we revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

27
econstor Make Your Publications Visible. A Service of zbw Leibniz-Informationszentrum Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre for Economics Fabella, Raul V. Working Paper Why fixed rent contracts are less prevalent: Weak third party enforcement and endogenous principal type UPSE Discussion Paper, No. 2016-06 Provided in Cooperation with: University of the Philippines School of Economics (UPSE) Suggested Citation: Fabella, Raul V. (2016) : Why fixed rent contracts are less prevalent: Weak third party enforcement and endogenous principal type, UPSE Discussion Paper, No. 2016-06, University of the Philippines, School of Economics (UPSE), Quezon City This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/162632 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. Terms of use: Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your personal and scholarly purposes. You are not to copy documents for public or commercial purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. If the documents have been made available under an Open Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu

Upload: others

Post on 08-Dec-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

econstorMake Your Publications Visible.

A Service of

zbwLeibniz-InformationszentrumWirtschaftLeibniz Information Centrefor Economics

Fabella, Raul V.

Working Paper

Why fixed rent contracts are less prevalent: Weakthird party enforcement and endogenous principaltype

UPSE Discussion Paper, No. 2016-06

Provided in Cooperation with:University of the Philippines School of Economics (UPSE)

Suggested Citation: Fabella, Raul V. (2016) : Why fixed rent contracts are less prevalent: Weakthird party enforcement and endogenous principal type, UPSE Discussion Paper, No. 2016-06,University of the Philippines, School of Economics (UPSE), Quezon City

This Version is available at:http://hdl.handle.net/10419/162632

Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:

Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichenZwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.

Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielleZwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglichmachen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.

Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten,gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dortgenannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte.

Terms of use:

Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for yourpersonal and scholarly purposes.

You are not to copy documents for public or commercialpurposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make thempublicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwiseuse the documents in public.

If the documents have been made available under an OpenContent Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), youmay exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicatedlicence.

www.econstor.eu

Page 2: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

UP School of Economics Discussion Papers

UPSE Discussion Papers are preliminary versions circulated privately to elicit critical comments. They are protected by Republic Act No. 8293

and are not for quotation or reprinting without prior approval.

University of the Philippines School of Economics and

National Academy of Science and Technology

Discussion Paper No. 2016-06 August 2016

Why Fixed Rent Contracts are Less Prevalent: Weak Third Party Enforcement and Endogenous Principal Type

by

Raul V. Fabella

Page 3: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

Why Fixed Rent Contracts are Less Prevalent: Weak Third Party Enforcement and Endogenous Principal Type

by

Raul V. Fabella

School of Economics University of the Philippines

Abstract

We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are less prevalent than crop share contracts despite Marshallian inefficiency. We consider the case where the type of the principal is endogenous to contract provisions and reneging by the principal may pay due to weak third party enforcement (TPE). We imbed the quality of TPE into the participation constraint of the agent in an effort-in-advance P-A model. The governance regime explicitly involves interplay of three categories of the Northian enforcement, viz., first, second and third party enforcement. Weak and strong TPE are formally defined. We show that the general contract derived nests the usual textbook contract when TPE is strong; weak TPE on the other hand results in a strictly positive induced risk aversion which always exceeds the inherent risk aversion of the agent. This prevents the power of the contract to equal one even when the agent is risk-neutral, thus, rendering a fixed-rent contract sub-optimal. JEL Classification D23, D82, D86 Key words: sharecropping, weak TPE, endogenous type, induced risk aversion Mailing address: Dr. Raul V. Fabella School of Economics University of the Philippines Diliman, Quezon City 1101 Email: [email protected]; [email protected]

Acknowledgments: The author thanks Ma. Cristina Bernido-Fabella for excellent editorial help.

Page 4: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

1. Introduction

Why are fixed rent contracts (FRC) less prevalent than mid-range agricultural

contracts, such as share contracts, despite the classical observation (Smith, 1776; Mill,

1848) made salient by Alfred Marshall’s famous footnote (1920) that input use in crop

share land will be lower than in own or leased land (see, e.g., Dubois, 2008)? Empirical

results seem to favor this view: Shaban (1987) empirically demonstrated that input use in

crop share land was significantly lower than input use in owned land and a priori in fixed

rent lands. This is corroborated by Laffont and Matuosi (1995) who show that

sharecroppers exert less effort than fixed renters. Obviously, factors other than efficiency

are at work to make share or mid-range contracting desirable. Braido (2006) however

claims that soil quality must be controlled for as crop share lands are generally of lower

quality. When such controls are employed the difference in effort by contract chosen

appears to diminish.

