the promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research

Upload: jose-luis-barragan

Post on 01-Jun-2018

226 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/9/2019 The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

    1/11

    ^ cademy oi Managem ent Review

    2000,

      Vol. 25, No. 1, 217-22G.

    NOTE

    THE PROMISE OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP AS A

    . FIELD OF RESEARCH

    SCOTT SHANE

    University of Maryland

    S. VENKATARAMAN

    tiniversity of Virginia

    To date the phenom enon of entrepreneurship ha s lacked a conceptual framework. In

    this note we draw upon previous research conducted in the different social science

    disciplines and applied fields of business to create a conceptual framework for the

    field. With this framework we explain a set of empirical phenomena and predict a set

    of outcomes not explained or predicted by conceptual frameworks already in exis-

    tence in other fields.

    For a field of social science to have useful-

    n ess ,

      i t must have a conceptual framework that

    explains and predicts a set of empirical phe-

    nomena not explained or predicted by concep-

    tual frameworks already in existence in other

    fields. To date, the phenomenon of entrepre-

    neurship has lacked such a conceptual f rame-

    work. Rather than explaining and predicting a

    unique set of empirical phenomena, enfrepre-

    n urs ip

      ha s becom e a broad label under which

    a hodgepodge of research is housed. What ap-

    pears to const i tu te entrepreneurship research

    today is some aspect of the setting (e.g., small

    businesses or new firms), rather than a unique

    conceptual domain. As a result, many people

    ha ve h ad troub le identifying the distinctive con-

    tribution of the field to the broader domain of

    bu sin ess stud ies, underm ining the field s legit-

    imacy. Researchers in other fields ask why en-

    trepreneurship research is necessary if it does

    not explain or predict empirical phenomena be-

    yond what is known from work in other fields.

    Moreover, the lack of a conceptual framework

    has precluded the development of an under-

    standing of many important phenomena not ad-

    equately explained by other fields.

    One example of this problem is the focus in

    the entrepreneurship l i terature on the relat ive

    We acknowledge the helpful comments of Ed Roberts on

    performance of individuals or firms in the con

    text of small or new businesses. Since strategi

    management scholars examine the difference

    in and s ustain ability of relative performance be

    tween competitive firms, this approach is no

    un iqu e (Ve nkataram an, 1997). Moreover, the ap

    proach does not provide an adequate test o

    en t r ep ren eu r sh ip , s in ce en t r ep ren eu r sh ip

    concerned with the discovery and exploitatio

    of profitable op portu nities. A perform ance ad

    va nt ag e over other firms is not a sufficient me a

    sure of entrepreneurial performance, because

     

    performance advantage may be insufficient t

    compensate for the opportunity cost of other a

    ternatives , a liquidity prem ium for time and cap

    ital,

      and a premium for uncertainty bearin

    Therefore, although a conceptual framework

    explain and predict relative performance b

    tween firms is useful to strategic managemen

    it is not sufficient for entrepreneurship.

    We attempt an integrating framework for th

    entrepreneurship field in the form of this not

    We believe that this framework will help entr

    preneurship researchers recognize the relatio

    ship among the multitude of necessary, but n

    sufficient, factors that compose entrepreneu

    ship, and thereby advance the quality of empi

    ical and theoretical work in the field. By provi

    ing a f ramework that both sheds l ight o

    u n e x p l a i n e d p h e n o m e n a a n d e n h a n c e s t h

  • 8/9/2019 The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

    2/11

    218

    Academy ol Management Review

    Januar

    tion as only a rese arch setting or teaching

    applicat ion.

    The note proceeds as follows. First, we define

    the domain of the field. Second, we explain why

    organizat ional researchers should study entre-

    preneurship. Third , we descr ibe why entrepre-

    neurial opportunities exist and why some peo-

    ple,  and not others, discover and exploit those

    opportunities. Fourth, we consider the different

    modes of exploitation of entrepreneurial oppor-

    tunities. Finally, we conclude with brief reflec-

    tions on the potential value of the framework

    presented here.

      EFINITION OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP

    Perhaps the largest obstacle in creating a con-

    cep tua l f ramework fo r the en t repreneursh ip

    field has been its definition. To date, most re-

    searchers have defined the field

      solely

      in terms

    of who the entrepreneur is and what he or she

    doe s (Ve nka taram an, 1997). The problem with

    this approach is that entrepreneurship involves

    the nexus of two phenomena: the presence of

    lucrative opportunities and the presence of en-

    terp risin g ind ivi du als (V enk ataram an, 1997). By

    defining the field in terms of the individual

    alone, entrepreneurship researchers have gen-

    erated incomplete definitions that do not with-

    stand the scrutiny of other scholars (Gartner,

    1988).

    The definition of an entrepreneur as a person

    who establis hes a new o rganizat ion is an exam-

    ple of this problem. Because this definition does

    not include consideration of the variation in the

    quality of opportunities that different people

    identify, it leads researchers to neglect to mea-

    sure oppor tun i t ies . Consequent ly , empir ica l

    support (or lack of support) for attributes that

    differentiate entrepreneurs from other members

    of society is often questionable, because these

    attributes confound the influence of opportuni-

    t ies and individuals.

    In contrast to previous rese arch, w e define the

    field of entrepreneurship as the scholarly exam-

    inatio n of how, by whom, and w ith wha t effects

    opportunities to create future goods and ser-

    vices are discovered, evaluated, and exploited

    (Ve nkata ram an, 1997). Co nseq uen tly, the field

    involves the study of

      sources

      of opportunities;

    ploitation of opportunities; and the set of

      indi

    viduals  who discover , ev alu ate , an d explo

    th em.

