traffic fines - ntanet.org...a decline in traffic fines in 2015 caused a budget crisis for the...

33
1 Taxation by Citation? Exploring Local Governments’ Revenue Motive for Traffic Fines Min Su Assistant Professor Louisiana State University Abstract Anecdotal evidence suggests that local governments may have a revenue motive for traffic fines beyond public safety concerns. Using California county-level data over a 12-year period, this article presents findings that counties increased per capita traffic fines by 40 to 42 cents in the year immediately after a 10-percentage-point tax revenue loss in the previous year; however, these counties did not reduce traffic fines if they experienced tax revenue increase in the previous year. This finding indicates that local governments view traffic fines a revenue source to offset tax revenue loss, but not as a smoother to manage revenue fluctuation. This article also presents findings that low-income, Hispanic-majority counties raised more traffic fines. Counties that generate more revenue from transient occupancy taxa tax typically paid by travelers and visitorsraised more traffic fines, indicting a tax exporting behavior by shifting the traffic fines burden on non-local drivers. Please do not cite or circulate this paper without author’s permission.

Upload: others

Post on 11-Feb-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 1

    Taxation by Citation? Exploring Local Governments’ Revenue Motive for

    Traffic Fines

    Min Su

    Assistant Professor

    Louisiana State University

    Abstract

    Anecdotal evidence suggests that local governments may have a revenue motive for traffic fines

    beyond public safety concerns. Using California county-level data over a 12-year period, this

    article presents findings that counties increased per capita traffic fines by 40 to 42 cents in the

    year immediately after a 10-percentage-point tax revenue loss in the previous year; however,

    these counties did not reduce traffic fines if they experienced tax revenue increase in the

    previous year. This finding indicates that local governments view traffic fines a revenue source

    to offset tax revenue loss, but not as a smoother to manage revenue fluctuation. This article also

    presents findings that low-income, Hispanic-majority counties raised more traffic fines. Counties

    that generate more revenue from transient occupancy tax—a tax typically paid by travelers and

    visitors—raised more traffic fines, indicting a tax exporting behavior by shifting the traffic fines

    burden on non-local drivers.

    Please do not cite or circulate this paper without author’s permission.

  • 2

    Traffic accidents remain one of the leading causes of unintentional injuries in the United

    States (Kochanek et al. 2016). The vast majority of these traffic accidents are caused by human

    errors such as speeding, driving under the influence of alcohol, not wearing a seat belt, and

    distracted driving. Government has a long history of using traffic law enforcement to deter

    unsafe driving behaviors. Among the various traffic law enforcement tools, traffic citation is the

    primary one. A number of studies find that traffic citations effectively improve road safety.

    Makowsky and Stratmann (2011) use municipal budget shortfalls as an instrumental variable to

    examine the effect of traffic tickets on road safety. They find that increasing the number of

    traffic tickets reduced traffic accidents and accident-related injuries. DeAngelo and Hansen

    (2014) demonstrate that a mass layoff of state highway troopers in Oregon due to budget cuts

    was associated with 12 to 29 percent increase in highway deaths and injuries. Luca (2015)

    similarly discovers that traffic citations significantly reduced accidents and nonfatal injuries in

    Massachusetts.

    While the ostensible goal of traffic citation is to improve road safety, a growing body of

    evidence shows that governments may see traffic fines an important revenue source. In Nevada,

    traffic fines provide the majority of funding for the state supreme court. A decline in traffic fines

    in 2015 caused a budget crisis for the Nevada Supreme Court (Chokshi 2015). In Louisiana,

    local traffic fines are the primary revenue source for public defenders (Robertson 2016). In

    California, traffic fines pay for over 50 state funds, many of which have no connection to the

    cited traffic violations (California State Auditor 2018). In Georgia, along highway I-75, a string

    of cities and counties are known as “ticket traps” that tap Disney-bound tourists and other pass-

    through traffic (Simmons 2014). The U.S. Department of Justice’s (2015) investigation on

  • 3

    Ferguson, Missouri brought national attention to governments’ misuse of law enforcement to

    generate revenues.

    Despite growing evidence, few studies have investigated governments’ revenue motive

    for traffic fines. One influential study was conducted by Garrett and Wagner (2009). They

    observed the relationship between the number of traffic tickets and the economic conditions in

    North Carolina counties from 1990 to 2003 and found that counties issued more traffic tickets in

    the year following a revenue decline in prior year. This finding provides evidence that local

    governments have a revenue motive for traffic fines. Yet, using changes in the number of traffic

    tickets is not the most precise way to measure governments’ revenue motive. Because

    governments can increase the base fine and/or add surcharges to each traffic citation, they could

    increase traffic fine revenues without issuing more traffic tickets. Another influential study was

    conducted by Makowsky and Stratmann (2009), using the speeding traffic stops data in

    Massachusetts municipalities over a two-month period in 2001. They found that the decline of

    property tax revenue increased the likelihood a driver receiving a traffic ticket and the dollar

    amount of each citation. Furthermore, the likelihood of receiving a speeding ticket was higher in

    fiscally stressed towns. However, Makowsky and Stratmann’s (2009) study focuses solely on

    speeding tickets. Since a substantial amount of traffic fines come from parking violation,

    particularly in big cities, a more precise analysis is to use traffic fine revenue from all traffic

    violations.

    This article analyzes governments’ revenue motive for traffic fines using California

    counties’ traffic fine revenue from Vehicle Code violations, including moving violations and

    parking violations. The time span covers fiscal years from 2004 to 2015. Controlling for

    demographic, economic, fiscal, enforcement, and road-related factors, the regression results

  • 4

    show a statistically significant increase in per capita traffic fines in the year immediately

    following a tax revenue decrease in the prior year. Tax revenue increase in the previous year

    however, does not have a significant influence on per capita traffic fines in the current year.

    These results provide evidence of local governments’ revenue motive for traffic fines—they see

    traffic fines a revenue source to offset tax revenue loss.

    Background on California Counties and Traffic Fines

    The Basics of California Counties

    California has 58 counties. According to the California State Association of Counties,

    these counties operate health and human services programs as agents of the state. They also carry

    out a broad range of countywide functions such as overseeing elections and operating the

    criminal justice system. Among these counties, 44 are general law counties and 14 are charter

    counties. Charter counties have a limited degree of independent authority over certain rules but

    they lack any extra authority in budgeting and revenue increase. San Francisco is the only

    consolidated city and county in the state. Throughout this article, the analysis focuses on 57

    counties, excluding San Francisco.

