undermining the foundations of organized crime and public sector

42
Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114fm Mp_1 rev2 page i UNDERMINING THE FOUNDATIONS OF ORGANIZED CRIME AND PUBLIC SECTOR CORRUPTION An Essay on Best International Practices Edgardo Buscaglia, Samuel Gonzalez-Ruiz, and William Ratliff HOOVER INSTITUTION on War, Revolution and Peace Stanford University 2005

Upload: lexuyen

Post on 29-Jan-2017

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114fm Mp_1 rev2 page i

UNDERMINING THEFOUNDATIONS OFORGANIZED CRIME ANDPUBLIC SECTOR CORRUPTIONAn Essay on Best International Practices

Edgardo Buscaglia,Samuel Gonzalez-Ruiz, andWilliam Ratliff

HOOVER INSTITUTIONon War, Revolution and Peace

Stanford University2005

Page 2: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114fm Mp_2 rev2 page ii

The Hoover Institution on War, Revolution and Peace,founded at Stanford University in 1919 by Herbert Hoover,who went on to become the thirty-first president ofthe United States, is an interdisciplinary research centerfor advanced study on domestic and international affairs.The views expressed in its publications are entirely those ofthe authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the staff,officers, or Board of Overseers of the Hoover Institution.

www.hoover.org

Essays in Public Policy No. 114

Copyright � 2005 by the Board of Trustees of theLeland Stanford Junior University

Material contained in this essay may be quoted with appropriate citation.

First printing 2005

Manufactured in the United States of America10 09 08 07 06 05 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1

Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data

Buscaglia, Edgardo.Undermining the foundations of organized crime and public sector corruption :an essay on best international practices / by Edgardo Buscaglia, Samuel Gonzalez-Ruiz,and William Ratliff.

p. cm. — (Essays in public policy ; no. 114)Includes bibliographical references.ISBN 0-8179-4672-1 (alk. paper)1. Transnational crime—Prevention—International cooperation. 2. Organized crime—

Prevention—International cooperation. 3. Public administration—Corrupt practices—Prevention—International cooperation. I. Gonzalez Ruiz, Samuel. II. Ratliff, William E.III. Title. IV. Series.

H96.E85 no. 114[HV6252]320.6 s—dc22[364.1/ 2005016589

Page 3: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_1 rev2 page 1

UNDERMINING THEFOUNDATIONS OFORGANIZED CRIME ANDPUBLIC SECTOR CORRUPTIONAn Essay on Best International Practices

Edgardo Buscaglia,Samuel Gonzalez-Ruiz, andWilliam Ratliff

Problems and Challenges

Corruption and organized crime are serious criminal phenomena, butthey are also much more than that. Not only is organized crime animpediment to national development and globalization, but with itslinks to terrorist groups worldwide, it is also a threat to the nationalsecurity of the United States and other open and opening societies.The recent histories of Pakistan and Colombia demonstrate clearlyhow organized criminal groups support the expansion of transnationalterrorism and even how misconceived domestic and international pol-

Edgardo Buscaglia is a research fellow at the Hoover Institution, Stanford University,and a senior research fellow at Columbia University. He is an expert advising theUnited Nations Institute for Training and Research (UNITAR). Samuel Gonzalez-Ruiz was deputy attorney general of Mexico (1995–99) and is a professor of law atthe University of Sevilla, Spain. William Ratliff is a research fellow at the HooverInstitution and a specialist in comparative international development.

Page 4: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_2 rev2 page 2

2 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

icies can simply make matters worse (Buscaglia 1999; Buscaglia andRatliff 2001). The threat that these activities of organized crime pre-sents is compounded because transnational criminal organizationsoften act with the tacit or explicit support of state authorities, as inthe illegal trafficking of radioactive, biological, and chemical materialsand in the more conventional transport of military and other equip-ment (Buscaglia and Gonzalez-Ruiz 2002). That is, criminal groupsfrequently expand their activities worldwide by capturing the publicpolicies of states with the support of corrupt public officials, who thendo not work conscientiously for the good of their own nations or ofthe international community. Just one example is the transnationalcriminal organizations in Russia that engage in the trafficking andsupplying of weapons to terrorist groups inside and outside the Fed-eration’s borders, which they do by corrupting local public officialsand officials in the military establishment (Buscaglia 1997).

Oganized crime, corruption, and links to terrorism are possiblebecause of weaknesses in the control mechanisms of state and civilsociety, as demonstrated by conditions in Colombia (Buscaglia andRatliff 2001) and by large-scale terrorist involvement in organizedcrime, including money-laundering, as has been the case with theIrish Republican Army in Northern Ireland (Economist 2005). Theoryand applied research suggest that there are interdependent links alongthe entire spectrum of political, socioeconomic, legal, and criminaljustice domains (Shelley 1995; Buscaglia and Gonzalez-Ruiz 2002;Buscaglia and Ratliff 2000). For example, the analytical results foundin Buscaglia and van Dijk (2003), from a sample of more than fivedozen countries worldwide, attest to the deep ties between the growthof organized crime and the growth of public sector corruption. Manybelieve incorrectly that in a large range of societies, the links betweenorganized crime and terrorists resemble the popular perceptions of aformal and structured “Mafia” type (Buscaglia and Gonzalez-Ruiz2002). But on the contrary, these criminal enterprises are dynamic

Page 5: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_3 rev2 page 3

3Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

and relatively loose structures, making the task of both law enforce-ment and intelligence analysis much more difficult (Williams 2001).

There is ample evidence of organized crime’s involvement insome major piratical attacks in the Malacca Strait, for example, withthe threats those attacks have posed to persons, to property, and tothe delivery of, among other things, 80 percent of the oil shipped toAsia’s booming economies. Indeed, organized crime may be involvedin the setting up of “phantom ships” that intelligence sources say areunder the control of al-Qaeda (Ratliff 2005a, 2005b; Burnett 2002).What is more, evidence suggests that these links between terrorismand organized crime are on the rise. For example, since 1990 thetransnational organized crime linked to specific terrorist operationshas increased at an average rate of 8, 19, and 21 percent yearly inLatin America, Africa, and Eurasia, respectively (Buscaglia and Gon-zalez-Ruiz 2002). Thus the links between organized crime and stateswith weak or corrupt governance constitute an important threat tointernational peace and security as well as to national developmentand well-being. They demand a response that will both improvenational governance and development and reduce links that threatennational and international security. The composite indexes of orga-nized crime and corruption in Buscaglia and van Dijk (2003) wereused to identify the institutional factors linked to reductions in com-plex crime. This policy essay goes one step further by delineating bestpractices in counteracting organized crime and public sector corrup-tion.

This essay is in three parts: (1) focus and background, (2) meth-odology and empirical analysis, and (3) policy recommendationstaken from the study of best international practices in counteractingorganized crime and public sector corruption.

Page 6: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_4 rev2 page 4

4 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

Focus and Background

The Focus of This Essay

The modernization of economic life in a globalized world is far moredifficult, and yet in a way more simple, than is often believed. Itrequires above all a will to change and then the choice and imple-mentation of constructive reforms that benefit the vast majority in acountry, not just the elite. The twentieth century has shown clearlythat “revolution” in the Leninist sense, the violent overthrow of agovernment by a small vanguard and its replacement by somethingpresumably different, does not benefit most people. In fact, it hasalways resulted in the creation of what Milovan Djilas called a “newclass,” a new elite. As Lenin himself knew well, “revolutions” caneasily become “restorations” of traditional authoritarian or despoticsystems, which is what happened in Russia, China, and several othercountries that for a long time took the communist route. And yet thereforms we discuss here are in many respects truly revolutionary, sincethey propose the adoption of very different ways of thinking and ofoften new institutions that convert without violence, or with lessviolence than in the country’s past, different ideas and objectives intoreality. Justifying the most revolutionary economic changes China hasever seen, Deng Xiaoping said: “To get rich is glorious.” The enor-mous changes that thinking has brought to China are readily appar-ent. Yet, while political authoritarianism has involved a degree ofrepression, although the traditional and communist statist orientationof the courts has continued, and although guanxi (connections) oftenis still the best way to get things done, the law is increasingly a toolof the powerless (Diamant, Lubman and O’Brien 2005).

The changes we discuss here require increasingly complicatedinteractions among individuals and organizations, nationally andinternationally. The mix of deregulation, the liberalization of inter-national trade, and the privatization of state enterprises has intensified

Page 7: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_5 rev2 page 5

5Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

the need for legal frameworks with clear rules for economic interac-tion (Buscaglia 1997). For example, the increasing permeability ofnational frontiers to international trade and ideas is of such magni-tude that it has forced national authorities to consider the adoptionof international best practices for protecting intellectual propertyrights (Buscaglia 1997; Buscaglia and Ratliff 2000). This essay focuseson identifying public policies aimed at counteracting organizedcrime’s links to public sector corruption. We describe national judi-cial, law enforcement, and social control practices and institutionswith a record of success and with the potential for at least partialapplication in other countries around the world.

