trade and labor market dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · march, 2016 caliendo, dvorkin, and parro (2015)...

60
Trade and Labor Market Dynamics Lorenzo Caliendo Maximiliano Dvorkin Fernando Parro Yale University, NBER St Louis Fed Federal Reserve Board March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24

Upload: others

Post on 25-Aug-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Trade and Labor Market Dynamics

Lorenzo Caliendo Maximiliano Dvorkin Fernando ParroYale University, NBER St Louis Fed Federal Reserve Board

March, 2016

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24

Page 2: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Introduction

Aggregate trade shocks can have different disaggregate effects (acrosslocations, sectors, locations-sectors) depending on

I degree of exposure to foreign tradeI indirect linkages through internal trade, sectoral tradeI labor reallocation process

We develop a model of trade and labor market dynamics thatexplicitly recognizes the role of labor mobility frictions, goods mobilityfrictions, I-O linkages, geographic factors, and international trade

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24

Page 3: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

This paper

Models with large # of unknown fundamentals: productivity, mobilityfrictions, trade frictions, and more...

Propose a new method to solve dynamic discrete choice models

I Solve the model and perform large scale counterfactuals withoutestimating level of fundamentals

I By expressing the equilibrium conditions of the model in relative timedifferences

Study how China’s import competition impacted U.S. labor marketsI 38 countries, 50 U.S. regions, and 22 sectors version of the modelI Employment and welfare effects across more than 1000 labor markets

F Employment: approx. 0.8 MM manuf. jobs lost, reallocation to servicesF Welfare: aggregate gains; very heterogeneous effects across labormarkets; transition costs reflect the importance of dynamics

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 2 / 24

Page 4: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Literature

Substantial progress in recent quantitative trade models, including Eatonand Kortum (2002) and its extensions: multiple sectors Caliendo and Parro(2015), spatial economics Caliendo et al. (2015), and other extensionsMonte (2015), Tombe et al. (2015), Fajgelbaum et.al. (2015), much more

I One limitation is their stylized treatment of the labor market (staticmodels, labor moves costessly or does not move)

We build on advances that underscore the importance of trade and labormarket dynamics: Artuç and McLaren (2010), Artuç Chaudhuri andMcLaren (2010), Dix-Carneiro (2014)

Relates to dynamic discrete choice models in IO, labor, macro literature Hotzand Miller (1993), Berry (1994), Kennan and Walker (2011), Dvorkin (2014)

Relates to recent research on the labor market effects of trade

I Because of direct import exposure: Autor, Dorn and Hanson (2013),and sectoral linkages: Acemoglu, Autor, Dorn and Hanson (2015),other channels Handley and Limao (2015) Pierce and Schott (2015)

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 3 / 24

Page 5: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Road map

Model

I Households’dynamic problemI Production structureI Equilibrium

Solution method

Application: calibration and results

Conclusion

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 4 / 24

Page 6: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Model

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 5 / 24

Page 7: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Households’problemN locations (index n and i) and each has J sectors (index j and k)The value of a household in market nj at time t given by

vnjt = u(cnjt ) + max

{i ,k}N ,Ji=1,k=0

{βE[vikt+1

]− τnj ,ik + ν εikt

},

s.t. u(cnjt ) ≡{log(bn) i f j = 0,log(wnjt /Pnt ) otherwise,

I β ∈ (0, 1) discount factorI τnj ,ik additive, time invariant migration costs to ik from njI εikt are stochastic i.i.d idiosyncratic taste shocks

F ε ∼ Type-I Extreme Value distribution with zero meanF ν > 0 is the dispersion of taste shocks

Unemployed obtain home production bn

Employed households supply a unit of labor inelastically

I Receive the competitive market wage wnjtI Consume cnjt = ∏J

k=1(cnj ,kt )α

k, where Pnt is the local price index

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 6 / 24

Page 8: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Households’problem - Dynamic discrete choice

Using properties of Type-I Extreme Value distributions one obtains:

The expected (expectation over ε) lifetime utility of a worker at nj

V njt = u(cnjt ) + ν log[∑Ni=1 ∑J

k=0 exp(

βV ikt+1 − τnj ,ik)1/ν

]Fraction of workers that reallocate from market nj to ik

µnj ,ikt =exp

(βV ikt+1 − τnj ,ik

)1/ν

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0 exp(

βVmht+1 − τnj ,mh)1/ν

.

