in Burundian provinces

    Source: Isteebu, 2009, p15

    1.3.1. Production processes

    The two main primary processing methods are the dry or unwashed process and the wet or

    washed process. Figure 3 shows the different steps in these processes. In both transformation

    processes, preliminary sorting and cleaning of the cherries is the first step. The damaged,

    unripe cherries are removed by hand or by flotation in washing channels. The next steps differ

    for the wet and dry process. The dry process is the oldest and simplest method. It requires less

    water, infrastructure and labor than the wet process. Almost all Robusta coffees and 90% of

    Arabica in Brazil are treated using the dry process. After cleaning, the cherries are dried in the

    sun. This is a step that heavily influences the quality of the coffee. The dried cherries are then

    stored in silos before transportation to a hulling machine, which removes all the remaining

    layers in one step (ICO, 2014b). The dry process delivers natural coffee (ITC, 2011). The key

    difference between the dry and wet process is the pulp removing operation. In the wet process

  • 11

    the pulp is separated from the beans before drying. This is done mechanically and should be

    initiated as soon as possible after harvesting to avoid deterioration of the fruit. Before

    proceeding to the next step, the beans need to pass screens and washing channels to separate

    out the unpulped and imperfect cherries. A parchment and a sticky mucilage layer now

    surround the coffee beans. This mucilage has to be removed by fermentation. After

    fermentation, the beans are washed in water and dried. In Africa, the coffee beans are often

    dried on drying tables. This method is appreciated and imitated around the world because it

    allows a uniform drying process with no fermentation. It may take up to four weeks before the

    cherries are perfectly dried, and this needs intensive hand labor to turn them and ensure even

    drying. The wet process produces fully washed coffee (ICO, 2014b). Coffee produced for both

    methods is called parchment coffee.

    Figure 3: Two main coffee cherries production processes

    Source: ITC, 2011, p189

  • 12

    In-between these two processes there is the semi-washed process. The semi-washed process is

    in the Great Lakes region of Central Africa performed by small hand equipment that pulps the

    ripe cherry (ITC, 2011). The semi-washed process differs from the dry process because of the

    pulp removing operation and differs from the wet process because there are no fermentation

    and washing tanks needed. However, the use of pulper and demucilager units are

    recommended (Winston et al., 2005).

    After drying, the coffee needs to be transported to the dry mill factory where the coffee grain is

    released of its parchment (hulling) (ICO, 2014b; Mutua, 2000). The two biggest dry mill factories

    in Burundi are in the hands of the government body SODECO, Société de déparchage et de

    conditionnement. SODECO is based in Bujumbura and Gitega and is a service provider, meaning

    that the coffee treated remains property of the cooperative. It processes the fully washed

    parched coffee to green coffee, ready to be exported (Cafe du Burundi, 2011).

    More than 95% of the coffee exports worldwide is exported as green coffee. Exports of roasted

    coffee are of negligible quantity. The coffee roasting is mostly performed by importing

    countries (ITC, 2011; Pay, 2009).

    Of all the Burundian coffee cherries 80 to 85 % are transformed in an industrial way to washed

    parchment coffee, and 15 to 20% is transformed at small-scale to semi-washed parchment

    coffee (Ired, 2011).

    Despite the advantages of selling coffee cherries to the washing station and produce washed

    parchment coffee (one gains time and gets higher prices) many coffee farmers still keep a part

    of the coffee cherries for home treatment (and thus produce semi-washed parchment coffee

    and sell their coffee to traders). Cochet (1995) cites some reasons: i) it is a way of family work

    for which the opportunity cost is low; ii) the harvested quantities are sometimes too low to

    undertake the journey to the washing station (the distance is often long and there is a lack of

    good conveyance); iii) some coffee farmers prefer to sell their coffee in accordance with their

    monetary needs throughout the year. The parchment coffee can be preserved for longer and

    can be sold as and when needed; iv) The farmers are often required to sell their coffee

    immediately because of lack of access to credit. The traders pay immediately, but give a lower

    price, which can be interpreted as an extremely high interest rate.

  • 13

    1.3.2. Production volatility

    Arabica coffee trees have a two-year harvest cycle, with consecutive bad and good harvesting

    years (Guariso, Ngabitsinze & Verpoorten, 2012). Figure 4 shows the production of green coffee

    in Burundi since 1980. Two major trends are noticeable: first, the total production of coffee in

    Burundi declined, probably due to old coffee trees still dating from colonial times, growing

    population requiring more land for food production and low international prices. A second

    trend is the more extreme fluctuations of production since 2000. In the eighties the coffee

    production fluctuated around 30.000 tons. After 2005 production fluctuated between 5.000

    and 30.000 tons. According to ARFIC the national coffee production of Burundi decreased from

    23 million ton in 2012-2013 to 10 million in 2013-2014, a decline of more than 50%

    (Nkengurutse, 2014, May 6).

    Possible explanations for these extreme fluctuations are climate change, ageing coffee trees,

    lack of fertilizers, demotivation of coffee farmers to take care of their plantations due to the

    privatization etc. (Twin, 2012). An interesting topic is the delayed reaction of supply on

    augmented prices. After a coffee year with high prices most cooperatives and farmers invest in

    new plants. Coffee trees can only be harvested three or four years after planting, resulting in a

    delayed supply effect of four years (Guariso et al., 2012).