Within criminal jurisdictions, the dark side of globalization—thecombining of increasing cross-border porosity and the use of advancedtechnologies by criminal enterprises—has generated a bonanza fororganized crime and public sector corruption (Buscaglia 2001). Thusorganized crime causes high costs for delineating and protectingproperty and contractual rights in many developed and developingcountries’ jurisdictions. These pernicious effects are sometimes com-pounded by an inconsistent application of organized crime laws andother laws, by judicial ineffectiveness, and worst of all, by corruptpractices within the state, when failure cannot be traced to outrightsabotage. As a result, societal transaction costs (reflecting the costsof acquiring information, negotiating complex transactions, and mon-itoring the compliance with agreements in society) have increased tolevels that make it unprofitable for those demanding and supplyinggoods and services within a market to invest there. The internationalbusiness community’s judgment on this matter is reflected in theWorld Economic Forum’s 2004 Global Competitiveness Report, inwhich the United States, northern Europe, and reforming Asiancountries almost always rate high while, with few exceptions, LatinAmerican and African countries rate low (World Economic Forum2004).

Abundant empirical research has shown significant links between

Page 8: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_6 rev2 page 6

6 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

a stronger rule of law and greater economic growth (Buscaglia 1993;Mauro 1995; de Soto 2000; Buscaglia and Dakolias 1999), at least inmuch of the world. Accordingly, many developed and developingcountries have attempted to reform their laws and judiciaries in theprocess of their political and social efforts to strengthen democracy,to enhance the protections of human rights, and to foster privateinvestment. Others, particularly in Asia, have begun successful eco-nomic reform with “informal” guanxi (connections), rather than withformal legal structures, which is just one of several reasons such anoverwhelming percentage of foreign investments in China have comefrom overseas Chinese. Over time these developing countries havesought to establish legal systems that are in varying degrees relatedto those in Western developed nations. In a globalized world, move-ment in this direction, particularly in international relations, seemsinevitable. Still, an international comparative analysis demonstratesthat legal and judicial reform has shown mixed results around theworld (Buscaglia and Dakolias 1999). Dysfunctional laws and limitedjudicial capacities in the police, prosecutorial, and judicial domainsare the common denominators in failed legal and judicial reformworldwide and thus usually impede good public sector governance andeconomic growth (Buscaglia 2001). A short account of the factorsexplaining these mixed results will be covered below.

Strengthening the rule of law, with the aim of securing propertyand civil rights for all citizens and of reducing corruption, improvingcontractual enforcement, and generating economic prosperity, is acomplicated process in several ways. It requires making the state’sexercise of power more coherent, more predictable, and more consis-tent with the incentives needed to foster investment and promoteeconomic growth. In its ideal form, a rule-of-law state is one in whichall individuals and groups, indeed the government itself, are subjectto the same laws, thus guaranteeing that every person, regardless ofsocioeconomic condition, ethnicity, or gender, will enjoy equal rights

Page 9: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_7 rev2 page 7

7Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

under a judicial system that is feasibly accessible to all (Buscaglia1995).

Economic progress in much of the world, as well as “simple jus-tice,” requires legal rules that are clearly defined and known to thepublic, but also rules that are interpreted and enforced by a judicialsystem immune to systemic abuses of politics and substantive andprocedural discretions. There is an increasing need for legal rules tobe designed, interpreted, and enforced consistently in nation statesand across international borders to enhance risk management andfoster wealth generation in an increasingly complex world (Buscaglia1993). Our analysis draws from the discipline known as the law andeconomics of development and growth. This discipline aims at iden-tifying changes in laws and improvements in interpretation andenforcement mechanisms that, within the social and legal traditionsof each country and the world, are able to enhance sustainable eco-nomic development and security.

Sources of Lawmaking and Economic Growth

One recently emergent line of research in the law and economics ofdevelopment literature concentrates on the socioeconomic founda-tions of the sources of those rules that will allow the law and itsenforcement mechanisms to adapt to a modern economy and, byadapting to it, foster economic growth. This topic is explored in atheoretical manner by Cooter (1996), who argues that efficiency isenhanced by a “bottom-up” process of capturing evolutionarily suc-cessful social norms (that is, coordinating mechanisms for social inter-action) that are already in place as “informally” relevant in humaninteraction. This decentralized approach to lawmaking stands in sharpcontrast to the centralization proposed by the first law and develop-ment movement that during the 1960s and 1970s advocated clearcentralization and modernization of laws through legal transplants.

The most important contribution in this first movement can be

Page 10: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_8 rev2 page 8

8 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

ascribed to Seidman (1978), who sponsored comprehensive, central-ized, and top-down legislative reform aimed at modernizing the publicand private dimensions of the law. In this approach, administrativelaw, as the top-down framework establishing the rules to be followedin relations between the state and private individuals, was related tothe expansion of the government’s role in societies worldwide. Thesources of inspiration for this movement included national traditions,the Enlightenment, Italian fascism, the rise (before the collapse) ofcommunist and socialist systems, the active advocacy of such inter-national institutions as the United Nations, and strong state-orientedmovements among intellectuals almost everywhere, the latter includ-ing the creators of the original law and economics movement. Thecommon law or judge-made law sustained by stare decisis suffered fromthis significant expansion of administrative law.

Today, legal systems around the world face a choice between gen-erating laws and regulations in a centralized, top-down way or legal-izing and enforcing social norms with a bottom-up approach, whichoften requires a degree of accommodation. That is, civil code systemscan continue to try to impose rules that are irrelevant much of thetime to real people, or they can try to make law relevant to the livesof people and society generally by capturing the norms of local,national, and international business and other communities. Follow-ing Hayek (1973), one can argue that the higher information con-straints that are the product of added social complexity in modernsocieties require public policy to decentralize lawmaking by capturingnorms and thus cutting market transaction costs, a reality recognizedvery clearly in Botswana (U.S. Department of State 2005). As Cooter(1996, 148) states, “efficiency requires the enforcement of customs inbusiness communities to become more important relative to the reg-ulation of business.” From this perspective, the irrelevance of the civiland commercial laws enacted by legislatures in many countries mustbe understood as a reflection of the lack of correspondence betweenthe essence of what the law stipulates and the social norms followed

Page 11: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_9 rev2 page 9

9Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

by people and businesses in their daily lives. When regulations orlaws so lack compatibility, the cost of complying and enforcing thelaw becomes higher, that is if the law functions at all.

These are what Hernando de Soto has called “bad laws,” or leg-islation that actually impedes or disrupts economic efficiency in muchof the world, resulting in the absence of secure property rights for alland thus in enormous levels of “dead capital” and in little nationaldevelopment. In his work, de Soto contrasts the approximate trans-action cost of complying with this “bad law” with the transaction costof following the social norm in an informal market. Here we see thatthe higher transaction cost is rooted in the drive of governments tocentralize lawmaking without regard for the true social practices fol-lowed by people. Thus de Soto argues that the size of informal sectorsaround the globe is intimately related to the way laws and regulationsfail to capture the social practices followed by society. Only when thelaws and regulations begin to reflect these practices will the transac-tion cost of the affected social interactions decline and a movementtoward efficiency occur (de Soto 1989, 1997, 2000). And as Buscaglia(1997) shows, until movement occurs, there will be a widening gapbetween law in action and law on the books. The choice is clear.Real change will come only when there is determination to changeand a willingness to reduce or somehow accommodate the culturaland institutional obstacles that can so easily prevent real legal reform(North 1990; Ratliff 1999; Vargas Llosa 2005).

Following Cooter (1994, 1996) and Mattei (1991), we argue thatgenerating obedience to laws requires compatibility between the sub-stance and procedures of these laws and the ethical code prevailingin society. Individuals in social frameworks seek the kind of predict-ability that will increase their ability to generate wealth through theirinteractions. In the real world, different levels of concentration ofpolitical and economic power may be compatible in varying degreeswith predictable rules of the game. But whatever the concentrationof political and economic power, when social norms and values sup-

Page 12: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_10 rev2 page 10

10 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

port the prevailing and predictable rules of political and economicinteraction, the efficiency of allocation and equity in interpreting andapplying these laws will reduce the transaction cost of social inter-action and enhance prospects for development.

With this reality in mind, societal norms must be found by publicinstitutions and transformed into formalized legal rights and obliga-tions in each branch of the law. One could here extend Cooter’sanalysis and state that to enhance effectiveness in the applicationand execution of laws, policies must follow not just the market butalso the nonmarket social norms. In a more comprehensive way, civilsociety’s market and nonmarket rules for social and political inter-action provide a foundation for lawmaking in the legislature and thejudiciary. By making laws based on what is familiar to the individual,a society can lower the transaction cost of human interactions andmove toward greater legal effectiveness and efficiency in its marketand nonmarket activities (Buscaglia and Ratliff 2000, 9–19). The evo-lution of intellectual property laws worldwide is a good example ofhow even legal transplants may provide a channel through whichnational laws start to follow business practices and social norms.

