a new approach to measuring financial contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return...

47
A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion Kee-Hong Bae Korea University G. Andrew Karolyi Ohio State University Rene ´ M. Stulz Ohio State University and NBER This article proposes a new approach to evaluate contagion in financial markets. Our measure of contagion captures the coincidence of extreme return shocks across countries within a region and across regions. We characterize the extent of contagion, its economic significance, and its determinants using a multinomial logistic regression model. Applying our approach to daily returns of emerging markets during the 1990s, we find that contagion is predictable and depends on regional interest rates, exchange rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme positive returns is mixed. Since 1997, economists, policymakers, and journalists have talked about the ‘‘Asian flu.’’ It has generally been perceived that the adverse currency and stock market shock that first affected Thailand in July 1997 propa- gated across the world with little regard for economic fundamentals in the affected countries. Before the Asian flu, there was the 1994 Mexican ‘‘Tequila crisis,’’ and since then, the 1998 ‘‘Russian virus.’’ Emerging markets economic crises, in general, have been characterized as contagious. According to Webster’s dictionary, contagion is defined as ‘‘a disease that can be communicated rapidly through direct or indirect contact.’’ Emerging markets economic crises have led to massive bailouts to quell contagion and have reduced support for free capital mobility. Bae and Karolyi grateful to the Dice Center for Research on Financial Economics for support; Bae also appreciates the financial support of the SK Research Award. We thank Tom Santner, Mark Berliner, Bob Leone, and Stan Lemeshow for useful discussions on methodology, Steve Cecchetti, Peter Christoffersen, Craig Doidge, Barry Eichengreen, Vihang Errunza, David Hirshleifer, Matthew Pritsker, Roberto Rigobon, Richard Roll, Karen Wruck, and, especially, an anonymous referee, and the editor, Cam Harvey, for comments. Comments from seminar participants at Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Korea University, McGill University, Yale University, Michigan State University, Universiteit Maastricht, Ohio State University, Rice University, Monte Verita Risk Management Con- ference, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, Global Investment Conference on International Investing, and the NYSE Conference on Global Equity Markets in Transition improved the article. Address correspondence to Ren e M. Stulz, Ohio State University, Fisher College of Business, 2100 Neil Ave. 806 A Fisher Hall, Columbus, OH 43210, or e-mail: stulz@cob. osu.edu. The Review of Financial Studies Fall 2003 Vol. 16, No. 3, pp. 717–763, DOI: 10.1093/rfs/hhg012 ª 2003 The Society for Financial Studies

Upload: others

Post on 05-Jun-2020

8 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

A New Approach to Measuring Financial

Contagion

Kee-Hong Bae

Korea University

G. Andrew Karolyi

Ohio State University

Rene M. Stulz

Ohio State University and NBER

This article proposes a new approach to evaluate contagion in financial markets. Our

measure of contagion captures the coincidence of extreme return shocks across

countries within a region and across regions. We characterize the extent of contagion,

its economic significance, and its determinants using a multinomial logistic regression

model. Applying our approach to daily returns of emerging markets during the 1990s,

we find that contagion is predictable and depends on regional interest rates, exchange

rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is

stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme positive returns is mixed.

Since 1997, economists, policymakers, and journalists have talked aboutthe `̀ Asian flu.'' It has generally been perceived that the adverse currencyand stock market shock that first affected Thailand in July 1997 propa-gated across the world with little regard for economic fundamentals in theaffected countries. Before the Asian flu, there was the 1994 Mexican``Tequila crisis,'' and since then, the 1998 ``Russian virus.'' Emergingmarkets economic crises, in general, have been characterized ascontagious. According to Webster's dictionary, contagion is defined as``a disease that can be communicated rapidly through direct or indirectcontact.'' Emerging markets economic crises have led to massive bailoutsto quell contagion and have reduced support for free capital mobility.

Bae and Karolyi grateful to the Dice Center for Research on Financial Economics for support; Bae alsoappreciates the financial support of the SK Research Award. We thank Tom Santner, Mark Berliner, BobLeone, and Stan Lemeshow for useful discussions on methodology, Steve Cecchetti, Peter Christoffersen,Craig Doidge, Barry Eichengreen, Vihang Errunza, David Hirshleifer, Matthew Pritsker, RobertoRigobon, Richard Roll, Karen Wruck, and, especially, an anonymous referee, and the editor, CamHarvey, for comments. Comments from seminar participants at Hong Kong University of Science andTechnology, Korea University, McGill University, Yale University, Michigan State University,Universiteit Maastricht, Ohio State University, Rice University, Monte Verita Risk Management Con-ference, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition,Global Investment Conference on International Investing, and the NYSE Conference on Global EquityMarkets in Transition improved the article. Address correspondence to Ren�e M. Stulz, Ohio StateUniversity, Fisher College of Business, 2100 Neil Ave. 806 A Fisher Hall, Columbus, OH 43210, ore-mail: stulz@cob. osu.edu.

The Review of Financial Studies Fall 2003 Vol. 16, No. 3, pp. 717±763, DOI: 10.1093/rfs/hhg012ã 2003 The Society for Financial Studies

Page 2: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

The International Monetary Fund (IMF) deputy managing director at thetime, Stanley Fischer, rationalized the 1994 Mexican bailout in this way:`̀ Of course, there was another justification: contagion effects. They werethere and they were substantial.''1 Contagion has led Bhagwati (1998) toargue that `̀ capital flows are characterized . . . by panics and manias.'' Ifmarkets work this way, it is not surprising that Stiglitz (1998) called forgreater regulation of capital flows, arguing that `` . . . developing countriesare more vulnerable to vacillations in international flows than everbefore.''

Even though this contagion connotes powerful images of economic andfinancial plagues, it is difficult to study scientifically. Evidence of thisdifficulty is that there is little agreement on even defining what financialcontagion means.2 Since equity market valuations reflect future economicactivity, much of recent research attempts to learn about contagion byinvestigating whether equity markets move more closely together in tur-bulent periods. There are considerable statistical difficulties involved intesting hypotheses of changes in correlations across quiet and turbulentperiods and recent investigations of this issue find at best mixed results [seeBaig and Goldfajn (1999) and Forbes and Rigobon (2001)]. Nevertheless,there does not seem to be strong evidence that stock returns in one countryare more highly correlated with returns in other countries during crisisperiods once one takes into account the fact that correlation estimates arelikely biased. A related literature demonstrates that, even though correla-tions change over time, it is difficult to explain changes in correlations.3

Perhaps the most important limitation of these investigations of finan-cial contagion is that they focus on asset return correlations in the firstplace. None of the concerns expressed about contagion seem to be basedon linear measures of association for macroeconomic or financial marketevents. In fact, these concerns are generally founded on the presumptionthat there is something different about extremely bad events that leads toirrational outcomes, excess volatility, and even panics. In the context ofstock returns, this means that if panic grips investors as stock returns falland leads them to ignore economic fundamentals, one would expect large

1 See his statement in Calvo (1996, p. 323).

2 For a review of the difficulties in defining contagion, see Dornbusch, Park, and Claessens (2001). A recentbook by Claessens and Forbes (2001) published this and more than 20 other articles from a February2000 World Bank/IMF conference, International Financial Contagion: How it Spreads and How it Can beStopped. These articles include theoretical models, a conceptual contribution, country case studies, andbroad-based empirical studies. Other important recent contributions include Eichengreen, Rose, andWyplosz (1996), Glick and Rose (1999), Masson (1999), Kaminsky and Reinhart (2000), Allen and Gale(2000), and Kyle and Xiong (2001). Eichengreen, Rose, and Wyplosz (1996) estimate probit regressions torelate the occurrence of a currency crisis in a country to predictive variables. Though their seminalanalysis is a precursor of our approach, it is not focused on the probability of the joint occurrence ofextreme events across countries.

3 See, for instance, Erb, Harvey, and Viskanta (1995), King, Sentana, and Wadhwani (1995), Longin andSolnik (1995, 2001), and Karolyi and Stulz (1996). See also the recent survey by Karolyi and Stulz (2003).

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

718

Page 3: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

negative returns to be contagious in a way that small negative returns arenot. Correlations that give equal weight to small and large returns are notappropriate for an evaluation of the differential impact of large returns. Itcould be that large shocks, because they exceed some threshold or gen-erate panic, propagate across countries, but this propagation is hidden incorrelation measures by the large number of days when little of impor-tance happens.

To address these concerns, a number of recent studies have extendedmodels of international asset return volatilities and correlations to allowfor these observed threshold (large absolute return) and asymmetric(negative return) effects. Some researchers have employed univariateand multivariate extreme value theory (EVT) from statistics [Longin(1996), Danielsson and de Vries (2000), Longin and Solnik (2001),Straetmans (1998), Starica (1999), Kaminsky and Schmuckler (1999),Pownall and Koedijk (1999), and Hartman, Straetmans, and de Vries(2001)]. Others have developed multivariate GARCH-M models allowingasymmetry [Ang and Chen (2002), Bekaert and Wu (2000)], Poisson jumps[Das and Uppal (2002)], and even Hamiltonian regime-switching [Angand Bekaert (2002)] in the joint dynamics of returns. In contrast, in thisarticle we abandon the correlation framework that previous researchershave focused on to study contagion and direct our attention instead tothe large positive and negative return days. To avoid a situation where ourresults are dominated by a few observations, we do not compute correla-tions of large returns, but instead measure the joint occurrences of largereturns. In order to determine whether there are more frequent jointoccurrences of large absolute value returns than expected, we calibratethese outcomes using Monte Carlo simulations of the joint returns-generating processes of international stock market returns with differentassumptions about their structure. We then develop an econometricmodel of the joint occurrences of large absolute value returns using multi-nomial logistic regression.

In part, we are influenced in our choice of methodology by theextensive use of multinomial logistic analysis in epidemiology researchon contagious diseases [Hosmer and Lemeshow (1989)]. In epidemiology,the model is used to answer questions such as: Given that N persons havebeen infected by a disease, how likely is it that K or more other personswill be affected by that disease? We use multinomial logistic regres-sions to model occurrences of large returns, which we refer to as ``excee-dances.'' With this model we can determine how likely it is that twoLatin American countries will have large returns on a particular daygiven that two countries in Asia have large returns on that day or thepreceding day.

An important advantage of this multinomial logistic analysis, especiallyrelative to those based on EVT, is that we can condition on attributes and

Measuring Financial Contagion

719

Page 4: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

characteristics of the exceedance events using control variables (or covari-ates) measured with information available up to the previous day. We findthat exchange rate changes, interest rate levels, and regional conditionalvolatility of equity market returns are statistically important covariatesthat help explain and predict exceedances in this model. We definecontagion within regions as the fraction of exceedance events that isnot explained by our covariates (exchange rates, interest rates, marketvolatility). We find that contagion differs across regions. Contagionappears to be much stronger within Latin America than it is withinAsia. Further, large positive and large negative returns are equallycontagious in Asia, but not in Latin America, where large negative returnsare more contagious.

Another advantage of our approach is that it enables us to considercontagion across regions as well as within regions. An earlier literature haslooked extensively at the transmission of information across advancedmarkets during the calendar day.4 Our investigation is related to thisliterature in that we consider the impact of exceedances among countriesin one region on the probability of observing exceedances among coun-tries in other regions. More specifically, we define contagion acrossregions as the fraction of the exceedance events in a particular regionthat is left unexplained by its own covariates but that is explained by theexceedances from another region. We find evidence of cross-regionalcontagion. Remarkably, the United States seems completely insulatedfrom any Asian contagion, even during the Asian crisis in 1997.

To apply our approach, we construct daily index returns from stocks inthe monthly investible indices of the International Finance Corporation(IFC indices) from April 1992 to December 1995 and then use the dailyindex returns provided by the IFC from January 1996 to December 2000for 17 Asian and Latin American markets of the Emerging MarketsDatabase (EMDB, now owned by Standard & Poor's). The sample periodextends from April 1992 through December 2000. These returns areparticularly well suited to our analysis because they correspond to thereturns of portfolios that can be held by foreign investors.

The article proceeds as follows. In Section 1 we present our data,provide statistics on joint occurrences of extreme returns, and calibratethe joint occurrences of extreme returns using Monte Carlo simulationevidence. In Section 2 we motivate the use of a multinomial logit model toexplain joint occurrences of extreme events and estimate such a model.The model is then used to show how contagion takes place within regions.

4 Important investigations of international `̀ spillovers'' of returns and volatility include studies by Eun andShim (1989), Hamao, Masulis, and Ng (1990), King and Wadhwani (1990), Engle, Ito, and Lin (1990),Bae and Karolyi (1994), Lin, Engle, and Ito (1994), and Susmel and Engle (1994). More recent contribu-tions include Ramchand and Susmel (1998), Ng (2000), Connolly and Wang (2003) and Dumas, Harvey,and Ruiz (2003).

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

720

Page 5: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

In Section 3 we investigate contagion across regions. We conclude inSection 4.

1� Measuring Financial Contagion as Coexceedances

In this section we first discuss our data and its properties. We then turn tothe distribution of extreme returns that we use throughout the study andcalibrate using Monte Carlo simulations whether the frequency of jointextreme returns within regions is consistent with various assumptionsabout the joint dynamics of returns.

1.1 Data

A number of explanations of contagion are based on actions by foreigninvestors. We therefore use indices that are representative of the capitali-zation of stocks that foreign investors can hold. Originally the Interna-tional Finance Corporation (IFC) produced such indices for emergingmarkets; currently these indices are produced by Standard & Poor's.5 Weuse the IFC indices from Asia and Latin America. To study the extent towhich contagion affects the United States and Europe, we also use theS&P 500 index for the United States and the Datastream InternationalEurope index for Europe. Our focus is on daily returns. Daily returns areavailable for the IFC indices since December 31, 1995. Using these data,the sample of daily returns therefore starts on December 31, 1995, andends on December 29, 2000 (1305 observations). While the sample perioddoes include the 1997 Asian crisis as well as the 1998 Russian crisis, we areconcerned that the sample is too short and that it excludes anotherimportant crisis event, namely, the Mexican peso devaluation ofDecember 1994. As a result, we proceed to construct value-weightedindexes of the stocks in the respective emerging markets using dailystock prices from Datastream International. Our effort is also facilitatedby the availability of the monthly IFC indexes from the EMDB 2000CD-ROM. Our index construction procedure follows a series of stepsand checks and is detailed in the appendix.

Table 1 provides sample statistics, including correlations for the fullsample periodÐApril 1, 1992, to December 29, 2000 (2283 observations).Not surprisingly, the properties of the indices vary dramatically acrosscountries. China has the highest average daily return (0.087%), but Brazilhas the highest daily return standard deviation (3.370%), almost fourtimes that of the United States and Europe. The largest positive extremereturn (58.708%) obtains for Pakistan, whereas Peru experienced the

5 Detailed information can be obtained from The IFC Indexes: Methodology, Definitions and Practices(February 1998, International Finance Corporation, Washington, DC) or Standard & Poor's EmergingMarket Data Base EMDB 2000TM Version 6.0 (CD-ROM).

Measuring Financial Contagion

721

Page 6: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Table

1S

um

mary

stati

stic

sof

dail

yre

turn

son

Inte

rnati

onal

Fin

anci

al

Corp

ora

tion

(IF

C)

emer

gin

gm

ark

ets

indic

es,

Apri

l1,

1992,

toD

ecem

ber

29,

2000

CH

NK

OR

PH

IT

WN

INA

IND

MA

LP

AK

SR

IT

HA

AR

GB

RA

CH

IC

OL

ME

XP

ER

VE

NU

SE

uro

pe

Mea

n(%

)0

.08

70

.01

90

.01

20

.01

7ÿ

0.0

30

0.0

02

0.0

21

0.0

37

0.0

16ÿ

0.0

29

0.0

26

0.0

44

0.0

25

0.0

05

0.0

29

0.0

54

0.0

39

0.0

60

0.0

53

Std

.D

ev.

(%)

2.8

88

2.7

23

1.7

58

1.8

21

1.8

23

3.2

71

2.1

03

2.5

02

1.3

73

2.4

26

2.1

07

3.3

70

1.2

46

1.2

67

2.0

73

2.4

71

2.5

44

0.9

38

0.8

26

Med

ian

(%)

0.0

00

0.0

00

0.0

00

0.0

00

0.0

00

0.0

06

0.0

01

0.0

00

0.0

00ÿ

0.0

29

0.0

05

0.0

20

0.0

00ÿ

0.0

13

0.0

03

0.0

01

0.0

00

0.0

33

0.0

89

Min

imu

m(%

)ÿ

38

.09ÿ

21

.71ÿ

10

.14ÿ

10

.80ÿ

18

.74ÿ

37

.54ÿ

22

.78ÿ

17

.74ÿ

8.7

1ÿ

16.0

8ÿ

14.1

3ÿ

27.5

1ÿ

6.7

0ÿ

6.9

3ÿ

20.8

5ÿ

41.9

0ÿ

14.8

7ÿ

7.1

0ÿ

4.1

1

Maxim

um

(%)

48

.08

27

.03

21

.59

7.3

614

.26

27.2

123

.90

58.7

017

.97

16.6

313

.35

35.2

99.2

69

.23

16.7

315.7

921.8

54.9

93.6

0

Co

rrel

ati

on

sC

HN

KO

RP

HI

TW

NIN

AIN

DM

AL

PA

KS

RI

TH

AA

RG

BR

AC

HI

CO

LM

EX

PE

RV

EN

US

Eu

rop

e

CH

N1

.00

0.0

90.0

10

.03ÿ

0.0

10.0

70.0

5ÿ

0.0

10.1

10.0

5

KO

R0

.07

1.0

00

.13

0.1

00

.11

0.0

00.1

50.0

50.0

60.2

00.1

7

PH

I0

.06

0.1

71

.00

0.2

00.1

40

.17

0.0

60.1

80.0

50.0

90.2

30.2

2

TW

N0

.02

0.1

20

.17

1.0

00

.12

0.0

50

.08

0.0

40.1

10.0

30.0

50.1

60.1

2

INA

0.0

50

.10

0.0

90

.04

1.0

00

.05

0.0

40

.06

0.0

10.0

40.0

2ÿ

0.0

10.0

60.0

5

IND

0.0

40

.15

0.3

60

.13

0.0

61.0

00.1

30

.09

0.1

40

.05

0.1

30.0

70.0

70.1

60.1

2

MA

L0

.04

0.1

80

.28

0.1

60

.08

0.3

61

.00

0.1

00.0

60

.09ÿ

0.0

10.0

90.0

30.0

50.2

10.1

0

PA

K0

.01

0.0

10

.07

0.0

50

.04

0.0

60

.08

1.0

00.0

20

.01

0.0

20

.03

0.0

30.0

00.0

90.0

30.0

3

SR

I0

.00

0.0

20

.07

0.0

20

.00

0.0

30

.04

0.0

41

.00

0.0

30.0

50

.03

0.0

60.0

20.0

10.0

30.0

20.0

3

TH

A0

.10

0.2

50

.36

0.1

50

.10

0.3

30

.38

0.0

70

.07

1.0

00

.16

0.1

00

.13

0.0

40.1

30.0

60.0

60.1

80.1

6

0.1

20.0

70.1

30.1

1

AR

G0

.03

0.1

00

.07

ÿ0

.01

0.0

20.0

70

.10

0.0

2ÿ

0.0

20

.10

1.0

0

BR

Aÿ

0.0

10

.09

0.0

50

.02

0.0

60

.05

0.0

50

.03

0.0

10.0

70

.39

1.0

0

CH

I0

.02

0.1

20

.15

0.0

90

.06

0.1

10

.11

0.0

50

.00

0.1

60

.42

0.3

11

.00

CO

L0

.05

0.0

40

.07

0.0

30

.02

0.0

70

.03

0.0

40

.04

0.0

50

.05

0.0

70

.09

1.0

0

ME

X0

.01

0.1

20

.11

0.0

40

.04

0.0

60.1

00

.06ÿ

0.0

10.0

90

.47

0.3

40

.39

0.0

71.0

0

PE

R0

.00

0.0

60

.05

0.0

30

.07

0.0

40.0

50

.01

0.0

20.0

50

.16

0.1

60

.17

0.0

30.1

71.0

0

VE

N0

.06

0.0

80

.07

0.0

30

.02

0.0

80

.07

0.0

00

.00

0.0

80

.17

0.1

40

.17

0.0

80.1

80.0

61.0

0

0.0

50.1

9

US

ÿ0

.02

0.0

80

.07

0.0

10

.02

0.0

20.0

10

.01

0.0

10.0

40

.39

0.2

70

.29

0.0

50.4

00.1

10.0

91.0

0

0.0

30.2

3

Eu

rop

e0

.07

0.1

60

.16

0.0

70

.04

0.1

20.1

70

.03

0.0

40.1

70

.27

0.1

70

.27

0.0

80.2

80.1

40.1

40.3

11.0

0

0.1

00.1

9

Each

ind

exfr

om

the

Em

ergin

gM

ark

etD

ata

base

(EM

DB

)is

ad

just

edto

refl

ect

acc

essi

bil

ity

of

the

mark

etan

din

div

idu

al

sto

cks

for

fore

ign

inves

tors

.S

um

mary

stati

stic

sin

clu

de

the

mea

n,

med

ian

,st

an

dard

dev

iati

on

,m

inim

um

,m

axim

um

,an

dco

rrel

ati

on

so

fd

ail

yin

dex

retu

rns.

