who pays for government? descriptive representation and

32
SHORT ARTICLE Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and Exploitative Revenue Sources Michael W. Sances, University of Memphis Hye Young You, Vanderbilt University We examine US city governmentsuse of nes and court fees for local revenue, a policy that disproportionately affects black voters, and the connections between this policy and black representation. Using data on over 9,000 cities, we show that the use of nes as revenue is common and that it is robustly related to the share of city residents who are black. We also nd that black representation on city councils diminishes the connection between black population and nes rev- enue. Our ndings speak to the potential of descriptive representation to alleviate biases in city policy. M uch recent public discussion focuses on racial dis- crimination by local ofcials and not only in terms of police violence. According to a US Justice De- partment report in the wake of the Michael Brown shooting in Ferguson, Missouria city with a majority black popula- tion but a majority white governmentcity ofcials urged the police chief to generate more revenue from trafc tickets and court nes to address a substantial sales tax shortfall. Indeed, about 20% of Fergusons revenues come from nes and re- lated sources. 1 Other observers note that the dependence on nes is not unique to Ferguson but also occurs in other Mis- souri communities. 2 Scholars have extensively documented racial bias in pe- destrian stops by law enforcement (Epp, Maynard-Moody, and Haider-Markel 2014; Gelman, Fagan, and Kiss 2007; Weaver and Lerman 2010), elected ofcialsresponse to con- stituent requests (Butler and Broockman 2011; White, Nathan, and Faller 2015), and public service delivery by bureaucrats (Einstein and Glick 2016; Ernst, Nguyen, and Taylor 2013). In contrast, bias in the form of local revenue generation is rarely discussed in this literature, perhaps because city ofcials are assumed to be limited in their policy discretion (Ferreira and Gyourko 2009; Peterson 1981). Police spending, on the other hand, is one of the few areas where past work does nd evi- dence of local discretion (Gerber and Hopkins 2011). We should therefore expect local governments to exercise discre- tion over law enforcement revenue as well. In this paper, we examine city governmentsuse of nes and court fees, a policy that disproportionately harms black voters. 3 Using data on over 9,000 cities, we show that the use of nes as revenue is both commonplace and robustly con- nected to the proportion of residents who are black: 86% of the cities in our sample obtain at least some revenue through nes and fees, with an average of about $8.00 per capita, and this is higher in cities with larger black populationsup to about $20.00 higher per capitawhen we compare cities with the lowest black populations to the highest. We then show that the relationship between black pop- ulation and nes is conditioned by black representation on the city council. Previous studies show that politicians are Michael W. Sances is assistant professor in the Department of Political Science at University of Memphis, Memphis, TN 38152. Hye Young You is assistant professor in the Department of Political Science at Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN 37203. Data and supporting materials necessary to reproduce the numerical results in the paper are available in the JOP Dataverse (https://dataverse.harvard .edu/dataverse/jop). An online appendix with supplementary material is available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/691354. 1. US Department of Justice, Civil Rights Division, Investigation of the Ferguson Police Department,March 4, 2015. 2. For instance, in Normandy, a city near Ferguson, 38% of revenue came from nes and court costs in 2013 (Contesting Trafc Fines, Missouri Sues 13 Suburbs of St. Louis,New York Times, December 18, 2014). 3. There is evidence that trafc and pedestrian stops that could lead to nes and fees are racially concentrated (Gelman et al. 2007; Weaver and Lerman 2010). See also the report of the Missouri state attorney general, 2014 Vehicle Stops Executive Summary,Missouri Attorney Generals Ofce, https:// ago.mo.gov/home/vehicle-stops-report/2014-executive-summary/ (accessed May 8, 2017). The Journal of Politics, volume 79, number 3. Published online May 11, 2017. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/691354 q 2017 by the Southern Political Science Association. All rights reserved. 0022-3816/2017/7903-0025$10.00 1090

Upload: others

Post on 05-Jan-2022

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

S H O R T A R T I C L E

Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representationand Exploitative Revenue Sources

Michael W. Sances, University of MemphisHye Young You, Vanderbilt University

We examine US city governments’ use of fines and court fees for local revenue, a policy that disproportionately affects

black voters, and the connections between this policy and black representation. Using data on over 9,000 cities, we show

that the use of fines as revenue is common and that it is robustly related to the share of city residents who are black. We

also find that black representation on city councils diminishes the connection between black population and fines rev-

enue. Our findings speak to the potential of descriptive representation to alleviate biases in city policy.

Much recent public discussion focuses on racial dis-crimination by local officials and not only in termsof police violence. According to a US Justice De-

partment report in the wake of the Michael Brown shootingin Ferguson, Missouri—a city with a majority black popula-tion but amajority white government—city officials urged thepolice chief to generate more revenue from traffic tickets andcourt fines to address a substantial sales tax shortfall. Indeed,about 20% of Ferguson’s revenues come from fines and re-lated sources.1 Other observers note that the dependence onfines is not unique to Ferguson but also occurs in other Mis-souri communities.2

Scholars have extensively documented racial bias in pe-destrian stops by law enforcement (Epp, Maynard-Moody,and Haider-Markel 2014; Gelman, Fagan, and Kiss 2007;Weaver and Lerman 2010), elected officials’ response to con-stituent requests (Butler andBroockman2011;White,Nathan,and Faller 2015), and public service delivery by bureaucrats(Einstein andGlick 2016; Ernst, Nguyen, and Taylor 2013). Incontrast, bias in the form of local revenue generation is rarely

discussed in this literature, perhaps because city officials areassumed to be limited in their policy discretion (Ferreira andGyourko 2009; Peterson 1981). Police spending, on the otherhand, is one of the few areas where past work does find evi-dence of local discretion (Gerber and Hopkins 2011). Weshould therefore expect local governments to exercise discre-tion over law enforcement revenue as well.

In this paper, we examine city governments’ use of finesand court fees, a policy that disproportionately harms blackvoters.3 Using data on over 9,000 cities, we show that the useof fines as revenue is both commonplace and robustly con-nected to the proportion of residents who are black: 86% ofthe cities in our sample obtain at least some revenue throughfines and fees, with an average of about $8.00 per capita, andthis is higher in cities with larger black populations—up toabout $20.00 higher per capita—when we compare cities withthe lowest black populations to the highest.

We then show that the relationship between black pop-ulation and fines is conditioned by black representation onthe city council. Previous studies show that politicians are

Michael W. Sances is assistant professor in the Department of Political Science at University of Memphis, Memphis, TN 38152. Hye Young You is assistantprofessor in the Department of Political Science at Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN 37203.