    Figure 4: Green coffee production in Burundi since 1982, for two different processing

    methods

    Source: Twin, 2012, p3

  • 14

    1.3.3. Burundian coffee quality

    The quality of coffee is a complex matter to discuss. It depends on invariant geographic

    characteristics such as soil, height, climate and rainfall, and on production and processing

    systems such as selectivity of picking the coffee cherries, and the wet or dry transformation

    method. Besides these natural characteristics of the region and the manmade characteristics of

    the treatment process, the quality of coffee is in its tasting and therefore very subjective

    (Mutua, 2000).

    Generally speaking, coffee can be divided into three quality categories: exemplary coffee, high

    quality coffee and mainstream coffee. Mainstream qualities account for 85%-90% of world

    coffee consumption, and exemplary and high quality is only 10% to 15% of the world market.

    Exemplary quality is coffee with a high intrinsic value, usually of limited availability and retailed

    under origin names. The market for high quality coffee is much broader and represents a big

    percentage of the specialty coffee market. It includes good quality, organic coffees, washed &

    superior quality natural robustas. Mainstream quality is coffee of average quality. On the

    international coffee market there is room from top quality coffee to undergrade or lowgrade

    coffee. Undergrades or lowgrades are coffee beans, which do not fit into the above mentioned

    categories and contain many defects (the maximum number of defects allowed depends on the

    market) (ITC, 2011).

    When the wet process is carefully done, the quality of the coffee beans will be better than

    when dry processed, and better prices can be negotiated. On average 80% of Burundian coffee

    is fully washed, thanks to the investments in building washing stations in the 80’s

    (Ntimpirangeza, 2010). Production of high quality coffee is of course only interesting for the

    coffee farmers if they are rewarded for the extra work. Like the price for conventional coffee,

    the premium paid for high quality coffee is determined by supply and demand. Because the

    quality coffee market is still very limited, producers should focus on both markets, selling their

    top quality on the specialty market and what remains on the mainstream market (ITC, 2011).

    Despite its high intrinsic quality, the Burundian coffee has been used as a cheap substitute for

    washed Arabica’s from Kenya, Ethiopia, Tanzania and Rwanda (Twin, 2012). Twin (2012) holds

    the lack of vision and strategy to promote Burundian quality coffee responsible for not

    maximizing its market value.

  • 15

    Improvement of coffee quality is a topical subject in Burundi. Some highly regarded Specialty

    Coffee events took place in Bujumbura: in August 2013 the Cup Of Excellence; in February 2014

    the 11th conference and exhibition of the African Fine Coffees Association. In March 2014 Iwacu

    writes “The production of high quality coffee starts in the field”, reporting on a one-week

    conference in Ngozi on production of quality coffee, organized by Kahawatu foundation

    (Ndayikengurukiye, 2014, March 7).

    Burundi and neighboring Rwanda however cope with a serious quality threat, the potato taste

    defect (PTD), causing an odor and flavor of rotten potatoes in the coffee cup (Pittalwala, 2013,

    August 23). This disease, which reduces the quality considerably, is caused by bacteria entering

    the cherries via insect bite of the Antestiopsis bug (Bouyjou, Decazy & Fourny, 1999). Much

    research still needs to be done on the subject but so far it is known that the potato taste defect

    is only apparent after brewing and thus generally occur after shipping (Pittalwala, 2013, August

    23).

    1.4. International coffee prices

    The coffee market is a very complex market to discuss. In order to give a general introduction,

    this part discusses the volatility of international coffee prices and the International Coffee

    Agreement designed to reduce this volatility. It is a very brief introduction but necessary to

    understand the following parts.

    Big fluctuations in demand and supply and very volatile prices are warp and weft at the

    international coffee market: prices of Arabica coffee rose at the start of 2014 by 90% due to

    drought in Brazil and market speculation. This will very likely affect the coffee prices for

    consumers (Matyn, 2014, March 12). In Burundi the price paid to the producers rose from 400

    BIF to 600 BIF (Nkengurutse, 2014, March 22). Only a few months earlier, coffee prices were

    described as reaching an historic low by International Business Times (Rudarakanchana, 2013,

    October 23). This price volatility can be explained by the fluctuating supply due to harvest

    cycles and weather conditions in the biggest export countries (Brazil, Colombia, Indonesia and

    Vietnam) (ITC, 2011). The extreme volatility of the coffee market affects the production and

    investment decisions in the coffee growing countries considerably. The demand for coffee and

    especially quality and certified coffee is growing in western countries, but profitability of coffee

    http://www.ibtimes.com/reporters/nat-rudarakanchana

  • 16

    cultivation in coffee producing countries is decreasing (Osorio, 2002; Rudarakanchana, 2013

    October 23).

    The International Coffee Agreement (ICA) came into force in 1962 and was introduced as an

    export quota system to stabilize and increase coffee prices. The International Coffee

    Organization (ICO) is the controlling body of the agreement, which is binding in all major

    producing countries and most consuming countries. In 1989 the quota system was suspended,

    mainly because of competition among producing countries that strove for larger market shares

    and thus brought about the demise of the quota system. The failure of this agreement resulted

    in deregulation of the market and due to new producers such as Vietnam and technological

    innovations in the roasting industry, prices fell sharply (Hoebink, Ruben, Elbers & Rijsbergen,

    2014). Since then there have been six subsequent agreements. The ICA of 2007 came into force

    in 2011 with the same objectives of stabilizing prices (ITC, 2011).

