the paho model for estimating the impact of changes in intellectual property rights joan rovira,...

57
The PAHO model for The PAHO model for estimating the impact of estimating the impact of changes in Intellectual changes in Intellectual Property Rights Property Rights Joan Rovira, Joan Rovira, Universitat de Barcelona Universitat de Barcelona Ismail Abbas Ismail Abbas , Universitat Politècnica de Catalunya , Universitat Politècnica de Catalunya

Upload: baldwin-bennett

Post on 25-Dec-2015

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Slide 1
  • The PAHO model for estimating the impact of changes in Intellectual Property Rights Joan Rovira, Universitat de Barcelona Ismail Abbas, Universitat Politcnica de Catalunya
  • Slide 2
  • 2 Content 1. Justification and objectives of the project 2. Model specification and description 3. Illustrative results for Colombia and Malaysia 4. Discussion Acknowledgement: This project has been funded by the PAHO-WHO
  • Slide 3
  • 3 Justification and objectives of the project
  • Slide 4
  • 4 The changing environment of IPR regimes Global trends and pressures towards an international upwards harmonization of IPR to developed countries standards Regional agreements: Single European Market-EU, NAFTA The TRIPS agreement Bilateral agreements National implementation of agreements and other policies
  • Slide 5
  • 5 The impact of changes in IPR regimes might affect, with varying levels of uncertainty: Market exclusivity - competition Prices Expenditure Consumption access health Foreign investment Domestic production, employment Imports exports - balance of trade R&D and innovation (global and domestic; general and on country-specific diseases) Technology transfer
  • Slide 6
  • 6 The timing of the impacts of changes in IPR provisions Short-term Test data exclusivity Conditions for compulsory licensing Date of enforcement, transitory periods ... Long term (well all be dead, according to J M Keynes?) Duration of patent (>20years) Scope of patentability ...
  • Slide 7
  • 7 Information needs of decision-makers Decision-makers, such as the negotiators of a trade agreement, must often consider and take quick decisions on proposals related to IPR, which might have a substantial impact on the future access to pharmaceuticals and, ultimately, on the health status in their countries. Although it is increasingly apparent to most developing countries negotiators that stronger (TRIPS plus) patent protection is likely to have negative net effects on drug accessibility and health status, trade agreements often require trade-offs in a given sector in order to obtain advantages (e.g. tariff reductions to agricultural exports) in other sectors. If concessions have to be considered or made in a given sector, it is important to be able to identify and quantify as precisely as possible the future impact, in order to compare it with the expected benefits from other sectors.
  • Slide 8
  • 8 Objectives of the project To develop a user-friendly tool for decision-makers that allows them to estimate the future impact of changes in IPR and related pharmaceutical policies To collect the required information, implement and test the model in several countries (initially, Colombia, Costa Rica and Guatemala, later Malaysia, Vietnam, India, ) To assess the information and knowledge gaps and to propose an agenda for future research
  • Slide 9
  • 9 Model specification and description
  • Slide 10
  • 10 Development of a Model to Assess the Impact of Changes in IPR Version: 17-11-2006 Development of a Model to Assess the Impact of Changes in IPR Version: 17-11-2006 Content Justification and objectives of the project. Introduction Literature review When to evaluate the impact Options to evaluate How to evaluate the impact Impact variables Presentation of the model of Impact of Changes in the IPR Structure and general characteristics of the model of Impact of Changes in the IPR Structure and general characteristics of the model of Impact of Changes in the IPR Operation of the model Translating IPR changes into model parameters Definition and calculation of impacts Key assumptions of the model
  • Slide 11
  • 11 Development of a Model to Assess the Impact of Changes in IPR Version: 17-11-2006 Development of a Model to Assess the Impact of Changes in IPR Version: 17-11-2006 Appendix 1: Model Specification Appendix 2: Data required for the application of the IPR Impact Model to a given country Appendix 3: Suggested Reporting Format for Country Analysis Appendix 4: Abbreviated Users manual
  • Slide 12
  • 12 The PAHO IPR Impact Model A general model, not a country application Deterministic (sensitivity analysis) Macroeconomic (agreggated) Computer assisted simulation model (Excel)
  • Slide 13
  • 13 The model estimates the impact of alternative scenarios on pharmaceutical expenditure, consumption and market share of the domestic industry over a defined time horizon. The baseline scenario estimates the evolution of the variables under the existing IPR rules. The alternative scenarios reflect the evolution of the variables under other combinations of IPR rules that might result from TRIPS enforcement, bilateral trade agreements or autonomous IPR and pharmaceutical policies, in general. The impact of a given alternative scenario x is defined as the difference in a given outcome variable between the baseline and the alternative scenario.
