chapter 5 choice

47
Chapter 5 Choice

Upload: virginia-boone

Post on 01-Jan-2016

28 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Chapter 5 Choice. Economic Rationality. The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses his most preferred alternative from those available to him. The available choices constitute the choice set. How is the most preferred bundle in the choice set located?. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Chapter 5 Choice

Chapter 5Choice

Page 2: Chapter 5 Choice

2

Economic Rationality

The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses his most preferred alternative from those available to him.

The available choices constitute the choice set.

How is the most preferred bundle in the choice set located?

Page 3: Chapter 5 Choice

3

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Page 4: Chapter 5 Choice

4

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Affordablebundles

Page 5: Chapter 5 Choice

5

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Affordablebundles

More preferredbundles

Page 6: Chapter 5 Choice

6

Rational Constrained Choice

Affordablebundles

x1

x2

More preferredbundles

Page 7: Chapter 5 Choice

7

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is the mostpreferred affordablebundle.

Page 8: Chapter 5 Choice

8

Rational Constrained Choice The most preferred affordable bundle

is called the consumer’s ordinary demand at the given prices and budget.

Ordinary demands will be denoted byx1*(p1,p2,m) and x2*(p1,p2,m).

Page 9: Chapter 5 Choice

9

Rational Constrained Choice

When x1* > 0 and x2* > 0 the demanded bundle is interior.

If buying (x1*,x2*) costs $m then the budget is exhausted.

Page 10: Chapter 5 Choice

10

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is interior.(a) (x1*,x2*) exhausts thebudget; p1x1* + p2x2* = m.

Page 11: Chapter 5 Choice

11

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is interior .(b) The slope of the indiff.curve at (x1*,x2*) equals the slope of the budget constraint.

Page 12: Chapter 5 Choice

12

Rational Constrained Choice (x1*,x2*) satisfies two conditions: (a) the budget is exhausted;

p1x1* + p2x2* = m (b) the slope of the budget

constraint, -p1/p2, and the slope of the indifference curve containing (x1*,x2*) are equal at (x1*,x2*).

Page 13: Chapter 5 Choice

13

Rational Constrained Choice Condition (b) can be written as:

That is,

Therefore, at the optimal choice, the ratio of marginal utilities of the two commodities must be equal to their price ratio.

2 1 1

1 2 2

dx MU pMRS

dx MU p

1 1

2 2

MU p

MU p

Page 14: Chapter 5 Choice

14

Mathematical Treatment

The consumer’s optimization problem can be formulated mathematically as:

One way to solve it is to use Lagrangian method:

Page 15: Chapter 5 Choice

15

Mathematical Treatment Assuming the utility function is

differentiable, and there exists an interior solution.

The first order conditions are:

Page 16: Chapter 5 Choice

16

Mathematical Treatment

So, for interior solution, we can solve for the optimal bundle using the two conditions:

1 1

2 2

1 1 2 2

,

.

MU p

MU p

p x p x m

Page 17: Chapter 5 Choice

17

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. Suppose that the consumer has

Cobb-Douglas preferences.

Then

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

MUUx

ax xa b1

1112

MUUx

bx xa b2

21 2

1

Page 18: Chapter 5 Choice

18

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So the MRS is

At (x1*,x2*), MRS = -p1/p2 so

MRSdxdx

U xU x

ax x

bx x

axbx

a b

a b

2

1

1

2

112

1 21

2

1

//

.

ax

bx

pp

xbpap

x2

1

1

22

1

21

*

** *. (A)

Page 19: Chapter 5 Choice

19

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So now we have

Solving these two equations, we have

xbpap

x21

21

* * (A)

p x p x m1 1 2 2* * . (B)

xam

a b p11

*

( ).

x

bma b p2

2

*

( ).

Page 20: Chapter 5 Choice

20

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example. So we have discovered that the most

preferred affordable bundle for a consumer with Cobb-Douglas preferences

is

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

( , )( )

,( )

.* * ( )x xam

a b pbm

a b p1 21 2

Page 21: Chapter 5 Choice

21

A Cobb-Douglas Example

x1

x2

xam

a b p11

*

( )

x

bma b p

2

2

*

( )

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

Page 22: Chapter 5 Choice

22

A Cobb-Douglas Example Note that with the optimal bundle:

The expenditures on each good:

It is a property of Cobb-Douglas Utility function that expenditure share on a particular good is a constant.

( , )( )

,( )

.* * ( )x xam

a b pbm

a b p1 21 2

.)(

,)(

),( *22

*11

mba

bm

ba

axpxp

Page 23: Chapter 5 Choice

23

Special Cases

Page 24: Chapter 5 Choice

24

Special Cases

Page 25: Chapter 5 Choice

25

Some Notes

For interior optimum, tangency condition is only necessary but not sufficient.

There can be more than one optimum.

Strict convexity implies unique solution.

Page 26: Chapter 5 Choice

26

Corner Solution

What if x1* = 0?

Or if x2* = 0?

If either x1* = 0 or x2* = 0 then the ordinary demand (x1*,x2*) is at a corner solution to the problem of maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint.

Page 27: Chapter 5 Choice

27

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

MRS = -1

Page 28: Chapter 5 Choice

28

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2.

Page 29: Chapter 5 Choice

29

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

x1 0*

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2.

2

*2 p

mx

Page 30: Chapter 5 Choice

30

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

x2 0*

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 < p2.

1

*1 p

mx

Page 31: Chapter 5 Choice

31

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case So when U(x1,x2) = x1 + x2, the most

preferred affordable bundle is (x1*,x2*) where

and

0,),(

1

*2

*1 p

mxx if p1 < p2

2

*2

*1 ,0),(

p

mxx if p1 > p2

Page 32: Chapter 5 Choice

32

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 = p2.

1p

m

2p

m

Page 33: Chapter 5 Choice

33

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

All the bundles in the constraint are equally the most preferred affordable when p1 = p2.

1p

m

2p

m

Page 34: Chapter 5 Choice

34

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2Better

Page 35: Chapter 5 Choice

35

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2

Page 36: Chapter 5 Choice

36

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2Which is the most preferredaffordable bundle?

Page 37: Chapter 5 Choice

37

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2

The most preferredaffordable bundle

Page 38: Chapter 5 Choice

38

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2

The most preferredaffordable bundle

Notice that the “tangency solution” is not the most preferred affordable bundle.

Page 39: Chapter 5 Choice

39

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Page 40: Chapter 5 Choice

40

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2

MRS = -

MRS = 0

MRS is undefined

U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Page 41: Chapter 5 Choice

41

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Page 42: Chapter 5 Choice

42

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Which is the mostpreferred affordable bundle?

Page 43: Chapter 5 Choice

43

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

The most preferredaffordable bundle

Page 44: Chapter 5 Choice

44

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2

U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

x1*

x2*

Page 45: Chapter 5 Choice

45

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

x1*

x2*

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m(b) x2* = ax1*

Page 46: Chapter 5 Choice

46

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Solving the two equations, we have

.app

amx;

appm

x21

*2

21

*1

Page 47: Chapter 5 Choice

47

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

xm

p ap11 2

*

x

amp ap

2

1 2

*