the implications of technical change in a marxian framework (dietzenbacher)

Upload: carpalopez

Post on 02-Jun-2018

219 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    1/13

    Vol.

    5

    (1989), No. 1,pp. 35 -46 Joumoi

    of

    EcOttOn^ S

    ZaUtiMlh fOr t

    by Springer-Verlag 1989

    The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian

    Framework

    By

    Erik Dietzenbacfaer Groningen, The Netherlands*

    (Received June 8,1988; revised version received April 20,1989)

    1. Introduction

    The effects of technical change on the price structure are well

    documented for a Sraffa-Leontief model with a con stant profit

    rate. See, for instance , H erre ro, Jimenez-R aneda, and Villar (1980),

    Fujimoto, Herrero, and Villar (1983) and Dietzenbacher (1988).

    Within a Marxian framework on the other hand, it is precisely the

    change in the rate of profit that has been extensively discussed.

    The question whether technical change causes the rate of profit to

    fall, as posited by M arx, or not, h as led to a vivid controv ersy. Fo r

    a recent con tribu tion see the d eb ate o n Sha ikh (1978), with

    comments by Arm strong and Glyn (1980), Bleany (1980), Naka tan i

    (1980) and Steedman (1980), and his own reply (Shaikh, 1980). See

    further e. g. Roemer (1977, 1979), Bowles (1981) and Salvado ri

    (1981). A central role in the discussion on the falling rate of profit

    has been played by the fam ous Okishio theorem (1961). It states

    that a technical change which reduces the cost of production

    (measured in current prices) implies a rise in the rate of profit. In a

    Marxian framework, little attention has been paid so far to the

    * An earlier version of this paper was presented at the Third Annual

    ^ongress of the Europiean Economic Association, held in Bologna,

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    2/13

    36 E. Dietzenbacher:

    price effects of technical change, whereas they occur simulta-

    neously with a change in the profit rate.

    In the present paper we focus on price changes in case of a

    rising, or falling, rate of profit. As such, we do not go into the

    debate on the falling rate of profit. We first prove in section 2 that

    for an innovation that leads to, for instance, a rise in the profit

    rate, the price in the innovating sector falls and, moreover, falls

    relatively the most. As a consequence, the percentual increase

    (resp. decrease) in the profits (per unit of output) is the least (resp.

    the most) for the innovating sector. Second, in section 3 we show

    that the criterion of cost-reduction is not only sufficient for the

    rate of profit to rise, but also necessary. Hence the converse of the

    well known Okishio theorem is also valid. This result implies that,

    given the mode under consideration, Marx's falling rate of profit

    can only be brought about by a technical change that extends the

    cost of production. Third, in section 4, we present similar results

    for three extensions of the basic model.

    Consider a pure circulating capital model where A is the nxn

    input matrix, I is the 1 x n row vector of direct labour inputs, b is

    the n X1 column vector which gives the subsistence wage bundle,

    jiis the equilibrium rate of profit and p is the 1 x n row vector of

    production prices in equilibrium. TTie wage rate is taken as unity.

    The equilibrium is specified by the following equations:

    p = (l-l-;r)(pA-t-l), (1)

    l = pb. (2)

    Let the augmented input matrix be defined as M = A-l-bl, then (t)

    can be written as

    (3)

    We assume that

    A, b and I are

    semi-positive^

    and

    that

    M is

    inde-

    composable

    and

    prod uctive . These conditions imply that

    the

    ^

    For vectors and matrices we adopt the following notations and

    expressions. x>0, non-negative, means JCf >0 for ali

    i;

    x >0,semi-positive,

    means x>0 and x^O; x>-0, positive, means x,>0 for aili

    For a non-negative, indecomposable matrix M that is productive,

    there exists an output vector x>0 such that x>Mx Ax+blx. This

    means that the technology is capable of prodi^ng a surplus over the

    requirements for subsistence. These three conditions are sufficient to guar-

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    3/13

    The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework 37

    equations (2) and (3) have a unique positive solution, i.e. n>0

    and

    f>0.