EM

DB

cou

ntr

ies

incl

ud

eC

hin

a(C

HN

),K

ore

a(K

OR

),P

hil

ipp

ines

(PH

I),

Taiw

an

(TW

N),

Ind

ia(I

NA

),In

do

nes

ia(I

ND

),M

ala

ysi

a(M

AL

),P

ak

ista

n(P

AK

),S

riL

an

ka

(SR

I),

Th

ail

an

d(T

HA

),A

rgen

tin

a(A

RG

),B

razi

l(B

RA

),C

hil

e(C

HI)

,C

olo

mb

ia(C

OL

),M

exic

o(M

EX

),P

eru

(PE

R),

an

dV

enez

uel

a(V

EN

).W

eals

oin

clu

de

dail

yre

turn

so

fS

&P

500

ind

exfo

rU

.S.

an

dD

ata

stre

am

Inte

rnati

on

al

Eu

rop

ein

dex

.T

he

corr

elati

on

sin

the

up

per

righ

tm

atr

ixare

bet

wee

nd

ail

yre

turn

so

fA

sian

ind

ices

inca

len

dar

tim

et

an

dth

ose

of

Lati

nA

mer

ica,

Un

ited

Sta

tes,

an

dE

uro

pe

ind

ices

inca

len

dar

tim

etÿ

1.A

ver

ages

of

corr

elati

on

sare

pre

sen

ted

init

ali

csan

dare

ass

oci

ate

dw

ith

the

blo

cko

fco

rrel

ati

on

sab

ove

an

dad

jace

nt

toth

est

ati

stic

.

722

Page 7: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

largest negative extreme return (ÿ 41.908%). All IFC indices have agreater standard deviation than indices for the United States and Europe.

Correlations within regions are higher than correlations across regions.However, none are particularly high except for the correlations amongBrazil, Argentina, Chile, and Mexico, which are all above 0.30. Anothercluster of moderately high correlations includes the markets of SoutheastAsia (Philippines, Indonesia, Malaysia, and Thailand). On a given day,trading starts in Asia and ends in the Americas. Consequently informationthat becomes available in Latin America at noon cannot affect stockprices in Asia the same day. We consider, therefore, correlations betweenreturns in Asia and Latin America on the same day as well as thosebetween returns in Asia today and Latin America on the preceding day.The correlations between returns in Asia and Latin America separated byone day (upper right matrix with average correlation of 0.07) are roughlythe same size as the same day correlations (lower left matrix with averagecorrelation of 0.05). But the correlations of returns in Asia andthose of the United States lagged by one day are greater (average correla-tion of 0.13) than the contemporaneous correlations (average correlationof 0.03).

1.2 Exceedances and coexceedances

Correlations have been much studied. We focus instead on occurrences ofextreme returns. At this point we arbitrarily define an extreme return, orexceedance, as one that lies either below (above) the 5th (95th) quantile ofthe marginal return distribution. Alternative definitions are used later.6

We treat positive extreme returns separately from the negative extremereturns. In Table 2 we report our counts of the number of joint occur-rences of extreme returns, or coexceedances, within a region on a parti-cular day. The left side of the table focuses on negative return (``bottomtail'') exceedances and the right side on positive return (``top tail'') excee-dances. We define a coexceedance count of i units for negative returns asthe joint occurrence of i exceedances of negative returns on a particularday. The table is to be read in four parts for the top and bottom tails of theAsian (top panel) and Latin American (bottom panel) regional markets.In each part, the 2283 days in the sample period are divided into those inwhich there are no exceedances in any country (e.g., 1526 such days inAsia for negative extreme returns), only one country exceedance (e.g., 530such days in Asia for negative extreme returns), and multicountry coex-ceedances. Note that we count not only the total number of days with

6 Longin (1996), Kaminsky and Schmukler (1999), Pownall and Koedijk (1999), and Longin and Solnik(2001) employ conditional parametric or nonparametric measures of extreme returns. Later we employ aconditional approach as a robustness check on our (co-)exceedances using an EGARCH model ofconditional volatility. We also employ different sizes for the tails.

Measuring Financial Contagion

723

Page 8: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Table

2S

um

mary

stati

stic

sof

(co-)

exce

edance

sfo

rdail

yem

ergin

gm

ark

etin

dex

retu

rns,

Apri

l1,

1992,

toD

ecem

ber

29,

2000

Mea

nre

turn

wh

en�

6

Nu

mb

ero

fn

egati

ve

(co

-)ex

ceed

an

ces

Nu

mb

ero

fp

osi

tive

(co

-)ex

ceed

an

ces

Mea

nre

turn

wh

en�

6(%

)�

65

43

21

00

12

34

5�

6(%

)

CH

Nÿ

7.5

62

21

327

79

1526

1507

76

23

10

31

15.0

3K

OR

ÿ8.2

24

10

615

35

44

1526

1507

41

33

21

85

68.0

5P

HI

ÿ6.7

23

13

15

14

24

45

1526

1507

43

32

18

11

37

7.0

9T

WN

ÿ4.9

54

46

633

61

1526

1507

66

24

15

41

46.1

1IN

Aÿ

5.8

43

55

10

28

63

1526

1507

61

34

85

33

3.6

1IN

Dÿ

9.5

55

14

14

11

35

35

1526

1507

42

27

23

13

45

18.5

2M

AL

ÿ6.1

75

12

17

16

33

31

1526

1507

41

30

22

12

36

9.3

5P

AK

ÿ10.1

34

36

430

67

1526

1507

61

34

94

33

3.8

2S

RI

ÿ3.7

63

33

823

74

1526

1507

79

25

62

11

2.4

1T

HA

ÿ7.8

55

14

15

21

28

31

1526

1507

36

34

21

10

67

10.6

8T

ota

lÿ

7.0

85

16

22

36

148

530

1526

1507

546

148

51

18

67

7.4

7

AR

Gÿ

8.9

67

610

15

31

45

1754

1691

52

35

13

85

17.1

2B

RA

ÿ11.3

26

612

17

27

46

1754

1691

58

31

13

74

110.8

1C

HI

ÿ4.7

97

611

18

24

48

1754

1691

45

41

17

55

16.6

2C

OL

ÿ3.6

65

15

12

18

73

1754

1691

86

19

52

20

--M

EX

ÿ7.5

67

67

17

34

43

1754

1691

65

28

97

41

7.3

2P

ER

ÿ5.8

45

011

11

27

60

1754

1691

65

29

11

44

15.7

9V

EN

ÿ6.6

76

54

12

31

56

1754

1691

77

25

73

11

7.3

7T

ota

lÿ

6.9

77

615

34

96

371

1754

1691

448

104

25

95

17.5

1

Ap

osi

tive

(neg

ati

ve)

or

`̀to

p-t

ail

''(`̀

bo

tto

m-t

ail

'')

exce

edan

cefo

rd

ail

yin

dex

retu

rns

corr

esp

on

dto

the

sub

set

of

ord

ered

retu

rns

that

com

pri

seth

eh

igh

est

(lo

wes

t)fi

ve

per

cen

to

fall

retu

rns.

Co

exce

edan

ces

rep

rese

nt

join

to

ccu

rren

ces

of

exce

edan

ces

acr

oss

cou

ntr

yin

dic

esb

yd

ay.

Aco

exce

edan

ceo

fi

mea

ns

that

ico

un

trie

sh

ave

an

exce

edan

ceo

nth

esa

me

day.

Co

exce

edan

ces

are

rep

ort

edfo

ri�

1,.

..,5

sep

ara

tely

an

dfo

ri

equ

al

tosi

xo

rm

ore

as

``�

6.''

Fo

rex

am

ple

,o

f2283

trad

ing

days,

ther

eare

148

occ

urr

ence

so

fn

egati

ve

or

bo

tto

m-t

ail

coex

ceed

an

ces

for

Asi

aw

ith

two

cou

ntr

ies

on

ly,

an

d27

of

tho

seo

ccu

rren

ces

incl

ud

eC

hin

aas

on

eo

fth

etw

oco

un

trie

sw

ith

bo

tto

m-t

ail

coex

ceed

an

ces.

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

724

Page 9: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

coexceedances of a given count, but we also identify which countriesparticipate in those events and how often.

In Asia, the distribution of coexceedances is mostly symmetric betweennegative and positive extreme returns. There are five days with six or morecountries in the bottom tail and seven days with six or more countries inthe top tail. The same symmetry holds for other numbers of coexcee-dances. The one case where there is a substantial difference between thebottom-tail coexceedances and the top-tail coexceedances is for the cate-gory of five coexceedances. In that case, there are 16 days withfive countries in the bottom tail and only 6 days with five countries inthe top tail. Indonesia was in the bottom tail for 14 of the 16 days with fivecountries and all 5 days with six or more countries. Malaysia was the nextmost regular participant in bottom-tail coexceedance events. During theAsian crisis, crisis countries (Thailand, Korea, Malaysia, and Indonesia)seem more likely to be in the bottom tail when other countries are in thebottom tail. Looking at the correlations of Table 1, these patterns inextreme returns are not a complete surprise since the crisis countrieshave higher correlations among themselves than with the noncrisis coun-tries. We report in Table 2 the average returns for each of the 10 Asiancountries when six or more Asian countries experience an exceedance on agiven day. Surprisingly the crisis countries do not always have largernegative returns on such days than noncrisis countries. The absolutevalue average return is higher for positive returns (7.47%) than for nega-tive returns (ÿ 7.08%) on such days.

Though Latin America has only seven countries, there are 7 days wheresix or more countries are in the bottom tail at the same time and 28 days intotal when four countries or more have extreme negative returns. Thiscontrasts with the case for positive extreme returns in which there is onlyone day when six countries or more have returns in the positive tail. InLatin America, and unlike Asia, there is clearer evidence of asymmetry inthat coexceedances of negative returns are more likely than coexceedancesof positive returns. Argentina, Chile, and Mexico are in each of thebottom-tail events with five or more coexceedances; by contrast,Colombia has a disproportionately large number of single-country excee-dances (73 out of 371). Among top-tail coexceedance counts, Colombia isagain less likely to be involved with other Latin American countries, likeArgentina, Chile, and Mexico, but much more likely to experience atop-tail event alone (86 of 448).

We compare but do not report coexceedance counts during the periodsbefore and after the July 1997 devaluation of the Thai Baht for Asia andbefore and after the December 1994 devaluation of the Mexican peso. Allbut five of the Asian bottom-tail and all but one of the top-tail coexcee-dances involving four countries or more (38 and 30, in total, respectively)take place after the devaluation of the Thai Baht. There are also clusters of

Measuring Financial Contagion

725

Page 10: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

large numbers of coexceedances in Latin America but they are distributedmore evenly over the period. Latin American coexceedances involvingfour countries or more experiencing negative extreme returns take placein early 1994 (four events) and around the December 1995 Mexican pesocrisis (seven events), but two more clusters appear in July 1997 andespecially in August 1998, the Russian default crisis period. The differ-ences before and after the Thai Baht devaluation for Asia and around theMexican peso and Russian default periods for Latin America reflect thesame result as that observed by Forbes and Rigobon (2002) and others ofan increase in correlations during the crisis periods. Indeed, such a result isdifficult to interpret because we should naturally see higher correlationsonce we condition on the occurrence of large returns. The reason for this isthat, in the presence of a common factor, large returns are more likely tobe associated with large realizations of the common factor. To understandwhether the existence of coexceedances can be explained by conditioningon large absolute value returns, we have to investigate what the distribu-tion of coexceedances would be if correlations were constant during thesample period. To this end we perform Monte Carlo simulation experi-ments.7

1.3 Contagion versus coexceedances: Monte Carlo simulation evidence

We now consider the following experiment. Suppose that the covariancematrix of returns is stationary over the sample period and that the returnsfollow a multivariate normal or Student's t distribution. Using that co-variance matrix, we simulate 5000 random realizations of the time series of2283 daily returns for the Asian countries. For each realization we identifythe returns below (above) the 5th (95th) percent quantile returns for thebottom (top) tail of the return distributions and perform the same non-parametric count across countries by region as in Table 2. Doing soprovides us with a distribution of exceedances and coexceedances. Weuse that distribution to calibrate the observed sample of coexceedances.The results are shown in Table 3 and for each scenario we report thesimulated mean, standard deviation, 5% and 95% quantiles, and thesimulated p-value of the 5000 replications.

The distribution of the coexceedances will depend on the assumptionsmade about the returns-generating process. To this end we perform theMonte Carlo simulation with three scenarios. The first scenario assumesthat returns are jointly distributed as multivariate normal. The secondscenario allows for the possibility of fatter tails with the multivariateStudent's t distribution. The degrees of freedom equal N�Kÿ 1, where

7 Susmel (2001) also documents the unusually large number of extreme negative returns among LatinAmerican index returns. His focus is on the implication of safety-first principles for U.S. investors whocreate a diversified portfolio using Latin American markets added to their purely domestic portfolio.

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

726

Page 11: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Table

3M

onte

Carl

osi

mula

tion

resu

lts

of

(co-)

exce

edance

sfo

rdail

yem

ergin

gm

ark

etre

turn

s

Nu

mb

ero

fn

egati

ve

(co

-)ex

ceed

an

ces

Nu

mb

ero

fp

osi

tive

(co

-)ex

ceed

an

ces

�6

54

32

10

01

23

45

�6

Pan

elA

:A

sia

Act

ual

516

22

36

148

530

1526

1507

546

148

51

18

67

Mo

nte

Carl

osi

mu

lati

on

sA

.M

ult

ivari

ate

no

rmali

tyS

imu

late

dm

ean

0.6

12.7

912.0

546.0

7170.1

5595.6

01455.7

31450.2

6598.0

8172.0

346.8

412.3

32.8

40.6

2S

tan

dard

dev

iati

on

0.7

71.6

43.2

66.0

010.6

418.9

911.9

112.0

519.0

410.4

96.0

03.3

01.6

60.7

85th

qu

an

tile

00

736

153

565

1436

1430

567

155

37

70

095th

qu

an

tile

26

18

56

188

627

1475

1470

629

189

57

18

62

p-v

alu

e0.0

00.0

00.0

00.9

60.9

81.0

00.0

00.0

01.0

00.9

90.2

70.0

70.0

60.0

0

B.

Mu

ltiv

ari

ate

t-d

istr

ibu

tio

n(d

egre

eo

ffr

eed

om�

5)

Sim

ula

ted

mea

n7.2

012.3

728.5

264.8

6153.7

5415.8

11600.4

81595.2

8418.5

2155.0

165.4

328.9

612.5

07.3

0S

tan

dard

dev

iati

on

2.5

63.3

14.8

37.0

710.8

918.6

414.0

914.1

918.4

711.0

37.0

94.8

43.3

52.5

55th

qu

an

tile

37

21

54

136

385

1577

1572

388

137

54

21

73

95th

qu

an

tile

12

18

37

77

172

447

1624

1619

448

173

77

37

18

12

p-v

alu

e0.8

60.1

70.9

31.0

00.7

20.0

01.0

01.0

00.0

00.7

50.9

90.9

90.9

90.6

0

C.

Mu

ltiv

ari

ate

GA

RC

HS

imu

late

dm

ean

1.1

64.9

615.5

65

0.0

6167.5

0560.5

61483.2

01484.2

0554.9

2167.0

054.2

216.4

04.8

41.4

2S

tan

dard

dev

iati

on

1.3

63.5

54.0

26.7

014.6

123.6

720.4

522.5

727.6

912.7

66.7

74.7

13.1

41.9

35th

qu

an

tile

01

839

135

517

1448

1450

502

144

42

10

10

95th

qu

an

tile

412

21

59

187

597

1519

1525

601

186

65

25

10

5p

-valu

e0.0

40.0

20.0

40.9

80.9

20.9

20.0

40.1

60.6

00.9

40.7

40.3

20.3

60.0

4

Pan

elB

:L

ati

nA

mer

ica

Act

ual

76

15

34

96

371

1754

1691

448

104

25

95

1M

on

teC

arl

osi

mu

lati

on

sA

.M

ult

ivari

ate

no

rmali

tyS

imu

late

dm

ean

0.1

71.4

17.4

92

9.4

2110.2

9451.1

01683.1

21678.7

5453.8

3111.1

729.9

87.6

31.4

60.1

8S

tan

dard

dev

iati

on

0.4

11.1

72.5

74.8

48.7

816.4

510.3

110.2

416.4

28.5

84.8

32.5

81.1

90.4

25th

qu

an

tile

00

322

96

424

1666

1662

426

97

22

40

095th

qu

an

tile

14

12

37

125

478

1700

1696

481

126

38

12

41

p-v

alu

e0.0

00.0

00.0

10.2

00.9

51.0

00.0

00.1

20.6

50.8

20.8

70.3

50.0

20.1

6

Measuring Financial Contagion

727

Page 12: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Table

3(c

onti

nu

ed)

Nu

mb

ero

fn

egati

ve

(co

-)ex

ceed

an

ces

Nu

mb

ero

fp

osi

tive

(co

-)ex

ceed

an

ces

�6

54

32

10

01

23

45

�6

B.

Mu

ltiv

ari

ate

t-d

istr

ibu

tio

n(d

egre

eo

ffr

eed

om�

5)

Sim

ula

ted

mea

n1.7

96.0

917.2

742.9

3109.6

7339.3

61765.8

91761.5

6342.1

5110.4

943.4

017.3

96.1

81.8

3S

tan

dard

dev

iati

on

1.3

12.3

83.8

55

.69

8.9

316.2

111.4

811.7

316.4

09.2

05.8

13.8

62.4

11.3

55th

qu

an

tile

02

11

34

95

313

1747

1742

315

95

34

11

30

95th

qu

an

tile

410

24

52

125

366

1784

1781

370

126

53

24

10

4p

-valu

e0.0

00.5

80.7

60.9

50.9

50.0

30.8

61.0

00.0

00.7

71.0

00.9

90.7

50.8

4

C.

Mu

ltiv

ari

ate

GA

RC

HS

imu

late

dm

ean

0.2

92.0

59.2

632

.46

109.9

3431.7

01697.3

11693.4

8433.6

1111.0

732.8

79.5

42.1

30.3

1S

tan

dard

dev

iati

on

0.5

51.5

43.2

85

.48

9.0

620.8

914.5

414.9

121.4

39.3

05.5

93.3

01.6

00.5

95th

qu

an

tile

00

424

95

397

1674

1669

399

96

24

40

095th

qu

an

tile

15

15

42

125

466

1722

1718

470

126

42

15

51

p-v

alu

e0.0

00.0

30.0

60.4

20.9

51.0

00.0

00.5

80.2

50.7

90.9

40.6

00.0

80.2

5

Un

der

the

nu

llh

yp

oth

esis

that

nati

on

al

emer

gin

gm

ark

etin

dex

retu

rns

inA

sia

an

dL

ati

nA

mer

ica

are

dra

wn

fro

ma

sim

ula

ted

retu

rnd

istr

ibu

tio

n,

we

emp

loy

aM

on

teC

arl

osi

mu

lati

on

toev

alu

ate

the

nu

mb

ero

f(c

o-)

exce

edan

ces

wit

hin

each

regio

n.

We

com

pu

teth

esa

mp

lem

ean

an

dth

evari

an

ce-c

ovari

an

cem

atr

ixo

fre

turn

san

dgen

erate

5000

ran

do

mre

ali

zati

on

s.F

or

each

reali

zati

on

we

com

pu

teth

en

um

ber

of

(co

-)ex

ceed

an

ces

for

a5%

thre

sho

ld,

as

inT

ab

le2.

Su

mm

ary

stati

stic

sfo

rth

e5000

rep

lica

tio

ns

incl

ud

eth

em

ean

,st

an

dard

dev

iati

on

,5%

qu

an

tile

,95%

qu

an

tile

,an

dsi

mu

late

dp-v

alu

e(t

he

nu

mb

ero

fre

pli

cati

on

sw

ith

coex

ceed

an

ces

ina

giv

enca

tego

ryex

ceed

ing

the

act

ual

nu

mb

ero

fco

exce

edan

ces)

.S

imu

lati

on

sare

run

un

der

thre

ed

iffe

ren

tm

od

els

of

retu

rnd

istr

ibu

tio

ns:

am

ult

ivari

ate

no

rmal

dis

trib

uti

on

,a

mu

ltiv

ari

ate

t-d

istr

ibu

tio

nw

ith

five

deg

rees

of

free

do

m,

an

da

mu

ltiv

ari

ate

GA

RC

H.

Th

ed

yn

am

ics

of

vari

an

cean

dco

vari

an

cem

atr

ixo

fre

turn

sfo

rea

chre

gio

nu

nd

erth

em

ult

ivari

ate

GA

RC

Hm

od

elis

ass

um

edto

foll

ow

the

spec

ific

ati

on

pro

po

sed

by

Din

gan

dE

ngle

(1994).

