thinking about the rise and decline of nations

Upload: selva-tor

Post on 05-Apr-2018

223 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    1/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 1

    Thinking about the Rise and Decline of Nations

    Daron Acemoglu

    June 2005

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    2/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 2

    Introduction

    Many scholars have noted a pattern of rise and decline;

    previously advanced civilizations collapse, while others prosper.

    Prominent examples include:

    The declines of the Roman Empire, the Egyptian empire,

    the Chinese Empire in the ancient times.

    The decline of Venice and Genoa and the rise of Englandand the Dutch Republic (and then the decline of the Dutch

    Republic).

    The decline of Inca and Aztec empires and the rise of the

    civilizations in North America in the New World.

    Existing theories:

    Building up of social rigidities (Olson).

    Military over-expansion (Kennedy).

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    3/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 3

    This Talk

    A different perspective on the rise and decline.

    Main idea: institutions appropriate (or only marginally costly)

    under certain circumstances become more costly later.

    Thus a theory of interactions between institutions and

    economic opportunities.

    Indirectly about:

    the costs and benefits of the different economic (political)

    systems?

    the potential for change and flexibility within given

    institutional environments.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    4/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 4

    Plan of Talk Two examples of rise and decline.

    Caribbean versus Northeast America (within a broader

    reversal of fortune among former European colonies).

    Venice and Spain versus England and the Dutch Republic. A Model of oligarchy versus democracy.

    Key trade-off between protecting the property rights of

    incumbents versus creating a level playing field for

    non-incumbents.

    Dynamic distortion of oligarchy.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    5/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 5

    The Reversal of Fortune

    Use of urbanization and density of population before European

    colonization as a proxy for income per capita and how

    advanced pre-colonial civilizations are.

    Robust negative relationship between income today and

    urbanization in 1500 among the former colonies.

    Robust negative relationship between income today and log

    population density in 1500.

    Not due to any geographic variable, or identity of colonial

    power.

    When urbanization and population density both included,

    population density is the main determinant.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    6/60

    LogGDP

    percapita,

    PP

    P,

    1995

    7

    8

    9

    10

    ARG

    AUS

    BGD

    BLZ

    BOL

    BRA

    CAN

    CHL

    COL CRI

    DOM DZAECU

    EGY

    GTM

    GUY

    HKG

    HND

    HTI

    IDN

    IND

    JAM

    LAO

    LKA

    MEXMYS

    NIC

    NZL

    PAK

    PAN

    PER

    PHL

    PRY

    SGP

    SLV

    TUN

    URY

    USA

    VEN

    VNM

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    7/60

    LogGDP

    percapita,

    PPP,

    1995

    6

    7

    8

    9

    10

    AGO

    ARG

    AUS

    BEN

    BFA B

    BHS

    BLZ

    BOL

    BRA

    BRB

    BWA

    CAF

    CAN

    CHL

    CIVCMRCOG

    COL

    COM

    CPV

    CRI

    DMADOMDZA

    ECU

    ERI

    ETH

    GAB

    GHAGIN

    GMB

    GRDGTM

    GUY

    HKG

    HND

    HTI

    IDN

    I

    JAM

    KEN

    KNA

    LAO

    LCA

    LKA

    LSO

    MAR

    MDG

    MEX

    MLIMOZ

    MRT

    MWI

    MYS

    NAM

    NERNGA

    NIC

    NPL

    NZL

    P

    PAN

    PER

    PHLPRY

    R

    SDN

    SEN

    SGP

    SLE

    SLVSUR

    SWZ

    TCD

    TGO

    TTO

    TUN

    TZA

    UGA

    URY

    USA

    VCT

    VEN

    VNM

    ZAF

    ZARZMB

    ZWE

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    8/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 6

    The Timing and Nature of the Reversal

    When did the reversal take place?

    Not when the Europeans plundered the previously rich

    societies or killed of their populations.

    In the 19th century, and intimately related to industrialization.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    9/60

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    90

    100

    Urbanization(%)

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    10/60

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    350

    400

    n

    dustrialProduction

    percapita

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    11/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 7

    Plantation Versus Industrialization

    Specific example of the nature ande timing of the reversal:

    The Caribbean Plantation societies in the 17th and 18th

    centuries initially prosperous, but then falling behind

    Northeastern United States.