D. Gale Johnson (1950) argued that repeated contracting could make the

productivity of sharecropped land comparable to that under fixed rent contracts. Cheung

(1969), echoing Johnson, argued absent transactions cost sufficient competition will

mimic a competitive labor market and thus efficient; but with transactions cost such as

effort monitoring share contracts mitigates labor shirking relative to the fixed wage

contract (FWC) and allows risk sharing as against fixed rent contracts under output

volatility. Hoffman (1984) showed for example that distant lands tend to be leased by

fixed rent contracts based on historical data on 83 contracts in 16th century France. Allen

and Lueck (1992) also show a higher tendency for share contracts (SC) with lower crop

division cost. Transaction cost and agency cost was also the motivation of Roumasset and

Page 5: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

2

Uy (1987) and Roumasset (1995) for SC desirability where agents provide multiple

inputs making for high monitoring cost. Multi-task models result in moral hazard

associated with substitution of effort across tasks which sharecropping can handle better

(Luporini and Parigi, 1996). For Joseph Stiglitz (1974), SC provided the optimal tradeoff

between risk sharing and incentives for effort. But evidence for the risk sharing motive

itself is empirically mixed (Braido, 2005). Allen and Lueck (1992) using crop variability,

viz., corn and wheat, conclude that risk sharing is not compelling motive. Laffont and

Matuosi (1995) also claim that tenant’s wealth, a proxy for risk aversion, does not figure

as determinant in the power of contracts in Tunisia. By contrast, Ackerberg and Botticini

(2002), by accounting for the endogeneity of contract choice, find a positive correlation

between the tenant’s contract share and the tenants’ wealth in support of the insurance

motive assuming that wealth is a good proxy for risk aversion. Dubois (2002) also show

that measured risk aversion index correlates positively with lower powered contracts after

controlling for the endogeneity of contract choice. Dubois (2002; 2008) following

Johnson (1950) and Adam Smith (1776) shows how non-contractible land quality can

explain sharecropping when this enters separately into the landlord’s utility function.

Dubois shows that a fixed rent contract is not optimal even with risk neutral tenant.

Limited liability, which motivates the tenant’s willingness to take on more risk under a

high powered contract, is a possible motive for SC (Shetty (1988). Ghatak and Pandey

(2000) combines limited liability and a multi-task feature to show that optimal tenancy

contract with joint moral hazard in effort and output risk even without risk neutrality of

tenants.

Page 6: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

3

Skill level may be a crucial contract choice factor. Eswaran and Kotwal (1985)

deduced SCs where unobserved skills of the players affect output. Muthoo (1998)

showed that, starting from moral hazard on the tenant’s skill level, no uncertainty and full

risk-neutrality, FRCs are best for tenants with high skill level while those with low skills

work for SC or FWC in the no-renegotiation regime; FRC is only a possibility absent the

no-renegotiation condition. Sen (2011) employed price volatility and imperfect

competition in the rural product markets to show that the unique contract type robust to

the emergence of third agent competing with the landlord is sharecropping.

Imperfect capital market naturally suggests itself as argument in contract choice.

Laffont and Matuosi (1995) showed that the power of the contract in Tunisia is

negatively related to the landlord’s working capital and positively related to the tenant’s

working capital. Exogenous influences such as crop volatility appears to factor in as well.

Pandey (2000) showed that the noisier the output, the lower is the power of the

sharecroppers’ contracts. Canjels (1998) showed that the likelihood of a plot being under

a SC is positively related to the measured risk. But Allen and Lueck (1999) show that

output risk does not have a positive impact on the probability of a crop being leased

under sharecropping.

Property rights have surfaced severally in the empirical and theoretical literature.

For Laffont and Matoussi (1995), crop sharing might constitute a way for the landlord to

extract the tenant’s surplus due to, as Braido (2005) put it, “the lack of enforceable

mechanisms available to the principal to extract the tenant’s surplus.” Thus, the

landlord’s preference for SC hangs on weak enforcement. Security of tenure emerges as

explanation for differential investment by tenants in owned versus leased land. That

Page 7: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

4

owned lands are less likely to be subject to expropriation seems to explain more specific

investments in owned lands than in leased lands in Pakistan (Jacoby and Mansuri, 2006);

Bandiera (2003) shows that fruit trees are more likely to be grown by Nicaraguan farmers

in their owned lands than in leased lands for the same reason.

An interesting observation on the literature is that contract choice outcomes tend

to be interpreted from the preference of the landlord or principal. But the tenant or agent

may also reject a take-it-or-leave-it contract offer opting instead for another contract that,

say, improves long-term stability. Banerjee and Ghatak (2004) show that eviction threats

or absence of property rights security can induce long-term investment by tenants where

long-term investments can stay the hand of the potential evictor. The tack we take here

dovetails the Laffont and Mattuosi view of the absence of adequate third party

mechanism to extract tenant’s surplus: in our case, however, it is the tenant’s inability to

compel the landlord to abide by the contract under weak TPE. The tenant may opt for a

contract that shares the bounty of a bumper harvest with the landlord to reduce the

likelihood of hold-up by the landlord.

Third party enforcement or public ordering made salient by the work of Douglass

North (1990) and Oliver Williamson (1985) though most influential in contract theory in

general (see e.g., Glanchant and Brousseau, 2002; Malin and Mortimort, 2002) seems to

have been given little explicit role in the sharecropping puzzle. Strong TPE is a canonical

assumption of orthodox contract theory and TPE weakness is countenanced only when

some contract provision is unenforceable by the TPE. When such is the case, the

incentives compatibility constraint is deployed to render the optimal ex-ante contract

shirking-free ex-post through the granting of informational rent to the agent. But reneging

Page 8: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

5

or hold-up can also be perpetrated by the landlords who, being normally wealthier, may

in fact wield more political influence than a tenant in a locality.

