topic 5 r&d and patent law - department of economics...

10
Topic 5 R&D and Patent Law 5.1 Classifications of Process Innovation classifies process (cost-reducing) innovation according to the magnitude of the cost reduction gener- ated by the R&D process. industry producing a homogeneous product firms compete in prices. initially, all firms possess identical technologies: with a unit production cost c 0 > 0. Q p c 0 c 2 c 1 p m (c 1 ) p m (c 2 ) p 1 = p 0 MR(Q) D Q 1 Q 0 Q 2 Figure 5.1: Classification of process innovation Definition 5.1 Let p m (c) denote the price that would be charged by a monopoly firm whose unit production cost is given by c. Then, (a) Innovation is said to be large (or drastic, or major) if p m (c) <c 0 . That is, if innovation reduces the cost to a level where the associated pure monopoly price is lower than the unit production costs of the competing firms. (b) Innovation is said to be small (or nondrastic, or minor) if p m (c) >c 0 . (Downloaded from www.ozshy.com) (draft=gradio21.tex 2007/12/11 12:19)

Upload: ngodang

Post on 16-Mar-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Topic 5

R&D and Patent Law

5.1 Classifications of Process Innovation

• classifies process (cost-reducing) innovation according to the magnitude of the cost reduction gener-ated by the R&D process.

• industry producing a homogeneous product

• firms compete in prices.

• initially, all firms possess identical technologies: with a unit production cost c0 > 0.

-

6llllllllllllllll

TTTTTTTTTTTTTT

Q

p

c0

c2

c1

pm(c1)

pm(c2)

p1 = p0

MR(Q)

D

Q1 Q0 Q2

Figure 5.1: Classification of process innovation

Definition 5.1Let pm(c) denote the price that would be charged by a monopoly firm whose unit production cost isgiven by c. Then,(a) Innovation is said to be large (or drastic, or major) if

pm(c) < c0. That is, if innovation reduces the cost to a level where the associated pure monopolyprice is lower than the unit production costs of the competing firms.

(b) Innovation is said to be small (or nondrastic, or minor) ifpm(c) > c0.

(Downloaded from www.ozshy.com) (draft=gradio21.tex 2007/12/11 12:19)

sugata
Text Box
608: Economics of Regulation Lecture Notes Winter 2012 p1
sugata
Text Box

5.2 Innovation Race 31

Example: Consider the linear inverse demand function p = a − bQ. Then, innovation is major ifc1 < 2c0 − a and minor otherwise.

5.2 Innovation Race

Two types of models:

Memoryless: Probability of discovery is independent of experience (thus, depends only on current R&Dexpenditure).

Cumulating Experience: Probability of discovery increases with cumulative R&D experience (like capitalstock).

5.2.1 Memoryless model

Lee and Wilde (1980), Loury (1979), and Reinganum. The model below is Exercise 10.5, page 396 inTirole.

• n firms race for a prize V (present value of discounted benefits from getting the patent)

• each firm is indexed by i, i = 1, 2, . . . , n

• xi ≥ 0 is a commitment to a stream of R&D investment (at any t, t ∈ [0,∞)).

• h(xi) is probability that firm i discovers the at ∆t when it invests xi in this time interval, whereh′ > 0, h′′ < 0, h(0) = 0, h′(0) =∞, h′(+∞) = 0

• τi date firm i discovers (random variable)

• τ̂idef= minj 6=i{τj(xj)} date in which first rival firm discovers (random variable).

Probability that firm i discovers before or at t is

Pr(τi(xi) ≤ t) = 1− e−h(xi)t, density is: h(xi)e−h(xi)t

Probability that firm i does not discover by t

Pr(τi(xi) > t) = e−h(xi)t

Probability that all n firms do NOT discover before t

Pr(τ̂i ≤ t) = 1− Pr{τj > t ∀i} = 1−(

1− e−∑ni=1 h(xi)t

)= e−

∑ni=1 h(xi)t

Define aidef=∑

j 6=i hj(xj).Remark : Probability at least one rival discovers before t

Pr(τ̂i ≤ t) = 1− Pr{τj > t ∀j 6= i} = 1− e−ait

The expected value of firm i is

Vi =

∞∫0

e−rte−t∑ni=1 h(xi) [h(xi)V − xi] dt =

h(xi)V − xir + ai + h(xi)