Data and supporting materials necessary to reproduce the numerical results in the paper are available in the JOP Dataverse (https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataverse/jop). An online appendix with supplementary material is available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/691354.

1. US Department of Justice, Civil Rights Division, “Investigation of the Ferguson Police Department,” March 4, 2015.

2. For instance, in Normandy, a city near Ferguson, 38% of revenue came from fines and court costs in 2013 (“Contesting Traffic Fines, Missouri Sues 13Suburbs of St. Louis,” New York Times, December 18, 2014).

3. There is evidence that traffic and pedestrian stops that could lead to fines and fees are racially concentrated (Gelman et al. 2007; Weaver and Lerman2010). See also the report of the Missouri state attorney general, “2014 Vehicle Stops Executive Summary,” Missouri Attorney General’s Office, https://ago.mo.gov/home/vehicle-stops-report/2014-executive-summary/ (accessed May 8, 2017).

The Journal of Politics, volume 79, number 3. Published online May 11, 2017. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/691354q 2017 by the Southern Political Science Association. All rights reserved. 0022-3816/2017/7903-0025$10.00 1090

Page 2: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

more likely to address issues relevant to constituents sharingsimilar descriptive traits (Broockman 2013) and that constit-uents disproportionately communicate more to same-racerepresentatives (Broockman 2014; Gay 2002). If the presenceof black representatives on city councils gives black citizens achannel to deliver complaints and concerns regarding un-equal treatment, descriptive representation may reduce acity’s use of fines. Alternatively, a black councilor could mon-itor the degree to which the budget depends on exploitativesources. Consistent with past findings that descriptive rep-resentation matters for city policy (Eisinger 1982; Mladenka1989; Stein 1986), we find that the presence of black councilmembers significantly reduces the relationship between raceand fines.

DATATo measure cities’ use of fines, we use the Census of Govern-ments (COG), a project of the US Census Bureau that col-lects revenue and expenditure data for all local governmentsevery five years. The COG asks cities howmuch revenue theycollect from “penalties imposed for violation of law; civilpenalties (e.g., for violating court orders); court fees if leviedupon conviction of a crime or violation . . . and forfeits ofdeposits held for performance guarantees or against loss ordamage (such as forfeited bail and collateral).” This variableonly includes penalties related to matters of law, and it doesnot include “penalties relating to tax delinquency; libraryfines; and sale of confiscated property” (US Census Bureau2011). We use the COG data from 2012.4 Of the 35,000 city,town, and township governments in the COG, we focus onthose with police and/or court systems only, as only thesegovernments have the capacity to issue fines, and we alsorestrict the sample to cities with populations of at least2,500.5 The resulting sample consists of 9,143 observations.

Because the raw amount of fine revenues is skewed, wedivide by city population, and we then take the logarithm plusone. We present the distribution of this variable in figure 1A,which shows that the majority of cities collect at least somerevenue fromfines and fees. Although 1,252 of the cities in our

sample report collecting zero revenue from fines, 7,891, or86%, collect greater than zero revenues.6 Among the full sam-ple, the average collection is about $8.00 per person (amongcities with greater than zero fines revenue, the average is$11.00). There is also substantial variation in the collectionof fines: it varies from a few cents to a few hundred dollarsper person.7

FINES, RACE, AND REPRESENTATIONWe combine our fines data with population information fromthe 2010 US Census. Figure 1B displays the relationship be-tween fine revenue and the proportion of a city’s populationthat is black (we log this variable as well, as it is similarlyskewed). This figure shows a clear positive relationship be-tween the two variables.

To account for potential confounding—cities with highblack populations may also differ in other ways that impactfines use—we next conduct a series of linear regressions of(log) fines per capita on (log) percent black population; wescale black population such that zero is the sample mini-mum and one is the sample maximum. We include a set ofmunicipal- and county-level variables meant to capture otherdeterminants offines thatmay also be related to percent blackpopulation: local finances (total local revenue, share of rev-enue from taxes, share of revenue from state and federal),demographics (log population, log population density, in-come per capita, share with a college degree, share overage 65), and county-level characteristics (crime per capita,police officers per capita, share Democratic vote in 2012,number of governments per capita, net migration). Notably,our set of demographic controls includes other measures ofethnic and racial diversity, including a Herfindahl index(Alesina, Baqir, and Easterly 1999), Theil’s measure of seg-regation (Theil 1972; Trounstine 2016), and the proportionsHispanic and foreign-born.

We summarize the results in table 1; we include the fullresults in the appendix (available online). In all specifica-tions, the point estimates on percent black population arestatistically significant: the estimates range from 1.0 to 1.5,and the smallest t-statistic is 9. Because log-log coefficients

4. While the data on fines revenue are available for both 2007 and 2012,we do not exploit the panel data structure because there is little variationwithin a city in terms of revenues from fines over the five-year period.

5. We code a city as having police or courts if the city reports spendingmore than zero dollars on either service. Based on our correspondence withthe Census Bureau, using the spending data is the best available method fordetermining which general purpose funds governments provide for whatservices. We focus on cities with at least 2,500 persons, as this is the con-ventional definition of urban areas used by the Census and many otherscholars (e.g., Boustan et al. 2013). In the appendix, we show that we achievesimilar results when we use all 35,000 observations, most of which have avalue of zero on the dependent variable.

6. Cities may report zero revenue from fines for several reasons. Theymay issue fines but not use them as a general revenue source (perhapsinstead putting the money in a separate state or local fund), they may haveissued no fines, or they may misreport. In the appendix, we show thatpopulation and income are the biggest predictors of having any revenuesfrom fines and fees. We also estimate a selection model for robustness,finding similar results.

7. On average, revenues from fines and fee make up 2% of a city’s ownrevenues. In the appendix, we replicate our findings using the fine revenueshare as the outcome variable.

Volume 79 Number 3 July 2017 / 1091

Page 3: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

are difficult to interpret (and more so when one of the un-transformed variables is a proportion), we translate the co-efficients to dollar amounts in the footer (we describe theprocedure for transforming the coefficients in the appendix).Substantively, the estimates imply that cities with the largestshare of black residents collect between $12.00 and $19.00more, per person, than cities with the smallest black share ofresidents.