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

728

Page 13: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

N is the number of countries (10 for Asia, 7 for Latin America) and K is setto values ranging from 1 (significant positive excess cokurtosis) to 25 (littleexcess cokurtosis, approximating multivariate normal). We exploreda number of choices of K, but report only our analysis for K � 5.8

One of the concerns expressed by Baig and Goldfajn (1999), Dorn-busch, Park, and Claessens (2001), and Forbes and Rigobon (2001,2002) is that contagion as measured by changes in cross-market correla-tions across quiet and turbulent periods can be biased by heteroscedasti-city. Forbes and Rigobon (2002) show how the bias can be corrected bya measure of the relative increase in the volatility of market returns, say,for example, during a crisis period. Neither of these two scenarios allowsfor the possibility of conditional heteroscedasticity in the index returns.Unfortunately there are not many choices available to specify a parsimo-nious, yet reasonably general structure with time-varying conditionalvolatility for a relatively large number of markets. One such parameter-ization is the multivariate generalized autoregressive conditional hetero-scedasticity (GARCH) model of Ding and Engle (1994).9 This Ding andEngle model constitutes our third scenario. Specifically, we estimate

Rit� �0� "it "tjtÿ 1 � N�0;Ht�

Ht � H0 � ���0 ÿ��0 ÿ ��0� � ��0 � "tÿ 1"0tÿ 1 � ��0 � Htÿ 1,

where Rit is the return on asset i between time tÿ 1 and t, and tÿ 1, the setof marketwide information available at tÿ 1. �0 is a constant parameterand "it and the associated N-vector, "t, are residuals that are conditionallydistributed multivariate normal with symmetric conditional covariance(N�N) matrix, Ht. In the law of motion equation for the conditionalvariances, � is an N-vector of ones, � and � are N-vectors of parameters(where � is the Hadamard matrix product, element by element), and H0 isan unobserved starting covariance matrix which we set equal to the samplecovariance matrix of the returns. We estimate this system using maximumlikelihood and the Berndt et al. (1974) optimization algorithm for the 10Asian and 7 Latin American markets and then simulate 5000 randomrealizations given the estimated (2N� 1) parameters. It is important tonote that the Ding and Engle model does not impose constant correlation,

8 A multivariate Student's t distribution could potentially have a vector of degrees of freedom. Our choiceto impose a single value for all returns series is restrictive. We thank the referee for this point.

9 This model structure has been successfully applied by De Santis and Gerard (1997, 1998), and morerecently, Ledoit, Santa-Clara, and Wolf (2003). The goal of the Ledoit, Santa-Clara, and Wolf study,however, is to propose a numerically feasible alternative `̀ Diagonal-Vech'' multivariate GARCH model.We thank the referee for pointing out this alternative conditional covariance structure.

Measuring Financial Contagion

729

Page 14: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

but rather guides the correlations in time by means of a constrained law ofmotion for the conditional volatilities. Readers should also be cautionedthat the law of motion does not allow for the covariance asymmetryfeatured in recent work by Ang and Chen (2002), that could generatehigh coexceedance counts following large negative return shocks.

Table 3 reports the results separately for Asia (panel A) and LatinAmerica (panel B). It is immediately apparent that we observe morecoexceedances than one would expect for Latin America, but not neces-sarily for Asia. This is true regardless of the assumption about the struc-ture of the joint returns-generating process. For example, we have fivedays where six or more countries in Asia have extreme negative returns. Inour simulations we generate an average of 0.61 days with the multivariatenormal scenario, 7.20 days on average in the multivariate Student's tscenario, and only 1.16 with the multivariate GARCH scenario.10 Thesimulation p-values indicate that the multivariate normal scenario deliversnot even one replication out of 5000 in which five or more days ofcoexceedances of negative returns of six or more countries occur. How-ever, the multivariate GARCH and Student's t scenarios do generate theactual number of coexceedances in 4% and 86% of the replications,respectively. For coexceedances of positive returns, the results are similar.In these cases, the sample has seven coexceedances involving six countriesor more and this count is larger than that generated by the multivariatenormal and GARCH scenarios (simulated p-value of 0.00 and 0.04,respectively), but it is not unusual for the Student's t scenarios ( p-valueof 0.60).

The results for Latin America are harder to reconcile with the simula-tions than the results for Asia. In these experiments, the multivariatenormal and GARCH scenarios fail to generate any (simulated p-valuesof 0.00) observations of six or more coexceedances of negative returns ofwhich there are seven in the actual sample. What is more surprising is thateven the Student's t scenario cannot deliver simulated coexceedancecounts as large as in the actual sample. By contrast, the number ofpositive-tail coexceedances in Latin America is not dramatically differentfrom the simulated counts. There is only one coexceedance event with sixor more countries, so each of the scenarios are able to offer a reasonablenumber of realizations that meet this challenge. But even the five

10 In order to check the validity of the calibration exercise, we examined the skewness and kurtosis of thesimulated returns from the three scenarios and compared them with the actual returns. Overall thekurtosis implied by the multivariate Student's t scenario for the marginal distributions of individualcountry index returns are reasonably close to the positive excess kurtosis in the actual returns. Theskewness statistics were, however, typically much lower. For the multivariate GARCH and normalscenarios, the skewness and kurtosis were even smaller than those of the Student's t. For example, Peru'sindex returns display excess positive skewness (0.26) and positive kurtosis (6.89). The average skewnesscoefficients for the three simulated scenarios (normal, Student's t, and GARCH) were 0.03, 0.28, andÿ 0.05, respectively; the average kurtosis coefficients were 0.01, 5.79, and 2.48, respectively.

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

730

Page 15: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

coexceedance events in which five Latin American countries experiencereturns in the top 5% tail occur in more than 2% of the replications for themultivariate normal scenario, 8% for the multivariate GARCH scenario,and 75% for the multivariate Student's t scenario. This asymmetry incoexceedance events represents another challenge for a model ofcontagion.

The bottom line from our simulation experiments is that it is moredifficult to explain the distribution of coexceedances for Latin Americathan Asia. Our simulation evidence suggests that the frequency of bottom-tail and top-tail coexceedances in Asia can be generated (in a large fractionof the 5000 replications) with a somewhat strong assumption about posi-tive excess cokurtosis in the Student's t distribution (though not with thenormal or GARCH models). For Latin America, this is not the case forthe bottom-tail coexceedance events for any scenario. At the same time,however, it is important to emphasize that the number of puzzling obser-vations is small. The events that occur too often compared to the multi-variate Student's t, GARCH, or normal distribution model are those inwhich most countries in a region have extreme returns at the same time.There are few such days, but from the perspective of contagion studies,those days are the most interesting.

2� Contagion within Regions

In this section we show how our approach is useful for understandingcontagion within regions. In the first part of the section we present ourapproach of using multinomial logistic regressions. In the second part ofthe section we provide estimates of the regressions for Asia and LatinAmerica.

2.1 The logistic regression approach

Extreme value theory (EVT) has proposed three possible types of limitingdistributions for minima or maxima of a variable which are the Gumbel,Fr�echet, and Weibull distributions [Longin (1996)], and each of these hasbeen applied to time series of financial returns. These studies typicallyestimate the parameters of these distributions using parametric (maximumlikelihood) and nonparametric approaches. We know of only a few appli-cations of multivariate EVT to stock returns [Straetmans (1998), Starica(1999), Hartman, Straetmans, and de Vries (2001), Longin and Solnik(2001)]. But even in these cases, a dependence function between theFr�echet, Gumbel, or Weibull distributions across variables must beassumed and it is typically a logistic function [Longin and Solnik(2001)]. Our approach is different.

Exceedances in terms of extreme positive or negative returns in aparticular country can be modeled as a dichotomous variable. However,

Measuring Financial Contagion

731

Page 16: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

our interest in coexceedances to capture contagion across many countrieswithin a region requires classification into many categories using a poly-chotomous variable. Multinomial logistic regression models, not verydifferent from the multivariate EVT applications, are popular approachesto estimate the probabilities associated with events captured in a poly-chotomous variable [Maddala (1983, chap. 2), Hosmer and Lemeshow(1989, chap. 8)]. If Pi is the probability associated with a category i of mpossible categories, then we can define a multinomial distribution given by

Pi � G��0ix�=�1 �Xmÿ 1

j� 1

G��0jx��, �1�

where x is the vector of covariates and �i the vector of coefficientsassociated with the covariates. Often the function G(�i

0x) is simplifiedusing a logistic function exp(�i

0x) which reduces Equation (1) to a multi-nomial logistic model. The model is estimated using maximum likelihoodwith the (log-) likelihood function for a sample of n observations given by

logL �Xn

i� 1

Xm

j� 1

IijlogPij, �2�

where Iij is an indicator variable that equals one if the ith observation fallsin the jth category, and zero otherwise. Because Pij is a nonlinear functionof the �'s, an iterative estimation procedure is employed and, for thispurpose, we choose the Broyden, Fletcher, Goldfard, and Shanno algo-rithm. The matrix of second partial derivatives delivers the informationmatrix and asymptotic covariance matrix of the maximum-likelihoodestimator for tests of significance of the individual estimated coefficients.Goodness-of-fit is measured using the pseudo-R2 approach of McFadden(1974) where both unrestricted (full model) likelihood, L!, and restricted(constants only) likelihood, L, functions are compared:11

pseudoR2� 1ÿ �logL!=logL�: �3�In our application to coexceedances across countries within Asia and

Latin America, we balance the need to have a model that is parsimoniousand yet one that richly captures the range of possible outcomes. Wetherefore choose to restrict our categories to five in number: 0, 1, 2, 3,and 4 or more coexceedances. For a simple model of constants, onlymÿ 1, or four parameters, need to be estimated. But for every covariateadded to the model, such as the conditional volatility of returns for theregional index, four additional parameters need to be estimated. Wechoose to estimate the coexceedances separately for positive and negative

11 Greene (2000, chap. 19) warns about the limitations of using pseudo-R2 for comparisons across models.

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

732

Page 17: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

extreme returns (though we test the importance of this distinction later).Finally, we compute the probability of a coexceedance of a specific level,Pi, by evaluating the covariates at their unconditional values,

P�i � exp��0ix���

1�Xmÿ 1

j� 1

exp��0jx��" #

, �4�

where x� is the unconditional mean value of x. From this measure andfollowing Greene (2000, chap. 19), we compute the marginal change inprobability for a given unit change in the independent covariate to testwhether this change is statistically significantly different from zero.

Because it is often difficult to judge whether changes in probabilities ofa given coexceedance level are large or small economically, we furthercompute the sensitivity or response of our probability estimates to the fullrange of values associated with different covariates instead of just at itsunconditional mean. These probabilities across the five categories add upto one and we use plots to illustrate visually the changes in these prob-abilities, a new approach in finance that we call the ``coexceedanceresponse curve.''12

Note that our key hypotheses relate to the existence of contagion acrossregions as well as measuring contagion within regions. Specifically we willassess the importance of the coexceedance events within Asia and LatinAmerica for the likelihood of an exceedance in the United States andEurope. To this end we will need to estimate a logistic regression model forthe United States, but it must necessarily be for a dichotomous variable orbinomial logistic regression. This is a simple version of our multinomiallogistic regression model, and all estimation procedures, inference tests,pseudo-R2, and even ``exceedance response curve'' plots are computedaccordingly. For simplicity, we compute the analogous models for Europeas a single entity.

2.2 Contagion within regions

Table 4 provides estimates of our multinomial logistic regressions for Asiaand Latin America. We estimate the regressions separately for the bottomtails and the top tails. The first panel shows estimates for Asia and thesecond panel has estimates for Latin America. At the end of each table wealso report results for the binomial models for the United States andEurope. Column (1) reports estimates of regressions for the bottom tailsfor Asia that provide us with estimates of probabilities of coexceedances.

12 Our coexceedance response curve analysis is inspired by the epidemiology study by Gillespie, Halpern,and Warner (1994) which examines lung cancer deaths per year among ex-smokers and employs covari-ates such as age, gender, college attendance, smoker, and years since quitting for ex-smokers.

Measuring Financial Contagion

733

Page 18: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Table

4M

ult

inom

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nre

sult

sfo

rdail

yre

turn

coex

ceed

ance

sof

emer

gin

gm

ark

etin

dic

es,

Apri

l1,

1992,

toD

ecem

ber

29,

2000

Bo

tto

mta

ils

To

pta

ils

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Asi

ab 0

1(c

on

stan

t)ÿ

1.0

58

aÿ

0.1

24

aÿ

1.4

53

aÿ

0.1

91

aÿ

1.3

12

aÿ

0.1

70

aÿ

1.0

15

aÿ

0.1

18

aÿ

1.2

59

aÿ

0.1

60

aÿ

1.2

40

aÿ

0.1

74

a

b 02

ÿ2.3

33

aÿ

0.1

17

aÿ

2.9

84

aÿ

0.1

46

aÿ

3.0

96

aÿ

0.1

48

aÿ

2.3

21

aÿ

0.1

17

aÿ

2.8

39

aÿ

0.1

40

aÿ

2.1

86

aÿ

0.0

98

a

b 03

ÿ3.7

47

aÿ

0.0

51

aÿ

4.8

65

aÿ

0.0

51

aÿ

6.6

13

aÿ

0.0

58

aÿ

3.3

86

aÿ

0.0

64

aÿ

4.2

81

aÿ

0.0

67

aÿ

3.8

65

aÿ

0.0

57

a

b 04

ÿ3.5

69

aÿ

0.0

57

aÿ

4.9

51

aÿ

0.0

52

aÿ

6.2

08

aÿ

0.0

48

aÿ

3.8

84

aÿ

0.0

46

aÿ

5.3

60

aÿ

0.0

36

aÿ

6.0

37

aÿ

0.0

32

a

b 11

(hit)

0.3

89

a0.0

58

a0.4

77

a0.0

77

a0.2

42

a0.0

33

a0.3

29

a0.0

48

a

b 12

0.5

65

a0.0

26

a0.6

07

a0.0

26

a0.4

46

a0.0

21

a0.6

18

a0.0

29

a

b 13

0.7

84

a0.0

08

a0.6

63

a0.0

05

a0.6

38

a0.0

10

a0.7

74

a0.0

11

a

b 14

0.8

74

a0.0

09

a0.8

16

a0.0

06

a0.8

31

a0.0

06

a0.8

14

a0.0

04

a

b 21

(eit)

1.0

77

a0.1

58

aÿ

1.0

03

aÿ

0.1

50

a

b 22

2.1

44

a0.1

02

aÿ

1.7

74

aÿ

0.0

82

a

b 23

2.2

16

a0.0

17

aÿ

1.8

72

aÿ

0.0

25

a

b 24

2.6

40

a0.0

19

aÿ

2.3

51

aÿ

0.0

11

a

b 31

(iit)

ÿ0.0

21

ÿ0.0

04

ÿ0.0

06

0.0

00

b 32

ÿ0.0

04

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

78

bÿ

0.0

04

b

b 33

0.1

47

a0.0

01

bÿ

0.0

53

ÿ0.0

01

b 34

0.0

83

0.0

01

0.0

46

0.0

00

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ2113.8

5ÿ

2006.2

1ÿ

1919.1

6ÿ

2139.1

6ÿ

2056.8

2ÿ

1998.9

0P

seu

do

-R2

5.0

9%

9.2

1%

3.8

5%

6.5

6%

Lati

nA

mer

ica

b 01

(co

nst

an

t)ÿ

1.5

54

aÿ

0.1

74

aÿ

2.0

97

aÿ

0.2

43

aÿ

2.4

31

aÿ

0.2

90

aÿ

1.3

28

aÿ

0.1

69

aÿ

1.6

72

aÿ

0.2

22

aÿ

1.8

52

aÿ

0.2

54

a

b 02

ÿ2.9

05

aÿ

0.1

02

aÿ

3.4

70

aÿ

0.1

20

aÿ

3.9

02

aÿ

0.1

20

aÿ

2.7

89

aÿ

0.1

06

aÿ

3.4

12

aÿ

0.1

24

aÿ

3.7

35

aÿ

0.1

22

a

b 03

ÿ3.9

43

aÿ

0.0

52

aÿ

5.0

83

aÿ

0.0

53

aÿ

5.7

38

aÿ

0.0

51

aÿ

4.2

14

aÿ

0.0

41

aÿ

5.3

61

aÿ

0.0

39

aÿ

5.7

84

aÿ

0.0

38

a

b 04

ÿ4.1

37

aÿ

0.0

45

aÿ

5.3

89

aÿ

0.0

43

aÿ

5.5

31

aÿ

0.0

37

aÿ

4.7

25

aÿ

0.0

28

aÿ

6.1

49

aÿ

0.0

23

bÿ

7.5

92

aÿ

0.0

21

b

b 11

(hit)

0.3

63

a0.0

44

a0.3

45

a0.0

43

a0.2

37

a0.0

33

a0.2

32

a0.0

33

a

b 12

0.3

74

a0.0

12

a0.3

59

a0.0

10

a0.3

90

a0.0

14

a0.4

08

a0.0

13

a

b 13

0.6

14

a0.0

06

a0.6

04

a0.0

05

a0.5

86

a0.0

04

a0.6

00

a0.0

04

a

b 14

0.6

47

a0.0

05

a0.6

51

a0.0

04

a0.6

57

a0.0

02

b0.6

65

a0.0

02

b

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

734

Page 19: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

b 21

(eit)

1.1

77

a0.1

42

aÿ

0.1

30

ÿ0.0

06

b 22

1.9

14

a0.0

59

aÿ

1.4

66

aÿ

0.0

53

a

b 23

1.9

62

a0.0

17

aÿ

1.4

88

aÿ

0.0

10

b

b 24

2.0

48

a0.0

13

aÿ

1.6

38

aÿ

0.0

05

b 31

(iit)

0.0

14

0.0

02

0.0

12

0.0

02

b 32

0.0

08

0.0

00

0.0

18

0.0

01

b 33

0.0

18

0.0

00

0.0

24

0.0

00

b 34

ÿ0.0

14

0.0

00

0.0

72

b0.0

00

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ1706.9

4ÿ

1636.2

4ÿ

1573.1

6ÿ

1746.6

1ÿ

1691.2

2ÿ

1664.9

6P

seu

do

-R2

4.1

4%

7.8

4%

3.1

7%

4.6

7%

US

b 01

(co

nst

an

t)ÿ

2.9

46

aÿ

0.1

40

aÿ

3.5

35

aÿ

0.1

53

aÿ

5.7

92

aÿ

0.2

25

aÿ

2.9

46

aÿ

0.1

40

aÿ

4.0

04

aÿ

0.1

48

aÿ

5.1

20

aÿ

0.1

77

a

b 11

(hit)

0.5

70

a0.0

25

a0.4

27

a0.0

17

a0.9

21

a0.0

34

a0.8

92

a0.0

31

a

b 21

(eit)

0.4

09

0.0

16

ÿ0.6

10

bÿ

0.0

21

b

b 31

(iit)

0.4

60

a0.0

18

a0.2

16

0.0

07

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ452.7

6ÿ

434.7

6ÿ

424.8

8ÿ

452.7

6ÿ

399.1

3ÿ

393.9

5P

seu

do

-R2

3.9

8%

6.1

6%

11.8

5%

12.9

9%

Eu

rop

eb 0

1(c

on

stan

t)ÿ

2.9

46

aÿ

0.1

40

aÿ

3.8

08

aÿ

0.1

58

aÿ

3.6

39

aÿ

0.1

32

aÿ

2.9

46

aÿ

0.1

40

aÿ

4.0

09

aÿ

0.1

57

aÿ

3.7

91

aÿ

0.1

25

a

b 11

(hit)

1.0

49

a0.0

44

a1.0

46

a0.0

38

a1.2

50

a0.0

49

a1.1

86

a0.0

39

a

b 21

(eit)

0.9

22

a0.0

33

aÿ

1.0

47

aÿ

0.0

34

a

b 31

(iit)

ÿ0.0

57

ÿ0.0

02

ÿ0.0

61

ÿ0.0

02

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ452.7

6ÿ

426.4

1ÿ

408.0

7ÿ

452.7

6ÿ

412.9

2ÿ

388.6

6P

seu

do

-R2

5.8

2%

9.8

7%

8.8

0%

14.1

6%

Th

en

um

ber

of

coex

ceed

an

ces

of

dail

yre

turn

sis

mo

del

edas

an

ord

ered

po

lych

oto

mo

us

vari

ab

lean

des

tim

ate

du

sin

ga

mu

ltin

om

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nm

od

el.

Pj

isd

efin

edas

the

pro

bab

ilit

yth

at

agiv

end

ay

isass

oci

ate

dw

ith

jco

exce

edan

ces

wh

ere

jeq

uals

0,

1,

2,

3,

4o

rm

ore

(fiv

eca

tego

ries

).T

he

mu

ltin

om

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nm

od

elis

giv

enb

yP

j�

exp

(x0 b

j)/[

1�P k

exp

(x0 b

k)]

,w

her

eb

isth

evec

tor

of

coef

fici

ents

,x

,th

evec

tor

of

ind

epen

den

tvari

ab

les,

an

dk

equ

als

1to

4.

Th

ep

rob

ab

ilit

yth

at

ther

eare

no

(co

-)ex

ceed

an

ces

equ

als

P0�

1/[

1+P k

exp

(x0 b

k)]

,w

hic

hre

pre

sen

tso

ur

base

case

.T

he

ind

epen

den

tvari

ab

les,

x,

incl

ud

eth

ein

terc

ept,

con

dit

ion

al

vo

lati

lity

of

the

regio

nal

ind

exat

tim

et

(ht)

,th

eaver

age

exch

an

ge

rate

(per

$U

S)

chan

ges

inth

ere

gio

n(e

t),

an

dth

eaver

age

inte

rest

rate

level

inth

ere

gio

n(i

t).