The view of North and Williamson that a good deal of economic

underdevelopment in many LDCs can be explained by weak TPE is especially pregnant

in the contract space. As North (1994) put it: “The inability of societies to develop

effective low cost enforcement is the most important source of both historical and

contemporary underdevelopment in the Third World.” Strong TPE allows contracts to

navigate the asynchrony in the quid and the quo of contracts allowing greater contracting

options and deeper markets (Williamson, 1983). Weak TPE severely narrows the mid-

range contracting space to small coherent groups where threat of penalty is effective. As

we will show here, one way it does so is to effectively bar fixed rate contracts.

Weak TPE may be in part due to one of the contractors being himself associated

in the contract enforcement. The state which supplies enforcement services in its

jurisdiction may for example be also either a principal or a partner in many long-term

contracts with the private sector participants. When the state has a weak commitment to

the rule of law, it may be unable to resist the popular clamor for change in rules in times a

private sector partner is showing profits. This surfaced recently in Metro-Manila,

Philippines, where the state regulator of water services, the Metropolitan Water and

Services System (MWSS), decided to deny the tariff adjustment petition of the two

private water service concessionaires, the Manila Water Company and Maynilad Water

Company, on the grounds of a new and different interpretation of the income tax

privilege of concessionaires in the governing concession contract. This, it seems upon

seeing that the concessionaires have begun showing profits since previous dispensations

Page 9: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

6

did not raise the issue when the concessionaires were still struggling. The concessionaires

view this as a violation of the concession contract which, had it been known ex-ante,

would have changed their behavior or even deterred them from signing up. The issue is

still under dispute (Wallace, 2015) “This gov’t does not honor contracts” Inquirer

Opinion, ABS-CBN News, Aug 10, 2015; Philippine Center for Investigative Journalism

(PCIJ), July 4, 2013). The behavior of the principal may thus be dependent on the

observed outcomes.

The crucial assumption we make here is that the type of the principal/landlord

may be endogenous to the realized outcome of the contract and hold-up by the landlord

may pay due to weak TPE. This feature of endogenous principal type is in accord with

North’s (1994) concept of “evolving mental models” where the behavioral type of players

may vary to accord with changing perception of circumstances and information. This is

also consistent with new results in cognitive psychology (see e.g., Costa-Gomez and

Weizsacker, 2008; Post et al., 2008). Contract theory already allows for multiple

behavioral types in the population but each agent has one fixed type. This already allows

an average variable, say, quality, to be endogenous which motivates, for example, credit

rationing in the Stiglitz-Weiss credit rationing model (1981) where the high interest rate

induces the flocking of bad borrowers that raises the risk load of loan portfolios.

In this paper, it is the size of the realized wage that may induce the principal to

shift types from abider type to hold-up type. Perhaps closest to this view in incomplete

contract theory is the tradeoff between rigidity and flexibility and the Hart and Moore’s

(2007) idea of “shading” on effort by parties under different contractual regimes.

Sharecropping is flexible as to the returns to the landlord while fixed rent is rigid. In a

Page 10: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

7

fixed rent contract there is no adjusting to the state of nature. This may motivate hold-up

by the principal in times of plenty and peasant revolt in times of scarcity (Scott, 1976). In

our case however, the choice of ex-ante contract is precisely to avoid costly hold-up.

The power of the contract defined as the degree of responsiveness of the agent’s

pay to the realized/observed output/revenue is an important concept in contract choice

theory. In a pure risk-sharing environment (i.e., with observable effort and random

output), the power of the contract is determined solely by the risk attitudes of the

principal P and the agent A. When w’(x) = 1, we say that FRC solves the optimal contract

problem. Thus, under a strong TPE, the contract choice is determined solely by the

inherent risk attitudes of players. Under weak TPE, this may no longer be the case.

When TPE is weak and the contract is effort-in-advance, the principal may

withhold the future payment. The principal, who delivers his contract obligation last,

enjoys what Hume (1769) called the “possession of advantage.” This asymmetric

empowerment alters the power of the contract.

In this paper, we explicitly imbed the TPE feature in the design of an effort-in-

advance adverse selection contracting model general enough to apply to both strong and

weak TPE environments. In the latter case, P may benefit by refusing to fully honor the

contracted wage, especially in instances when the contracted wage is especially high.

Thus, the type of the principal is endogenous to the quality of TPE and the realized

outcome. To focus analysis on the adverse selection and the governance angles, we

eschew moral hazard.