    Although the phenomenon of entrepreneur

    ship provides research questions for many dif

    ferent scholarly fields, ' organization scholar

    are fundam entally concerned w ith three sets o

    r e sea r ch q u es t io n s ab o u t en t r ep ren eu r sh ip

    (1) why, when , and how o ppo rtun ities for th

    creation of goods and services come into exis

    tence; (2) why, when, an d how some p eople an

    not others discover and exploit these opportuni

    t ies; an d (3) why, whe n, and how different mo de

    of action are used to exploit entrepreneurial op

    portunities.

    Before reviewing existing research to answe

    these quest ions, we provide several caveat

    about our approach. First, we take a disequilib

    rium approach, which differs from equilibrium

    approaches in economics (Khilstrom & Laffon

    1979) and social psychology (McClelland, 1961

    In equilibrium models, entrepreneurial opportu

    nities either do not exist or are assumed to b

    randomly distributed across the population. Be

    cause people in equilibrium models cannot dis

    cover opportunities that differ in value from

    those discovered by others, who becomes a

    entrepreneur in these m odels depen ds solely o

    th e a t t r ib u te s o f p eo p le . Fo r ex amp le , i

    Khilstrom and Laffont 's (1979) equil ibr ium

    model, entrepreneurs are people who prefer un

    certainty.

    Although we believe that some dimensions o

    equilibrium models are useful for understand

    ing entrepreneurship, w e argue that these mod

    els are necessar i ly incomplete . Entrepreneuria

    behavior is transitory (Carroll & Mosakow sk

    1987).

     Moreover, estimates of the number of pe

    p le who eng age in en t reprene ur ia l behav io

    ra ng e from 20 perc ent of the pop ulatio n (Reyn

    olds  White, 1997) to over 50 percent (Aldrich

    Zimmer, 1986). Since a la rge an d div erse grou

    of people engage in the transitory process o

    entrepreneurship, it is improbable that entrepre

    neu rship ca n be explain ed solely by reference

    a cha racteristic of certain peo ple ind epen dent o

    the situations in which they find themselve

    Therefore, when we argue that some people an

      For example, economists are interested in the distrib

    tion of entrepreneurial talent across productive and unpr

  • 8/9/2019 The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

    3/11

    Shane and Venia taraman

    21

    not others engage in entrepreneurial behavior ,

    we are describing the tendency of certain peo-

    ple to respond to the situational cues of oppor-

    tunities—not a stable characteristic that differ-

    entiates some people f rom others across al l

    situations.^

    Second, we argue that entrepreneurship does

    not require, but can include, the creation of new

    organizations. As Amit, Glosten, and Mueller

    (1993) and Casson (1982) explain, entrepreneur-

    ship can also occur within an existing organiza-

    tion. Moreover, opportunities can be sold to

    other ind ividu als or to existing o rganization s. In

    this note we do not exam ine th e creation of new

    organizations per se but, rather, refer interested

    readers to excellent reviews on firm creation in

    org ani zat ion al ecology (Aldrich, 1990; Singh &

    Lu m sd en , 1990), ec on om ics (C av es, 1998;

    Ge roski, 1995), an d o rga niz atio nal theory (Gart-

    ner, 1985; Katz & Gar tne r, 1988; Low & MacMil-

    lan, 1988).^

    Third, our framework complements sociologi-

    cal and economic work in which researchers

    have examined the population-level factors that

    influence firm creation. Stinchcombe (1965) iden-

    tified societal factors that enhance incentives to

    organize and organizing ability. Aldrich (1990)

    and Singh and Lumsden (1990) have provided

    review s of factors en ha nci ng firm foundings and

    have described the effects of such factors as

    environmental carrying capacity, interpopula-

    tion processes, and institutional factors. Simi-

    larly, Baumol (1996) has related the institutional

    environment to the supply of people who are

    willing to create firms.

    Although these other frameworks are valu-

    able to entrepreneurship scholars, they involve

    a set of issues different from those with which

    we are concerned. Our framework differs from

    the se in that (1) w e focus on the existen ce, dis-

    covery, and exploitation of opportunities; (2) we

    examine the influence of individuals and oppor-

    tunit ies, rather than environmental antecedents

    an d con sequ enc es; and (3) we consider a frame-

    work broader than firm creation.

      We also argu e that entrepreneurship can be undertaken

    by a single individual or a set of people who undertake the

    steps of the process collectively or independently.

      Many researchers argue that entrepreneurship occurs

    Fourth, our framework also complements re

    sea rch on the p roc ess of firm crea tion (e.g., Gart

    ne r, 1985; Katz & G ar tn er , 1988; Katz, 1993). Ex

    plaining this process is important, but researc

    on it involves examining a different set of issue

    from those we explore. Firm creation proces

    researchers examine resource mobilization, firm

    organizing, and market making, starting wit

    the assumption that opportunities exist, hav

    been discovered, and will be exploited throug

    the creation of new firms. Since we lack th

    space to review both the processes of entrepre

    n e u r s h i p t h r o u g h m a r k e t m e c h a n i s m s a n

    through firm creation, we limit our discussion t

    the conditions under which entrepreneurial op

    portunities are exploited through firms and mar

    kets, and we refer readers to these other frame

    works for information on the process of firm

    creation.

    WHY STUDY ENTREPRENEURSHIP?