Evolution of the distribution of labor across markets

Lnjt+1 = ∑Ni=1 ∑J

k=0 µik ,njt Likt

Frechet and Multiplicative costs

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 7 / 24

Page 9: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Production - Static sub-problem

Notice that at each t, labor supply across markets is fully determinedI We can then solve for wages such that labor markets clear, using a veryrich static spatial structure (CPRHS 2015)

In each nj there is a continuum of intermediate good producers withtechnology as in Eaton and Kortum (2002)

I Perfect competition, CRS technology, idiosyncratic productivityznj ∼Fréchet(1, θj ), deterministic sectoral regional TFP Anj

qnjt (znj ) = znj

[Anj [lnjt ]

ξn [hnjt ]1−ξn

]γnj J

∏k=1[Mnj ,nkt ]γ

nj ,nk

Each n, j produces a final good (for final consumption and materials)I CES (elasticity η) aggregator of sector j goods from the lowest costsupplier in the world subject to κnj ,ij ≥ 1 “iceberg”bilateral trade cost

Intermediate goods Final goods

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 8 / 24

Page 10: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Production - Static sub-problem - Equilibrium conditionsSectoral price index,

Pnjt (wt ) = Γnj[∑Ni=1 A

ij [x ijt (wt )κnj ,ij ]−θj

]−1/θj

Let X ijt (wt ) be total expenditure. Expenditure shares given by

πnj ,ijt (wt ) =[x ijt (wt )κnj ,ij ]−θjAij

∑Nm=1[x

mjt (wt )κnj ,mj ]−θjAmj

,

where x ijt (wt ) is the unit cost of an input bundleLabor Market clearing

Lnjt =γnj (1− ξn)

wnjt∑Ni=1 πij ,njt (wt )X

ijt (wt ),

where γnj (1− ξn) labor share

Input bundle

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 9 / 24

Page 11: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Sequential and temporary equilibrium

State of the economy = distribution of labor Lt = {Lnjt }N ,Jn=1,j=0

I Let Θ ≡({Anj}, {κnj ,ij}, {τnj ,ik},

{Hnj

}, {bn}

)N ,J ,J ,Nn=1,j=0,i=1,k=0

DefinitionGiven (Lt ,Θ) , a temporary equilibrium is a vector of wt (Lt ,Θ) thatsatisfies the equilibrium conditions of the static sub-problem

DefinitionGiven (L0,Θ) , a sequential competitive equilibrium of the model is asequence of {Lt , µt , Vt , wt (Lt ,Θ)}∞

t=0 that solves HH dynamic problemand the temporary equilibrium at each t

With µt = {µnj ,ikt }N ,J ,J ,Nn=1,j=0,i=1,k=0, and Vt = {V

njt }N ,Jn=1,j=0

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 10 / 24

Page 12: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Solution Method

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 11 / 24

Page 13: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Solving the model

Solving for an equilibrium of the model requires information on ΘI Large # of unknowns N + 2NJ +N2J +N2J2I Productivity, endowments of local structures, labor mobility costs,home production, and trade costs

As we increase the dimension of the problem– adding countries,regions, or sectors– the number of parameters grows geometrically

We solve this problem by computing the equilibrium dynamics of themodel in time differences

Why is this progress?I As in DEK (2008), Caliendo and Parro (2015), by conditioning onobservables one can solve the model without knowing the levels of Θ

F We apply this idea to a dynamic economy

I Condition on last period migration flows, trade flows, and production

F Solve for the value function in time differences

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 12 / 24

Page 14: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Equilibrium conditions

Expected lifetime utility

V njt = log(wnjtP nt) + ν log

[N∑i=1

J∑k=0

exp(

βV ikt+1 − τnj ,ik)1/ν

]

Transition matrix (migration flows)

µnj ,ikt =exp

(βV ikt+1 − τnj ,ik

)1/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

exp(

βVmht+1 − τnj ,mh)1/ν

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 13 / 24

Page 15: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Equilibrium conditions

Transition matrix (migration flows) at t = −1, Data

µnj ,ik−1 =exp

(βV ik0 − τnj ,ik

)1/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

exp(

βVmh0 − τnj ,mh)1/ν

Transition matrix (migration flows) at t = 0, Model

µnj ,ik0 =exp

(βV ik1 − τnj ,ik

)1/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

exp(

βVmh1 − τnj ,mh)1/ν

Take the time difference

µnj ,ik0

µnj ,ik−1=

exp(βV ik1 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

exp(βV ik0 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0exp(βV mh1 −τnj ,mh)

1/ν

∑Nm′=1 ∑J

h′=0 exp(βV m′h′0 −τnj ,m′h′)

1/ν

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 9 / 24

Page 16: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Equilibrium conditions

Transition matrix (migration flows) at t = −1, Data

µnj ,ik−1 =exp

(βV ik0 − τnj ,ik

)1/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

exp(

βVmh0 − τnj ,mh)1/ν

Transition matrix (migration flows) at t = 0, Model

µnj ,ik0 =exp

(βV ik1 − τnj ,ik

)1/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

exp(

βVmh1 − τnj ,mh)1/ν

Take the time difference

µnj ,ik0

µnj ,ik−1=

exp(βV ik1 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

exp(βV ik0 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0exp(βV mh1 −τnj ,mh)