We show how contracts tend to combine weak TPE with second party provision;

in this case, the choice of contract to keep the contract within what Klein (1996) calls

Page 11: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

8

“the self-enforcing range of the contract.” In Section 2, we present as benchmark the

familiar P-A model where the type of the principal is fixed and known up to a fixed

probability distribution and the implicit underlying TPE is strong. In Section 3, we

explicitly imbed a TPE regime in the participation constraint defining along the way

weak and strong TPE. To relate the type of the principal with the wage rate, the

probability q that the principal abides by the contract is first derived as a positive function

of the TPE regime, a negative function of the contracted wage. In Section 4, we first

show that the derived general contract nests the familiar textbook optimal contract when

TPE is strong. We make a distinction between the inherent risk aversion and the induced

risk aversion of the agent and show that the latter exceeds the former only under weak

TPE. Thus, the power of the contract is always lower under weak―than under

strong―TPE. We then show that a fixed rent contract is never optimal under weak TPE

even when the agent is inherently risk-neutral and principal is risk-averse, conditions

which normally suffice for a fixed rent contract under strong TPE. The reason is that the

agent’s induced risk aversion in weak TPE regimes exceeds zero even as the inherent risk

aversion is zero. We summarize in Section 5.

2. The Benchmark Model

In this section, we present the textbook model of optimal contract which will

serve as benchmark for our result in the next section. Consider the case of a principal P

producing revenue x using the services e of one agent A. Revenue x is a random variable

with density function f(x, e), x ∈ X, e is effort and f ′ = (∂f/∂e) > 0. Revenue x is costlessly

observable ex-post. P’s utility is B(π), π = x – w, where π is profit, w is the wage of A and

Page 12: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

9

w, e

B′ > 0, B′′ < 0. A’s utility is U(w(x), e) = u(w(x)) – v(e) where u′(w) > 0, u′′(w) < 0 and

v′(e) > 0, v′′(e) > 0. A’s reservation utility is U0. To isolate the problem of governance, we

let e be costlessly observable. The optimal contract C(w, e) solves the problem P.1 as

follows:

max ∫ B(x – w)f(x, e)dx (1)

s.t. ∫ [u(w(x)) – v(e)] f(x, e)dx > U0.

The first order conditions for an interior maximum are:

(i) -B′(x – w) + λu′(w) = 0

(2) (ii) B(x – w) + λ[(u(w) – v′(e))] = 0.

(2)(i) implies that λ > 0 and the participation constraint (PC) in (1) holds as equality.

Combining (2.i) and (2.ii) eliminates λ and generates the efficiency condition which,

together with the PC, forms two equations in two unknowns w and e. Solving for w and e

gives the optimal risk sharing contract C(w0, e0). The cost of the contract to the principal

is w0.

Differentiating (2.i) with respect to x, substituting for λ and solving for w′(x)

gives the standard power of the contract, w′(x)0:

w′(x)0 = RP(RP + RA)-1, (3)

Page 13: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

10

where RP = (B′′/B′) and RA = -(u′′/u′) are Arrow-Pratt measures of absolute risk aversion

for P and A, respectively. We will call RA the inherent absolute risk-aversion of A since

it is based on A’s utility function alone. w′(x)0 measures the responsiveness of w to

actually observed x and 0 < w′(x)0 < 1. If RP = 0, (B′′ = 0), and A is risk-averse, then w′

(x)0 = 0, so the contract is a fixed wage contract where P bears all and A bears no risk. If

RP > 0 and RA = 0, w′(x)0 = 1 and the contract is a franchise or a pure rent contract and A

bears all the risk while P bears no risk by receiving a fixed rent.

If w′(x)0 > 0, then part or even the entire wage is necessarily paid after realized x

is observed at the end of the cycle. This comes as a share of the surplus or output. As

long as part of the payment is delayed till the end of the cycle, it is vulnerable to ex-post

opportunism since effort e0 once expended cannot be redeployed and thus has the

property of asset specificity.

Suppose the reneging principal pays A not the contracted w* but something less,

w0. For example, in a linear effort-in-advance contract, w = a + bx, P may withhold bx

and A receives only w0 = a. P’s ex-post profit will be higher by bx. The textbook

contracting literature says that P will not renege because there is an outside third party

that will mete out a penalty L > bx on P with probability one. Thus, effort-in-advance

contracts become insulated from ex-post opportunism in a strong TPE environment.

Another way of stating this is that strong TPE dissolves the distinction between spot and

forward contracts. Unfortunately and especially in developing economies, the

enforcement environment is not so reliable as was shown in our example on water

concession contracts in Metro-Manila.

Page 14: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

11

3. The TPE Environment

A. Principal Type

Suppose that P has only two options, either to pay the contracted wage w or to

pay a fixed w0 < w. The issue is the likelihood that P will renege, i.e., pay only w0 in a

particular TPE environment. If TPE is strong, P will never renege since the subsequent

punishment is certain and by definition in excess of opportunism gain. If TPE is weak, P

may be tempted to renege if the gain attached to the opportunism is substantial and

exceeds the expected penalty. In this case, P’s type is endogenous.

Suppose there are N potential principals producing x using the same technology.