Th

eco

nd

itio

nal

vo

lati

lity

ises

tim

ate

das

EG

AR

CH

(1,1

)u

sin

gth

eIF

Cin

ves

tib

lere

gio

nal

ind

ex.

Th

eli

kel

iho

od

for

the

mu

ltin

om

ial

logit

mo

del

[McF

ad

den

(1975)]

isn

um

eric

all

yev

alu

ate

du

sin

gth

eB

royd

en,

Fle

tch

er,

Go

ldfa

rb,

an

dS

han

no

alg

ori

thm

.P

art

ial

der

ivati

ves

of

pro

bab

ilit

ies

wit

hre

spec

tto

the

vec

tor

of

ind

epen

den

tvari

ab

les

are

com

pu

ted

at

the

mea

ns

of

x[G

reen

e(2

000,

chap

.19)]

an

dare

rep

ort

edn

ext

toth

eco

effi

cien

tes

tim

ate

s.G

oo

dn

ess-

of-

fit

ism

easu

red

by

McF

ad

den

'sp

seu

do

-R2

equ

al

to1ÿ

(L!/L

),

wh

ere

L!

isth

eu

nre

stri

cted

lik

elih

oo

d,

an

dL

is

the

rest

rict

edli

kel

iho

od

[Mad

da

la(1

983,

chap

.2)]

.T

he

logit

regre

ssio

nis

esti

mate

dse

para

tely

for

po

siti

ve

(to

p-t

ail

)an

dn

egati

ve

(bo

tto

m-t

ail

)co

exce

edan

ces.

a,

bD

eno

tes

sign

ific

an

cele

vel

sat

the

1%

an

d5%

,re

spec

tivel

y.

Measuring Financial Contagion

735

Page 20: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

We find (not reported) that there is a probability of 66.84% that no Asiancountry has a bottom-tail return. If bottom-tail exceedances were inde-pendent, this probability would be 59.87% (or 0.9510). The coefficient b01

is associated with the event ``Y� 1,'' or the case where one country has anextreme return, and its probability is 23.22%; for example, computed asthe special case of the logistic function, exp(b01)/[1�Pkexp(�0k)]. Sincethere are no covariates, these probabilities are the sample frequenciesreported in Table 2; for example, 530 occurrences of single-country nega-tive return exceedances in Asia during the 2283 days. In column (2) weadd the conditional volatility of the Asian index (hit) as a covariate.13 Wefind that the conditional volatility increases the probability of extremereturns significantly. To see the impact of conditional volatility, it is usefulto evaluate the marginal probability of exceedances with respect to theconditional volatility. An increase in conditional volatility increases theprobability of all exceedances, but the effect decreases as we look at highernumbers of joint occurrences. For instance, a 1% increase in the condi-tional volatility increases the probability of one exceedance by 0.058% andthe probability of four or more occurrences by 0.009%. All the partialderivatives are significant at the 5% level. The pseudo-R2 is 5.09%.

In column (3), we add the average exchange rate change in the region(eit) a well as the average interest rate level (iit) in the region.14 This allowsus to answer the question of whether the probability of co-exceedances isaffected by exchange rate shocks to the region and by the level of theinterest rates. We see that this is indeed the case if we look at the regressioncoefficients. If currencies fall on average (eit rises), extreme returns aremore likely. Few of the interest rate coefficients are significant. Thesignificant bottom-tail coefficients are positive, making it more likelythat a negative exceedance will occur when interest rates are high. Thetwo significant upper-tail coefficients are of opposite sign, which is puz-zling. Moreover, the magnitude of the partial derivatives for changes in eit

is two to three times larger than for the partial derivatives for hit. Thepartial derivatives are computed at the means of the regressors and are notsignificant for one, two, or four or more exceedances. Adding exchangerate changes and the level of interest rates almost doubles the pseudo-R2

to 9.21 percent. The economic and statistical significance of exchange ratechanges raises the question of whether the stock retun contagion we

13 The conditional volatility is estimated from a univariate EGARCH(1,1) model to the value-weightedAsian and Latin American regional indexes, as created by IFC after 1995 and reconstructed back to April1992 as described in Section 2.

14 Data on daily exchange rates relative to the U.S. dollar and mterest rates for each country are tamed fromDatastream International. The interest rate series chosen is typically the short-term rate of interestavailable in Datastream with availability back to 1992. We computed simple equally-weighted averagerate changes and average interest rates by region for these covariates.

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

736

Page 21: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

measure is actually foreign exchange contagion since we measure returnsin dollars. To examine this issue, we estimated our models in local cur-rency returns, but do not report the results because they are similar tothose we do report.

When we look at the top-tail events (models 4±6 in Table 4), we find noevidence that coexceedance events are less likely for positive extremereturns than for negative extreme returns. A pairwise comparison of thecoefficients in columns (1) and (4) cannot reject that the coefficients areequal (Wald chi-square statistic of 0.21, p-value of 0.65, not reported).15

Hence, for Asia, there is no evidence that contagion is somehow moreimportant for negative returns than it is for positive returns. Conditionalvolatility is a statistically important covariate for positive coexcee-dances.16 The exchange rate coefficients are negative and significant. Inother words, the likelihood of seeing positive extreme returns in more thanone country increases when on average the exchange rate in the regionappreciates. The interest rate variables provide almost no information forpositive coexceedances. The pseudo-R2s are much lower for positivereturns than they are for negative returns, so that our covariates aremore successful at explaining coexceedances for negative returns thanfor positive returns.

In the second panel of Table 4 we see that the results for Latin Americadiffer substantially from those for Asia. The probability of having noextreme return on a day is much higher for Latin America than it is forAsia. We estimate the probability of having no extreme return to be76.83% for Latin America, while it is 66.84% for Asia. The probabilityof having four or more Latin American countries experience an extremereturn on the same day is higher than the corresponding probability forAsia (b04 of ÿ 4.137 implies a probability of 1.23%). The explanatoryvariables are significant for Latin America in the same way that they arefor Asia, except that interest rates do not appear to be useful in explainingcoexceedances of extreme negative returns in Latin America. The partialderivatives of the probabilities with respect to regressors are significantexcept for interest rates, but they are smaller for conditional volatility andlarger for exchange rates than those for Asia. Turning to the positiveextreme returns, we see that the probability of having no positive extremereturn is higher than the probability of having no negative extreme return.Our test of equality for the probability of positive extreme return and

15 We estimate a logit model for all coexceedances, positive or negative, and introduce a dummy variablecovariate equal to one if the coexceedance was positive. The Wald test that the coefficients on the dummyvariable are jointly equal to zero is distributed as chi-square with three degrees of freedom.

16 If high regional market volatility occurs because of high volatility in a common factor, it is not surprisingthat a large number of coexceedances arise.

Measuring Financial Contagion

737

Page 22: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

negative extreme return coexceedances confirms the asymmetry for coex-ceedances of four or more extreme returns. Specifically coexceedances offour or more extreme returns are more likely for negative extreme returnsthan for positive extreme returns (Wald chi-square statistic of 3.17,p-value of 0.07, not reported).

We also include the United States and Europe in the third and fourthpanels of Table 4. For the United States, the coefficient on the conditionalvolatility of the market is positive and significant for both negative-and positive-tail events, but the partial derivative of the probability ofan exceedance with respect to the conditional volatility is larger forpositive-tail events. Exchange rate and interest rate levels offer onlyweak explanatory power.17 The pseudo-R2s are higher for the top tailthan in any other regression. For Europe, there is clear evidence that anincrease in the conditional volatility of returns increases the probability oftail events. The exchange rate coefficients are significant, but the interestrate coefficients are not. The pseudo-R2s are substantially higher thanthose of the emerging market regions for the positive tail events.

Figure 1 illustrates the coexceedance response curves of Asia associatedwith the model in column (3) of Table 4. Note that these plots apply onlyto the bottom-tail events. Such curves are important in understanding theimpact of the covariates on the probability of exceedances. In the tableswe provide estimates of the partial derivatives of the exceedance probabil-ities with respect to the regressors evaluating the partial derivatives at themeans of the regressors. However, these partial derivatives give an incom-plete picture of the impact of changes in the regressors because theprobabilities are not linear functions of the regressors.

Plotting the probability of exceedances as a function of a regressor overthe whole relevant range of the regressor permits us to better assess howchanges in the regressor affect the probability of exceedances. Considerthe top plot that shows the sensitivity of implied conditional probabilitiesof different numbers of coexceedances to the conditional volatility ofAsian index returns. The different areas of the plot correspond to differentcoexceedance events. Clearly the probability of various coexceedances inAsia increases with the conditional volatility, but it does so nonlinearly.When the conditional volatility of Asian markets exceeds 3% or 4% perday, for example, the probability of two or more coexceedances reachesalmost 45%. An obvious issue is that one has to be cautious in evaluatingsuch a result because we end up focusing on a subset of an already smallnumber of extreme events. The two other figures are associated with the

17 For the United States we employed the equally weighted average exchange rate for all countries in Asiaand Latin America in the binomial tests as well as the daily Federal funds rate. For Europe we used thedeutsche mark--U.S. dollar (or Euro--U.S. dollar) bilateral exchange rate and the short rate in Germanyas a proxy. All data are from Datastream International.

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

738

Page 23: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Figure 1Coexceedance response curves of negative extreme returns in Asia

Measuring Financial Contagion

739

Page 24: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

model for the exchange rate change and interest rate level covariates. Ofinterest is that the sensitivity of coexceedances to interest rate levels issimilar to conditional volatility, but the sensitivity to exchange rate chan-gesÐno doubt in large part due to the Asian crisis periodÐis dramaticand highly nonlinear. The response curve slope is relatively flat unlessrather large average exchange rate depreciations of 1% or more per dayoccur, after which the probability of regional contagion (two or morecoexceedances) rises to a maximum of 50% to 80%.

Two robustness checks follow. First, we provide a full set of Wald chi-square tests of the restriction that the regression coefficients are the samefor positive exceedances and negative exceedances to which we havealready referred above. We find that for Asia we cannot reject the hypo-thesis that positive- and negative-return joint exceedances are equallylikely. For Latin America, there is an asymmetry in coexceedances offour or more where negative coexceedances are more likely. Second, wealso extended the analysis to incorporate some dynamics in coexceedancesby considering whether knowing the number of extreme returns of yester-day is helpful in predicting the number of extreme returns today. Theresults (not reported) show that the lagged values of coexceedances arestatistically significant for Latin America and Asia, and less so forEurope, but are not significant for the exceedances in the United States.This specification ignores, however, the lagged effects of the interest rate,exchange rate, and regional conditional volatility covariates or a multi-day horizon for measuring coexceedance events. We address thesesupplementary issues in the next section.

How well specified these particular models are is an open question. Ourprimary focus is on the extent of contagion across regions, so it is impor-tant that our tests condition on reasonable covariates that affect conta-gion within regions. We offer a number of sensitivity tests to address thisconcern in the next section.

3� Contagion Across Regions

In this section we investigate contagion across regions. The type of ques-tion we address is whether the number of coexceedances, or joint occur-rences of extreme returns, of a given number in Asia can help predict thenumber of coexceedances or extreme returns in Latin America or in otherregions. To the extent that there is a fraction of the coexceedances in LatinAmerica that is left unexplained by its own covariates that can beexplained by coexceedances in Asia, we will interpret this as evidence ofcontagion across regions. In the first part of the section, we answerthis type of question using a base model. In the second part of the section,we explore alternate specifications, robustness tests, and calibrationexercises.

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

740

Page 25: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

3.1 The base model

To investigate the question we are interested in, we reestimate the modelsof Table 4 for Asia, Latin America, the United States, and Europe,respectively, but add two covariates related to coexceedances (Y �jt) andregional market volatility (hjt

� ) from each of the other regions during thepreceding trading session that day (except for the United States and LatinAmerican trading sessions, which are contemporaneous). Timing conven-tions are important since U.S. and Latin American markets open after themarkets in Asia close. Therefore we add to the Asian contagion regres-sions the number of extreme returns in Latin America on the previoustrading day and the conditional volatility of the Latin American regionalindex as of the previous day. As we are careful to condition on exceedanceevents or conditional volatility from the previous trading day, we interpretthese results as evidence of predictability of contagion.

The model for Asia is given in column (1) of Table 5 for the bottom tailsand in column (4) for the top tails. The regression coefficients on thenumber of exceedances in Latin America are significant (b5k for k equals 1to 4 are all significant at the 1% level) for all but two-country coexcee-dances. In evaluating the derivative of the exceedance probabilities (``�prob'') at the unconditional mean of the covariates, we note that anincrease in the number of exceedances in Latin America increases theprobability of all one-country and four-country-or-more exceedance out-comes in Asia for negative tail events. It seems surprising at first that thecoefficient b53 is significant while its associated change in probability isnot, but this no doubt reflects the nonlinear logistic mapping. Because theslope of the probability function depends on the covariates, the signifi-cance of this slope depends on the value of the covariates used to estimatethe slope.

A concern with these results is that the number of exceedances in LatinAmerica might proxy for an exceedance in the United States, since LatinAmerican markets are open at the same time as the U.S. market. This turnsout not to be the case. We reestimated our regressions, adding a variablethat takes a value of one if the United States has an exceedance and zerootherwise. Adding this dummy variable does not change our results. Thisindicates that there is something unique about contagion among emergingmarkets. The coefficients are significant for all exceedance outcomes forpositive tails, but the partial derivatives of the probabilities are not. We addtwo Wald chi-square statistics associated with tests of the null hypothesisthat the block of coefficients associated with the conditional volatility andthe number of exceedances in the other market are jointly zero. The con-ditional volatility of Latin America does not seem to be very helpful inpredicting exceedances in Asia. Introducing this variable weakens theestimates of the impact of changes in the conditional volatility of Asia onthe probability of exceedances in Asia.

Measuring Financial Contagion

741

Page 26: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Table

5C

onta

gio

nte

stre

sult

sof

mult

inom

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nfo

rdail

yre

turn

coex

ceed

ance

sof

emer

gin

gm

ark

etin

dic

es,

Apri

l1,

1992,

toD

ecem

ber

29,

2000

Bo

tto

mta

ils

To

pta

ils

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Asi

aF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Eu

rop

eF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Eu

rop

eb 0

1(c

on

stan

t)ÿ

1.4

14

aÿ

0.1

90

aÿ

1.6

25

aÿ

0.2

24

aÿ

1.6

70

aÿ

0.2

31

aÿ

1.2

43

aÿ

0.1

77

aÿ

1.3

20

aÿ

0.1

85

aÿ

1.4

61

aÿ

0.2

13

a

b 02

ÿ3.2

49

aÿ

0.1

55

aÿ

3.7

72

aÿ

0.1

73

aÿ

3.7

12

aÿ

0.1

70

aÿ

2.2

63

aÿ

0.1

02

aÿ

2.4

92

aÿ

0.1

13

aÿ

2.5

65

aÿ

0.1

15

a

b 03

ÿ7.1

54

aÿ

0.0

57

aÿ

7.7

04

aÿ

0.0

55

aÿ

7.5

63

aÿ

0.0

53

aÿ

3.9

09

aÿ

0.0

54

aÿ

4.6

47

aÿ

0.0

62

aÿ

4.5

72

aÿ

0.0

61

a

b 04

ÿ6.5

60

aÿ

0.0

38

aÿ

7.1

32

aÿ

0.0

43

aÿ

7.0

98

aÿ

0.0

45

aÿ

7.0

51

aÿ

0.0

28

bÿ

7.5

13

aÿ

0.0

28

bÿ

7.5

07

aÿ

0.0

21

b

b 11

(hit)

0.4

46

a0.0

73

a0

.357

a0.0

59

a0.3

52

a0.0

57

a0.3

53

a0.0

52

a0.2

84

a0.0

42

a0.2

43

a0.0

35

a

b 12

0.5

53

a0.0

24

a0

.427

a0.0

17

a0.4

45

a0.0

19

a0.6

54

a0.0

30

a0.5

23

a0.0

24

a0.5

04

a0.0

24

a

b 13

0.5

75

a0.0

04

a0

.475

a0.0

03

b0.5

00

a0.0

03

b0.8

52

a0.0

11

a0.6

29

a0.0

08

a0.6

56

a0.0

08

a

b 14

0.7

94

a0.0

04

a0

.670

a0.0

04

a0.6

47

a0.0

04

a0.7

96

a0.0

03

b0.6

45

a0.0

02

b0.7

77

a0.0

02

b

b 21

(eit)

1.0

82

a0.1

61

a0

.997

a0.1

49

a1.0

54

a0.1

57

aÿ

0.9

81

aÿ

0.1

49

aÿ

0.9

61

aÿ

0.1

47

aÿ

0.9

27

aÿ

0.1

42

a

b 22

2.1

56

a0.1

03

a2

.048

a0.0

94

a2.1

47

a0.0

99

aÿ

1.7

16

aÿ

0.0

79

aÿ

1.6

62

aÿ

0.0

76

aÿ

1.6

11

aÿ

0.0

74

a

b 23

2.2

98

a0.0

16

a2

.166

a0.0

14

a2.2

22

a0.0

14

aÿ

1.8

09

aÿ

0.0

23

aÿ

1.7

47

aÿ

0.0

21

aÿ

1.7

12

aÿ

0.0

21

a

b 24

2.7

20

a0.0

15

a2

.574

a0.0

15

a2.6

32

a0.0

16

aÿ

2.3

41

aÿ

0.0

08

aÿ

2.2

75

aÿ

0.0

08

bÿ

2.2

58

aÿ

0.0

06

b

b 31

(iit)

ÿ0.0

21

ÿ0.0

04

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.0

02

ÿ0.0

10

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.0

08

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

01

0.0

01

0.0

01

0.0

01

b 32

ÿ0.0

02

0.0

00

0.0

34

0.0

02

0.0

12

0.0

01

ÿ0.0

80

bÿ

0.0

04

bÿ

0.0

57

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.0

64

bÿ

0.0

04

b 33

0.1

60

a0.0

01

b0

.194

a0.0

01

b0.1

77

a0.0

01

bÿ

0.0

60

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

04

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

46

ÿ0.0

01

b 34

0.0

77

0.0

01

0.1

29

b0.0

01

0.1

17

b0.0

01

0.0

76

0.0

00

0.1

14

0.0

00

0.0

29

0.0

00

b 41(h

jt*)

0.0

55

0.0

08

0.2

43

a0.0

38

a0.5

00

a0.0

80

aÿ

0.0

52

ÿ0.0

08

0.0

62

0.0

08

0.3

33

a0.0

52

b

b 42

0.1

24

0.0

06

0.4

04

a0.0

18

a0.7

81

a0.0

34

aÿ

0.0

63

ÿ0.0

03

0.1

42

0.0

07

0.4

23

b0.0

18

b 43

0.1

90

b0.0

01

0.5

66

a0.0

04

b0.7

23

b0.0

04

ÿ0.1

85

ÿ0.0

03

0.2

41

0.0

03

0.8

79

a0.0

12

a

b 44

ÿ0.0

98

ÿ0.0

01

0.2

31

0.0

01

0.6

00

0.0

03

0.0

75

0.0

00

0.5

55

a0.0

02

b1.3

67

a0.0

04

b 51

(Yjt*

)0.1

57

b0.0

27

b0

.670

a0.0

98

b0.4

02

0.0

57

0.2

05

a0.0

29

b0.3

39

0.0

41

0.0

13

ÿ0.0

14

b 52

0.0

12

ÿ0.0

02

1.3

62

a0.0

62

a0.7

09

b0.0

31

0.4

05

a0.0

19

a0.9

50

a0.0

46

b0.8

42

a0.0

46

a

b 53

0.3

62

b0.0

03

1.8

84

a0.0

13

b1.9

89

a0.0

14

b0.6

73

a0.0

09

a1.7

28

a0.0

24

a0.7

28

0.0

10

b 54

0.8

89

a0.0

05

a2

.610

a0.0

16

b1.9

88

a0.0

13

b0.8

34

a0.0

03

b1.5

67

a0.0

06

1.4

43

a0.0

04

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ1895.4

5ÿ

1884.2

0ÿ

1885.9

8ÿ

1978.2

6ÿ

1976.4

5ÿ

1967.3

1P

seu

do

-R2

10.3

1%

10.8

5%

10.7

6%

7.5

0%

7.5

9%

8.0

2%

w2(h

jt*)

8.2

3(0

.08)

21.1

4(0

.00)

31.5

0(0

.00)

5.9

0(0

.21)

12.7

4(0

.01)

37.0

2(0

.00)

w2(Y

jt*)

38.2

5(0

.00)

46.5

9(0

.00)

29.5

7(0

.00)

34.1

6(0

.00)

24.9

7(0

.00)

13.8

8(0

.01)