    Caribbean plantation societies rich from sugar. Highly

    oligarchic societies, dominated by the richest plantationowners. Supported by repressive political institutions.

    Relatively efficient for production and processing of sugar for

    the plantation owners. But no room for change.

    In contrast, the more democratic Northeast United States,

    more flexible to take advantage of new economic opportunities.

    In fact, 19th century growth in the U.S., fueled by industry and

    entrepreneurs not previously part of the ruling elite.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    12/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 8

    Institutions and Industrialization

    Whether a society has institutions of private property or

    extractive institutions may matter much more when new

    technologies require broad-based economic participation.

    Industrialization is such a process, requiring investments from

    a large number of agents who were not previously part of the

    ruling elite.

    Therefore, there are natural reasons to expect that institutional

    differences will matter much more during the age of industry.

    We find that there is a strong interaction between institutions

    and industrialization: institutions start mattering much more

    in the age of industry.

    This explains why the reversal took place during the 19th

    century.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    13/60

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    14/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 9

    Rise of Europe

    Western Europe grows faster than Eastern Europe and Asia

    after 1500 using either urbanization rates as proxy for income

    or Maddisons estimates for GDP.

    When we break things out into Atlantic vs. non-Atlantic

    Western Europe, almost all of the faster growth is driven by

    growth in Atlantic nations (Belgium, Britain, Denmark,

    France, Ireland, the Netherlands, Portugal and Spain).

    Same pattern when we look at city growth.

    The timing of takeoff of various Atlantic ports consistent with

    timing of involvement in Atlantic trade by individual countries.

    Among Atlantic countries, early growth in Spain and Portugal,

    but short lived. Major growth in Britain and Dutch Rep.

    Related to institutional change in Britain and Dutch Rep.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    15/60

    Urbanization rates

    weighted by population

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    16/60

    Urbanization rates

    weighted by population

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800

    A l i d W E A l i d E

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    17/60

    GDP per capita from 1500

    weighted by population

    0

    500

    1000

    1500

    2000

    2500

    1500 1600 1700 1820

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    18/60

    GDP per capita from 1500

    weighted by population

    0

    500

    1000

    1500

    2000

    2500

    1500 1600 1700 1820 1

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    19/60

    Average of log population in Iberian Atlantic ports and other cities

    (balanced panel)

    0

    0. 5

    1

    1.5

    2

    2. 5

    3

    3. 5

    4

    4. 5

    5

    13 0 0 14 0 0 15 0 0 16 0 0 17 0 0 17 5 0

    Iberian cities, not Atlantic ports

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    20/60

    Average of log population in British Atlantic ports and other cities

    (balanced panel)

    0

    1

    2

    3

    4

    5

    6

    1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800

    British cities not Atlantic ports

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    21/60

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    22/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 10

    Interpretation

    Caribbean plantation economies did well initially because they

    provided the right incentives to the major asset holders insociety.

    Similar to Venice in the 15th century or even to Spain after the

    discovery of the New World.

    But long-run growth requires a process of creativedestruction with new entrance and new blood coming in.

    Difficult when the regime dominated by incumbents.

    Thus industrialization more likely in Northeast United States.

    Also, institutional change supporting sustained economic

    growth more likely in places where incumbents weaker;

    institutional change in England and the Dutch Republic but

    not in Spain.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    23/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 11

    Ingredients of Model Construct a simple theoretical model to emphasize and clarify

    the trade-offs.

    Consider an economy where agents enter entrepreneurship or

    production work.

    Heterogeneity in entrepreneurship.

    Entrepreneurial talent imperfectly correlated over time.

    Two types of policy distortion:

    Redistributive taxation with incentive costs.

    Entry barriers protecting incumbents.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    24/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 12

    Trade-off Between Oligarchy and Democracy

    Entry in democracy, sclerosis in oligarchy.

    Lower investment in democracy.

    Worse allocation of talent in oligarchy.

    Democracy more equal, oligarchy more unequal (lower wages

    higher profits).

    Oligarchy gets worse over time as the comparative advantage of

    incumbents gets worse.

    Oligarchy and democracy creating different types of distortions.