While data limitations prevent us from ruling out unob-servable city-level confounders—we lack enough panel vari-ation to implement a difference-in-differences design and thecity council election data for a discontinuity design are un-available—in the appendix we re-estimate the regression intable 1 while including state-level and county-level fixed ef-fects. This specification controls for all possible unobservedconfounding variables, provided that they vary at the statelevel or the county level. The relationship between race andfines is robust to these strategies. Thus, while strong con-clusions regarding causality would be unwise here, we dodemonstrate a strong, robust relationship that is consistentwith a causal effect. Also in the appendix, we show that ourestimates are robust to clustering errors at the county level,that the impact of race is seen in both large (above 10,000 per-sons) and small (less than 10,000 persons) cities, and that theresults are unchanged when using a two-stage selection modelto account for cities reporting zero fines revenue.

To explore the moderating effect of descriptive repre-sentation, we use data on city councilor races from the 2006and 2011 International City/County Management Associa-tion (ICMA). Unlike the COG, not all cities respond to theICMA surveys; those that do so tend to be larger, and our

sample reduces to about 3,700 cities after merging with theICMA. However, we are able to replicate the results fromtable 1 on this smaller subsample, which suggests that anypatterns evident using this subset of cities would likely holdin the full sample. We estimate the impact of descriptive rep-resentation by interacting the share of the population that isblack with the presence of at least one black city councilor, us-ing the same set of control variables as before. The interac-tion represents how the relationship between fines and blackpopulation changes when moving from no black councilor

Figure 1. Distribution of fines per capita and relationship with black population. Sample is all US cities that spend more than zero on law enforcement. The

dashed vertical line in panel A denotes the sample average, the solid line in panel B represents the regression line, and the dashed line in panel B is a lowess

line. Both fines and black population are logged, with the scales exponentiated for readability. The number of observations in each figure is 9,143.

Table 1. Revenue from Fines and Black Population inUS Cities

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Percent blackpopulation 1.47*** 1.35*** 1.16*** 1.02***

(.06) (.06) (.12) (.12)Effect size ($) 18.91 16.79 13.65 11.59

(1.08) (1.04) (1.98) (1.78)Controls:

Local finances Yes Yes YesDemographics Yes YesCrime, fragmen-tation, mobility,Democratic vote Yes

Note. The sample size is 8,665 for all specifications. Robust standarderrors are in parentheses.* p ! .05.** p ! .01.*** p ! .001.

1092 / Representation and Exploitative Revenue Sources Michael W. Sances and Hye Young You

Page 4: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

to having at least one black councilor. If this interaction isnegative, the presence of minority city council membersreduces the relationship between fines and race.

In the first two columns of table 2, we report specifica-tions where we exclude the interaction terms. The relation-ship between fines and black population holds in the relativelysmaller subsample of cities for which we can obtain data oncity council race. The lack of an unconditional effect for blackcouncilor suggests that black representatives’ own prefer-ences play only a limited role in revenue collection. In con-trast, the third and fourth columns include the interactionbetween black population and an indicator for the presence ofat least one black councilor. As predicted, the interactions arenegative. Comparing the magnitudes of the coefficients, therelationship between race and fines is 50% less in cities with atleast one black representative.8

It is important to note that our results do not indicate thatthe presence of a black council member completely elimi-nates the relationship between race and fines. The baselinerelationship between black population and reliance on finesholds, albeit at a substantially reduced magnitude, even whendescriptive representation is achieved. Although local gov-ernment officials may decide the overall portfolio of revenuesources, street-level bureaucrats also wield significant discre-tion (Lipsky 2010), and their own biases could affect who re-ceive traffic tickets and other penalties, as previous researchsuggests (Antonovics and Knight 2009).

DISCUSSIONAssembling a new data set on fines use and using variation indescriptive representation, we find municipal governmentswith higher black populations rely more heavily on fines andfees for revenue. Further, we find that the presence of blackcity council members significantly reduces—though doesnot eliminate—this pattern. While data limitations preventus from implementing more credible designs, the robustrelationships we observe are consistent with race playing acrucial causal role in the degree to which cities rely on re-gressive revenue sources.

Aside from regressivity (Harris, Evans, and Beckett 2010),policing for revenue may disenfranchise. Contact with lawenforcement decreases democratic participation (Lerman andWeaver 2014; Weaver and Lerman 2010), and that fines andfees are often implemented in a racially biased fashion mayhelp explain why turnout is lower among poor minority vot-ers (Hajnal 2009). While descriptive representation at the citycouncil level decreases fine use, fines may make descriptiverepresentation less likely by depressing minority turnout(Hajnal and Trounstine 2005).

Future work should explore themechanisms that producethese patterns. One interpretation of our results is that cash-strapped cities target poor andminority voters simply becausethey are less likely to complain and not due to any inherentbias. An alternative interpretation, however, is that fines andother law enforcement policies are intended as methods of so-cial control (Soss, Fording, and Schram 2008). We encouragefuture studies that explicitly attempt to untangle these twoexplanations.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTSWe thank Larry Bartels, Amanda Clayton, Joshua Clinton,Adam Dynes, Marc Hetherington, Dave Lewis, Bruce Op-penheimer, Jessica Trounstine, Alan Wiseman, and seminarparticipants at the 2016 Southern Political ScienceAssociationconference for comments. We also thank Jessica Trounstinefor sharing data.

REFERENCESAlesina, Alberto, Reza Baqir, and William Easterly. 1999. “Public Goods and

Ethinic Divisions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (4): 1243–84.Antonovics, Kate, and Brian Knight. 2009. “A New Look at Racial Pro-

filing: Evidence from the Boston Police Department.” Review of Eco-nomics and Statistics 91 (1): 163–77.

Boustan, Leah, Fernando Ferreira, Hernan Winkler, and Eric Zolt. 2013.“The Effect of Rising Income Inequality on Taxation and Public Ex-penditures: Evidence from U.S. Municipalities and School Districts,1970–2000.” Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (4): 1291–1302.

Broockman, David. 2013. “Black Politicians AreMore IntrinsicallyMotivatedto Advance Blacks’ Interests: A Field Experiment Manipulating PoliticalIncentives.” American Journal of Political Science 57 (3): 521–36.

Table 2. Revenue from Fines and Black Representation onCity Councils

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Percent blackpopulation 1.26*** 1.00*** 1.50*** 1.00***

(.12) (.19) (.14) (.19)Any black council 2.13 2.09 .39** .23

(.07) (.07) (.14) (.15)Black population #

any black council 2.94*** 2.61*(.25) (.28)

Controls Yes Yes

Note. The sample size is 3,764 in all specifications. Robust standard errorsare in parentheses.* p ! .05.** p ! .01.*** p ! .001.

