zephyr concepts - black-litterman

Upload: gautam-praveen

Post on 03-Jun-2018

225 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/11/2019 Zephyr Concepts - Black-Litterman

    1/4

  • 8/11/2019 Zephyr Concepts - Black-Litterman

    2/4

    22 Investments&Wealth MONITOR

    F E A TURE

    raditionally, the standard proce-

    dure to come up with the required fore-

    casts for the expected return, standard

    deviation, and correlation coeffi cients

    for the chosen asset classes has been torely on historical data. Running MVO

    with these historical estimates often

    results in unintuitive and poorly diversi-

    fied portfolios. Moreover, if an investor

    makes small changes to the historical

    return forecasts based on her own

    assessment of future market behav-

    ior, then the resulting changes in the

    optimal portfolio allocations are often

    unintuitive and erratic.

    The Black-Litterman Model

    Te BLM, introduced by Fisher Black

    and Robert Litterman in 1992, is a

    mathematical model for obtaining

    stable and consistent return forecasts

    for a set of asset classes. When these

    return forecasts are used as input to the

    MVO calculation, the resulting portfo-

    lios tend to be much more intuitive and

    less erratic than the ones that are based

    on historical return estimates.

    Te BLM does not address the issue

    of finding estimates for the standard

    deviations and correlation coeffi cients.

    As far as those are concerned, historical

    values have turned out to be reasonably

    stable. Moreover, the MVO calculation

    is much less sensitive to these inputs

    than it is to the return estimates.

    Te Black-Litterman approach

    consists of two separate parts. Te first

    part addresses the problem of MVO

    portfolios being unintuitive and poorly

    diversified. Te second part addresses

    the fact that MVO portfolios are erratic;

    that is, they are overly sensitive to small

    changes in the return forecasts.

    BLM Part 1: Achieving Well-

    Diversified Portfolios

    Te fact that classical MVO portfolios,

    based on historical return forecasts,

    tend to be unintuitive and poorly di-

    versified should not come as a surprise.

    Te mathematics of MVO is purely

    focused on maximizing the expected re-

    turn for each level of risk. It simply does

    not know what we human investors

    consider to be intuitive and well-diver-sified. o achieve an output that meets

    our idea of an intuitive portfolio, we

    must find a way of making intuitive-

    ness of a portfolio part of the input

    of the MVO algorithm. Tat is exactly

    what the first part of the BLM does.

    Te first step is to identify the consensus

    portfolio, that is, the default portfolio that

    an investor should buy in the absence of

    any special information, inclination,

    opinion, speculation, or the like. Tis is

    how the investor communicates to theBLMand thus, indirectly, to the MVO

    calculationwhat is to be viewed as an

    intuitive, well-balanced portfolio.

    By far the most common choice for

    the consensus portfolio is the market

    portfolio; that is, the portfolio where the

    weights of the asset classes are propor-

    tional to their respective total market

    capitalizations. Terefore, it may be

    FIGURE 2: MVO WITH BLM RETURN FORECASTS

    FIGURE 3: MVO WITH SMALL-VALUE FORECAST LOWERED

    Cas : Black-Litterman Return vs. Risk (Standard Deviation)

    0 1 15 20 2 3

    3

    4

    5

    6

    7

    8

    9

    10

    11

    Risk (Standard Deviation

    Return

    Asse AllocationUS Bond -Aggrega e

    US Large p Growh

    Large p lu

    ll r th

    US Small ap Value

    Cas : Historical Forec sts Return vs. Ri k (Stan ar Deviation)

    6 7 9 10 11 12 13 14 1 16

    10

    11

    12

    13

    14

    Risk (Standard Devi tion

    Return

    Asset Allocation

    - t

    Large ap ro h

    L al

    US Sm ll Cap rowth

    mall ap al e

    2009 Investment Management Consultants Association. Reprint with permission only.

  • 8/11/2019 Zephyr Concepts - Black-Litterman

    3/4

    23January/February 2009

    F E A TURE

    worth pointing out that the mathemat-

    ics of the BLM depends in no way on

    how the investor came up with the con-

    sensus portfolio. From a purely math-

    ematical point of view, any choice is as

    good as the next one. It is true, however,

    that the market portfolio remains the

    consensus portfolio of choice for most

    investors. Tat is the reason why asset

    allocation programs such as Zephyrs

    AllocationADVISOR come with regu-

    larly updated market capitalizations for

    the most common asset classes, and

    they use the market portfolio as the

    default consensus portfolio.