    But long-run growth may be slower in oligarchy because of

    dynamic costs of entry barriers.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    25/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 13

    Understanding Rise and Decline of Nations

    oligarchy less harmful initially, even encouraging investment

    because less redistribution away from major producers.

    but harmful as comparative advantage of oligarchs disappears.

    oligarchy particularly harmful when new technologies shift

    investment opportunities from insiders to newcomers.

    oligarchy less flexible than democracy

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    26/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 14

    Regime Dynamics When does oligarchy transition to democracy?

    Two possibilities:

    1. Smooth transition to democracy because of within-elite

    conflict (small producers disbanding oligarchy).

    2. Conflict over regimes.

    Incumbents richer, can maintain the system that serve

    their interests.

    Path dependence in equilibrium regimes possible.

    Caribbean vs. United States in the 18th and 19thcenturies.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    27/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 15

    Model

    Infinite horizon economy, with the unique non-storable good, y.

    Preferences

    Uj0 = E0t=0

    tcjt , (1)

    Assume each agent dies with a small probability , consider the

    limit of this economy with 0.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    28/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 16

    Model (continued)

    Choice between entrepreneurship and production work.

    Entrepreneurial talent ajt {AL, AH} with AL < AH.

    Either already own an active firm, or set it up (costly when

    there are entry barriers).

    Each agent starts period t with entrepreneurial talent

    ajt {AH, AL}, and sjt {0, 1} which denotes the individual

    possesses an active firm.

    Agent with sjt = 1 member of the elite.

    Each agent takes the following decisions: cjt , ejt {0, 1}.

    If ejt = 1, then he also makes investment, employment, and

    hiding decisions, kjt , ljt and h

    jt , where h

    jt denotes whether he

    decides to hide his output in order to avoid taxation.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    29/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 17

    Model (continued)

    Three policy choices: a tax rate t on firms, lump-sum transfer,

    Tt, and a cost Bt to set up a new firm (pure waste).

    Production function for talent ajt :

    11

    (ajt)(kjt )

    1(ljt ),

    To simplify assume that ljt = , and that entrepreneur himself

    can work in his firm as one of the workers.

    Denote: bt Bt/.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    30/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 18

    Model (continued)

    Denote the wage rate by wt 0.

    Profit function (without hiding):

    t, kjt , a

    jt , wt

    =

    1 t1

    (ajt)(kjt )

    1(ljt ) wtl

    jt k

    jt , (2)

    With hiding:

    t, kjt , ajt , wt

    = 1 1

    (ajt )(kjt )1(ljt ) wtljt kjt.

    Thus

    t ,

    Labor market clearing: 10 ejtdj = jSEt dj 1, where SEt isthe set of entrepreneurs at time t.

    For agents with sjt = 0, setting up a new firm may entail an

    additional cost Bt because of entry barriers.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    31/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 19

    Model (continued)

    Law of motion of individual states:

    sjt+1 = ijt , (3)

    ajt+1 =

    AH with probability H if ajt = A

    H

    AH with probability L if ajt = A

    L

    AL with probability 1 H if ajt = AH

    AL with probability 1 L if ajt = A

    L

    , (4)

    Stationary distribution fraction of high-productivity agents:

    M L

    1 H + L

    .

    Assume

    M > 1,

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    32/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 20

    Model (continued)

    Timing of events:

    1. Entrepreneurial talents,

    ajt

    , are realized.

    2. The entry barrier for new entrepreneurs Bt is set.

    3. Agents make occupational choices, ejt.

    4. Entrepreneurs make investment decisions kjt .

    5. The labor market clearing wage rate, wt, is determined.

    6. The tax rate on entrepreneurs, t, is set.

    7. Entrepreneurs make hiding decisions, hjt.

    where

    ajt

    shorthand for the mapping at : [0, 1]

    AL, AH

    ,

    etc.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    33/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 21

    Analysis

    Economic equilibrium: subgame perfect equilibrium given apolicy sequence {bt, t}t=0,1,....

    Equilibrium investments:

    kjt = (1 t)1/ajt. (5)

    t, wt | sjt , a

    jt

    =

    1 (1 t)

    1/ajt wt. (6)

    Tax revenues:

    Tt = t (1 t)1

    1

    jSE

    t

    ajt , (7)

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    34/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 22

    Analysis (continued)

    Who will become an entrepreneur?