    Traffic Fines in California Counties

    In California, Vehicle Code violations fall into three categories: infractions,

    misdemeanors, and felonies (see Table 1). An individual who receives a citation for a traffic

    violation is assessed an amount consisting of a base fine plus several penalty surcharges and

    assessment fees. The state legislature and the Judicial Council set the base fine. The base fine

    varies depending on the type of violation. In addition to the base fine, state and county

    governments impose surcharges and fees. The various surcharges and fees significantly increase

  • 5

    the total cost of a violation. As demonstrated in Table 1, failure to stop at a stop sign with a base

    fine of $35 could cost up to $238 after all associated penalty surcharges and assessment fees are

    added. Counties and courts are authorized to set their own surcharge level and/or levy additional

    surcharges and fees. Thus, the amount of penalties for a particular traffic violation differs by

    county.

    [Table 1 here]

    County courts collect traffic fines from citations written within county territory. After the

    court reports traffic fines to the county’s auditor-controller, the auditor-controller distributes the

    county’s shared proportion to relevant county funds and sends the state’s shared proportion to the

    State Controller (California State Auditor 2018). Overall, the state receives roughly half of traffic

    fine revenue; counties 40 percent, cities and other collection programs 10 percent (LAO 2017).

    Counties report traffic fine revenue to the State Controller annually in “Counties Financial

    Transactions Reports.” The Empirical Modeling and Data Source section introduces details of

    these reports. Figure 1 presents a map of per capita traffic fines of California counties over a 12-

    year period (2004-2015). Of all 57 counties excluding San Francisco, three counties’ per capita

    traffic fines exceed $15. They are Glenn County ($25.73), Imperial County ($19.12), and

    Siskiyou County ($15.26).

    [Figure 1 here]

    Table 2 offers further information on per capita traffic fines distribution among California

    counties. The two-sample t-test results suggest that rural counties, general law counties, low-

    income counties, and Hispanic-majority counties have higher per capita traffic fines than their

    counterparts. These preliminary results present a brief overview of per capita traffic fines in

  • 6

    California counties. They also provide guidance on building the empirical model to examine

    these counties’ revenue motive for traffic fines in the next section.

    [Table 2 here]

    Institutional Constraints on Raising Taxes and Non-tax Revenues

    In California, the single largest own-source revenue for counties is property tax. In 1977,

    California counties received 74 percent of own-source general fund revenue from property tax

    whereas counties in the rest of the U.S. on average received 57 percent of their own-source

    revenue from property taxes (see Figure 2). In 1978, voters in California passed an amendment

    to the state Constitution—the People’s Initiative to Limit Property Taxation, commonly known

    as Proposition 13. Prior to Proposition 13, California local governments determined their

    property tax rates independently with few limitations. Proposition 13 fundamentally changed

    local governments’ fiscal authority and revenue structure. This constitutional amendment was

    designed to: (1) set the property tax rate at one percent of a property’s assessed value; (2) set

    property values at their 1976 level, and allow the reassessment of property values only upon

    change of ownership; (3) limit property tax increase to an inflation rate or two percent per year,

    whichever was less; (4) give state government the authority to distribute property tax among

    local governments; (5) require a two-thirds vote of the state legislature to increase non-property

    taxes; and (6) require a two-thirds vote of electors for local special taxes.

    The passage of Proposition 13 substantially constrains local governments’ property tax

    collection. Counties were affected the most, because they relied solely on property tax for

    discretionary revenue. In the first year after its passage, California counties’ property tax

    plummeted by over 50 percent (see Figure 2). The property tax constraints have forced local

  • 7

    governments to look for alternative revenue sources, most notably: enterprise revenues, property-

    related fees, user charges, and a variety of small general-purpose taxes such as transient

    occupancy tax and utility users tax.

    [Figure 2 here]

    Yet, Proposition 13 was only the first of a series of institutional constraints that limit

    local revenue-raising capacity. In 1986, voters passed California Proposition 62 that requires

    general taxes to be approved by a majority of local voters, and special taxes to be approved by

    two-thirds of local voters1. In 1996, voters passed Proposition 218. This constitutional

    amendment restricts local governments’ use of post-Proposition 13 revenue tools such as

    assessments, fees, and user charges. It requires that fees charged to property owners such as

    those from water, sewer, and garbage collection may not exceed the cost of providing the

    services. Revenues from fees and user charges cannot be used for general governmental services.

    In addition, Proposition 218 extends voter-approval requirements of general taxes to all local

    governments (charter cities previously were not affected by Proposition 62). It requires that a

    general tax must be presented to voters at a regularly scheduled local election. It also requires all

    the assessments, fees, and user charges must be presented to voters prior to their creation or

    proposed increase. However, changes of the assessments, fees, and user charges do not need

    voter approval. They only need a majority approval of the state legislature or a majority approval

    of the local governing body. The lack of voter-approval on changes of the assessments, fees, and

    user charges was changed in 2010 when voters passed Proposition 26. This constitutional

    amendment requires a two-thirds supermajority voter-approval to pass any change of the

    assessments, fees, and user charges. Tax revenue allocations that previously could be enacted by

    a simple majority vote now also require a two-thirds supermajority voter-approval.

  • 8

    Local Governments’ Revenue Motive for Traffic Fines

    Since the passage of Proposition 13 in 1978, California’s past four decades are marked by

    voters imposing institutional constraints on local governments’ revenue authority, local

    governments maneuvering around the institutional constraints, and voters passing new

    constitutional amendments closing the “loopholes.” Institutional theories assert that

    institutions—rules and their enforcement mechanisms—determine choice of actions in a specific

    decision situation. Ostrom (2005) structured individuals’ choice of actions into three categories:

    forbidden (must not do), required (must do), and permitted (may do) actions. Ostrom’s categories

    of actions can be used to analyze California counties’ choices of revenue sources. The forbidden

    actions include to increase property tax rate, to raise user charges or fees for general

    governmental services, and to charge fees for services beyond the costs of providing the services.

    The required actions include various voting requirements to raise taxes, assessments, fees, and

    user charges. The permitted actions include using available revenue sources that do not have

    institutional restrictions.

    While county legislators and officials cannot take the “forbidden actions” to raise revenue,

    they have the discretion to take the “required actions” or “permitted actions” to raise revenue

    within institutional constraints (Ingram and Clay 2000). These decision-makers are most likely to

    choose a revenue source that has the least strict institutional constraints. In California, one area

    that has not received much institutional constraints is traffic fines and surcharges. State and local

    governments can add surcharges to the base fines. The increase of surcharges only needs

    approval from state or local governing body. No statute or regulation imposes caps on revenue

    accrued from the adding surcharges. Since the Great Recession, California added penalty

    surcharges to the traffic violations base fines twice. Once was in 2008 when the state added the

  • 9

    Criminal Conviction Assessment fees of $35 per infraction conviction, and $30 per felony or

    misdemeanor conviction. The second time was in 2010 when the state added an Emergency

    Medical Air Transportation fee of $4 per conviction (California State Auditor 2018). These add-

    on surcharges make California’s traffic fines the highest in the county (LCCR 2017).