1/ν

∑Nm′=1 ∑J

h′=0 exp(βV m′h′0 −τnj ,m′h′)

1/ν

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 9 / 24

Page 17: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Equilibrium conditions

Transition matrix (migration flows) at t = −1, Data

µnj ,ik−1 =exp

(βV ik0 − τnj ,ik

)1/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

exp(

βVmh0 − τnj ,mh)1/ν

Transition matrix (migration flows) at t = 0, Model

µnj ,ik0 =exp

(βV ik1 − τnj ,ik

)1/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

exp(

βVmh1 − τnj ,mh)1/ν

Take the time difference

µnj ,ik0

µnj ,ik−1=

exp(βV ik1 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

exp(βV ik0 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0exp(βV mh1 −τnj ,mh)

1/ν

∑Nm′=1 ∑J

h′=0 exp(βV m′h′0 −τnj ,m′h′)

1/ν

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 9 / 24

Page 18: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Equilibrium conditions

Take the time difference

µnj ,ik0

µnj ,ik−1=

exp(βV ik1 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

exp(βV ik0 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0exp(βV mh1 −τnj ,mh)

1/ν

∑Nm′=1 ∑J

h′=0 exp(βV m′h′0 −τnj ,m′h′)

1/ν

Simplify

µnj ,ik0

µnj ,ik−1=

exp(V ik1 − V ik0

)β/ν

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0exp(βV mh1 −τnj ,mh)

1/ν

∑Nm′=1 ∑J

h′=0 exp(βV m′h′0 −τnj ,m′h′)

1/ν

Use µnj ,mh−1 once again

µnj ,ik0 =µnj ,ik−1 exp

(V ik1 − V ik0

)β/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

µnj ,mh−1 exp(Vmh1 − Vmh0

)β/ν

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 10 / 24

Page 19: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Equilibrium conditions

Take the time difference

µnj ,ik0

µnj ,ik−1=

exp(βV ik1 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

exp(βV ik0 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0exp(βV mh1 −τnj ,mh)

1/ν

∑Nm′=1 ∑J

h′=0 exp(βV m′h′0 −τnj ,m′h′)

1/ν

Simplify

µnj ,ik0

µnj ,ik−1=

exp(V ik1 − V ik0

)β/ν

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0exp(βV mh1 −τnj ,mh)

1/ν

∑Nm′=1 ∑J

h′=0 exp(βV m′h′0 −τnj ,m′h′)

1/ν

Use µnj ,mh−1 once again

µnj ,ik0 =µnj ,ik−1 exp

(V ik1 − V ik0

)β/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

µnj ,mh−1 exp(Vmh1 − Vmh0

)β/ν

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 10 / 24

Page 20: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Equilibrium conditions

Take the time difference

µnj ,ik0

µnj ,ik−1=

exp(βV ik1 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

exp(βV ik0 −τnj ,ik)1/ν

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0exp(βV mh1 −τnj ,mh)

1/ν

∑Nm′=1 ∑J

h′=0 exp(βV m′h′0 −τnj ,m′h′)

1/ν

Simplify

µnj ,ik0

µnj ,ik−1=

exp(V ik1 − V ik0

)β/ν

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0exp(βV mh1 −τnj ,mh)

1/ν

∑Nm′=1 ∑J

h′=0 exp(βV m′h′0 −τnj ,m′h′)

1/ν

Use µnj ,mh−1 once again

µnj ,ik0 =µnj ,ik−1 exp

(V ik1 − V ik0

)β/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

µnj ,mh−1 exp(Vmh1 − Vmh0

)β/ν

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 10 / 24

Page 21: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Equilibrium conditions

Expected lifetime utility

V njt = log(wnjtP nt) + ν log

[N∑i=1

J∑k=0

exp(

βV ikt+1 − τnj ,ik)1/ν

]

Transition matrix

µnj ,ikt =exp

(βV ikt+1 − τnj ,ik

)1/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

exp(

βVmht+1 − τnj ,mh)1/ν

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 10 / 24

Page 22: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Equilibrium conditions - Time differences

Expected lifetime utility

V njt+1 − Vnjt = log(

w njt+1/w njtP nt+1/P nt

) + ν log[N∑i=1

J∑k=0

µnj ,ikt exp(V ikt+2 − V ikt+1

)β/ν]

Transition matrix

µnj ,ikt+1

µnj ,ikt

=exp

(V ikt+2 − V ikt+1

)β/ν

N∑m=1

J∑h=0

µnj ,mht exp(Vmht+2 − Vmht+1

)β/ν

where w njt+1/w njtP nt+1/P nt

is the solution to the temporary equilibrium in time

differences

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 10 / 24

Page 23: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Temporary equilibrium conditionsHow to solve for the temporary equilibrium in time differences?