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

742

Page 27: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mA

sia

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Eu

rop

eF

rom

Asi

aF

rom

US

Fro

mE

uro

pe

b 01

(co

nst

an

t)ÿ

2.3

57

aÿ

0.2

82

aÿ

2.1

41

aÿ

0.2

56

aÿ

2.5

07

aÿ

0.3

03

aÿ

1.8

22

aÿ

0.2

53

aÿ

1.3

87

aÿ

0.1

85

aÿ

1.9

48

aÿ

0.2

70

a

b 02

ÿ3.9

69

aÿ

0.1

15

aÿ

3.8

49

aÿ

0.1

13

aÿ

4.0

47

aÿ

0.1

24

aÿ

3.4

68

aÿ

0.1

05

aÿ

3.3

39

aÿ

0.1

06

aÿ

3.9

89

aÿ

0.1

27

a

b 03

ÿ6.0

52

aÿ

0.0

52

aÿ

6.0

94

aÿ

0.0

49

aÿ

6.4

18

aÿ

0.0

45

aÿ

5.6

85

aÿ

0.0

38

aÿ

5.3

38

aÿ

0.0

35

aÿ

5.5

93

aÿ

0.0

37

a

b 04

ÿ6.3

26

aÿ

0.0

36

aÿ

7.3

08

aÿ

0.0

25

bÿ

6.5

82

aÿ

0.0

31

aÿ

8.2

49

aÿ

0.0

17

ÿ7.7

56

aÿ

0.0

17

ÿ9.0

48

aÿ

0.0

16

b 11

(hit)

0.3

68

a0.0

47

a0.4

35

a0.0

55

a0.3

22

a0.0

41

a0.2

80

a0.0

40

a0.3

58

a0.0

52

a0.2

13

a0.0

30

a

b 12

0.3

59

a0.0

10

a0.4

44

a0.0

12

a0.3

24

a0.0

09

a0.5

30

a0.0

16

a0.5

46

a0.0

17

a0.3

70

a0.0

12

a

b 13

0.5

59

a0.0

05

a0.6

42

a0.0

05

a0.5

51

a0.0

04

a0.6

34

a0.0

04

a0.7

38

a0.0

05

a0.6

06

a0.0

04

a

b 14

0.5

48

a0.0

03

a0.6

49

a0.0

02

b0.5

67

a0.0

03

a0.7

22

a0.0

01

0.7

45

a0.0

02

0.5

62

a0.0

01

b 21

(eit)

1.1

44

a0.1

39

a1.0

86

a0.1

33

a1.1

65

a0.1

42

aÿ

0.1

71

ÿ0.0

14

ÿ0.1

92

ÿ0.0

17

ÿ0.1

11

ÿ0.0

05

b 22

1.9

09

a0.0

56

a1.8

78

a0.0

55

a1.9

16

a0.0

59

aÿ

1.4

95

aÿ

0.0

50

aÿ

1.4

60

aÿ

0.0

50

aÿ

1.4

02

aÿ

0.0

49

a

b 23

1.9

85

a0.0

16

a1.9

46

a0.0

15

a2.0

02

a0.0

13

aÿ

1.5

14

aÿ

0.0

10

bÿ

1.5

08

aÿ

0.0

10

bÿ

1.3

99

aÿ

0.0

10

b

b 24

2.1

21

a0.0

11

a2.1

23

a0.0

07

b2.1

28

a0.0

10

aÿ

1.7

47

aÿ

0.0

04

ÿ1.6

61

aÿ

0.0

04

ÿ1.6

85

aÿ

0.0

03

b 31

(iit)

0.0

12

0.0

02

0.0

04

0.0

00

0.0

17

0.0

02

0.0

10

0.0

02

ÿ0.0

05

ÿ0.0

01

0.0

15

0.0

02

b 32

0.0

11

0.0

00

0.0

06

0.0

00

0.0

13

0.0

00

0.0

10

0.0

00

0.0

03

0.0

00

0.0

27

0.0

01

b 33

0.0

26

0.0

00

0.0

30

0.0

00

0.0

36

0.0

00

0.0

22

0.0

00

0.0

06

0.0

00

0.0

22

0.0

00

b 34

0.0

04

0.0

00

0.0

38

0.0

00

0.0

07

0.0

00

0.0

84

b0.0

00

0.0

77

0.0

00

0.1

08

a0.0

00

b 41

(hjt*

)ÿ

0.1

17

bÿ

0.0

15

ÿ0.3

27

aÿ

0.0

42

a0.0

12

0.0

01

ÿ0.1

96

aÿ

0.0

27

aÿ

0.4

71

aÿ

0.0

70

a0.0

40

0.0

06

b 42

ÿ0.2

75

bÿ

0.0

08

ÿ0.3

67

bÿ

0.0

10

0.0

63

0.0

02

ÿ0.5

44

aÿ

0.0

17

aÿ

0.5

59

aÿ

0.0

16

b0.0

67

0.0

02

b 43

0.0

58

0.0

01

ÿ0.1

87

ÿ0.0

01

0.1

03

0.0

01

ÿ0.1

32

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.4

90

bÿ

0.0

03

ÿ0.3

49

ÿ0.0

03

b 44

0.1

61

0.0

01

ÿ0.0

44

0.0

00

0.4

17

0.0

02

ÿ0.3

33

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.4

80

ÿ0.0

01

0.6

62

0.0

01

b 51

(Yjt*

)0.1

01

0.0

10

0.8

35

a0.0

97

a0.9

30

a0.1

14

a0.2

55

a0.0

37

a0.8

24

a0.1

16

a0.7

56

a0.1

08

a

b 52

0.4

90

a0.0

15

a1.9

11

a0.0

57

a1.0

99

a0.0

32

b0.4

02

a0.0

12

b1.6

44

a0.0

52

a1.3

88

a0.0

44

a

b 53

0.2

80

0.0

02

2.3

52

a0.0

19

a2.6

13

a0.0

19

a0.0

70

0.0

00

1.1

24

0.0

06

1.2

05

0.0

07

b 54

0.5

13

a0.0

03

b3.8

99

a0.0

14

b2.7

57

a0.0

13

b0.8

48

a0.0

02

2.7

22

a0.0

06

2.1

45

a0.0

04

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ1555.1

8ÿ

1522.9

9ÿ

1541.1

9ÿ

1640.9

4ÿ

1637.0

0ÿ

1646.9

2P

seu

do

-R2

8.8

9%

10.7

8%

9.7

1%

6.0

5%

6.2

8%

5.7

1%

w2(h� jt)

11.6

9(0

.02)

13.6

9(0

.01)

1.8

1(0

.77)

24.4

5(0

.00)

30.1

7(0

.00)

4.9

4(0

.29)

w2(Y� jt)

25.2

9(0

.00)

92.7

6(0

.00)

63.1

7(0

.00)

29.9

8(0

.00)

37.1

0(0

.00)

27.8

8(0

.01)

US

Fro

mA

sia

Fro

mL

ati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mE

uro

pe

Fro

mA

sia

Fro

mL

ati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mE

uro

pe

b 1(c

on

stan

t)ÿ

5.8

42

aÿ

0.2

24

aÿ

6.5

77

aÿ

0.2

05

aÿ

5.9

11

aÿ

0.2

15

aÿ

5.1

50

aÿ

0.1

78

aÿ

5.4

53

aÿ

0.1

70

aÿ

5.0

59

aÿ

0.1

63

a

b 2(h

it)

0.3

70

a0.0

14

a0.4

37

a0.0

14

a0.1

70

0.0

06

0.8

84

a0.0

31

a1.0

43

a0.0

33

a0.9

30

a0.0

30

a

b 3(e

it)

0.4

22

0.0

16

0.3

14

0.0

10

0.5

30

b0.0

19

bÿ

0.6

11

bÿ

0.0

21

bÿ

0.5

91

bÿ

0.0

18

bÿ

0.7

45

aÿ

0.0

24

a

b 4(i

it)

0.4

55

a0.0

17

a0.5

58

a0.0

17

a0.4

51

a0.0

16

a0.2

19

0.0

08

0.2

47

b0.0

08

b0.1

99

0.0

06

b 4(h� jt)

0.0

20

0.0

01

ÿ0.1

77

ÿ0.0

06

0.3

47

0.0

13

ÿ0.0

05

0.0

00

ÿ0.2

04

bÿ

0.0

06

bÿ

0.2

58

ÿ0.0

08

b 4(Y� jt)

0.1

85

0.0

07

0.9

14

a0.0

28

a1.5

51

a0.0

57

a0.0

45

0.0

02

0.6

78

a0.0

21

a1.7

56

a0.0

56

a

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ423.0

1ÿ

381.0

0ÿ

409.5

5ÿ

393.8

7ÿ

378.2

8ÿ

378.5

0P

seu

do

-R2

6.5

7%

15.8

5%

9.5

4%

13.0

1%

16.4

5%

16.4

0%

w2(h� jt)

0.0

7(0

.79)

3.8

1(0

.05)

2.5

0(0

.11)

0.0

0(0

.97)

5.7

2(0

.02)

1.1

8(0

.28)

w2(Y� jt)

3.3

6(0

.07)

90.3

6(0

.00)

31.1

9(0

.00)

0.1

7(0

.68)

33.3

7(0

.00)

35.7

9(0

.00)

Measuring Financial Contagion

743

Page 28: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Table

5(c

onti

nu

ed)

Bo

tto

mta

ils

To

pta

ils

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Eu

rop

eF

rom

Asi

aF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Asi

aF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

Sb 1

(co

nst

an

t)ÿ

4.3

11

aÿ

0.1

33

aÿ

3.6

09

aÿ

0.1

21

aÿ

4.0

17

aÿ

0.1

29

aÿ

4.2

58

aÿ

0.1

28

aÿ

3.7

81

aÿ

0.1

20

aÿ

4.1

87

aÿ

0.1

31

a

b 2(h

it)

0.9

58

a0.0

30

a0.9

83

a0.0

33

a1.0

31

a0.0

33

a0.9

87

a0.0

30

a1.0

44

a0.0

33

a0.8

96

a0.0

28

a

b 3(e

it)

0.9

80

a0.0

30

a0.9

97

a0.0

33

a1.0

08

a0.0

32

aÿ

1.1

20

aÿ

0.0

34

aÿ

1.0

81

aÿ

0.0

34

aÿ

1.0

73

aÿ

0.0

34

a

b 4(i

it)

ÿ0.0

10

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

83

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.0

23

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

25

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

83

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.0

13

0.0

00

b 4(h

jt*)

ÿ0.0

07

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

70

ÿ0.0

02

ÿ0.0

42

ÿ0.0

01

0.0

67

0.0

02

0.0

35

0.0

01

0.2

51

0.0

08

b 4(Y

jt*)

0.6

24

a0.0

19

a0.5

27

a0.0

18

a1.9

44

a0.0

62

a0.4

64

a0.0

14

a0.3

63

a0.0

12

a1.0

51

a0.0

33

a

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ384.8

9ÿ

395.6

8ÿ

386.2

8ÿ

376.0

2ÿ

383.4

2ÿ

380.5

6P

seu

do

-R2

14.9

9%

12.6

1%

14.6

8%

16.9

5%

15.3

1%

15.9

5%

w2(h

jt*)

0.0

1(0

.92)

0.8

8(0

.35)

0.0

7(0

.79)

0.8

1(0

.37)

0.3

0(0

.58)

3.4

2(0

.06)

c2(Y

jt*)

45.4

0(0

.00)

27.3

6(0

.00)

52.6

6(0

.00)

21.8

5(0

.00)

9.2

4(0

.00)

11.1

4(0

.00)

Th

en

um

ber

of

coex

ceed

an

ces

of

dail

yre

turn

sis

mo

del

edas

an

ord

ered

po

lych

oto

mo

us

vari

ab

lean

des

tim

ate

du

sin

ga

mu

ltin

om

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nm

od

el.

Pj

isd

efin

edas

the

pro

bab

ilit

yth

at

agiv

end

ay

isass

oci

ate

dw

ith

jco

exce

edan

ces,

wh

ere

jeq

uals

0,

1,

2,

3,

4o

rm

ore

(fiv

eca

tego

ries

).T

he

mu

ltin

om

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nm

od

elis

giv

enb

yP

j�

exp

(x0 b

j)/[

1+P k

exp

(x0 b

k)]

,w

her

eb

isth

evec

tor

of

coef

fici

ents

,x

,th

evec

tor

of

ind

epen

den

tvari

ab

les,

an

dk

equ

als

1to

4.

Th

ep

rob

ab

ilit

yth

at

ther

eare

no

(co

-)ex

ceed

an

ces

equ

als

P0�

1/[

1+P k

�1

,4

exp

(x0 b

k)]

,w

hic

hre

pre

sen

tso

ur

ba

seca

se.

Th

ein

dep

end

ent

vari

ab

les,

x,

incl

ud

eth

ose

inT

ab

le3

plu

sth

en

um

ber

of

dail

yre

turn

coex

ceed

an

ces

fro

man

oth

erre

gio

n(Y

*)

an

da

mea

sure

of

con

dit

ion

al

vo

lati

lity

fro

man

oth

erre

gio

n(h

* j).

Th

eco

nd

itio

nal

vo

lati

lity

ises

tim

ate

das

EG

AR

CH

(1,1

)u

sin

gth

eIF

Cin

ves

tib

lere

gio

nal

ind

ex.

Part

ial

der

ivati

ves

of

pro

bab

ilit

ies

wit

hre

spec

tto

the

vec

tor

of

ind

epen

den

tvari

ab

les

are

com

pu

ted

at

the

mea

ns

of

xan

dare

rep

ort

edn

ext

toth

eco

effi

cien

tes

tim

ate

s.G

oo

dn

ess

of

fit

ism

easu

red

by

McF

ad

den

'sp

seu

do

-R2

equ

al

to1ÿ

(L!/L

),

wh

ere

L!

isth

eu

nre

stri

cted

lik

elih

oo

d,

an

dL

is

the

rest

rict

edli

kel

iho

od

[Mad

dala

(1983),

chap

.2)]

.T

he

logit

regre

ssio

nis

esti

mate

dse

para

tely

for

po

siti

ve

(to

p-t

ail

)an

dn

egati

ve

(bo

tto

m-t

ail

)co

exce

edan

ces.w2

(hjt*

)an

dw2

(Yjt*

)are

Wald

chi-

squ

are

test

sfo

rth

ere

stri

ctio

ns

that

b k1�

b k2�

b k3�

b k4�

0w

her

ek

is4

an

d5,

resp

ecti

vel

y,

wit

hp-v

alu

esin

pare

nth

eses

.

a,

bD

eno

tes

sign

ific

an

cele

vel

sat

the

1%

an

d5%

,re

spec

tivel

y.

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

744

Page 29: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

When we turn to contagion from the United States (models 2 and 5), wesee that the coefficients on the U.S. exceedance have significant coeffi-cients, and the effect on the probability is larger than the effect from LatinAmerica. In addition, the conditional volatility of the United States ishelpful to predict exceedances in Asia. Of interest is whether the UnitedStates had an extreme return seems more helpful in predicting the numberof negative extreme returns in Asia than the number of positive extremereturns, although the Wald statistics indicate that both are significant atthe 1% level. Finally, the results from adding European exceedances ascovariates (models 3 and 6) are weaker than those obtained from addingU.S. covariates for negative returns, but they are still statistically signifi-cant. Comparing the regressions of Table 5 for Asia with those of Table 4,we see that the pseudo-R2 is higher in all cases (though, of course, it is notadjusted for degrees of freedom). We also see that we cannot reject thehypothesis that the new coefficients on the conditional variances andon the number of exceedances are significantly different from zero, exceptthat the Latin American conditional volatility does not significantly affectthe number of positive exceedances in Asia.

The contagion tests for Latin America are presented in the secondpanel. Remember that Asian markets close before the markets in LatinAmerica open on the same day; as a result, we use same-day returns inmeasuring contagion from Asia to Latin America. For the negativeextreme returns, we find that Latin America has more negative extremereturns if Asia has more negative extreme returns, at least for two-countryand four-country-or-more coexceedances. The results for conditionalvolatility are mixed and possibly negative, which suggests that there maybe complex interaction effects among the conditional volatility processesof the different regions. The exceedance shocks from the United Statesand Europe have a larger and more consistent impact than those fromAsia. The effect of the conditional volatility from the United States is alsostrangely negative, though not from Europe. The pseudo-R2s of the LatinAmerican regressions increase more by adding covariates from anotherregion than the pseudo-R2s of Asia. For all the regressions, we cannotreject the hypothesis that the coefficients on the additional variables aresignificant.

Finally, we turn to the United States and Europe in the third and fourthpanels of Table 5. Asian extreme returns or conditional volatility havelittle effect on the probability of a negative extreme return for the UnitedStates and none on the probability of a positive extreme return for theUnited States. In contrast, extreme returns from Latin America and fromEurope have a significant effect. Since markets in Latin America are openwhen markets in the United States are open, a concern is that contagionfrom Latin America is really contagion indirectly from the UnitedStates itself. Finally, Europe's probability of negative extreme returns is

Measuring Financial Contagion

745

Page 30: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

significantly affected by extreme returns in all other regions. Again, how-ever, we have to be concerned about the interpretation of this result, sinceEuropean markets are open part of the time when U.S. and Latin Amer-ican markets are open.

The coexceedance response curve plots in Figure 2 for Asia show howthe conditional volatility and the number of extreme returns in LatinAmerica, the United States, and Europe affects the probability of extremereturns in Asia. The plots for Latin America are given in Figure 3. We cansee that the probability of exceedances in Asia increases as the conditionalvolatility of the Latin American returns increases and as the number ofexceedances in Latin America increases. However, the impact of anincrease in the number of Latin American exceedances on the probabilityof four or more exceedances in Asia never reaches 10%. The impact ofAsian exceedances on the probability of one or two exceedances in LatinAmerica (Figure 3) seems modest and the impact of Asian exceedances onthree and four or more exceedances in Latin America is weaker than theimpact of Latin American exceedances on the probability that Asia willhave three or four or more exeedances. Viewed from this perspective,contagion seems sharper from Latin America to Asia than from Asia toLatin America. Further, contagion affecting emerging markets is strongerthan contagion affecting developed countries. Similar plots (not reportedto save space) show that the United States is largely unaffected by coex-ceedances or conditional volatility from Asia. It is somewhat more dra-matically affected by coexceedances in Latin America, but as discussedearlier, the relation between exceedances in Latin America and an excee-dance in the United States is hard to interpret. Europe is more insulatedthan the United States from contagion in Latin America, but more sensi-tive to contagion from Asia than the United States.

3.2 Calibration, robustness tests, and alternative specifications

The returns among countries of the regions we consider are correlated asevidenced by Table 1. One would therefore expect that extreme returns inone region are more likely to be accompanied by extreme returns inanother region and that the coexceedance patterns are just another mani-festation of these correlations. To evaluate this hypothesis we extend thesimulation experiment in Section 1.3 to evaluate our multinomial logisticregression model results. In this experiment we perform Monte Carlosimulations of 2283 daily returns (corresponding to the April 1, 1992, toDecember 29, 2000, period) for each country in Asia and Latin Americausing 1000 replications of the historical mean vector and variance-covariance matrix and assumptions about the joint returns-generatingprocess. As before, we propose the multivariate normal, multivariateStudent's t (with five degrees of freedom), and the multivariate GARCH

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

746

Page 31: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

using the Ding and Engle (1994) specification. This time, however, thesimulation is for all 17 countries in both regions. For each replication wecount coexceedance events in both regions and estimate a simplifiedversion of the multinomial logistic regression model of Table 5. To pro-ceed with the experiments, we only examine whether the number of coex-ceedances in one region can be forecast with the number of coexceedancesin another region. We only perform the experiments for contagion fromLatin America to Asia and from Asia to Latin America.

From Latin America to Asia

Figure 2Coexceedance response curves of negative extreme returns in Asia to the conditional volatility andnumber of coexceedances of overseas market.

Measuring Financial Contagion

747

Page 32: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

The results are available from the authors. Basically we cannot explainthe coefficients on coexceedances from the other region for Asia or LatinAmerica. For the multivariate normal and Student's t scenarios, wecannot explain the magnitude of the bj coefficients associated with Y �jtcoexceedances for positive or negative extreme returns. The multivariateGARCH model has only moderate success delivering simulation p-valuesof at most 5% for top-tail exceedances and 16% for the bottom tails. The

From Latin America to Asia

Figure 2Continued

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

748

Page 33: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

pseudo-R2 statistics in the simulations reach values as large as in the actualdata in at most 1% of the replications. For Latin America, in particular,the highest simulation p-value for any coexceedance coefficient is 3% forthe top tail in the multivariate GARCH scenario and 23% in the bottomtail also for the multivariate GARCH scenario. Perhaps even more strik-ing for Latin America, the pseudo-R2 is at least four times higher in thedata than it is in any of the simulations.

Figure 3Coexceedance response curves of negative extreme returns in Latin America to the conditional volatilityand number of coexceedances of overseas market

Measuring Financial Contagion

749

Page 34: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

We consider a battery of robustness checks. We reestimated our multi-nomial logistic regressions with Monday dummies. These dummies areinsignificant. We also reestimated the models of Table 5 using localcurrency returns. The results are virtually unchanged, except that thepseudo-R2 are lower in Asia and Latin America. In Table 6 we reportour contagion tests using lagged conditioning variables. Though it is anin-sample experiment, it allows us to investigate further the predictabilityof contagion. We see immediately that the pseudo-R2 falls. However, the

Figure 3Continued

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

750

Page 35: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

significance of yesterday's coexceedances from the other regions is not lessthan the significance of same day coexceedances. The table providesevidence that contagion across regions is predictable and that the numberof coexceedances of another region provides useful information in pre-dicting contagion.