    Figure 5 depicts the international market prices for Arabica and Robusta coffee between 1980

    and 2010. There is a sharp decline in prices after the demise of the ICA in 1989. The fall in

    earnings is particularly severe for countries where coffee represents a high share of the export

    revenue, such as Burundi. Prices peaked in 1994 and 1997 due to respectively frost damage and

    drought in Brazil. In 2001 a 30-year low was reached due to oversupply of coffee, called the

    ‘coffee crisis’ by the ICO (Osorio, 2002). After a small depression in 2008, caused by the global

    financial crisis, prices reached a high in August 2010 (Fairtrade International, 2011f).

    http://www.ibtimes.com/reporters/nat-rudarakanchana

  • 17

    Figure 5: International market prices for Arabica and Robusta coffee (1980-2010)

    Source: Guariso et al., 2012, p403.

    Coffee prices are determined by availability, quality and market trends such as expectations,

    speculation, currency exchange rate changes etc. The New York Board of Trade (NYBOT)

    determines the price for Arabica coffee and the London International Financial Futures and

    Options Exchange (LIFFO) for Robusta coffee. These are future prices reflecting the future

    estimated availability and demand for coffee as a whole. This one single price index reflects an

    average quality. High quality Arabica coffee will therefore have a positive differential in the

    New York price (ITC, 2011).

    2. Cooperatives

    After the financial crisis renewed interest in the cooperative as an alternative organization

    form, was showed. The United Nations declared 2012 the international year of cooperatives

    (UN, 2012). Agricultural cooperatives proved their importance in achieving food security (UN,

    2013). ILO, the International Labor Organization, created the cooperative facility for Africa

    (CoopAFRICA), a regional technical cooperation program, in order to achieve the Millennium

    Development Goals and strengthen the cooperative network (Pollet, 2009). All this clearly

    indicates renewed interest and belief in cooperatives and what they can achieve.

  • 18

    In Burundi cooperatives play an important role in the coffee sector. Valentinov (2007) develops

    an explanation why cooperatives are important in agriculture. He argues family farms

    experience high transaction costs that can limit the ability to realize economies of scale. Family

    farms are also less suitable to develop market power. The disadvantages of the family farm

    represent the major motives for the creation of agricultural cooperatives.

    In what follows a definition and the main principles of a cooperative are given. Paragraph 2.2

    discusses briefly the history of cooperatives in Africa, paragraph 2.3 and paragraph 2.4

    elaborate on the main advantages and challenges of cooperatives. All literature discussed

    focuses on agricultural cooperatives in an African context.

    2.1. Definition

    The ICA, international Cooperative Alliance, defines a cooperative “an autonomous association

    of persons united voluntarily to meet their common economic, social and cultural needs and

    aspirations through a jointly-owned and democratically-controlled enterprise” (ICA, 2014). To

    be considered as a cooperative, the organization must meet seven internationally recognized

    principles:

    - Open and voluntary membership. This connotes no discrimination of gender, religion,

    race, or social, political preference;

    - Democratic member control. The members of the cooperative actively participate in

    decision and policy making and representatives are elected in a democratic manner;

    - Member economic participation. A part of the capital of the cooperative is made of

    contributions of members, and members receive limited compensation for their

    membership fees. Cooperatives return surplus income to members in proportion to

    their use of the cooperative, not to their investment. Moreover, this capital is

    democratically controlled and is most often allocated to development of the

    cooperative, to facilitate transactions for members and to support other activities;

    - Cooperatives should be autonomous and independent. They are controlled by their

    members, not by external organizations or governments;

    - Crucial role of cooperatives in education, training and information of their members,

    employees, elected representatives. This is important for the development of the

    cooperative;

  • 19

    - Cooperation among cooperatives and strengthening of the cooperative network which

    lead to better service for their members;

    - Concern for community. Cooperatives take care of the sustainable development of their

    communities;

    (ICA, 2014)

    Economic theories about cooperatives are found in new institutional economics, which

    criticizes the neoclassical theory for its unrealistic assumptions of zero transaction and

    adjustment costs and exclusive focus on profit maximization. The new institutional economics

    focuses on the existence of transaction costs, property right structures and agency theories.

    The theory pays attention to institutional constraints and alternative organization forms

    (Ortmann & King, 2007a). Helmberger & Hoos (1962) can be considered as the first authors

    presenting a mathematical behavioral model of agricultural cooperatives. The optimization

    problem of the cooperative in their model is the maximization of the price per unit by

    distributing all earnings back to its members in proportion to their use of the cooperative.

    Generally, agricultural cooperatives can be classified in three subgroups: marketing

    cooperatives which negotiate better prices and produce and sell agricultural products; farm

    supply cooperatives which buy farm supplies such as fertilizer, seeds… and redistribute these

    among their members at advantageous prices; and service cooperatives which organize

    services such as transport, insurance, storage for their members (Ortmann & King, 2007a).