    Te BLM also requires the investor

    to make a forecast for the risk-free rate

    and for the risk premium of the consen-

    sus portfolio. It is important to know

    that the chosen risk premium will not

    ultimately affect the portfolio weights. It

    is merely a way to ensure that the BLMreturn forecasts have plausible values.

    Te risk-free rate, on the other hand, is

    an essential input to the model.

    Based on these inputs, the BLM will

    calculate a set of return forecasts called

    the implied returns. Te implied returns

    have the following property: When

    used as inputs to the MVO calculation,

    they will make the consensus portfolio

    appear at one particular point on the

    effi cient frontier. More precisely, the

    consensus portfolio will appear exactly

    at the point on the effi cient frontier

    where the Sharpe ratio is maximal.

    In summary, we can describe the

    first part of the BLM as follows: Te

    model allows the investor to describe

    what she considers to be the consensus

    portfolio. Te model then produces

    a set of implied returns, which, when

    used as input to the MVO calcula-

    tion, force the effi cient frontier to be

    anchored to the consensus portfo-

    lio. Rather than producing arbitrary,

    unpredictable portfolios, MVO now

    will produce the consensus portfolio at

    the point of the maximum Sharpe ratio,

    and it will smoothly deviate from the

    consensus portfolio as one moves away

    from the point of the maximum Sharpe

    ratio on the effi cient frontier.o see the difference between

    classical MVO with historical return

    forecasts and MVO with BLM return

    forecasts, compare figures 1 and 2. Te

    historical forecasts result in a concen-

    trated portfolio that contains no growth

    stocks at all. Te BLM return forecasts

    result in a well-diversified portfolio that

    takes its cues from the market portfolio.

    BLM Part 2: Making Return

    Forecasts Consistent

    Recall that the second complaint about

    classical MVO is that small changes in

    the return forecasts often result in large,erratic changes to the resulting port-

    folios on the effi cient frontier. Again,

    this phenomenon should not come as

    a surprise. Suppose you are running

    an MVO with a standard set of asset

    classes that include small-value stocks,

    as in figure 1.

    Looking at the return forecast for

    your small-value asset class, you decide

    that you expect it to return less in the

    future; therefore, you slightly lower the

    return forecast. Now if you run your

    MVO again with just that one small

    modification, you will find that your

    portfolio allocations have changed in a

    dramatic and unintuitive manner. For

    example, figure 3 shows what happens if

    you start with the MVO of figure 1 and

    then lower the 14.75-percent historical

    forecast for small-value stocks slightly to

    13 percent. Te result is that small-value

    stocks completely disappear from the

    portfolio, leaving us with only bonds and

    large-value stocks. Why did this happen?

    Recall that in addition to the return fore-

    casts, you also gave the MVO calculation

    a set of correlation coeffi cients, which

    describe the dependencies between the

    returns of the asset classes. Terefore,

    when you modified the return estimate

    of small-value stocks, these correlations

    implied corresponding changes in the

    other assets classes return estimates. But

    you did not make those corresponding

    changes. You have thus created an incon-

    sistent set of inputs. Te result is a bad

    case of GIGO (garbage in, garbage out).

    Given inconsistent input, MVO producesmeaningless, random portfolios.

    Te second part of the BLM fixes

    this problem in a way that is, although

    mathematically very complex, easy to

    understand on a high level. When the

    investor makes changes to the return

    forecasts that were obtained in the first

    part of the BLM, the BLM does not take

    these changes at face value. Instead, it

    FIGURE 4: MVO WITH BLM VIEW RAISING SMALL-VALUE FORECAST

    Case: Bl ck-Litterman Return vs. Risk (Stan ard Devi ti n

    5 10 15 2 25 0

    3

    4

    5

    6

    7

    8

    9

    1

    11

    1

    Risk (Standard Deviation

    Return

    L h

    US Large p V lu

    m ll ap rowth

    mall al

    As t Allocations

    2009 Investment Management Consultants Association. Reprint with permission only.

  • 8/11/2019 Zephyr Concepts - Black-Litterman

    4/4

    24 Investments&Wealth MONITOR

    F E A TURE

    makes the modified return forecasts

    consistent in the sense that it takes into

    account how the investors modifica-

    tions affect other asset classes based

    on the correlations between the asset

    classes. When these new, consistent

    return forecasts are used as input to the

    MVO calculation, the resulting change

    in the portfolio allocations no longer

    is erratic and unintuitive. o see this,

    compare figures 2 and 4. Figure 4 shows

    the effect of raising the BLM return

    forecasts for small-value stocks from

    7.63 percent to 9 percent. Te allocation

    to small-value stocks increases, leaving

    the weights of the other asset classes

    relatively untouched.