    Many scholars ask, either implicitly or explic

    itly, why anyone should study entrepreneurship

    Data are difficult to obtain, theory is underde

    veloped, and many f indings to date are th

    same as those obtained in other areas of bus

    ness. In response, we offer three reasons fo

    studying the topic. First, much technical info

    mation is ultimately embodied in products an

    services (Arrow,

     1962),

     and e ntreprene urship is

    mechanism by which society converts technic

    information into these products and service

    S e c on d , e n t r e p r e n e u r s h i p i s a m e c h a n i s m

    through which temporal and spatial inefficien

    cies in an economy are discovered and mit

    g at ed (Kirzner, 1997). Fi na lly , of the differen

    sources of ch an ge in a capitalis t society, Schum

    peter (1934) isolated entrepreneurially driven i

    novation in products and processes as the cru

    c i a l e n g i n e d r i v i n g t h e c h a n g e p r o c e s

    Therefore, the abse nce of entrepr ene ursh ip fro

    our collective theories of markets, firms, organ

    zations, and change makes our understandin

    of the business landscape incomplete . As Bau

    mol eloquently remarks, the study of busine

    without an understanding of entrepreneursh

    is like the study of Sh ak esp ear e in which th

    Prince of Denmark has been expunged from th

  • 8/9/2019 The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

    4/11

     

    cademy oi Management

      Review

    Januar

    THE EXISTENCE DISCOV ERY AND

    EXPLOITATION OF ENTREPRENEURIAL

    OPPORTUNITIES

    The Existence of Entrepreneuria l Opportunit ies

    To ha ve entre pren eurs hip, you must first hav e

    entrepreneurial opportunit ies. Entrepreneurial

    opportunities are those situations in which new

    goods, services, raw materials, and organizing

    methods can be introduced and sold at greater

    th an thei r cost of produ ction (C ass on, 1982). Al-

    though recognition of entrepreneurial opportu-

    nities is a subjective process, the opportunities

    themselves are object ive phenomena that are

    not known to all parties at all times. For exam-

    ple,  the discovery of the telephone created new

    opportu nities for comm unication, w hethe r or not

    people discovered those opportunit ies.

    Entrepreneurial opportunities differ from the

    larger set of all opportunities for profit, particu-

    larly opportunities to enhance the efficiency of

    exisfing goods, services, raw materials, and or-

    ganizing methods, because the former require

    the discovery of new me ans-e nds relat ionships,

    whereas the latter involve optimization within

    existing means-ends frameworks (Kirzner, 1997).

    Because the range of options and the conse-

    quences of exploiting new things are unknown,

    e n t r e p r e n e u r i a l d e c i s i o n s c a n n o t b e m a d e

    through an optimization process in which me-

    chanical calculat ions are made in response to a

    given set of alternatives (Baumol, 1993).

    Entrepreneurial opportunities come in a vari-

    ety of forms. Although the focus in most prior

    research has been on opportunities in product

    markets (Venkataraman, 1997) , opportunit ies

    also exist in factor markets, as in the case of the

    discovery of new materials (Schumpeter, 1934).

    Moreover, within product market entrepreneur-

    ship,

      Drucker (1985) has described three different

    categories of opportunities: (1) the creation of

    new information, as occurs with the invention of

    new technologies; (2) the exploitation of market

    inefficiencies that result from information asym-

    metry, as occurs across time and geography;

    an d (3) the reac tion to shifts in the rel ativ e c osts

    an d benefits of altern ative us es for resources, a s

    occurs wi th po l i t ica l , regu la to ry , o r demo-

    graphic changes .

    Previous researchers have argued that entre-

    preneur ia l oppor tun i t ies ex is t p r imar i ly be-

    cause different members of society have differ-

    given the potential to transform them into a dif

    ferent s ta te (Kirzner, 1997). B eca us e pe op le po s

    sess different beliefs (because of a lucky hunch

    superior intuition, or private information), the

    make different conjectures about the price a

    which markets should clear or about what pos

    sible new m arkets could be create d in the future

    When buyers and s ellers hav e different belief

    about the value of resources, both today and i

    the future, goods and services can sell above o

    below their marginal cost of production (Schum

    peter,

      1934).

     An entrepreneurial discovery occu

    when someone makes the conjecture that a se

    of reso urce s is not put to its best use (i.e., th

    reso urce s are price d too low, given a belie

    about the price at which the output from thei

    combination could be sold in another location

    at another time, or in another form). If the con

    jecture is acted upon and is correct, the individ

    ual will earn an entrepreneurial profit. If th

    conjecture is acted upon and is incorrect, th

    individual will incur an entrepreneurial los

    (Casson, 1982).

    Eritrepreneurship requires that people hol

    different beliefs about the value of resources fo

    two reasons. First , entrepreneurship involve

    joint production, where several different re

    sources ha ve to be brought togethe r to crea te th

    new product or service. For the entrepreneur t

    obtain control over thes e resourc es in a way th a

    makes the opportunity profitable, his or her con

    jecture about the accuracy of resource price

    must differ from those of resource owners an

    other po tent ial e ntr ep ren eu rs (Cass on, 1982).

    resource owners had the same conjectures a

    the entrepreneur, they would seek to appropr

    at e the profit from th e opportunity by pricing th

    resources so that the entrepreneur 's profit ap

    proach ed zero. Therefore, for e ntrep rene ursh i

    to occur, the resource owners must not shar

    completely the entrepreneur 's conjectures. Se

    ond, if all people (potential entrepreneurs) po

    sessed the same entrepreneurial conjecture

    they would compete to capture the same entr

    preneurial profit, dividing it to the point that th

    incentive to pursue the opportunity was elim

    nated (Schumpeter, 1934).

    But why should people possess different b

    liefs about the prices at which markets shou

    clear? Two answers have been offered. First,

    Kirzner (1973) has observed, the process of di

    covery in a market setting requires the partic

  • 8/9/2019 The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

    5/11

     

    Shane and VenJcataraman

    22

    wide variety of things. People make decisions

    on the basis of hunches, intuition, heuristics,

    and accurate and inaccurate information, caus-

    ing their decisions to be incorrect some of the

    t ime.

     Since decision s are not alw ay s correct, this

    proc ess lea ds to errors that crea te shorta ges,

    surpluses, and misallocated resources. An indi-

    vidu al alert to the pres enc e of an error may

    buy resou rces wh ere prices are too low, recom-

    bine them, and sell the outputs where prices are

      too high.