    To test California counties’ revenue motive for traffic fines, a direct way is to see the

    responsiveness of traffic fines to revenue changes. Specifically, whether a government increases

    traffic fines following a revenue decline. The next section introduces the empirical modeling

    strategy and data sources.

    Empirical Modeling and Data Sources

    Dependent Variable

    This article uses California counties’ per capita traffic fines as the dependent variable.

    California counties differ considerably in population. The largest county Los Angeles has over

    10 million residents whereas the smallest county Alpine has less than 1,200 residents.

    Normalizing traffic fines by county population account for heterogeneity across counties. The

    per capita traffic fines are also adjusted for inflation using consumer price index (CPI) with 2004

    as the base year.

    The traffic fine revenue data comes from “Counties Financial Transactions Reports”

    published by California State Controller’s Office. The California State Controller’s Office

    requires counties and other local governmental entities to report their financial and statistical

    data on a uniform basis each year within seven months after the close of a fiscal year. Data

    reported in these reports comes from the audited financial statements, if available. The traffic

    fine revenue is reported as “Vehicle Code Fines” in these reports, which consists the net revenue

  • 10

    from fines and forfeitures for Vehicle Code violations within a county, including the county’s

    share from arrests made in cities. This variable also includes fines from various parking

    violations defined in the Vehicle Code. Fines from violations of local traffic ordinances are not

    included (State Controller’s Office 2017, 114). Table 3 gives the descriptions of all variables,

    summary statistics, and data sources.

    [Table 3 here]

    Independent Variables

    To test local governments’ revenue motive for traffic fines, a direct way is to see the

    responsiveness of counties’ per capita traffic fines to tax revenue changes. If county governments

    view traffic fines a revenue source to offset tax revenue loss, they would increase traffic fines in

    the year following a tax revenue decrease in the previous year(s). They may not necessarily

    reduce traffic fines following a tax revenue increase in the previous year(s). Thus, this article

    hypothesizes that the impacts of tax revenue increase and decrease on counties’ per capita traffic

    fine revenue are different. To examine the asymmetric impacts, the model includes both tax

    revenue increase and tax revenue decrease as independent variables.

    Tax revenue increase is measured by multiplying tax growth rate from year t-1 to year t

    with a positive dummy that equals one if tax growth rate is positive, and zero otherwise. Tax

    revenue decrease is measured by multiplying tax growth rate with a negative dummy that equals

    one if tax growth rate is negative, and zero otherwise. In the sample of 57 counties over a 12-

    year period, 55 percent of the observations are periods of tax revenue increase and the remaining

    45 percent are periods of tax revenue decrease. The two variables are both lagged by one year.

    Considering California counties start the budget preparation process several months before the

  • 11

    start of a new fiscal year, the last year’s tax revenue changes are expected to have the strongest

    influence on current year’s effort of raising traffic fines. The model includes tax revenue increase

    and tax revenue decrease lagged by up to three years to capture the influence of tax revenue

    changes in the recent past on current year’s per capita traffic fines. Using lagged independent

    variables not only helps isolate the causal effect of tax revenue changes on per capita traffic fines,

    it also allows us to assess the robustness of findings.

    The tax revenue data also comes from “Counties Financial Transactions Reports.” A

    county’s total tax revenue consists of revenue from property tax, sales tax, and a number of small

    taxes.2Total tax revenue excludes the in-lieu taxes from the state in order to measure counties’

    own-source tax revenue more precisely.3Tax revenues are inflation adjusted using CPI prior to

    the calculation of growth rates.

    In addition to changes of tax revenue, researchers find that traffic citations are determined

    by various factors (Garrett and Wagner 2009; Makowsky and Stratmann 2009; Sances and You

    2017). The empirical model includes a number of control variables with year and county fixed

    effects. The empirical model is formally expressed as:

    𝑇𝑟𝑎𝑓𝑓𝑖𝑐 𝐹𝑖𝑛𝑒𝑖,𝑡

    = 𝛼 + 𝛽1𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝑅𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑛𝑢𝑒 𝐼𝑛𝑐𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑠𝑒𝑖,𝑡−1 + 𝛽2𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝑅𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑛𝑢𝑒 𝐼𝑛𝑐𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑠𝑒𝑖,𝑡−2

    + 𝛽3𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝑅𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑛𝑢𝑒 𝐼𝑛𝑐𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑠𝑒𝑖,𝑡−3 + 𝛾1𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝑅𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑛𝑢𝑒 𝐷𝑒𝑐𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑠𝑒𝑖,𝑡−1

    + 𝛾2𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝑅𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑛𝑢𝑒 𝐷𝑒𝑐𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑠𝑒𝑖,𝑡−2 + 𝛾3𝑇𝑎𝑥 𝑅𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑛𝑢𝑒 𝐷𝑒𝑐𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑠𝑒𝑖,𝑡−3 + 𝛿𝑋𝑖,𝑡

    + 𝜃𝑡 + 𝜆𝑖 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡

    where 𝛼 is the constant term.𝑋𝑖,𝑡 is a matrix of control variables in county i at year t assumed to

    affect a county’s traffic fine revenue. 𝜃𝑡 denotes year fixed effect that controls for aggregate

  • 12

    factors affecting all counties such as national or statewide economic downturns. 𝜆𝑖 denotes

    county fixed effect that controls for county-specific, time-invariant factors affecting traffic

    citations. 𝜀𝑖,𝑡 is the error term.

    Demographic and Economic Factors

    The 𝑋𝑖,𝑡 matrix contains control variables broadly defined as county demographic,

    economic, fiscal, enforcement, and road-related factors that are expected to correlate with traffic

    fines. As demonstrated in Table 2, rural counties have significantly higher per capita traffic fines.

    The model includes population density, a measure often used to define rural and urban territories

    by the Census Bureau. Population density is defined in this article as the number of persons per

    square mile of land area. The county square miles data comes from “Counties Financial

    Transactions Reports,” and county population data comes from California Department of

    Finance. The population aged between 15 and 24 is traditionally considered the highest risk

    group by auto insurance companies, and data shows that this age group is more likely to be

    involved in fatal car crashes (NHTSA 2015). The model thus includes the share of population

    between 15 and 24 in a county’s total population as a control variable. Results in Table 2 also

    indicate that low-income counties have higher per capita traffic fines. The model includes county

    poverty rates obtained from the Census Bureau to control counties’ economic wealth.