    Let us now take a closer look at how

    this second part of the BLM presents

    itself to the investor. After completing

    the first part of the BLM, where the con-

    sensus portfolio is entered, the investor

    is presented with the implied returns.

    At this point, it is possible to state views

    on how the investor thinks the implied

    returns ought to be modified.

    In theory, a view can be any linear

    relationship between the returns. In

    practice, only two special kinds of views

    are relevant:

    An absolute view is a view of the

    form, I believe that asset class A will

    have a return of x percent.

    A relative view is a view of the form,

    I believe that asset class A will out-perform asset class B by x percent.

    In addition, the investor may attach

    a level of confidence to each view; that

    is, a view can be held with more or less

    confidence. Te more confidence the

    investor has in a view, the more the view

    will affect the outcome of the calculation.

    When the investor has entered the

    views, the BLM will modify the implied

    returns according to the views. In

    doing so, it will take into account how

    the returns of the different asset classes

    affect each other via the correlations.

    As mentioned before, this is a math-

    ematically very complex task. In fact,

    it may seem like an impossible task:

    When an investor states more than one

    view, it is quite likely that these views

    will be contradictory to some extent.

    Suppose, for example, that the investor

    states two views:

    1. I believe that asset class A will

    return x percent.

    2. I believe that asset class A will out-

    perform asset class B by y percent.

    When the BLM processes the first

    view, it will set the return forecast of

    asset class A to x percent, and it will

    modify the return forecasts of all other

    asset classes according to their correla-

    tions with asset class A. In particular, it

    will arrive at a certain return forecast

    for asset class B. In all likelihood, the

    difference between the return forecasts

    for asset classes A and B will not equal

    y percent, as stipulated by the second

    view. Terefore, to process the second

    view, the BLM has to modify the return

    forecasts of asset class A or asset class

    B again, thus violating the result of

    processing the first view.

    So what the BLM typically does is

    a balancing act between several views

    that contradict each other. In otherwords, the BLM does not really make

    the return forecasts consistent; rather,

    it makes them statistically consistent in

    the sense that it finds the best compro-

    mise between the views. One might

    expect that finding a compromise in

    a situation like that would involve an

    element of discretion. In other words,

    one might expect that there would be

    different schools of thought on how

    to define that compromise. Somewhat

    surprisingly, it turns out that this is

    not the case. Te situation at hand is

    an instance of a very solid and well-founded mathematical theory known

    as generalized least squares estimation,

    which is backed by more than 200 years

    of mathematical research. Least squares

    estimation has countless applications

    in navigation, surveying, oil drilling,

    geodesy, and target finding, and many

    other areas. Its validity and appropri-

    ateness are not a matter of conten-

    tion. It thus is fair to say that the BLM

    provides us with scientifically sound

    return-forecasts.

    Summary

    Te Black-Litterman model is a front

    end for classical mean-variance opti-

    mization. Te purpose of the BLM is

    twofold:

    By anchoring the MVO portfolios to

    a consensus portfolio that the inves-

    tor provides, the BLM causes the

    MVO calculation to produce intui-

    tive, well-diversified portfolios.

    When an investor states views

    regarding return estimates, the BLM

    processes these views to make them

    statistically consistent. As a result,

    the portfolios produced by the MVO

    will reflect the investors view in a

    plausible manner rather than jump-

    ing erratically as they would without

    the BLMs preprocessing.

    Te BLM model achieves its

    purpose using sound mathematical

    principles whose value has been proven

    in a wide variety of fields in science and

    engineering.

    Thomas Becker, PhD, is a mathema-

    tic ian and scienti f i c software engi-

    neer at Zephyr Associates, Inc. in

    Zep hy r Co ve , NV. He ear ne d a Ph D

    in mathematics from the University

    of Heidelberg, Germany. Contact him

    at [email protected].

    . . . the BLM does not really make the re-turn forecasts cons istent; rather, it makes th em

    statistically consistent in the sense that it findsthe best compromise between the views.

    2009 Investment Management Consultants Association. Reprint with permission only.