the fall and rise of the brazilian cotton sector · the fall and rise of the brazilian cotton...

87
THE FALL AND RISE OF THE BRAZILIAN COTTON SECTOR by Johannes Lissdaniels Fredrik Saïd Madsen NATIONALEKONOMISKA INSTITUTIONEN VID LUNDS UNIVERSITET Department of Economics at the University of Lund 2011:7 Minor Field Study Series No. 215 Mailing address: ISSN 0283-1589 Nationalekonomiska Institutionen Box 7082 S-220 07 LUND Sweden

Upload: tranminh

Post on 03-May-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

THE FALL AND RISE OF

THE BRAZILIAN COTTON SECTOR

by

Johannes Lissdaniels

Fredrik Saïd Madsen

NATIONALEKONOMISKA INSTITUTIONEN

VID LUNDS UNIVERSITET

Department of Economics at the University of Lund

2011:7

Minor Field Study Series

No. 215

Mailing address: ISSN 0283-1589

Nationalekonomiska Institutionen Box 7082

S-220 07 LUND Sweden

1|84

Lund University Department of Economics Bachelor’s Thesis August 28, 2011

The Fall and Rise of the Brazilian Cotton Sector An Institutional Analysis of the Recent Success

by

Johannes Lissdaniels

Fredrik Saïd Madsen

Advisor: Yves Bourdet, Associate Professor

2|84

Abstract

Brazil has recently become the fifth largest producer and fourth largest exporter of cotton in

the world. This success story is exceptional, as the Brazilian cotton production reached record

low levels in the mid-1990s. Since then, however, production has more than recovered owing

to an impressive growth of 43 % during the last decade, which is high in comparison to the

world average of 28 %. The purpose of this thesis is to gain knowledge about the underlying

factors behind the recent success of the Brazilian cotton sector. Our findings suggest that the

emergence of a new sector structure associated with higher coordination among the actors

within the sectors and an altered incentive structure for the producers are key components in

understanding this recent success. However, there are still challenges to be solved and we

believe that further success will depend on how these challenges are met in the future.

Keywords: Brazil, cotton, structural change, co-ordination, competition.

Acknowledgements

We would like to extend our gratitude to the Swedish International Development Cooperation

Agency (SIDA) for granting us a scholarship to make this thesis possible to realize. We would

also like to thank our advisor, Yves Bourdet, for introducing us to this interesting topic.

Moreover, we would like to extend special thanks to Djalma Fernandes de Aquino at

CONAB, Hideko Tsukide Nabas at BM&F and Ricardo Zanatta Machado at the Ministry of

Agriculture for sharing their knowledge concerning data relevant for our thesis. We would

also like to express our deepest gratitude to all of the participants in the interviews we

conducted during our field study in Brazil.

3|84

4|84

Table of Contents Abstract.................................................................................................................................... 2

Acknowledgements................................................................................................................. 3

Table of Contents.................................................................................................................... 4-5

List of Charts, Tables and Figures........................................................................................ 6

List of Abbreviations.............................................................................................................. 7

1. Introduction......................................................................................................................... 8-9

Purpose and Methodology.............................................................................................. 8-9

Delimitation..................................................................................................................... 9

2. Conceptual Framework...................................................................................................... 10-11

Co-ordination and Competition.................................................................................... 10-11

3. Analytical Framework........................................................................................................ 12-14

Cotton Sector Structure and Challenges...................................................................... 12-13

Linking Cotton Sector Organization and Performance.............................................. 13-14

4. The Brazilian Cotton Sector.............................................................................................. 15-24

Historical Background................................................................................................... 15-17

Cotton Sector Structure: Traditional Cultivation....................................................... 17-19

Economic Reform and Sector Structure Transformation.......................................... 19-22

Cotton Sector Structure: Commercial Cultivation...................................................... 23-24

5. Assessing the Brazilian Cotton Sector: Process Indicators............................................. 25-55

Pricing ............................................................................................................................. 25-34

Traditional Sector Structure.................................................................................. 26-27

Market Structure for Purchase of Cotton................................................... 26-27

Government Support Programs................................................................... 27

Current Market Structure..................................................................................... 28-34

Market Structure for Purchase of Cotton................................................... 28-29

Current Governmental Price Support Policies........................................... 30-34

Credit and Input Provision............................................................................................ 34-39

Credit Provision pre-1990s.................................................................................... 35

Government Support..................................................................................... 35

Current Channels for Financing Inputs............................................................... 36-39

Public Credit Support................................................................................... 36-37

National and International Banks................................................................ 37

Agribusiness................................................................................................... 37-38

The Role of Co-operatives............................................................................. 38-39

Research........................................................................................................................... 39-45

The Development of Research through Time...................................................... 39-44

Research in the Traditional Sector Structure............................................. 39-40

Arrival of the Boll Weevil in the 1980s........................................................ 40

Intensification of Research............................................................................ 41-43

Developments in Ginning.............................................................................. 43-44

Amount of Varieties Developed............................................................................ 44-45

Extension.......................................................................................................................... 45-48

Historical Perspective on Extension..................................................................... 46-48

Traditional Extension Services..................................................................... 46

Emerging Actors in the New Sector Structure............................................ 46-48

Quality Control and Marketing..................................................................................... 48-55

History of Quality Control and Marketing......................................................... 49-53

Traditional Quality Control.......................................................................... 49

Improvements in Quality Control................................................................ 50-51

Marketing Improves Reputation.................................................................. 51-53

Performance in Quality......................................................................................... 53-55

6. Assessing the Brazilian Cotton Sector: Outcome Indicators.......................................... 56-65

5|84

Cost Base.......................................................................................................................... 56-58

Production Costs..................................................................................................... 56-58

Yields................................................................................................................................ 58-60

Trends in Yields and Production........................................................................... 58-60

Overall Competitiveness................................................................................................. 60-65

Comparative Advantages and Disadvantages...................................................... 60-61

Brazil’s Cotton Production from a World Market Perspective......................... 61-62

Measuring Overall Competitiveness..................................................................... 63-65

7. Summary & Conclusions.................................................................................................... 66-67

References................................................................................................................................ 68-78

Articles and Books.......................................................................................................... 68-74

Web Sources.................................................................................................................... 75-77

Data Sources.................................................................................................................... 78

Interviews and Meetings........................................................................................................ 79-80

Meetings .......................................................................................................................... 79

Phone Interviews............................................................................................................. 79-80

Appendix 1............................................................................................................................... 81

Appendix 2............................................................................................................................... 82-84

6|84

List of Charts, Tables & Figures Chart 1. Linking Cotton Sector Organization and Performance....................................... 14

Figure 1. Cotton Producing Regions in Brazil..................................................................... 18

Figure 2. Regional Contribution to National Production................................................... 22

Chart 2. Farm Sizes and Wealth Determining whether Having Ginning or not.............. 23

Chart 3. Brazilian Cotton Price Support System................................................................. 31

Table 1. Public Intervention in the Brazilian Cotton Sector.............................................. 33

Figure 3. Brazilian Cotton Prices.......................................................................................... 33

Figure 4. Amount of Varieties Developed, by Decade......................................................... 44

Figure 5. Performance in Quality.......................................................................................... 54

Figure 6. Input Costs.............................................................................................................. 57

Figure 7. Brazilian Cotton......................................................................................................59

Figure 8. Brazil’s Position on the World Market................................................................ 62

Figure 9. Exports & Imports................................................................................................. 64

Figure 10. RCA....................................................................................................................... 65

Figure 11. Amount of Varieties Developed, 1970-2011....................................................... 81

Table 2. Estimated Production Costs of Cotton................................................................... 82

Table 3. Regions Represented in Costs................................................................................. 83

7|84

List of Abbreviations

ABAPA – Associação Baiana dos Produtores de Algodão

ABRAPA – Associação Brasileira dos Produtores de Algodão

ACC – Adiantamento sobre Contrato de Câmbio

AGF – Aquisição do Governo Federal

AGOPA – Associação Goiana dos Produtores de Algodão

AMIPA – Associação Mineira dos Produtores de Algodão

AMPA – Associação Mato-grossense dos Produtores de Algodão

AMPASUL – Associação Sul Mato-grossense dos Produtores de Algodão

ANEA – Associação Nacional dos Exportadores de Algodão

BM&F – Bolsa de Mercadorias & Futuros

CCAB – Consórcio Cooperativo Agropecuário Brasileiro

CEPEA/ESALQ – Centro de Estudos Avançados em Economia Aplicada

CFC – Common Fund for Commodities

CFP – Companhia de Financiamento da Produção

CIRAD – Centre de Coopération Internationale en Recherche Agronomique pour le Développement

CLASPAR – Empresa Paranaense de Classificação de Produtos

COAGEL – Cooperativa Agropecária Goioerê Ltda

COAMO – Agroindustrial Cooperativa Mourãoense

COCAMAR – Cooperativa Agroindustrial Maringaense

COODETEC – Cooperativa Central de Pesquisa Agrícola

CPR - Cédula de Produto Rural

CTNBio – Comissão Técnica Nacional de Biossegurança

Embrapa Algodão – Empresa Brasileira de Pesquisa Agropecuária, Algodão

EPAMIG – Empresa de Pesquisa Agropecuária de Minas Gerais

EGF - Empréstimo do Governo Federal

FACUAL – Fundo de Apoio à Cultura do Algodão

FBET – Fundação Blumenauense de Estudos Têxteis

FOT – Free-on-Truck, Prices after Ginning

FOB – Free-on-Board, Prices when Loaded on a Boat for Export

GDP – Gross Domestic Product

GMV – Gene-Modified Variety

ha – Hectares

HVI – High-Volume Instruments

IAC – Instituto Agronômico de Campinas

IAPAR – Instituto Agronômico do Paraná

ICA – International Cotton Association

ICAC – International Cotton Advisory Committee

ICMS – Imposto sobre Operações relativas à Circulação de Mercadorias e Prestação de Serviços de Transporte

Interestadual e Intermunicipal e de Comunicação

IMAmt – Instituto Mato-grossense do Algodão

IMEA – Instituto Mato-grossense de Economia Agropecuária

INFAOL – Instituto de Fomento ao Algodão e Oleaginosas

ITMF – International Textile Manufacturers Federation

lb – Pounds

LPC – Lei de Proteção de Cultivares

MDM – Maeda Delta&Pine Land Monsanto

OCEPAR – Organização das Cooperativas do Estado do Paraná

PEP – Prêmio para Escoamento do Produto

PEPRO – O Prêmio Equalizador Pago ao Produtor

PGPM – Política de Garantia de Preços Mínimos

PPP – Public-Private Partnership

PROP – Contrato Privado de Opção de Venda

R$ – The Brazilian Currency, Real

RTCA – Regulamento Técnico de Identidade e de Qualidade para a Classificação do Algodão em Pluma

SNCR – Sistema Nacional do Crédito Rural

8|84

1. Introduction

The Brazilian cotton sector has recently experienced structural change and a tremendous

recovery in production. Before the 1990s, cotton production was mainly small-scale.1 In the

early 1990s however, the Brazilian economy underwent economic reforms leading to the fall

of the earlier sector structure as well as a profound decrease in production. Brazil became the

second largest importer of cotton in the world during this period.2 These events could have

been the end of the Brazilian cotton production, but in the mid-1990s, a new sector structure

with large-scale producers emerged. Along with the emergence of the new sector structure,

cotton production more than recovered. The growth rate in production since the mid-1990s

has averaged 3.7 % annually, which is high if compared to the world average of 2.5 %.3,4

Owing to this increase in production, Brazil managed to become the fifth largest producer and

fourth largest exporter of cotton in the world.5

The recovery of Brazilian cotton production is exceptional, especially when considering the

challenges cotton sectors generally face on the world market. Cotton prices are relatively low

in comparison to other crops and the volatility of prices also implies considerable risks for

cotton producers.6 Additionally, cotton has to compete with synthetic fibers on the world

market, making production of high-quality cotton paramount for a cotton sector to stay

competitive.

Despite these challenges, the Brazilian cotton sector has displayed a remarkable performance.

The increased cotton production since the mid-1990s has paved the way to outperforming

most cotton producing countries and resulted in success.

Purpose and Methodology

The purpose of this thesis is to gain knowledge about the underlying factors behind the recent

success of the Brazilian cotton sector. A conceptual and analytical framework recently

developed and used in a World Bank study evaluating African cotton sectors is used in this

1 Buainain & Batalha (2007), p. 48, 51; Filho & Alves (2007), p. 63.

2 Kiawu et al (2011), p. 12.

3 The numbers are based on calculations made by the authors.

4 Estur (2006), p. 10; CONAB (2011-08-01).

5 McCue (2010).

6 Tschirley et al (2009), p. 14-17.

9|84

process. By applying this framework to the Brazilian cotton sector we aim at contributing to a

deeper understanding of the recent development.

In order to obtain information for the study, semi-structured interviews with a broad range of

cotton sector stakeholders were held. Additionally, various sources of literature were

consulted together with statistics collected mainly from the Ministry of Agriculture in Brazil,

CONAB, USDA and BM&F.

Delimitation

This thesis does not consider the cotton sector as a whole. In accordance with the aim of this

thesis we solely focus on the production of seed cotton and predominately cotton lint. We

thereby exclude the resultant activities of cotton production e.g. cottonseed oil and cake

industries.

Due to scarcity of time in Brazil and the large geographical extension of the country we

choose to focus our study on the cotton production in the Cerrado,7 as the major part of

Brazil‟s cotton production is carried out there. We do not attempt to analyze current cotton

production in the South or in the North.

7 The Cerrado is irregularly distributed across 10 regions in Brazil: Goiás, Mato Grosso, Mato Grosso do Sul,

Minas Gerais, São Paulo, Bahia, Piauí, Maranhão, Tocantins and Rondônia. See Kiawu et al (2011).