    1. Entry equilibrium where all entrepreneurs have ajt = AH.

    2. Sclerotic equilibrium where agents with sjt = 1 become

    entrepreneurs irrespective of their productivity.

    An entry equilibrium will emerge only if the net gain to a

    high-skill non-entrepreneur of incurring the entry cost and

    setting up a firm (at a given wage) is positive.

    This net gain takes into account the future benefit of becoming

    an elite protected from competition (as a function of future

    entry barriers etc.). Determined by simple dynamic programming taking

    equilibrium policies as given.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    35/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 23

    Analysis (continued)

    Let the value function of a worker of type z as a function of the

    sequence of future policies and equilibrium wages, (pt,wt):

    Wz

    pt,wt

    = wt + Tt + C Wz

    pt+1,wt+1

    , (8)

    where the continuation values from time t + 1 onwards are:

    CWz pt+1,wt+1 =z max

    WH

    pt+1,wt+1

    , VH

    pt+1,wt+1

    bt+1

    (9)

    + (1 z)max

    WL

    pt+1,wt+1

    , VL

    pt+1,wt+1

    bt+1

    .

    These incorporate optimal occupational choice from time t+1

    onwards.

    Similarly, for a current entrepreneur

    Vz

    pt,wt

    = wt + Tt + z (t, wt) + C V

    z

    pt+1,wt+1

    , (10)

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    36/60

    wt LS

    LD

    wtL

    wtH

    wtH+bt

    wtL-bt

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    37/60

    wt LS

    LD

    wtH+bt

    wtL

    wtL-bt

    wtH

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    38/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 24

    Analysis (continued)

    Define the net value of entrepreneurship as a function of an

    individuals skill a and ownership status, s,

    N V

    pt, wt | Az, s

    = Vz

    pt,wt

    Wz

    pt,wt

    (1 s) bt,

    where the last term is the entry cost for agents with s =0.

    N V pt, wt | AH, sjt

    = 1 N V pt, wt | ajt

    , sand

    N V

    pt, wt | ajt , s

    NV

    pt, wt | AL, sjt = 0

    .

    Therefore, high-skill incumbents remain entrepreneurs and

    low-productivity workers never become entrepreneurs.

    Whether low-productivity incumbents remain entrepreneurs

    depends on taxes, wages and entry barriers.

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    39/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 25

    Analysis (continued)

    Define entry equilibrium wage such that

    N V

    pt,

    wHt , wt+1

    | ajt = AH, sjt = 0

    = 0.

    So

    wHt

    1 (1 t)

    1/AH bt

    +

    CVHpt+1,wt+1 CWHpt+1,wt+1 ,

    Similarly, sclerotic wage is

    wLt

    1 (1 t)

    1/AL

    +

    CVL pt+1,wt+1 CWL pt+1,wt+1 .

    An entry equilibrium only when

    wHt wLt . (11)

    d l f N

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    40/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 26

    Analysis (continued)

    Therefore, in equilibrium wet = wHt .

    Define fraction of high-productivity entrepreneurs:

    t = Pr

    ajt = AH | ejt = 1

    = Pr

    ajt = A

    H |j SEt

    Since no entry barriers initially, 0 = 1.

    Law of motion of t:

    t = Ht1 + L(1 t1) if (11) does not hold1 if (11) holds . (12)

    Ri d D li f N i 27

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    41/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 27

    Political Equilibrium

    Consider two simple extreme political regimes:

    1. Democracy: the policies bt and t are determined by

    majoritarian voting, with each agent having one vote.

    2. Oligarchy (elite control): the policies bt and t are

    determined by majoritarian voting among the elite at time t.

    Focus on Markov perfect equilibria.

    Ri d D li f N ti 28

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    42/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 28

    Democracy

    Non-elites in the majority.

    Majoritarian voting: taxes will be chosen to maximize per

    capita transfers,

    Tt (bt, t) =

    t(1t)1

    1

    jSE

    t

    ajt if t

    0 if t >

    , (13)

    where t is the tax rate expected by the entrepreneurs and t is

    the actual tax rate set by voters.

    Since 0 profits, entry barriers will be chosen to maximize

    equilibrium wages, thus bt = 0. Intuitively, entry barriers reduce labor demand and depress

    wages.