    2.2. History of cooperatives in Africa

    The modern cooperative originates from Western Europe and was introduced to Africa in the

    19th century by colonial authorities. The cooperative sector of those days was imposed and had

    no links with existing pre-colonial structures and traditions. The foreign models were designed

    for colonial purpose and benefits. Sub-Saharan Africa has known many failures of rural

    cooperatives between 1960 and 1990, which is often attributed to management problems and

    internal weaknesses of the cooperatives. Lack of knowledge and experience in management is

    often a core problem (Develtere & Pollet, 2008; Van Niekerk, 1988). To blame are also local

    politics and the donor sector. The donor sector preferred the one-size-fits-all strategy and

    invested excessively in poorly adjusted, non-viable cooperatives (Develtere & Pollet, 2008). A

  • 20

    review of the World Bank in 1986 showed that 50% of all agricultural projects in Africa were

    operated by cooperatives (Pohlmeier, 1990). Often, members of cooperatives were more

    development aid partners than owners and decision makers of their own cooperative.

    Many cooperatives functioned as semi-public and bureaucratic enterprises rather than private,

    voluntary businesses. The colonial traditions heavily influenced the organizational structure and

    the positioning in the socio-economic sector of cooperatives. Develtere (2008) define the

    Belgian colonialism in Congo and the former Urundi-Rwanda as a social movement tradition.

    The cooperative featured as an instrument of collective action and established social

    organizations played the crucial role of bringing people together. Indigenous people were free

    to set up own cooperatives, which were semi-public enterprises that generated income for

    administrative structures and additional income for the local population. After World War II the

    Belgian colonial authorities created special cooperative departments, which promoted the

    creation of indigenous cooperatives and registered new ones. The paternalistic approach of the

    Belgian colonists required that each committee contained one or more Belgian representatives.

    The cooperative role in Belgian Central Africa continued without support of the colonials. Local

    entrepreneurs set up credit or savings cooperatives supported by catholic missionaries. In

    Burundi, a strong cooperative sector did not emerge. The Cooperative department, created in

    1976, supported consumer cooperatives and later credit and saving societies, but very few

    were sustainable. Religious organizations, social movements and non-governmental

    organizations filled up the space with private initiatives. Survey studies in 9 countries in Africa

    showed the lack of coherent cooperative movement and the negative connotations around

    cooperatives (Pollet, 2009). Develtere, Pollet & Wanyaruma (2008) write about the renaissance

    of the African movement. Despite the history, the cooperative organizational form did not

    disappear from the scene. It continues to play a determining role in economic and social

    sectors, but carries its history with it. “The colonial and post-colonial phases they went through

    have definitely left their mark on the way people look at cooperatives, the way cooperatives

    operate, and the way external patrons such as governments and the donor community relate

    with them.” (Develtere, Pollet & Wanyaruma, 2008, p xiii-p xiv) However, the scene changed:

    many African countries have been through a period of liberalization. ILO created COOPAFRICA in

    2007, to guide this renaissance period of the cooperative movement. The goal of COOPAFRICA is

    to improve the efficiency, management and governance of the cooperatives in order to create

  • 21

    more jobs, reduce poverty and provide social protection. This can be achieved through working

    on a favorable legal and institutional environment, a stronger voice of the cooperative

    movement, better management etc. (Pollet, 2009).

    2.3. Advantages of the cooperative organization form

    Why are cooperatives created rather than more conventional business entities, or rather than

    individual trade relations? The non-state sector consists primarily of the business community,

    which insists on the necessity of return on investment, and the civil society organizations,

    insisting on primacy of community values and ethics. Cooperatives are an in-between form,

    combining the value rationale of the civil society with the entrepreneurial rationale of the

    business community (ILO, 2001).

    Literature on market access of small-scale farmers in the developing world reveals many

    difficulties such as information asymmetries and credit constraints (Poulton, Dorward & Kydd,

    2010). The National Council of Farmer Cooperatives argues that cooperatives strengthen

    bargaining power; maintain access to competitive markets; capitalize on new market

    opportunities; obtain needed products and services on a competitive basis; improve income

    opportunities; reduce costs and manage risks (NCFC, 2014). Three main advantages of the

    cooperative organization form are discussed below: transaction costs, scale economies and

    ability to fill market vacuums.

    2.3.1. Transaction costs

    Transaction costs are the costs of organizing and transacting exchanges. This can be divided

    into search and information costs, bargaining and decision costs, and policing and enforcement

    costs (Williamson, 1985). The theory on transaction costs was initiated by Coase (1937) and

    remains a popular theme in the new institutional economics (Szabó, 2002). Transaction costs

    are considered as one of the main reasons to integrate (Ollila & Nilsson, 1995; Williamson,

    1985).

    Smallholder farmers experience high unit transaction costs in all non-labor transactions. Access

    to inputs, services and training is difficult. However, they have a competitive advantage in

    access to labor over large producers because of the low costs of family labor (Poulton et al.,

  • 22

    2010). Collective action to overcome these high transaction costs and barriers to the market

    has proven to be effective (Stockbridge, Dorward & Kydd, 2003).

    The cooperative is able to overcome information barriers more easily than individual farmers.

    The cooperative has more resources to collect information and can diffuse this information to

    its members. Hereby the market transparency increases and the chance of market failure

    lowers. More access to information and lower transaction costs means better market access.