2. Conceptual Framework

In order to analyze cotton sector performance in Brazil we make use of a conceptual

framework developed by Tschirley et al (2009).8 According to this framework, cotton sector

performance is closely linked with cotton sector organization, which is understood as the

institutional settings of the market and the associated degree of co-ordination and

competition.9

Co-ordination and Competition

Poulton et al (2004) argue that the neoclassical ideal model of perfect competition implies

both perfect competition and perfect co-ordination.10

In fact the only co-ordination needed in

the most basic version of the neoclassical model is vertical co-ordination of supply and

demand – co-ordination between players at different levels of the market - and this is achieved

through the price mechanism. However, North (1990) argued that “a highly sophisticated set

of institutions, which make information available and define and enforce the „rules of the

game‟ ” is implicit in the model.11

Taking institutions into account, horizontal co-ordination is

achieved through obedience of these rules that also determine the scope of the market. In this

hypothesized efficient market, there are no distractions except for the price and therefore both

competition and co-ordination are carried out effectively. In the real world of imperfections

however, where the assumptions of the model never fully hold, co-ordination can be difficult

to achieve, nor may competition be perfect.

The first concept influencing sector performance, co-ordination, is defined by Poulton et al

(2004) as “efforts or measures designed to make players within a market system act in a

common or complementary way or towards a common goal”.12

If government involvement is

low or if state capacity is weak, horizontal co-ordination – co-ordination between players at

the same level of the market – may be required for provision of public goods critical to cotton

sector performance, such as quality control and research.13

However, there are several co-

8 This framework draws on earlier work by Poulton et al (2004), Tschirley et al (2006) and Tschirley et al (2007)

among others. The framework is further presented in Tschirley et al (2009) and Tschirley et al (2010). 9 Tschirley et al (2009), p. xxv.

10 Poulton et al (2004), p. 521.

11 Poulton et al (2004), p. 521, referring to North (1990).

12 Poulton et al (2004), p. 521.

13 Tschirley et al (2010), p. 297; Kelly & Tschirley (2008).

10|84

11|84

ordination challenges that need to be solved in order for the provision to be successful.14

The

actors must first agree on what they should invest in, e.g. type of research. Secondly, they

must agree on how this should be done, e.g. how the research is to be funded and what the

distribution of responsibilities should be. Lastly, the parties need to solve how enforcement is

to be carried out, in order to handle opportunistic behavior such as free riding, e.g. consuming

the benefits of research without having participated in the production of the knowledge. If the

actors do not succeed in solving these challenges co-ordination will fail and the actors will

suffer the consequences of a lack of public goods. Alternatively, the actors organize

collectively and create institutions and organizations to handle these challenges in order to

secure provision of public goods vital to sector performance.

There is a strong link between the way in which co-ordination is carried out and the number

of actors in the cotton sector. When the sector comprises a few actors, co-ordination is likely

to be relational, “characterized by informal agreements enforced by consensus or private

sanction”.15

As the number of actors increases however, formal institutions are more likely to

co-ordinate the actors, but as Poulton et al (2004) argue, often with losses in effectiveness.

The second concept influencing sector performance is the associated degree of competition in

the market for purchase of cotton, i.e. the market to which the producers sell their product,

cotton seed or cotton lint depending on market structure. Tschirley et al (2009) define this

market as “the nature of players and entities in the sector, together with the distribution of

roles and power between them” and “the set of rules, regulations and other legal instruments

that are imposed on participants in the sector to enable it to operate and limit conflicts”.16

In

accordance with these definitions, different market structures for the purchase of cotton can

be delineated. Tschirley et al (2009) firstly distinguish between regulated marked-based

sectors.17

The former refers to national or regional monopolies and the latter refers either to a

concentrated or competitive market depending on the number of buyers.18

14

Poulton et al (2004), p. 522. 15

Ibid, p. 523. 16

Tschirley et al (2010), p. xxvi. 17

Tschirley et al (2009), p. 45. 18

Tschirley et al (2010), p. 46.

12|84

3. Analytical framework

As will be shown in the first part of this section, the degree to which co-ordination and

competition is carried out is hypothesized to influence sector performance. Different sector

structures, each with its own associated degree of the two concepts, will thus have different

hypothesized performance. In order to test these hypotheses Tschirley et al (2009) developed

an analytical framework comprising a set of empirical performance indicators, and these are

the subjects to which we will turn in the latter part of this section.

Cotton Sector Structure and Challenges

According to the conceptual framework developed by Tschirley et al (2009) cotton sector

performance is closely linked with the associated degree of co-ordination and competition.

The performances that are relevant to assess derive from four main cotton sector challenges

identified by Poulton et al (2004),19

and these challenges are:

provision of input credit to farmers

maintenance of quality control

maintenance of a high-quality research system and effective extension of resulting

research knowledge and products, and

payment of an attractive seed cotton price

Poulton et al (2004) hypothesized that small holder-based sectors with effective co-ordination

will perform better in the first three of these challenges,20,21

whereas sectors with competitive

markets for purchase of cotton are more likely to pay a higher cotton price to farmers. This

hypothesis is based on the assumption that ginners provide these services. We argue, though

that in a market structure where ginners, or more generally, the actors buying farmers‟ cotton,

have no central function as providers of these services, other actors in the sector, e.g.

19

Tschirley et al (2009), p. 51, referring to Poulton et al (2004). 20

Tschirley et al (2009), p. 47, referring to Poulton et al (2004). 21

The work by Tschirley et al (2009) serves to assess smallholder-based cotton sectors in Africa. In these sectors

ginners have a central role both as buyers of seed cotton and as providers of the services in focus of the

challenges listed by Poulton et al (2004). In these sectors there is likely to be a trade-off between competition

and co-ordination. One reason is that competition positively impacting prices paid to farmers at the same time

can undermine co-ordination among the ginneries necessary for the provision of public goods. For more

information on the reasons and consequences of the trade-off, see Tschirley et al (2009).

13|84

producers, must make sure that these services are provided. In such a market structure, co-

ordination among these actors will most certainly, ceteris paribus, facilitate this provision.

Linking Cotton Sector Organization and Performance: Empirical

Performance Indicators

Cotton sector performance depends to a great extent on how the challenges identified by

Poulton et al (2004) are met, which in turn are influenced by the institutional structure of the

market and the associated balance between competition and co-ordination. In order to assess

cotton sector performance, Tschirley et al (2009) developed empirical performance indicators

that are based on these challenges.

The performance indicators assess cotton sectors performance at various levels of the

market.22

At the producer level, the challenges identified by Poulton et al (2004) will be

analyzed by the use of five process indicators, which focus on the quality of the services

provided at producer level, as well as prices paid. The services include public good generation

– research & quality control – input provision and extension. In Chart 1, which links co-

ordination and competition to performance, the process indicators are represented by the

rectangular boxes. At the company level, the effects of how well the services are carried out

will influence cotton production and yields, as well as company cost base. Cotton production,

yields and company cost base may therefore be thought of as intermediate outcome indicators

which are also influenced by exogenous factors such as soil fertility.

Yields and cost base, along with cotton prices, taxes and subsidies, of which the latter two

largely are exogenous, are major determinants of producers‟ profitability. The cost base of

production further influences the sector‟s overall competitiveness along with quality control,

since adequate quality control results in positive sector reputation on the world market. Lastly,

a well performing cotton sector should be able to positively influence the overall economy,

i.e. have a positive macro-economic impact. These last three concepts are referred to as final

outcome indicators.

22

Tschirley et al (2009), p. 54.

14|84

15|84

4. The Brazilian Cotton Sector

This chapter serves to give the reader an overview of cotton production in Brazil. Firstly a

historical background of cotton production will be presented; both the overall development of

cotton production as well as its relation to overall economic policies will be touched on.

Thereafter follows a delineation of the sectors‟ structure in the pre-mid-1990s. Then a section

describing the events causing the collapse of cotton production in the 1990s as well as the

factors contributing to the emergence of a new production structure will be presented. Lastly,

the new sector that emerged will be described.

Historical Background

Brazil has a long history of cotton cultivation. When the Portuguese arrived in the 16th

century, cotton was already grown in the country.23

Over the course of the forthcoming

centuries cotton cultivation expanded, and by the second half of the 18th

century Brazil had

already begun exporting cotton to Europe.24

Cotton soon became an important crop for export,

along with sugar, tobacco and coffee.25

In the beginning of the 20th

century, agriculture had

become the foundation upon which the Brazilian economy was based and coffee export solely

accounted for seventy percent of Brazil‟s foreign currency revenues.26

In response to the international crisis of the 1930s, a reorientation of the Brazilian economy

began.27

The great depression had heavily affected the Brazilian export sectors and, as a

response, the Vargas regime implemented policies emphasizing self-sufficiency through

national industrialization. These new policies laid the foundation for the import-substitution

strategy that later came to dominate economic policy-making from the 1950s until the

1980s.28

The agricultural sector soon became integrated in this new national development project. The

industrialization demanded overcoming food supply and foreign reserve restrictions, and

agriculture gave, in respect to these restrictions, a supportive role.29

In order to compensate

23

Lunardon (2000), p. 1. 24

ABRAPA (2004), p. 16-17. 25

de Almeida (2009), p. 3. 26

Barros (2008), p. 3-4. 27

Guimarães (2005) p. 531. 28

Barros (2009); Guimarães (2005). 29

Barros (2009), p. 2.

16|84

the agricultural sector for the industrial bias, the government created credit and price support

programs and began investing in infrastructure and agricultural research.30

Cotton was cultivated in the state of São Paulo before the international crisis, but it was not

until the 1930s when the coffee export profoundly decreased that cotton production started to

expand.31

São Paulo soon became the leading region of cotton production in Brazil and the

state gained international reputation, as Brazil became one of the world‟s top producers.32

Cotton production continued to expand the following decades, and in the beginning of the

1960s São Paulo was still the leading region followed by Paraná.

In 1964, after the military coup, the government devaluated the exchange rate, which gave

stimulus to export. 33

In order to reduce the dependence on coffee exports, the government

initiated an agricultural diversification program, which led to further expansion of the

cultivated area in São Paulo and Paraná.34

These two policies stimulated cotton production

and a few years later Brazil became the fifth largest producer in the world, with a cotton lint

production of 600 000 tons in 1969, and the third largest cotton exporter, with an export of

400 000 tons.35

Until the 1970s, the development of the cotton sector had been closely linked to its exports, to

which the majority of the production had been designated.36

In 1973, however, the

government implemented profound restrictions on cotton exports – quantitative controls and

export taxes – in order to stimulate manufactured exports and the domestic textile industry.37

These export restrictions were in large maintained until 1988 and as a result cotton exports

fell.

In the beginning of the 1980s larger extensions of land were for the first time planted,

requiring tractors and harvesting machines.38

Production and exports increased initially. In the

mid-1980s, however, it became clear that large-scale production was not sustainable in the

30

OECD (2005), p. 69. 31

ABRAPA (2004), p. 20; Alves (2006), p. 22. 32

Brannstrom (2010), p. 169. 33

Guimarães (2005). 34

Guimarães (2005); Kiawu et al (2011), referring to Barros (2009). 35

Alves (2006), p. 23-24. 36

Ibid, p. 24, 32. 37

Ibid, p. 25. 38

Macdonald (2009).

17|84

South. At this time, the international cotton price reached low levels, which, in combination

with higher production costs and the advancement of boll weevil, resulted in decreased

production.39

During this period, although still accounting for 10% of world exports, Brazil

became a major importer of cotton for the first time.40

The import substitution strategy had indeed shown good performance until this point in time,

contributing to an average growth of 7.5 % from 1945 to 1980.41

However, growth had come

at the expense of high inflation, balance of payments problems and a large external debt.42

These factors contributed to what became known as the “lost decade” for Brazil and the

demise of the import substitution strategy. The cotton sector became profoundly affected by

the macroeconomic shift that followed and it would take almost a decade for cotton

production to recover.

Cotton Sector Structure: Traditional Cultivation

The cotton sector prior to the mid-1990s was in large small-holder based and production was

mainly carried out in the southern parts of Brazil in the states of São Paulo and Paraná, even

though the largest area was cultivated in the North East, as seen in Figure 1.43

Although

attempts at large-scale production were made in the beginning of the 1980s, cotton was, until

1997, predominantly handpicked and labor-intensive. Estimates show that over one million

cotton cultivators were active in the 1970s.44

Cotton seeds were exclusively provided by the government, through regional institutions such

as CATI in São Paulo and CAFE do Paraná in Paraná. In some parts of the country, e.g. the

North East, cotton seeds were subsidized and provided by federal states.45

After the harvest farmers sold their seed cotton directly, or through intermediaries, to

ginneries.46

Intermediaries were mostly used when the geographical distance to the ginnery

was long, or when farmers cultivated on rented land. In the latter case, farmers sold their seed

39

Buainain & Batalha (2007), p. 4. 40

Ibid, p. 50. 41

Barros (2008), p. 4. 42

OECD (2005), p. 31. 43

Filho & Alves (2007), p. 53. 44

Interview Cotton Consultoria (2011-07-27); Interview IAPAR (2011-08-02). 45

Interview ABRAPA (2011-07-21). 46

Barros & Beltrão (2008), p. 1274.

18|84

cotton to the landowner that later sold the seed cotton to a ginnery. Most commonly however

farmers sold their seed cotton directly to ginneries.

The market structure for the purchase of seed cotton,47

i.e. level of competition between

ginneries, was market-based during this period, albeit concentrated. Barros and Beltrão (2008)

describe the market as an oligopsony, i.e. a market comprising few buyers.48

After ginning, cotton lint could either be sold to the domestic market or for export. When

sold to the domestic market, brokers – so-called corretores – were often used as

intermediaries before the cotton was bought by the domestic textile industry.49

If the cotton

47

Seed cotton is the denomination of cotton directly after harvest. This type of cotton contains both fibers (lint)

and seeds. As cotton needs processing in order for textile companies to use it, seed cotton is sent to a ginnery.

When cotton has been ginned – i.e. when seeds have been separated from the lint – the cotton lint is ready to be

used in fabric production. 48

Barros & Beltrão (2008), p. 1274. 49

Ibid, p. 1275.

19|84

lint was designated for export, exporters bought cotton before selling to the importing

country.