8. Calculations of substantive magnitudes are available in the ap-pendix, as are results using interactions with the share of the council thatis black. The appendix also presents results that relax the assumption of alinear relationship between race and fines.

Volume 79 Number 3 July 2017 / 1093

Page 5: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Broockman, David. 2014. “Distorted Communication, Unequal Repre-sentation: Constituents Communicate Less to Representatives Not ofTheir Race.” American Journal of Political Science 58 (2): 307–21.

Butler, Daniel, and David Broockman. 2011. “Do Politicians Racially Dis-criminate against Constituents? A Field Experiment on State Legisla-tors.” American Journal of Political Science 55 (3): 463–77.

Einstein, Katherine Levine, and David M. Glick. 2016. “Does Race AffectAccess to Government Services? An Experiment Exploring Street-LevelBureaucrats and Access to Public Housing.” American Journal of Po-litical Science 61 (1): 100–116.

Eisinger, Peter. 1982. “Black Employment in Municipal Jobs: The Impactof Black Political Power.” American Political Science Review 76 (2):380–92.

Epp, Charles R., Steven Maynard-Moody, and Donald P. Haider-Markel.2014. Pulled Over: How Police Stops Define Race and Citizenship. Chicago:University of Chicago Press.

Ernst, Rose, Linda Nguyen, and Kamilah Taylor. 2013. “Citizen Control:Race at the Welfare Office.” Social Science Quarterly 94 (5): 1283–1307.

Ferreira, Fernando, and Joseph Gyourko. 2009. “Do Political Parties Mat-ter? Evidence from U.S. Cities.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (1):399–422.

Gay, Claudine. 2002. “Spirals of Trust? The Effect of Descriptive Repre-sentation on the Relationship between Citizens and Their Govern-ment.” American Journal of Political Science 46 (4): 717–32.

Gelman, Andrew, Jeffrey Fagan, and Alex Kiss. 2007. “An Analysis of theNew York City Police Department’s ‘Stop-and-Frisk’ Policy in the Con-text of Claims of Racial Bias.” Journal of the American Statistical Asso-ciation 102 (479): 813–23.

Gerber, Elizabeth, and Daniel Hopkins. 2011. “When Mayors Matter: Es-timating the Impact of Mayoral Partisanship on City Policy.” AmericanJournal of Political Science 55 (2): 326–39.

Hajnal, Zoltan. 2009.America’s Uneven Democracy. Cambridge: CambridgeUniversity Press.

Hajnal, Zoltan, and Jessica Trounstine. 2005. “Where Turnout Matters:The Consequences of Uneven Turnout in City Politics.” Journal ofPolitics 67 (2): 515–35.

Harris, Alexes, Heather Evans, and Katherine Beckett. 2010. “DrawingBlood from Stones: Legal Debt and Social Inequality in the Contem-porary United States.” American Journal of Sociology 115 (6): 1753–99.

Lerman, Amy E., and Vesla Weaver. 2014. “Staying Out of Sight? Con-centrated Policing and Local Political Action.” ANNALS of the Amer-ican Academy of Political and Social Science 651 (1): 202–19.

Lipsky, Michael. 2010. Street-Level Bureaucracy: Dilemmas of the Indi-vidual in Public Service. 30th anniversary edition. New York: RussellSage Foundation.

Mladenka, Kenneth. 1989. “Blacks and Hispanics in Urban Politics.” Amer-ican Political Science Review 83 (1): 165–91.

Peterson, Paul. 1981. City Limits. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Soss, Joe, Richard C. Fording, and Sanford F. Schram. 2008. “The Color

of Devolution: Race, Federalism, and the Politics of Social Control.”American Journal of Political Science 52 (3): 536–53.

Stein, Lana. 1986. “Representative Local Government: Minorities in theMunicipal Work Force.” Journal of Politics 48 (3): 694–713.

Theil, Henri. 1972. Statistical Decomposition Analysis: With Applicationsin the Social and Administrative Sciences. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

Trounstine, Jessica. 2016. “Segregation and Inequality in Public Goods.”American Journal of Political Science 60 (3): 709–25.

US Census Bureau. 2011. “Government Finance and Employment Classi-fication Manual: Descriptions of Miscellaneous General RevenueCategories.” https://www.census.gov/govs/www/class_ch7_misc.html.(accessed May 8, 2017).

Weaver, Vesla M., and Amy E. Lerman. 2010. “Political Consequences ofthe Carceral State.” American Political Science Review 104 (4): 817–33.

White, Ariel, Noah Nathan, and Julie Faller. 2015. “What Do I Need toVote? Bureaucratic Discretion and Discrimination by Local ElectedOfficials.” American Political Science Review 109 (1): 129–42.

1094 / Representation and Exploitative Revenue Sources Michael W. Sances and Hye Young You

Page 6: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Online Appendix to “Who Pays for Government?

Descriptive Representation and Exploitative Revenue

Sources”

Michael W. Sances∗ Hye Young You†

∗Michael W. Sances ([email protected]) is assistant professor in the Department ofPolitical Science at University of Memphis, Memphis, TN 38152.†Hye Young You ([email protected]) is assistant professor in the Depart-

ment of Political Science at Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN 37203.

Page 7: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Relationship Between Fines and Percent Black in the

Full Sample

In this section we report the relationship between fines and percent black in the full sample

of 36,147 general purpose governments from the 2012 Census of Governments. We show

this relation in Figure A1.

A1

Page 8: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

0

12

5

10

20

35

100

500

Fin

e r

eve

nu

e p

er

ca

pita

0 1 5 10 25 50 100

Percent black population

Figure A1: Revenue from fines and the racial composition of cities: results from all generalpurpose governments.

A2

Page 9: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Regressions Predicting Sample Inclusion and Any Fines

Revenue

In this section we describe how our sample cities may differ from the population of roughly

34,000 municipalities in the COG. First, we regress an indicator for sample inclusion –

defined as 1 if a city spends more than zero on courts and/or police, and if the city’s 2010

population is greater than or equal to 2,500 persons, and 0 if these two conditions do not

both hold – on the full set of controls we use in the main analyses. Second, we change the

outcome to an indicator for whether the city reports collecting any revenue from fines.

We show these regressions in Table A1. We scale all right-hand side variables such that

a zero represents the sample minimum and one represents the sample maximum.