  • Slide 14
  • 14
  • Slide 15
  • 15 Final impact variables Impact of scenario x: IMV x : Increase in expenditure/sales/market value rC x : Relative reduction in consumption (in units) RMSD x : Reduction in the sales of the domestic industry RMSD x : Reduction in the sales of the domestic industry
  • Slide 16
  • 16 The model first computes the number and proportion of AI under exclusivity for all years over the time horizon: The data input required includes: TAPto: Number of AI (active ingredients) on the market at the beginning of the initial year AIi: Number of AI entering the market each year AOi: Number of AI exiting the market each year AIPPi: Number of AI entering the market with patent protection each year AIDPi: Number of AI entering the market with test data protection each year
  • Slide 17
  • 17 The duration of the effective exclusivity time derived from a patent is computed as: EEP = PD DT + PDE + TTC + DGE, where: PD is the nominal patent duration DT is the time elapsed between patent filling and registration/market authorization PDE is the extension of patent duration due to compensation for delays in patent approval, which might affect a certain proportion of AI, pPDE) TTC is the time elapsed between the patent expiration time and generic market entry (associated to Bolar provision) DGE is the delay in generic market entry due to the linkage between registration and patent, which might affect a certain proportion of AI, pDGE)
  • Slide 18
  • 18
  • Slide 19
  • 19 The model then computes the average price differential of medicines between the baseline and any alternative scenario by means of a price index that takes the value 1 each year of the baseline scenario: ( Alternative scenarios x are indicated by the superindex ( x ) Pi = 1 P x i = [1+( pe x i pei)*(RPec 1) + (1- pe x i)*(pdi- pd x i)*(RPbd 1)] pei: Share of the relevant market under exclusivity in year i RPec: Relative weighted average price of an AI under exclusivity (APe) vs. its price under competition (APc) pd x i: share of branded products in the non-exclusive segment RPbd: Relative weighted average price of an branded vs. unbranded (INN) AI
  • Slide 20
  • 20 Reduction in consumption (quantities demanded) and expenditure increase are taken as proxis for reduction in access caused by price increases. The demand function is assumed to have a constant price-elasticity, e, and the following expression: q = k p e where q: units demanded k: constant p: price (index) e: price-elasticity of demand; e = (dq/q)/(dp/p) The price-elasticity of demand indicates the relative change in the quantity demanded as a response to a 1% change in price.
  • Slide 21
  • 21 The expenditure/sales/market value in the baseline scenario is computed as: MV i = MV i-1 *(1+) The expenditure/sales/market value in the alternative scenario x is computed as: MVi x = MV x i = MVi* P x i e+1
  • Slide 22
  • 22 Impact of a change of the price on consumption and expenditure
  • Slide 23
  • 23
  • Slide 24
  • 24 The reduction in market sales of domestic industry under scenario x, RMSD x i is computed as: RMSD x i = MVDi - MVD x i = k de * pei* MVi + k dc *(1-pei)* MVi - (k de *pei* MV x i + k dc *(1-pe x i)* MV x i) where k de : market share of domestic industry in markets under exclusivity k dc : market share of domestic industry in markets under competition MVDi: Market sales of domestic industry in year i
  • Slide 25
  • 25
  • Slide 26
  • 26 The main assumptions of the model are: 1. Under the alternative scenario x, the units of the products now under exclusivity, (pe x i pei), will attain a higher relative price than under competition, Rpec. 2. The market share (in monetary terms) of each AI is the same for all AI throughout their market life 3. Competition in an AI market begins immediately or some years after patent protection and test data exclusivity end. 4. The average price of an AI instantaneously drops by a given fixed proportion when competition starts.
  • Slide 27
  • 27 5. The model assumes that the domestic industry will maintain all the time and under any scenario the initial market share in the markets under exclusivity and under competition. As it is likely to have a higher share in the competitive market, as long as the competitive market decreases in relative terms, the share of the domestic industry in the total market will come down. The absolute value of this market share cannot be unambiguously predicted as it depends, as well, on the growth of the market. 5. The model assumes that the domestic industry will maintain all the time and under any scenario the initial market share in the markets under exclusivity and under competition. As it is likely to have a higher share in the competitive market, as long as the competitive market decreases in relative terms, the share of the domestic industry in the total market will come down. The absolute value of this market share cannot be unambiguously predicted as it depends, as well, on the growth of the market.