The cotton sector during this period demonstrated a low level of co-ordination, i.e. actors in

the supply chains did not in general engage in collaboration with one another.50

However,

among farmers collaboration could be strong. In Paraná for example, farmers were organized

in co-operatives, which were largely based on knowledge and traditions of immigrating

Europeans, who had brought their associative spirits to the new land.51

Small and medium-

sized farmers sought to create economies of scale through this kind of collaboration. Co-

operatives had an important role in e.g. providing warehousing, and in a few cases the co-

operatives provided ginning services.52

Farmer collaboration through co-operatives did not

extend much beyond Paraná, and in other parts of Brazil farmers were less organized.

Economic Reforms and Sector Structure Transformation

In the late 1980s, the financial ability of the Brazilian government had collapsed and it

became apparent that the import substitution strategy was no longer affordable.53

As a

consequence, a great restructuring of the economy began. This restructuring later became

known as the Washington Consensus and entailed trade liberalization, deregulation of

domestic markets and privatization of state owned enterprises.54

Still, it was not until 1994,

when the Real Plan was implemented, that the government began to get inflation under

control. Continuing the trade liberalization, Brazil entered MERCOSUL, a customs union

with other South American countries.55

The cotton sector in particular, and agricultural sector in general, was heavily affected by the

restructuring of the economy. At the end of the 1980s the government could no longer finance

the agricultural support programs from which the cotton sector had benefited. Credit support

was curtailed, the minimum price fell sharply and liberalization of the cotton trade began in

1988.56

50

BNDES (1997), p. 4. 51

Pessa (2007), p. 92; Interview OCB (2011-07-20). 52

Pessa (2007), p. 109-110; Massuda (2005), p. 5; Interview Cotton Consultoria (2011-07-27). 53

Kiawu et al (2011) p. 11; OECD (2005), p. 70. 54

Kiawu et al (2011) p. 11; OECD (2005), p. 31. 55

OECD (2005), p. 31. 56

Kiawu et al (2011) p. 11; Alves (2006), p. 38; CONAB (2011-08-01).

20|84

Non-tariff barriers and export licensing were eliminated, and the import tariff was reduced

from 55 % in 1987 to 10 % in 1988-1989 and to 0 % in 1990-1994.57

However, agriculture also benefited from the opening of the economy. Foreign investment,

technology, inputs and machinery now became available for domestic producers who, for

some commodities, managed to increase their production despite falling commodity prices,

for instance because input prices fell more rapidly than commodity prices.58

For cotton production however, these reforms brought a severe crisis. Cotton producers, who

previously both benefited from government support and protection, now suffered from their

own inefficiency when forced to compete with the world market.59

Cotton production fell

from 750 million tons in 1988-1989 to 465 million tons in 1996/1997,60

and Brazil went from

being a net exporter of cotton in the late 1980s to becoming the world‟s second largest

importer in 1996-97.61

The cultivated area in Brazil fell from 2229.6 thousand ha in 1988/89

to 657.5 thousand ha in the 1996/97 season.62

It is estimated that the crisis in cotton

production from the mid-1980s to the mid-1990s directly caused unemployment of about 800

000 producers, leading to one of the largest and fastest urban migrations in peacetime in the

modern history of Brazil.63

Simultaneously with the ongoing crisis, a new phase in the Brazilian cotton history began.

This new phase began in 1988 in the state of Mato Grosso when Grupo Itamarati – a farm in

Campo Novo do Parecis in Mato Grosso – started to seek crop rotation alternatives for soy

produced in the region.64

Cotton turned out to be the perfect crop rotation alternative as it

consumes nitrogen, extensively left in the land by the soy plant.65

At this time there were no

seeds on the market adapted to the specific agro-ecological conditions in the Cerrado.

Responding to this situation, Grupo Itamarati began working together with Embrapa Algodão

and Fundação MT to develop varieties adapted to the region‟s specific conditions.66

The

57

Alves (2006), p. 39; Kiawu et al (2011), p. 28. 58

Kiawu et al (2011), p. 13; OECD (2005), p. 12. 59

Buainain & Batalha (2007), p. 50. 60

The authors‟ calculations based on data from CONAB. 61

Kiawu et al (2011), p. 12. 62

CONAB (2011-08-01). 63

Buainain & Batalha (2007), p. 48. 64

Freire (2007), p. 27. 65

Macdonald (2009). 66

ABRAPA (2004), p. 23; Alves (2006), p. 49.

21|84

breakthrough came with the variety CNPA ITA 90 in the 1992/93 season and the producers

subsequently started to experiment by rotating soy with cotton.67

However, it was not until the

1997/98 season that cotton production started to expand in the Cerrado.

There are several reasons why cotton production started expanding in the 1997/98 season.

Firstly, diseases had struck soy cultivation, which increased the demand for crop rotation.68

Secondly, the price of soy decreased significantly in the mid-1990s at the same time as the

cotton price increased and therefore it became more profitable to cultivate cotton in relation to

soy. Moreover, the price of land decreased in the Cerrado relative to the price of land in the

South - i.e. São Paulo and Paraná and as a consequence many soy farmers moved their

production from the South to the Cerrado where they subsequently started to cultivate

cotton.69

Prior to the cotton expansion in the Cerrado, there were no co-operatives in the region.70

Cultivation of cotton demanded expertise that could classify cotton lint and it was not viable

for every producer to set up a laboratory on the farm. Cultivators from the South had begun

moving to Mato Grosso in the 1980s taking with them their organizational experience and

know-how, and based on this knowledge producers now started to create co-operatives that

built laboratories for classification.

Cotton production was far from a safe bet. The producers faced a lot of different challenges

that had to be overcome in order for production to be viable. The producers decided to unite

to confront these challenges and, as a result, the association AMPA was created in September

1997. During the same year, producers, concerned over a tax on commercialized cotton, the

ICMS (usually 12 % on merchandise in circulation), decided to go to the federal government

in Mato Grosso. With such low margins as the producers faced, this tax had a profound

impact on the profitability and viability of the production.71

The negotiations with the federal

government resulted in the creation of PROALMAT, a cotton incentive program. It was

agreed that producers associated with AMPA would get a 75 % reduction of the ICMS if

satisfying a number of conditions specified by PROALMAT, emphasizing sustainability, e.g.

67

Pessa (2007), p. 94. 68

Buainain & Batalha (2007), p. 65. 69

Interview OCB (2011-07-20). 70

Pessa (2007), p. 110. 71

Interview Libero Commodities (2011-07-13).

22|84

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

19

76

/77

19

78

/79

19

80

/81

19

82

/83

19

84

/85

19

86

/87

19

88

/89

19

90

/91

19

92

/93

19

94

/95

19

96

/97

19

98

/99

20

00

/01

20

02

/03

20

04

/05

20

06

/07

20

08

/09

20

10

/11

Shar

e o

f P

rod

uct

ion

(%

)

Season

Figure 2. Regional Contribution to National Production North North East Center West South East South

Source: CONAB. Note: The shares for the season 2010/11 is an estimate.

control of pests and diseases.72

With this tax reduction cotton cultivation continued.

Furthermore, 15 % of the reduction was to go a fund – administrated by the foundation

FACUAL73

– supporting inter alia cotton research, marketing and commercialization.74

The events during the period from 1988/89 to 1997/98 resulted in a shift of cotton production

from the South to the Cerrado (see Figure 2). The more favorable climate in the Cerrado could

now be exploited, thanks to the development of new varieties.75

The topography in the

Cerrado also permitted mechanization of production. Larger areas now became cultivated and

cotton cultivation in Brazil shifted from being small-scale and labor-intensive in the South, to

large-scale and capital intensive in the Cerrado.76

The events throughout the late 1980s to the

mid-1990s thus not only resulted in a regional shift of cotton cultivation but also in a

structural transformation of the cotton sector. The new structure that emerged will be more

thoroughly described in the following section.

72

SEFAZ-MT (2011-08-27). 73

Since FACUAL later became renamed as IMAmt, we will onwards refer to the foundation as IMAmt. 74

Pessa (2007), p. 94. 75

Barros et al (2007), p. 56. 76

Buainain & Batalha (2007), p. 51; Filho & Alves (2007), p. 63.

23|84

Cotton Sector Structure: Commercial Cultivation

Currently, cotton is predominantly cultivated in the Cerrado by commercial firms that use

mechanized production techniques. The number of producers in the cotton sector has varied

over the last 5 years from about 1000 to 2000 producers.77

The majority of the producers‟

main crop is soy, which is rotated with cotton and commonly corn. Only a few producers

have cotton as a main crop.

The cost-base for cultivating cotton in the Cerrado necessitates a rather large cultivated area

in order for the production to be viable. Therefore production is carried out on a large scale.

As shown in Chart 2, most producers take advantage of the associated economy of scale and

vertically integrate ginning in their production. Today, about 90 % of the approximately 270

ginneries are owned either by single producers or co-operatives.78

Producers can also hire

independent ginning companies or traders to perform this service, where the former gin about

10 % of national seed cotton and the latter 1-2 %.

In the current sector structure cotton seeds are supplied by three sources: by companies

developing varieties, e.g. Bayer, Dow, Syngenta, by co-operatives, e.g. COMDEAGRO, or by

dealers, i.e. independent firms specialized in selling seeds.79

In contrast to in the previous

structure, the government has no role in supplying cotton seeds.

77

Interview ABRAPA (2011-07-21). 78

Buainain & Batalha (2007), p. 57; Interview ABRAPA (2011-07-21); Interview Libero Commodities (2011-

07-13). 79

Interview AMPA (2011-08-01); Interview Monsanto Algodão (2011-07-29).

24|84

After ginning, producers sell their cotton lint through intermediaries to the domestic market or

for export. Brokers operate as intermediaries on the domestic market and traders operate as

intermediaries when selling for export. We would define the market for purchase of cotton lint

as market-based and competitive. The market will be further delineated by pricing.

Concerning organization among producers, the majority are organized in co-operatives

specialized in a number of different functions. These functions are inter alia helping producers

with commercializing of cotton, purchase of inputs and provision of public goods such as

quality control. The common denominator defining a co-operative is that a co-operative is a

commercial organization comprising producers and in contrast to an association has the legal

right of selling and purchasing products and services.80

Co-operatives are usually financed

through single membership dues and have no objectives but providing the services demanded

by the members.81

It is common that producers are members of several co-operatives, thereby

accessing the broad range of services available.

Most producers are also members of producers associations inspired by AMPA. There are

now eight state associations represented nationally by ABRAPA founded in 1999.82

ABRAPA is considered to be the legitimate representative of Brazilian cotton producers and

its members represent 96 % of the total area cultivated, 99 % of the production and 100 % of

exports. ABRAPA‟s mission is to represent and promote the interest of the Brazilian cotton

producers domestically and internationally, for both public and private stakeholders.

ABRAPA also provides assistance and support to producers, to enhance profitability of

production.

80

Interview AMPA (2011-08-01). 81

Interview UNICOTTON (2011-07-08). 82

ABRAPA (2011-08-27).

25|84

5. Assessing the Brazilian Cotton Sector: Process

Indicators

The conceptual framework generates hypotheses concerning cotton sector performance based

on sector organization. More precisely, the way in which the sector is organized is

hypothesized to influence concepts vital for sector performance captured by the process

indicators. The first process indicator presented in this section – pricing – is influenced by the

organizational structure of the cotton sector through the market where producers sell their

cotton. A competitive market is expected to offer producers higher prices whereas a

concentrated market is expected to offer less attractive prices to the producers. The remaining

four process indicators – credit & input provision, research, extension and quality control –

according to the theory are influenced by the level of co-ordination among actors in the

sector, where a higher level of co-ordination, ceteris paribus, is hypothesized to facilitate

provision of these services. We will now turn to each of these process indicators in more

detail.

Pricing

The price that producers receive for cotton influences to a large extent the incentives to

cultivate the crop. Producers‟ decision to invest in cotton production is however determined

by more factors than solely the cotton price. Most producers cultivate several crops – most

commonly soy, cotton and corn – and commercial producers base their decision of which crop

to cultivate for the next season on the expected relative profitability between the crops,

influenced by relative prices and costs.83

Additionally, producers must manage the risk

associated with crop cultivation, deriving e.g. from volatile commodity prices. The investment

decision is taken under the restraint of the specific agronomical restrictions producers face

and the process mostly results in a diversification of the planted crops where cotton normally

accounts for up to 15 % of the cultivated area, a higher share of cultivated cotton entails a risk

few producers are willing to take. Given this, a higher cotton price most certainly, ceteris

paribus, stimulates increased production.

According to the conceptual framework, the degree to which producers receive an attractive

price is influenced by the market structure for purchase of cotton, i.e. the competition among

83

Interview Libero Commodities (2011-07-13).

26|84

buyers. As we have seen, this market structure changed profoundly during the 1990s. We will

therefore examine the incentive structure for cultivation of cotton before and post

restructuring of the sector in the following sections.

Moreover, as cotton prices are very volatile on a seasonal basis, the government has

developed price support programs in order to reduce the risk associated with cultivation and

stimulate production.84

We argue that in order to understand the trajectory of cotton

production in Brazil, these programs have to be taken into account. Therefore, also the

government‟s price support programs will be described before and after the restructuring of

the sector.

Traditional Sector Structure

Market Structure for Purchase of Cotton

In the traditional sector pre-mid-1990s, cotton was mainly cultivated by small and middle-

sized farmers who either directly or through intermediaries sold their seed cotton to ginneries.

According to Barros & Beltrão (2008), the market for purchase of seed cotton pre-mid-1990s

could be characterized as an oligopsony, i.e. a market comprising few buyers.85

Ginners had

considerable bargaining power under which farmers had little opportunity to influence the

price. Moreover, cotton farmers did not gain from delivering cotton of good quality. However,

if they delivered cotton of low quality, they could receive a lower price. Another sources

indicates that ginneries only paid farmers based on weight, fully leaving out the influence of

quality in setting the price.86

The gains from cotton cultivation thus did not seem to accrue to the producers in the

traditional sector structure, but to other downstream agents.87

We can furthermore conclude

that producers in the traditional structure had poor incentives to deliver cotton with good

quality. Nonetheless, producers did benefit from a government support program that

guaranteed a minimum price for their seed cotton. Given the high volatility of the cotton

84

Interview Ministry of Agriculture (2011-07-19). 85

Barros & Beltrão (2008), p. 1274. 86

BNDES (1997), p. 2. 87

There does not seem to exist any data from which we can calculate exactly how large share of the FOT price –

i.e. ex-ginnery – producers receive.