A3

Page 10: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

(1) (2)Sample inclusion Any fines revenue

Percent black population 0.17∗∗∗ 0.17∗∗∗

(0.01) (0.03)Total own-source revenue pcp 0.37 0.04

(0.37) (0.17)Pct revenue from taxes -0.11∗∗∗ -0.11∗∗∗

(0.01) (0.02)Pct revenue from state and fed -0.04∗∗∗ -0.05

(0.01) (0.03)Log population 2.39∗∗∗ 0.25∗∗∗

(0.02) (0.03)Population density 1.11∗∗∗ 0.55∗∗∗

(0.13) (0.10)Income per capita 0.78∗∗∗ 0.42∗∗∗

(0.07) (0.06)Pct college educated 0.32∗∗∗ -0.15∗∗∗

(0.02) (0.04)Pct age 65+ 0.09∗∗∗ 0.10

(0.02) (0.06)Segregation 0.04 -0.04

(0.04) (0.05)Percent Hispanic 0.09∗∗∗ 0.07∗

(0.02) (0.03)Herfindahl index -0.05∗∗ -0.13∗∗∗

(0.02) (0.04)Percent foreign born 0.25∗∗∗ 0.12∗∗

(0.04) (0.05)Crime per-capita 0.49∗∗∗ -0.10∗

(0.03) (0.05)Police officers per-capita -0.02 -0.08

(0.03) (0.05)Democratic vote share 0.03∗∗ -0.03

(0.01) (0.03)Govs per 1,000 persons 0.80∗∗∗ -0.19∗

(0.02) (0.08)Net migration rate 0.14∗∗∗ -0.16∗∗

(0.03) (0.05)Constant -0.92∗∗∗ 0.89∗∗∗

(0.01) (0.03)Sample size 34,108 8,665R-squared 0.56 0.05

Table A1: Regressions predicting indicators for sample inclusion and any revenue fromfines. Robust standard errors in parentheses. * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001.

A4

Page 11: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Computing Substantive Effect Sizes

Because our main regression results use a log-transformed variable as both the dependent

and independent variable, expressing the effect in substantive terms requires transforming

it back into the original scale. To do this, we calculate predicted values for the outcome

variable when black is one and take the average, then exponentiate this average. We then

repeat this procedure for the outcome when black is zero. We then take the difference

between these two quantities. Formally, where X is a vector of sample averages for our

covariates, we calculate

exp (Y1)− exp (Y0),

where

Y1 = E[Fines Per Capitai|Percent Black Populationi = 1]

= α + β + γX

Y0 = E[Fines Per Capitai|Percent Black Populationi = 0]

= α + γX

When standard errors are presented, we calculate these by bootstrapping the above pro-

cedure for 500 iterations.

A5

Page 12: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Robustness Checks for Table 1

In this section we show the relationship between black population and fines is robust to

alternative specifications. Table A2 shows the results. For row (7), we estimate a two-

stage selection model where, in the first stage, we estimate the probability of collecting

any fines, and in the second stage the outcome is logged fines revenue per capita as before.

We use the same set of predictors in each stage.

A6

Page 13: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Estimate(s.e.)

(1) Baseline 1.02∗∗∗

(0.12)(2) State Fixed Effects 1.02∗∗∗

(0.13)(3) County Fixed Effects 1.04∗∗∗

(0.21)(4) County-Clustered Standard Errors 1.02∗∗∗

(0.17)(5) Population Under 10,000 0.92∗∗∗

(0.17)(6) Population Over 10,000 0.91∗∗∗

(0.18)(7) Selection Model 0.68∗∗∗

(0.11)

Table A2: Robustness checks for Table 1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001.

A7

Page 14: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Full Regression Results from Tables 1 and 2

In this section we show estimates and standard errors for all the predictors used in the

regressions summarized in Table 1 and 2 in the main text. All predictors are scaled such

that zero is the sample minimum and one is the sample maximum. Table A3 shows the

full results for Table 1; Table A4 shows the results for Table 2, as well as specifications

where use use the share of the council that is black instead of an indicator (columns

(5) and (6)). Note we obtain essentially the same point estimates using the continuous

measure, where the point estimate represents moving from no black councilors to a fully

black council. However, given so few of our cities have even one black councilor, we do

not believe we are actually capturing the impact of a change as dramatic as moving from

none to all.

A8

Page 15: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

(1) (2) (3) (4)Percent black population 1.47∗∗∗ 1.35∗∗∗ 1.16∗∗∗ 1.02∗∗∗

(0.06) (0.06) (0.12) (0.12)Total own-source revenue pcp 8.75∗ 6.49∗ 6.37∗∗

(3.59) (2.55) (2.46)Pct revenue from taxes -0.39∗∗∗ -0.73∗∗∗ -0.69∗∗∗

(0.08) (0.08) (0.08)Pct revenue from state and fed -0.53∗∗∗ -0.11 -0.03

(0.12) (0.11) (0.11)Log population 0.01 -0.00

(0.13) (0.13)Population density 4.38∗∗∗ 4.69∗∗∗

(0.53) (0.59)Income per capita 2.44∗∗∗ 2.46∗∗∗

(0.25) (0.26)Pct college educated -0.24 -0.15

(0.14) (0.14)Pct age 65+ 0.06 0.12

(0.23) (0.23)Percent Hispanic 0.61∗∗∗ 0.56∗∗∗

(0.13) (0.13)Percent foreign born 0.56∗∗ 0.74∗∗∗

(0.20) (0.20)Herfindahl index 0.18 0.26

(0.14) (0.14)Segregation -0.00 0.04

(0.20) (0.20)Crime per-capita 0.25

(0.24)Police officers per-capita 0.75∗∗∗

(0.19)Democratic vote share -0.87∗∗∗

(0.10)Govs per 1,000 persons -0.89∗∗∗

(0.25)Net migration rate -0.47∗

(0.18)Constant 1.74∗∗∗ 1.98∗∗∗ 1.51∗∗∗ 1.92∗∗∗

(0.02) (0.09) (0.08) (0.12)Sample size 8,665 8,665 8,665 8,665R-squared 0.08 0.11 0.17 0.18

Table A3: Full regression output from Table 1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001.