(Downloaded from www.ozshy.com) (draft=gradio21.tex 2007/12/11 12:19)

sugata
Text Box
608: Economics of Regulation Lecture Notes Winter 2012 p2
sugata
Text Box
sugata
Text Box

5.2 Innovation Race 32

Result 5.1R&D investment actions are strategically complements

Proof. Let xj = x for all j 6= i. Then, ai = (n− 1)h(x). First order condition is,

0 =∂Vi∂xi

=1

()2

{[h′(xi)V − 1][(n− 1)h(x) + h(xi) + r]− h′(xi)[h(xi)V − xi]

}.

Using the implicit function theorem,

∂xi∂x

=−[h′(xi)V − 1](n− 1)h′(x)

φwhere

φ = V h′′(xi)[(n−1)h(x)+h(xi)+r]+h′(xi)[h′(xi)V −1]− [h′(xi)V −1]h′(xi)−h′′(xi)[h(xi)V −xi].

The second and third terms cancel out so,

φ = V h′′(xi)[(n− 1)h(x) + h(xi) + r]− h′′(xi)[h(xi)V − xi] < 0

Therefore, ∂xi/∂x > 0.

Lee and Wilde show a series of propositions:

(1) give condition under which ∂x̂/∂n > 0.

(2) ∂τi/∂n < 0

(3) ∂Vi/∂n < 0

(4) x̂ > x∗ (excessive R&D, where social optimal is calculated by maximizing nV )

5.2.2 Cumulating experience model

Fudenberg, Gilbert, Stiglitz, and Tirole (1983) provide a model with cumulative experience.

• V is prize (only to winner), c per-unit of time R&D cost

• ti innovation starting date of firm i, i = 1, 2

• Assumption: t2 > t1 = 0 (firm 1 has a head start)

• ωi(t) = experience (length of time) firm i is engaged in R&D

• hence, ω1(t2) > ω2(t2) = 0. Note that ω2(t) = 0 for t ≤ t2.

• µi(t)def= µ(ωi(t)) = probability of discovering at t+ dt

• Hence, µ1(t) > µ2(t) for all t > 0. Also µ2(t) = 0 for t ≤ t2.

• c = (flow) cost of engaging in R&D.

(Downloaded from www.ozshy.com) (draft=gradio21.tex 2007/12/11 12:19)

sugata
Text Box
608: Economics of Regulation Lecture Notes Winter 2012 p3
sugata
Text Box
sugata
Text Box

5.2 Innovation Race 33

Expected instantaneous profit conditional that no firm having yet made the discovery is

µi(t)V − c

Probability that neither firm makes the discovery before t

e−∫ t0 [µ1(ω1(τ))+µ2(ω2(τ))]dτ

When both firms undertake R&D, from t1 and t2, respectively,

Vi =

∞∫ti

e−[rt+∫ t0 [µ1(ω1(τ))+µ2(ω2(τ))]dτ ] [µi(ωi(t))V − c] dt

Assumptions:

(1) R&D is potentially profitable for the monopolist. Formally, there exists ω̄ > 0 such that µ(ω)V −c >0 for all ω > ω̄; and µ(0)V − c < 0.

(2) R&D is profitable for a monopolist. Formally,

∞∫0

e−[rt+∫ t0 [µ(τ)]dτ ] [µ(t)V − c] dt > 0.

(3) R&D is unprofitable for a firm in a duopoly. Formally,

∞∫0

e−[rt+∫ t0 [2µ(τ)]dτ ] [µ(t)V − c] dt < 0.

-

6

ω2

ω1

V2 > 0

V2 < 0

V1 < 0actual path

k

t2

45◦

V2(ω1, ω2) = 0

V2(ω1, ω2) = 0

Firm 1 stays in

Firm 2 stays in

Both stay in

Figure 5.2: Locuses of Vi(ω1(τ), ω2(τ)) = 0, i = 1, 2 (note: t2 > t1 = 0)

(Downloaded from www.ozshy.com) (draft=gradio21.tex 2007/12/11 12:19)

sugata
Text Box
608: Economics of Regulation Lecture Notes Winter 2012 p4
sugata
Text Box
sugata
Text Box

5.3 R&D Joint Ventures 34

Results:

(1) ε-preemption. That is, firm 2 does not enter the race.