Let g be the probability of being punished and L > 0 be the statutory penalty attached to

P’s reneging on the contract of this type. The typical (see, e.g., Cooter, 1996) expected

benefit, Eri, i = 1, 2,…, n, from reneging is thus:

Eri = (w – w0) – gL – Ai, i = 1, 2,…, N (4)

where Ai > 0 is Pi’s personal conscience cost of reneging by i, (w – w0) is the gain from

paying w0 instead of the full w. Suppose Ai is uniformly distributed in the interval [0, A0]

where A0 is the highest possible conscience cost. Note that Pi abides by the contract if Eri

< 0 or Ai > (w – w0) – gL. The probability that any randomly drawn Pi is an abider (i.e.,

pays the contracted wage w) is, in view of the uniform distribution, (1 – Ai/A0) = q, or

q = [A0 + gL – (w – w0)]/A0. (5)

Agent A knows A0, g, L and w0 which are public knowledge ex-ante. The interesting

aspect is that the likelihood, q, that the principal is an abider depends not only on the TPE

Page 15: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

12

quality, gL, and the inherent rectitude A0 of the principal but also on contract provision w.

It is linear and negative in w. A0, the conscience cost of reneging, stands for North’s first

party enforcement while gL is proxy for North’s TPE. The contract structure which is

endogenous to TPE is proxy for North’s second party enforcement (SPE). The present

model thus exhibits interplay between the three Northian enforcement categories in

optimal contracts. Note that as A0 becomes very large, q approaches 1 or the principal is

an abider. This may be the case within small coherent groups where hardwired abidance

is the norm. The same happens if gL becomes very large. But where these two factors are

weak, a rising w can reduce the likelihood of compliance by P.

B. A’s Expected Utility

When q < 1, the PC of A is

∫ [qu(w) + (1 – q)u(w0) – v(e)] f(x, e)dx > U0. (6)

The analysis assumes a strictly positive expected marginal utility of w, i.e.,

∫ [qu′(w) + q′(u(w) – u(w0))] f(x, e)dx > 0 (7)

which, however, is lower than when q is exogenous since q′ < 0. A’s benefit from

increased w is tempered by the higher likelihood that P will cross over to being a

renegade. Of course, if q = 1 and q’ = 0, (7) reduces to ∫u′(w)f(.)dx, the familiar textbook

expected marginal utility of w to A.

C. Taxonomy of TPE

Page 16: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

13

Definition 1: (i) The TPE environment is strong if gL ≥ (w – w0), that is, if q ≥ 1

(truncated as q = 1) and q’ = 0; (ii) It is weak if gL < (w – w0) that is, if q <

1 and q’ < 0.

Remark: (1.i) says that the penalty meted by the TPE for opportunism by P

exceeds the gain (w – w0) from the same act. If TPE is absent (gL = 0), q

< 1 and q’ < 0.

D. Contract Structure

P now solves the programming problem P.2, which maximizes the same objective

function as in (1) subject to the new PC given by (6). The first order necessary condition

for an interior maximum are:

(i) -B′ + λ[qu′(w) + q′(u(w) – u(w0))] = 0

(8) (ii) B(x – w) + λ(qu(w) + (1 – q)u(w0) – v′) = 0.

Since the expected marginal utility to A of w is always positive by (7), λ > 0 from

(8.i) and the PC binds as equality. Combining (8.i) and (8.ii) gives the efficiency

condition which together with the PC can be solved for the generalized optimal contract

C(w**, e**). If we let q = 1 and q’ = 0, (8) exactly reduces to (2) above and the resulting

contracts are identical. Therefore, the contract in (2), C(w*, e*), is nested in (8) as a

special case when TPE is strong. Likewise, C(w**, e**) approaches C(w*, e*) in the

limit as A0 approaches infinity, that is, if the conscience cost A0 of reneging, is infinite.

The foregoing shows that the familiar textbook contract is a special case of the contract

derived here. We formally state this:

Page 17: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

14

Proposition 1: (i) (w**, e**) = (w*, e*) if TPE is strong. (ii) (w**, e**) → (w*,

e*) as A0 → ∞.

A multiplicity of types of contract is possible depending on the strength of the TPE. We

now explore the implication of weak TPE on the power of the contract. It is easy to show

that for a given effort level, the optimal wage w is higher under weak TPE, thus making

the contract cheaper for the principal.

4. POWER of the CONTRACT

In this section, we derive the power of the contract under weak TPE as described

above. Differentiating (8.i) with respect to x and solving for w′(x) gives

w′(x) = RP[RP + RA

0]-1 (9)

which differs from (3) only with the replacement of RA by RA

0. Now

RA

0 = -(H′′ + h′)(H′ + h)-1

where

H′′ = qu′′(w) < 0

since

H′ = qu′(w) > 0,

and

h′ = 2q′u′(w) < 0,

since

h = q′[u(w) – u(w0)] < 0

Page 18: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

15

and q′ < 0. Thus, RA

0 can be viewed as the induced measure of absolute risk aversion of

the agent. Note that by (7), [H’ + h] > 0. Note also that if q` = 0 (q = 1), RA0 reduces to

RA in (2). We have the following:

Lemma 1: The Induced Index of Absolute Risk Aversion RA

0 has the following

properties: (i) RA0 > RA, that is, the induced index of absolute risk aversion

of A is higher than the inherent index of absolute risk aversion of A under

weak TPE. (ii) RA0 = RA under strong TPE; (iii) RA

0 > 0 under weak TPE

even when the agent is inherently risk-neutral (RA = 0).