27|84

price, this program was essential for keeping producers in business during periods of low

market price. This program is the subject to which we now turn.

Government Price Support programs

The first price interventions for agricultural commodities in Brazil were introduced in the

1940s, when PGPM was established together with a governmental intervention agency CFP,

today known as CONAB.88

Since the beginning, PGPM has operated through various

instruments to establish minimum prices, using both credit programs and direct governmental

purchases (AGF).89

In the 1980s, the minimum price of seed cotton was set in relation to

production costs. AGF was the main instrument used to establish the minimum price and

purchases were carried out by CFP. In order to reduce the high cost associated with

warehousing of purchased cotton the government also offered marketing loans – EGF –

enabling farmers to withhold their cotton seed in periods of low market price. The farmers

could then, at the end of the loan term, sell their cotton at the market price and repay the loan,

or sell their product directly to CPF receiving the minimum guaranteed price.90

AGF was

however associated with high administrative and warehousing costs, and, most notably, the

program demanded a large amount of resources in order to finance the purchases. In 1985 for

example, the AGF alone accounted for purchases of 1 000 000 tons of seed cotton and in 1988

for purchases of 200 000 tons.91

At the end of the 1980s the price support program became a

heavy burden for the government‟s budget and furthermore, the required funds contributed to

inflation. Thus, as the financial ability of the Brazilian government was curtailed, the

minimum prices froze and by 1990 the price had fallen by 50 % compared to its level in 1981.

The freeze of the minimum price in the beginning of the 1990s contributed to a large extent to

the collapse of cotton production. Therefore, in response, the government continued, during a

few years, despite monetary and fiscal restrictions, to support agricultural production through

price interventions and preferential loans.92

Once again, however, these interventions led to

high costs of warehousing and fiscal stress. At this time, it became apparent that agricultural

price support policies needed to be reformed.

88

Cruz (2007), p. 4; OECD (2005), p. 71. 89

Cruz (2007), p. 4-7. 90

OECD (2005), p. 71-73. 91

CONAB (2011-08-01). 92

OECD (2005), p. 73, 76.

28|84

Current Market Structure

Market Structure for Purchase of Cotton

Today, cotton cultivation is mainly carried out by commercial firms in the Cerrado that have

control over the crop until processed to cotton lint. The market that is of interest to study is

therefore the market for purchase of cotton lint.

A producer can choose to sell cotton lint either directly or through a co-operative to a buyer.

Most producers choose to sell through co-operatives as these organizations provide services

that can be of benefit when commercializing the crop. By uniting in co-operatives producers

take advantage of economies of scale and can thereby inter alia employ professional managers

that help the members to commercialize their cotton. Producers are free to be members in

several co-operatives if preferred. When this is the case, they simply choose to sell their

cotton through the co-operative that offers the best contact. In practice these co-operatives

help producers to find buyers and elaborate information upon which producers can base their

selling decision, e.g. market prognosis. Co-operatives also have an advantage in that they can

sell larger quantities of cotton than single producers can do individually. Thereby, the

bargaining power in negotiations with buyers increases. In the Cerrado, the first co-operative

uniting cotton producers for commercializing of cotton was UNICOTTON, created in 1998 in

Mato Grosso.93

Today UNICOTTON represents 10 % of the total production in Brazil.

Producers also benefit from other entities when commercializing their cotton. IMEA created

in 1998 is one good example. The institute, created by producers, is a non-profitable

organization that aims at contributing to the development of the sector.94

IMEA provides

information and strategic analyses of which crops that are profitable to cultivate for each

season. Producers also receive market analyses and statistics on which their investment

decisions can be based.

Producers choose between selling cotton for the domestic market or for export. When selling

for the domestic market, brokers serve as intermediaries between the seller and the domestic

textile industry. For this service they receive a commission of generally 0.1 % of contract

value. Brokers thereby have incentives to offer as lucrative contracts as possible to producers.

93

UNICOTTON offers far more services than just commercialization, for example classification. 94

Interview IMEA (2011-07-13).

29|84

Producers can sell directly to the domestic industry as well, but this is less common. When

selling for the export market, producers sell their cotton to traders. There are however some

traders that sell cotton to the domestic industry as well. There are currently about fifteen

traders active on the cotton market, of which the majority entered the market in the early

2000s. Between these traders there exists a competitive environment and we find no reasons

to suspect that the producers do not receive a fair market price.95

In May 2010 a new trader entered the market, named Libero Commodities.96

This newly

established trader is a co-operative founded by producers representing 75 % of the

Brazilian cotton producers. Through this establishment the competition among the traders will

most likely increase further.97

Nevertheless, cultivating cotton entails a large risk associated with the volatile cotton price. In

order to handle this risk producers generally sell their cotton in advance using futures

contracts. Through this contract the producers hedge against future price fluctuations and can

thereby operate in a more secure environment. About 60 % of the Brazilian cotton production

is sold through this mechanism before harvest and some 15-20 % is sold already before

planting.98

Future contracts are usually used more frequently when selling to traders than for

the domestic industry. A disadvantage of using future contracts, though, is that the market

price may be higher than the exercise price when the contract expires. When this occurs, the

contract hinders the seller from taking advantage of the more lucrative market price.

According to the current president of ABRAPA, there were many producers that could not

take advantage of the high cotton price for this reason.99

95

The price traders receive when selling the cotton for export is not known to the public. Calculating the share

producers receive of the price offered to traders is therefore difficult. To calculate it indirectly is also hard since

all traders sell with future contracts. Therefore, we cannot simply take the spot world market price as an estimate

for the price offered to traders. 96

Interview Libero Commodities (2011-07-13). 97

The producers will thus soon know the previously unknown margin of the traders, as Libero Commodities

operate on the market with the same conditions as the other traders. 98

Interview COOALESTE (2011-07-06); Interview IBA (2011-07-22); Interview Libero Commodities (2011-

07-13). 99

G1 (2008-08-27).

30|84

Current Governmental Price Support Policies

The current price support program is inspired by the support program active in the US until

1988 and stems from a number of policy revisions implemented in 1996.100

In contrast to the

previous program, based on covering production cost, the current system aims at reducing

price instability while maintaining domestic prices at around world market levels. A further

goal is to reduce the fiscal burden of the system, while providing a small subsidy to producers

suffering high cost associated with underdeveloped infrastructure.101

This new price support

system operates through an interaction of various forms of governmental purchases, price

equalizations and credit support programs as delineated in Chart 3. We will now go through

the main instruments operating to ensure the minimum guaranteed cotton price.

AGF is the traditional price support program in Brazil and consists of direct governmental

purchases carried out by CONAB. In the current system, the volume of purchases is limited

by the budgetary funds allocated to the program for each season.102

The program is mostly

active when periods of excessive domestic supply coincide with limited export

opportunities.103

The cotton stocks acquired by CONAB are then ideally sold to the domestic

market when the domestic supply is weak and import is limited.

In 1996 the government introduced a government sell option contract. The aim of this

instrument was to extend the government‟s commitment to protect producers from price falls,

despite facing limited budgetary resources, while reducing the direct purchases carried out

through AGF.104

Producers and co-operatives can buy the put option, announced by CONAB

usually during harvest, by paying a price, called premium, at a public auction. The contract

gives the holder the right to sell the cotton in the future for a predestinated price, called an

exercise price, comprising the minimum price plus storage costs, when the contract expires.105

100

OECD (2005), p. 77. 101

Ibid, p. 19. 102

OECD (2005), p. 77. 103

Stefanelo (2005), p. 56-57. 104

Ibid, p. 35-36, 77-78. 105

Bitencourt et al (2008), p. 8.

31|84

The holder of the contract chooses to exercise the option if the market price at this time is

below the exercise price. In this case CONAB is responsible for buying the cotton for the

exercise price. In order to further reduce direct purchases, however, the government initiates

auctions where CONAB may buy back or transfer the option.106

In the first case – Recompra

dos Contratos de Opção de Venda – the government bays back the option from the option

holder in a reversed auction. The producer or co-operative then sells the cotton on the market

for the market price and receives the difference between market price and the exercise price

established in the option contract from the government. In the second case – Repasse dos

Contratos de Opção de Venda – the government pays a subsidy to a third party that assumes

responsibility for buying the cotton if the contract is exercised. Through these mechanisms,

the government minimizes the potential direct purchases associated with the option contract

while fewer financial resources are required.

106

Stefanelo (2005), p. 81.

32|84

PEP – introduced in 1996 – is another instrument that serves to reduce budgetary funds and

public stockholding while guaranteeing the minimum price.107

In auctions arranged by

CONAB, commercial buyers of cotton are offered a premium. The premium represents the

difference between the minimum guaranteed price and the price the buyer is willing to pay.

The buyer who is willing to accept the lowest premium in the auction wins. The producer then

receives a payment equal to the minimum price and the buyer receives the cotton. In this way

the government avoids making actual purchases.

For the 2004/2005 season a new option contract was released. This option contract – PROP –

is similar to the government sell option with the difference that in this case it is commercial

buyers that purchase the cotton, and not the government.108

The role of the government is

instead to organize auctions establishing the parties of the option contract.

In 2006 a new instrument for cotton price support was introduced – PEPRO – under the

influence of lobbying from ABRAPA.109

The premium is a subvention paid by the

government to producers and co-operatives that meet the requirements of ICMS. The

premium is based on the difference between the market price and the minimum guaranteed

price and paid to the producers when the market price is below the minimum guaranteed

price. A key difference with this program compared to the previous programs is that it

promotes exports by compensating producers when the US$ weakens in relation to the R$.110

In Table 1 the years in which the minimum price support was active is shown by charting the

development of the ESALQ/BM&F and the minimum price from 1997 until June 2011. The

ESALQ/BM&F price, which is the price in São Paulo, is higher than the price at farm gate but

can serve as reference price for regional cotton prices if transport costs are subtracted.

As shown by Figure 3, the ESALQ/BM&F price has been substantially higher than the

minimum price only in 2003, 2004 and 2011. All other years since 1997, the minimum price

support was active. In Table 1 we can further see that the minimum price support was

107

OECD (2005), p. 82. 108

Ibid, p. 79, 82. 109

ABRAPA (2008), p. 30. 110

Bitencourt et al (2008), p. 10.

33|84

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

R$

Year

Figure 3. Brazilian Cotton Prices Minimum price ESALQ/BMF

Source: CONAB, CEPEA/ESALQ.

Table 1. Public Intervention in the Brazilian Cotton Sector

Year Production AGF Options Executed PEP PROP PEPRO Total (b+c+d+e+f) Total/Production

a) b) c) d) e) f) g) g)/a) (%)

1990/1991 716.80 - - - - - - 0.0 %

1991/1992 667.10 - - - - - - 0.0 %

1992/1993 420.30 10.51 - - - - 10.51 2.5 %

1993/1994 483.90 5.52 - - - - 5.52 1.1 %

1994/1995 537.10 1.51 - - - - 1.51 0.3 %

1995/1996 410.00 4.19 - - - - 4.19 1.0 %

1996/1997 305.80 0.68 - - - - 0,68 0.2 %

1997/1998 411.00 0.11 - 170.03 - - 170.14 41.4%

1998/1999 520.10 70.05 45.65 229.50 - - 345.19 66.4%

1999/2000 700.30 0.47 30.27 245.52 - - 276.26 39.4 %

2000/2001 938.80 0.26 - 289.06 - - 289.32 30.8 %

2001/2002 766.20 - - 224.94 - - 224.94 29.4 %

2002/2003 847.50 5.29 - 153.00 - - 158.29 18.7 %

2003/2004 1309.40 - - - - - - 0.0 %

2004/2005 1298.66 - - 28.30 - - 28.30 2.2 %

2005/2006 1037.86 4.48 - 197.70 272.20 - 474.38 45.7 %

2006/2007 1524.00 0.39 - 1.80 - 461.70 463.89 30.4 %

2007/2008 1602.20 1.05 - - - 728.90 729.95 45.6 %

2008/2009 1213.70 - - - - 1023.70 1023.70 84.3 %

2009/2010 1194.10 - - - - 792.20 792.20 66.3 %

2010/2011 1835.00 - - - - - - 0.0 %

Source: CONAB, OECD (2005).

34|84

inactive from 1990 until the 1997/1998 season. The crisis of the cotton sector led the

government to initiate support to stimulate production that year and the minimum price was

raised with 7 % in 1997 as the program became active.111

According to our calculations 41 %

of total production benefited from the support in 1997 and in 1998 the share was 66 %. If we

take into account the option contract offered in 1998 than 91.6 % of total production was

covered by the minimum price support. It is further shown that the price support later

decreased somewhat progressively until 2003 to rebound again in 2005 to reach a cover of 84

% of production in 2008. Initially the minimum guaranteed price was established using PEP,

often in combination with EGF, and in 1998 and 1999 through the government sell option

contract. The PROP was used only one year, in 2005, and since then the instrument used for

establishing the minimum price has been PEPRO.

We thus find the government price support to be a crucial component for the rebound of

cotton production in 1997. Cotton producers who were operating in an uncertain environment

and facing low margins benefited from the reassurance that they would receive a minimum

price. Without this guarantee it is not certain that producers would have invested in cotton

production in such large extent as was done.

Credit and Input Provision

Cotton production in Brazil is to a large extent dependent on the availability of credits.

Credits are used to finance overall production costs and inputs. Compared to other crops,

cotton cultivation is expensive. Cotton cultivation faces up to 3 times as high production costs

as soy and up to 4.5 times as high production costs as corn.112

The major reasons for the high

production costs are the long cycle of cotton cultivation of 180-210 days in Brazil, the

widespread presence of diseases and pests and the poor soil fertility in the Cerrado. The

reorientation of production to Cerrado further increased the demand for financial resources, as

production became mechanized and capital-intensive. The poor availability of affordable

credits has at times been a major constraint to production. Today, the highest production costs

are costs for fertilizers and pesticides.