    Therefore cooperatives can be a deserving competitor of bigger players on the market

    (Ortmann & King, 2007b).

    Cooperation means a stronger voice at the bargaining table. This may result in financial

    reductions for the cooperative and better prices for the cooperative members (Markelova,

    Meinzen-Dick, Hellin & Dohrn, 2009; Szabó, 2002).

    Last are enforcement costs. These are the costs of searching, making up and concluding

    contracts with outsiders. Outsiders can be financial institutions, buyers, intermediaries, non-

    governmental organizations etc. Collective action can facilitate this communication and

    overcome barriers to entry (Markelova et al., 2009; Thorp, Stewart & Heyer, 2005).

    2.3.2. Scale Economies

    By working cooperatively, products and services can be obtained on a competitive basis. This is

    better known as scale economies. The possibility of scale economies may increase the

    investment possibilities (Ortmann & King, 2007b). Besides cost reduction of inputs, the

    increased production volume and joint deliveries to the market can increase the market power,

    reduce the transaction costs and improve the bargaining power for better prices

    (Mujawamariya, D’Haese & Speelman, 2013).

    In addition, collective action provides ample opportunities to improve the marketing of the

    products or services. Cooperatives are well suited to create entry into new markets such as

    certified or high quality markets (by obtaining the necessary information, achieving quality

    standards, gaining a bigger quantity) or to introduce value-adding activities in existing value

    chains (by innovating and/or branding) (Markelova et al., 2009).

  • 23

    2.3.3. Filling up a market vacuum

    Cooperative business can create a solution for certain needs in societies that are not provided

    by the market. This may be social needs or economic needs. Markelova et al. (2009) conclude

    collective action can help correct missing credit markets and fill in coordination gaps. They cite

    many case studies where collective action enabled farmer’s access to financial loans, easier and

    more affordable transportation and other services. In the case study of Mujawamariya et al.

    (2013) in Rwanda, 46% of the farmers received credit of the cooperative.

    2.4. Operating difficulties inherent in cooperatives

    Cook (1995), Ortmann & King (2007a) and Royer (1999) present five core problems inherent to

    the organizational form of cooperatives: the free-rider problem, the horizon problem, the

    portfolio problem, the control problem and the influence cost problem are discussed below.

    2.4.1. Free-rider problem

    The free-rider problem of cooperatives exists both internally and externally. The internal free-

    rider problem arises because returns and rights are distributed to the members proportional to

    the use of the cooperative (for example: kilos of coffee brought to the cooperative) and not

    proportional to their initial investment. New members therefore receive the same rights as

    existing members, even though they are not required to make up-front investments. The

    existing members see their returns dilute and are discouraged to invest in the cooperative. On

    the other hand decisions that increase cash flow per member arise more frequently (Cook,

    1995; Royer, 1999).

    External free-rider problems originate if the cooperative provides goods and services for its

    members, but cannot exclude non-members from benefiting. This arises when the provided

    goods and services are public goods (Cook, 1995; Ortmann & King, 2007a).

    2.4.2. Horizon problem

    Cooperatives generally underinvest in research, development and marketing, typically assets

    with long-term return (Ortmann & King, 2007a). This problem is caused by the simple fact that

    members only benefit from the activities of the cooperative as long as they are member. This

  • 24

    puts pressure on the decision-making units to focus on current pay-offs instead of future

    development and payments (Cook, 1995; Ortmann & King, 2007a; Royer, 1999).

    2.4.3. Portfolio problem

    Members of a cooperative cannot diversify their investments according to their own welfare

    and risk preferences (Royer, 1999). Risk-averse members will pressure the board to lower risk

    possibly at a cost of higher returns. Therefore suboptimal portfolios will arise (Cook, 1995).

    Diversification by outside investors is not possible, because they are excluded from investments

    in the cooperative (Ortmann & King, 2007a; Royer, 1999).

    2.4.4. Control problem

    Principal-agent problems will likely arise because of the division of control and ownership.

    Divergence of interest between the principal (cooperative members and board of directors) and

    the agent (management) are difficult to solve (Cook, 1995). Moreover the members experience

    an information problem because there exists no equity exchange market where the value of the

    shares and the management performance can be deducted from (Royer, 1999). This is less a

    problem in small homogeneous cooperatives (Cook, 1999; Ortmann & King, 2007a).

    2.4.5. Influence cost problem

    “Influence costs are those costs associated with activities in which members or groups within an

    organization engage in an attempt to influence the decisions that affect the distribution of

    wealth or other benefits within an organization” (Royer, 1999, p56). Ortmann & King (2007a)

    and Royer (1999) argue this is particularly a problem in cooperatives since the interests of the

    members are related to individual farm production and are thus more diverse than the

    interests of corporate stockholders who aim to maximize wealth.

    3. The Fairtrade label

    “Fairtrade is an alternative approach to conventional trade and is based on a partnership

    between producers and consumers. Fairtrade offers producers a better deal and improved terms

    of trade. This allows them the opportunity to improve their lives and plan for their future.

    Fairtrade offers consumers a powerful way to reduce poverty through their everyday shopping.”

    (Fairtrade International, 2011g; Introducing Fairtrade).