    2. The Effects of a Change nthe Profit Rate

    Suppose that a technical cha nge app ears in sector (or process)

    i.

    This affects A', the j-th column of the input matrix A, and/or /,.

    The augm ented inp ut m atrix M is therefore also changed in its j-th

    column M'. As a consequence the rate of profit and the prices

    change. We assume that the subsistence wage bundle remains the

    same. Using bars over the symbols to denote the new technology,

    the equilibrium after the technical change is specified by the

    following equations:

    4

    I = p 6 . (5)

    It is assumed that also A and I are semi-positive and that M is

    indecomposable and productive. Consider the relative changes in

    the production prices, that isPj/pj. The following theorem asserts

    that the relative price changes are bounded by the relative change

    of the price in sector

    i,

    in which the techn ical chang e h as taken

    place.

    Theorem 1:

    \f n>n: pj/pj

    >

    ip,/p^

    (1H- * ) / ( l

    +n > p^/pi

    for all

    j

    (,

    \^ n,

    = 1

    -I-

    x ) piVPfor

    j

    ^ s

    MJ

    =

    M^.

    F or

    j

    = rthere are three possibilities, (i)

    //

    > 1+

    n

    pM' ,

    thus p>(l-i-;ir) plVLJThe Subinvariance theorem* implies that the

    Frobenius root of M, that is 1/(1

    -hx ,

    is smaller than _l/ (;i -f

    n ,

    thus

    n>ji,

    which is a con tradiction, (ii)

    />;

    < (1-I-;r)pM ' implies

    P< (l +

    ;r p M

    and

    7i,

    = (1H-;r)pM ' must hold. Thus

    P= ( l + :^ )pM. Q .E.D .

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    4/13

    38 E. Dietzenbacher:

    F or

    a

    rising rate

    of

    profit for ins tan ce , this the ore m states that

    the largest relative price decrease willbeobserved insector i.If

    pr od uc t / is the only pro du ct th at is requ ired for the subsistence of

    the wo rkers ( i . e . A ,> 0 a nd

    bj = O

    for

    all

    j i),

    then

    Pi = Pi

    and

    Pj>Pj,

    as

    follows from p b

    =

    p b

    =

    1 . H ow ever

    if

    there

    is a

    prod-

    uct j other tha n j , tha t isrequi red forsubs istence (i. e. bj > 0 for

    s o m e

    / V I , it

    follows that

    the

    pr ice

    in

    sector

    /

    falls,Pin: Sj/sj> (. /s (1-f )/(l { n)> s,/Sifor allj#i,

    if nn, therateof

    profit rises. The corollary asserts that for the innovated process the

    (per unit) profit incre ases relatively the least or dec reases relatively

    the most.

    At

    first sight, this result seems

    to be

    surprising,

    a

    few

    remarks however are

    in

    place.

    First,

    the

    statem ent hold s also with respect

    to

    to ta l profits,

    provided that the output isno t affected by th e tech nica l change.

    Total profit in sec tor i increases pe rce ntu ally th e least or decreases

    percentually them ost. It is obviou s however, that the absolute

    increase (decrease)

    of

    the total profit doe s

    not

    need

    to be the

    smallest (largest)

    in

    sector

    i

    Second, consumers may be expected

    to react on the price changes. Substitution will leadto a different

    final demand vector and consequently to

    a

    differen t ou tp ut vector.

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    5/13

    The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework 39

    Therefore it is very well possible that the re is a decrease in the (pe r

    unit) profit of sector

    i

    and an increase in its tota l profit du e to a

    rise of its output. Third, it is not possible to state whether technical

    change induces a rise or a fall in the (per unit) profit of sector

    i

    It

    can only be asserted that there is at least one sector for which the

    (per unit) profit increases, as follows from

    s s)

    b = x / ( l

    -*-

    ^ )

    As an illustration of this latter remark, we present two

    numerical examples of technical change. The first is labour-saving

    and yields an increase in the (per unit) profit of each sector. The

    second

    is

    capital-saving a nd leads to a decrease in the (per unit)

    prof-

    it of the innovating sector and to increases for the other sectors:

    [0.35 0.05

    A= 0.15 0.45 0.05 |, b = | 1/3 | , l=(0.15, 0.15, 0.15), thus

    0.15 0.15

    ro.40 0.1

    = 0.20 o.f

    [0.20 0.2

    a o 0.301

    M

    = j

    0.20 0.50 0.10 .