    Second, as Schumpeter (1934) explained, econ-

    omies operate in a constant state of disequilib-

    rium. Technological, po litical, social, regulatory,

    and other types of change offer a continuous

    supply of new information about different ways

    to use re source s to en ha nc e wea lth. By making it

    possible to transform resources into a more

    valuable form, the new information alters the

    value of resources and, therefore, the resources'

    proper equ ilibrium price. Becau se information is

    imperfectly distributed, all economic actors do

    not receive new information at the same time.

    Consequently, some people obtain information

    before others about resources lying fallow, new

    discoveries being made, or new markets open-

    ing up. If economic actors obtain new informa-

    tion before others, they can purchase resources

    at below their equilibrium value and earn an

    entrepreneurial profit by recombining the re-

    sources and then sell ing them (Schumpeter ,

    1934).

    The informational sources of opportunity m ay

    be easier to see in the case of new technology,

    but they need not be restricted to technological

    developments. For example, the production of

    the movie  itanic  generated new information

    about who was a desirable teen idol. An entre-

    preneur could respond to this new information

    by acting on the conjecture that posters of Leo-

    nard o DeCap rio would sell for grea ter than their

    cost of production.

    Because entrepreneur ia l oppor tuni t ies de-

    pen d on asym m etries of information a nd beliefs,

    eventual ly , en trepreneur ia l oppor tuni t ies be-

    come cost inefficient to pursue. First, the oppor-

    tunity to ea rn e ntrep rene urial profit will provide

    an incentive to man y econom ic actors. As oppor-

    tunities are exploited, information diffuses to

    other members of society who can imitate the

    innovator and appropriate some of the innova-

    the opportunity and increase overall demand

    compet i t ion even tua l ly beg ins to domina t

    (Hann an & Fre em an, 1984). W hen the entry o

    add i t iona l en t r ep reneurs r eaches a r a te a

    which the benefits from new entrants exceed

    the costs, the incentive for people to pursue th

    opportunity is reduced, because the entrepre

    neurial profit becomes divided among more an

    more actors (Schumpeter, 1934).

    Second, the exploitation of opportunity pro

    vides information to resource providers abou

    the value of the resources that they possess an

    leads them to raise resource prices over time, i

    order to capture some of the entrepreneur

    profit for them se lv es (Kirzner, 1997). In short, t h

    diffusion of information and learning about th

    accuracy of decisions over time, combined wit

    the lure of profit, will reduce the incentive fo

    people to pursue any given opportunity.

    The duration of any given opportunity de

    pends on a variety of factors. The provision o

    monopoly rights, as occurs with patent prote

    tion or an exclusive contract, increases the du

    ration. Similarly, the slowness of informatio

    diffusion or the lags in the timeliness wit

    which others recognize information also in

    crea se the duration, particu larly if time provide

    reinforcing advantages, such as occur with th

    adopt ion of technical s tandards or learnin

    curve s. Finally, the inability of oth ers (due

    various isolating mechanisms) to imitate, su

    stitute, trade for or acquire the rare resourc

    required to drive down the surp lus (Venkatar

    man, 1997: 133) increases the duration.

    The iscovery of Entrepreneurial Opportun iti

    Although an opportunity for entrepreneuri

    profit might exist, an individual can earn th

    profit only if he or she reco gnize s that the oppo

    tunity exists and has value. Given that an asym

    metry of beliefs is a precondition for the exi

    tence o f en t r ep reneur ia l oppor tun i t i e s , a

    opportunities must not be obvious to everyo

    all of the time (Hayek,  1945). At any point in tim

    only some su bset of the population will discov

    a given opportunity (Kirzner, 1973).

    Why do some people and not others discov

    par t icular entrepreneur ia l oppor tuni t ies? A

    though the null hypothesis is blind luck, r

    search has suggested two broad categories

    factors that influence the probab ility that pa rt

  • 8/9/2019 The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

    6/11

     

    cademy ol

      anagement

     Review

    Janua

    t ies :  (1) the p os se ssi on of the prior information

    ne ce ss ary to identify a n oppo rtunity an d (2) the

    cogni t ive propert ies necessary to value i t .

    Information corridors. Human beings all pos-

    sess different stocks of information, and these

    stocks of information influence their ability to rec-

    ognize particular opportunities. Stocks of informa-

    tion create mental schemas, which provide a

    framework for recognizing new information. To

    recognize an opportunity, an entrepreneur has to

    hav e prior information that is complem entary with

    the new information, which triggers an entrepre-

    neurial conjecture (Kaish  Gilad,

      1987).

     This prior

    information m ight be ab out u ser ne ed s (Von Hip-

    pel,

      1986) or specific as jjects of the produ ction

    function (Bruderl, Preisendorfer,  Ziegler, 1992).

    The information necessary to recognize any

    given opportuni ty is not widely dis t r ibuted

    across the population because of the specializa-

    tion of info rma tion in soc iety (Hayek, 1945). Peo-

    ple special ize in information because special-

    ized information is more useful than general

    information for most a ctiv ities (Becker & Mur-

    phy,

      1992).

     As a result , no two peop le s har e all of

    the same information at the same time. Rather,

    information about underutilized resources, new

    technology, unsated demand, and poli t ical and

    regulatory shifts is distributed according to the

    idiosyncratic life circumstances of each person

    in the population (Venkataraman, 1997).

    The development of the Internet provides a

    useful example. Only a subset of the population

    has had entrepreneurial conjectures in response

    to the development of this technology. Some

    people sti ll do not know what the Internet is or

    that profitable opportunities exist to exploit it.