Price index

Pnjt (wt ) = Γnj[∑Ni=1 A

ij [x ijt (wt )κnj ,ij ]−θj

]−1/θj

,

Trade shares

πnj ,ijt (wt ) =[x ijt (wt )κnj ,ij ]−θjAij

∑Nm=1[x

mjt (wt )κnj ,mj ]−θjAmj

,

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 11 / 24

Page 24: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Temporary equilibrium - Time differencesHow to solve for the temporary equilibrium in time differences?

Price index

Pnjt+1(wt+1) =[∑Ni=1 πnj ,ijt [x ijt+1(wt+1)]

−θj]−1/θj

,

Trade shares

πnj ,ijt+1(wt+1) =πnj ,ijt [x ijt+1(wt+1)]

−θj

∑Nm=1 πnj ,mjt [xmjt+1(wt+1)]−θj

,

Where Pnjt+1 = Pnjt+1/P

njt , x

ijt+1 = x

ijt+1/x

ijt , wt+1 = wt+1/wt

Same “hat trick”applies to all equilibrium conditions

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 11 / 24

Page 25: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Solving the model

Proposition

Given(L0, µ−1,π0,VA0,GO0

), (ν, θ, β), solving the equilibrium in time

differences does not require the level of Θ, and solves

Y njt+1 = (wnjt+1/P

nt+1)

1/ν ∑Ni=1 ∑J

k=0 µnj ,ikt [Y ikt+2]β,

µnj ,ikt+1 =µnj ,ikt [Y ikt+2]

β

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0 µnj ,mht [Ymht+2]β,

Lnjt+1 = ∑Ni=1 ∑J

k=0 µik ,njt Likt ,

where wnjt+1/Pnt+1 solves the temporary equilibrium given Lt+1, where

Y ikt+1 ≡ exp(V ikt+1 − V ikt )1/ν.

Example

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 12 / 24

Page 26: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Solving for counterfactuals

Want to study the effects of changes in fundamentals Θ = Θ′/Θ

I Recall that

Θ ≡({Anj}, {κnj ,ij}, {τnj ,ik},

{Hnj

}, {bn}

)N ,J ,J ,Nn=1,j=0,i=1,k=0

I TFP, trade costs, labor migration costs, endowments of localstructures, home production

We can use our solution method to study the effects of changes in Θ

I One by one or jointlyI Changes across time and space

Proposition

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 13 / 24

Page 27: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Appplication: The Rise of China

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 14 / 24

Page 28: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

The rise of China

U.S. imports from China almost doubled from 2000 to 2007I At the same time, manufacturing employment fell while employment inother sectors, such as construction and services, grew

Several studies document that an important part of the employmentloss in manufactures was a consequence of China’s trade expansion

I e.g., Pierce and Schott (2012); Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013),Acemoglu, Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2014)

We use our model, and apply our method, to quantify and understandthe effects of the rise of China’s trade expansion, “China shock”

I Initial period is the year 2000I We calculate the sectoral, regional, and aggregate employment andwelfare effects of the China shock

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 15 / 24

Page 29: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Identifying the China shock

Follow Autor, Dorn, and Hanson (2013)I We estimate

∆MUSA,j = a1 + a2∆Mother ,j + uj ,

where j is a NAICS sector, ∆MUSA,j and ∆Mother ,j are changes in U.S.and other adv. countries, imports from China from 2000 to 2007

Obtain predicted changes in U.S. imports with this specification

Use the model to solve for the change in China’s 12 manufacturingindustries TFP

{AChina,j

}12j=1 such that model’s imports match

predicted imports from China from 2000 to 2007

I We feed in to our model{AChina,j

}12j=1

by quarter from 2000 to 2007

to study the effects of the shock

Figure: shock and predicted imports

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 16 / 24

Page 30: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Taking the model to the data (quarterly)

Model with 50 U.S. states, 22 sectors + unempl. and 38 countriesI More than 1000 labor markets

Need data for(L0, µ−1,π0,VA0,GO0

)I L0 : PUMS of the U.S. Census for the year 2000I µ−1 : Use CPS to compute intersectoral mobility and ACS to computeinterstate mobility Details Table

I π0 : CFS and WIOD year 2000I VA0 and GO0 : BEA VA shares and U.S. IO, WIOD for other countries

Need values for parameters (ν, θ, β)I θ : We use Caliendo and Parro (2015)I β = 0.99 Implies approximately a 4% annual interest rateI υ = 5.34 (implied elasticity of 0.2) Using ACM’s data andspecification, adapted to our model Estimation

Need to deal with trade deficits. Do so similar to CPRHS Imbalances

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 17 / 24

Page 31: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Employment effectsFigure: The Evolution of Employment Shares

0 10 20 30 40 5060.50

61.00

61.50

62.00

62.50

63.00

Time (quarters)

Em

ploy

men

t sha

re (

%)

Services - No China ShockServices - China Shock

0 10 20 30 40 507.45

7.50

7.55

7.60

7.65

Time (quarters)E

mpl

oym

ent s

hare

(%

)