  • 25

    This definition from the Fairtrade website reveals the core idea of Fairtrade. Fairtrade counts

    on the goodwill of consumers to pay a surplus for its products, which offer improved living

    conditions to the producers by paying them higher prices. Fair Trade is the umbrella term for all

    initiatives working on improvement of the terms of trade for small-scale producers in the

    South. This includes labels such as UTZ and Rainforest Alliance but also more direct trade

    relations making efforts for just prices (Sidwell, 2008). It is important to note that this research

    only discusses the Fairtrade labels issued by Fairtrade Labeling International (Flo-Cert). This is

    the largest and most widely recognized Fairtrade certification system but certainly not the only

    one, although some authors write that Fairtrade is seeking a monopoly position of all ethical

    labels (Mohan, 2010; Sidwell, 2008).

    This part of the literature review focuses on the producer organizations’ side of the Fairtrade

    label and does not cover the Fairtrade consumer perspective. The pricing policy is discussed in

    paragraph 3.1 and the certification process in paragraph 3.2. Paragraph 3.3 cites impact studies

    about the positive impacts of certification. Paragraph 3.4 covers the relevant critiques on

    Fairtrade for this case study.

    3.1. Pricing policy

    The Fairtrade certificate guarantees the coffee producer a minimum price per kilo of coffee

    beans. Whenever the market price is higher than the Fairtrade minimum price, producers

    receive the market price or the price negotiated at contract signing. When the market price

    falls beneath the Fairtrade minimum, all Fairtrade contracts have to guarantee at least the

    Fairtrade minimum price (Fairtrade International, 2011b). Figure 6 shows this clearly.

  • 26

    Figure 6: The Arabica Coffee Market 1989-2010: Comparison of Fairtrade and New York Prices

    Source: Fairtrade International, 2011f, p1

    Table 2 indicates the different Fairtrade minimum prices valid since 1 April 2011. The Fairtrade

    minimum price for Arabica Coffee differs for fully washed and natural coffee (0.05 USD/pound

    difference). The minimum price for fully washed Arabica coffee is fixed on 1.40 USD/pound and

    is equal in all countries (Fairtrade International, 2011e). How is this minimum price

    determined? The minimum price should cover the average costs of production of the farmers

    and therefore, the costs of sustainable production are estimated. The cost estimates are based

    on information of the production and export process of all the Fairtrade producers worldwide

    (Pricing Subunit, 2010). Surprisingly this minimum is equal worldwide. In addition to this

    Fairtrade minimum price, the Fairtrade buyers have to pay a premium. This premium is

    earmarked for investment in socio-economic and environmental projects of the cooperative

    (Fairtrade International, 2011b).

  • 27

    Table 2: Fairtrade minimum prices and premiums for different varieties of Arabica coffee

    Product variety Price applies to Fairtrade minimum price

    (USD/pound)

    Fairtrade premium (USD/pound)

    Valid from

    Conventional, natural

    Worldwide 1.35 0.20 01 April 2011

    Organic, natural Worldwide 1.65* 0.20 01 April 2011

    Conventional, washed

    Worldwide 1.40 0.20 01 April 2011

    Organic, washed Worldwide 1.70* 0.20 01 April 2011

    *Organic differential of 0.30 USD/pound

    Source: Fairtrade International, 2011e, coffee

    Fairtrade International also states that facilitating long term trading partnerships is one of their

    core objectives. Besides the price advantages of the Fairtrade certificate, traders should help

    the cooperative by providing credit of up to 60% of the total sales volume, on request of the

    cooperative. This is designed to facilitate access to credit for the cooperatives (Fairtrade

    International, 2011c). However Flo-Cert does not determine the interest rate that can be

    charged and suggests the cooperatives to verify if local credit might be cheaper (Elliot, 2012).

    3.2. The certification process

    FLO, Fairtrade Labeling Organization, is an international association that determines the

    international norms of Fairtrade. The Fairtrade labels are issued by Flo-Cert. Important to

    notice is that Fairtrade coffee labels are never given to individual producers, only to

    cooperatives. To gain access to the Fairtrade system, an individual farmer must therefore first

    join a cooperative (Fairtrade International, 2011a). The focus on democratically run producer

    organizations is necessary for interaction and allocation of the social premium, but is also part

    of Flo-Cert’s mission to empower individual producers (Elliot, 2012).

  • 28

    The Burundian coffee cooperatives are classified as small-scale producers organizations. Flo-

    Cert defines small-scale producers as:

    - The farmers spend most of their time on agricultural activities on their own property.

    - Most of the work is executed by family members.

    - The income generated from these activities is their main revenue.

    - Their limited infrastructure, capital and goods make it necessary to pool with other

    producers to commercialize and sell their goods on the market.

    Small-scale producers organizations must be comprised of a majority of small-scale producers

    and the organization needs to be democratic. Each member has an equal vote and benefits are

    equally distributed (Fairtrade International, 2011d).

    The Fairtrade certification process is demanding. Flo-Cert enumerates all the requirements to

    obtain the Fairtrade certificate. These requirements are divided into core requirements and

    development requirements. Core requirements need to be satisfied in order to become a

    Fairtrade organization. Development requirements specify advancement and continual

    development of the cooperative. These are subdivided into general, trade, production and

    environmental protection, working conditions and commercial activities. The working

    conditions imply no child labor, no forced labor, freedom of association and collective

    bargaining. The requirements about commercial activities contain standards about the

    Fairtrade premium and plans, and about the participation and democracy in the cooperative.