    Ri d D li f N ti 29

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    43/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 29

    Democracy (continued)

    Proposition 1 A democratic equilibrium always features t =

    and bt = 0, and ejt = 1 if and only if a

    jt = A

    H, and t = 1. The

    equilibrium wage rate is given by

    wDt =

    1 (1 )1/AH,

    and the aggregate output is

    YDt = YD

    1

    1 (1 )

    1

    AH. (14)

    Perfect equality.

    Ri d D li f N ti 30

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    44/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 30

    Oligarchy

    Policies determined by majoritarian voting among the elite.

    To simplify this talk, assume

    12

    AH

    AL+ 1

    2, (15)

    which ensures that low and high-skill elites prefer low taxes.

    Otherwise, low-skill elites side with the workers to tax the

    high-skilled elites.

    Rise and Decline of Nations 31

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    45/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 31

    Oligarchy (continued)

    Then entry barriers will be set

    bt bEt

    AH

    1 +

    CVH

    pt+1,wt+1

    CWH

    pt+1,wt+1

    .

    (16)

    so as to prevent entry.

    Imposing wet+n = 0 for all n 0,

    VL =1

    1

    1

    1 H

    AL + LAH

    (1 (H L))

    , (17)

    and

    VH =1

    1

    1

    1

    1 L

    AH +

    1 H

    AL

    (1 (H L))

    .

    (18)

    Rise and Decline of Nations 32

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    46/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 32

    Oligarchy (continued)

    Using these equilibrium relationships,

    bt = bE

    1

    1

    1

    1

    1 L

    AH +

    1 H

    AL

    (1 (H L))

    .

    (19)

    Wages are zero and aggregate output is

    YEt = t1

    1 AH + (1 t)

    1

    1 AL (20)

    where

    t = Ht1 + L(1 t1)

    with

    limt

    YEt = YE

    1

    1

    AL + M(AH AL)

    . (21)

    Rise and Decline of Nations 33

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    47/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 33

    Oligarchy (continued)

    Proposition 2 Suppose that condition (15) holds. Then an

    oligarchic equilibrium features t = 0 and bt = bE as given by (19),

    and the equilibrium is sclerotic, with equilibrium wages w

    e

    t = 0,and fraction of high-skill entrepreneurs

    t = Ht1 +

    L(1 t1) starting with 0 = 1. Aggregate

    output is given by (20) and decreases over time starting at

    YE0 =1

    1AH with limt Y

    Et = Y

    E

    as given by (21).

    Rise and Decline of Nations 34

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    48/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 34

    Comparison of Oligarchy and Democracy

    We always have that initially:

    1

    1 (1 )

    1

    AH < YE0 =1

    1 AH.

    Will oligarchy fall behind democracy?

    If (1) democratic taxes are low and not very distortionary;(2) selection of entrepreneurs is difficult, and (3)

    comparative advantage in entrepreneurship is important,

    then oligarchy ultimately worse than democracy:

    Condition for this:

    (1 )1

    > AL

    AH+ M

    1 A

    L

    AH

    . (22)

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    49/60

    Output

    Output

    Output

    YD

    YE

    YE0

    YE

    Yt

    Rise and Decline of Nations 35

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    50/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 35

    Comparison of Oligarchy and Democracy(continued)

    Workers always worse off in oligarchy than in democracy.

    What about entrepreneurs?

    High-skill entrepreneurs always better off. But

    Proposition 3 If

    1 H

    AL/AH + L

    (1 (H L)) 0 a new technology arrives.

    Productivity with new technology:

    1

    1 (ajt)

    (kjt )1(ljt )

    ,

    where > 1

    Law of motion of ajt orthogonal to ajt , and given by

    a

    j

    t+1 =

    AH with probability H if ajt = A

    H

    AH with probability L if ajt = A

    L

    AL with probability 1 H if ajt = AH

    AL with probability 1 L if ajt = A

    L

    , (24)

    Rise and Decline of Nations 37

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    52/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 37

    New Technologies (continued)

    In democracy, aggregate output jumps from YD to

    YD 1

    1 (1 )

    1

    AH.