Construction - No China ShockConstruction - China Shock

0 10 20 30 40 50

14.7

14.8

14.9

15

Time (quarters)

Em

ploy

men

t sha

re (

%)

W & Retail - No China ShockW & Retail - China Shock

0 10 20 30 40 5014.50

15.00

15.50

16.00

16.50

Time (quarters)

Em

ploy

men

t sha

re (

%)

Manufacturing - No China ShockManufacturing - China Shock

Chinese competition reduced the share of manufacturing employmentby 0.5% in the long run, ∼0.8 million employment loss

I About 50% of the change not explained by a secular trend

Proposition Validation

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 18 / 24

Page 32: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Manufacturing employment effects

Sectors most exposed to Chinese import competition contribute moreI 1/2 of the decline in manuf. employment originated in the Computer &Electronics and Furniture sectors Sectoral contributions

F 1/4 of the total decline comes from the Metal and Textiles sectors

I Food, Beverage and Tobacco, gained employment

F Less exposed to China, benefited from cheaper intermediate goods,other sectors, like Services, demanded more of them (I-O linkages)

Unequal regional effects Spatial distribution

I Regions with a larger concentration of sectors that are more exposed toChina lose more jobs Regional contributions

F California, the region with largest share of employment in Computer &Electronics, contributed to about 12% of the decline

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 19 / 24

Page 33: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Welfare effects across labor markets

Figure: Welfare changes across labor markets

0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 10

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

Percentage change

Den

sity

Note: Largest and smallest 5 percentile are excluded

Very heterogeneous response to the same aggregate shock welfare

I Most labor markets gain as a consequence of cheaper imports fromChina

I Unequal regional effects welfare reg

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 20 / 24

Page 34: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Transition cost to the steady state

Figure: Transition cost to the steady state across labor markets

-8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 10 120

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

Percentage change

Den

sity

Note: Largest and smallest 5 percentile are excluded

Adjustment costs reflect the importance of labor market dynamicsI With free labor mobility AC=0

Heterogeneity shaped by trade and migration frictions as well asgeographic factors.

AC

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 21 / 24

Page 35: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Welfare effects across countries

Figure: Welfare effects across countries

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

Per

cent

age

chan

ge

Aus

tral

ia

Aus

tria

Bel

gium

Bra

zil

Bul

garia

Can

ada

Cyp

rus

Cze

ch R

epub

lic

Den

mar

k

Est

onia

Fin

land

Fra

nce

Ger

man

y

Gre

ece

Hun

gary

Indi

a

Indo

nesi

a

Irel

and

Ital

y

Japa

n

Kor

ea

Lith

uani

a

Me

xico

Net

herla

nds

Pol

and

Por

tuga

l

Res

t of t

he W

orld

Rom

ania

Rus

sia

Slo

vaki

a

Slo

veni

a

Spa

in

Sw

eden

Tai

wan

Tur

key

Uni

ted

Kin

gdom

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 22 / 24

Page 36: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Conclusion

Develop a dynamic and spatial model to quantify the disaggregateeffects of aggregate shocks

Show how to perform counterfactual analysis in a very rich spatialmodel without having to estimate a large set of unobservables

Dynamics and realistic structure matters for capturing veryheterogenous effects at the disaggregate level

Our model can be applied to answer a broader set of questions:changes in productivity or trade costs in any location in the world,commercial policies, and more...

Where we go from here:1- Migration crisis in Europe.2- Human capital accumulation

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 23 / 24

Page 37: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

This is the END

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 24 / 24

Page 38: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Results with Fréchet and Multiplicative Costs

Expected lifetime utility

V n,jt = u(cn,jt)+

(∑Ni=1 ∑J

k=0

(βV i ,kt+1 τn,j ;i ,k

)1/ν)ν

,

Measure of workers that reallocate (Choice equation)

µn,j ;i ,kt =

(βV i ,kt+1 τn,j ;i ,k

)1/ν

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0

(βVm,ht+1 τn,j ;m,h

)1/ν.

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 25 / 24

Page 39: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Information in CPS and ACS

State A State BInd 1 Ind 2 . . . Ind J Ind 1 Ind 2 . . . Ind J

StateA

Ind 1 x x . . . xInd 2 x x . . . x. . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Ind J x x xTotal y y . . . y y y . . . y

StateB

Ind 1 x x . . . xInd 2 x x . . . x. . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Ind J x x xTotal y y . . . y y y . . . y

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 26 / 24

Page 40: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Model - Intermediate goods

Representative firms in each region n and sector j produce acontinuum of intermediate goods with idiosyncratic productivities znj

I Drawn independently across goods, sectors, and regions from a Fréchetdistribution with shape parameter θj

I Productivity of all firms is also determined by a deterministicproductivity level Anj