111

BNDES (1997), p. 4. 112

Interview Ceres Consultoria Agronômica (2011-07-08).

35|84

Credit Provision pre-1990s

Government support

Provided by the Brazilian government, rural credit has been the primary instrument for

assisting the Brazilian agriculture.113

The credits are provided through various programs in the

National Rural Credit System – SNCR – initiated in 1965. SNCR has since then played an

important role in the development of the agricultural sector by provision of subsidized credits.

In response to the macro-economic crisis in the 1980s, however, the credit support needed to

be reduced in order to combat inflation. The government subsequently introduced an

indexation of the loans granted. The indexation resulted in higher interest rates, and as the

output prices lagged in adjusting to hyperinflation, farmer‟s repayment capacity profoundly

fell. A severe debt accumulation followed and in 1995 the value of non-performing loans

reached 30 % of the total rural credit. The threat of spillover effect to the private bank sector,

lobbying from the agricultural sector and the social impact of the debt accumulation led the

government to initiate a debt rescheduling in the mid-1990s. After a number of negotiations,

it was decided in 2001 to extend the repayment period until 2025. It is now estimated that

approximately half of the overall benefits to farmers in Brazil from 1995-2004 stemmed from

this debt rescheduling.114

The crisis resulted in an 80 % decrease in credits from the 1980s to the 1990s.115

For cotton

producers that already faced low prices and higher production cost during the 1980s,

reduction of credits became yet another factor contributing to the collapse of production. The

debt crisis and hyperinflation led producers to seek alternative types of credits when the

public support curtailed.116

This process was facilitated by the liberalization and opening of

the economy as producers gained freer access to foreign markets. The legacy of

macroeconomic uncertainty is still present, though. Today, interest rates offered by domestic

commercial banks are still high and producers are generally forced to seek other financial

solutions. Subsidized credits from governmental programs still play a role although

alternative ways of accessing capital has increased significantly since the 90s.

113

OECD (2005), p. 88-90. 114

Ibid, p. 19. 115

Helfand & de Rezende (2001), p. 5-6. 116

OECD (2005), p. 91.

36|84

Current Channels for Financing Inputs

Today, producers have three main sources providing credits. These sources are public credit

support, national and international private banks and agribusiness.

Public Credit Support

Currently, the public credit support, SNCR, is administrated by the three largest banks in

Brazil – Banco do Brasil, Banco do Nordeste and Banco da Amazônia – in co-operation with

298 federal, state and co-operative banks that provides credits supported by the government to

agricultural producers.117

SNCR operates through various kinds of programs and cotton

producers have access to three categories of credits: production, marketing, and investment

credits.118

The maximum amount a single cotton producer has access to for each season, all

programs added, is 600 000 R$.119

In relation to overall cost this amount is small. Therefore,

it is mainly small producers that make use of these credits, i.e. about 30 % of all producers.

The main programs relevant for cotton producers are:

EGF is a marketing loan closely integrated with the minimum price system.120

EGF is used

when the market price is lower than the minimum price. Through this loan producers in need

of cash are able to wait to commercialize their cotton while waiting for a more lucrative

market price in the future. The size of the loan is based on the quantity of cotton times the

established minimum price, and the term of the loan is typically 180 days. Harvested cotton

serves as collateral for the loan. Simultaneously with this credit it has been common for

cotton producers to enroll in sell option programs or the PEP, as the borrowers through these

means are guaranteed the minimum price when the loan term expires which enables them to

repay the marketing loan.121

The EGF has been widely applied in the cotton sector amounting

up to 30 % of total annual funds for the program in the early 2000s, covering up to 46 % of

total cotton production.122

CPR is another instrument created by the government that enables producers to use future

contracts as collateral for receiving cash advances from the Banco do Brasil or input advances

117

Ibid, p. 72, 88. 118

Ibid, p. 92. 119

BCB (2008-08-27). 120

OECD (2005) p. 92. 121

Ibid, p. 94-95. 122

Ibid, p. 94.

37|84

from agribusiness.123

Cash advances are limited to 50 % of the future contract value. CPR has

been successful in the sense that through this legally enforced document agricultural

producers have been helped to receive private financing. For cotton producers the CPR was

used most in 2004 and 2005 and accounted during these two years for 20 % of the SNCR

designated for the cotton sector.124

In addition to the marketing loans described above, producers have access to production

loans, which aim to stimulate production through provision of subsidized interest rates, of

8.75 % (2011).125

The loans are used to buy inputs for planting and have a term of about 9

months. It is estimated that cotton producers have received up to 75 million US$ annually

during the last decade in subsidized interest rates.126

Concerning investment credits, one of the

most important programs is MODERFROTA, which give loans to farmers buying agricultural

machinery. Since the mid-1990s, this program has played an important role in agricultural

mechanization in Brazil.127

National and International Private Banks

Interest rates offered by the domestic banks are high, about 20-25 %.128

Generally, producers

do not have such high margins and are therefore forced to seek financing through other

channels. The largest producers, about 10-15 % of all producers, have been able to access the

international banking market and subsequently managed to benefit from the lower

international interest rate.129

To some extent, producers have been able to benefit from

domestic banks through ACC, which enables producers that have sold their cotton for export

to use futures contracts to receive cash advances.

Agribusiness

As credit accessibility remains a challenge, alternative solutions have emerged where

producers to a large extent finance inputs through agribusiness. To some degree producers can

receive loans from agribusiness when purchasing goods. A good example is the multinational

company John Deere, the largest firm selling machinery in Brazil, which offers financial

123

OECD (2005), p. 88; USDA (2008-08-27). 124

Kiawu et al (2011), p.15. 125

FETAG-AL (2008-08-27). 126

ICAC (2011), p. 5. 127

OECD (2005) p. 104, referring to Brandão and Rezende (2004). 128

ICAC (2011), p. 7. 129

Interview Libero Commodities (2011-07-13); Interview IBA (2011-07-22).

38|84

solutions through its own bank. About 45 % of all machinery sold to cotton producers by the

firm is financed through the John Deere Bank.130

One alternative financial method is to use

future contracts as collateral when buying inputs. Producers can thereby gain access to inputs

before planting, and later pay for the purchase when receiving the payment for the cotton

specified in the future contract. In this way, producers can access inputs used for planting

even though they may not have access to cash or credit at that time. When credit accessibility

has been particularly scarce, producers have sometimes had the opportunity to pay firms

selling inputs with cotton. This method, called barter, has been particularly used when buying

pesticides.131

However, cotton producers have not managed to obtain adequate financing through these

sources described above. The lack of available credits has been and still is one of the major

obstacles producers face. In 2007/2008 the difficulty of obtaining credits resulted in a 25 %

decrease in area for 2008/2009.132

Due to the lack of financial possibilities in that season,

producers switched to soy cultivation.133

Estimates indicate that cotton producers financed 40

% of the production from their own pocket in 2008/2009, comparing to an estimated average

of 7 %.

The Role of Co-operatives

In order to reduce cost of inputs, most producers organize in co-operatives. In this way, larger

quantities can be bought at a lower the price. One successful example is UNICOTTON which

has managed to reduce pesticide costs by 30 % for its members.134

Another example is the co-

operative CCAB that was created in order to reduce the costs of fertilizers and pesticides.

Today, CCAB unites 69 000 producers from different agricultural sectors and represents 65 %

of cotton production.135

Initially the co-operative managed to reduce the price for fertilizers

by approximately 15 %. The market for fertilizers is controlled by a few companies and for

this reason producers today have a lower possibility of influencing the price, which has

increased significantly. The role of co-operatives has been further extended to include

130

Interview John Deere (2011-07-04). 131

ABAPA (2008-08-27). 132

ABRAPA (2010), p. 104. 133

Hrapsky & Autry (2009), p. 3. 134

UNICOTTON (2008-08-27). 135

MDIC (2008-08-27).

39|84

production of certain inputs. The co-operative COOPERBIO is an example of this and was

recently created to produce energy that could be used by its members.136

In the delineation of this process indicator, we have presented the channels through which

producers access credits and inputs. According to the conceptual framework, access to capital

and inputs is influenced by co-ordination among the actors in the sector. We can conclude

though, that even though producers do collaborate, e.g. to reduce input prices, access to

capital remains low. It thus appears as if access to credits is mainly determined by exogenous

factors and that the bottleneck of accessible credits mainly stems from the poorly developed

financial sector in Brazil.

Research

The objective of research in the Brazilian cotton sector has always been to increase viability

of cotton cultivation, and research has recently also contributed to environmentally friendly

technologies. In order for research to be efficient, it has to contribute to higher fiber quality,

higher productivity, lower input costs, region-specific technologies as well as resistance to

diseases and pests. Research is of critical importance to satisfy these aims and its importance

stems from two sources. Firstly, input costs are relatively high in cotton cultivation and

research must therefore aim to lower these costs.137

Secondly, diseases tend to mutate over

time, and research must thus continue to infinity as new technologies always have

to be developed to counter new threats.

The Development of Research through Time

Research in the Traditional Sector Structure

Prior to the restructuring of the cotton sector in the 1990s, research had mainly been public. It

all began in 1921 when the Ministry of Agriculture recognized the importance of promoting

improvement of varieties, as cotton always has been subject to diseases and pests impeding

productivity.138

Owing to this recognition, the first genetic improvement program was

initiated by the public institution IAC in the state of São Paulo in 1924, aiming at developing

136

COOPERBIO (2008-08-27). 137

Bélot et al (2005), p. 492. 138

Freire et al (2007b), p. 267.

40|84

region-specific technologies.139

In the 1970s, new public institutions emerged with similar

aims, inter alia IAPAR in Paraná (1972), EPAMIG in Minas Gerais (1974) and Embrapa

Algodão in Paraíba (1975).140

Some private research initiatives were taken as well before the

restructuring in the 1990s – e.g. by INFAOL and Algodoeira São Miguel141

– but these were,

as we later will show, of limited importance in comparison to public actors‟ research

contributions.

Arrival of the Boll Weevil in the 1980s

Coinciding with the debt crisis and the end of the ISI period in the late 1980s, a severe

outbreak of the boll weevil occurred.142

The pest soon turned out to be the most devastating

pest in Brazil‟s cotton history as substantial decreases in yields followed as a consequence of

its arrival.143

Embrapa Algodão quickly realized the severity of the pest and began to conduct

research on alternative crops for cotton producers.144

Since the boll weevil not only was a

nation-specific pest, but also had migrated to Argentina and Paraguay, it soon evoked

international attention. This led to the birth of an internationally co-ordinated research project

headed by the international organizations ICAC and CFC.145

The first steps of this project

were taken in 1995, when the projects‟ participants – in Brazil‟s case IAC, IAPAR, Embrapa

Algodão and Instituto Biológico – were summoned to a workshop at IAPAR‟s headquarters in

Londrina, Paraná. This workshop had two aims; the first was to present existing knowledge of

the pest and the second was to “define the division of work between participating

institutions”.146,147

As the project progressed, three more workshops were held to present the

findings. All the countries involved benefited from the project, as the project resulted in

productivity-increasing and environmentally friendly pest management technologies, i.e.

integrated pest management. These new technologies were later transferred to extension staff

in the participating countries, and have since then contributed to an improvement of Brazilian

cotton cultivation.148

139

IAC (2008), p. 36. 140

IAPAR (2010), p. 9; Embrapa Algodão (2000), p. 9-10; EPAMIG (2011-08-20). 141

Junior (1996), p. 157. 142

Embrapa Algodão (2000), p. 11-12. 143

Praça (2007), p. 6; Sendin & Stadler (2002), p. 2. 144

Embrapa Algodão (2000), p. 11-12. 145

Stadler (2001), p. 4-8. 146

Sendin & Stadler (2002), p. 6. 147

The quote was translated from Portuguese to English by the authors. 148

Stadler (2001), p. 45-48.

41|84

Intensification of Research

Public research institutions would still prove to have a significant role in the new sector

structure, but the involvement of the private sector was soon to become increasingly

pronounced as cotton cultivation entered a new phase. When the relocation of cotton

cultivation began in 1988, no varieties adapted to the Cerrado‟s ecological conditions had yet

been developed.149

Traditional varieties were not productive enough in the new environment,

and Grupo Itamarati – which often is referred to as the pioneer of cotton cultivation in the

Cerrado – hence began importing varieties from Israel. Embrapa Algodão was later invited to

evaluate the results of the newly imported varieties, but neither the productivity nor the

quality was high enough in order for cultivation to be viable. Grupo Itamarati and Embrapa

Algodão therefore established a public-private partnership (PPP) in 1989 to increase viability

of cotton cultivation in the Cerrado. In the three-year period 1989-1991, the PPP evaluated 70

varieties, both imported varieties – for instance from the US and Egypt – as well as nationally

developed varieties from IAPAR, IAC and EPAMIG. The PPP bore fruit in 1992 as the new

variety CNPA ITA 90 had been developed. According to Suinaga (2003), much of the

development of cotton cultivation in the Cerrado can be traced back to this variety, owing to

the rise in productivity the variety led to.150

CNPA ITA 90 was more than twice as productive

as traditional varieties, and the variety was also adapted to mechanized harvest which was

perfect for the large-scale system that became implemented in cotton cultivation in the 1990s.

Although the development of CNPA ITA 90 was a huge step forward for cotton cultivation in

the Cerrado regions, yields fell dramatically in the second half of the 1990s due to the advent

of the “blue disease”.151

Cotton producers then realized that co-ordinated research investments

would be needed so as to assure the profitability of cultivation, and research thus began to be

conducted within foundations in order to combat diseases and pests. The first foundation in

which cotton producers united – together with Grupo Itamarati and Embrapa Algodão – was

within Fundação MT in Mato Grosso (1995),152

and a new PPP was hence established. From

this point onward, new foundations began to emerge throughout the Cerrado, inter alia

Fundação GO in Goiás (1997), IMAmt in Mato Grosso (1998), Fundação BA in Bahia (1999)

149

Freire (2007), p. 27-29; Freire et al (2007b), p. 269-276; Suinaga (2003), p. 14. 150

Suinaga (2003), p. 14. 151

Freire (2007), p. 34-35. 152

Fundação MT was already founded in 1993 to satisfy the needs of soy producers. However, as cotton started

to encounter difficulties, the foundation extended its research activities to cotton in 1995.