    [0 .20 0.20 0.40 J

    Note that all rowsums are equal to 0.8, hence the Frobenius

    root of M, that is

    1/ 14-;r),

    yields 0.8 and n= 0.25. All column-

    sums are also equal to 0.8, so that p = (1 ,1 ,1 ) and s =

    7rp/(l -f ;r) = 0.2 p = (0.2, 0.2, 0.2).

    When the direct labour input in sector

    1

    reduces to 0.03, the

    augmented input matrix becomes

    0.36 0.10 0.301

    0.16 0.50 0.10 .

    0.16 0.20 0.40j

    The rowsums equal 0.76, hence

    1/ 14-^)

    = 0.76 and

    ;T=

    0.316.

    P= (0.857, 1.118, 1.025) and s =;*p /( l- f ^) = 0.24 p = (0.206,

    0-268, 0.246).

    Starting from the original situation again, consider a capital-

    saving technical change where each element in the first column of

    A decreases with 0.10. Then

    = [0.30 0.10 0.30

    ^A

    0.10 0.50 0.10

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    6/13

    40 E. Dietzenbacher:

    3 . Cost-ReductioD

    In the discussion on the falling rate of profit, an im po rtan t role

    has been played byO kishio s theorem (1961). Sup pose that capi-

    talists co ntem plate the ado ptio n of a technica l innov ation in sector

    i

    It

    is

    assu m ed, often implicitly, that

    the

    m arkets

    are

    fully compet-

    itive

    so

    tha t

    the

    decision

    of no

    individual firm

    has a

    measurable

    impact on,

    for

    ins tance,

    the

    relative p rices. Supp ose that each firm

    decides

    to

    in t roduce

    the new

    technology

    if it is

    cost-reducing,

    w here the pro du ction costs are evaluated

    at

    cu rren t p rices . Clearly,

    their short-run profit rate rises, yielding super profits

    and a dis-

    equil ibr ium. However , af ter the prices hav e readjusted , so as to

    equil ibrate

    the

    rate

    of

    profit again,

    the new

    rate

    of

    profit will

    be

    higher than the oldrate. S o, rough ly spea king, O kishio s theorem

    states that

    the

    rate

    of

    profit will rise

    if

    technical change

    is

    intro-

    duced

    in

    sector

    /

    when

    it is

    co st-reducing

    at

    current prices.

    The

    /th

    e lement

    of the

    vector

    pM

    gives

    the

    production costs

    (evaluatedat prices p) in s ec tor / an d is equa l to pM . Th e criterion

    of cost-reduction means that the following ineq uali ty ho lds:

    Ipjdj, l

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    7/13

    The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework 41

    heorem 2:

    Cost-reduction

    o n> yt,

    cost-extension

    n

    implies cost-reduction.

    From tjieorem

    1

    follows_that

    pj/Pj>Pt/Pi

    for all

    j^i.

    T h en ; p M '

    i M i i / P p J i

    i / d

    z J I / W

    j j j j

    = p M '. ' Q. E. D .

    To our knowledge, the converse of the Okishio theorem has

    never been stated explicitly before. This is rather surprising

    because in proving the first assertion it is not necessary to use the

    price inferences from theorem 1. The one-to-one correspondence

    above is altematively obtained by proving (i) cost-reduction

    implies

    7i>7t,

    (ii) cost-extension implies

    7i ;r) ,_theorem 1

    ipj/Pj>pi/Pi

    for

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    8/13

    42 E. Dietzenbacher:

    4.