Finally, it is clear that a centralized and discretionary top-downapproach to lawmaking has led to a general rejection (or in the bestof cases, the irrelevance) of formal legal systems in many countries.In these countries, large segments of the population often perceivethemselves as divorced from the formal law generated by legislativebodies. This institutional “divorce” reflects a gap between the “formallaw in the books” and the “law in action” that is characteristic ofsuch countries, which are many. Because of this gap, large segmentsof the population who lack the information or resources to overcomethe significant substantive and procedural barriers preventing accessto court systems pursue informal means in their general interactionsin society and in redressing their grievances. For example, the relationbetween these socioeconomic barriers and the growth of alternativedispute resolution mechanisms has been empirically demonstrated in

Page 13: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_11 rev2 page 11

11Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

seventeen countries (Buscaglia and Stephan 2004). In practice, infor-mal institutions provide an escape valve in certain kinds of conflictwhere states do not offer secure popular access to formal dispute res-olution mechanisms. In Colombia, people may even turn to guerrillassupporting drug lords for “legal” redress (Buscaglia and Ratliff 2001).Yet many other disputes over fundamental rights and public interestsgo unresolved by any “legal” institution. This state of affairs under-mines the legitimacy of the state, hampers economic interactions, anddisproportionately burdens the poorest segments of the population (deSoto 2000).

This institutional “divorce” contrasts the promises of laws andcommitments on the books with the realities of nondelivery and theresulting lack of improvement in, or even deterioration of, most peo-ple’s lives. And when these failures are repeated, they teach disrespectfor law itself, particularly when the population is acquainted with themore responsive common law tradition in the United States. In LatinAmerica, for example, there have been centuries of unfulfilled prom-ises, for as a Peruvian analyst says, “law” has almost always been“political law,” serving the interest of the elite in power rather thanthat of the people as a whole. This has contributed to Latin America’sterrible inequalities and chronic underdevelopment, or very unevendomestic development, as in Brazil, since real change has beenimpeded by cultural attitudes and institutional obstacles dating backto the colonial period, and earlier (Vargas Llosa 2005). As recentpolls by Latinobarometro show, only about 20 percent of Latin Amer-icans have much or even some confidence in their justice systems;the majority correctly consider most of their judicial systems in var-ying degrees corrupt, inefficient, and in the pockets of the elite.

In Asia, where there is no nearby tradition of the common law’s“equality before the law,” it has been more complicated. Legal reformshave been passed in China, for example, but the new laws often arenot fully implemented. In some cases there is no pretense of “state oflaw” legality (Yardley 2005; Laogai 2003–2004). At the same time,

Page 14: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_12 rev2 page 12

12 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

although China is by no means a rule-of-law state, it has had thehighest sustained growth rate in the world (about 9.5 percent yearlyfor almost twenty-five years). The editors of a recent study concludethat most elites in China think that “law is essential because it con-tributes to a more orderly society” (Diamant, Lubman and O’Brien2005, 7). As in Latin America, there is often a large gap betweenlaws on the books and laws effectively implemented. But most peoplein China, unlike those in Latin America, have benefited significantlyfrom reform under Deng Xiaoping and subsequent party leaders, eventhough the Communist Party still controls the justice system (Mertha2005).

Legal Transplants and Economic Efficiency

There are three main sources of a country’s laws. First, governmentleaders can draw up a law completely from within their country’s ownsociojudicial tradition, implementing it through the country’s owninstitutional mechanisms. Second, they can import rules as a packagefrom outside their domestic political-legal tradition and try to adoptthem exactly or largely as they were drawn up abroad. Or third, theycan import a law from outside but adapt it to work effectively (or ifthe “reformers” are ignorant or wish to sabotage the effort, ineffec-tively) in the cultural context of their own country. Indeed, as shownin the negotiations to define “organized crime” mentioned below,adaptations of one’s original position are often essential to being ableto work constructively with other groups or countries that see thingssomewhat differently for cultural and other reasons. Some kinds oflaws are more likely to be adopted with little or no change, those ofan international nature, while other kinds are more likely to be sub-stantially adapted, those dealing mainly with domestic issues. Theprincipal factor in the beginning is deciding which of these optionsto choose, and this decision will depend on what the reformers want,or at least claim they want, to accomplish.

Page 15: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_13 rev2 page 13

13Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

Watson (1978) demonstrated that legal transplants have a longhistory, whether in the wholesale transfer of civil law to Latin Amer-ica in the past or in the adoption of an individual law today. Onemay then ask why, from an international pool of laws available fortransplant, certain rules and institutions are commonly adopted,adapted, and later enacted in varied jurisdictions, whereas others arerejected. For example, why do so many countries adopt (through theratification of international conventions) certain rules and standardsto protect intellectual property, even if they do not carry them outvery effectively, while they reject others? Why has China so effec-tively used foreign ideas in its anti-counterfeiting enforcement regimeat all judicial levels (Mertha 2005)? Or more fundamentally, why dosome countries adopt adversarial judicial systems and oppose inquis-itorial systems, or separation of powers as opposed to parliamentarysystems? In the end, to what degree do Watson’s observations applyusefully to Asia? Some analysts say little or perhaps not at all (Alford1995).

The economic analysis of the law can provide an explanation andguide to transplants by applying tests to determine if the transplantedlegal rules are the most efficient and effective possible. That is, anintertemporal cost-benefit analysis may explain why some legal rulesand systems are adopted or adapted and others rejected. Eggertsson(1990) warned that different legal systems might compute the costand benefit of legal rules differently, because real economic and legalfactors (such as national resource endowments or sociojuridical cul-ture) vary across regions and nations. And legal reform is subject topolitical pressure from individuals or groups inside or outside the state,including the dominant international powers of the time. For exam-ple, a profound alteration in an existing legal system may threatenthe private professional interests of lawyers and others or challengethe interests of public officials whose cooperation is essential for theeffective application, interpretation, and enforcement of new laws(Buscaglia and Ratliff 2000).

Page 16: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_14 rev2 page 14

14 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

A case study of legal transplants from best-practice countries canbe provided by examining the generation of the existing internationallegal framework to combat organized crime. As stated in the begin-ning, transnational organized crime has been experiencing a bo-nanza owing to the mix of increasing international cross-bordertechnological improvements and liberalization of commerce. Becausetransnational organized crime represents what economists call aninterjurisdictional (i.e., international) negative externality or “publicbad,” a group of pioneer countries, including Italy and the UnitedStates, tried to develop a common international legal framework thatcould be transplanted to other countries to combat criminal enter-prises through common operational mechanisms. Even with this deci-sion made, problems emerged immediately. At first, even thedefinition of organized crime seemed to present a barrier to an inter-national agreement. In time, law enforcement agencies in Europedeveloped a number of operational definitions of the term “organizedcriminal group.” Those definitions agreed on the following crucialelements: such a group must be structured, possess some degree ofpermanence and continuity through time, commit serious crimes forprofit, employ violence, corrupt public officials, launder criminal pro-ceeds, and reinvest in the licit economy.

Inspired by the best international practices, during the 1990smore than a hundred country delegations seeking legal transplantsdrew up the United Nation’s Convention against Transnational Orga-nized Crime, also known as the Palermo Convention.1 For practicalreasons, article 1 of the Palermo Convention defines an organizedcriminal group as “a structured group, committing serious crimes forprofit.” This very broad definition was settled on rather than oneincluding the most common kinds of organized crime, such as traf-ficking in drugs, arms, persons, stolen cars, protected species, or ter-rorism. Still the convention focused on the same kinds of groups ashave been singled out by law enforcement agencies using the Falconechecklist, which was later incorporated into the so-called Falcone

Page 17: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_15 rev2 page 15

15Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

framework.2 This is evident from the three protocols supplementaryto the convention, treating trafficking in persons, smuggling ofmigrants, and trafficking in firearms, as well as from provisions in theconvention treating such secondary characteristics of organized crim-inal activity as corruption, violence, money-laundering, and reinvest-ment in the licit economy. Thus, well over a hundred countries nowhave transplanted legislative frameworks compatible with the PalermoConvention.

But as suggested above, the idea that economic growth dependson a rule-of-law state has not been borne out so far in much of Asia.A number of Asian countries were among the signatories of thePalermo Convention, but it is worth asking why they signed in thatcase and not in others. As a top Chinese official said in December2000, “The Convention represents a new milestone in internationalcooperation against transnational organized crime. The nature of thiscrime dictates that such cooperation be further strengthened” (UnitedNations Information Service 2000). Indeed, the Chinese, and someother Asian countries, were actively cooperating against al-Qaedawell before America’s traumatic 9/11 (Nazarbayev, interview, March21, 2000). Often, in reforming Asia, commitment to Western-influ-enced or -dictated legal reform has been less intended to defend theindividual rights of people or of businesses as such than to advancegovernment policies, which frequently have benefited most of thepeople. Many reforming Asian governments became interested inWestern-style legal transplants primarily when they saw how usefulthese transplants would be in their pursuit of critically important for-eign trade and investment.