  • Slide 28
  • 28 Preliminary results for Colombia The time horizon for the simulation is 2005-2050. In the baseline scenario the share of the market under exclusivity rises until 2019 and remains stable thereafter at 43% If patent duration is extended to 21 years, the market share under exclusivity levels off a year later, in 2020, at a 47%, and pharmaceutical expenditure is 5.7% higher than in the baseline scenario. Increasing by one year the duration of the exclusivity for test data protection would imply a stabilization of the market share under exclusivity in 2019 at 44% and a 1.5% increase in expenditure over the baseline scenario. If Colombia had not enforced product patent protection in 2000 and test data protection in 2002, it might have saved an estimated 69% of the pharmaceutical expenditure over the simulated period.
  • Slide 29
  • 29 IPR Impact Model Preliminary Results in Malaysia Final purpose of analysis was to estimate the likely impact a stronger IPR protection on medicine prices in Malaysia if Malaysia signs the US- Malaysia FTA bilateral agreement
  • Slide 30
  • 30 Preliminary results based on currently available data The time horizon for the simulation is 2007-2047 If all standard USFTA provisions are accepted, the worst case scenario simulated would result in increase in pharmaceutical expenditure of 46% or a reduction in consumption of 56% If data exclusivity alone is introduced, the worst case scenario simulated would result in a reduction of consumption by 50% or an increase in expenditure of 38% If the proportion of medicines that are patented increases, the worst case scenario simulated is a reduction in consumption of 36% or an increase in expenditure of 28%
  • Slide 31
  • 31Discussion The model has proved easy to understand and use by decision-makers with no previous experience in simulation models Most of the information required for running the model was available and relatively easy to collect in the pilot test countries The model results are very sensitive to the data and assumptions on the initial number of AI, and of those entering and exiting the market. The number of existing AI should be adjusted in order to ensure that it reflects the number of AI in the market that have a market share similar to the future new entrants.
  • Slide 32
  • 32Discussion Additional analyses are also required on the price differential of AI in competitive markets and in markets under exclusivity conditions Although the results look plausible, it is necessary to improve the evidence base by undertaking systematic reviews and, when required, new analyses of the impacts of IPR changes. The values of some of the parameters that define the scenarios in the model directly reflect the options of the decision maker, e.g. duration of the patent or year of enforcement of pharmaceutical patents. For other parameters the values are less straightforward, and will require specific studies and subjective technical judgments. E.g. how will an hypothetical broader scope of patentability affect the proportion of AI that will enter the market with patent protection?
  • Slide 33
  • 33
  • Slide 34
  • 34 Months after First Generic Entry into Market Generic Penetration of Brand Market: Units Sales and Price per Unit SOURCE: Compiled by the PRIME Institute, University of Minnesota from data found in Kidder, Peabody Generic Units as % of Total Unit Sold Generic Price as % of Brand Price Commodity Equilibrium Price Reached (Modest Price Inflation Expected) 6 Months Exclusivity (Generic) Generic Price Competition (More Firms = Lower Prices)
  • Slide 35
  • 35 Estimating the price differential exclusivity-competition The price of original drug under exclusivity is 100 The average price of the generics after three years of patent expiration is 25 Market share of generics after three years is 85% and that of the original product, 15% The final average price of the AI is: 100 x 0,15 + 25 x 0,85 = 38,75 The price of the AI under exclusivity is 2,5 times that of the price under competition
  • Slide 36
  • 36 Source: Danzon and Furukawa, Health Affairs, 2003
  • Slide 37
  • 37 Estimation of relative average prices of drugs Sales of unbranded generics (UBG) / Total sales Sales of unbranded generics (UBG) / Total sales --------------------------------------------------------------------- = --------------------------------------------------------------------- = Units of unbranded generics (UBG) / Total units Units of unbranded generics (UBG) / Total units Units of UBG x average UBG price / Total units x average price Units of UBG x average UBG price / Total units x average price = -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- = Units of unbranded generics (UBG) / Total units Units of unbranded generics (UBG) / Total units average UBG price average UBG price = --------------------------- = RELATIVE PRICE OF UBG = --------------------------- = RELATIVE PRICE OF UBG average price average price
  • Slide 38
  • 38 Estimation of potential savings from an INN policy POTENTIAL SAVINGS (in % of total sales) = POTENTIAL SAVINGS (in % of total sales) = SHARE OF BRANDED GENERICS SALES x ( 1 - RELATIVE PRICE OF UBG / RELATIVE PRICE OF BG ) x 100 Assumptions: In the absence of brand names, competition would reduce the present prices of BG to the level of UBG.