The production function of a variety with znj and Anj is given by

qnjt (znj ) = znj

[Anj [lnjt ]

ξn [hnjt ]1−ξn

]γnj J

∏k=1

[Mnj ,nkt ]γ

nj ,nk,

with ∑Jk=1 γnj ,nk = 1− γnj

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 27 / 24

Page 41: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Model - Intermediate good prices

The cost of the input bundle needed to produce varieties in (nj) is

xnjt = Bnj[(rnjt)ξn (

wnjt)1−ξn

]γnj J

∏k=1

[Pnkt ]γnj ,nk

The unit cost of a good of a variety with draw znj in (nj) is

xnjtznj[Anj ]−γnj

and so its price under competition is given by

pnjt (zj ) = min

i

{κnj ,ij x ijtz ij [Aij ]γij

},

with κnj ,ij ≥ 1 are “iceberg”bilateral trade costBack Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 28 / 24

Page 42: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Model - Final goods

The production of final goods is given by

Qnjt =[∫

RN++[qnjt (z

j )]1−1/ηnjφj (z j )dz j]ηnj/(ηnj−1)

,

where z j = (z1j , z2j , ...zNj ) denotes the vector of productivity drawsfor a given variety received by the different n

The resulting price index in sector j and region n, given ourdistributional assumptions, is given by

Pnjt = $[∑Ni=1[x

ijt κnj ,ij ]−θj [Aij ]θ

jγij]−1/θj

,

where $ is a constant

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 29 / 24

Page 43: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Data - Quarterly gross flows

Current Population Survey (CPS) monthly frequencyI Information on intersectoral mobilityI Source of offi cial labor market statisticsI We match individuals surveyed three months apart and compute theiremployment (industry) or unemployment status

F Our 3-month match rate is close to 90%

American Community Survey (ACS) to compute interstate mobilityI Representative sample (0.5 percent) of the U.S. population for 2000I Mandatory and is a complement to the decennial CensusI Information on current state and industry (or unemployment) and statethey lived during previous year

I Limitation: no information on workers past employment status orindustry

Table Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 30 / 24

Page 44: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Data - Quarterly gross flows

Table: U.S. interstate and intersectoral labor mobility

Probability p25 p50 p75Changing j in same n 3.74% 5.77% 8.19%Changing n but not j 0.04% 0.42% 0.73%Changing j and n 0.03% 0.04% 0.06%Staying in same j and n 91.1% 93.6% 95.2%

Note: Quarterly transitions. Data sources: ACS and CPS

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 31 / 24

Page 45: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Identifying the China shockFigure: Predicted change in imports vs. model-based Chinese TFP change

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

5.0

1

10

100

1000

10000

100000

Foo

d, B

ev,

To

b

Text

iles

Wo

od

, Pap

er

Pet

role

um

, Co

al

Ch

em

ical

s

Pla

stic

s, R

ub

be

r

No

nM

etal

lic

Met

al

Mac

hin

ery

Co

mp

ute

r, E

lect

Tran

spo

rt M

tg

Furn

itu

re M

tg

Esti

mat

ed c

han

ge in

mea

sure

d T

FP (

qu

arte

rly,

per

cen

t)

Pre

dic

eted

ch

ange

in U

.S. i

mp

ort

s (m

illio

ns,

log

scla

e)

Predicted change in U.S. imports from China Change in measured TFP in China

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 32 / 24

Page 46: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Identifying the China shockFigure: Predicted change in imports vs. model-based Chinese TFP change

0.95

1

1.05

1.1

1.15

1.2

1

10

100

1000

10000

100000

Food, B

ev, Tob

Textiles

Wood, Paper

Petroleum, Coal

Chem

icals

Plastics, Rubber

Nonmetallic

Metal

Machinery

Computer, Elect

Transport M

fg

Furniture M

fg

Estimated China chan

ge in

 TFP

 (Quarterly)

Predicted chan

ge in

 U.S. imports (m

illio

ns, log scale)   

Predicted change in U.S. imports from China Change in TFP in China

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 33 / 24

Page 47: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Manufacturing Employment Effects

Figure: Sectoral contribution to the change in manuf. employment

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

Per

cent

age

chan

ge

Foo

d, B

ev.,

Tob

.

Tex

tiles

Woo

d, P

aper

Pet

role

um, C

oal

Che

mic

als

Pla

stic

s, R

ubbe

r

Non

met

allic

Met

al

Mac

hine

ry

Com

pute

r, E

lect

.

Tra

nspo

rt M

fg.

Fur

nitu

re M

fg.