Thus for many the decision to undertake legal reform was in largepart prompted by pragmatism and made more progress with the lawgoverning international than domestic affairs. Consider the case ofintellectual property legislation in China and other Asian countries,including, as the experience of the third author testifies, Hong Kongwhile still under British control. The implementation of these laws,

Page 18: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_16 rev2 page 16

16 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

like adherence to World Trade Organization membership require-ments, often flows from pressure from abroad or pressure from domes-tic businesses that realize their production and earnings will rise ifadherence to the law is more complete (Ginsburg 2000). In late April2005 Washington said that it would step up its monitoring of whatthe acting U.S. trade representative said was “rampant piracy andcounterfeiting” in China (China Reform Monitor 2005). According toone top analyst of China’s legal reform, deep reform will be a long-term process in that country (Lubman 1999).

Methodology and Empirical Analysis

The analysis supporting the policy recommendations later in thisessay is found in Buscaglia and van Dijk (2003), an empirical analysisof organized crime activities and public sector corruption in manycountries worldwide, which was released by the United Nations Officeon Drugs and Crime.3 In the discussion above, corruption was broadlydefined as the abuse of public power for private gain. In order to drawup an organized crime index, the extent of organized crime in a coun-try was assessed using indicators contained in operational investiga-tions conducted by law enforcement agencies (e.g., the Falconechecklist) and in the United Nations Organized Crime Conventionand its protocols. It was decided that the official data of criminalactivities on police records offered little reliable information on theextent of organized crime in a country. For example, police seizuredata on drug trafficking did not show any correlation with other orga-nized crime factors. So the data were omitted and other sources hadto be found or developed.

The Buscaglia and van Dijk study (2003) deals with corruptionstretching from the streets, including the experiences of ordinary peo-ple and of businesspeople in their interactions, to individuals andgroups in the highest offices in the country. High-level corruptionrefers to the extent and frequency with which illegal interest groups

Page 19: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_17 rev2 page 17

17Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

penetrate state institutions and manipulate public policies to favortheir interests. To measure high-level corruption, the authors con-structed a composite index that takes into account (1) the percep-tional indicators on distortions arising from interest groups, (2) theindependence of policies from special interest groups’ pressure, (3)the likelihood of biased judicial rulings, (4) the perceptions on thepercentage of the value of a public procurement—related contractpaid for bribes, and (5) the prevalence of state capture.

To assess the prevalence of street-level corruption, the authorsused an indicator compiled by the International Crime VictimizationSurvey (ICVS), whose funding was provided by the Ministry of Justiceof the Netherlands, which records how often people experience actualrequests for bribes in each country. ICVS data refer to and covermainly street-level corruption and the medium-level corruption thatan average citizen faces while interacting with public agencies. The2003 study also sought country-specific data on the primary activitiesof organized crime groups, such as credit card fraud and trafficking indrugs, firearms, stolen cars, cigarettes, and human beings.

Finally, a composite index was constructed including objectiveindicators of six primary activities, all based on crime statistics com-piled by Interpol and the United Nations. These were financial fraudas well as trafficking in human beings, drugs, firearms, stolen cars, andsmuggled cigarettes. In addition, the following four secondary aspectswere also included in the organized crime composite index: (1) costimposed by organized crime on business activity, (2) extent of theinformal economy as a proportion of gross domestic products, (3)organized crime violence, and (4) money-laundering.4

One important source was the World Economic Forum’s surveyof business (2000), aimed at measuring the cost imposed on firms byorganized crime. This survey provided an estimate of the extent ofvictimization of businesses by such crime. The country ranking, basedon the World Economic Forum’s index, was correlated with indexesfor corruption and violence (homicide). The three indexes were found

Page 20: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_18 rev2 page 18

18 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

to be highly correlated across the large group of countries selectedand, as a result, a composite index of nonconventional crime wasconstructed. Although the composite index has proved robust andhas not been much affected by the inclusion or exclusion of individualindicators, continuing efforts are being made to add further statisticalindicators.

When designing and drafting organized crime legislation, legis-lators must pay particularly close attention to identifying the perni-cious factors expanding the gap between the law enacted in the booksand the law in action. We demonstrate a clear relationship betweenthe frequency of objectively measured organized crime and the qualityof judicial rulings. Case-file analyses performed in sixty-seven coun-tries by Buscaglia (2001) show that a proper foundation and moti-vation are lacking in vast numbers of court rulings in criminal andcivil jurisdictions. This explains much of the low predictability, con-sistency, and coherency (i.e., lack of the rule of law) perceived by thepublic (Buscaglia and van Dijk 2003). These kinds of assessments incriminal, civil, and labor jurisdictions have uncovered many rulingswithin the same case-types where a contradictory application of juris-prudential criteria is present in the same court or in courts corre-sponding to the same jurisdiction. Moreover, substantive flaws arefound during audits of court rulings where, for example, case-relatedfacts are systematically not adjusted to the required categorizationstipulated by the criminal or civil codes. Other abuses include unjus-tified procedural delays, contradictory uses of jurisprudence in thesame case-types found in the same court, and the use of irrelevantjurisprudence or unrelated (i.e., incorrect) laws to support judicialrulings (Buscaglia and Gonzalez-Ruiz 2002).

The Buscaglia and van Dijk (2003) analysis also demonstratesthat judicial independence is strongly related to levels of organizedcrime. And results show a strong relationship between the perceivedindependence of the judiciary and the perceived extent of judicialcorruption. Statistical analysis confirmed that independent judges

Page 21: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_19 rev2 page 19

19Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

were less vulnerable to corruption and better able to implement lawsagainst organized crime, even when the political system and otherareas of the state had been captured by organized crime. In the coun-tries included in the study discussed above, corrupt judges were foundto abuse their substantive and procedural discretion through rulingsthat slowed down or obstructed law enforcement in organized crimecases. Among the factors making it possible for organized crime tocapture the court system, the most important were procedural com-plexity and abuses of substantive judicial discretion. Those links wereverified (e.g., that greater procedural complexity was linked to judicialcorruption and to higher levels of organized crime). The link betweenthe abuse of substantive judicial discretion on the one hand, andjudicial corruption and increases in organized crime on the other, wasconfirmed through another analysis. Moreover, the lack of predict-ability in judicial rulings was linked to higher levels of both courtcorruption and organized criminal activities (Buscaglia and van Dijk2003, appendix A, tables 13, 1–19).

These and other abuses of judicial discretion constitute the mainfactor hampering effective legal implementation and cause an increas-ing gap between law on the books and law in action. There is a clearcause-effect relationship between more consistent and more coherentjudicial rulings linked to drug trafficking and lower levels of organizedcrime. Improved consistency and coherency are ensured by effectivecontrol systems applied to rulings by either judicial councils or appel-late court systems. Comparatively rated, the countries with the bestjudicial systems and lowest levels of organized crime are, in decreasingorder: Iceland, Norway, Denmark, Singapore, Finland, Austria, Swe-den, Luxembourg, Switzerland, New Zealand, Hong Kong, and theUnited Kingdom. On the other hand, those countries found to lackconsistency and coherence in their rulings (i.e., those having frequentabuses of judicial discretion) are also countries where organized crimetends to grow. The worst in these respects, in declining order, areColombia, Venezuela, Indonesia, the Russian Federation, Argentina,

Page 22: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_20 rev2 page 20

20 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

Mexico, Brazil, the Philippines, South Africa, Thailand, India, andthe Slovak Republic. These results (Buscaglia and van Dijk 2003) arefounded on United Nations’ databases.5

In sum, the countries with the best legal implementation strate-gies in the organized crime domain have developed computerized casemanagement processes for police, prosecutors, and judges, codevel-oping multiagency task force systems (for investigations and prose-cutions) and computerized court administration. Such reform hasmade internal corruption and infiltration by organized crime lesslikely through organizational re-engineering, including elimination ofprocedural complexity, and through reducing the abuse of proceduraland substantive judicial discretion. In that connection, legislaturesmust contribute to empowering the judicial system to take on newand innovative programs by amending laws to allow the introductionof electronic ways of handling complex evidence linking many casefiles, and by enacting subsidiary legislation for better case manage-ment and for upgrading judges’ salaries.