A9

Page 16: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Percent black population 1.26∗∗∗ 1.00∗∗∗ 1.50∗∗∗ 1.00∗∗∗ 1.47∗∗∗ 0.98∗∗∗(0.12) (0.19) (0.14) (0.19) (0.14) (0.18)

Any black council -0.13 -0.09 0.39∗∗ 0.23(0.07) (0.07) (0.14) (0.15)

Black pop X any black council -0.94∗∗∗ -0.61∗(0.25) (0.28)

Percent black council 0.41 0.20(0.22) (0.22)

Black pop X black council -1.06∗∗ -0.64(0.33) (0.37)

Total own-source revenue pcp 4.33∗∗ 4.35∗ 4.36∗(1.66) (1.70) (1.70)

Pct revenue from taxes -0.55∗∗∗ -0.55∗∗∗ -0.54∗∗∗(0.11) (0.11) (0.11)

Pct revenue from state and fed -0.01 -0.00 -0.00(0.18) (0.18) (0.18)

Log population 0.00 -0.05 -0.05(0.20) (0.20) (0.20)

Population density 5.90∗∗∗ 5.95∗∗∗ 5.96∗∗∗(1.24) (1.24) (1.24)

Income per capita 2.53∗∗∗ 2.53∗∗∗ 2.53∗∗∗(0.36) (0.36) (0.36)

Pct college educated -0.27 -0.28 -0.28(0.21) (0.21) (0.21)

Pct age 65+ -0.61 -0.57 -0.57(0.33) (0.33) (0.33)

Crime per-capita -1.04∗∗ -1.07∗∗ -1.08∗∗(0.35) (0.35) (0.35)

Police officers per-capita 0.76∗ 0.81∗∗ 0.80∗∗(0.30) (0.30) (0.30)

Democratic vote share -0.72∗∗∗ -0.71∗∗∗ -0.70∗∗∗(0.15) (0.15) (0.15)

Govs per 1,000 persons -1.02∗ -1.04∗∗ -1.04∗∗(0.40) (0.40) (0.40)

Net migration rate -0.46 -0.47 -0.48∗(0.24) (0.24) (0.24)

Segregation 0.49 0.55 0.55(0.30) (0.30) (0.31)

Percent Hispanic 0.67∗∗∗ 0.60∗∗ 0.60∗∗(0.18) (0.19) (0.19)

Herfindahl index 0.10 0.34 0.33(0.22) (0.24) (0.25)

Percent foreign born 0.23 0.09 0.09(0.31) (0.32) (0.32)

Constant 1.96∗∗∗ 2.18∗∗∗ 1.90∗∗∗ 2.15∗∗∗ 1.90∗∗∗ 2.16∗∗∗(0.04) (0.16) (0.04) (0.17) (0.04) (0.17)

Sample size 3,764 3,764 3,764 3,764 3,764 3,764R-squared 0.05 0.14 0.05 0.14 0.05 0.14

Table A4: Full regression output from Table 2. Robust standard errors in parentheses. *p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001.

A10

Page 17: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Substantive Effect of Descriptive Representation

To illustrate the substantive magnitude of these results, we use our regression coefficients

to compute marginal effects. We use coefficient estimates from the specification reported

in column (5), which uses an indicator for any black representation, as moving from zero

to one on this measure is more realistic than changing from an all-white to an all-black

council. Given that our dependent variable is logged, we translate the marginal effects

back into dollar amounts by exponentiating predicted values.

That is, for varying levels of black population, we compute the marginal effect of black

representation on revenue from fines,

exp (Y1,x)− exp (Y0,x),

where

Y1,x = E[Fines Per Capitai|Any Black Councilori = 1,

Percent Black Populationi = x]

= α + β1 + β2 ∗ x+ β3 ∗ x

Y0,x = E[Fines Per Capitai|Any Black Councilori = 0,

Percent Black Populationi = x]

= α + β2 ∗ x

We then plot estimates of these marginal effects against levels of black population in

Figure A2, with 95% confidence intervals calculated using the bootstrap (500 iterations),

which illustrates the conditional impact of black representation: in cities with entirely

white populations, going from the minimum to the maximum on black representation is

associated with an increase in fine revenues of about three dollars, per capita. As black

A11

Page 18: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

population increases, however, the sign of the effect changes, increasing in magnitude

from minus four dollar per capita in cities with twenty percent black population to over

minus thirteen dollars per capita in cities with entirely black populations. When blacks

are represented primarily by whites, the use of fines is higher; yet when blacks gain

descriptive representation on the city council, the use of fines is lessened.

In Figure A3, we reproduce this marginal effects plot using a continuous measure of

black membership on the city council, namely the percent of the city council that is black.

As with the estimates reported in Table 2 in the main text, the marginal effects are quite

similar to those obtained using the binary measure.

A12

Page 19: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

−20

−15

−10

−5

0

5

0 20 40 60 80 100

Percent black population

on

re

ve

nu

e f

rom

fin

es

Eff

ect

of

an

y b

lack c

ou

ncil

Figure A2: Fines revenue and black representation: interaction with black population.This figure plots estimates of the effect of having any black city councilor, on fines revenueper capita, for different levels of black population. Dashed lines span 95% confidenceintervals (generated by bootstrap with 500 iterations). Estimates are calculated using thecoefficient estimates from column (5) of Table 2, and are in dollars per capita terms.

A13

Page 20: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

−20

−10

0

10

0 20 40 60 80 100

Percent black population

on

re

ve

nu

e f

rom

fin

es

Eff

ect

of

pe

rce

nt

bla

ck c

ou

ncil

Figure A3: Fines revenue and black representation: interaction with black population.This figure plots estimates of the effect of the percent of the city council that is black,on fines revenue per capita, for different levels of black population. Dashed lines span95% confidence intervals (generated by bootstrap with 500 iterations). Estimates arecalculated using the coefficient estimates from column (5) of Table 2, and are in dollarsper capita terms.

A14

Page 21: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Results Using Percent of Revenue from Fines

In this section we show we obtain similar results for Figure 1, Table 1, and Table 2 in the

main text when we use the share of local revenue from fines as opposed to the amount

of fines revenue per capita. Figure A4 shows the results corresponding to Figure 1 in the

text; and Tables A5 and A6 show results corresponding to Tables 1 and 2.

A15

Page 22: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

0

500

1000

1500

2000

Nu

mb

er

of

citie

s

0 1 5 10 20 35 100

Fines as percent of total revenue

(A)

0

1

2

5

10

20

35

100

Fin

e r

eve

nu

e p

er

ca

pita

0 1 5 10 25 50 100

Percent black population

(B)

Figure A4: Distribution of fines as share of revenue and relationship with black popu-lation. Sample is all U.S. cities that report spending more than 0 on law enforcement.Dashed vertical line denotes the sample average in panel (A), and solid line represents theregression line in panel (B). Both fines and black population are logged, with the scalesexponentiated for readability. The number of observations in each figure is 9,143.