42|84

and Fundação Centro-Oeste in Mato Grosso (2000).153,154

All of these foundations established

PPPs with Embrapa Algodão with a shared aim, namely to develop region-specific varieties

by cross-breeding already existing varieties, and CNPA ITA 90 became a vital variety utilized

to satisfy that aim.

What also spurred the creation of new foundations was a change in legislation, which would

also give incentives for multinational companies to invest in research in the Cerrado.155

In

1997, a new law on variety protection – LPC – was implemented, awarding royalties to actors

that develop varieties. As LPC together with the “blue disease” spurred the creation of new

foundations, multinational companies – such as Bayer, Syngenta, Dow and the joint-venture

MDM156

– entered the market, all with the objective of developing new varieties and pest

management technologies.157

Some of these multinational companies have established PPPs together with Embrapa

Algodão, such as Monsanto (1997) and Syngenta (2010),158

and a few of them have also got

gene-modified varieties (GMVs) approved for commercialization by CTNBio, the public

institution for testing and approving GMVs. CTNBio began approving these varieties in 2005

after a change in biosafety legislation and has until now approved five types of GMVs –

Bollgard® I, Bollgard

® II, Round-up Ready

®, WideStrike™ and LibertyLink

® – originating

from Monsanto, Dow and Bayer.159

Evidence of GMVs‟ effects on the environment and on

productivity has so far been ambiguous, but most evidence nevertheless points at positive

economic and environmental effects.160

As GMVs display both resistance against pests and

resistance against weedicides that otherwise would kill the plant, cotton producers can thus

decrease the amount of chemicals used and so decrease input costs in cultivation.161

153

Freire et al (2007b), p. 42-43, 268-291; FACUAL (2006), p. 15-17; Freire (2004); Bélot et al (2005), p. 483. 154

The partnerships between Embrapa Algodão and Fundação MT, and Embrapa Algodão and Fundação Centro-

Oeste ended in 2000 and 2006 respectively. However, the rest of the partnerships mentioned in this chapter have

been intact since their establishment. 155

Bélot et al (2005), p. 482-483; do Nascimento & da Silva (2008), p. 5-6. 156

MDM was a joint venture between Grupo Maeda, Delta & Pine Land and Monsanto. As the joint venture was

acquired by Monsanto in 2007, we will henceforth refer to MDM as Monsanto. 157

Monsanto (2010), p. 4-7; Bayer (2008), p. 8; Syngenta (2010), p. 19. 158

Branco & Vieira (2010), p. 43; Syngenta (2010), p. 36. 159

Monsanto (2010), p. 6-8; Bayer (2010), p. 9-11; Levy (2009), p. 1; CIB (2009), p. 9-11; Krieger (2006), p. 1. 160

See for instance Krieger (2006), CIB (2009), Torres (2008) and Nunes (2009). 161

Interview IMAmt (2011-06-21).

43|84

Another private actor that has contributed research in the Cerrado is the co-operative

COODETEC; the research began as a project within an umbrella organization for co-

operatives OCEPAR in partnership with CIRAD – a French development agency – in Paraná

(1990). 162

As a result of an initiative taken by the thirty-eight co-operatives members of

OCEPAR, COODETEC became an own entity in 1995.163

COODETEC then continued both

the partnership with CIRAD and the research project conducted by OCEPAR, aiming at

developing new technologies. COODETEC extended its research activities to the Cerrado in

1999, and in 2008, COODETEC‟s research program was acquired by IMAmt.164

This

acquisition has been successful as new varieties with resistance to diseases, higher fiber

quality and higher productivity have been developed as a consequence.

Partnerships have also become more common between public institutions, such as between

IAPAR and IAC.165

The reason for participating in these kinds of partnerships, according to

de Almeida, researcher at IAPAR, is that the potential for technological development is

increasing. Owing to that actors involved in a partnership get access to each other‟s

germplasms,166

each actor has a bigger set of genes to work with and thus also a bigger

potential of developing improved varieties. This is a huge advantage and also a reason for

why PPPs and other types of partnerships have become increasingly common in research.167

Developments in Ginning

In the mid-2000s, it was revealed that cotton producers had problems obtaining the quality

needed to satisfy the demand on the world market.168

As ginning has a significant impact on

fiber quality, and as quality of fibers determines both prices received as well as demand for

cotton lint, associations – i.e. AGOPA in Goiás, ABAPA in Bahia and AMPA in Mato Grosso

– invested in a research program so as to improve the ginning process.169

The program

involved replacing old cotton gins with new gins in order to increase cotton quality, and

analyses were carried out during the period 2005-2006 to evaluate the results of the project.170

162

Freire et al (2007b), p. 298; Bélot et al (2005) ; p. 482-483; Alves (2006), p. 55. 163

COODETEC (2011-08-13); Biotecnologia (2011-08-15), p. 4-7. 164

Filho et al (2010), p. 10-11. 165

Interview IAPAR (2011-08-02). 166

Germplasms are collections of seeds and genes used when developing new varieties. 167

Interview Monsanto (2011-07-29); Interview Embrapa Algodão (2011-07-25); Interview IAPAR (2011-08-

02). 168

UNICOTTON (2006), p. 9. 169

Chanselme et al (2007), p. 2; Interview IAC (2011-08-02). 170

Chanselme et al (2007), p. 3, 16-20.

44|84

5

16

4 12

17

24

5

7

20

5

28

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

1970-1979 1980-1989 1990-1999 2000-2009

Am

ou

nt

of

Var

ieti

es

Decade

Figure 4. Amount of Varieties Developed, by Decade Private Foundations Private & Multinational Companies Public Public Private Partnerships

Source: See Appendix 1.

The net effect turned out to be positive, as the amount of thrash diminished, and middling and

reflectance improved, but the amount of neps increased.171

There is therefore still much room

for improvement, but as this program identifies the strong and weak links in the supply chain,

it will be possible, according to Ribas (2009), to obtain enhanced viability of cotton

cultivation with similar programs in the future.172

Amount of Varieties Developed

The number of developed varieties is the indicator we use to assess the performance of

research, and as can be seen in Figure 4, the development of new varieties has increased

substantially during the past two decades. Comparing the 1990s to the 1980s, an increase of

183 % can be noted. A similar comparison between the 2000s and the 1990s shows an

increase of 156 %, and the most impressive comparison would be to compare 1990-2009 to

1970-1989 where the total increase reaches 481 %.

During the 1970s and 1980s, the private sector had a limited role, when actors such as

Algodoeira São Miguel and INFAOL developed varieties, but these actors did not develop

171

Neps are tangled clusters of fibers. See section 5.1.5.2. for a description of fiber characteristics. 172

Ribas (2009), p. 53-56.

45|84

any more varieties after the 1970s. Instead, the public sector had the main role prior to the

restructuring and has since the 1970s developed more varieties with each decade. When the

restructuring took place in the 1990s, more varieties were developed as a result of new

partnerships, co-ordinated research investments by producers and the advent of multinational

companies. This trend was positive until approximately ten years ago when the

amount of developed varieties began to display a negative trend (see Appendix 1).173

The reason for this negative trend mainly stems from the fact that producers often only pay

royalties to the actors developing varieties once. Since most of the producers have their own

ginneries, many producers keep the seeds after processing. Producers can then either plant

these seeds the following season, or sell the seeds to other producers. By these means,

producers have the possibility of only buying seeds once and thereafter reproducing the seeds

themselves. Reproducing seeds of varieties developed before the implementation of LPC is

permitted according to the law, but difficulties are encountered when producers reproduce

seeds of varieties developed after the law‟s implementation. As earlier mentioned, actors

developing varieties are entitled to royalties, but as approximately 50 % of the seeds planted

each year have been reproduced by producers, opportunities to receive royalties are often lost.

Disincentives to develop new varieties have therefore appeared. The reproduction of seeds

can also lead to other problems, e.g. to the erosion of the seed market as has been the case of

soy in Rio Grande do Sul where dealers had to withdraw their activities. The Ministry of

Agriculture has realized that the law is vaguely defined and is therefore currently revising the

law in order to tackle the problem.174

It is hence likely that the law soon will be changed and

that more royalties in the future will be paid.

Despite problems of receiving royalties, however, co-ordination between producers, as well as

co-ordination between public and private actors on the market, has ensured a substantial

increase in varieties available for production. Consequently, production has become both

more viable and more environmentally friendly since the mid-1990s.

Extension

In order to cultivate cotton efficiently, cotton producers must possess knowledge in many

areas, such as how to manage pests, weeds and diseases, what products to use against them,

173

Bélot et al (2005), p. 491; Interview IMAmt (2011-06-12); Interview Ministry of Agriculture (2011-07-21). 174

Interview Ministry of Agriculture (2011-07-21).

46|84

how these threats impede production, how to manage soil, fertilization, harvesting etc.175

The

aim of extension, i.e. technical assistance, is to transfer knowledge of these areas to cotton

producers, enabling them to take decisions themselves regarding what has to be done in the

fields. Extension is therefore an important factor in cotton production, as efficient extension

results in increased viability.

Historical Perspectives on Extension

Traditional Extension Services

Extension activities began in the 1960s as a public initiative through the institutions CATI in

the state of São Paulo and EMATER in Paraná and in the Northeast.176

These institutions

provided extension to all cotton producers in Brazil, except in Paraná, where approximately

50 % of the producers received extension from co-operatives. These co-operatives – e.g.

COAMO, COOPAVEL and the umbrella organization for co-operatives OCEPAR – were

financed by cotton producers. Public institutions and co-operatives were to provide extension

until the 1990s, when public institutions and co-operatives terminated their extension

activities. Existing extension practices had not been adequate enough to handle the boll

weevil, and this pest – along with the debt crisis – ensured the demise of extension in the

traditional sector structure.

Emerging Actors in the New Sector Structure

When cultivation moved to the Cerrado in the 1990s, extension services also went through a

substantial change. Most of the to-be cotton producers in the Cerrado had never cultivated

cotton before the restructuring, and they therefore demanded knowledge in order to make

cultivation possible.177

Since cotton producers now were larger, they had access to more

capital and could therefore afford to hire private consulting firms to satisfy their needs.178

Hence, along with the expansion of cotton cultivation, the number of consulting firms in the

Cerrado also increased.179

Today, it is estimated that approximately a thousand consultants

provide extension in the Cerrado, and these consultants stay for months and even up to a year

175

Sanchez (2005), p. 1-2; Interview Ceres Consultoria Agronômica (2011-07-08). 176

Junior (1996), p. 157; Interview Cotton Consultoria (2011-07-27); Interview CATI (2011-07-28). 177

Interview Cotton Consultoria (2011-07-27). 178

Interview Ceres Consultoria Agronômica (2011-07-08). 179

Interview Cotton Consultoria (2011-07-27).

47|84

on the farms in order to solve problems encountered in the field.180

Many of the consulting

firms – such as Círculo Verde in Bahia and Ceres Consultoria Agronômica in Mato Grosso –

also have their own cultivation fields where they can assess new management technologies.181

Additionally, consulting firms often have access to a portion of a cotton producer‟s area

where they can observe how new management technologies work in practice.182

More capital does not only contribute to the possibility of hiring consulting firms, but the

largest cotton producers also have a full-time employed agronomist on their farms.183

These

agronomists provide extension and assist cotton producers in decision-making. The largest

cotton producers thereby vertically integrate extension in their activities and do not require the

services of consulting firms when they employ an agronomist.

Despite this fact, all cotton producers in the Cerrado receive extension from consulting

firms.184

In Mato Grosso do Sul and Minas Gerais, consulting firms are the only actors on the

market providing extension services. In Mato Grosso, Goiás and Bahia, however, extension is

also provided by associations and foundations. The reason is that cotton producers need

extension advice that is more general – i.e. extension that deals with problems all cotton

producers confront – and cotton producers therefore make co-ordinated investments in

extension services.185

Extension is therefore also provided by the foundations Fundação GO

and Fundação MT, and by the associations ABAPA and AMPA through their affiliated

foundations FUNDEAGRO and IMAmt.186

The associations have so-called ATRs – i.e.

extensionistas – that travel to farms regularly to collect data, and cotton producers are later

informed about problems in cultivation through field days, reports, courses etc.187

Extension services are to a certain extent also provided by multinational pesticide

companies.188

In the end of the 1990s, companies such as FMC, BASF and IHARA entered

the Brazilian cotton sector and when these companies sell pesticides to cotton producers,

180

Interview Ceres Consultoria Agronômica (2011-07-08). 181

Interview Ceres Consultoria Agronômica (2011-07-08); Interview ABAPA (2011-08-10). 182

Interview Ceres Consultoria Agronômica (2011-07-08). 183

Interview IMAmt (2011-06-21). 184

Interview AMIPA (2011-08-10); Interview AMPASUL (2011-08-10); Interview Cotton Consultoria (2011-

07-27) 185

Interview AMPA (2011-08-01). 186

Alves (2006), p. 55; Interview AGOPA (2011-08-10). 187

Interview ABAPA (2011-08-10); Interview IMAmt (2011-06-21). 188

Interview IMAmt (2011-06-21).

48|84

information on how to use these pesticides is also provided when delivered.

IHARA does not only provide extension when pesticides are sold, but the company also

participated in the creation of the group GBCA in 2000.189

The aim of the group‟s creation

was to gather the most experienced consulting firms in the Brazilian cotton sector so as to

concentrate all existing knowledge on how to solve problems in cotton cultivation. GBCA

currently consists of one extensionista from IHARA and twelve consultants from consulting

firms throughout Brazil, representing approximately 60 % of total cotton production. GBCA

regularly holds meetings to discuss problems in cultivation, and trips are also organized to

different regions in order to collect information about new management technologies. These

technologies are later evaluated in the consultants‟ own regions in order to assess the new

technologies‟ adaptability. The group therefore exhibits considerable multiplier effects as

knowledge created at one place in Brazil becomes dispersed to the rest of the country through

GBCA. Since consultants within GBCA co-ordinate their actions aiming at optimizing

cultivation, cotton producers have benefited substantially from the creation of

GBCA as both cotton producers and the group share the same aim.