    Cognitive properties. Since the discovery of

    entrepreneurial opportunities is not an optimi-

    zat ion process by which people make mechani-

    cal calculations in response to a given a set of

    alternatives imposed upon them (Baumol, 1993),

    people must be able to identi fy ne w me ans-e nds

    relat ionships that are generated by a given

    change in order to discover entrepreneurial op-

    portunities. Even if a person possesses the prior

    information necessary to discover an opportu-

    nity, he or she may fail to do so because of an

    inabi l i ty to see new means-ends relat ionships.

    Unfortunately, visualizing these relationships is

    difficult. Rosenberg (1994) points out that history

    is rife with examples in which inventors failed

    to see commercial opportuni t ies (new means-

    tion of important technologies—from the tel

    graph to the laser.

    Prior research has shown that people differ i

    their ability to identify such relationships. Fo

    example, research in the field of cognitive sc

    ence has shown that people vary in their abil

    t ies to combine existing concepts and inform

    tion into new ide as (see Ward, Smith, & Vai

    1997,

     for sev era l revie w a rticles). Recently, a fe

    researchers have begun to evaluate empir ical

    the role that cognitive properties play in th

    discovery of entrepreneurial opportunities (se

    Busenitz & Barney, 1996; Kaish & Gilad, 199

    Shav er & Scott, 1991). For exam ple , Sa ras va th

    Simon, an d Lave (1998) ha ve s how n tha t s ucc es

    ful entrepreneurs see opportunities in situation

    in which other people tend to see risks, where

    Baron (in press) has found that entrepreneu

    may be more likely than other persons to di

    cover opportunities because they are less like

    to engage in counterfactual thinking (i .e. , le

    likely to invest time and effort imaging wh

      might hav e been in a given situation), le

    likely to exp erien ce regret over mis sed opport

    nit ies,

      and are less susceptible to inaction ine

    tia.

    The Decision to Exploit Entre prene urial

    Opportuni t ies

    Although the discovery of an opportunity is

    necessary condition for entrepreneurship, i t

    not sufficient. Subsequent to the discovery of a

    opportunity, a potential entrepreneur must d

    cide to exploit the opportunity. We do not hav

    precise figures on the aborting of discovere

    opportunities, but we do know that not all di

    covered opportunities are brought to fruitio

    Why, whe n, and how . do some pe ople a nd n

    others exploit the opportunities that they di

    cover? The answer again appears to be a fun

    tion of the joint ch ara cte ristic s of the o pportun i

    and the nature of the individual (Venkatarama

    1997).

    Nature of the opportunity. The characteristi

    of opportunities themselves influence the wil

    ingn ess of people to exploit them . Entreprene u

    ial opportunities vary on several dimension

    which influences their expected value. For e

    ample, a cure for lung cancer has greater e

    pected value than does a solution to student

    need for snacks at a local high school. The e

  • 8/9/2019 The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

    7/11

    Shane and Venicafaraman

     

    d v alu e of the entr epre neu rial profit will be

    lack of liquidity of the in vestm ent of

    n ce rta in ty (Kirzner, 1973; Sch um pete r, 1934).

    To date, research ha s shown that , on avera ge,

    en t rep reneurs exp lo i t oppor tun i t i e s hav ing

    higher expected value. In particular, exploita-

    tion is more common when expected demand is

    large (Schmookler, 1966; Schumpeter, 1934), in-

    dustry profit margins are high (Dunne, Roberts,

      Sam uel son , 1988), the technology life cycle is

    young (Utterback, 1994), the density of competi-

    tion in a particular opportunity space is neither

    too low nor too hig h (Ha nna n Fre em an, 1984),

    th e cost of cap ita l is low (Sha ne, 1996), a nd pop -

    ulation-level learning from other entrants is

    av ai la bl e (Aldrich W ieden me yer, 1993).

    Indiv idual differences. Not all potential entre-

    preneurs will exploit opportunit ies with the

    same expected value. The decision to exploit an

    opportunity involves weighing the value of the

    opportunity against the costs to generate that

    value and the costs to generate value in other

    w a y s .

      Thus, people consider the opportunity

    cost of pursuing alternative activities in making

    the decision whether or not to exploit opportuni-

    ties and pursue opportunities when their oppor-

    tunity cost is lower (Amit, Mueller, 8f Cockburn,

    1995;  Reynolds, 1987). In addition, people con-

    sider their costs for obtain ing the resources nec-

    essary to exploit the opportunity. For example,

    Evans and Leighton (1991) showed that the ex-

    ploitation of opportunit ies is more common

    when people have greater f inancia l capi ta l .

    Similarly, Aldrich and Zimmer (1986) reviewed

    research findings that showed that stronger so-

    cial ties to resource providers facilitate the ac-

    quisition of resources and enhance the proba-

    bility of opportunity exploitation. Furthermore,

    Cooper, Woo, and Dunkelberg (1989) found that

    people are more likely to exploit opportunities if

    they have developed useful information for en-

    trepreneurship from their previous employment,

    presumably because such information reduces

    the cost of opportunity exploitation. Finally, the

    transferability of information from the prior ex-

    perience to the opportunity (Cooper et al., 1989),

    as wel l as pr ior entrepreneur ia l exper ience

    probability of exploitation of entrepreneurial

    opportunity because learning reduces its cost.

    The decision to exploit an entrepreneurial op-

    portunity is also influenced by individual differ-

    ences in perceptions. The creation of new prod-

    uc t s and marke t s invo lves downs ide r i sk

    because time, effort, and money must be in-

    vested before the distribution of the returns is

    know n (Knight, 1921; V en ka ta ram an , 1997). Sev

    eral researchers have argued that individua

    differences in the willingness to bear this risk

    influence the decision to exploit entre pren euria

    opportunities (Khilstrom  Laffont, 1979; Knigh

    1921). For exam ple, people who exploit opportu

    nities tend to frame information more positively

    and then respond to these positive perceptions

    (Palich  Bagby, 1995).