    The participation of the members in the decisions of the cooperative goes through the general

    assembly. Flo-Cert requires an open and annual general assembly, which functions as the

    highest decision organ (Fairtrade International, 2011d).

    The decision to certify is an important investment decision where the cost and expected benefit

    should be carefully analyzed. Freelance auditors recruited by Flo-Cert inspect the Fairtrade

    organizations annually. Specialized certifiers, supervised by an independent certification

    committee, take the final certification decision. If the evaluation is negative, the cooperative

    needs to take corrective actions (Fairtrade International, 2011d).

    Fairtrade certification is costly. The certification fees depend on the number of members of the

    cooperative. The costs of an initial audit of a small producer organization with 50 to 100

  • 29

    members is €2040, for 101 to 250 members it is €2250, and for 251 to 500 members €2450 etc.

    The annual audit costs are on average €457 less than the initial audit costs (Flo-Cert, 2013a).

    The certification costs have been criticized as excessive and only necessary to finance the

    bureaucracy of Fairtrade (Mohan, 2010). Again, it is remarkable that costs are equal worldwide.

    If these costs are too high for the cooperative there is the possibility of applying for a grant

    from the producer certification fund. These grants never fully cover certification costs but are

    intended as co-financing support and can cover 75% of the annual certification costs (Fairtrade

    International, 2007).

    3.3. Positive impact

    The recent popularity of labels can be explained by two evolutions, one in the coffee producing

    countries and one in the coffee consuming countries. In the production countries poverty of

    coffee farmers remained high due to the low production level and volatility of prices. In the

    West the demand for socially and environmentally responsible coffee grew. Certificates have

    been praised as a valuable marketing advantage in consumer markets. They add value to the

    product and the consumer is willing to pay for this (Stellmacher & Grote, 2011).

    By the end of 2009, 827 producer organizations in 60 developing countries were registered

    under Flo-Cert and were able to supply Fairtrade certified products. The production is mostly

    concentrated in Latin-America (Mohan, 2010). According to Sidwell (2008), 25% of Fairtrade

    coffee is produced in Mexico. Coffee is the most valuable product within the Fairtrade system

    and accounts for 25% of Fairtrade sales. Nevertheless, the market share of Fairtrade coffee

    remains low: in 2009 it represented 1% of total coffee products worldwide. Worth noticing is

    the impressive growth of Fairtrade sales: in 2011 global sales were more than six times larger

    than seven years earlier (Elliot, 2012). This is attributed to the product diversification and

    engagement with large corporations and multinationals of Fairtrade (Mohan, 2010).

    Many economic authors defend the idea that Fairtrade represents an alternative speciality

    market, not notably different from other speciality markets such as organic coffee or kosher

    meat (Becchetti & Rosati, 2007; Hiscox, 2007; Mohan, 2010).

  • 30

    “There is not one single coffee but instead many different coffee products which are

    differentiated from one another in terms of quality, blends, packaging and also, more recently,

    ‘social responsibility’ features” (Mohan, 2010, p42)

    Besides the pricing advantages, it has been argued that Fairtrade offers strong incentives for

    organizational capacity building2 by working with democratically controlled cooperatives (to

    represent small-scale producers) and unions (to represent the workers). This stimulates the

    production and marketing skills of the members. Dealing with cooperatives implies that

    Fairtrade farmers also benefit from the cooperative advantages such as stronger bargaining

    power, training and credit possibilities (see part I, 2.3) (Mohan, 2010). Field research by Boot,

    Wunderlich & Bartra (2003), Hoebink et al. (2014), Nelson, Tallontire & Collinson (2002),

    Murray, Raynolds & Taylor (2003) and Zadek &Tiffen (1996) confirms Fairtrade certification has

    improved the capacity building of the producers. The advantages cited are: improved market

    information, best practices in growing and processing and access to pre-financing (Elliot, 2012).

    3.4. Criticism

    Fairtrade reviews and analyses are numerous. A study of Solidaridad, an international

    organization focusing on sustainable food production (Solidaridad, 2014), provides a summary

    of conclusions of the different impact studies subdividing them into very

    positive/positive/limited effects and mixed results (Hoebink et al., 2014). This research will

    cover critical analysis on three main themes relevant for this case study: impact on poverty

    reduction, the oversupply problem and the nexus quality-Fairtrade.

    3.4.1. Impact on poverty reduction

    A question that is often raised is whether Fairtrade helps to rule out extreme poverty. In most

    cases becoming member of a cooperative requires a financial contribution. Only the farmers

    able to make small savings can join a cooperative and benefit from the Fairtrade system.

    Cooperatives are therefore organizations for the middle layer and fail to include the poorest

    (Bernard & Spielman, 2009; Münkner, 1976). On the other hand investment and capital of the

    2“Organizational capacity building is the strengthening of internal organizational structures, systems and processes, management, leadership, governance and overall staff capacity to enhance organizational, team and individual performance” (AID STAR-two, 2011, p1).