Our findings indicate that the adequacy of extension has risen during the past two decades.

Co-ordination between producers, between consulting firms as well as co-ordination between

countries – i.e. the internationally co-ordinated project headed by ICAC and CFC mentioned

in research – have assured that cotton producers currently receive high-quality extension

services. Owing to these factors, extension services are today more viable than in the

traditional sector structure.

Quality Control & Marketing

Well-functioning quality control and marketing systems influence demand positively and are

vital in order for a cotton sector to stay competitive on the world market190

. When supplying

cotton of high quality, cotton producers receive a premium – i.e. a higher price – and together

with a well-functioning marketing, commercialization of cotton is facilitated due to cotton

producers gaining a good reputation. Cotton also has to compete with synthetic fibers – e.g.

polyester – and delivering cotton of high quality is therefore paramount for cotton producers‟

189

IHARA (2010), p. 36; Interview Ceres Consultoria Agronômica (2011-07-08); Interview Cotton Consultoria

(2011-07-27); GBCA (2011-08-12). 190

Tschirley et al (2009), p. 21-26, 90-91.

49|84

survival on the market. Textile companies also benefit from well-functioning quality control

as these companies gain the possibility of buying the adequate cotton needed for a specific

fabric.191

Textile companies can thus adjust their spinners to the fabric being produced and by

these means optimize the production process.

History of Quality Control and Marketing

Traditional Quality Control

Quality control was mainly carried out by public institutions and co-operatives before the

demise of the traditional sector structure. The public institutions BM&F in the state of São

Paulo and CLASPAR in Paraná – founded in 1918 and 1957 respectively – were the two first

institutions to conduct quality control in the Brazilian cotton sector.192

In the 1970s, co-

operatives in Paraná – such as COCAMAR, COAMO and COAGEL – also began conducting

quality control.193

Although these actors classified cotton and aimed at raising the awareness

of quality‟s importance among cotton producers, both the quality and reputation of Brazilian

cotton were rather poor, partly due to the traditional sector structure‟s characteristics and

partly due to inadequate quality control.194

Since cotton producers operated in an oligopsony,

buyers of cotton had a larger bargaining power than cotton producers, leaving cotton

producers without rewards for delivering high-quality cotton. No premium was to be received

for delivering cotton of high quality, and when delivering low-quality cotton, cotton

producers were penalized by receiving a lower price. Additionally, quality control was

inadequate due to deficient equipment and the character of classification. The equipment used

for classifying cotton was both slow and far from standardized, and much classification was at

the time manual and visual.195

These classification methods were not precise enough to

provide a multidimensional and adequate analysis of cotton quality. Cotton producers thus did

not have the incentives needed to produce cotton of high quality, as many fiber characteristics

could not be measured and no premia could be collected.

191

Sestren & de Lima (2007), p. 765, 772; Ferreira et al (2008), p. 1238. 192

Brannstrom (2010), p. 174; CLASPAR (2011-08-23). 193

Interview FBET (2011-08-02); Interview COCAMAR (2011-08-22); Interview COAMO (2011-08-23). 194

Barros & Beltrão (2008), p. 1273-1274; Interview EISA Interagrícola (2011-08-12). 195

Filho & Alves (2007), p. 79-80; Interview EISA Interagrícola (2011-08-12); Interview FBET (2011-08-02).

50|84

Improvements in Quality Control

Quality control remained fairly unchanged until the end of the 1990s, when new actors on the

market emerged to provide classification services. After cotton cultivation had moved to the

Cerrado, cotton producers had nowhere to classify cotton, except for public institutions and

co-operatives in the states São Paulo and Paraná. As these states were geographically distant

from the Cerrado, classifying cotton was expensive for cotton producers since cotton had to

be transported long distances to be classified.196

In order to reduce transport costs, cotton

producers decided to make co-ordinated investments in classification laboratories in co-

operatives and associations throughout the Cerrado. These investments led to the creation of

the co-operatives ALLCOTTON in Goiás (2000), and UNICOTTON (1998) and

COOPERFIBRA in Mato Grosso (2001),197

and to the inauguration of laboratories within the

associations AMIPA in Minas Gerais (2006), AMPASUL in Mato Grosso do Sul (2007),

ABAPA in Bahia (2009) and AGOPA in Goiás (2011).198

Furthermore, other actors moved to

the Cerrado to classify cotton owing to cotton producers‟ demand. BM&F has today affiliates

throughout the Cerrado, and Kuhlmann – an international company that came to Brazil in

2006 – also provide classification services.199

Coinciding with the emergence of new actors on the market, electronic and more precise

classification methods – i.e. high-volume instruments (HVI) – also became adopted.200

As

mentioned earlier, classification in the traditional sector structure was not standardized, and

manual and visual methods were utilized. In the new sector structure however, a significant

standardization has occurred owing to a new law that came into force under the Ministry of

Agriculture in 2002.201

This law – RTCA – aimed at stimulating exports through adopting

international standards in cotton classification, and HVI began to be adopted by actors on the

market already in 2003. Today, all cotton is classified using HVI and the method measures

fourteen characteristics of cotton quality.202

As HVI is more precise in comparison to manual

and visual methods, more characteristics of cotton are taken into account in classification.

196

Interview AMIPA (2011-08-10). 197

dos Santos et al (2005), p. 2; Interview UNICOTTON (2011-07-08); Interview COOPERFIBRA (2011-08-

10); ALLCOTTON (2011-08-24). 198

Interview ABAPA (2011-08-10); Interview AMIPA (2011-08-10); Interview AMPASUL (2011-08-10);

Interview; AGOPA (2011-08-10). 199

Interview Kuhlmann (2011-08-12); Interview COOPERFIBRA (2011-08-10). 200

Interview FBET (2011-08-02). 201

Fiedler (2007), p. 821. 202

Interview Multigrain (2011-07-08); Interview UNICOTTON (2011-07-08).

51|84

Since cotton producers are also more aware of cotton quality, they have greater incentives to

produce high-quality cotton.203

Classification of cotton is not compulsory according to RTCA, but if classification is to be

carried out, regulations and norms under the law have to be followed. Cotton graders204

need a

long education to classify cotton, and being acknowledged and licensed by the Ministry of

Agriculture is necessary.205

The norms – specified as ISO 9001:2008 – set standards for inter

alia color of clothes used and temperature in the laboratory, and usage of equipment.

According to international standards, the equipment used in classification must be calibrated

every hour in order to avoid distorted quality measures.

Since all actors classifying cotton do not possess the technical capacity required to follow all

these norms and regulations, some of these actors receive technical assistance and regular

audits from other actors on the market. Two of the actors providing technical assistance and

auditing are Kuhlmann and FBET.206

FBET is a foundation founded by textile companies in

1967, aiming at providing classification services to textile companies. As FBET was founded

so early, the foundation has both credibility and experience, and the co-operative

COOPERFIBRA and the associations AMIPA and AGOPA therefore have partnerships with

FBET. Since Kuhlmann also has many years of experience, the associations AMPASUL and

ABAPA have similar kinds of partnerships with Kuhlmann. In these partnerships, FBET and

Kuhlmann provide technical assistance and auditing to ensure that norms and regulations are

followed. If any of the norms or regulations are not met, FBET and Kuhlmann have the right

to terminate the partnerships, and some actors have already had to withdraw their

classification activities owing to incredibility. Since credibility is vital in order for co-

operatives and associations to classify, these actors have incentives to ensure that norms and

regulations are followed. The partnerships mentioned above have been intact so far.

Marketing Improves Reputation

Due to the poor reputation of Brazilian cotton in the end of the 1990s, Brazil encountered

difficulties exporting cotton.207

As cotton cultivation expanded, cotton producers began

203

Filho & Alves (2007), p. 79-80. 204

A cotton grader is a person whose job is to classify cotton. 205

Sestren & de Lima (2007), p. 773; Interview UNICOTTON (2011-07-08). 206

Interview Kuhlmann (2011-08-12); Interview FBET (2011-08-02). 207

Interview EISA Interagrícola (2011-08-12).

52|84

supplying more cotton than was demanded by the domestic textile industry.208

Since cotton

producers had nowhere to sell the remaining cotton owing to its reputation and lack of

networks abroad, AMPA initiated marketing activities in 1998, aiming at promoting Brazilian

cotton on the world market. When ABRAPA was founded in 1999, ABRAPA took over and

extended AMPA‟s marketing activities, and executives from all associations affiliated to

ABRAPA currently engage in marketing activities in order to promote Brazilian cotton

abroad.

Marketing activities are carried out in two ways, either by going abroad to attend international

events or by receiving guests from other countries. ABRAPA has so far both participated in

international conferences – arranged by e.g. ICA, ICAC and ITMF – and received guests from

other countries, for instance from China, Japan and Indonesia.209

When ABRAPA receives

guests, ABRAPA generally gives an overview of Brazilian cotton cultivation, and organizes

trips to ginneries and cotton fields in order to display ginning and harvesting for the visitors.

ABRAPA is not the only association that has conducted marketing activities, since ANEA –

an association founded by traders in 1999 – also has promoted Brazilian cotton abroad.210

In

2006, ANEA – together with BM&F – initiated a program to improve the reputation of

Brazilian cotton on the world market, as well as to ensure that traders prioritize cotton of the

highest quality for exports.211

If traders obey the rules of the program, they are allowed to

participate. However, if any of the traders damage the program‟s credibility, ANEA has the

right to exclude that trader.

When cotton production began to increase in the end of the 1990s, marketing activities were

of vital importance for cotton producers. As the domestic market became saturated and the

reputation was poor, co-ordinated marketing efforts through AMPA, ABRAPA, and ANEA

and BM&F ensured that cotton producers had markets to which they could sell their cotton.

Without these marketing efforts, producers would have been less prone to produce more as

domestic demand already was satisfied. Co-ordinated marketing activities thereby constituted

208

Interview AMPA (2011-08-01); Interview ABRAPA (2011-07-21). 209

ABRAPA (2010), p. 36; ABRAPA (2008), p. 26-29; ABRAPA (2007), p. 34-43; Interview AMPA (2011-08-

01). 210

ABRAPA (2008), p. 26-29; Interview EISA Interagrícola (2011-08-12). 211

ABRAPA (2008), p. 26-29; ANEA (2011-08-24).

53|84

an important factor in increasing production, as these activities improved the reputation of

Brazilian cotton and thereby made new markets accessible.

Performance in Quality

As out-lined above, fourteen characteristics of cotton are measured when classifying cotton.

These characteristics can be divided into two groups, namely intrinsic and extrinsic

characteristics.212

Intrinsic characteristics are those only affected by the type of cotton

cultivated, i.e. the inherent traits of a variety. Some of the intrinsic characteristics entail

resistance, elongation, fiber length, uniformity of fiber lengths and micronaire, which is a

measure of fiber maturity and fineness. Extrinsic characteristics on the other hand are those

affected by external factors, for instance weather, harvesting and ginning. Reflectance,

middling (whiteness), leaf grade (amount of foreign material and contamination) and the

amount of neps (clusters of tangled fibers) are some examples of extrinsic characteristics.

Cotton has to be of high quality – intrinsically and extrinsically – for a cotton producer to get

a high premium. In order for actors on the market to know how to value cotton of a certain

quality, base quotations have been implemented.213

Base quotations determine what quality

cotton should exhibit in order to be valued according to the world market price. If cotton

would be of higher quality than the base quotation, cotton producers receive a higher price

than the world market price and vice versa. This rule applies to all characteristics except for

micronaire, where the best quality is the base quotation.

In Figures 5a-5f, quality data is presented. Middling and leaf grade, resistance and uniformity,

show tendencies of improvement, and micronaire has been relatively stable. Fiber length has

also improved during the past two decades, but has historically been longer (see Figures 5e

and 5f). The reason that cotton had longer fibers before the 1990s is that another species of

cotton was cultivated, namely tree cotton.214

As upland cotton – which had shorter fibers –

was more adapted to mechanized harvesting, this species substituted tree cotton in the

restructuring, and the fiber length therefore decreased. Shorter fibers may seem to have

212

Ferreira et al (2008), p. 1248-1249; Ferreira & Freire (2008), p. 878-879; Marquié et al (2004), p. 7; de

Santana et al (2004), p. 216-219. 213

Interview UNICOTTON (2011-07-08). 214

Buainain & Batalha (2007), p. 50; Interview CATI (2011-07-28); Interview Embrapa Algodão (2011-07-25).

54|84

26

26,5

27

27,5

28

28,5

29

29,5

30

30,5

31

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

20

12

Ave

rage

Re

sist

ance

(gf

/te

x)

Year

a) Resistance Average Resistance Trend Base Quotation Limits

2,5

3

3,5

4

4,5

5

5,5

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

20

12

Ave

rage

Mic

ron

aire

Year

b) Micronaire Average Micronaire Trend Base Quotation Limits

79

79,5

80

80,5

81

81,5

82

82,5

83

83,5

84

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

20

12

%

Year

c) Uniformity Uniformity Trend Base Quotation

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

20

12

%

Year

d) Middling & Leaf Grade Over Base Quotation Over & Within Base Quotation Trends

26

26,5

27

27,5

28

28,5

29

29,5

30

30,5

31

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

20

12

Ave

rage

Fib

er

Len

gth

(m

m)

Year

e) Fiber Length Average Fiber Length Trend Base Quotation

23

24

25

26

27

28

29

30

31

32

33

34

19

20

19

25

19

30

19

35

19

40

19

45

19

50

19

55

19

60

19

65

19

70

19

75

19

80

19

85

19

90

19

95

20

00

20

05

20

10

20

15

20

20

Ave

rage

Fib

er

Len

gth

(m

m)

Year

f) Fiber Length, Historical View Average Fiber Length Base Quotation

Figure 5. Performance in Quality

Source: BM&F, ANEA, CONAB, Kuhlmann, USDA (2011), Gonçalves & Gonçalves (2007) and Filho & Alves (2007). Note: A detailed description on how the data was calculated is given in Appendix 2.