    Fiscal Factor

    Political economic theories predict that local governments’ decision to choose a revenue

    tool is modeled as if government officials maximize their effective voter support. They achieve

    this goal by “tax exporting” on nonvoters (Inman 1989; Gade and Adkkins 1990; Braid 2005). In

    the case of traffic citations, researchers find that out-of-state and out-of-town drivers face

  • 13

    different enforcement standards than local drivers. Non-local drivers are more likely to receive

    traffic tickets than verbal warnings. They also pay larger amounts of fines (Makowsky and

    Stratmann 2009, 2011; Roach 2015). Because existing information cannot identify whether

    traffic violations were committed by local or non-local drivers, this article uses a proxy—

    tourism—to account for this effect. This variable is measured as the share of transient occupancy

    tax as a percent of a county’s total own-source revenues. California counties and cities are

    authorized to impose a transient occupancy tax on individuals who stay at hotels, motels, and

    similar accommodations for a period of 30 days or less. As such, this tax is typically paid by

    non-local residents. Larger share of transient occupancy tax thus indicates a larger number of

    non-local drivers in a county.

    Law Enforcement and Crime Factors

    Traffic law enforcement is an important component in traffic citations. Traffic law

    enforcement officers often have the discretion to give verbal warnings or traffic citations for

    minor infractions. Thus, local governments are able to raise more traffic fines if they decide to

    implement traffic laws more strictly. Since the currently known data source does not allow us to

    measure traffic law enforcement directly, this article uses a proxy variable—police presence—to

    control county-level differences in law enforcement. This variable is measured as the number of

    sworn law enforcement personnel per 1,000 county residents.4The model also includes the arrest

    rates, measured as the number of arrests made by law enforcement agencies per 1,000 county

    residents. Because law enforcement officials have limited time and resources, increase in crime

    rates could result in less focus on traffic law enforcement (Garrett and Wagner 2009).

  • 14

    Road-Related Factors

    California counties’ road network is classified as arterial roads and collector roads

    according to the Federal Highway Administration’s classification of functional streets and

    highways. Arterial roads are high-capacity roads that carry longer-distance flows between

    important centers of activity. These roads often have four or more lanes and are designed for

    unimpeded high-speed movement. Typical arterial roads include the interstate system, freeways,

    expressways, and major conventional highways. Data shows that 77 percent of fatal auto vehicle

    crashes occur on urban arterial roads, and 62 percent on rural arterial roads (IIHS 2016).

    Collector roads are low-to-moderate-capacity roads that move traffic from local streets to arterial

    roads. They are designed to provide access to residential properties. Because arterial roads carry

    large traffic volumes with high speed and have more accidents, it is reasonable to expect more

    traffic law enforcement focus on arterial roads and more traffic citations issued on arterial roads.

    The model includes arterial road mileage in a county as a percent of total arterial roads mileage

    in California as a control variable. This variable is hypothesized to be positively associated with

    a county’s per capita traffic fines. Another road-related variable is collector road mileage in a

    county as a percent of total collector roads mileage in California. This variable is hypothesized to

    be negatively associated with per capita traffic fines.

    Time Span of the Sample

    The sample includes 57 of the 58 counties in California, excluding San Francisco, the

    only consolidated city and county government. The time span of the sample covers 12 fiscal

    years, from 2004 to 2015. In June 2015, California launched a one-time Traffic Amnesty

    Program that provided relief to individuals from unpaid traffic and non-traffic tickets. The

    program began on October 1, 2015 and ended on April 3, 2017. To avoid the influence of this

  • 15

    event on the analysis results, the ending point of the sample is fiscal year 2015.5This sample is a

    balanced panel dataset with 684 observations. The next section presents and interprets the

    regression results.

    Estimation Results

    Table 4 presents the regression results from three empirical specifications. Each of the

    three models was estimated with county and year fixed effects. The standard errors, reported in

    parentheses, were clustered by individual counties. The second and third models include

    independent variables lagged up to two and three years to test the influence of tax revenue

    changes not only in the previous year but also in the recent past on counties’ per capita traffic

    fines. Of all three models, only the one-year lag of tax revenue decrease (i.e. tax revenue loss in

    the previous year) has a significant impact on local traffic fines. Results are robust to the

    inclusion of the two-year and three-year lags of tax revenue changes. Holding all other variables

    constant, 10-percentage-point tax revenue loss in the previous year leads to 40 to 42 cents

    increase in per capita traffic fines in the current year. The result that previous year’s tax revenue

    changes has the strongest influence on traffic fines is not surprising. California counties start

    their budget preparation process several months before the end of current fiscal year. Thus,

    current year’s tax revenue is the most relevant indicator of revenue forecast in the new fiscal year.

    If a county has a tax revenue loss in the current year, county officials and legislators will make a

    less optimistic tax revenue forecast. They are likely to increase revenue-raising efforts in non-tax

    revenue sources, especially those with the least institutional constraints such as traffic citations.

    This article focuses on tax revenue changes rather than total revenue changes used in Garret and

    Wagner’s (2009) study due to endogeneity concern, because traffic fines are part of counties’

  • 16

    total revenue. Moreover, the lagged tax revenue changes helps isolate the causal effect of

    counties’ budget conditions on traffic fines.

    The coefficients on lags of positive tax revenue change are not statistically significant in

    any of the three models, suggesting that tax revenue increase in the previous year and recent past

    does not affect current year’s local traffic fines. The fact that counties raised traffic fines after

    experiencing a tax revenue loss but do not reduce traffic fines in response to a tax revenue

    increase indicates these counties do not use traffic fines to smooth tax revenue fluctuations.

    Rather, they behave to some degree like revenue maximizers (Garret and Wagner 2006). This is

    not to say that these local governments are Leviathans (Brennan and Buchanan 1977; Oates

    1985). They are forced to seek alternative revenue sources with no or less strict intuitional

    constraints. Extant studies show that since the passage and Proposition 13 and similar

    constitutional amendments, California local governments have switched their revenue-raising

    effort from property taxes to other revenue sources to circumvent institutional constraints thereby

    gradually changing local revenue structures (Shires, Ellwood, and Sprague 1998; Wassmer 2008).

    The coefficients on control variables also provide interesting insights into local

    governments’ collection of traffic fines. One variable that show consistent statistical significance

    across all three models is ‘poverty’—a county’s poverty rate. Holding other variables constant,

    one-percentage-point poverty rate increase raises per capita traffic fines by 16 to 17 cents. This

    result indicates that counties with high poverty rates rely more on traffic fines. However, this

    result is not sufficient to conclude that residents in low-income counties bear the burden of

    traffic fines. The dataset does not contain information to identify whether a Vehicle Code

    violator is a local resident or an out-of-town driver. It is plausible that much of the traffic fines

    are paid by out-of-town drivers who drive through the county. Anecdotal evidence shows that

  • 17

    local governments without a well-endowed tax base take advantage of their other asset—having

    major interstate highways running through the counties (LaRose 2016).