A concern we have expressed is that contagion is just the outcome ofhigh volatility. We investigated this concern in a preliminary way with ourMonte Carlo simulations using multivariate GARCH scenarios. Anotherapproach to investigate this concern is to define exceedances differentlyfrom how we have defined them so far. With the exceedances defined interms of the sample period returns, we necessarily have an outcome wherewe have more exceedances in periods of higher conditional volatility.Alternatively we can define exceedances using conditional volatility itself,so that the probability of observing an exceedance is always the same(assuming multivariate normality for returns and a constant conditionalmean). In Table 7 we define positive extreme returns to be those thatexceed 1.65 times the conditional volatility and negative extreme returnsthose that are below ÿ 1.65 times the conditional volatility. The mainimpact of defining extreme returns this way is that a region's conditionalvolatility is no longer useful in predicting that region's coexceedances.However, coexceedances in one region still provide useful information inpredicting coexceedances in another region. For instance, the number ofcoexceedances in Latin America helps explain the number of coexcee-dances in Asia. Surprisingly, with this definition of exceedances, interestrates are no longer useful to predict exceedances, but exchange ratechanges still are.

We use two more definitions of exceedances. We reestimate (notreported) the base model regression, but use exceedances computed overthree days instead of over one day as regressors. That is, a coexceedanceevent is defined as one in which more than one market experiences anextreme return within a moving three-day window. The objective of thisrobustness check is to assess in a rough way the nature of the dynamics incoexceedances within a region. Overall, the results are similar to those ofthe base case in Table 5 for Asia, but weaker for Latin America.18 Finally,we define exceedances by the 2.5% quantile rather than the 5% quantile.Proceeding this way, we have fewer exceedances. The results (again, notreported) reveal a similar pattern in coefficients, partial derivatives ofprobabilities relative to covariates, and coexceedance responses to Table 5,but inference tests lose power.

18 Another possible concern that we do not investigate with the alternative specifications using multidayhorizons and lagged covariates is with nonstationarity of the explanatory variables. Park and Phillips(2000) demonstrate the complications in the limiting distributions for binary choice models with expla-natory variables generated as integrated processes. The potential impact on multinomial logit models isan open question, however. We thank Richard Roll and our referee for pointing this out.

Measuring Financial Contagion

751

Page 36: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Table

6C

onta

gio

nte

stre

sult

sof

mult

inom

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nfo

rdail

yre

turn

coex

ceed

ance

sof

emer

gin

gm

ark

etin

dic

esusi

ng

lagged

condit

ionin

gva

riable

s,A

pri

l1,

1992,

toD

ecem

ber

29,

2000

Bo

tto

mta

ils

To

pta

ils

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Asi

aF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Eu

rop

eF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Eu

rop

eb 0

1(c

on

stan

t)ÿ

1.2

41

aÿ

0.1

53

aÿ

1.4

91

aÿ

0.1

92

aÿ

1.5

18

aÿ

0.1

98

aÿ

1.1

71

aÿ

0.1

57

aÿ

1.2

43

aÿ

0.1

65

aÿ

1.3

90

aÿ

0.1

94

a

b 02

ÿ3.0

08

aÿ

0.1

51

aÿ

3.5

66

aÿ

0.1

73

aÿ

3.4

39

aÿ

0.1

67

aÿ

2.3

37

aÿ

0.1

08

aÿ

2.5

69

aÿ

0.1

20

aÿ

2.6

46

aÿ

0.1

22

a

b 03

ÿ7.2

66

aÿ

0.0

58

aÿ

7.9

37

aÿ

0.0

56

aÿ

7.6

28

aÿ

0.0

54

aÿ

4.0

29

aÿ

0.0

59

aÿ

4.7

23

aÿ

0.0

67

aÿ

4.7

37

aÿ

0.0

66

a

b 04

ÿ6.4

27

aÿ

0.0

50

aÿ

7.1

39

aÿ

0.0

55

aÿ

6.9

67

aÿ

0.0

56

aÿ

6.9

77

aÿ

0.0

35

bÿ

7.2

89

aÿ

0.0

35

bÿ

7.4

93

aÿ

0.0

26

b

b 11

(hit)

0.4

04

a0.0

63

a0

.312

a0.0

49

a0.3

07

a0.0

48

a0.3

15

a0.0

45

a0.2

50

a0.0

36

a0.2

09

a0.0

29

a

b 12

0.5

31

a0.0

25

a0

.408

a0.0

18

a0.4

31

a0.0

20

a0.6

00

a0.0

28

a0.4

75

a0.0

22

a0.4

56

a0.0

22

a

b 13

0.4

57

a0.0

03

b0

.349

a0.0

02

0.3

92

a0.0

02

b0.8

05

a0.0

11

a0.5

98

a0.0

08

a0.6

13

a0.0

08

a

b 14

0.7

04

a0.0

05

a0

.571

a0.0

04

a0.5

63

a0.0

04

a0.7

94

a0.0

04

a0.6

65

a0.0

03

b0.7

72

a0.0

03

b

b 21

(eitÿ

1)

0.2

46

0.0

36

0.2

37

0.0

35

0.2

52

0.0

37

ÿ0.4

10

aÿ

0.0

60

bÿ

0.3

88

aÿ

0.0

57

bÿ

0.3

41

bÿ

0.0

50

b

b 22

0.3

52

0.0

16

0.3

46

0.0

15

0.3

62

b0.0

16

ÿ0.8

75

aÿ

0.0

43

aÿ

0.8

61

aÿ

0.0

42

aÿ

0.7

73

aÿ

0.0

38

a

b 23

0.9

39

a0.0

07

a0

.948

a0.0

07

a0.9

37

a0.0

07

aÿ

0.5

75

bÿ

0.0

07

ÿ0.5

31

bÿ

0.0

06

ÿ0.4

32

ÿ0.0

05

b 24

0.8

22

a0.0

06

a0

.854

a0.0

06

a0.8

76

a0.0

07

aÿ

0.8

01

aÿ

0.0

03

bÿ

0.7

70

aÿ

0.0

03

bÿ

0.6

72

aÿ

0.0

02

b 31

(iitÿ

1)

ÿ0.0

33

ÿ0.0

07

ÿ0.0

12

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.0

21

ÿ0.0

05

ÿ0.0

15

ÿ0.0

02

ÿ0.0

08

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

06

0.0

00

b 32

ÿ0.0

07

0.0

00

0.0

28

0.0

02

0.0

04

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

71

bÿ

0.0

04

bÿ

0.0

48

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.0

55

ÿ0.0

03

b 33

0.1

87

a0.0

02

b0

.226

a0.0

02

b0.1

98

a0.0

02

bÿ

0.0

44

ÿ0.0

01

0.0

05

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

29

0.0

00

b 34

0.1

14

b0.0

01

0.1

68

a0.0

01

b0.1

49

a0.0

01

b0.0

86

0.0

01

0.1

13

0.0

01

0.0

48

0.0

00

b 41

(h� jt)

0.0

45

0.0

07

0.2

48

a0.0

38

a0.5

03

a0.0

79

aÿ

0.0

42

ÿ0.0

07

0.0

68

0.0

08

0.3

56

a0.0

55

b

b 42

0.0

92

0.0

05

0.3

79

a0.0

17

a0.6

91

a0.0

32

aÿ

0.0

49

ÿ0.0

02

0.1

60

0.0

08

0.4

65

a0.0

20

b

b 43

0.1

94

b0.0

02

0.6

05

a0.0

04

b0.6

97

b0.0

04

ÿ0.1

75

ÿ0.0

03

0.2

65

0.0

04

0.9

25

a0.0

13

a

b 44

ÿ0.1

65

ÿ0.0

02

0.2

02

0.0

01

0.4

28

0.0

02

0.0

78

0.0

01

0.5

34

a0.0

03

b1.3

38

a0.0

05

b

b 51

(Y� jt)

0.1

58

b0.0

27

b0

.720

a0.1

02

b0.4

25

0.0

58

0.2

18

a0.0

31

b0.3

70

0.0

45

ÿ0.0

10

ÿ0.0

18

b 52

ÿ0.0

14

ÿ0.0

04

1.4

30

a0.0

68

a0.7

47

b0.0

34

0.4

15

a0.0

19

a1.0

46

a0.0

51

a0.7

94

b0.0

44

b

b 53

0.3

00

0.0

02

1.9

81

a0.0

13

b2.0

28

a0.0

14

b0.6

89

a0.0

10

a1.7

70

a0.0

25

a0.7

11

0.0

10

b 54

0.8

42

a0.0

07

a2

.624

a0.0

20

a2.0

95

a0.0

17

a0.8

29

a0.0

04

b1.4

70

a0.0

07

1.4

95

a0.0

05

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ1959.8

0ÿ

1942.9

9ÿ

1946.7

7ÿ

2015.9

8ÿ

2013.6

9ÿ

2003.6

3P

seu

do

-R2

7.7

1%

8.5

0%

8.3

2%

5.7

4%

5.8

5%

6.3

2%

w2(h� jt)

8.5

5(0

.07)

22.9

0(0

.00)

28.7

6(0

.00)

5.0

4(0

.28)

13.5

7(0

.01)

41.2

6(0

.00)

w2(Y� jt)

36.0

1(0

.00)

52.3

2(0

.00)

35.7

1(0

.00)

37.5

7(0

.00)

28.1

5(0

.00)

15.3

6(0

.00)

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

752

Page 37: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mA

sia

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Eu

rop

eF

rom

Asi

aF

rom

US

Fro

mE

uro

pe

b 01

(co

nst

an

t)ÿ

2.2

63

aÿ

0.2

66

aÿ

1.9

99

aÿ

0.2

35

aÿ

2.4

11

aÿ

0.2

86

aÿ

1.8

38

aÿ

0.2

48

aÿ

1.4

07

aÿ

0.1

81

aÿ

1.9

65

aÿ

0.2

65

a

b 02

ÿ3.5

18

aÿ

0.1

13

aÿ

3.1

91

aÿ

0.1

03

aÿ

3.5

66

aÿ

0.1

22

aÿ

3.8

37

aÿ

0.1

29

aÿ

3.8

03

aÿ

0.1

33

aÿ

4.3

67

aÿ

0.1

51

a

b 03

ÿ5.5

84

aÿ

0.0

57

aÿ

5.4

77

aÿ

0.0

52

aÿ

5.8

93

aÿ

0.0

49

aÿ

5.5

20

aÿ

0.0

41

aÿ

5.1

56

aÿ

0.0

37

aÿ

5.4

25

aÿ

0.0

39

a

b 04

ÿ5.9

02

aÿ

0.0

41

aÿ

6.7

79

aÿ

0.0

30

bÿ

6.1

03

aÿ

0.0

36

aÿ

8.5

61

aÿ

0.0

19

ÿ8.1

44

aÿ

0.0

18

ÿ9.2

05

aÿ

0.0

17

b 11

(hit)

0.3

67

a0.0

45

a0.4

42

a0.0

55

a0.3

19

a0.0

39

a0.2

66

a0.0

37

a0.3

43

a0.0

49

a0.1

98

a0.0

28

a

b 12

0.3

86

a0.0

12

a0.4

92

a0.0

15

a0.3

45

a0.0

11

a0.4

45

a0.0

15

a0.4

44

a0.0

14

a0.2

97

a0.0

10

a

b 13

0.5

69

a0.0

06

a0.6

71

a0.0

06

a0.5

62

a0.0

05

a0.6

17

a0.0

04

a0.7

33

a0.0

05

a0.6

02

a0.0

04

a

b 14

0.5

52

a0.0

04

a0.6

57

a0.0

03

b0.5

72

a0.0

03

a0.6

82

a0.0

01

0.7

06

a0.0

01

0.5

42

a0.0

01

b 21

(eitÿ

1)

0.3

17

b0.0

40

b0.2

94

b0.0

37

b0.3

55

a0.0

45

a0.1

59

0.0

24

0.0

96

0.0

14

0.1

92

0.0

29

b 22

0.3

03

0.0

09

0.3

03

0.0

09

0.3

63

0.0

12

0.2

83

0.0

10

0.2

84

0.0

10

0.3

74

b0.0

13

b

b 23

0.2

71

0.0

02

0.2

52

0.0

02

0.3

08

0.0

02

ÿ0.3

43

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.4

61

ÿ0.0

04

ÿ0.3

56

ÿ0.0

03

b 24

0.3

18

0.0

02

0.4

07

0.0

02

0.3

76

0.0

02

ÿ0.8

08

ÿ0.0

02

ÿ1.0

46

bÿ

0.0

03

ÿ0.9

51

ÿ0.0

02

b 31

(iitÿ

1)

0.0

12

0.0

02

0.0

01

0.0

00

0.0

17

0.0

02

0.0

10

0.0

01

ÿ0.0

05

ÿ0.0

01

0.0

14

0.0

02

b 32

0.0

04

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

10

0.0

00

0.0

05

0.0

00

0.0

30

0.0

01

0.0

27

0.0

01

0.0

46

a0.0

02

b

b 33

0.0

22

0.0

00

0.0

18

0.0

00

0.0

30

0.0

00

0.0

15

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

02

0.0

00

0.0

16

0.0

00

b 34

0.0

06

0.0

00

0.0

36

0.0

00

0.0

08

0.0

00

0.1

01

a0.0

00

0.0

94

b0.0

00

0.1

17

a0.0

00

b 41

(h� jt)

ÿ0.1

28

bÿ

0.0

15

ÿ0.3

72

aÿ

0.0

46

aÿ

0.0

07

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.1

87

aÿ

0.0

26

aÿ

0.4

53

aÿ

0.0

67

a0.0

62

0.0

09

b 42

ÿ0.3

51

aÿ

0.0

12

bÿ

0.5

56

aÿ

0.0

18

bÿ

0.0

74

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.4

54

aÿ

0.0

16

aÿ

0.4

18

aÿ

0.0

12

0.1

63

0.0

06

b 43

ÿ0.0

10

0.0

00

ÿ0.3

11

ÿ0.0

02

ÿ0.0

31

0.0

00

ÿ0.1

33

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.5

16

bÿ

0.0

03

ÿ0.4

20

ÿ0.0

04

b 44

0.0

93

0.0

01

ÿ0.1

29

0.0

00

0.2

65

0.0

02

ÿ0.2

67

0.0

00

ÿ0.4

00

ÿ0.0

01

0.6

47

0.0

01

b 51

(Y� jt)

0.1

04

0.0

10

0.8

48

a0.0

96

a0.9

83

a0.1

18

a0.2

57

a0.0

37

a0.8

45

a0.1

17

a0.7

68

a0.1

07

a

b 52

0.4

77

a0.0

17

a1.8

34

a0.0

62

a1.1

34

a0.0

37

b0.3

97

a0.0

13

b1.7

65

a0.0

61

a1.5

21

a0.0

52

a

b 53

0.2

78

0.0

03

2.2

55

a0.0

21

a2.6

33

a0.0

22

a0.0

48

0.0

00

1.1

88

0.0

07

1.2

42

0.0

08

b 54

0.5

15

a0.0

04

b3.7

74

a0.0

17

b2.7

77

a0.0

17

a0.8

37

a0.0

02

2.9

60

a0.0

06

2.3

53

a0.0

04

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ1610.6

9ÿ

1575.6

6ÿ

1595.4

7ÿ

1658.1

6ÿ

1651.7

2ÿ

1658.9

6P

seu

do

-R2

5.5

4%

7.5

9%

6.4

3%

5.1

4%

5.5

1%

5.0

9%

w2(h� jt)

12.7

1(0

.01)

20.6

9(0

.00)

0.9

6(0

.92)

20.6

3(0

.00)

9.1

9(0

.06)

19.7

0(0

.00)

w2(Y� jt)

26.0

3(0

.00)

94.3

1(0

.00)

69.5

5(0

.00)

29.9

5(0

.00)

42.5

9(0

.00)

33.1

7(0

.01)

US

Fro

mA

sia

Fro

mL

ati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mE

uro

pe

Fro

mA

sia

Fro

mL

ati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mE

uro

pe

b 1(c

on

stan

t)ÿ

5.5

10

aÿ

0.2

16

aÿ

6.3

17

aÿ

0.2

02

aÿ

5.6

20

aÿ

0.2

10

aÿ

5.1

08

aÿ

0.1

80

aÿ

5.4

51

aÿ

0.1

73

aÿ

5.0

43

aÿ

0.1

67

a

b 2(h

it)

0.4

26

a0.0

17

a0.4

61

a0.0

15

a0.2

40

0.0

09

0.8

68

a0.0

31

a1.0

31

a0.0

33

a0.8

87

a0.0

29

a

b 3(e

itÿ

1)

ÿ0.3

00

ÿ0.0

12

ÿ0.2

47

ÿ0.0

08

ÿ0.2

49

ÿ0.0

09

ÿ0.3

46

ÿ0.0

12

ÿ0.4

14

ÿ0.0

13

ÿ0.3

17

ÿ0.0

11

b 4(i

itÿ

1)

0.3

83

a0.0

15

a0.5

01

a0.0

16

a0.3

85

a0.0

14

a0.2

17

0.0

08

0.2

49

b0.0

08

b0.2

05

0.0

07

b 4(h� jt)

0.0

17

0.0

01

ÿ0.1

61

ÿ0.0

05

0.3

53

0.0

13

0.0

03

0.0

00

ÿ0.1

97

bÿ

0.0

06

bÿ

0.2

09

ÿ0.0

07

b 4(Y� jt)

0.1

83

0.0

07

0.9

12

a0.0

29

a1.4

42

a0.0

54

a0.0

43

0.0

01

0.6

95

a0.0

22

a1.5

83

a0.0

52

a

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ425.5

6ÿ

383.0

3ÿ

413.2

7ÿ

396.0

8ÿ

379.7

3ÿ

382.4

5P

seu

do

-R2

6.0

0%

15.3

9%

8.7

1%

12.5

1%

16.1

2%

15.5

2%

w2(h� jt)

0.0

5(0

.92)

3.1

9(0

.07)

2.6

4(0

.10)

0.0

0(0

.99)

5.5

3(0

.02(

0.8

1(0

.37)

w2(Y� jt)

3.3

1(0

.00)

91.1

7(0

.00)

28.6

3(0

.00)

0.1

5(0

.69)

34.7

6(0

.00)

32.0

8(0

.01)

Measuring Financial Contagion

753

Page 38: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Table

6(c

onti

nued

)

Bo

tto

mta

ils

To

pta

ils

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Eu

rop

eF

rom

Asi

aF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Asi

aF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

Sb 1

(co

nst

an

t)ÿ

4.2

01

aÿ

0.1

53

aÿ

3.5

46

aÿ

0.1

39

aÿ

3.9

44

aÿ

0.1

49

aÿ

4.2

37

aÿ

0.1

54

aÿ

3.8

41

aÿ

0.1

45

aÿ

4.2

28

aÿ

0.1

57

a

b 2(h

it)

0.9

31

a0.0

34

a0.9

72

a0.0

38

a1.0

00

a0.0

38

a1.0

34

a0.0

38

a1.0

75

a0.0

41

a0.9

19

a0.0

34

a

b 3(e

itÿ

1)

0.0

41

0.0

01

0.1

08

0.0

04

0.1

23

0.0

05

0.2

83

0.0

10

0.2

86

0.0

11

0.2

96

0.0

11

b

b 4(i

it1)

0.0

11

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

56

ÿ0.0

02

0.0

02

0.0

00

0.0

01

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

51

ÿ0.0

02

0.0

15

0.0

01

b 4(h

jt*)

ÿ0.0

14

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

76

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.0

40

ÿ0.0

01

0.0

90

0.0

03

0.0

68

0.0

03

0.2

97

b0.0

11

b

b 4(Y

*jt)

0.5

80

a0.0

21

a0.4

66

a0.0

18

a1.7

77

a0.0

67

a0.3

83

a0.0

14

a0.2

83

b0.0

11

b0.8

04

a0.0

30

a

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ405.3

2ÿ

415.9

5ÿ

407.1

2ÿ

400.7

5ÿ

406.6

7ÿ

403.7

0P

seu

do

-R2

10.4

7%

8.1

2%

10.0

7%

11.4

8%

10.1

7%

10.8

3%

w2(h

jt*)

0.0

3(0

.86)

0.9

8(0

.320

0.0

7(0

.79)

1.5

4(0

.21)

1.3

0(0

.25)

5.1

1(0

.02)

w2(Y

jt*)

40.9

6(0

.00)

22.6

5(0

.00)

45.8

0(0

.00)

16.0

4(0

.00)

5.8

0(0

.02)

6.7

7(0

.01)

Th

en

um

ber

of

coex

ceed

an

ces

of

dail

yre

turn

sis

mo

del

edas

an

ord

ered

po

lych

oto

mo

us

vari

ab

lean

des

tim

ate

du

sin

ga

mu

ltin

om

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nm

od

el.