    Extensions of tbe Basic M odel

    We conclude this paper by presenting the results for three

    extensions of the basic model as given by (2) and (3). ' First, the

    subsistence wage bundle is allowed to change, second, non-depre-

    ciating fixed capital is taken into account and, third, heteroge-

    neous labour is taken into consideration.

    Clearly, the assumption that the real wage bundle remains

    fixed is unlikely to hold in real life. Also, it is well known that the

    rate of profit m ay fall d ue to a cost-reduc ing tech nical change if

    the wage bundle is allowed to vary. Take, for example, an inno-

    vation that reduces the costs of production (evaluated in current

    prices) but at the same time leads to a higher demand for labour.

    As all firms w ould ad op t this new tech nolo gy, it is conc eivable that

    the real wage rises. It may even rise so much that the equilibrium

    rate of profit falls.

    Let the equilibrium for the new technology be specified by the

    following equations, instead of by the equations (4) and (5):

    p = ( l - l - ;*)pM and I = p 6 ,

    where b denotes the new wage bundle. Cost-reduction is defined

    again by equation (6). It should be noted that in the present case

    equation (6) is not equivalent to equation (7). The assertions with

    respect to the relative price changes are slightly weakened in

    comparison with those of theorem 1.

    Theorem 3:

    If

    n>it: pj/pj

    >

    [(1+n /il + n ]

    m in

    {p,//j,; 1}

    for all

    j =i,

    if

    7i

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    9/13

    The Im plications

    of

    Technical C hange

    in

    a Marxian Framework43

    Theorem

    4:

    If p6>pb: cost-reduction n,

    cost-equality

    =>

    n

    nn,

    cost-equality o n

    = M

    cost-extension

    n^,

    cost-equality

    =>n>n

    cost-extension

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    10/13

    44 E. Dietzenbacher:

    of the new direct labo ur inp ut of sectori as induced by the change

    in the wage bundle. For pB denotes the value of the new wage

    bundle in terms of the old wage rate. The value of the new wage

    bundle in terms of the new wage rate equals one of course, as the

    wage rate is taken as the numeraire.

    Knowledge with regards to pBpb, enables us furthermore

    to sh arpen the results in theorem 3. Fo r instance, pB>pb and

    pB = pb= l imply pB>pB. Now consider the case

    7i>jt

    and suppose that

    pi'^p,.

    Theorem 3 the n yields

    pj/pj>

    1

    --

    n)/il + n)>\

    for all

    j

    # / or, equivalently, p

    B

    > pB, which is a

    contradiction. Therefore, in case pB>pb and ^ > ; ; it follows that

    piipi/pi)il jT)/i\ n)

    for all y # i . The expres-

    sions of theorem 3 can th us be further refined by use of the

    following assertions.

    Corollary 3:

    If n>n: pB > pb=> pi< Pi,

    pB < p b Pi,

    if

    M=Tt: ph> phopi>Pi,

    pB < pb /,

    pb ,>^pE'>(H-7r)pM'.

    The following result asserts that th eorem 2 rem ains valid while

    theorem 1 is only weakened slightly.

    Theorem 6:

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    11/13

    The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework 45

    As a final extension of the basic model, heterogeneous labour

    is taken into consideration . We adop t the form ulation of Bowles

    and Gintis (1977) and Krause (1981). Assume there are mtypes of

    labour and let the direct input coefficients be given by the

    mxn

    matrix L. Each type of worker has its own subsistence wage

    bundle, given by the co lumns o fth e

    nxm

    matrix B, which is taken

    constant. The different wage rates are given by the 1 x m row

    vectorw = pB. Replacing (1) and (2), equilibrium is specified by

    the following equations;

    wL), (8)

    w

    = p B . (9)

    These equations can be rewritten as (3) with M = A

    -I-

    BL. It is

    apparent that theorems

    1

    and 2 remain valid. In addition, the

    following, similar expressions hold for the wage rates under the

    assumption that each type of worker uses at least one product

    (other than i) for subsistence.'