    The variable ‘tourism’ is statistically significant in two of the three models. This variable

    is measured as transient occupancy tax (TOT) as a share of a county’s own-source revenues.

    Since non-local residents pay most of the TOT, this variable is a proxy measure of visitors and

    travelers in a county. The coefficients suggest that holding other variables constant, one-

    percentage-point increase in the share of TOT in local own-source revenues raises per capita

    traffic fines by 38 to 42 cents. The result here supports the notion that local governments transfer

    the traffic fines burden onto non-local residents, in this case, out-of-town drivers.

    The two road-related variables are also statistically significant across all three models.

    Consistent with the hypothesis, traffic fines are strongly associated with the type of road network.

    Arterial roads, due to the large and high-speed traffic volumes they carry, are where the majority

    of traffic accidents happen. Traffic law enforcement thus has a considerable focus on arterial

    roads. In recently years, California allows automated enforcement—the use of cameras to

    enforce traffic safety laws. Although still a controversial issue, the use of red light cameras and

    license plates recognition cameras greatly improve the efficiency and accuracy in traffic law

    enforcement. Most of these cameras were installed on busy arterial roads. The regression results

    suggest that holding other variables constant, if a county’s arterial roads mileage as percent of

    total arterial roads mileage in the state increases by one-percentage point, the county’s per capita

    traffic fines would increase by 66 to 76 cents. In contrast, if a county’s collector roads mileage

    share increases by one-percentage point, the county’s per capita traffic fines would decrease by

    80 to 90 cents.

  • 18

    Conclusion

    Government traffic fines generally do not receive much public scrutiny. Most states do

    not require voter approval to increase the base fine or to add surcharges. The lack of institutional

    constraints and public scrutiny on raising traffic fines may create a revenue incentive to

    governments, especially those that face fiscal stress. This article finds empirical evidence of local

    governments’ revenue motive for traffic fines using county-level data in California. Results

    suggest that California counties increased per capita traffic fines in the year right after a tax

    revenue decline in the previous year; however, these counties did not reduce per capita traffic

    fines after a tax revenue increase. This indicates that local governments view traffic fines as a

    revenue source to offset tax revenue loss; they do not use traffic fines as revenue-smoother to

    ease tax revenue fluctuations.

    This article also finds that low-income counties rely more on traffic fines. Counties that

    generate more revenues from transient occupancy tax—a tax typically paid by travelers and

    visitors—raise more traffic fines, indicating a possible tax exporting behavior by imposing the

    traffic fines on non-local drivers. Counties with a greater proportion of arterial roads raise more

    traffic fines whereas counties with a greater proportion of collector roads raise less traffic fines.

    Imposing monetary punishment on those who violate traffic laws is an effective policy

    tool to deter misbehaviors and to compensate society for the damage caused by these

    misbehaviors. However, “taxation by citation”—the excessive use of traffic fines for revenue

    purpose—could seriously undermine trust between citizens and government law enforcement

    agencies, as a Missouri state senator wrote to the Wall Street Journal (Schimitt 2015).

    Aggressive use of traffic citations makes citizens see police more of traffic fine predators instead

  • 19

    of road safety protectors. Furthermore, excessive use of traffic citations jeopardizes employment.

    In many states, failure to pay traffic fines can result in license suspension. Because the

    overwhelming majority of Americans drive to work and many occupations require a valid driver

    license (Tomer 2017), those who have their license suspended may not be able to keep their jobs.

    The lack of a valid driver license and a reliable transportation puts obstacles in the way of job

    searching and future employment. Considering a large number of low-wage and blue-collar jobs

    require a driver license, some concerns the excessive use of traffic citations and license

    suspension may impose a greater burden on low-income families (LCCR 2017). The racial

    profiling and racial disparity in traffic stops as demonstrated in the cases of Ferguson and other

    cities raise another concern that the excessive traffic law enforcement may disproportionately

    affect African-American communities (U.S. Department of Justice 2015; Epp, Maynard-Moody,

    and Haider-Markel 2017). Finally yet importantly, traffic fines are not a sustainable revenue

    source for government functions (California State Auditor 2018). In all, traffic citations should

    not be used as means to generate revenues.

    In recent years, a few states have recognized this issue of local governments’ misuse of

    traffic fines and started traffic fines reforms. In 2015, Missouri Governor signed a municipal

    court reform bill (the Senate Bill 5) that caps municipalities’ percentage of general revenue

    collected from traffic fines. Also in 2015, California launched a one-time Traffic Amnesty

    Program that provides relief to individuals from unpaid traffic and non-traffic tickets. Missouri

    and California are not the only states with the “taxation by citation” issue. States need careful

    review of local traffic law enforcement to make sure that traffic citations are used for public

    safety purposes and not for revenue purpose.

  • 20

    Endnotes

    1. General taxes are levied by a general-purpose government and used at the discretion of

    the local government’s governing body, on any program or services. A special tax is a tax

    that needs one of the following conditions: levied by special districts, school districts, and

    community college districts; dedicated to a specific purpose; property-related taxes but

    not the property tax (LAO 2014).

    2. These small taxes include transportation tax (non-transit purpose), property transfer tax,

    transient occupancy tax, timber yield tax, aircraft tax, construction tax, and utility user

    tax.

    3. Counties and cities receive in-lieu tax revenues from the state, one from the Vehicle

    License Fee Property Compensation Fund, the other from Sales and Use Tax

    Compensation Fund.

    4. Sworn law enforcement officers are those who have a badge, carry a firearm, and have

    arrest power when performing their duties. This is in contrast with non-sworn (also called

    civilian) law enforcement officers.

    5. All California counties end their fiscal year 2015 on June 30, 2015. Thus, the Traffic

    Amnesty Program that took effect on October 1, 2015 did not affect counties’ traffic fine

    revenue in fiscal year 2015.

  • 21

    References

    Braid, Ralph M. 2005. Tax Competition, Tax Exporting and Higher-government Choice of Tax

    Instruments for Local Governments. Journal of Public Economics 89 (9-10): 1789-1821.

    Brennan, Geoffrey, and James M Buchanan. 1977. Towards a Tax Constitution for Leviathan.

    Journal of Public Economics 8 (3): 255-73.

    California State Auditor. 2018. California State Auditor Report 2017-126: Penalty Assessment

    Funds. Sacramento, CA: California State Auditor.

    https://www.bsa.ca.gov/pdfs/reports/2017-126.pdf

    Chokshi, Niraj. 2015. The Chief Justice of Nevada’s Supreme Court Says a Decline in Traffic

    Tickets is Starving His Budget. The Washington Post, March 23.

    https://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/govbeat/wp/2015/03/23/the-chief-justice-of-

    nevadas-supreme-court-says-a-decline-in-traffic-tickets-is-starving-his-

    budget/?noredirect=on&utm_term=.9914310e05db

    DeAngelo, Gregory, and Benjamin Hansen. 2014. Life and Death in the Fast Lane: Police

    Enforcement and Traffic Fatalities. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 6 (2):

    231-57.