    In oligarchy, elites will stay in entrepreneurship despite their

    worse comparative advantage

    For example, if AL > AH, then aggregate output jumps to

    and remains at

    YE 1

    1 AL + M(AH AL)

    ,

    Potential explanation for why oligarchic societies dont adjust

    well to new opportunities/technologies.

    Rise and Decline of Nations 38

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    53/60

    Rise and Decline of Nations 38

    Regime Dynamics

    Two cases to consider:

    1. Conflict within the elitewhen low-skill elites worse off in

    oligarchy than in democracy (when condition (23) holds),

    they disband oligarchy when they become the majoritywithin the elite.

    2. Conflict between classes over regimesthe elite prefer

    oligarchy and the citizens democracy; income distribution

    matters for regime dynamics; possibility of path dependence.

    Rise and Decline of Nations 39

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    54/60

    Regime Dynamics (continued)

    Suppose that, in oligarchy, current elite can legislate apermanent transition to democracy. Then

    Proposition 4 Suppose (15) holds and the society starts

    oligarchic.

    If (23) does not hold, then for all t the society remains

    oligarchic.

    If (23) holds, then the society remains oligarchic until date

    t = t where t = min t N such that t 1/2 (whereby

    t = Ht1 +

    L(1 t1) for t < t starting with 0 = 1).

    At t, the society transitions to democracy.

    The low-skill elites disband the oligarchy when they become

    the majority.

    Rise and Decline of Nations 40

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    55/60

    Conflict over Regimes Different set of issues arise when no smooth transition to

    democracy.

    Under many plausible scenarios, wealth influences political

    power. Consider a reduced-form model of this.

    Suppose that the probability that an oligarchy switches to

    democracy is qDt = qD (Wt1), where Wt1 = W

    Et1 W

    Wt1

    is the difference between the levels of wealth of the elite and

    the citizens at time t 1.

    Assume qD () decreasing.

    Rise and Decline of Nations 41

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    56/60

    Conflict over Regimes

    Similarly, when democratic, a society becomes oligarchic with

    probability

    qOt = qO (Wt1)

    where now qO () is a non-decreasing function, with qO (0) = 0,so that with perfect equality, there is no danger of switching

    back to oligarchy.

    Here Wt refers to the income gap between the initial elite

    (those with with sj1 = 1) and the citizens.

    Rise and Decline of Nations 42

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    57/60

    Conflict over Regimes (continued)

    Then regime dynamics are:

    Dt =

    0 with probability 1 qD (Wt1) if Dt1 = 0

    1 with probability qD (Wt1) if Dt1 = 0

    0 with probability qO (Wt1) if Dt1 = 1

    1 with probability 1 qO (Wt1) if Dt1 = 1

    ,

    (25)

    Suppose that each agent saves out of current income at a

    constant (exogenous) rate < 1.

    ThereforeWt =

    Wt1 + Y

    Et1

    .

    Rise and Decline of Nations 43

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    58/60

    Conflict over Regimes (continued)

    This implies that in oligarchy

    Wt

    = t

    n=1

    nYEt

    n(26)

    and

    limt

    Wt = W YE

    1 , (27)

    where YE

    is given by (21).

    Rise and Decline of Nations 44

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    59/60

    Conflict over Regimes (continued)

    This implies that starting from low wealth levels, wealth

    inequality will increase in oligarchy.

    Therefore, transition from oligarchy to democracy may become

    harder as oligarchy persists.

    In particular, if there exists W < W such that

    qD

    W

    = 0, then after a certain number of periods, thesociety will be stuck in oligarchy.

    In contrast, in democracy, all agents earn the same amount, so

    when Dt+k = 1 for all k 0,

    Wt+1 = Wt and limt

    Wt = 0. (28)

    The implication is that a switch back to oligarchy is most likely

    soon after a switch from oligarchy to democracy.

    Rise and Decline of Nations 45

  • 8/2/2019 Thinking About the Rise and Decline of Nations

    60/60

    Shortcomings and Future Directions

    No managerial delegation. In practice, it may be possible to

    remain a member of the elites while delegating control of firms

    to high-skill agents.

    Entry barriers do not generate direct revenue. If they did, theoligarchy may want to allow some entry while democracy may

    also want to use entry barriers.

    Develop less reduced-form models of why wealth may influence

    political power.