A16

Page 23: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

(1) (2) (3) (4)Percent black population 0.54∗∗∗ 0.62∗∗∗ 0.63∗∗∗ 0.55∗∗∗

(0.03) (0.03) (0.05) (0.05)Total own-source revenue pcp -5.07∗ -4.99∗ -5.03∗

(2.35) (2.36) (2.41)Pct revenue from taxes 0.16∗∗ 0.10 0.10

(0.05) (0.06) (0.06)Pct revenue from state and fed 0.65∗∗∗ 0.70∗∗∗ 0.75∗∗∗

(0.08) (0.08) (0.08)Log population -0.52∗∗∗ -0.56∗∗∗

(0.07) (0.07)Population density 1.65∗∗∗ 1.84∗∗∗

(0.27) (0.30)Income per capita 0.82∗∗∗ 0.82∗∗∗

(0.13) (0.14)Pct college educated -0.32∗∗∗ -0.27∗∗∗

(0.07) (0.07)Pct age 65+ -0.59∗∗∗ -0.53∗∗∗

(0.13) (0.13)Percent Hispanic 0.17∗ 0.14

(0.07) (0.07)Percent foreign born 0.27∗ 0.39∗∗∗

(0.11) (0.11)Herfindahl index 0.01 0.04

(0.06) (0.06)Segregation -0.15 -0.12

(0.11) (0.11)Crime per-capita 0.39∗∗

(0.12)Police officers per-capita 0.15

(0.11)Democratic vote share -0.46∗∗∗

(0.05)Govs per 1,000 persons -0.64∗∗∗

(0.11)Net migration rate -0.27∗∗

(0.09)Constant 0.54∗∗∗ 0.36∗∗∗ 0.43∗∗∗ 0.67∗∗∗

(0.01) (0.06) (0.05) (0.06)Sample size 8,665 8,665 8,665 8,665R-squared 0.04 0.10 0.13 0.14

Table A5: Share of revenue from fines, and black population. Robust standard errors inparentheses. * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001.

A17

Page 24: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Percent black population 0.74∗∗∗ 0.70∗∗∗ 0.83∗∗∗ 0.70∗∗∗ 0.82∗∗∗ 0.69∗∗∗(0.06) (0.09) (0.07) (0.09) (0.07) (0.09)

Any black council -0.16∗∗∗ -0.10∗∗ 0.03 0.01(0.04) (0.03) (0.07) (0.07)

Black pop X any black council -0.35∗∗ -0.20(0.13) (0.14)

Percent black council -0.06 -0.05(0.10) (0.11)

Black pop X black council -0.31 -0.19(0.17) (0.19)

Total own-source revenue pcp -3.16 -3.15 -3.14(1.92) (1.91) (1.90)

Pct revenue from taxes 0.18∗∗ 0.18∗∗ 0.18∗∗(0.07) (0.07) (0.07)

Pct revenue from state and fed 0.65∗∗∗ 0.65∗∗∗ 0.65∗∗∗(0.11) (0.11) (0.11)

Log population -0.48∗∗∗ -0.50∗∗∗ -0.51∗∗∗(0.10) (0.10) (0.10)

Population density 3.16∗∗∗ 3.18∗∗∗ 3.18∗∗∗(0.71) (0.71) (0.71)

Income per capita 0.77∗∗∗ 0.76∗∗∗ 0.76∗∗∗(0.17) (0.17) (0.17)

Pct college educated -0.17 -0.17 -0.18(0.10) (0.10) (0.10)

Pct age 65+ -0.96∗∗∗ -0.95∗∗∗ -0.95∗∗∗(0.17) (0.17) (0.17)

Percent Hispanic 0.32∗∗ 0.30∗∗ 0.30∗∗(0.10) (0.10) (0.10)

Percent foreign born 0.06 0.01 0.00(0.17) (0.17) (0.17)

Herfindahl index -0.06 0.02 0.03(0.11) (0.12) (0.13)

Segregation -0.02 0.00 0.01(0.16) (0.16) (0.16)

Crime per-capita -0.25 -0.26 -0.27(0.16) (0.16) (0.16)

Police officers per-capita 0.12 0.13 0.13(0.13) (0.13) (0.13)

Democratic vote share -0.38∗∗∗ -0.37∗∗∗ -0.37∗∗∗(0.07) (0.07) (0.07)

Govs per 1,000 persons -0.63∗∗∗ -0.64∗∗∗ -0.64∗∗∗(0.18) (0.18) (0.18)

Net migration rate -0.16 -0.16 -0.17(0.12) (0.12) (0.12)

Constant 0.54∗∗∗ 0.70∗∗∗ 0.52∗∗∗ 0.69∗∗∗ 0.52∗∗∗ 0.69∗∗∗(0.02) (0.08) (0.02) (0.08) (0.02) (0.08)

Sample size 3,764 3,764 3,764 3,764 3,764 3,764R-squared 0.05 0.17 0.06 0.17 0.06 0.17

Table A6: Share of revenue from fines, and black representation. Robust standard errorsin parentheses. * p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001.

A18

Page 25: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Fines and Representation: Non-Parametric Results

In this section we show the results in Table 2 in the main text are robust to relaxing the

assumption of a linear relationship between black population and fines. In Figure A5 we

plot fines per capita against percent black for cities without (left panel) and with (right

panel) any black councilor. Whether using a linear specification or a lowess smoother,

we see the relationship between fines and race is weaker in cities with at least one black

councilor.

One concern raised by plotting the raw data is whether the interaction we observe is

an artifact of differences in the distribution of the independent variable (percent black

population) between cities with and without a black councilor. Thus in Figure A6 we

show the average level of fines per capita for each quintile of black population, for cities

with and without a black councilor. Importantly, we calculate the quintiles separately for

each group of cities, such that a change across quintiles is comparable between the two

groups. (Using the same quintiles for each group gives similar results.) We find results

that are similar to the linear models in the text, and the lowess estimates in Figure A5.