(2) if we add another stage of uncertainty (associated with developing the innovation), leapfrogging ispossible and there is no ε-preemption

5.3 R&D Joint Ventures

Many papers (see Choi 1993; d’Aspremont and Jacquemin 1988; Kamien, Muller, and Zang 1992; Katz1986, and Katz and Ordover 1990).

• two-stage game: at t = 1, firms determine (first noncooperatively and then cooperatively) how muchto invest in cost-reducing R&D and, at t = 2, the firms are engaged in a Cournot quantity game

• market for a homogeneous product, aggregate demand p = 100−Q.

• xi the amount of R&D undertaken by firm i,

• ci(x1, x2) the unit production cost of firm i

ci(x1, x2)def= 50− xi − βxj i 6= j, i = 1, 2, β ≥ 0.

Definition 5.2We say that R&D technologies exhibit (positive) spillover effects if β > 0.

Assumption 5.1Research labs operate under decreasing returns to scale. Formally,

TCi(xi) =(xi)2

2.

We analyze 2 (out of 3) market structures:

(1) Noncoordination: Look for a Nash equilibrium in R&D efforts: x1 and x2.

(2) Coordination (semicollusion): Determine each firm’s R&D level, x1 and x2 as to maximize jointprofit, while still maintaining separate labs.

(3) R&D Joint Venture (RJV semicollusion): Setting a single lap. The present model does not fit thismarket structure.

5.3.1 Noncooperative R&D

The second period

πi(c1, c2)|t=2 =(100− 2ci + cj)2

9for i = 1, 2, i 6= j. (5.1)

(Downloaded from www.ozshy.com) (draft=gradio21.tex 2007/12/11 12:19)

sugata
Text Box
608: Economics of Regulation Lecture Notes Winter 2012 p5
sugata
Text Box

5.3 R&D Joint Ventures 35

The first period

maxxi

πi =19

[100− 2(50− xi − βxj) + 50− xj − βxi]2 −(xi)2

2

=19

[50 + (2− β)xi + (2β − 1)xj ]2 −(xi)2

2. (5.2)

The first-order condition yields

0 =∂πi∂xi

=29

[50 + (2− β)xi + (2β − 1)xj ](2− β)− xi.

x1 = x2 ≡ xnc, where xnc is the common noncooperative equilibrium

xnc =50(2− β)

4.5− (2− β)(1 + β). (5.3)

5.3.2 R&D Coordination

The firms seek to jointly choose x1 and x2 to1

maxx1,x2

(π1 + π2),

where πi, i = 1, 2 are given in (5.1). The first-order conditions are given by

0 =∂(π1 + π2)

∂xi=∂πi∂xi

+∂πj∂xi

.

The first term measures the marginal profitability of firm i from a small increase in its R&D (xi), whereasthe second term measures the marginal increase in firm j’s profit due to the spillover effect from anincrease in i’s R&D effort. Hence,

0 =29

[50 + (2− β)xi + (2β − 1)xj ](2− β)− xi

+29

[50 + (2− β)xj + (2β − 1)xi](2β − 1).

Assuming that second order conditions for a maximum are satisfied, the first order conditions yield thecooperative R&D level

xc1 = xc2 = xc =50(β + 1)

4.5− (β + 1)2. (5.4)

We now compare the industry’s R&D and production levels under noncooperative R&D and coop-erative R&D.

Result 5.2(a) Cooperation in R&D increases firms’ profits.(b) If the R&D spillover effect is large, then the cooperative R&D levels are higher than the noncoop-

erative R&D levels. Formally, if β > 12 , then xc > xnc. In this case, Qc > Qnc.

(c) If the R&D spillover effect is small, then the cooperative R&D levels are lower than the noncoop-erative R&D levels. Formally, if β < 1

2 , then xc < xnc. In this case, Qc < Qnc.