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 34 / 24

Page 48: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Sectoral concentration across regions

Computers an Electronics (shares)

LL

2222

LK

2221

LZ

323

LR

2211

AL

2222

AO

222

AT

2224

EE

222

LL

322

AL

2252

II

22223

IE

122

IL

222IN

121

IL

2227

KS

2224KY

2214

LL

2211

EE

2212

EE

122

EL

227EI

225

EN

222

ES

2219

EO

2232

ET

2222

NE

2222NV

2212

NI

229

NJ

122

NE

124

NY

322

NA

427

NE

2213

OI

124

OK

2224

OR

1122

AL

122

RI

2212

SA

2222

SE

2217

TN

122

TX

1121

TT

2273

VT

2225

VL

2294

AL

123

AV

2224

AI

2AY

2221

Wood and Paper (shares)

LL

666

LK

2622

LZ

267

LR

161

AL

666

AO

2667

AT

2611

EE

2666

LL

266

AL

669

II

2626

IE

2666

IL

161IN

2

IL

166

KS

261KY

261

LL

266

EE

169

EE

2666

EL

161EI

262

EN

162

ES

161

EO

261

ET

2611

NE

2621NV

2617

NI

261

NJ

169

NE

2619

NY

266

NA

6

NE

2616

OI

169

OK

2691

OR

1

AL

662

RI

2611

SA

6

SE

2622

TN

166

TX

661

TT

2662

VT

2626

VL

261

AL

1

AV

2667

AI

761AY

2627

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 35 / 24

Page 49: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Manufacturing employment effects

Figure: Regional contribution to the change in manuf. employment

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

Perc

enta

ge c

hang

e

Alab

ama

Alas

ka

Ariz

ona

Arka

nsas

C

alifo

rnia

C

olor

ado

Con

nect

icut

D

elaw

are

Flor

ida

Geo

rgia

H

awai

i Id

aho

Illin

ois

Indi

ana

Iow

a Ka

nsas

Ke

ntuc

ky

Loui

sian

a M

aine

M

aryl

and

Mas

sach

uset

ts

Mic

higa

n M

inne

sota

M

issi

ssip

pi

Mis

sour

i M

onta

na

Neb

rask

a N

evad

a N

ew H

amps

hire

N

ew J

erse

y N

ew M

exic

o N

ew Y

ork

Nor

th C

arol

ina

Nor

th D

akot

a O

hio

Okl

ahom

a O

rego

n Pe

nnsy

lvan

ia

Rho

de Is

land

So

uth

Car

olin

a So

uth

Dak

ota

Tenn

esse

e Te

xas

Uta

h Ve

rmon

t Vi

rgin

ia

Was

hing

ton

Wes

t Virg

inia

W

isco

nsin

W

yom

ing

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 36 / 24

Page 50: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Regional welfare effects

LL

6666

LK

6699

LZ

6655

LR

6669

AL

6652

AO

6646

AT

6646

EE

2662

LL

6665

AL

664

II

6669

IE

6625

IL

6669IN

666

IL

665

KS

6655KY

666

LL

6659

EE

6652

EE

6662

EL

6666EI

666

EN

6662

ES

6665

EO

666

ET

6695

NE

6649NV

6654

NI

6665

NJ

6646

NE

6652

NY

6659

NA

6666

NE

6642

OI

6664

OK

6699

OR

6665

AL

666

RI

6644

SA

6695

SE

6625

TN

6665

TX

6652

TT

6692

VT

6664

VL

666

AL

6665

AV

6645

AI

6699AY

2662

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 37 / 24

Page 51: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Sectoral and regional welfare effects

Sectoral effects very different in the long run than in the short runI Services and Construction gain the most Sectoral effects

F Reasons: no direct exposure, benefit from cheaper intermediate inputs,increased inflow of workers from manufacturing

I Welfare gains are more uniform in the long runF Workers reallocate from depressed industries

U.S. regions fare better in the short and the long run Regional effects

I Regions benefit directly from cheaper intermediate goods from ChinaF and indirectly from the effect of imports on the cost of inputspurchased from other U.S. regions

I The regional welfare distribution is more uniform in the long runF workers reallocate from regions with lower real income

Worst off individual labor marketsI F Wood and Paper in Nevada, Transport and Equip. in Louisiana, and

Wholesale and Retail in Alaska

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 38 / 24

Page 52: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Solving the model

Proposition

Given(L0, µ−1,π0,VA0,GO0

), (ν, θ, β), and Θ = {Θt}∞

t=1, solving theequilibrium in time differences does not require Θ, and solves

Y njt+1 = (wnjt+1/P

nt+1)

1/ν ∑Ni=1 ∑J

k=0 µnj ,ikt [Y ikt+2]β,

µnj ,ikt+1 =µnj ,ikt [Y ikt+2]

β

∑Nm=1 ∑J

h=0 µnj ,mht [Ymht+2]β,

Lnjt+1 = ∑Ni=1 ∑J

k=0 µik ,njt Likt ,

where wnjt+1/Pnt+1 solves the temporary equilibrium at Lt+1 given Θt+1,

and Y ikt+1 ≡ exp(V ikt+1 − V ikt )1/ν

Back Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 39 / 24

Page 53: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

How to perform counterfactuals?