Proof: (i) The induce absolute risk aversion of A under weak TPE is RA

0 = -(H′′

+ h′)(H′ + h)-1. The same under strong TPE is [-(H′′)(H′)-1] = [-(u′′ (w)/u′

(w))] = RA. But h′ < 0 under weak TPE and when added to H′′ < 0 only

raises the numerator, while h < 0 under weak TPE added to H′ > 0 reduces

the denominator which however remains positive by (7). Thus, RA0 > RA.

(ii) Under strong TPE both h, h′ = 0 since q′ = 0. Thus, RA0 = RA. (iii)

Suppose A is risk neutral, u′′(w) = 0, then RA0 = -(h′)(H′ + h)-1 > 0. In

contrast to RA = 0 when u′′(w) = 0. Thus, RA0 > RA when A is risk-neutral.

QED

Proposition 2: (i) w′(x) = w′(x)0, when TPE is strong. (ii) w′(x) < w′(x)0 when

TPE is weak.

Page 19: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

16

Proof: (i) If TPE is strong, RA0 = RA from the Lemma 1 and w’(x) = w’(x)0; (ii) If

TPE is weak, RA0 > RA, so w′(x) < w′(x)0 by Lemma 1. Q.E.D.

Thus, the power of the contract under strong TPE is nested in the power of the contract

under the more general model. When A knows that a very generous offer by P (high w)

has no effect on the likelihood of contract abidance by P, the power of the contract is

unaffected. Otherwise, the power of the contract will respond. Why this happens is of

interest. The advantage of a high powered contract is that A shares in high realizations of

x. But it is also in those times when the gain from reneging (w(x) – wo) is higher and the

temptation for P to renege is stronger under weak TPE. An instance of induced risk

aversion sometimes occurs in the financial sector: when a bank starts to offer abnormally

high interest on savings deposits, alert depositors become more vigilant because a default

may be in the offing. In effect, A is induced towards more risk aversion. A corollary of

(2.ii) is that the combination of inherent risk neutrality in A and strict risk aversion in P

under weak TPE do not suffice to make a franchise/fixed rent contract optimal as they do

under strong TPE.

Proposition 3: (Sub-optimality of Fixed Rent Contracts Under Weak TPE):

Suppose A is inherently risk-neutral (u′′ = 0) and P is strictly risk-averse

(B′′ < 0). If TPE is weak, w’(x) < 1, the fixed wage contract is never

optimal.

Proof: A fixed rent contract under a weak TPE requires w’(x) = 1. But by Lemma

(1.iii), RA0 > 0 under risk neutrality in A. Thus, w′(x) < 1 or a fixed rent

contract is never optimal under weak TPE. QED

Page 20: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

17

The more power a contract has, the greater the likelihood of a hold-up by P under

weak TPE when the x is large. The temptation to renege is especially great in the fixed

rent farm contracts when the harvest is bumper as all the incremental benefits accrues to

A and nothing to P. In this case, the tenant or agent insists that the contract gives landlord

or principal property rights over a part of the best possible outcome; agent A prefers a

contract that divides ex-post rents, as it were, more equitably (Masten, 1988). Similarly

this preference for sharecropping keeps the relationship within the self-enforcing range of

the contract (Klein, 1996). This also instances what Williamson called hazard

equilibration (see, e.g., Masten and Saussier, 2000). This helps explain the more

widespread adoption of share tenancy not only in the past but also still in the present.

This also calls to mind the trade-off between contract flexibility and rigidity

introduced by Hart and Moore (2007) in incomplete contracting. In incomplete

contracting, contracts are left purposely incomplete until the required information

becomes available in the future. There follows a renegotiation to divide the fruits of non-

contractible investments. But due to the sharing ex-post, parties may “shade” on their

effort. A SC is flexible, that is, adjusts returns to parties according to the state of nature

but the tenant may shade on effort; the fixed rent contract elicits full effort but cannot

adjust to the state of nature. In these circumstances, the tenant will either shade on effort

under a fixed rent contract to manage a likelihood of hold-up and recontracting or ex ante

choose the SC to attain the same thing―keep the contract within the self-enforcing range.

This strategy prevents costly hold-up and recontracting.

The application of the view herein proposed naturally goes beyond agriculture.

This may also explain the dominance of large politically connected enterprises (The

Page 21: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

18

Economist, 2001, “In Praise of Rules,” Survey of Asian Business). Weak TPE or

alternatively weak rule of law means a constant threat of adverse changes in rules by the

state when business is booming. Connected dealings, like a SC, makes the political

establishment a party to the bounty and thus eases the threat. The phenomenon of large

businesses in many LDCs having either direct or indirect―and many times, elicit

connected dealings with the political establishment―may be viewed from this lens as a

form of an implicit SC where the political establishment, in exchange for the connected

flows, protects the firm from outright expropriation by the state when profit is high. Truly

unconnected and rules-based large private businesses―especially those involved with

basic services such as water and power―run the constant risk of expropriation by rules

change. Only when states have demonstrated credible commitment to the rule of law do

truly unconnected firms become viable. The parliamentary control of government

finances in England (North and Weingast, 1989) was an example of such credible

commitment. This rendered market players comfortable enough not only to extend long

term loans to the sovereign but also to increasingly own and run unconnected large

independent enterprises.