1See Salant and Shaffer (1998) for a criticism of the symmetry of R&D assumption.

(Downloaded from www.ozshy.com) (draft=gradio21.tex 2007/12/11 12:19)

sugata
Text Box
608: Economics of Regulation Lecture Notes Winter 2012 p6
sugata
Text Box

5.4 Patents 36

5.4 Patents

• We search for the socially optimal patent life T (is it 17 years?)

• Process innovation reduces the unit cost of the innovating firm by x

• For simplicity, we restrict our analysis to minor innovations only.

• market demand given by p = a−Q, where a > c.

-

6

ccccccccccccc

M DL

c

c− x

a− c a− (c− x) aQ

p

a

Figure 5.3: Gains and losses due to patent protection (assuming minor innovation)

M(x) = (a− c)x and DL(x) =x2

2. (5.5)

5.4.1 Innovator’s choice of R&D level for a given duration of patents

Denote by π(x;T ) the innovator’s present value of profits when the innovator chooses an R&D levelof x. Then, in the second stage the innovator takes the duration of patents T as given and chooses inperiod t = 1 R&D level x to

maxx

π(x;T ) =T∑t=1

ρt−1M(x)− TC(x). (5.6)

That is, the innovator chooses R&D level x to maximize the present value of T years of earning monopolyprofits minus the cost of R&D. We need the following Lemma.

Lemma 5.1

T∑t=1

ρt−1 =1− ρT

1− ρ.

(Downloaded from www.ozshy.com) (draft=gradio21.tex 2007/12/11 12:19)

sugata
Text Box
608: Economics of Regulation Lecture Notes Winter 2012 p7
sugata
Text Box

5.4 Patents 37

Proof.

T∑t=1

ρt−1 =T−1∑t=0

ρt =1

1− ρ− ρT − ρT+1 − ρT+2 − . . .

=1

1− ρ− ρT (1 + ρ+ ρ2 + ρ3 + . . .)

=1

1− ρ− ρT

1− ρ=

1− ρT

1− ρ.

Hence, by Lemma 5.1 and (5.5), (5.6) can be written as

maxx

1− ρT

1− ρ(a− c)x− x2

2,

implying that the innovator’s optimal R&D level is

xI =1− ρT

1− ρ(a− c). (5.7)

Hence,

Result 5.3(a) The R&D level increases with the duration of the patent. Formally, xI increases with T .(b) The R&D level increases with an increase in the demand, and decreases with an increase in the unit

cost. Formally, xI increases with an increase in a and decreases with an increase in c.(c) The R&D level increases with an increase in the discount factor ρ (or a decrease in the interest

rate).

5.4.2 Society’s optimal duration of patents

Formally, the social planner calculates profit-maximizing R&D (5.7) for the innovator, and in periodt = 1 chooses an optimal patent duration T to

maxT

W (T ) ≡∞∑t=1

ρt−1[CS0 +M(xI)

]+

∞∑t=T+1

ρt−1DL(xI)− (xI)2

2

s.t. xI =1− ρT

1− ρ(a− c). (5.8)

Since∞∑

t=T+1

ρt−1 = ρT∞∑t=0

ρt =ρT

1− ρ

and using (5.5), (5.8) can be written as choosing T ∗ to maximize

W (T ) =CS0 + (a− c)xI

1− ρ− (xI)2

21− ρ− ρT

1− ρs.t. xI =

1− ρT

1− ρ(a− c). (5.9)

Thus, the government acts as a leader since the innovator moves after the government sets the patentlength T , and the government moves first and chooses T knowing how the innovator is going to respond.

(Downloaded from www.ozshy.com) (draft=gradio21.tex 2007/12/11 12:19)

sugata
Text Box
608: Economics of Regulation Lecture Notes Winter 2012 p8
sugata
Text Box

5.5 Appropriable Rents from Innovation in the Absence of Property Rights 38

We denote by T ∗ the society’s optimal duration of patents. We are not going to actually performthis maximization problem in order to find T ∗. In general, computer simulations can be used to find thewelfare-maximizing T in case differentiation does not lead to an explicit solution, or when the discretenature of the problem (i.e., T is a natural number) does not allow us to differentiate at all. However,one conclusion is easy to find:

Result 5.4The optimal patent life is finite. Formally, T ∗ <∞.