    The decision to exploit entre pren euria l oppor

    tunities is also influenced by individual differ

    ences in optimism. People who exploit opportu

    n i t i e s typ ica l ly pe rce ive the i r chances o f

    success as much higher than they really are—

    and much higher than those of others in thei

    indu stry (Cooper, Woo, Du nke lber g, 1988)

    Moreover, when these people create new firms

    they often enter industries in which scale econ

    omies play an important role at less than mini

    mum efficient sc al e (Audre tsch, 1991), an d they

    enter industries at rates exceeding the equilib

    rium nu m be r of firms (Gort Kleppe r, 1982).̂

    However, in most industries, at most points i

    time,

     most new firms fail (Dunne et al.,

     1988),

     an

    few firms ever displace incumbents (Audretsch

    1991),

     sug gestin g that p eople who exploit oppo

    tunities, on avera ge, are overly optimistic abou

    the valu e of the opportun ities they discover. Thi

    overoptimism motivates the exploitation of op

    portunity by limiting information, stimulatin

    rosy forecasts of the future (Kahneman

    Lovallo, 1994), trig ge rin g th e se ar ch for rela

    tively small amounts of information (Kaish

    Gilad , 1991), an d l ea din g pe op le to act first an

    analyze later (Busenitz  Barney, 1997).

    Other individual differences may be impo

    tant in explaining the willingness to exploit op

    portunit ies . Researchers have argued that peo

    ple with greater self-efficacy and more intern

    locus of control are more likely to exploit oppo

    tunities, because exploitation requires people

    *

      The information signals generated by the entrepren

  • 8/9/2019 The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

    8/11

     

    Academy  o anagement  fleview Janua

    act in the face of skepticism of others (Chen,

    G re e ne ,

     

    Crick, 1998). Sim ilarly, opp ortun ity ex -

    ploi ta t ion involves ambiguity, and people who

    have a greater tolerance for ambiguity may be

    more likely to exploit opportunities (Begley

    Boyd, 1987). Finally , the e xp loitatio n of o ppo rtu-

    nity is a setting in which people can achieve,

    providing a valuable cue for those who possess

    a high need for achievement (McClelland, 1961).

    Consequently, those who are high in need for

    achievement may be more l ikely than other

    members of society to exploit opportunities.

    Readers should note that the a t t r ibutes that

    increase the probability of opportunity exploita-

    t ion do not necessari ly increase the probabil i ty

    of success. For example, overoptimism might be

    associated with a higher probability of both ex-

    ploitation and failure. Of the population of indi-

    viduals who discover opportuni t ies in a given

    industry, those who are pessimist ic may choose

    not to exploit discovered opportun i t ies b eca use

    they more accurate ly est imate what i t wil l take

    to compete and how many other people will try

    to do similar things. Overoptimist ic individu als

    do not stop themselves from exploiting these

    opportuni t ies , because their overoptimism l im-

    its information and motivates rosy forecasts of

    the future.

    shown that entrepreneurship is less l ikely t

    take the form of de novo startups when capita

    market imperfections make it difficult for inde

    pendent ent repreneurs  to, secu re finan cing (C

    he n Levin, 1989). En trep ren eu rsh ip is mo r

    likely when the pursuit of entrepreneurial op

    portunity requires the effort of individuals wh

    lack incentives to do so in large organizations

    when scale economies, f i rs t mover advantages

    and learning curves do not provide advantage

    to ex istin g firms (Co hen Levin, 1989); an

    when industries have low barriers to entry (Ac

      Au dretsch , 1987). Re sear ch on the appr op

    ability of information has shown that entrepre

    neurship is more likely to take the form of d

    novo startups when information cannot be pro

    tected well by intellectual property laws, inhib

    iting the sale of entrepreneurial opportunitie

    (Cohen Levin, 1989). Fina lly, re se arc h on th

    nature of opportuni t ies has show n that entrepre

    neurship is more likely to take the form of d

    novo startups when opportuni t ies are more un

    certa in (Cas son, 1982), wh en op po rtun ities d

    not require complementary assets (Teece, 1986

    and when opportuni t ies des t roy competenc

    (Tush man An derso n, 1986).

    MO DES OF EXPLOIT TION

    Another critical question concerns how the ex-

    ploitation of entrepreneurial opportunities is or-

    gan ized in the econom y. Two major institution al

    a r ra nge me nt s fo r t he e xp lo i t a t i on o f t he se

    opportunities exist—the creation of new firms

    (hierarchies) and the sale of opportunities to ex-

    is t ing fi rms (markets)—but the common as-

    sumption is that most entrepreneuria l act ivi ty

    occurs through de novo startups. However, peo-

    ple within organizat ions who discover opportu-

    ni t ies sometimes pursue those opportuni t ies on

    behalf of their existing organizations and some-

    t ime s e s t a b l i sh ne w orga n iz a t ions , w he re a s

    independent actors sometimes sel l their oppor-

    tuni t ies to exis t ing organiza t ions and some-

    t imes establ ish new organizat ions to pursue the

    opportuni t ies .