5. Conclusion

Why are FRCs less prevalent than SCs despite the superior efficiency attached to

the former? One reason among others is that under weak TPE, the agent or tenant tries to

reduce the risk of contract reneging by the principal/landlord in times of bumper harvest

to which the landlord has no claim under FRC. A SC does this. We show this by

considering an adverse selection effort-in-advance principal-agent contract where the

Page 22: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

19

type of the principal is endogenous to contract terms and the quality of TPE. The

probability that the principal will renege rises with gain from reneging which rises with

the bumper harvest. We formally characterize strong TPE as one that eliminates the

possibility of ex-post opportunism through the certainty of penalty in excess of the gains

from reneging. Weak TPE in contrast leaves room for profitable reneging. When TPE is

strong, the optimal contract in this model is identical to the familiar textbook principal-

agent contract. Thus, the textbook optimal contract model is nested in the more general

model presented here. They differ markedly when TPE is weak. One difference is in the

power of the contract.

The paper first deduces the likelihood that the principal will cross over from

abider to renegade. This likelihood displays an interesting interplay between the three

Northian enforcement categories in the contracting space: first party, second party and

third party enforcement. This likelihood rises with the gain from reneging which rises

with the contracted wage rate. This in turn induces a risk aversion in the agent in excess

of his inherent risk aversion. This impacts the power of the contract. A contract has more

incentive power when A’s pay is more closely tied to the outcome x. But if high w due to

high x also raises the risk of reneging by P, it is less desirable even to a risk neutral A. We

show that the power of the contract under weak TPE is always less than the power of the

same contract under strong TPE. In particular, a fixed rent contract is never optimal even

when the principal is risk-averse and the agent inherently risk neutral. When the harvest

is bumper, the income of the agent from the output under a fixed rent contract spikes and

to which P has no claim. The high return to reneging will tempt the principal to break the

contract and appropriate part of the bumper harvest for himself. Where third party

Page 23: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

20

enforcement is weak (the principal may sometimes himself be the contract enforcer, as in

a feudal regime), this contract type will be avoided.

Weak TPE has been implicated as culprit in the poor performance of economies.

Here, we suggest two pathways by which market is fettered and poor performance is

induced by weak TPE. First of all, certain contracts (e.g., the fixed rent contracts) become

barred even when efficient for risk sharing under strong TPE. Thus, weak TPE induces a

shallow market among large heterogeneous populations. Second, the cost of contracts for

upright principals (those with very high A0 and have no intention to renege) rises. In

markets where abiders and renegers compete, the abiders will be selected for extinction.

Thus, the weak TPE also acts as a selection mechanism for poor quality principals and

poor outcomes.

Page 24: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

21

References

ABS-CBN News (PHL). August 10, 2015. Water income tax dispute subject to arbitration. Philippine Center for Investigative Journalism (PCIJ), July 4, 2013.

Ackerberg, Daniel A. and Maristella Botticini. 2002. Endogenous matching and the empirical determinants of contract form. Journal of Political Economy 110 (3), 564-591.

Allen, Douglas W. and Dean Lueck. 1992. Contract choice in modern agriculture: Cash rent versus cropshare. Journal of Law and Economics 35 (2), 397-426.

Allen, Douglas W. and Dean Lueck. 1999. The role of risk in contract choice. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, vol. 15(3), 704-36.

Bandiera, Oriana. 2003. Contract duration and investment incentives: Evidence from land tenancy agreements. Mimeo, London School of Economics.

Banerjee, Abhijit and Maitreesh Ghatak. 2004. Eviction threats and investment incentives. Journal of Development Economics 74 (2), 469-488.

Braido, Luis H.B. 2005. “Insurance and incentives in sharecropping,” in P. Chiappori and C. Gollier (eds), Insurance: Theoretical Analysis and Policy Implications. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Braido, Luis H.B. 2006. “Insurance and Incentives in Sharecropping,” in P. Chiappori and C. Gollier (eds), Competitive Failures in Insurance Markets. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Brousseau, E. and J.M. Glanchant, 2002. “The economics of contracts and the renewal of economics,” in E.E. Brouseau and J.M. Glanchant (eds.). The Economics of Contracts: Theories and Applications. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Canjels, Eugene. 1998. Does risk affect the choice between share and fixed rent contracts? Mimeo, New School University.

Cheung, Steven N.S. 1969. Transaction costs, risk aversion, and the choice of contractual arrangements. Journal of Law & Economics 12 (1): 23-42.

Cooter, R. 1996. “The rule of state law and the rule-of-law state: Economic analysis of the legal foundations of development,” in Bruno, M. and B. Pleskovic (eds.), Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics. The World Bank, Washington DC.