Best International Practices in CounteractingOrganized Crime and Public Sector Corruption

There have been some successful or “model” national experiences inthe fight against organized crime and public sector corruption. All ofthese best practices were tailored to local institutions before beingcarried out nationally. For example, the institutional fight againstorganized crime, developed during the 1980s and early 1990s inFrance, Italy, and the United States, included the best practices dis-cussed below (Buscaglia and Gonzalez-Ruiz 2002). Policy analysisbased on the Buscaglia and van Dijk (2003) composite indexesexplained above confirms a very strong association between high lev-els of organized crime and high levels of public sector corruption. Onthe one hand, rampant corruption offers opportunities for organizedcrime that will be readily exploited by emerging terrorist groups in

Page 23: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_21 rev2 page 21

21Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

their constant quest to supply their operations. On the other hand,when organized crime acquires a dominant position, corruption in thepublic sector is bound to grow and the state is likely to be capturedpartly or completely by criminal groups. The ways in which organizedcrime and public sector corruption “feed” each other justifies treatingthese complex crimes in the joint manner used throughout our policyrecommendations below. Following are some of the best internationalpractices in analyzing and counteracting organized crime and publicsector corruption.

The Organized Crime–Corruption Nexus

Five levels of organized criminal infiltration of the public sectors havebeen identified and need to be addressed by policy makers. (1) Thefirst level consists of sporadic acts of bribery or other abuse of publicoffice in local government agencies by organized crime. This kind ofinfiltration can be found in most developing countries with weakgovernance. (2) The second level consists of frequent corruption inlow-ranking state officials on the organized crime payroll. This secondkind of infiltration is commonly directed at international bordercheckpoints to ease the traffic of illegal goods and human beings. (3)The third level occurs when organized crime infiltrates the mid-ranksof public sector agencies in an attempt to capture the operationaleffectiveness of, for example, law enforcement and the judiciary, thuseasing the operations of criminal groups. (4) The fourth level of infil-tration compromises the heads of public agencies, like the formerMexican drug czar, responsible directly or indirectly for fighting orga-nized crime–related activities (Buscaglia and Gonzalez-Ruiz 2002) oroccurs in agencies providing potential long-term benefits to a criminalgroup, such as Paraguay’s custom office. This level represents anincreased perniciousness with negative long-term effects on the abilityof the state to eradicate corruption and organized crime. (5) Finally,the fifth level of infiltration of organized crime encompasses the cap-

Page 24: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_22 rev2 page 22

22 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

ture of the state’s policies by criminal groups who are then able tobias lawmaking, law enforcement, and judicial decisions themselves.This fifth kind of state infiltration, which has been prevalent in theRussian Federation, involves high officials such as senators, ministers,or even presidents of countries. At this fifth level of infiltration, orga-nized crime groups compromise the campaign financing of politicians,act through other more common kinds of extortion or through familyconnections to high officials, and engage in public procurement. Thisstate capture represents the highest level of public sector corruptionand is the basic ingredient in the expansion and consolidation oftransnational organized crime.

Experiences in countries’ fighting the links between organizedcrime and public sector corruption show that soft measures alone,such as integrity awareness campaigns, do not have much effect andcan even reinforce public cynicism. As shown in Buscaglia and Gon-zalez-Ruiz (2002), the organized crime–corruption nexus can only betackled through a two-pronged approach of civil society, throughoperational social control mechanisms on the one hand, and moreeffective law enforcement and prosecution-judicial units on the other.

Criminal Justice Reform: Legislative Issues and Investigative Tools

In order to successfully implement the right legal and criminal justicepolicy reforms against the combination of organized crime and publicsector corruption, states must first have appropriate legal instruments.

In the legal domain, a few countries such as the United Statesand Germany have pioneered legal practices in which the conspiracyor agreement to commit a crime can be punished, and as a result,these countries have successfully reduced the scale and scope of orga-nized crime. France has declared illicit association, or membership-participation in a criminal enterprise, a form of criminal activity, andthis practice has been transplanted from the criminal code of Franceto the codes of other countries, in particular, of Italy, Spain, and some

Page 25: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_23 rev2 page 23

23Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

states in Latin America. Other countries have outlawed crimes com-mitted collectively by groups. In Italy these are called “associatedcrimes” or “Mafia-type crimes.” In the United States, legislators haveenacted the Racketeer Influenced and Corrupt Organizations law (theso-called RICO statute) that prohibits engaging in an enterpriseinvolved in a pattern of criminal activity (racketeering). Judicial rul-ings have established that a “RICO enterprise” has an organizationalstructure that carries on its business through primarily criminal activ-ities, with the high probability that these activities will continue inthe future. In all these countries it has been shown that the inno-vative statutes of the country-specific laws can, and have, greatlyenhanced the judicial system’s ability to dismember or at least inhibita criminal organization.6

Within these legal frameworks, several countries pioneering anti-Mafia policies have also improved their operational ability to gatherand analyze complex evidentiary material, over and above the tradi-tional or conventional techniques of investigation. These moderntechniques include wire-tapping, controlled deliveries, electronic sur-veillance, and testimony obtained from witnesses through offers ofimmunity or other incentives, coupled with the protection of wit-nesses. Here the United States and Italy have taken the lead.

Moreover, the experiences of Germany, Italy, and the UnitedStates in fighting organized crime show that law enforcement re-quires the most advanced intelligence analysis capabilities in general,and financial intelligence capabilities in particular. These nationalcapabilities should include the ability to engage in case-specific inter-national law enforcement and judicial cooperation to support antic-ipatory, proactive investigations and prosecutions by clearlydetermining (1) the structure, composition, and primary activities ofcriminal networks; (2) the criminal groups’ modus operandi (includ-ing their production, marketing, and financial logistics); (3) the con-tacts of organized crime groups with licit business sectors; and (4) theclear delineation of international anticipatory law enforcement strat-

Page 26: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_24 rev2 page 24

24 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

egies. This approach to investigating and prosecuting criminal groupshas shown a record of success in Italy and the United States by pre-venting and hampering the strategies of organized crime to capturestates through high-level corruption.

The Need for Specialized Anti-Mafia Units

International experience further shows that establishing specializedunits against organized crime in the police and judicial systems (suchas in Mexico) or task forces in the criminal justice system engaged ininternational mutual assistance (such as in the United States) is aneffective tool in fighting organized crime.

The establishment of a task force to conduct a complex investi-gation may be limited to the participation of a single agency or maytake a multiagency approach in which representatives from lawenforcement and the judiciary are assigned to specific cases. For exam-ple, a task force (composed of skilled police investigators, prosecutors,and financial intelligence units) offers the opportunity to use a ded-icated unit without depleting the investigative resources of a singleorganization. The use of team members from other investigative orregulatory agencies often facilitates the gathering of complex evi-dence. The team concept allows the clear allocation of assignmentsand responsibilities among members and promotes a sense of unity,all necessary for the team’s success.

In this context, questions of leadership need to be addressed.When multiple agencies are represented in a common work unit, aleadership team must be established with two or more investigatorsfrom different agencies who share main responsibilities and confiden-tial information on investigative strategies. Legal advisers or prose-cutorial representatives should be included in the team to give timelylegal assistance and direction on gathering evidentiary material.

As stated above, the building of specialized units in all segmentsof the criminal justice system is essential for success. The team-based

Page 27: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_25 rev2 page 25

25Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

management of cases, including specialized pools of investigators,prosecutors, and judges, has been introduced with success in Chile,Singapore, and Italy to handle complex criminal cases involving assetforfeiture. In Mexico and some other countries, the formation of eliteunits of judicial and federal law enforcement agents has been crucialin achieving improvement in the investigations and prosecutions oforganized crime cases (Buscaglia and Gonzalez-Ruiz 2002). In addi-tion, these cases have shown that a national coordinating strategyneeds to provide for a centralized and consistent database on orga-nized crime groups to be consulted in real time by law enforcementand judicial officers.

Upgrading Judicial Follow-Up

Although higher expenditures for criminal justice by themselves donot ensure better organized crime and corruption control, clearly thecriminal justice systems of most developing countries with the polit-ical commitment to fight organized crime are critically underfunded.The differences in current and capital spending between developedand developing countries are increasing. For example, developingcountries spend an average of $5 to $10 on criminal justice per citi-zen. However, highly developed economies spend over $165 per cit-izen on police, prosecutors, and judges. Developed economies havemore to spend, and sometimes they even overspend. Yet the analysisconducted in Buscaglia and van Dijk (2003) shows that 87 percentof low- and middle-income countries in the large sample do not allo-cate enough resources to keep their criminal justice systems runningfunctionally. Besides budget increases, reallocations of current budgetresources may be warranted in many of these countries where thepolice already receive disproportionately generous funding, whereasthe prosecutorial and court domains starve from the lack of basicoperational resources. Without functioning prosecutorial and judicialsystems, law enforcement alone cannot contribute effectively to better

Page 28: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_26 rev2 page 26

26 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

conditions for implementing laws and thus combating complexcrimes.