Proof. It is sufficient to show that the welfare level under a one-period patent protection (T = 1)exceeds the welfare level under the infinite patent life (T =∞). The proof is divided into two parts forthe cases where ρ < 0.5 and ρ ≥ 0.5.

First, for ρ < 0.5 when T = 1, xI(1) = a− c. Hence, by (5.9),

W (1) =CS0 + (a− c)2

1− ρ− (a− c)2

21− 2ρ1− ρ

=CS0

1− ρ+

(a− c)2

1− ρ1 + 2ρ

2. (5.10)

When T = +∞, xI(+∞) = a−c1−ρ . Hence, by (5.9),

W (+∞) =CS0

1− ρ+

(a− c)2

(1− ρ)2− (a− c)2

2(1− ρ)2=

CS0

1− ρ+

(a− c)2

2(1− ρ)2. (5.11)

A comparison of (5.10) with (5.11) yields that

W (1) > W (∞)⇐⇒ (a− c)2

1− ρ1 + 2ρ

2>

(a− c)2

2(1− ρ)2⇐⇒ ρ < 0.5. (5.12)

Second, for ρ ≥ 0.5 we approximate T as a continuous variable. Differentiating (5.9) with respectto T and equating to zero yields

T ∗ =ln[3 +

√6 + ρ2 − 6ρ− ρ]− ln(3)

ln(ρ)<∞.

Now, instead of verifying the second-order condition, observe that for T = 1, dW (1)/dT = [(a −c)2ρ(1− 5ρ) ln(ρ)]/[2(1− ρ)2] > 0 for ρ > 0.2.

5.5 Appropriable Rents from Innovation in the Absence of Property Rights

Following Anton an Yao (AER, 1994), we show that

• Even without patent law, a non-reproducible innovation can provide with a substantial amount ofprofit.

• This holds true also for innovators with no assets (poor innovators).

The model

• One innovator, financially broke

• πM profit level if only one firm gets the innovation

• πD profit level to each firm if two firms get the innovation

(Downloaded from www.ozshy.com) (draft=gradio21.tex 2007/12/11 12:19)

sugata
Text Box
608: Economics of Regulation Lecture Notes Winter 2012 p9
sugata
Text Box

5.5 Appropriable Rents from Innovation in the Absence of Property Rights 39

• Innovator reveals the innovation one firm

• then, the informed firm offers a take-it-or-leave-it contract R = (RM , RD) = payment to innovatorin case innovator does not reveal to a second firm (RM ), or he does reveal (RD).

• Innovator approaches another firm and asks for a take-it-or-leave-it offer before revealing the innova-tion

• Innovator accepts/rejects the new contract

j�

•Innovator approaches firm 1Approaches firm 2

?

Firm 1 offers contract

R = (RM , RD)

j

Does not approachfirm 2

Innovator approaches firm 2

?Firm 2 offers contract S

SπI = RM

π1 = πM −RMz πI = RM

π1 = πM −RM

Innovator rejects

9

Accepts

πI = RD + S

π2 = πD − Sπ1 = πD −RD

Figure 5.4: Sequence of moves: An innovator extracting rents from firms

Will the innovator reveal to a second firm?

Suppose that innovator already has a contract from firm 1, R = (RM , RD).

Without revealing, innovator will accept a second contract, S from firm 2 if

RD + S > RM

Hence, firm 2 will offer a take-it-or-leave-it contact of S = RM −RD + ε.

Firm 2 will offer a contract S if π2 = πD − S > 0, or S < πD.

Firm 1’s optimal contract offering

Hence, firm 1 will set contract R to satisfy RM − RD ≥ πD > S to ensure rejection. Hence, firm 1maximizes profit by offering R = (RM , RD) = (πD, 0).

(Downloaded from www.ozshy.com) (draft=gradio21.tex 2007/12/11 12:19)

sugata
Text Box
608: Economics of Regulation Lecture Notes Winter 2012 p10
sugata
Text Box