Next, rather than using an interaction, we examine the relationship between fines

revenue and a measure of black underrepresentation: the difference between the share of

the population that is black, and the share of the city council that is black.1 We show

the bivariate relationship in Figure A7, and we estimate regressions with and without

covariates in Table A7. We find similar results using this alternative measure: cities with

the highest levels of underrepresentation collect about 12 dollars more per capita than

cities with the lowest levels when we omit controls, an 5 dollars more per capita when we

include controls.

1We code the few cities that are “overrepresented” – where the black council share exceeds

the black population share – as zero, though results are similar if we do not.

A19

Page 26: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

0

1

2

5

10

20

35

100

500

0 1 5 10 25 50 100 0 1 5 10 25 50 100

No black councilor At least one black councilor

Fin

es r

eve

nu

e p

er

ca

pita

Percent black population

Figure A5: Relationship between fines and race for cities without and with any blackrepresentation. Dashed lines represent linear fits; solid lines represent moving averagescomputed using a lowess smoother.

A20

Page 27: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Without black councilor

With black councilor

5

10

15

Fin

es r

eve

nu

e p

er

ca

pita

1 2 3 4 5

Quintile of black population

Figure A6: Fines revenue per capita by quintile of black population. Points represent theaverage amount of fines revenue per capita, with lines spanning 95% confidence intervals.The top series represents cities with at least one black councilor; the bottom series rep-resents cities without any black councilors. The quintile of black population share arecomputed separately for each series.

A21

Page 28: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

0

1

2

5

10

20

35

100

500

Fin

es r

eve

nu

e p

er

ca

pita

0 1 5 10 25 50 100

Black underrepresentation

Figure A7: Revenue from fines and black underrepresentation. Dashed line represents alinear regression; solid line represents a moving average computed using a lowess smoother.Black underrepresentation is the difference between the share of the population that isblack and the share of the city council that is black.

A22

Page 29: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

(1) (2)Percent black population 0.88*** 0.42***

(0.10) (0.11)

Effect size ($) 11.82 4.96(1.74) (1.31)

Controls X

Table A7: Revenue from fines and black underrepresentation.

A23

Page 30: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

Data Sources

In this section we provide more details on our data sources, particularly the city- and

county-level covariates (for information on fines, please see the main text).

Local fiscal variables (total local revenue, the share of total revenue from taxes, and

the share of total revenue from state and federal sources) also come from the 2012 Census

of Governments. Data on demographic variables (percent black, population, population

density, income per capita, education, age, percent Hispanic, and percent foreign born)

are from the 2010 U.S. Census and the American Community Survey.

We obtained the ICMA data on city councilor race via Jessica Trounstine, who pro-

vided us with cross-sections of these data from the years 1986, 1992, 1996, 2001, 2006, and

2011. To attain a large enough number of cities regarding race for city councilors, we com-

bine observations from 2006 and 2011 in the ICMA data, yielding a sample of about 3,800

cities. Because the ICMA sample is not a panel, but is instead a repeated cross-sectional

design, we only have about 1,500 cities where we observe city councilor race in both waves.

Of these, only about 100 saw changes in the racial composition of the city council; about

half of these saw a decrease as opposed to an increase. We merge the ICMA data with the

Census of Governments data using the Federal Information Processing Standard (FIPS)

code that is available in each data set.

The regressions reported in the text also include several county-level covariates, in

cases where city-level measures are unavailable. Measures of total reported crimes per

capita come from the FBI’s Uniform Crime Reporting Program for 2012. Total police

officers per capita come from the Department of Justice’s Census of State and Local Law

Enforcement Agencies for 2008. Democratic vote share from the 2012 election is from

Congressional Quarterly’s Voting and Elections Collection. The total number of local

governments in a city’s home county, per capita, is also from the Census of Governments.

The net migration rate, an estimate based on decennial Census figures, is generated by

researchers at the Applied Population Laboratory at the University of Wisconsin (see

A24

Page 31: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

http://www.netmigration.wisc.edu), with the estimates we use coming from the 2000-

2010 interval.

Table A8 presents summary statistics for variables used in the analysis. The top panel

includes summary statistics for cities that provide law enforcement. The bottom panel

includes summary statistics for all cities included in the Census of Governments data.

A25

Page 32: Who Pays for Government? Descriptive Representation and

(a) Sample municipalitiesCount Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max.

Fines revenue per capita 9,143 18 30 0 678Fines as share of local revenue 9,143 2 3 0 88Percent black population 9,143 8 15 0 98Percent black city council 4,005 6 14 0 100Total own-source revenue pcp 9,143 1,374 1,760 8 111,169Pct revenue from taxes 9,143 56 24 0 100Pct revenue from state and fed 9,143 18 14 0 95Population 9,143 507,338 1,133,867 3,326 9,519,338Population per sq. mi. 9,143 1,842 2,340 5 57,116Income per capita 9,142 27,553 12,502 2,919 141,337Pct college educated 9,143 17 9 0 50Pct age 65+ 9,143 15 5 1 80Segregation x100 9,143 4 5 0 66Percent Hispanic 9,143 10 15 0 100Herfindahl x100 9,143 28 23 1 100Percent foreign born 9,143 7 9 0 73Crimes per 100k 9,143 494 269 0 4,172Police officers per-capita 9,142 2 2 0 25Democratic vote share 9,100 50 13 11 90Govs per 1,000 persons 8,685 0 1 0 10Net migration rate 9,086 3 10 -31 97

(b) All municipalitiesCount Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max.

Fines revenue per capita 35,445 12 88 0 10,222Fines as share of local revenue 35,202 1 5 0 100Percent black population 35,445 5 13 0 100Percent black city council 4,743 6 14 0 100Total own-source revenue pcp 35,445 964 11,857 0 1,930,759Pct revenue from taxes 35,202 63 30 0 100Pct revenue from state and fed 35,334 25 21 0 100Population 35,548 193,091 655,016 67 9,519,338Population per sq. mi. 35,447 820 1,507 0 57,116Income per capita 35,029 24,480 11,796 129 386,079Pct college educated 35,274 13 9 0 100Pct age 65+ 35,445 17 6 0 100Segregation x100 35,445 2 4 0 76Percent Hispanic 35,445 5 11 0 100Herfindahl x100 35,445 16 21 0 100Percent foreign born 35,280 3 6 0 100Crimes per 100k 35,543 389 281 0 4,172Police officers per-capita 35,514 2 1 0 31Democratic vote share 35,464 46 12 5 90Govs per 1,000 persons 34,875 2 3 0 39Net migration rate 35,511 1 9 -47 97

Table A8: Summary statistics.

A26