In this framework, the courts must monitor and control the prog-ress of cases from filing to disposition by following a group manage-ment approach with a first-instance court judge and a pool ofprosecutors jointly managing the case. Experience in Singapore showsthat the assignment of cases to different management tracks (i.e.,assignment of case files to express, standard, and complex tracksbased, among other things, on the quality and quantity of evidentiarymaterial) can also reduce the procedural time and abuse of discretionin judicial rulings. Singapore’s judicial experience shows that this sys-tem of anticipatory management usually needs to be supported bycomputerized case-tracking technology, which makes it possible tohandle case assignments and respond to law enforcement and judicialofficers’ concerns on-line in real time. Therefore, reform must ensurethe channeling of more cases to these special task forces, increasingthe attention given to financial investigations and the building ofmore valuable evidentiary material supported by intelligence analysis.

In best-practice countries such as Italy, Singapore, and the UnitedStates, a system to implement asset forfeitures and their financialmanagement has also been upgraded to expedite the most effectivemeasures against the most important foundations and roots of orga-nized crime. Technical personnel and judicial staff must adopt betterinformation technologies to support case management and the latestinvestigative techniques such as the use of electronic surveillance, aswell as undercover operations and collaborating witnesses. As anincentive to achieve greater operational efficiency, law enforcementagencies can be allowed to retain the proceeds of asset forfeitures,which can be allocated to staff welfare accounts and organizationalimprovements. In Chile, for example, an agency handles payment offines and refunds of bail electronically, with payments credited to thelaw enforcement departments achieving predetermined performanceindicators. Experience in Singapore and elsewhere shows that higher

Page 29: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_27 rev2 page 27

27Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

salaries attract more qualified personnel if subject to strict perfor-mance-based indicators, thus making corrupt practices less likely(Root 1996; Nadelmann 1993). Yet structural reform of the judicialsystem is needed first and must include strengthening and moderniz-ing financial management and budgeting, as well as training anddeveloping administrative staff.

Involving Civil Society

The criminal justice systems with the highest effectiveness in fightingorganized crime and public sector corruption usually rely on the will-ingness of citizens to collaborate with state law enforcement efforts.Building this public confidence and trust in the criminal justice sys-tem requires first showing civil societies the tangible results of suc-cessful policy reform. Moreover, the leaders of the judiciary and lawenforcement, the attorney general, chief prosecutor, chief of nationalpolice, and members of the Supreme Court, must set good examplesby adopting high ethical standards and by establishing strict proce-dures for ensuring that cases are attended to with due process and areconcluded expeditiously. In this, the political will and ability to exe-cute reform are preconditions for building public trust and later forcarrying out successful criminal justice policies.

The reform of the criminal justice system in best-practice coun-tries has needed the help and support of other institutions. Politicalsupport has fostered an independent criminal justice system and theability to fight organized crime and public sector corruption, as shownin the legal and judicial reform carried out in Chile and Costa Rica(Buscaglia 1997). Recognizing this early on, countries such as Italyhave sought to build bridges between the public sectors and civilsociety. The relative success in fighting against state captures orches-trated by the Mafia in Palermo (Italy) shows that public information-education campaigns, coupled with the fostering of innovativecultures of institutional change within the state, have been catalysts

Page 30: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_28 rev2 page 28

28 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

in reducing the pernicious effect of organized crime on public sectorcorruption (Orlando 2001).

In addition, civil society institutions such as the bar associationand law schools can play an important part in the reform process. Forexample, establishing civil society bodies, each composed of a panelof lawyers and other members of the public acting as “court watchers,”has proved to enhance the legitimacy of the judiciary in Italy, CostaRica, and the United States. Successful efforts at forging partnershipsfor reform set a good example of the balance that can be struckbetween internal priorities on the one hand and public sector andsocietal concerns on the other.

Enhancing Judicial Independence

A balance between judicial accountability and the judicial institu-tions’ independence from political forces is a necessary condition forachieving success in enforcing laws to fight organized crime and publicsector corruption (Orlando 2001), just as an efficient judiciary isessential for fast and lasting economic development (Begovic 2004).Yet this balance between democratic accountability and institutionalindependence requires a prior basic consensus among the main polit-ical forces within countries. Constitutional provisions requiring theseparation of powers are not enough to guarantee the judicial inde-pendence needed for the unbiased and transparent interpretation andenforcement of the law. Formal constitutional provisions are not evena necessary condition for attaining judicial independence. Countriessuch as Israel, New Zealand, Sweden, and the United Kingdom—allcountries with high levels of judicial independence coupled with loworganized crime and low levels of corruption—do not possess consti-tutionally entrenched judicial independence.

The examination of international experience shows that thepolitical elements contributing to an independent criminal justice sys-tem’s ability to fight organized crime and public sector corruption can

Page 31: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_29 rev2 page 29

29Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

be identified. For example, the cases of Costa Rica, and to somedegree, Chile, show that when the political concentration of powerin the legislative and executive branches is relatively balanced, sothat alternation in power is the likely outcome of periodical elections,judicial systems are all the more able to interpret laws with inde-pendence and autonomy. To some degree, a balance of power amongtruly competing political forces creates an increased willingnessamong politicians to give up a good part of their political control ofcourt and prosecutorial decisions in order to avoid a “mutually assureddestruction” in subsequent electoral periods when the opposition maytake over the reins of power. This sequential game between or amongpolitical forces operates as a tacit insurance policy that guaranteesgreater independence of the criminal justice system from politicalwhims (Buscaglia 1997).

Accordingly, a framework guiding policy makers during legal andjudicial reform must first identify the main areas where undue pressureis most likely to hamper the state’s ability to adjudicate cases of orga-nized crime and public sector corruption. The identification of theseareas must focus on the links between judicial systems and other gov-ernmental and nongovernmental institutions, without neglecting toreview factors hampering independence in the judiciaries themselves.Once the political preconditions for the policy reforms mentionedabove are present, initiatives must then address technical best prac-tices. Lessons from case studies in Costa Rica, Chile, Italy, and Sin-gapore show the following best practices enhancing the judicialindependence of courts and prosecutors (Buscaglia 1997; Root 1996):

1. The development of improved, uniform, and widespread case-management systems, coupled with transparent, coherent, andconsistent rules for case assignments.

2. The adoption of uniform and predictable administrative (i.e., per-sonnel and budget-related) measures founded on rewards and pen-

Page 32: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_30 rev2 page 30

30 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

alties driven by performance-based indicators, thus clarifying thecareer horizon of judicial and law enforcement officers.

3. The reform of the criminal justice system’s organizational struc-ture. This includes introducing a more divided set of organiza-tional roles for judicial, prosecutorial, and police personnel tosecure their own internal independence.

4. The enhancement of the judiciary’s ability to review the consis-tency and coherency of decisions instilled in court rulings byimproving the effectiveness of judicial (appellate-based) reviewsand by allowing the monitoring of civil society–based social con-trol mechanisms, working hand in hand with the media (e.g.,court-watching NGO types).

5. The governance-related improvements in links between the polit-ical arena and judiciary in accord with the preconditionsdescribed above.

Policies in the Socioeconomic and Financial Domains

Those countries pursuing best-practice policies in the fight againstorganized crime and public sector corruption have also adopted eco-nomic and financial policies that go beyond the legal and judicialmeasures stated above. It is clear now that in tackling corruption andorganized crime, multidimensional measures are needed.

In the economic-financial domain in the fight against organizedcriminal groups, best practices include

1. Reducing poverty and raising salaries for public employees tohamper the uncontrolled growth of corruption that tends toincrease political instability, which in turn stimulates the pene-tration of the state by national criminal organizations or, worse,by transnational ones

2. Reducing the incidence and dimension of informal markets that

Page 33: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_31 rev2 page 31

31Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

provide the economic inputs and outputs related to organizedcrime

3. Improving the distribution of income and wealth

4. Reducing barriers to the international exchange of goods andservices

5. Adopting and more coherently applying financial regulationsthrough specialized supervisory state agencies for handling finan-cial investigations

In the financial regulatory domain, the experience of Mexicoshows that the state’s ability to trace, identify, monitor, seize, andconfiscate financial assets and other criminal proceeds is critical tothe strategy of any organized crime containment program. Thisrequires a major global infrastructure of legislation not only forrestraining criminal proceeds but also for confiscation purposes.

As drug-related issues gain prominence in the international polit-ical culture, there have been several efforts to reform the anti-laun-dering and criminal proceeds legislation in many countries, as well asto expand the police and prosecutorial roles in financial investigations(including customs and excise), increasingly involving tax fraud andterrorist activities. For instance, in 2000 the Financial Action TaskForce (FATF) launched its “Non Co-operating Countries and Terri-tories Initiative.” This initiative, a move toward an all-crime andtransnational organized crime focus, was intended to counteract theslow adoption of FATF standards in some territories and is accom-panied by guidelines for regulated banks in imposing more severesanctions for noncompliance. Even more complicated at this pointwould be an international effort to legalize certain drugs, an effortthat many advocate (and many others strongly oppose) in order tobetter control drug use and the crime that now surrounds drug use(Carpenter 2003; Jordan 1999).