    Epp, Charles R., Maynard‐Moody, Steven, and Donald Haider‐Markel. 2017. Beyond Profiling:

    The Institutional Sources of Racial Disparities in Policing. Public Administration Review,

    77 (2): 168-178.

    Gade, Mary N, and Lee C Adkins. 1990. Tax Exporting and State Revenue Structures. National

    Tax Journal 43 (1): 39-52.

    https://www.bsa.ca.gov/pdfs/reports/2017-126.pdfhttps://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/govbeat/wp/2015/03/23/the-chief-justice-of-nevadas-supreme-court-says-a-decline-in-traffic-tickets-is-starving-his-budget/?noredirect=on&utm_term=.9914310e05dbhttps://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/govbeat/wp/2015/03/23/the-chief-justice-of-nevadas-supreme-court-says-a-decline-in-traffic-tickets-is-starving-his-budget/?noredirect=on&utm_term=.9914310e05dbhttps://www.washingtonpost.com/blogs/govbeat/wp/2015/03/23/the-chief-justice-of-nevadas-supreme-court-says-a-decline-in-traffic-tickets-is-starving-his-budget/?noredirect=on&utm_term=.9914310e05db

  • 22

    Garrett, Thomas A, and Gary A Wagner. 2009. Red Ink in the Rearview Mirror: Local Fiscal

    Conditions and the Issuance of Traffic Tickets. The Journal of Law and Economics 52 (1):

    71-90.

    Garrett, Thomas A, and Gary Wagner. 2006. Are Traffic Tickets Countercyclical? Federal

    Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series 2006-048A.Federal Reserve Bank of St.

    Louis, August. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=923158

    IIHS (Insurance Institute for Highway Safety). 2016. Roadway and Environment: Fatality Facts.

    Arlington, VA: Insurance Institute for Highway Safety and Highway Loss Data Institute

    http://www.iihs.org/iihs/topics/t/roadway-and-environment/fatalityfacts/roadway-and-

    environment

    Ingram, Paul, and Karen Clay. 2000. The Choice-within-Constraints New Institutionalism and

    Implications for Sociology. Annual Review of Sociology 26 (1): 525-46.

    Inman, Robert P. 1989. The Local Decision to Tax: Evidence from Large U.S. Cities. Regional

    Science and Urban Economics 19 (3): 455-91.

    Kochanek, Kenneth D., Murphy, Sherry L., Xu, Jiaquan, and BetzaidaTejada-Vera. 2016.

    National Vital Statistics Reports on Deaths: Final Data for 201465 (4). Hyattsville, MD:

    Centers for Disease Control and Prevention

    https://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/nvsr/nvsr65/nvsr65_04.pdf

    LAO (Legislative Analysts’ Office). 2014. A Look at Voter-Approval Requirements for Local

    Taxes. Sacramento, CA: California Legislative Analysts’ Office.

    https://lao.ca.gov/reports/2014/finance/local-taxes/voter-approval-032014.pdf

    https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=923158http://www.iihs.org/iihs/topics/t/roadway-and-environment/fatalityfacts/roadway-and-environmenthttp://www.iihs.org/iihs/topics/t/roadway-and-environment/fatalityfacts/roadway-and-environmenthttps://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/nvsr/nvsr65/nvsr65_04.pdfhttps://lao.ca.gov/reports/2014/finance/local-taxes/voter-approval-032014.pdf

  • 23

    LAO (Legislative Analysts’ Office). 2017. Overview of Criminal Fine and Fee System.

    Sacramento, CA: California Legislative Analysts’ Office.

    https://lao.ca.gov/handouts/crimjust/2017/Fine-and-Fee-Overview-022717.pdf

    LaRose, Greg. 2016. 3 Louisiana Towns Collect more in Speeding Fines than Taxes. The Times-

    Picayune, September 29.

    https://www.nola.com/politics/index.ssf/2016/09/police_fines_fuel_local_govern.html

    LCCR (Lawyers’ Committee for Civil Rights). 2017. Paying More for Being Poor: Bias and

    Disparity in California’s Traffic Court System. San Francisco, CA: Lawyers Committee

    for Civil Rights of the San Francisco Bay Area. https://lccr.com/wp-

    content/uploads/LCCR-Report-Paying-More-for-Being-Poor-May-2017-5.4.17.pdf

    Luca, Dara Lee. 2015. Do Traffic Tickets Reduce Motor Vehicle Accidents? Evidence from a

    Natural Experiment. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 34 (1): 85-106.

    Makowsky, Michael D, and Thomas Stratmann. 2009. Political Economy at any Speed: What

    Determines Traffic Citations? American Economic Review 99 (1): 509-27.

    Makowsky, Michael D, and Thomas Stratmann. 2011. More Tickets, Fewer Accidents: How

    Cash-Strapped Towns Make for Safer Roads. The Journal of Law and Economics 54 (4):

    863-88.

    NHTSA (National Highway Traffic Safety Administration). 2015. Traffic Safety Facts 2015

    Data: Speeding. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Transportation.

    https://crashstats.nhtsa.dot.gov/Api/Public/Publication/812409

    https://lao.ca.gov/handouts/crimjust/2017/Fine-and-Fee-Overview-022717.pdfhttps://www.nola.com/politics/index.ssf/2016/09/police_fines_fuel_local_govern.htmlhttps://lccr.com/wp-content/uploads/LCCR-Report-Paying-More-for-Being-Poor-May-2017-5.4.17.pdfhttps://lccr.com/wp-content/uploads/LCCR-Report-Paying-More-for-Being-Poor-May-2017-5.4.17.pdfhttps://crashstats.nhtsa.dot.gov/Api/Public/Publication/812409

  • 24

    Oates, Wallace E. 1985. Searching for Leviathan: An Empirical Study. The American Economic

    Review 75 (4): 748-57.

    Ostrom, Elinor. 2005. Understanding Institutional Diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University

    Press.

    Roach, Michael. 2015. Is the Highway Patrol Really Tougher on Out-of-State Drivers? An

    Empirical Analysis. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 15 (2): 769-96.

    Robertson, Campbell. 2016. In Louisiana, the Poor Lack Legal Defense. The New York Times,

    March 19. https://www.nytimes.com/2016/03/20/us/in-louisiana-the-poor-lack-legal-

    defense.html

    Sances, Michael W, and Hye Young You. 2017. Who Pays for Government? Descriptive

    Representation and Exploitative Revenue Sources. The Journal of Politics 79 (3): 1090-

    94.