Pj

isd

efin

edas

the

pro

bab

ilit

yth

at

agiv

end

ay

isass

oci

ate

dw

ith

jco

exce

edan

ces,

wh

ere

jeq

uals

0,

1,

2,

3,

4o

rm

ore

(fiv

eca

tego

ries

).T

he

mu

ltin

om

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nm

od

elis

giv

enb

yP

j�

exp

(x0 b

j)/[

1+

�kex

p(x0 b

k)]

,w

her

eb

isth

evec

tor

of

coef

fici

ents

,x

isth

evec

tor

of

ind

epen

den

tvari

ab

les,

an

dk

equ

als

1to

4.

Th

ep

rob

ab

ilit

yth

at

ther

eare

no

(co

-)ex

ceed

an

ces

equ

als

P0�

1/[

1+

�kex

p(x0 b

k)]

wh

ere

keq

uals

1to

4,w

hic

hre

pre

sen

tso

ur

base

case

.T

he

ind

epen

den

tvari

ab

les,

x,in

clu

de

the

inte

rcep

t,co

nd

itio

nal

vo

lati

lity

of

regio

nal

ind

exat

tim

et

(ht)

,th

ela

gged

aver

age

exch

an

ge

rate

(per

$U

S)

chan

ges

inth

ere

gio

n(e

tÿ

1),

the

lagged

aver

age

inte

rest

rate

level

inth

ere

gio

n(i

tÿ

1),

the

nu

mb

ero

fd

ail

yre

turn

co-

exce

eda

nce

sfr

om

an

oth

erre

gio

n(Y

* j),

an

da

mea

sure

of

con

dit

ion

al

vo

lati

lity

fro

man

oth

erre

gio

n(h

* j).

Th

eco

nd

itio

nal

vo

lati

lity

ises

tim

ate

das

EG

AR

CH

(1,1

)u

sin

gth

eIF

Cin

ves

tib

lere

gio

nal

ind

ex.

Fo

rth

eco

nta

gio

nte

stfr

om

Lati

n,

US

,an

dE

uro

pe

toA

sia,

lagged

h* j

an

dY

* jare

use

dto

ad

just

for

the

no

nsy

nch

ron

ou

str

ad

ing.

Part

ial

der

ivati

ves

of

pro

bab

ilit

ies

wit

hre

spec

tto

the

vec

tor

of

ind

epen

den

tvari

ab

les

are

com

pu

ted

at

the

mea

ns

of

xan

dare

rep

ort

edn

ext

toth

eco

effi

cien

tes

tim

ate

s.G

oo

dn

ess-

of-

fit

ism

easu

red

by

McF

ad

den

'sp

seu

do

-R2

equ

al

to1ÿ

(L!/L

),

wh

ere

L!

isth

eu

nre

stri

cted

lik

elih

oo

d,

an

dL

is

the

rest

rict

edli

kel

iho

od

[Mad

dala

(1983,

chap

.2)]

.T

he

logit

regre

ssio

nis

esti

mate

dse

para

tely

for

po

siti

ve

(to

p-t

ail

)an

dn

egati

ve

(bo

tto

m-t

ail

)co

exce

edan

ces.w2

(hjt*

)an

dw2

(Yjt*

)are

Wald

chi-

squ

are

test

sfo

rth

ere

stri

ctio

ns

thatb k

1�b k

2�b k

3�b k

4�

0,w

her

ek

is4

an

d5,

resp

ecti

vel

y,

wit

hp

-valu

esin

pare

nth

eses

.

19

a,

bD

eno

tes

sign

ific

an

cele

vel

sat

the

1%

an

d5%

,re

spec

tivel

y.

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

754

Page 39: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Table

7C

onta

gio

nte

stre

sult

sof

mult

inom

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nfo

rdail

yre

turn

coex

ceed

ance

sfr

om

condit

ional

extr

eme

retu

rns,

Apri

l1,

1992

toD

ecem

ber

29,

2000

Bo

tto

mta

ils

To

pta

ils

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Asi

aF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Eu

rop

eF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Eu

rop

eb 0

1(c

on

stan

t)ÿ

1.3

12

aÿ

0.1

79

aÿ

1.4

63

aÿ

0.2

05

aÿ

1.3

93

aÿ

0.1

92

aÿ

0.9

92

aÿ

0.1

48

aÿ

0.9

76

aÿ

0.1

45

aÿ

1.1

10

aÿ

0.1

65

a

b 02

ÿ2.9

12

aÿ

0.1

14

aÿ

2.8

62

aÿ

0.1

11

aÿ

2.7

38

aÿ

0.1

06

aÿ

1.5

07

aÿ

0.0

59

aÿ

1.4

40

aÿ

0.0

57

aÿ

1.7

60

aÿ

0.0

72

a

b 03

ÿ6.3

93

aÿ

0.0

33

aÿ

6.5

15

aÿ

0.0

35

bÿ

6.6

36

aÿ

0.0

37

aÿ

4.5

97

aÿ

0.0

53

aÿ

5.0

17

aÿ

0.0

52

aÿ

4.7

28

aÿ

0.0

51

a

b 04

ÿ4.9

61

aÿ

0.0

20

bÿ

4.7

75

aÿ

0.0

17

bÿ

5.2

95

aÿ

0.0

22

bÿ

4.4

90

aÿ

0.0

15

bÿ

4.2

30

aÿ

0.0

17

bÿ

4.4

23

aÿ

0.0

20

b

b 11

(hit)

ÿ0.0

25

ÿ0.0

04

ÿ0.0

75

ÿ0.0

14

ÿ0.0

42

ÿ0.0

08

ÿ0.0

99

ÿ0.0

17

ÿ0.1

03

ÿ0.0

17

ÿ0.1

49

aÿ

0.0

24

b

b 12

0.0

33

0.0

02

0.0

73

0.0

04

0.0

97

0.0

05

ÿ0.1

24

ÿ0.0

05

ÿ0.1

47

ÿ0.0

06

ÿ0.2

72

bÿ

0.0

12

b 13

ÿ0.1

97

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

82

0.0

00

ÿ0.1

54

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.1

09

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.2

61

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.1

66

ÿ0.0

01

b 14

0.2

15

0.0

01

0.3

52

0.0

01

0.1

95

0.0

01

0.4

59

b0.0

02

0.3

74

b0.0

02

0.3

25

0.0

02

b 21

(eit)

0.7

88

a0.1

15

a0

.781

a0.1

14

a0.7

80

a0.1

14

aÿ

0.4

01

aÿ

0.0

54

ÿ0.4

01

aÿ

0.0

53

ÿ0.3

94

aÿ

0.0

51

b 22

1.3

96

a0.0

53

a1

.318

a0.0

50

a1.3

07

a0.0

50

aÿ

1.2

12

aÿ

0.0

55

aÿ

1.2

52

aÿ

0.0

59

aÿ

1.2

45

aÿ

0.0

58

a

b 23

1.7

96

a0.0

09

a1

.746

a0.0

09

a1.7

43

a0.0

09

aÿ

1.2

79

aÿ

0.0

14

aÿ

1.3

67

aÿ

0.0

13

aÿ

1.3

29

aÿ

0.0

14

a

b 24

1.6

43

a0.0

06

b1

.678

a0.0

06

b1.5

91

a0.0

06

bÿ

1.4

28

aÿ

0.0

04

bÿ

1.5

13

aÿ

0.0

06

bÿ

1.4

52

aÿ

0.0

06

b

b 31

(iit)

ÿ0.0

04

0.0

00

0.0

09

0.0

01

0.0

02

0.0

00

0.0

16

0.0

04

0.0

13

0.0

03

0.0

19

0.0

04

b 32

ÿ0.0

18

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

13

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

17

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

62

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.0

71

ÿ0.0

04

ÿ0.0

54

ÿ0.0

03

b 33

0.1

08

0.0

01

0.1

23

0.0

01

0.1

21

0.0

01

0.0

44

0.0

01

0.0

71

0.0

01

0.0

42

0.0

00

b 34

ÿ0.0

64

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

69

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

20

0.0

00

ÿ0.1

23

0.0

00

ÿ0.1

17

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.1

17

ÿ0.0

01

b 41

(hjt*

)0.0

61

0.0

08

0.2

11

a0.0

34

a0.1

97

0.0

32

ÿ0.0

64

ÿ0.0

09

ÿ0.0

71

ÿ0.0

12

0.1

13

0.0

15

b 42

0.1

69

a0.0

07

b0

.120

0.0

03

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

02

ÿ0.2

25

bÿ

0.0

11

ÿ0.1

74

ÿ0.0

08

0.2

43

0.0

11

b 43

0.2

06

0.0

01

0.3

52

0.0

02

0.8

01

b0.0

04

0.1

19

0.0

02

0.4

60

b0.0

05

b0.5

83

b0.0

06

b 44

0.0

19

0.0

00

ÿ0.2

51

ÿ0.0

01

0.1

28

0.0

00

ÿ0.1

67

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

60

0.0

00

0.6

07

0.0

03

b 51

(Yjt*

)0.1

43

0.0

21

0.3

63

0.0

47

0.6

80

a0.1

01

a0.1

51

b0.0

21

0.6

78

a0.1

09

a0.2

55

0.0

44

b 52

0.1

31

0.0

04

0.8

94

b0.0

35

b0.8

09

b0.0

29

0.4

13

a0.0

18

a0.7

88

b0.0

30

ÿ0.0

65

ÿ0.0

08

b 53

0.8

31

a0.0

04

b2

.210

a0.0

12

b1.9

65

a0.0

10

b0.3

82

0.0

04

1.8

64

a0.0

18

b1.3

05

a0.0

15

b

b 54

0.8

63

a0.0

04

b2

.590

a0.0

10

b2.2

38

a0.0

09

b1.1

27

a0.0

04

b2.5

78

a0.0

10

b0.9

34

0.0

04

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ1744.3

3ÿ

1744.5

2ÿ

1747.4

1ÿ

1960.7

3ÿ

1963.5

5ÿ

1976.0

9P

seu

do

-r2

3.7

8%

3.7

7%

3.6

1%

2.8

5%

2.7

1%

2.0

8%

w2(h

jt*)

9.3

3(0

.05)

9.1

0(0

.06)

7.6

3(0

.11)

8.6

4(0

.07)

8.9

9(0

.06)

7.9

7(0

.09)

w2(Y

jt*)

33.9

3(0

.00)

37

.32

(0.0

0)

29.6

2(0

.00)

41.3

7(0

.00)

36.8

9(0

.00)

8.5

5(0

.07)

Measuring Financial Contagion

755

Page 40: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Table

7(c

onti

nued

)

Bo

tto

mta

ils

To

pta

ils

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Co

eff.

�p

rob

.C

oef

f.�

pro

b.

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mA

sia

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Eu

rop

eF

rom

Asi

aF

rom

US

Fro

mE

uro

pe

b 01

(co

nst

an

t)ÿ

1.9

75

aÿ

0.2

43

aÿ

1.9

07

aÿ

0.2

36

aÿ

2.0

63

aÿ

0.2

58

aÿ

1.2

61

aÿ

0.1

54

aÿ

0.9

69

aÿ

0.1

14

aÿ

1.2

65

aÿ

0.1

54

a

b 02

ÿ4.2

25

aÿ

0.0

90

aÿ

4.4

79

aÿ

0.0

92

aÿ

4.1

80

aÿ

0.0

90

aÿ

3.1

93

aÿ

0.1

10

aÿ

2.5

76

aÿ

0.0

86

aÿ

3.1

83

aÿ

0.1

13

a

b 03

ÿ4.8

72

aÿ

0.0

24

aÿ

4.8

70

aÿ

0.0

22

bÿ

5.3

63

aÿ

0.0

23

bÿ

5.2

51

aÿ

0.0

39

aÿ

5.9

57

aÿ

0.0

46

aÿ

5.6

31

aÿ

0.0

42

a

b 04

ÿ6.5

46

aÿ

0.0

27

bÿ

6.9

53

aÿ

0.0

23

bÿ

7.1

26

aÿ

0.0

20

bÿ

6.2

44

aÿ

0.0

16

bÿ

5.5

43

aÿ

0.0

19

bÿ

6.5

86

aÿ

0.0

17

b

b 11

(hit)

0.1

69

a0.0

22

a0.1

89

a0.0

25

a0.1

43

a0.0

19

a0.0

15

0.0

01

0.0

37

0.0

05

ÿ0.0

21

ÿ0.0

03

b 12

0.1

77

b0.0

03

0.1

52

0.0

03

0.1

85

b0.0

04

0.0

52

0.0

02

0.1

12

0.0

04

ÿ0.0

21

ÿ0.0

01

b 13

0.0

95

0.0

00

0.2

07

0.0

01

0.0

53

0.0

00

0.1

47

0.0

01

0.0

22

0.0

00

0.0

70

0.0

01

b 14

0.2

17

b0.0

01

0.2

39

0.0

01

0.1

67

0.0

00

0.4

31

a0.0

01

0.3

89

a0.0

01

0.3

07

a0.0

01

b 21

(eit)

0.9

76

a0.1

24

a0.9

91

a0.1

27

a1.0

05

a0.1

29

aÿ

0.2

03

ÿ0.0

19

ÿ0.2

12

ÿ0.0

23

ÿ0.1

64

ÿ0.0

14

b 22

1.6

02

a0.0

33

a1.6

39

a0.0

33

a1.5

71

a0.0

33

aÿ

1.4

49

aÿ

0.0

53

aÿ

1.3

67

aÿ

0.0

49

aÿ

1.3

96

aÿ

0.0

54

a

b 23

1.4

99

a0.0

07

b1.4

83

a0.0

06

b1.4

59

a0.0

06

b0.3

55

0.0

04

1.1

90

a0.0

11

a0.3

87

0.0

04

b 24

1.7

25

a0.0

07

b1.7

59

a0.0

06

b1.7

36

a0.0

05

bÿ

1.8

39

aÿ

0.0

05

ÿ1.6

50

aÿ

0.0

06

ÿ1.7

53

aÿ

0.0

05

b 31

(iit)

0.0

01

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

01

0.0

00

0.0

05

0.0

01

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

12

ÿ0.0

02

ÿ0.0

01

0.0

00

b 32

ÿ0.0

01

0.0

00

0.0

12

0.0

00

0.0

01

0.0

00

0.0

11

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

07

0.0

00

0.0

16

0.0

01

b 33

ÿ0.0

56

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

48

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

39

0.0

00

0.0

43

0.0

00

0.0

63

b0.0

01

0.0

50

0.0

00

b 34

0.0

13

0.0

00

0.0

32

0.0

00

0.0

23

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

11

0.0

00

ÿ0.0

11

0.0

00

0.0

07

0.0

00

b 41

(hjt*

)ÿ

0.0

72

ÿ0.0

11

ÿ0.0

89

ÿ0.0

14

0.0

74

0.0

08

ÿ0.2

06

aÿ

0.0

29

aÿ

0.3

54

aÿ

0.0

50

aÿ

0.1

90

ÿ0.0

30

b 42

0.1

38

0.0

03

0.2

86

0.0

07

0.2

67

0.0

06

ÿ0.1

18

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.4

76

bÿ

0.0

15

0.1

20

0.0

06

b 43

0.3

25

b0.0

02

0.0

61

0.0

00

0.8

25

b0.0

04

ÿ0.3

41

ÿ0.0

02

0.1

13

0.0

02

0.0

04

0.0

00

b 44

0.3

95

a0.0

02

b0.3

76

0.0

01

0.8

31

b0.0

02

ÿ0.0

56

0.0

00

ÿ0.1

07

0.0

00

0.6

47

0.0

02

b 51

(Yjt*

)0.2

60

a0.0

33

a0.8

40

a0.1

03

a0.7

62

a0.0

95

a0.1

85

b0.0

23

b0.3

74

0.0

40

0.4

92

b0.0

63

b 52

0.4

62

a0.0

10

b2.0

57

a0.0

42

a1.4

25

a0.0

30

a0.5

03

a0.0

18

a1.6

50

a0.0

58

a0.9

43

a0.0

33

b

b 53

0.5

79

b0.0

03

2.8

18

a0.0

13

b2.6

68

a0.0

12

b0.1

62

0.0

01

1.8

78

a0.0

14

b1.3

47

b0.0

10

b 54

0.5

68

b0.0

02

3.3

54

a0.0

11

b3.4

64

a0.0

10

b0.9

23

a0.0

02

1.5

73

b0.0

05

2.3

03

a0.0

06

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ1426.1

4ÿ

1411.0

4ÿ

1414.2

6ÿ

1627.5

5ÿ

1635.2

5ÿ

1638.9

5P

seu

do

-R2

5.4

0%

6.4

1%

6.1

9%

3.2

0%

2.7

4%

2.5

2%

w2(h

jt*)

21.9

8(0

.00)

6.2

8(0

.18)

8.4

7(0

.08)

12.6

9(0

.01)

15.7

2(0

.00)

5.5

4(0

.24)

w2(Y

jt*)

26.0

8(0

.00)

81.7

2(0

.00)

69.0

8(0

.00)

36.9

2(0

.00)

42.6

0(0

.00)

23.6

8(0

.01)

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

756

Page 41: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

US

Fro

mA

sia

Fro

mL

ati

nF

rom

Eu

rop

eF

rom

Asi

aF

rom

Lati

nF

rom

Eu

rop

eb 1

(co

nst

an

t)ÿ

3.9

01

aÿ

0.1

70

aÿ

4.3

81

aÿ

0.1

62

aÿ

4.2

41

aÿ

0.1

70

aÿ

3.3

77

aÿ

0.1

52

aÿ

3.8

86

aÿ

0.1

60

aÿ

3.3

62

aÿ

0.1

51

a

b 2(h

it)

ÿ0.0

99

ÿ0.0

04

ÿ0.2

63

ÿ0.0

10

ÿ0.4

70

bÿ

0.0

19

b0.0

84

0.0

04

0.0

39

0.0

02

0.0

81

0.0

04

b 3(e

it)

0.3

54

0.0

15

0.2

34

0.0

09

0.5

09

b0.0

20

bÿ

0.6

93

aÿ

0.0

31

aÿ

0.6

57

aÿ

0.0

27

aÿ

0.7

38

aÿ

0.0

33

a

b 4(i

it)

0.1

89

0.0

08

0.2

14

b0.0

08

b0.2

14

b0.0

09

b0.0

63

0.0

03

0.0

98

0.0

04

0.0

57

0.0

03

b 4(h

jt*)

ÿ0.0

21

ÿ0.0

01

0.0

70

0.0

03

0.5

50

b0.0

22

bÿ

0.0

22

ÿ0.0

01

0.0

39

0.0

02

ÿ0.0

29

ÿ0.0

01

b 4(Y

*jt)

0.1

07

0.0

05

0.8

44

a0.0

31

a1.6

65

a0.0

67

a0.0

35

0.0

02

0.6

38

a0.0

26

a0.4

52

0.0

20

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ428.8

6ÿ

395.8

4ÿ

414.8

0ÿ

442.5

4ÿ

425.1

6ÿ

442.0

5P

seu

do

-R2

0.7

1%

8.3

5%

3.9

6%

0.9

7%

4.8

6%

1.0

8%

w2(h

jt*)

0.0

5(0

.82)

0.7

9(0

.37)

4.4

8(0

.03)

0.0

6(0

.81)

0.1

2(0

.73)

0.0

1(0

.92)

w2(Y

jt*)

0.6

3(0

.43)

73.8

4(0

.00)

32.6

6(0

.00)

0.0

7(0

.79)

39.8

4(0

.00)

1.2

1(0

.27)

Eu

rop

eF

rom

Asi

aF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

SF

rom

Asi

aF

rom

Lati

nA

mer

ica

Fro

mU

Sb 1

(co

nst

an

t)ÿ

3.4

71

aÿ

0.1

21

aÿ

2.9

97

aÿ

0.1

12

aÿ

3.3

32

aÿ

0.1

15

aÿ

2.9

92

aÿ

0.1

00

aÿ

2.8

41

aÿ

0.0

94

aÿ

3.0

70

aÿ

0.1

01

a

b 2(h

it)

0.0

82

0.0

03

ÿ0.0

91

ÿ0.0

03

0.0

39

0.0

01

ÿ0.5

49

bÿ

0.0

18

bÿ

0.5

01

ÿ0.0

17

bÿ

0.8

16

bÿ

0.0

27

b

b 3(e

it)

1.0

11

a0.0

35

a1.0

40

a0.0

39

a1.0

95

a0.0

38

aÿ

1.5

81

aÿ

0.0

53

aÿ

1.5

91

aÿ

0.0

53

aÿ

1.5

83

aÿ

0.0

52

a

b 4(i

it)

ÿ0.0

43

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

86

ÿ0.0

03

ÿ0.0

38

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

30

ÿ0.0

01

ÿ0.0

53

ÿ0.0

02

ÿ0.0

05

0.0

00

b 4(h� jt)

0.0

77

0.0

03

0.1

15

0.0

04

0.1

28

0.0

04

0.1

06

0.0

04

0.0

53

0.0

02

0.3

33

0.0

11

b 4(Y� jt)

0.7

70

a0.0

27

a0.5

87

a0.0

22

a2.3

67

a0.0

82

a0.2

53

b0.0

08

b0.3

04

b0.0

10

b0.9

89

a0.0

33

a

Lo

g-l

ikel

iho

od

ÿ402.8

4ÿ

415.7

2ÿ

399.2

5ÿ

406.4

8ÿ

407.0

2ÿ

405.3

4P

seu

do

-R2

10.4

4%

7.5

8%

11.2

4%

12.4

9%

12.3

7%

12.7

3%

w2(h� jt)

0.9

7(0

.32)

3.1

4(0

.08)

0.4

5(0

.50)

1.7

9(0

.18)

0.4

5(0

.50)

2.8

7(0

.09)

w2(Y� jt)

58.5

6(0

.00)

28.5

6(0

.00)

77.7

2(0

.00)

4.6

5(0

.03)

5.5

5(0

.02)

7.7

6(0

.01)

Extr

eme

retu

rns

are

def

ined

inte

rms

of

exce

edan

ces

bey

on

da

thre

sho

ldth

at

vari

eso

ver

tim

ew

ith

the

con

dit

ion

al

vo

lati

lity

of

regio

nal

mark

etre

turn

s.S

pec

ific

all

y,

the

tim

e-se

ries

of

con

dit

ion

al

vo

lati

liti

es,

hit,

for

each

cou

ntr

yin

dex

iat

tim

et

are

ob

tain

edu

sin

gE

GA

RC

H(1

,1)

mo

del

.T

hen

,a

retu

rn,

r it,

isd

efin

edas

extr

eme

ifjr itj>

1.6

5h

it.