Page 34: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_32 rev2 page 32

32 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

Main Conclusions

The ability of a country to develop economically and of internationalterrorist groups to operate effectively within a country depends inlarge part on the terrorists’ logistical and strategic links to organizedcriminal networks and on the degree of support they enjoy from pub-lic sector corruption. The levels of organized crime and of publicsector corruption in countries are determined first by the quality ofthe central state institutions, such as the police, prosecutors, andcourts. This relationship seems to hold for countries in all stages ofdevelopment. In this context, the institutional forces preconditioningimprovements in the legal fight against corruption and organizedcrime are accounted for in this essay. These conditions are the onesfostering an institutional environment within which criminal justicecan be administered in an unbiased and transparent fashion. Inde-pendently of these institutional determinants, the levels of organizedcrime and corruption are linked to human development while under-development and rampant organized crime go hand in hand. Thislink points to the vicious circle of poverty exploited by terroristorganizations and in extreme cases to deficient state agencies that arebrought under the control of organized crime.

Taken as a group, these facts confirm that organized crime, cor-ruption, and underdevelopment prosper in an environment of badgovernance. Insufficiencies in economic and financial regulation andpoor legal-judicial infrastructures are among the many negativeaspects of governance relevant for crime control. This appears to bethe case for developing countries generally and for countries inpostconflict situations in particular. Countries that have given priorityto crime and corruption control in the early stages of developmentare now among the most economically successful in their regions,among them Singapore in Southeast Asia and Botswana in sub-Saharan Africa. In Europe, the capital city of Sicily, Palermo, offersa telling example of how better control of the local Mafia has come

Page 35: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_33 rev2 page 33

33Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

along with strong economic revival. The list of countries and regionswith dysfunctional state systems, rampant organized crime and cor-ruption, and stagnant economies is depressingly long by comparison(World Bank 2002). These dysfunctional states simply emphasize thefact that by strengthening their ability to prevent and control orga-nized crime, states can both fight the economic foundations of ter-rorism and eliminate a major impediment to human, economic, andeven political development.

Too few developing countries and development experts seem tohave fully appreciated the far-reaching effect of a functioning justicesystem (Ratliff and Buscaglia 1997). Unlike conventional crime,which seems largely controlled by structural root causes outside thesphere of short- or medium-term influence of the state (van Dijk1999), organized crime and corruption seem more susceptible to stateinterventions. This finding has important implications for both crimecontrol and development policies. If development prospects aredependent on the effective control of organized crime and corruptionthrough law enforcement and the rule of law, the latter emerge asthe main hidden success or failure conditions of human development,at least in many parts of the world, or perhaps everywhere in thelonger term. This conclusion opens the prospect of enhanced devel-opment through constructive, focused interventions of relatively lim-ited proportions in developing countries. Investment in the legalinfrastructure of developing countries, aimed at abilities to deal withorganized crime, will be small in comparison with the investmentneeded to bring physical infrastructures up to international standards,but the latter will be far more possible, in most areas, in a countryruled by law. The return on investment, in increased human devel-opment, will be vastly higher in the medium period than whatresulted from traditional development cooperation in the past.

One could say that the world’s legal landscape has been trans-formed within a decade as an increasing number of countries, forexample, have enforced or adopted laws permitting or requiring the

Page 36: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_34 rev2 page 34

34 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

disclosure of assets and mutual legal assistance, though these coun-tries’ actual conformity with the FATF’s standards varies. Few repu-table financial centers offer bank secrecy as an option. Nevertheless,the visible enforcement of financial regulations aimed at the proceedsof organized crime has been modest. Moreover, the operational in-ability of police, prosecutors, and judges to handle cases involvingfinancial investigations is still an institutional constraint in mostcountries. In short, experience in Chile, Italy, Mexico, and theUnited States shows that strengthened financial regulatory frame-works come hand in hand with lower levels of organized crime, atthe same time that these frameworks are not easily adopted or imple-mented.

Notes

1. For the text of the convention, see www.unodc.org/palermo/convmain.html.

2. The Falcone checklist gives an operational account of organized criminalgroups working in a certain jurisdiction by describing the composition,structure, modus operandi, licit-illicit linkages, and other aspects neededfor the investigation and prosecution of criminal networks. For moredetails, see Buscaglia and Gonzalez-Ruiz (2002).

3. This jurimetric study covers a large sample of countries, representingworldwide interregional diversity stratified by level of socioeconomicdevelopment. It deals with the following states and territories: Albania,Argentina, Australia, Austria, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Belgium, Bolivia, Bot-swana, Brazil, Bulgaria, Canada, China, Colombia, Costa Rica, Croatia,Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Georgia, Germany,Greece, Hong Kong Special Administrative Region of China, Hungary,India, Indonesia, Ireland, Italy, Jamaica, Japan, Kyrgyzstan, Latvia, Lith-uania, Malaysia, Malta, Mongolia, Netherlands, Paraguay, Peru, Philip-pines, Poland, Portugal, Republic of Korea, Romania, Russian Federation,Singapore, Slovakia, Slovenia, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland,Thailand, Uganda, Ukraine, United Kingdom of Great Britain andNorthern Ireland, United States of America, Venezuela, Vietnam, Yugo-

Page 37: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_35 rev2 page 35

35Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

slavia, the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, and Zimbabwe. Polit-ical, governmental, socioeconomic, legal, and criminal justice factors areall tested for statistical significance in explaining the ups and downs inorganized crime and public sector corruption.

4. In particular, Buscaglia and van Dijk (2003) compiled data on the smug-gling of firearms (taking into account manufacturing, sales, imports, andexports—already computed by the UN); the estimates of cigarette smug-gling, car theft, and consumer fraud victimization (ICVS); the number ofhomicides (UN, Interpol, World Health Organization); the size of theinformal economy (Heritage Foundation); the business sector’s percep-tions of organized crime prevalence (World Economic Forum); the inflowof laundered money in millions of dollars per year as a part of the grossdomestic product (Walker Index); and the trafficking in human beings bynationalities of suspects (UN Center for International Crime Prevention[CICP] Human Trafficking database). They ranked each country for eachvariable to compute the composite organized crime index as an average ofthe rankings that every country shows for each item mentioned above.Each component showed strong correlations with the organized crimeindex, with costs for business, homicide, and money-laundering being thebest predictors.

5. Statistical tables showing the results of the study presented here can befound at www.unodc.org/pdf/crime/forum/stat_tables.pdf.

6. Refer to US Code Title 18 (RICO laws). On participation in a criminalassociation, see the French Criminal Code, Title V, articles 450-1–450-4;the Italian Penal Code, Royal Decree No. 1398 of October 19, 1930,articles 416, “Association for purposes of committing offences,” and 416bis, “Mafia-type association”; and the Spanish Criminal Code, articles 515and 516, on illicit association.

References

Alford, William P. 1995. To Steal a Book Is an Elegant Offense: IntellectualProperty Law in Chinese Civilization. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford UniversityPress.

Begovic, Boris, et al. 2004. Corruption in Judiciary. Belgrade: Center for Liberal-Democratic Studies.

Page 38: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_36 rev2 page 36

36 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

Burnett, John S. 2002. Dangerous Waters: Modern Piracy and Terror on the HighSeas. New York: Dutton.

Buscaglia, Edgardo. 1993. “Legal and Economic Development: The MissingLinks.” Journal of Inter-American Studies and World Affairs. Winter.

———. 1997. “An Economic Analysis of Corrupt Practices within the Judi-ciary in Latin America.” Law and Economics (Deventer, Netherlands: Klu-wer Press) 5:289–321.

———. 1999. Judicial Corruption in Developing Countries: Its Causes and Eco-nomic Consequences. Essays in Public Policy. Stanford, Calif.: HooverInstitution Press.

———. 2001. “An Analysis of Judicial Corruption and Its Causes: An Objec-tive Governance-Based Approach.” International Review of Law and Eco-nomics 21 (2): 233–249.

Buscaglia, Edgardo, and Maria Dakolias. 1999. “Comparative InternationalStudy of Court Performance Indicators: A Descriptive and AnalyticalAccount.” Legal and Judicial Reform Unit Technical Paper. Washington,DC: World Bank.

Buscaglia, Edgardo, and Samuel Gonzalez-Ruiz. 2002. “How to Design aNational Strategy against Organized Crime in the Framework of theUnited Nations?” In Palermo Convention in the Fight against OrganizedCrime. Vienna: United Nations International Drug Control Programme.23–26.

Buscaglia, Edgardo, and William Ratliff. 2000. Law and Economics in Develop-ing Countries. Stanford, Calif: Hoover Institution Press.

———. 2001. War and Lack of Governance in Colombia. Essay in Public Policy,No. 107. Stanford, Calif.: Hoover Institution Press.

Buscaglia, Edgardo, and Jan van Dijk. 2003. “Controlling Organized Crimeand Public Sector Corruption: Results of the Global Trends Study.” InUnited Nations Forum. Vienna: United Nations Press.