  • Slide 39
  • 39
  • Slide 40
  • 40 Impact of generic competition on pharmaceutical prices (1) (A substantial share of) the reduction of ARV annual treatment costs between 2000 and 2003 from US$ 10.000 to 300 should (probably) be accounted to generic competition. A recent WHO-HAI study, The price of medicines, shows ratios between generic and branded originals in the range of 1:2 (Armenia), 1:3 (Sri Lanka), and from 1:2 up to 1:7 in Kazakhstan
  • Slide 41
  • 41 Impact of generic competition on pharmaceutical prices (2) A recent study applied WHO-HAI methodology in Malaysia Survey was conducted from October-2004 to January 2005. 48 drugs were surveyed by using systematic sampling technique in four geographical regions of Malaysia Babar et al, A survey of medicine prices in Malaysia by using WHO/HAI methodology. UCSI-USM, October 2005.
  • Slide 42
  • 42 Median MPRs of IB, MSG and LPG in Public for Procurement Sector, Private Sector Retail Pharmacies and Dispensing Doctors Sector Median MPRs of IB, MSG and LPG in Public for Procurement Sector, Private Sector Retail Pharmacies and Dispensing Doctors Sector Drugs Public Sector PSRPDDS Innovator Brands 2.4116.3515.40 Most Sold Generic 1.566.897.76 Lowest Price Generic 1.096.577.76
  • Slide 43
  • 43 Private Retail Pharmacies
  • Slide 44
  • 44
  • Slide 45
  • 45 Thanks for your attention For additional information, please contact Joan Rovira [email protected]
  • Slide 46
  • 46 Fixed parameters YI: Initial year of simulation period YL: Last year of simulation period TAPt n : Number of existing active ingredient (AI) in the market in year t n; t n t n AOi: Number of AI exiting the market in year i; i > t n DT: Time from patent filling (or approval) of an AI to market registration (approval) of the original product MVt o : Total sales/expenditure of the relevant market in year t o : annual rate of growth of MV RPec: Relative weighted average price of an AI under exclusivity (APe) vs. its price under competition (APc) d: discount rate k de : market share of domestic industry in markets under exclusivity k dc : market share of domestic industry in markets under competition
  • Slide 47
  • 47 Scenario-dependent parameters YP: initial year of product patent enforcement pp: Percentage of patented (product patent) AI entering the market in year i PD: Patent duration in years YDP: initial year of data protection enforcement AIDPi: Number of AI entering the market in year i with test data protection DE: Duration of exclusivity due to test data protection TTC: Time from patent expiration to generic competition e: price-elasticity of demand
  • Slide 48
  • 48 Impact variables Impact of scenario x: IMV x i: Increase in total sales/expenditure of the relevant market in year i. RICi: Reduction in consumption (units) in year i RMSD x i: Reduction in market sales of domestic industry in year i
  • Slide 49
  • 49
  • Slide 50
  • 50 ASEF ASIA-EUROPE FOUNDATION CULTURES &CIVILISATIONS DIALOGUE 8th Talks on the Hill Re-righting Intellectual Property: Economic and Social policy challenges in Asia and Europe Singapore, 7th-9th of May 2006 SELECTED ASEF ROUND TABLE RECOMMENDATIONS:
  • Slide 51
  • 51 Allowing for greater flexibilities in using TRIPS Many of the Europeans felt that their governments should be more forthcoming about telling the developing countries that it is acceptable for them to use the flexibilities that TRIPS provides. In addition to governments, companies should also start to recognise the flexibilities that are built in TRIPS for example parallel imports.
  • Slide 52
  • 52 Releasing the Pressure The group also called upon governments and patent companies to refrain from using pressure tactics that result in developing countries adopting higher standards of intellectual property protection and enforcement than they need to or are able to.
  • Slide 53
  • 53 Understanding the depth of Intellectual Property Many of the participants from developing countries recognised the need to gain more concrete advice before signing on the treaties such as the Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT) and indicated that their governments need to realise that intellectual property is far more important and pervasive than previously thought.
  • Slide 54
  • 54 Distinguishing between obligations and pressures Linked to this point was the need for developing countries to focus on dissecting much of the information that they are receiving from the various international organisations as well as other governments into obligations and pressures. In doing so, the countries would be better able to more positively lay out their policy in alignment with their priorities and national interest.
  • Slide 55
  • 55 Diversifying the decision- making process National governments should diversify the decision-making process on treaties and other agreements linked to intellectual property. This comes with a growing recognition that this issue can no longer be limited to a few specialists. For example, professionals and decision- makers from the health sector should be involved in the discussion and negotiation of both FTA and internal policies when they are likely to have an impact on the price and access to medicines and health services.
  • Slide 56
  • 56 Value in involving civil society at multilateral forums Members of the group recognised that independent civil society has a useful role to play at the multilateral level and their involvement and views should be better taken into consideration in the decision-making processes within the WTO and WIPO.
  • Slide 57
  • 57 Thanks for your attention For additional information, please contact Joan Rovira [email protected]