Th

en

um

ber

of

coex

ceed

an

ces,

of

dail

yre

turn

sis

mo

del

edas

an

ord

ered

po

lych

oto

mo

us

vari

ab

lean

des

tim

ate

du

sin

ga

mu

ltin

om

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nm

od

el.

Pjis

def

ined

as

the

pro

bab

ilit

yth

at

agiv

end

ay

isass

oci

ate

dw

ith

jco

exce

edan

ces,

wh

ere

jeq

uals

0,

1,

2,

3,

4o

rm

ore

(fiv

eca

tego

ries

).T

he

mu

ltin

om

ial

logit

regre

ssio

nm

od

elis

giv

enb

yP

j�

exp

(x0 b

j)/[

1+

�kex

p(x0 b

k)]

,w

her

eb

isth

evec

tor

of

coef

fici

ents

,x

,th

evec

tor

of

ind

epen

den

tvari

ab

les,

an

dk

equ

als

1to

4.

Th

ep

rob

ab

ilit

yth

at

ther

eare

no

(co

-)ex

ceed

an

ces

equ

als

P0�

1/

[1+P k

exp

(x0 b

k)]

,w

her

ek

equ

als

1to

4,

wh

ich

rep

rese

nts

ou

rb

ase

case

.T

he

ind

epen

den

tvari

ab

les,

x,

incl

ud

eth

ose

inT

ab

le5.

Th

eco

nd

itio

nal

vo

lati

lity

ises

tim

ate

das

EG

AR

CH

(1,1

)u

sin

gth

eIF

Cin

ves

tib

lere

gio

nal

ind

ex.

Part

ial

der

ivati

ves

of

pro

bab

ilit

ies

wit

hre

spec

tto

the

vec

tor

of

ind

epen

den

tvari

ab

les

are

com

pu

ted

at

the

mea

ns

of

xan

dare

rep

ort

edn

ext

toth

eco

effi

cien

tes

tim

ate

s.G

oo

dn

ess

of

fit

ism

easu

red

by

McF

ad

den

'sp

seu

do

-R2

equ

al

to1ÿ

(L!/L

),

wh

ere

L!

isth

eu

nre

stri

cted

lik

elih

oo

d,

an

dL

is

the

rest

rict

edli

kel

iho

od

[Mad

dala

(1983,

chap

.2)]

.T

he

logit

regre

ssio

nis

esti

mate

dse

para

tely

for

po

siti

ve

(to

p-t

ail

)an

dn

egati

ve

(bo

tto

m-t

ail

)co

exce

edan

ces.w2

(hjt*

)an

dw2

(Yjt*

)are

Wald

chi-

squ

are

test

sfo

rth

ere

stri

ctio

ns

thatb k

1�

b k2�

b k3�

b k4�

0,

wh

ere

kis

4an

d5,

resp

ecti

vel

y,

wit

hp-v

alu

esin

pare

nth

eses

.

a,

bD

eno

tes

sign

ific

an

cele

vel

sat

the

1%

an

d5%

,re

spec

tivel

y.

Measuring Financial Contagion

757

Page 42: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Finally, we consider alternative estimation approaches for our problem.Because our multinomial logit model fails to account for the ordinalnature of our coexceedance measure as the dependent variable, we maylose efficiency compared to an ordered logit model, which is explicitlydesigned to capture the ordering information. The ordered logit, alsoknown as a proportional-odds ordered logit model, requires the odds ofadjacent categories, defined by different threshold or cutoff points alongthe ordinal scale, to have the same ratio for all independent variablecombinations. As a result, there is only one set of coefficients estimatedfor the covariates instead of four sets separately for each outcome in themultinomial logit. However, this model implies that the odds of observingfive coexceedances instead of four are equivalent to the odds of observingthree coexceedances instead of two. Such a constraint will generate less-efficient estimates if the odds are not proportional [Brant (1990), Petersonand Harrell (1990)]. With this concern in mind, we chose to featurethe unordered multinomial logit. However, in unreported results, wereplicated our contagion tests across regions using the ordered modeland found that our inferences about the coexceedance variable Y�j (coeffi-cients and marginal effects) and the pseudo-R2 were consistent and verysimilar. Some propose diagnostic tests for ordered logit models relative tomultinomial (unordered) logit models based on the differences in the log-likelihood values [Brant (1990)]. One such test is referred to as a`̀ likelihood ratio test.'' It is computed as ÿ 2(LoÿL), where Lo (L) isthe log-likelihood of the ordered (unordered) logit, which is distributed asa chi-square with p(cÿ 2) degrees of freedom, where c is the number ofcategories (c� 5 for Asia and Latin America) and p is the number ofcovariates ( p� 5 in our case). This diagnostic regularly rejects the orderedlogit model in favor of the multinomial, with only one exception. Notethat this diagnostic cannot be used as a formal measure of fit, as themodels are not nested.

Another alternative is the negative binomial model, which is a generali-zation of the Poisson regression model used mainly for count data. Thismodel specifies that each observation is drawn from a Poisson distributionwith an expected number of events per period that is related to indepen-dent variables, or covariates. The advantage of the negative binomialmodel is that it does not assume equality of the expected mean andvariance. We hesitate to employ this model, as it is typically used incross-sectional analysis and less often with time-series data [Greene(2000, section 19.9)]. In this model we do not need to assign categories,as in the ordered and unordered logit models, and as a result, the system issmaller, with only one coefficient estimated for each covariate.19 We

19 We tested the restriction in the multinomial logit models in Section 4.1 that the coefficients across the categoriesof one, two, three, and four or more coexceedances are equal and rejected these restrictions easily for the caseof Asia and Latin America. These restricted models are closest in spirit to the negative binomial model.

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

758

Page 43: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

replicate our tests for contagion across regions with this model (unre-ported) and find that our inferences about contagion effects are evenstronger between Asia and Latin America and between the emergingmarket regions and Europe. Contagion from Asia and Latin America tothe United States is measurably lower, however.

Our multinomial logistic regression model results for contagion withinand across regions are not simply manifestations of the correlations ofreturns in those markets, even if we allow for returns-generating processeswith excess kurtosis and time-varying volatility. The findings are robust tospecifications with seasonal dummies, lagged conditioning information,local currency (versus U.S. dollar) denominated returns, multiday hori-zons for exceedance counts, and even conditional measures of extremesbased on conditional volatility. We also explore other econometricmethods including ordered logit, proportional odds, and negative bi-nomial regression models. If anything, these alternative specificationslikely strengthen our main findings on the existence of contagion effectsacross regions.

4� Conclusion

In this article we propose a new approach to the study of financialcontagion. The key presumption of our approach is that contagion is aphenomenon associated with extreme returns: if there is contagion, small-return shocks propagate differently from large-return shocks. We there-fore investigate the propagation of large-return shocks within regions andacross regions. Such an approach faces two problems. First, focusing onlarge-return shocks, by definition, decreases sample size and limits thepower of our tests. One must be careful not to let inferences be dominatedby a few datapoints. As a result, we choose to focus on counts of coin-cidences of extreme returns rather than on correlations of joint extremereturns. Our modeling approach employs the multinomial logistic regres-sion approach to reflect this new and different focus. Second, one wouldexpect large returns to be more highly correlated than small returns. As aresult, one has to make sure that the apparent contagion of large returns isnot simply the outcome of conditioning a study on large returns. We useMonte Carlo simulations to calibrate our results with different scenariosaccording to what one would find if returns were distributed as multi-variate normal, Student's t, and even with GARCH effects. We find thatwe have too many cases where large negative returns occur in mostcountries of a region. Further, we find that the number of large negativereturns in one region is more useful to predict the number of large negativereturns in another region than if the returns in the two regions weredistributed multivariate normal, Student's t, or GARCH. We also findthat the number of joint occurrences of extreme returns within a region

Measuring Financial Contagion

759

Page 44: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

can be explained by regional conditional volatility, the level of interestrates, and exchange rate changes.

Contagion is a source of great concern for policymakers and has gen-erated a large and growing academic literature. We find in our study ofemerging markets that the propagation of large negative returns acrossregions is anomalous if stock return indices follow a joint returns-generating model with normal or fat tails or even if the conditionalvolatility of returns varies over time. Whether this anomalous propaga-tion should be a matter of serious concern will depend on the views ofreaders. Nevertheless, our article has a number of clear results:

1. Contagion is more important in Latin America than in Asia.2. Contagion from Latin America to other regions of the world is

more important than contagion from Asia.3. The United States is largely insulated from contagion from Asia.4. Contagion is predictable conditional on prior information.

A natural extension of our study would be to investigate whetheralternate distributional assumptions could explain our results. Further,our study uses daily returns and focuses on same-day, lagged one-day, andeven three-day contagion. But a useful extension of the study would be tolook at longer-horizon contagion. Such an analysis would make it possibleto investigate whether there are thresholds of cumulative returns abovewhich propagation of returns becomes more intense. It would also beuseful to apply the approach to a broader cross section of individualstock or sector index returns within countries. The approach developedin this article would be well suited for such analyses. There is a longtradition that focuses on modeling the properties of extreme returns.A factor model might capture both the properties of extreme returns andof other returns. It would be a challenge to develop a model that wouldcapture the nonlinearities that we emphasize, but such a model couldprovide useful insights about the contagion quantified in this article.

Appendix

Every three month, stocks in the EMDB Global Index for each market are identified and

sorted by market capitalization (adjusted for the free-float if cross-holding data is provided).

Stocks are included until 50 stocks are included or until the threshold of 90% of the EMDB

Global Index capitalization is met. Daily returns are computed from daily log differences of a

value-weighted portfolio of constituent stocks and both local currency and U.S. dollar-

denominated (net of log difference of daily exchange rate) returns. Though we start the

procedure as far back as December 1989, the official start date for all markets is April 1, 1992.

We verify our selection and construction criteria by examining the statistical attributes of the

index series and the correlations with the actual IFC indexes after December 31, 1995.

Overall, the coverage in terms of market capitalization is well over 90% even if the 50 stock

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

760

Page 45: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

limit is not met, due to the skewness of the composition in many of these emerging markets.

Most correlations between the constructed and actual IFC indexes are well over 0.95 (median

0.988) for all but three exceptional cases (Colombia, 0.88; India, 0.89; Peru, 0.83) indicating

the construction process is reasonably sound. We report only the results using our con-

structed indexes, but all the tests reported in this article are estimated using the actual IFC

indexes also. Further details on the scope of coverage and components is available from the

authors upon request.

ReferencesAllen, F., and D. Gale, 2000, ``Financial Contagion,'' Journal of Political Economy, 108, 1--34.

Ang, A., and G. Bekaert, 2002, `̀ International Asset Allocation with Time-Varying Correlations,'' Reviewof Financial Studies, 15, 1137±1187.

Ang. A., and J. Chen, 2002, `̀ Asymmetric Correlation of Equity Portfolios,'' Journal of FinancialEconomics, 63, 443±494.

Bae, K.-H., and G. A. Karolyi, 1994, `̀ Good News, Bad News and International Spillovers of StockReturn Volatility Between Japan and the U.S.,'' Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 2, 405--438.

Baig, T., and I. Goldfajn, 1999, `̀ Financial Market Contagion in the Asian Crisis,'' working paper,International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

Bekaert, G., and G. Wu, 2000, ``Asymmetric Volatility and Risk in Equity Markets,'' Review of FinancialStudies, 13, 1--42.

Berndt, E., B. Hall, R. Hall, and J. Hausman, 1974, `̀ Estimation and Inference in Nonlinear StructuralModels,'' Annals of Economics and Social Measurement, 4, 653--665.

Bhagwati, J., 1998, `̀ The Capital Myth,'' Foreign Affairs, 77(3), 7--12.

Brant, R., 1990, `̀ Assessing Proportionality in the Proportional Odds Model for Ordinal LogisticRegression,'' Biometrics, 35, 1171--1178.

Calvo, G., 1996, Private Capital Flows to Emerging Markets After the Mexican Crisis, Institute forInternational Economics, Washington, DC.

Claessens, S., and K. Forbes, 2001, International Financial Contagion, Kluwer Academic, New York.

Connolly, R., and A. Wang, 2003, `̀ International Equity Market Comovements: EconomicFundamentals or Contagion,'' Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 11, 23±43.

Danielsson, J., and C. de Vries, 2000, `̀ Value-at-Risk and Extreme Returns,'' working paper, LondonSchool of Economics.

Das, S., and R. Uppal, 2002, `̀ The Effect of Systemic Risk on International Portfolio Choice,'' workingpaper, UBC.

De Santis, G., and B. Gerard, 1997, `̀ International Asset Pricing and Portfolio Diversification with Time-Varying Risk,'' Journal of Finance, 52, 1881--1912.

De Santis, G., and B. Gerard, 1998, `̀ How Big is the Premium for Currency Risk?'' Journal of FinancialEconomics, 49, 375--412.

Ding, Z., and R. Engle, 1994, `̀ Large Scale Conditional Covariance Modeling, Estimation and Testing,''working paper, University of California at San Diego.

Dornbusch, R., Y.-C. Park, and S. Claessens, 2001, `̀ Contagion: How it Spreads and How it can beStopped?'' in S. Claessens and K. Forbes (eds), International Financial Contagion, Kluwer Academic,New York.

Measuring Financial Contagion

761

Page 46: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Dumas, B., C. Harvey, and P. Ruiz, 2003, `̀ Are Common Swings in International Stock Returns Justifiedby Subsequent Changes in National Outputs,'' working paper, Duke University.

Eichengreen, B., A. Rose, and C. Wyplosz, 1996, `̀ Contagious Currency Crises: First Tests,''Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 98, 463--484.

Engle, R. F., T. Ito, and W.-L. Lin, 1990, ``Meteor Showers or Heat Waves? Heteroskedastic Intra-DailyVolatility in the Foreign Exchange Market,'' Econometrica, 58, 525--542.

Erb, C. B., C. R. Harvey, and T. E. Viskanta, 1995, `̀ Country Risk and Global Equity Selection,'' Journalof Portfolio Management, 21, 74--83.

Eun, C. S., and S. Shim, 1989, ``International Transmission of Stock Market Movements,'' Journal ofFinancial and Quantitative Analysis, 24, 241--256.

Forbes, K., and R. Rigobon, 2001, `̀ Measuring Contagion: Conceptual and Empirical Issues,'' inS. Claessens and K. Forbes (eds), International Financial Contagion, Kluwer Academic, New York.

Forbes, K., and R. Rigobon, 2002, `̀ No Contagion, Only Interdependence: Measuring Stock MarketCo-movements,'' forthcoming in Journal of Finance.

Gillespie, B., M. Halpern, and K. Warner, 1994, `̀ Patterns of Lung Cancer Risk in Ex-smokers,'' inN. Lange, L. Billard, D. Brillinger, L. Conquest and J. Greenhouse, eds., Case Studies in Biometry, Wiley,New York.

Glick, R., and A. K. Rose, 1999, `̀ Contagion and Trade,'' Journal of International Money and Finance, 18,603--617.

Greene, W., 2000, Econometric Analysis, 4th ed., Macmillan, New York.

Hamao, Y., R. W. Masulis, and Victor Ng, 1990, `̀ Correlations in Price Changes and Volatility AcrossInternational Stock Markets,'' Review of Financial Studies, 3, 281--308.

Hartmann, P., S. Straetmans, and C. de Vries, 2001, `̀ Asset Market Linkages in Crisis Periods,'' workingpaper, Universiteit Maastricht.

Hosmer, D., and S. Lemeshow, 1989, Applied Logistic Regression, Wiley, New York.

Kaminsky, G. L., and C. Reinhart, 2000, `̀ On Crises, Contagion and Confusion,'' Journal of InternationalEconomics, 51, 145--168.

Kaminsky, G. L., and S. L. Schmukler, 1999, ``What Triggers Market Jitters?'' Journal of InternationalMoney and Finance, 18, 537--560.

Karolyi, G. A., and R. M. Stulz, 1996, `̀ Why do Markets Move Together? An Investigation ofU.S.--Japan Stock Return Comovements,'' Journal of Finance, 51, 951--986.

Karolyi, G. A., and R. M. Stulz, 2003, `̀ Are Assets Priced Locally or Globally?'' in G. Constantinides,M. Harris and R. Stulz, eds., Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Elsevier Science, Amsterdam, TheNetherlands.

King, M., E. Sentana, and S. Wadhwani, 1995, `̀ Volatility and Links Between National Stock Markets,''Econometrica, 62, 901--933.

King, M. A., and S. Wadhwani, 1990, ``Transmission of Volatility Between Stock Markets,'' Review ofFinancial Studies, 3, 5--33.

Kyle, A. S., and W. Xiong, 2001, ``Contagion as a Wealth Effect,'' Journal of Finance, 56,1401--1440.

Ledoit, O., P. Santa-Clara, and M. Wolf, 2003, `̀ Flexible Multivariate GARCH Modeling with anApplication to International Stock Markets,'' forthcoming in Review of Economics and Statistics.

Lin, W.-L., R. F. Engle, and T. Ito, 1994, `̀ Do Bulls and Bears Move Across Borders? InternationalTransmission of Stock Returns and Volatility,'' Review of Financial Studies, 7, 507--538.

The Review of Financial Studies / v 16 n 3 2003

762

Page 47: A New Approach to Measuring Financial Contagion...rate changes, and conditional stock return volatility. Evidence that contagion is stronger for extreme negative returns than for extreme

Longin, F. M., 1996, `̀ The Asymptotic Distribution of Extreme Stock Market Returns,'' Journal ofBusiness, 69, 383--408.

Longin, F. M., and B. Solnik, 1995, `̀ Is the Correlation in International Equity Returns Constant:1970--1990?'' Journal of International Money and Finance, 14, 3--26.

Longin, F. M., and B. Solnik, 2001, ``Extreme Correlations of International Equity Markets DuringExtremely Volatile Periods,'' Journal of Finance, 56, 649--676.

Maddala, G. S., 1983, Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics, CambridgeUniversity Press, Cambridge.

Masson, P., 1999, `̀ Contagion,'' Journal of International Money and Finance, 18, 587--602.

McFadden, P., 1974, ``The Measurement of Urban Travel Demand,'' Journal of Public Economics, 3,303--328.

Ng., A., 2000, `̀ Volatility Spillover Effects from Japan and the U.S. to the Pacific-Basin,'' Journal ofInternational Money and Finance, 19, 207--233.

Park, J. Y., and P. C. B. Phillips, 2000, `̀ Nonstationary Binary Choice,'' Econometrica, 68,1249--1280.

Peterson, B., and F. Harrell, Jr., 1990, `̀ Partial Proportional Odds Models for Ordinal ResponseVariables,'' Applied Statistics, 39, 205--217.

Pownall, R. A., and K. G. Koedijk, 1999, ``Capturing Downside Risk in Financial Markets: The Case ofthe Asian Crisis,'' Journal of International Money and Finance, 18, 853--870.

Ramchand, L., and R. Susmel, 1998, `̀ Volatility and Cross-Correlation Across Major Stock Markets,''Journal of Empirical Finance, 5, 397--416.

Starica, C., 1999, `̀ Multivariate Extremes for Models with Constant Conditional Correlations,'' Journalof Empirical Finance, 6, 515--553.

Stiglitz, J., 1998, `̀ Distinguished Lecture on Economics in Government: The Private Uses of PublicInterests: Incentives and Institutions,'' Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12, 3--22.

Straetmans, S., 1998, `̀ Extreme Financial Returns and Their Comovements'' (Ph.D. dissertation),Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam, Amsterdam.

Susmel, R., 2001, `̀ Extreme Observations and Diversification in Latin American Emerging EquityMarkets,'' Journal of International Money and Finance, 20, 971±986.

Susmel, R., and R. F. Engle, 1994, `̀ Hourly Volatility Spillovers Between International Equity Markets,''Journal of International Money and Finance, 13, 3--26.

Measuring Financial Contagion

763