    Corollary 4:

    The following expressions ho ld for all /c=

    l . . .

    m:

    If n>

    Tt:

    w^/Wk> pj/pi,

    ii ii = IpjBjt = Eipj/pj)PjBjk> ipi/pi) ^PjBjt

    j

    ~ Pi^Pi) n't. Strict inequality follows from the assumption, which

    states that for all

    fc

    here is a j # iwith

    B,*

    >0

    Q.

    E. D.

    Note that the prices

    Pj

    and the wage rates w^ as determined by

    (8) and (9) are un ique up to ascalar In the basic model (1) and (2)

    the wage rate was set at unity. As a consequence

    pi

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    12/13

    46 E. Dietzenbacher: Technical Change in a Marxian Framework

    Bleany, M. (1980): Maurice Dobb's Theory of Crisis: A Comment.

    Cambridge Joumal of

    Economics4:

    7173.

    Bowles, S. (1981): Technical Change and the Profit Rate: A Simple Proof

    of the Okishio nieorem.

    Cambridge Joumal of Economics

    5:

    183-186.

    Bowles, S., and Gintis, H. (1977): ITie Marxian Theory of Value and

    Heterogeneous Labour: A Critique and Reformulation. Cambridge

    Joumal of Economics

    1: 173192.

    Dietzenbacher, E. (1988): Perturbations of Matrices: A Theorem on the

    Perron Vector and its Applications to Input-Output Models. Joumal

    ofEconomics48 :389412.

    Fujimoto, T. (1981): An Elementary Proof of Okishio's Theorem for

    Models with Fixed Capital and Heterogeneous Labour.

    Metro

    economica33 :2127.

    Fujimoto, T.; Herrero, C; and Villar, A. (1983): Technical Changes and

    their Effects on the Price Structure.

    Metroeconomica

    35: 123127.

    Herrero, C ; Jimenez-Raneda, L; and Villar, A. (1980): The Selection of

    Techniques in Multisectoral Models of Simple Production: A Mathe-

    matical Revision. Metroeconomica32:

    155171.

    Krause, U. (1981). Heterogeneous LabouT and the Fundamental Marxian

    Theorem. Review ofEconomicStudies48: 173178.

    Nakatani, T. (1980): The Law of Falling Rate of Profit and the Compet-

    itive Battle: Comment on Shaikh. Cambridge

    Joumal of

    Economics

    A

    6 5 6 8 .

    Okishio, N. (1961): Technical Change and the Rate of Profit. Kobe

    UniversityEconomic Review7: 8699.

    Roemer, J. (1977): Technical Change and the 'Tendency of the Rate of

    Profit to Fair.

    Joumal of Economic Theory

    16; 403424.

    (1979): Continuing Controversy on the Falling Rate of Profit: Fixed

    Capital and Other Issues. Cambridge Joumal of Economics3:

    3 7 9 3 9 8 .

    Salvadori, N. (1981): Falling Rate of Profit with a Constant Real Wage.

    An Example. Cambridge

    Joumal of Economics

    5: 5966.

    Schefold, B. (1978): Multiple Product Techniques with Properties of

    Single Product Systems. Joumal ofEconomics38 :

    2953.

    Seneta, E. (1981):

    Non negative Matrices and Markov Chains.

    (2nd ed.)

    New York: Springer-Verlag.

    Shaikh, A. (1978): Political Economy and Capitalism: Notes on Dobb's

    Theory of Crisis. Cambridge Joumal ofEconomics2:

    233251.

    (1980): Marxian Competition versus Perfect Competition: Further

    Comments on the So-called Choice of Technique.

    Cambridge Journal

    of

    Economics

    4: 75S3.

    Steedman, I. (1980): A Note on the 'Choice of Technique' under Capi-

    talism. Cambridge Joumal ofEconomics4:6164.

  • 8/11/2019 The Implications of Technical Change in a Marxian Framework (Dietzenbacher)

    13/13