    Research shows that the choice of mode de-

    pends on the nature of the industria l organiza-

    tion, the opportunity, and the appropriability re-

    CONCLUSION

    Entrepreneurship is an important and re le

    vant field of study. Although those in the fiel

    face many difficul t quest ions, we have pre

    sented a framework for exploring them. We rec

    ognize that we may hav e offered som e un certa i

    assumptions, potent ia l ly f lawed logical argu

    men ts, or hav e m ade s ta tem ents that wil l prov

    ultimately, to be incon sistent with da ta yet to b

    col lected. Nevertheless, this framework pro

    vides a starting point. Since it incorporates in

    formation gained from many disciplinary van

    t a g e p o i n t s a n d e x p l o r e d t h r o u g h m a n

    different methodologies, we hope that i t wi

    prod scholars from many different fields to joi

    us in the quest to create a systematic body o

    i n f o r m a t i o n a b o u t e n t r e p r e n e u r s h i p . M a n

    skep tics claim th at the crea tion of such a body o

    theory and the subsequent assembly of empir

    cal support for it are impossible. We hope tha

    other scholars will join our effort to prove thos

  • 8/9/2019 The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

    9/11

    Shane and VenJcataraman

    22 5

    REFERENCES

      Z., & Au dretsch, D. 1987. Innovation , m arket structu re,

    and firm size.  Review ol Econom ics and Statistics 71:

    567-574.

    organizational founding rates. Entrepreneurship Theory

    and Practice. Spring: 7-24.

    & W iedenm eyer, G. 1993. From tr aits to rate s:

    An ecological perspective on organizational foundings.

    Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence, and

    Growth

    1: 145-195.

    & Zimmer, C. 1986. En trepre neu rship through

    social networks. In D. Sexton

     

    R. Smilor (Eds.).

     The art

    and science ol entrepreneurship.

      3-23. Cambridge, MA:

    Ballinger.

     

    Mu eller, E. 1993. Cha lleng es to theory

    development in entrepreneurship research.  Journal ol

    Management Studies

    30: 815-834.

    , Mu eller, E., & Coc kbu m, I. 1995. Opp ortunity costs

    and entrepreneurial activity. Journal ol Business Ventur-

    ing. 10: 95-108.

    sources for invention. In R. Nelson (Ed.),

      The rate and

    direction ol inventive activity:

      Economic and

     social lac-

    tors:

     609-626. Princeto n, NJ: Princeton University P ress.

     1991.

     New firm survival and the technological

    regime, fleview   ol Economics and Statistics 88: 520-526.

    . In press. Co unterfactual thinking a nd venture for-

    mation: The potential effects of thinking about what

    might have been.

    Journal

      ol Business Venturing.

    Baumo l, W. J. 1989. En trepr ene urs hip in economic theory.

    American

      Economic Review

      Papers and Proceedings:

    64-71.

    Baumol, W. 1993. Formal entrepre neurs hip theory in econom-

    ics:

      Existence and bounds.

     Journal ol Business Ventur-

    ing

    8: 197-210. , . ; ,

    Baumol, W. 1998. Enfrepreneurship,  management and the

    structure ol payolls.

      Cam bridg e, MA: MIT Press.

    Becker, G., & Murphy, K. 1992. The division of labor, coordi-

    nation costs, and knowledge.

      Quarterly Journal  ol Eco-

    nomics 107: 1137-1180.

    Begley, T., & Boyd, D. 1987. Psyc holog ical cha racte ristic s

    associated with performance in entrepreneurial firms

    and smalle r businesses. Journal

      ol Business Venturing

    2:   79-93.

    Bru derl, J., Preisen do rfer, P., & Ziegler, R. 1992. Su rviva l

    chances of newly founded business organiza t ions.

    American Sociological Review. 57: 227-242.

    Busenitz, L.,

     

    Barney, J. 1997. Differences betw een entre pre-

    neurs and managers in large organizations: Biases and

    heuristics in strategic decision-making.

     Jou rnal ol Busi-

    ness

     Venturing

    12: 9-30.

    Carro ll, G., & M osakow ski, E. 1987. The care er dyn am ics of

    Casson, M. 1982.

      The entrepreneur.

      Totowa, NJ: Barnes &

    Noble Books.

    Cave s, R. 1998. Industrial o rganization and new findings on

    the turnover and mobility of firms.

     Journal ol

      Economic

    Liter ature . 36: 1947-1982.

    Chen, C, Greene, P.,

     

    Crick, A. 1998. Does entrepreneuria

    self-efficacy distinguish entrepreneurs from managers?

    Journal

      ol

      usiness

     Venturing

    13: 295-318.

    Cohen, W.,

     

    Levin, R. 1989. Emp irical s tud ies of inno vation

    and market structure. In R. Schma lensee & R. Willig

     Eds.), Handbook ot industrial organization

    vol.

     II: 1060

    1107.

     New York: Elsevier.

    Cooper, A., Woo, C , & Dun kelberg, W. 1988. En trepr eneu rs

    perceived chances for success.

     Journal ol Business Ven

    turing

    3: 97-108.

    Cooper, A., Woo, C, & Dunk elberg, W. 1989. Entrep reneur-

    ship and the initial size of firms.   Journal ol Business

    Venturing

    4: 317-332.

    Drucker, P. 1985. Innovation an d e ntrep rene ursh ip. New

    York: Harper

     

    Row.

    Dunn e, T., Rob erts, M.,

     

    Samuelson, L. 1988. Patterns of firm

    entry and exit in U.S. manu facturing industries. R and

    Journal

      ol Economics

    19: 495-515.

    Evans , D., & Leighton, L. 1989. Some em pirical asp ect s of

    entrepreneurship. American Economic   Review 79

    519-535.

    Gartner, W.

     1985.

     A

     conceptual framework for describing th

    phenom enon of new venture creation . Academy of

     Man

    agement Review 10: 696-708.

    Gartn er, W. B. 1988. Who is the entr epre neu r? is the wron g

    question. A merican

     Journal ot Small Business

    12: 11-32

    Geroski, P. 1995. Wh at do we know abo ut en try? Intern a

    tional Journal

      ot Industrial Organization 13:

     421-440.

    Gort, M., & Klepper, S. 1982. Time pa th s in th e diffusion of

    product inno vations. Economic

      Journal

    92: 830-853.