    Schmitt, Eric. 2015. ‘Taxation by Citation’ Undermines Trust between Cops and Citizens. The

    Wall Street Journal, August 7. https://www.wsj.com/articles/taxation-by-citation-

    undermines-trust-between-cops-and-citizens-1438987412

    Shires, Michael, Ellwood, John, and Mary Sprague. 1998. Has Proposition 13 Delivered? The

    Changing Tax Burden in California. San Francisco, CA: Public Policy Institute of

    California. http://www.ppic.org/content/pubs/report/R_998MSR.pdf

    Simmons, Andria. 2014. Atlanta’s Ticket Traps: Slow down or Pay up? The Atlanta Journal-

    Constitution, October 18. https://www.myajc.com/news/transportation/atlanta-ticket-

    traps-slow-down-pay/6JZfycaeaKQ3jYJGRxtHII/

    https://www.nytimes.com/2016/03/20/us/in-louisiana-the-poor-lack-legal-defense.htmlhttps://www.nytimes.com/2016/03/20/us/in-louisiana-the-poor-lack-legal-defense.htmlhttps://www.wsj.com/articles/taxation-by-citation-undermines-trust-between-cops-and-citizens-1438987412https://www.wsj.com/articles/taxation-by-citation-undermines-trust-between-cops-and-citizens-1438987412http://www.ppic.org/content/pubs/report/R_998MSR.pdfhttps://www.myajc.com/news/transportation/atlanta-ticket-traps-slow-down-pay/6JZfycaeaKQ3jYJGRxtHII/https://www.myajc.com/news/transportation/atlanta-ticket-traps-slow-down-pay/6JZfycaeaKQ3jYJGRxtHII/

  • 25

    State Controller’s Office. 2017. Counties Financial Transactions Report Instructions.

    Sacramento, CA: California State Controller’s Office. https://www.sco.ca.gov/Files-

    ARD-Local/LocRep/Cities%20FTR%20Instructions.pdf

    Tomer, Adie. 2017. America’s Commuting Choices: 5 Major Takeaways from 2016 Census Data.

    Brookings. October 3. https://www.brookings.edu/blog/the-

    avenue/2017/10/03/americans-commuting-choices-5-major-takeaways-from-2016-

    census-data/

    U.S. Department of Justice. 2015. Investigation of the Ferguson Police Department. Washington,

    D.C.: U.S. Department of Justice Civil Rights Division

    https://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files/opa/press-

    releases/attachments/2015/03/04/ferguson_police_department_report.pdf

    Wassmer, Robert. 2008. California’s State and Local Revenue Structure after Proposition 13: Is

    Denial an Appropriate Way to Cope? Paper presented at the State and Local Tax Policy –

    Out of the Box Conference. Atlanta, GA., May 14.

    https://www.sco.ca.gov/Files-ARD-Local/LocRep/Cities%20FTR%20Instructions.pdfhttps://www.sco.ca.gov/Files-ARD-Local/LocRep/Cities%20FTR%20Instructions.pdfhttps://www.brookings.edu/blog/the-avenue/2017/10/03/americans-commuting-choices-5-major-takeaways-from-2016-census-data/https://www.brookings.edu/blog/the-avenue/2017/10/03/americans-commuting-choices-5-major-takeaways-from-2016-census-data/https://www.brookings.edu/blog/the-avenue/2017/10/03/americans-commuting-choices-5-major-takeaways-from-2016-census-data/https://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files/opa/press-releases/attachments/2015/03/04/ferguson_police_department_report.pdfhttps://www.justice.gov/sites/default/files/opa/press-releases/attachments/2015/03/04/ferguson_police_department_report.pdf

  • 26

    Figures and Tables

  • 27

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    19

    71

    19

    72

    19

    73

    19

    74

    19

    75

    19

    76

    19

    77

    19

    78

    19

    79

    19

    80

    19

    81

    19

    82

    19

    83

    19

    84

    19

    85

    19

    86

    19

    87

    19

    88

    19

    89

    19

    90

    19

    91

    19

    92

    19

    93

    19

    94

    19

    95

    19

    96

    19

    97

    19

    98

    19

    99

    20

    00

    20

    01

    20

    02

    20

    03

    20

    04

    20

    05

    20

    06

    20

    07

    20

    08

    20

    09

    20

    10

    20

    11

    20

    12

    20

    13

    20

    14

    20

    15

    Pro

    per

    ty T

    ax R

    even

    ues

    as

    a P

    erce

    nt of

    Counti

    es' O

    wn

    -so

    urc

    e G

    ener

    al F

    und R

    even

    ue

    Data source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Census Bureau (county governments data). Author's calculation.

    Figure 2. Counties' Dependence on Property Tax: United Statas vs. California

    Counties in all states Counties in California

  • 28

    Table 1. An Example of Traffic Fines and Fees Schedule

    As of January 1, 2017 Calculation of Charge Stop Sign Violation

    (Infraction)

    DUI of Alcohol/Drugs

    (Misdemeanor)

    Standard Fines and Fees

    Base Fine Depends on violation 35 390

    State Penalty Assessment $10 for every $10 of a base fine 40 390

    County Penalty Assessment $7 for every $10 of a base fine 28 273

    Court Construction Penalty Assessment $5 for every $10 of a base fine 20 195

    Proposition 69 DNA Penalty Assessment $1 for every $10 of a base fine 4 39

    DNA Identification Fund Penalty Assessment $4 for every $10 of a base fine 16 156

    EMS Penalty Assessment $2 for every $10 of a base fine 8 78

    EMAT Penalty Assessment $4 per conviction 4 4

    State Surcharge 20% of base fine 7 78

    Court Operations Assessment $40 per conviction 40 40

    Conviction Assessment Fee $35 per infraction conviction and $30 per

    felony or misdemeanor conviction

    35 30

    Night Court Fee $1 per fine and fee imposed 1 1

    Restitution Fine $150 minimum per misdemeanor conviction

    and $300 minimum per felony conviction

    - 150

    Examples of Additional Fines and Fees That Could Apply

    DUI Lab Test Penalty Assessment Actual costs up to $50 for specific violations - 50

    Alcohol Education Penalty Assessment Up to $50 - 50

    County Alcohol and Drug Program Penalty

    Assessment

    Up to $100 - 100

    Total 238 2024

    Three Traffic Violation Categories

    Traffic infractions are minor offenses such as speeding or failing to stop at a stop sign. Traffic infractions are not punishable by jail time but by a

    base fine of up to $100.