Carpenter, Ted Galen. 2003. Bad Neighbor Policy: Washington’s Futile War onDrugs in Latin America. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

China Reform Monitor. 2005. “Taking the PRC to Task on Intellectual Prop-erty,” no. 587 (May 5).

Cooter, Robert. (1994). “Structural Adjudication and the New Law Mer-chant: A Model of Decentralized Law.” International Review of Law andEconomics 14:215–231.

Page 39: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_37 rev2 page 37

37Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

———. 1996. “The Theory of Market Modernization of Law.” InternationalReview of Law and Economics 16 (2): 141–172.

de Soto, Hernando. 1989. The Other Path (Harper & Row, 1990).

———. 1997. “Preface.” The Law and Economics of Development, ed. EdgardoBuscaglia, William Ratliff, and Robert Cooter. New Jersey: JAI Press.

———. 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West andFails Everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books.

Diamant, Neil J., Stanley B. Lubman, and Kevin J. O’Brien, editors. 2005.Engaging the Law in China. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.

Economist. 2005. “A New Offensive.” March 3.

Eggertsson, Thrainn. 1990. Economic Behavior and Institutions. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.

Financial Action Task Force on Money Laundering, Annual Report 2000–2001.Paris.

Ginsburg, Tom. 2000. “Does Law Matter for Economic Development? Evi-dence from East Asia.” Law & Society Review 34 (3).

Hayek, Friedrich A. 1973. Law, Legislation and Liberty. Chicago: University ofChicago Press.

Jordan, David. 1999. Drug Politics: Dirty Money and Democracies. Norman:University of Oklahoma Press.

Laogai. 2003–2004. Laogai Handbook. Washington, DC: Laogai ResearchFoundation.

Lubman, Stanley. 1999. Bird in a Cage: Legal Reform in China after Mao. Stan-ford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.

Mattei, Ugo. 1991. “Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries: A Compar-ative Approach.” International Review of Law and Economics 11 (3): 265–275.

Mauro, Paolo. 1995. “Corruption and Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics111: 681–711.

Mertha, Andrew. 2005. “Shifting Legal and Administrative Goalposts.” InDiamant, Ludman, and O’Brien, Engaging the Law in China.

Nadelmann, Ethan. 1993. Cops across Borders: The Internationalization of U.S.Criminal Law Enforcement. University Park: Pennsylvania State Univer-sity Press.

Page 40: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_38 rev2 page 38

38 Buscaglia, Gonzalez-Ruiz, and Ratliff

Nazarbayev, Nursultan, Kazakhstan president. 2000. Interview by WilliamRatliff. March 21. Astana, Kazakhstan. Hoover Institution Archives.

North, Douglass. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Perfor-mance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Orlando, Leoluca. 2001. Fighting the Mafia and Renewing Sicilian Culture. SanFrancisco: Encounter Books.

Ratliff, William. 1999. “Development and Civil Society in Latin America andAsia.” The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Sciences565 (September).

———. 2003. Doing it Right and Doing it Wrong: Education Reform in Asia andLatin America. Essay in Public Policy. Stanford, Calif.: Hoover InstitutionPress.

———. 2005a. “Interviews with Officials of the International MaritimeBureau’s Piracy Reporting Centre in Kuala Lumpur and Ship CaptainsWho Use the Malacca Strait.” Interviews by William Ratliff. March. SeeSan Francisco Chronicle. “Pirates Preying on Vessels Could Instead BeTerrorists.” May 8.

———. 2005b. “Red Dragon, Black Gold,” Hoover Digest,” no. 2. Spring.

Ratliff, William, and Edgardo Buscaglia. 1997. “Judicial Reform: TheNeglected Priority in Latin America.” The Annals of the American Acad-emy of Political and Social Science 550 (March).

Root, Hilton. 1996. Small Countries, Big Lessons: Governance and the Rise ofEast Asia. New York: Oxford University Press.

Seidman, Robert B. 1978. State, Law and Development. New York: St Martin’sPress.

Shelley, Louise I. 1995. “Transnational Organized Crime: An ImminentThreat to the Nation-State?” Journal of International Affairs ( CASE Jour-nals) 48 (Winter): 463–489.

“United Nations Convention against Transnational Organized Crime andthe Protocols Thereto” at www.odccp.org/odccp/crime_cicp_convention.html.

United Nations Information Service. 2000. “Palermo Convention’s High-Level Political Signing Conference.”

U.S. Department of State. 2005. “Background Note: Botswana.”

Page 41: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp 114 Mp_39 rev2 page 39

39Undermining Organized Crime and Public Corruption

van Dijk, Jan. 1999. The Experience of Crime and Justice. Oxford: Oxford Uni-versity Press.

Vargas Llosa Alvaro. 2005. Liberty for Latin America: How to Undo Five Hun-dred Years of State Oppression. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.

Watson, Alan. 1978. “Comparative Law and Legal Change.” Columbia LawJournal 313:45–67.

Williams, Phil. 2001. “Organising Transnational Crime: Networks, Marketsand Hierarchies.” In Combating Transnational Crime: Concepts, Activitiesand Responses, ed. Phil Williams and Dimitri Vlassis. London: Frank Cass.

World Bank. 2002. World Bank Group Work in Low-Income Countries underStress: A Task Force Report.

World Economic Forum. 2000. “Organized Crime Imposes Cost on Busi-nesses.” In The Global Competitiveness Report. Geneva, Switzerland: WEFPress.

———. 2004. Global Competitiveness Report 2004–2005.

Yardley, Jim. 2005. “Issue in China: Many in Jail without Trial.” New YorkTimes, May 9.

Page 42: Undermining the Foundations of Organized Crime and Public Sector

Hoover Press : EPP 114 hepp list Mp_40 rev0 page 40

ESSAYS IN PUBLIC POLICY

The Future of the Korean Peninsulaand Northeast Asian SecurityLee Hoi-Chang, 2005

The Debate on China’s Exchange Rate:Should or Will It Be Revalued?Jialin Zhang, 2004

Russia’s Oil in America’s Future:Policy, Pipelines, and ProspectsWilliam Ratliff, 2003

Doing It Wrong and Doing It Right:Education in Latin America and AsiaWilliam Ratliff, 2003

The Right to Private PropertyTibor R. Machan, 2002

Some Implications of the Turnover ofPolitical Power in TaiwanLinda Chao, Ramon H. Myers, andJialin Zhang, 2002

War and Lack of Governance in Colombia:Narcos, Guerrillas, and U.S. PolicyEdgardo Buscaglia and William Ratliff,2001

Personalizing Crises Alastair Smith, 2000

Democratizing the World TradeOrganization Fiona McGillivray, 2000

In Sickness or in Health: The KyotoProtocol versus Global WarmingThomas Gale Moore, 2000

U.S.-China Trade Issues after theWTO and the PNTR Deal: A ChinesePerspective Jialin Zhang, 2000

Climate Policy—from Rio to Kyoto:A Political Issue for 2000—and BeyondS. Fred Singer, 2000

The Divided China Problem:Conflict Avoidance and ResolutionLinda Chao and Ramon H. Myers, 2000

A Strategic Flip-Flop in the Caribbean:Lift the Embargo on CubaWilliam Ratliff and Roger Fontaine, 2000

Political Instability as a Source of GrowthBruce Bueno de Mesquita, 2000

Who Benefits and Who Pays for MinimumWage Increases in California? A Perspectiveon Proposition 210 Thomas MaCurdy andMargaret O’Brien-Strain, 2000

Party Intellectuals’ Demands forReform in Contemporary ChinaWenfang Tang, 1999

The Case against the International MonetaryFund Lawrence J. McQuillan, 1999

Judicial Corruption in Developing Countries:Its Causes and Economic ConsequencesEdgardo Buscaglia, 1999

Capitalism and Its Discontents:The Adam Smith AddressMichael J. Boskin, 1999

The Economic Effects of the LiabilitySystem Daniel P. Kessler, 1999

Reforming Hazardous Waste PolicyHilary Sigman, 1999

Welfare for the Well-Off: HowBusiness Subsidies Fleece TaxpayersStephen Moore, 1999

Using Power and Diplomacyto Deal with Rogue StatesThomas H. Henriksen, 1999

The Congressional Response toSocial Security Surpluses, 1935–1994John F. Cogan, 1998

Hong Kong under Chinese Rule:The First Year David Newman andAlvin Rabushka, 1998

Affirmative Action in Higher Education:A Dilemma of Conflicting PrinciplesJohn H. Bunzel, 1998

Publications in this series address public policy issues or developments of interest toa broad audience including government officials, the media, and scholars. Somerecent essays are posted on our website (www.hoover.org). A complete list of Essaysin Public Policy published since 1984 is available on request.

HOOVER INSTITUTION PRESSStanford University • Stanford, CA 94305-6010 • (650) 723-3373