Solve the model conditioning on observed data at an initial periodI Value added, Trade shares, Gross production, all consistent withobserved labor allocation across labor market at t = 0

I Use the labor mobility matrix µ−1. For this, we we need to specifyagents expectations at t = −1 about future policies

Assumption: Policy changes are unanticipated at t = −1I Allows us to condition on observed data and solve for the sequentialequilibrium with no policy changes

I Let {Vt}∞t=0 be the equilibrium sequence of values with constant

policies, where Vt = {V i ,kt }N ,Ji=1,k=1.I The assumption implies that the initial observed labor mobility matrix

µ−1 is the outcome of forward looking behavior under {Vt}∞t=0.

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 40 / 24

Page 54: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Solving the model (example)

Figure: Equilibrium Value Functions in Time Differences

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 1100.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

Time (quarters)

Ynj t

Proposition

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 41 / 24

Page 55: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Taking the model to the data (quarterly)

υ = 5.34 (implied elasticity of 0.2) Using ACM’s data andspecification, adapted to our model

I Data: migration flows and real wages for 26 years between 1975-2000,using March CPS

I We deal with two issues: functional forms, and timing

Estimating equation

log µnj ,ikt /µnj ,njt = C +β

υlogw ikt+1/w

njt+1 + β log µnj ,ikt+1 /µnj ,njt+1 +vt+1,

I We transform migration flows from five-month to quarterly frequencyI GMM estimation, past flows and wages used as instrumentsI ACM estimate υ = 1.88 (annual), υ = 2.89 (five-month frequency)

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 42 / 24

Page 56: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Model validationCompare reduced-form evidence with model’s predictions

I First run second-stage regression in ADH with our level of aggregationI Then, run same regression with model generated data

Table: Reduced-form regression results

∆Lmit ∆uitdata model data model(1) (2) (3) (4)

∆IPWuit -1.718 -1.124 0.461 0.873(0.194) (0.368) (0.138) (0.252)

Obs 49 50 49 50R2 0.51 0.16 0.13 0.20

Results are largely aligned with those in ADH

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 43 / 24

Page 57: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Adjustment costs

We follow Dix-Carneiro (2014)’s measure of adjustment cost

The steady-state change in the value function due changes infundamentals is given by V njSS (Θ)− V

njSS

Therefore, the transition cost for market nj to the new long-runequilibrium, AC nj (Θ), is given by

AC nj (Θ) = log

11−β

(V njSS (Θ)− V

njSS

)∑∞t=0 βt

(V njt+1(Θ)− V

njt+1

) ,

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 44 / 24

Page 58: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Imbalances

Assume that in each region there is a mass of one of RentiersI Owners of local structures, obtain rents ∑Jk=1 r

ikt H

ik

I Send all their local rents to a global portfolioI Receive a constant share ιi from the global portfolio, with ∑Nn=1 ιn = 1

Imbalances in region i given by

J

∑k=1

r ikt Hik − ιiχt ,

where χt = ∑Ni=1 ∑J

k=1 rikt H

ik are the total revenues in the globalportfolio

Rentier uses her income to purchase local goodsI Same preferences as workers

Back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 45 / 24

Page 59: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Welfare effects from changes in fundamentals

Let W njt (Θ) be the welfare effect of change in Θ = Θ′/Θ

W njt (Θ) =

∞∑s=t

βs log cnjs(µnj ,njs )ν

,

I Note that this is a consumption equivalent measure of welfareI (µnj ,njs )ν is the change in the option value of migration

In our model, cnjt = wnjt /Pnt is shaped by several mechanisms,

cnjt =w njt

∏Jk=1(w

nkt )

αk ∏Jk=1

(w nktP nkt

)αk

,

I First component reflects the unequal effects within a regionI Second component is common to all HH residing in region n, given by

J

∑k=1

αk

(log(πnk ,nkt )−γnk/θk − ξn log

LnktHnk

).

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 46 / 24

Page 60: Trade and Labor Market Dynamics · 2016. 5. 17. · March, 2016 Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 1 / 24. Introduction Aggregate trade

Welfare effects from changes in fundamentalsLet W nj

t (Θ) be the welfare effect of change in Θ = Θ′/Θ

W njt (Θ) =

∞∑s=t

βs log cnjs(µnj ,njs )ν

,

I Note that this is a consumption equivalent measure of welfareI (µnj ,njs )ν is the change in the option value of migration

In a one sector model with no materials and structures, cnt = wnt /Pnt

W nt (Θ) =

∑s=t

βs log(πn,ns )

−1/θ

(µn,ns )ν,

Similar to a ACM (2010) + ACR (2012)

back

Caliendo, Dvorkin, and Parro (2015) ()Trade and Labor Markets Dynamics March, 2016 47 / 24