    Hannan, M.,

     

    Freeman,

     J

    1984. Structural inertia and orga

    izational change. American Sociological Review, 49

    149-184.

    Hayek, F. 1945. The u se of kn ow ledge in society.

      America

    Economic

      Review

    35; 519-530.

    Kah nem an, D., & Lovallo, D. 1994. Timid ch oices an d bold

    forecasts:

     A

     cognitive persp ective on risk takin g. In R.

    Rumelt, D. E. Schendel, & D. Teece (Eds.), Fundament

    issues in

      strategy: A research agenda:

      71-98. Bosto

    Ballinger.

    Kaish, S., & Gilad , B. 1991. Ch arac teris tics of op por tun itie

    search of entrepreneurs versus executives: Sources, in

    terests, and general  alertness. Journal  ol Business Ve

    turing

    6:

     45-61.

    Katz, J., & Gartn er, W. 1988. Prop erties of em erg ing org an

    zations. Academy

      ot Management Review 13:

      429-44

    Khilstrom, R.,

     

    Laffont, J. 1979. A general equilibrium ent

    preneurial theory of firm formation based on risk ave

    sion. Journal

     ol Political Economy 87:

     719-748.

    Kirzner, I. 1973. Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicag

  • 8/9/2019 The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

    10/11

     

    Academy ol Management Review

    Januar

    Kirzner, I. 1997. Entrepreneurial discovery and the competi-

    tive market process: An Austrian approach.  Journal of

    Economic Literature.  35: 60-85.

    Knight, F. 1921.

     Risk

    uncertainty and profit.  New York:

    Augustus Kelley.

    Low, M., Ma cMillan, I. 1988. En trep ren eur ship : Pa st re-

    search and future challenges. Journal of Management

    14: 139-161.

    McClelland, D. 1961. The achieving society.  Princeton, NJ:

    Van Nostrand.

    Palich , L., Bagby, R. 1995. Using cognitive theory to ex plain

    entrepreneurial r isk-taking: Challenging conventional

    wisdom.  Journal of Business Venturing 10: 425-438.

    Rey nolds , P. 1987. New firms: Soc ietal co ntribu tion ve rsu s

    survival potent ia l .  Journal of  Business  Venturing 2:

    23 1-24 6. ^-V.w,-r̂ ' •; .;:• : -

    Rey nolds , P., W hite, S. 1997. The entrepreneurial process.

    Greenwich, CT: Greenwood Press.

    Roberts, E. 1991. Entrep reneurs in high (echnoiogy: Lessons

    from   MIT and

      beyond.

      New York: Oxford University

    Press.

    Rose nberg, N. 1994. Uncertainty an d tech nologica l ch ang e.

    Conference   on growth and development: The economics

    of the 21st century.  Stanford, CA: Stanford University,

    Center for Economic Policy Research.

    Sa ras va thy , D., Simon, H., Lave, L. 1998. Perc eivin g and

    ma nag ing bu sines s r isks: Differences between entre-

    preneurs and bankers .

      Journal of Economic Behavior

    and Organization.  33: 207-225.

    Schmookler, J. 1966. Invention an d economic g rowth. C am-

    bridge , MA: Harva rd U niversity P ress.

    Schumpeter, J. 1934. Capitalism socialism and d emocrac

    New York: Harp er Row.

    Shane, S.

     1996.

     Explaining variation in rates of entreprene

    ship in the United States: 1899-1988.

     ouma

    o{

     Manag

    ment 22: 747-781.

    Sha ver, K. G., Scott, L. R. 1991. Person, process, and cho

    The psychology of new venture creation. Entrepreneu

    ship Theory and Practice. Winter: 23-42.

    Singh, J., Lum sden, C. 1990. Theory an d res ea rch in org a

    izational ecology. Annuai f leview   of Sociology. 

    161-195.

    Stinchcombe, A. 1965. Social structure and organ ization

    In J. March (Ed.), Handbook   of organizations:  260-2

    Chicago: Rand McNally.

    Teece,

      D. 1986. Profiting from te chn olog ical inno vatio n: I

    plications for integration, collaboration, licensing, an

    public policy.  Research Policy 15: 286-305.

    Tush man , M., Anderson, P. 1986. Techno logical discont

    nuities and organizational environments. Administr

    tive Science  Quarterly.  31: 439-465.

    Utterback, J. 1994.

      Mas tering the dynamics of innovatio

    Cam bridge , MA: Harvard Busin ess School Press.

    Ve nkata rama n, S. 1997. The distinctive d om ain of entrepr

    neurship research: An editor's perspective. In

     J

    Katz

    Brockhaus (Eds.), Advances in entrepreneurship,  fir

    emergence and growth

    vol. 3: 119-138. Gre enw ich, C

    JAI Press .

    Von Hippel, E. 1986. Lead users: A source of novel produ

    concepts. Management Science, 32: 791-805.

    W ard, T., Sm ith, S., Vaid , J. (Eds.). 1997. Creative thoug

    Washington, DC: American Psychological Association

    Scott Shane  is associate professor of entrepreneurship in the Robert H. Smith School

    of Business and director of research at the Dingman Center for Entrepreneurship at

    the University of Marylan d. He received his

     Ph.D.

     from the University of P enns ylvan ia.

    His current research focuses on entrepreneurship in high-technology settings.

    S.  Venkataraman is the Sa mu el L. Slover Assoc iate Professor of Busine ss A dministra-

    tion an d director of researc h at the Batten Center for Entrep reneuria l Lea dersh ip in the

    Darden Graduate School of Business Administration at the University of Virginia. He

    received his Ph.D. from the University of Minnesota. His current research focuses on

    entrepreneurship theory.

  • 8/9/2019 The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

    11/11