    Traffic misdemeanors are offenses punishable by imprisonment in a county jail, a base fine of up to $1,000, or both. Examples of traffic

    misdemeanors include driving under the influence of alcohol and/or drugs and reckless driving.

    Traffic felonies are serious offenses such as accidents resulting in injury or death to another person. Such offenses are punishable by

    imprisonment, a base fine of no less than $1,000 and up to $10,000, or both.

  • 29

    Note: the base fine is rounded to the nearest $10 to calculate these additional charges. For example, the $35 base fine for a failure to stop would round up to

    $40. DUI = Driving Under Influence; EMS = Emergency Medical Services; and EMAT = Emergency Medical Air Transportation.

    Source: Legislative Analysts’ Office(2017, 2).

  • 30

    Table 2. Comparison of Per Capita Traffic Fines by County Group

    County Groups Mean Difference

    (1) (2) (1) (2) (1)-(2)

    Urban or suburban (n=432) Rural (n=252)a 4.08 5.86 -1.79***

    Charter (n=156) General law (n=528)b 3.83 5.00 -1.17***

    Low-income (n=69) All others (n=615)c 8.27 4.34 3.93***

    White-majority (n=39) All others (n=360)d 3.75 5.19 -1.43*

    Hispanic-majority (n=40) All others (n=359)e 6.85 4.85 2.00**

    Note: a. the designation of a “Rural” county is based on the Rural-Urban Commuting Area Codes (RUCAs)

    developed by California State Office of Rural Health Policy. According to RUCAs, 36 counties in the sample are

    urban or suburban, and 21 counties are rural. More information on RUCAs is available at

    https://www.ers.usda.gov/data-products/rural-urban-commuting-area-codes.aspx.

    b. the California Constitution recognize two types of counties: charter counties and general law counties.

    More information on county structure and powers is at http://www.counties.org/general-information/county-

    structure-0.

    c. a county is defined “Low-income” if its median income falls below $24,020.58, the 10th percentile for

    median income of all counties from 2004 to 2015.

    d. a county is defined “White-majority” if non-Hispanic whites are greater than 84.11% of its total population.

    The 84.11% is the 90th percentile for non-Hispanic whites’ share of a county’s total population of all counties from

    2010 to 2015.

    e. a county is defined “Hispanic-majority” if Hispanics are greater than 51.29% of its total population. The

    51.29% is the 90th percentile Hispanics’ share of a county’s total population of all counties from 2010 to 2015.

    f. statistically significant level: * at 10%, ** at 5%, *** at 1%.

    https://www.ers.usda.gov/data-products/rural-urban-commuting-area-codes.aspxhttp://www.counties.org/general-information/county-structure-0http://www.counties.org/general-information/county-structure-0

  • 31

    Table 3. Variable Descriptions, Summary Statistics, and Data Sources

    Variable Description Mean Min Max Sources

    Traffic fine per capita Net revenues from fines and forfeitures for Vehicle

    Code violations divided by county population

    4.16

    (4.82)

    0 30.96 California State

    Controller's Office

    Tax revenue increase Per capita tax revenue growth rate × a positive dummy

    (a positive dummy equals one if tax revenue growth

    rate at time t is positive, and zero otherwise)

    3.75

    (6.66)

    0 58.62 California State

    Controller's Office

    Tax revenue decrease Per capita tax revenue growth rate × a negative dummy

    (a negative dummy equals one if tax revenue growth

    rate at time t is negative, and zero otherwise)

    -2.45

    (4.45)

    -41.04 0 California State

    Controller's Office

    Density Number of persons per square mile of land area 354.29

    (676.98)

    1.60 4015.17 California Department

    of Finance and

    California State

    Controller's Office

    Population ages 15-24 Number of persons ages 15-24 as a percent of a

    county's total population

    14.24

    (2.86)

    8.57 25.29 California Department

    of Finance

    Poverty Poverty rate (all ages) 15.32

    (4.91)

    5.60 29.70 Census

    Tourism Transient occupancy taxes (the “TOT” or the hotel

    room taxes) as a percent of a county's total own-

    source revenues

    2.30

    (5.78)

    0 48.10 California State

    Controller's Office

    Police Presence Number of sworn law enforcement personnel per 1,000

    county residents

    1.94

    (1.36)

    .73 12.89 California Criminal

    Justice Statistics

    Center

    Arrest rate Number of arrests (including felonies, misdemeanor,

    and status offenses) made by law enforcement

    agencies per 1,000 county residents

    45.61

    (13.82)

    20.48 129.67 California Criminal

    Justice Statistics

    Center

    Arterial roads Arterial roads mileage in a county as a percent of total

    arterial roads mileage in California

    1.75

    (3.31)

    0 27.56 California Department

    of Transportation

  • 32

    Collector roads Collector roads mileage in a county as a percent of total

    collector roads mileage in California

    1.75

    (2.62)

    0 23.04 California Department

    of Transportation

    Note: a. the sample includes 57 of California’s 58 counties. San Francisco is omitted because it is a consolidated city and county government.

    b. number in parentheses are standard deviations.

  • 33

    Table 4. Effect of County Per Capita Tax Revenue Changes on Traffic Fine Revenues

    Variable (1) (2) (3)

    Tax revenue increase lagged 1 year .004 (.009) .008 (.010) .010 (.011)

    Tax revenue increase lagged 2years .009 (.008) .014 (.009)

    Tax revenue increase lagged 3years .013 (.012)

    Tax revenue decrease lagged 1 year -.042 (.019)** -.040 (.017)** -.042 (.018)**

    Tax revenue decrease lagged 2years -.010 (.019) -.008 (.016)

    Tax revenue decrease lagged 3years -.041 (.023)

    Density .005 (.004) .005 (.004) .003 (.004)

    Population ages 15-24 -.386 (.260) -.322 (.274) -.333 (.317)

    Poverty .156 (.072)** .161 (.082)* .170 (.087)*

    Tourism .378 (.225)* .419 (.243)* .330 (.215)

    Police Presence .131 (.367) -.115 (.392) -.117 (.404)

    Arrest rate .059 (.048) .052 (.051) .034 (.046)

    Arterial roads .659 (.328)** .692 (.351)* .761 (.379)**

    Collector roads -.795 (.309)** -.824 (.323)** -.902 (.352)**

    (Year dummies results omitted)

    Number of Observations 570 513 456

    Adjusted R .234 .217 .200

    F-statistics 2.82*** 2.47*** 2.41***

    Note: a. robust standard errors are clustered by county in parentheses.

    b. variables with monetary value are deflated using consumer price index.

    c. each model was estimated with county and year fixed effects that are not reported.

    d. the sample contains 57 counties in California from 2004 to 2015.

    e. statistically significant level: * at 10%, ** at 5%, *** at 1%.