  • 31

    middle layer helps the poorer members to cooperate out of poverty (Develtere & Pollet, 2008).

    Another important matter is proven by research in Jimma (Ethiopia) by Jena, Chichaibelu,

    Stellmacher & Grote (2012). They conclude that the cooperative effect often rules out the

    certification effect: efficient cooperatives obtain more easily a Fairtrade certification, whereas

    less efficient cooperatives do not benefit from the Fairtrade system. Mohan (2010) explains the

    complex applications, costly investments and costs of inspection exclude the least developed

    cooperatives. Jena et al. (2012) therefore make the remark that when the impact of the

    certification is measured, there is a strong cooperative effect that needs to be taken into

    consideration.

    Fairtrade quantitative impact analyses are scarce in sub-Saharan Africa. A recent study based

    on balanced panel data with a four-year interval in Kenya, Uganda and Ethiopia reveals limited

    impact of Fairtrade on livelihoods of the coffee farmers (Hoebink et al., 2014). This is mainly

    attributed to the limited sales of the certified coffee to the Fairtrade market and coffee

    representing only a part of the income of the farmers. Moreover, the positive certification

    effects evened out over time. However, the same study does report a positive impact on the

    number of educational programs in the certified cooperatives, but questions if this is due to the

    certification effect or the cooperative effect (Hoebink et al., 2014). An impact study

    commissioned by TransFair Germany and Max Havelaar Foundation Switzerland, two Fairtrade

    trademarks, based on interviews, discussions and observations in six different countries,

    concluded overall positive effects of the Fairtrade certificate. These were: slightly higher and

    stable incomes for coffee farmers in Peru; more education and training programs covering

    agricultural topics; strengthening of organization and market knowledge; positive community

    effects through the Fairtrade Premium; a longer planning horizon of rural population which

    translates into more savings and investments; etc. (Ceval, 2012). Giovannucci et al. (2008) show

    that the social, ecological and economic impacts of the Fairtrade certification are very

    dependent of the local context.

    Another issue was raised after the coffee prices peak in 2010. Many Fairtrade buyers reported

    to be left high and dry (Elliot, 2012, p2) because cooperatives sold their coffee to independent

    buyers who offered higher market prices. Nevertheless, Fairtrade encourages sustainable and

    predictable contracting and thus many cooperatives signed Fairtrade contracts months before

    the price peaked in the summer of 2010. And thus the following question of Elliot (2012, p2) is

  • 32

    very relevant: “Unexpected spikes aside, if commodity prices stay relatively high, will producers

    still see value in fairtrade certification?”

    3.4.2. Stable prices guarantee?

    “The sort of guarantees that Fair Trade claim are provided to producers, are therefore not as

    secure as might be thought by many purchasers.” (Mohan, 2010, p56)

    Levi & Linton (2003) claim that since 1990 coffee production increased by 15 percent

    worldwide, whereas consumption only increased by 7 percent. This production increase was

    caused by deregulation, which followed the abolishment of the International Coffee Agreement

    in 1989 (see part I, 1.4). The Fairtrade market experiences a similar problem. The demand is still

    very low in Western countries. In Europe it represents 1% of the total coffee market but only

    0.2% in the United States3 (Levi & Linton, 2003). The existing Fairtrade cooperatives can only

    sell half of their coffee on the Fairtrade market. This is caused by the fact that offer exceeds

    demand. The global supply of certified coffee is estimated to be two to four times greater than

    the demand for Fairtrade coffee (De Janvry, McIntosh & Sadoulet, 2010). For other Fairtrade

    certified product markets the numbers look better (Elliot, 2012).

    Mendez, Bacon, Olson, Petchers et al. (2010) confirm that certified farmers receive higher

    prices and coffee revenues, but sustainable livelihood effects were not reached due to too

    limited sales to certified markets. Certified cooperatives have no certainty of finding Fairtrade

    buyers and thus no guarantee of receiving the Fairtrade minimum price. The supply-driven

    certification system4 offers strong incentives for over-certification (De Janvry et al., 2010). The

    claim by Fairtrade that it protects producers against market volatility and guarantees stable

    prices is therefore often not true. A study in Ethiopia shows that members of cooperatives

    often engage in side selling and multi-certification to overcome this obstacle. The side sales

    range from 25% in Kenya and Uganda up to 50% in Ethiopia (Hoebink et al., 2014).

    3 The difference can mainly be attributed to the longer history of mobilization around food issues in Europe and the subvention of NGO efforts to promote Fairtrade coffee (Levi & Linton, 2003).

    4 The Fairtrade certification system is supply-driven because cooperatives can apply for certification and Flo-Cert does not take into account the demand for certified coffee in its decisions to certify or not (De Janvry et al., 2010).

  • 33

    3.4.3. Lack of recognition for quality

    How does the Fairtrade system stimulate the production of good quality coffee? The New

    Standards for Coffee from April 2011 demand that at least 25% of the socio-economic premium

    (5 USD cents per pound) is invested in productivity and quality improvement. This is expected

    to have a high return and to provide a way to reduce poverty among the Fairtrade producers.

    Fairtrade International clusters the investments in three groups: creating the conditions for

    improvement; investment at farm level; investment and investment at producer organization

    level. The first cluster may include research, technical assistance, training and exchange visits,

    credit facility