Costa-Gomez, M.A. and G. Weizacker. 2008. Stated beliefs and play in normal form games. The Review of Economic Studies 75 (3), 729-762.

Dubois, P. 2002. Moral hazard, land fertility and sharecropping in a rural area of the Philippines. Journal of Development Economics 68, 35–64.

Dubois, Pierre. "Sharecropping." The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, second edition. Eds. Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume. Palgrave Macmillan. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online. Palgrave Macmillan. 18 November 2008.

Page 25: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

22

Eswaran, Mukesh and Ashok Kotwal. 1985. A theory of contractual structure in agriculture. American Economic Review 75: 352–367.

Ghatak, M. and Pandey, P. 2000. Contract choice in agriculture with joint moral hazard in effort and risk. Journal of Development Economics 63, 303-26.

Hart, Oliver and John Moore. 2007. Incomplete contracts and ownership: Some new thoughts. American Economic Reviewi 97(2), 182-186.

Hoffman, Philip T. 1984. The economic theory of sharecropping in early modern France. Journal of Economic History 44 (2), 309-319.

Hume, David. 1978 [1740, 1888]. A treatise of human nature. L.A. Selby-Bigge (ed.). Revised 2nd edition by P. Nidditch. Clarendon Press, Oxford.

Jacoby, Hanan and Ghazala Mansuri. 2006. Incomplete contracts and investment: A study of land tenancy in Pakistan. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3826, February 2006.

Johnson, D. Gale. 1950. Resource allocation under share contracts. Journal of Political Economy 58 (2), 111-123.

Klein, B. 1996. Why hold-up occur: the self-enforcing rane of contractual relationships. Economic Inquiry 34:444-463.

Laffont, Jean-Jacques and Mohamed S. Matoussi. 1995. Moral hazard, financial constraints and sharecropping in El Oulja. Review of Economic Studies 62(3), 381-399.

Luporini, A. and Parigi, B. 1996. Multi-task sharecropping contracts: the Italian Mezzadria. Economica 63, 445–57.

Malin, Eric and David Mortimort, 2002. Transaction Costs and Contract Theory. Paper provided by HAL in its series Post-Print with number halshs-00440475.

Marshall, Alfred. 1920. Principles of economics (8th ed.). Macmillan and Co., Ltd., London.

Masten, Scott E. 1988. Minimum bill contracts: theory and policy. Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 37(1), 85-97.

Masten, Scott E. and Stéphane Saussier. 2000. Economietrics of contracts: An assessment of Developments in the empirical literature on contracting. Revue d'Économie Industrielle, Programme National Persée, vol. 92(1), 215-236.

Mill, John S. 1848. Principles of Political Economy. Edited by W. J. Ashley, Longmans Company, London (1936).

Muthoo, Abhinay. 1998. Renegotiation-proof tenurial contracts as screening mechanisms. Journal of Development Economics 56: 1–26.

Page 26: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

23

North, D. 1990. Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

North, D. 1994. Economic performance through time. The American Economic Review 84, pp. 359-368.

North, D. and B. Weingast. 1989. Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in 17th century England,” Journal of Economic History 1993, pp. 51-69.

Pandey, Priyanka. 2000. Contract choice in agriculture with joint moral hazard in effort and risk. Journal of Development Economics 63(2): 303-326.

Post, T, Van den Assem M J, Balthussen G and R H Thaler. 2008. Deal or no deal? Decision making under risk in a large payoff game. The American Economic Review, 38-71.

Roumasset, James and Marilou Uy. 1987. Agency costs and the agricultural firm. Land Economics vol. 63(3), 290-302.

Roumasset, James. March 1995. The nature of the agricultural firm. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 26 (2): 161-177.

Scott, James. 1976. The moral economy of the peasant: Rebellion and subsistence in Southeast Asia. Princeton University Press: Princeton, New Jersey.

Sen, Debapriya. 2011. A theory of sharecropping: the role of price behavior and imperfect competition. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 80 (1):181–199.

Shaban, Radwan Ali. 1987. Testing between competing models of sharecropping. Journal of Political Economy, vol. 95, no. 5 (October 1987), pp. 893-920.

Shetty, Sudhir. 1988. Limited liability, wealth differences, and the tenancy ladder in agrarian economies. Journal of Development Economics 29: 1-22.

Smith, Adam. 1776. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. Edited by Edwin Cannan, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Stiglitz, Joseph. 1974. Incentives and risk sharing in sharecropping. The Review of Economic Studies 41 (2): 219–255.

Stiglitz, Joseph and Andrew Weiss. 1981. Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information. The American Economic Review 71, no. 3, 313-333.

Wallace, P. December 29, 2015. This government does not honor contracts, Inquirer Opinion, ABS-CBN News, Aug 10, 2015; Philippine Center for Investigative Journalism (PCIJ), July 4, 2013.

Williamson, Oliver. 1983. Credible commitments: Using hostages to support exchange. American Economic Review 73, pp.519-540.

Page 27: We revisit the question of why fixed rent contracts are

24

Williamson, Oliver. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational contracting. The Free Press, New York.