54|8

4

55|84

been a disadvantage for cotton producers as longer fibers equal a higher premium, but as

textile companies implemented new technologies adapted to shorter fibers coinciding with the

restructuring, the loss of fiber length was only of minor importance.215

The two factors directly contributing the most to improvements in quality during the past two

decades are research and mechanized harvesting. Co-ordinated research investments have

contributed to longer fibers and also ensured improvements in uniformity and resistance

through the development of new varieties.216

Mechanized harvesting has decreased

contamination and has therefore contributed to better results in middling and leaf grade, as

cotton today is both whiter and less contaminated. According to Beltrão, researcher at

Embrapa Algodão, the reflectance of cotton has also improved over the past two decades.

Moreover, co-ordination between producers and between associations, co-operatives and

other private actors on the market has increased the awareness of quality among producers

since standardized classification methods have been adopted. Quality – along with reputation

– has therefore improved substantially during the past two decades, giving Brazilian cotton a

competitive edge on the world market.

215

Before the restructuring, mainly ring spinning was used by textile companies. Coinciding with the

restructuring of the cotton sector, textile companies adopted rotor spinning, which did not demand as long fibers

as ring spinning. The loss of fiber length was therefore not severe for cotton producers as textile companies‟

demand still was satisfied. 216

Interview Embrapa Algodão (2011-07-25).

56|84

6. Assessing the Brazilian Cotton Sector: Outcome

Indicators217

In the previous section we have described and linked concepts vital for sector performance to

sector organization. How well these concepts and services, i.e. research, extension, quality

and input provision, are carried out is hypothesized to influence the outcome of cotton

production. In this section this outcome will be analyzed by focusing on production costs,

yields and overall competitiveness.

Cost Base

Whether production is sustainable or not from an economical perspective is largely influenced

by the overall cost of production. Overall company costs, according to the analytical

framework, are influenced by how well the process indicators perform. For example research

would have a positive impact on production costs as new varieties more resistant to pests and

diseases can be developed. New varieties could further increase production per hectare, which

would imply lower costs. An efficient extension can decrease production costs as producers

gain new knowledge of more efficient production methods and on information on how to

handle overall problems related to cultivation.

Production Costs

In this section we will examine how overall production costs have changed during the last

decade. We will pay special attention to the cost of pesticides and fertilizers, as these are the

largest costs for producers in Brazil.

As shown in Figures 6a-6d, the average production cost in Brazil has increased by 23 % since

1999 to 2009, from approximately 1.9 R$/kg to 1.5 R$/kg, according to our calculations. We

can further conclude that overall costs peaked in 2004-2005, likely under influence of the

increased costs for fertilizers and pesticides. The trend in overall production costs may come

as a surprise considering the good performance on research and extension. There are however

many factors affecting production costs that are exogenous to the framework we use, such as

weather conditions, exchange rate fluctuations, changes in taxation etc. Most likely, costs

217

Due to lack of adequate data, the final outcome indicators macro-economic impact and profitability of

companies will not be presented in this assessment.

57|84

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

19

99

/20

00

20

00

/20

01

20

01

/20

02

20

02

/20

03

20

03

/20

04

20

04

/20

05

20

05

/20

06

20

06

/20

07

20

07

/20

08

20

08

/20

09

20

09

/20

10

Shar

e (

%)

Season

c) Inputs' Share of Total Costs Fertilizers Pesticides Fertilizers and Pesticides

0

0,2

0,4

0,6

0,8

1

1,2

1,4

1,6

1,8

19

99

/20

00

20

00

/20

01

20

01

/20

02

20

02

/20

03

20

03

/20

04

20

04

/20

05

20

05

/20

06

20

06

/20

07

20

07

/20

08

20

08

/20

09

20

09

/20

10

Co

sts

(R$

/kg)

Season

a) Average Total Costs Average Total Cost

00,05

0,10,15

0,20,25

0,30,35

0,40,45

0,5

19

99

/20

00

20

00

/20

01

20

01

/20

02

20

02

/20

03

20

03

/20

04

20

04

/20

05

20

05

/20

06

20

06

/20

07

20

07

/20

08

20

08

/20

09

20

09

/20

10

Co

sts

(R$

/kg)

Season

b) Costs of Pesticides Costs of Pesticides

0

0,05

0,1

0,15

0,2

0,25

0,3

0,35

0,4

19

99

/20

00

20

00

/20

01

20

01

/20

02

20

02

/20

03

20

03

/20

04

20

04

/20

05

20

05

/20

06

20

06

/20

07

20

07

/20

08

20

08

/20

09

20

09

/20

10

Co

sts

(R$

/kg)

Season

d) Costs of Fertilizers Costs of Fertilizers

Figure 6. Input Costs

Source: CONAB, Filho & Alves (2007).

57|8

4

58|84

would have increased even more if no research or extension had been carried out. The

only way to assess the exact impact of the process indicators would be to hold all other

variables constant over time, which they seldom are in real world. Drawing conclusions

therefore becomes harder.

We can conclude that costs for pesticides and fertilizers have increased by approximately

17 % and 163 % respectively. It is further shown that their share of total costs increased

by 45 % and 56 % respectively during 1999-2009. This does not necessarily mean that

the usage of pesticides or fertilizers, i.e. the quantity consumed in kg, has increased.

Instead the increased costs can stem from higher prices. Therefore, research and

extension may have resulted in decreased use of pesticides and thus contributed to lower

costs even though the actual costs of pesticides may have increased. The increased cost

for fertilizers can be explained by the increased domestic demand resulting from

increased production.218

The supply did not manage to meet this higher demand and thus

the price increased.

Yields

Cotton lint yields are a fundamental indicator of sector performance. The efficiency of

cotton cultivation influences both company profitability and sector competitiveness.

Yields are in turn influenced by the process indicators described in the previous section.

In this section the trends in yields and production will be presented.

Trends in Yields and Production

Figure 7 shows the trends in yields, production and the amount of area cultivated from

1976/1977 to the 2010/2011 season. As shown, the trend in production is positive from

1976/1977 to 1984/1985 but becomes negative from 1984/1985 to 1996/1997. Initially

the decline is mainly caused by the arrival and spread of the boll weevil in the mid-

1980s. From 1988 to the mid-1990s the decline is mainly an effect of the liberalization

of cotton trade, the freeze of government minimum prices and reduced credit support.

During this period the traditional sector collapsed. The effects on cotton production are

severe leading to a decline in production by 370.7 million tons, from a production of

218

Interview COABRA (2011-08-17).

59|84

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

3500

4000

4500

19

76

/77

19

77

/78

19

78

/79

19

79

/80

19

80

/81

19

81

/82

19

82

/83

19

83

/84

19

84

/85

19

85

/86

19

86

/87

19

87

/88

19

88

/89

19

89

/90

19

90

/91

19

91

/92

19

92

/93

19

93

/94

19

94

/95

19

95

/96

19

96

/97

19

97

/98

19

98

/99

19

99

/00

20

00

/01

20

01

/02

20

02

/03

20

03

/04

20

04

/05

20

05

/06

20

06

/07

20

07

/08

20

08

/09

20

09

/10

20

10

/11

Yie

lds (kg/h

a) & P

rod

uctio

n (th

ou

sand

ton

s)

Are

a (t

ho

usa

nd

ha)

Season

Figure 7. Brazilian Cotton Area Production Yields

Source: CONAB.

674.5 million tons in 1983/1984 to 305.8 million tons in 1996/1997.

The relocation of production to the Cerrado and the resultant increase in production in

the 1997/1998 season leads to a trend break. As a result of research, new varieties were

developed, which for the first time enabled a larger production in the Cerrado.

Production is from this point onwards mechanized and carried out in large scale where

new technologies have been adopted. These factors increased productivity significantly.

At the same time cotton producers benefited from government support as minimum

prices and credit support were reintroduced. The positive trends in production and

productivity continue until today as research activities increase further and new varieties

are developed, albeit in a slower pace, and the new knowledge is efficiently transferred

to producers through private and associative extension. Price fluctuations and poor

access to credits have however resulted in three large production falls. The fall in 2005-

2006 was mainly a consequence of the decreased cotton prices. The international

financial crisis was the main cause of the last production fall in 2008/2009, as producers‟

access to capital sharply decreased. As a response to increased world market prices in

2010, estimated production for this season has reached a new record in Brazil with an

increase of almost 70 % in relation to last season.

60|84

Furthermore, in 2007/2008 the demand for fertilizers on the world market increased and at the

same time the domestic supply in Brazil could still not satisfy the domestic demand. These

factors consequently led to doubled fertilizer prices that year.

We thus conclude that the production cost has increased for cotton producers during the last

decade and the main reason for this increase seems to be increased fertilizer costs. Today,

fertilizer cost accounts for approximately 25 % of overall cost according to our calculations.

Overall Competitiveness

In this part of the analytical framework the competitiveness of the Brazilian cotton sector will

be examined. The section begins with a presentation on Brazil‟s comparative advantages and

disadvantages in cotton production. Thereafter, we will show Brazil‟s position on the world

market for 2009/2010. Lastly, Brazil‟s cotton trade will be presented together with the RCA

indicator of comparative advantage.

Comparative Advantages and Disadvantages

Brazil has a comparative advantage in agriculture that stems from the abundance of land.219

The area in the Cerrado alone accounts for 25 % of Brazil‟s land mass, and despite an already

large agricultural use of land there are approximately still 90 million hectares available for

cultivation.220

The possibility of extending the area for cotton cultivation is rare in an

international perspective. Together with China and Turkey, Brazil is one of a few countries in

the world with this possibility.221

The climate conditions in the Cerrado are ideal for cotton production. Cultivation benefits

from a regular rain period during the growing season from October to March, which allows

for cotton to be rain fed and not dependent on irrigation.222

This is an advantage, as cotton

plants need large amounts of water in order to grow. When the rain period is over in March,

the dry season follows. Cotton bolls then open and the plants are no longer exposed to rain,

which after the opening of the cotton bolls can contaminate the fibers. The well-defined rain

and dry periods are in this way ideal for cultivating cotton of high quality. The Cerrado being

219

OECD (2005), p. 22. 220

Macdonald (2010). 221

Bélot et al (2005) p. 492. 222

Interview Ceres Consultoria Agronômica (2011-07-08); Interview IMAmt (2011-06-21).

61|84

a savanna has furthermore a topography that permits mechanical farming, as adequate

machines cannot be used if the ground is steeper than 10 degrees.223

Cultivation in the Cerrado also has drawbacks. The poor soil fertility requires a large amount

of fertilizers and the winter lacks cold periods that kill off pests.224

For these two reasons the

usage of both fertilizers and pesticides is high.

The major obstacle for agricultural producers in Brazil is the poorly developed infrastructure.

Only 10 % of the roads in Brazil are paved and for cotton, which is solely transported by truck

within the country, often with a journey of 1500 km to the closest port, transportation costs

become high.225

For agricultural products in general, transportation costs amount to 15-20 %

of the FOB price.226

For this reason, the cost of transporting cotton in Brazil becomes about

twice as high as the cost of shipping cotton from Brazil to China.227

Brazil’s Cotton Production in World Market Perspective

Since the collapse of production in the 1990s, Brazil has emerged as a significant actor on the

world market. Figures 8a-8d show Brazil‟s position on the world market during 2009/2010. It

is shown that Brazil in that season had become the fifth biggest producers in the world

surpassed by only China, India, the US and Pakistan. In terms of yields, i.e. productivity,

Brazil has become the third most productive cotton producing country in the world, with the

highest yields of rain fed cotton of all countries.228

Concerning export, Brazil was the fourth

biggest exporter in 2009/2010 with most of the exports going to Asian countries. The biggest

importer of Brazilian cotton was Indonesia followed by South Korea, China, Pakistan and

Turkey. It is not unlikely that Brazil will become the fourth largest producer in the world

surpassing Pakistan for the 2010/2011 season. It will most likely also climb in the export

league this season.

223

Buainain & Batalha (2007), p. 22. 224

Interview Ceres Consultoria Agronômica (2011-07-08); Interview IMAmt (2011-06-21). 225

OECD (2005), p. 57; McCue (2010). 226

USDA (2008-.08-27). 227

McCue (2010). 228

Ibid.

6850

5050

2654 2019

1187

2009/2010

a) Production - World Top Ranking China India US Pakistan Brazil

2613

1390

820

433 420

2009/2010

b) Exports - World Top Ranking

US India Uzbekistan Brazil Australia

62|8

4

1844 1762

1480 1357 1313

2009/2010

c) Yields - World Top Ranking

Israel Australia Brazil Turkey Mexico

72345 66039

51763

23366 22717

2009/2010

d) Principal Destinations of Brazilian Cotton Exports

Indonesia South Korea China Pakistan Turkey

Figure 8. Brazil’s Position on the World Market

Source: ABRAPA (2010).

63|84

Measuring Overall Competitiveness

A direct indication of whether a sector is competitive or not comes from its ability to generate

surpluses,229

which can be calculated by using FOT or FOB costs and revenues. As this thesis

assesses how sector performance has changed over time, in relation to sector structure and

organization, a rather extensive FOT or FOB costs and revenues data, covering up to 20 years,

would be preferred. However, historical data on FOT or FOB costs and revenues does not

seem to exist. Therefore, we will measure cotton sector competitiveness indirectly under the

assumption that competitiveness can be “revealed” by observing trade patterns. The indicator

we will use is the revealed comparative advantage RCA.

There exist a number of different RCA measures.230

As Brazil both exports and imports cotton

we have chosen to use the RCA(3) index. The RCA(3) index is calculated for a single country

and refers solely to that country‟s own trade performance in a single commodity. The index is

calculated as follows:

Where X represents exports and M is imports and the index ranges from -1 to +1. If the index

is negative, it indicates that the country has a comparative disadvantage in that commodity

and if the index is positive the country has a comparative advantage. If the index gives values

around zero no clear conclusion can be made. As exports and imports, and thus also the

index, are affected by political restrictions on trade, we present the RCA values from 1988

and onwards as cotton trade liberalized that year.

Before we present the RCA values however, we show how exports and imports have changed

throughout the years. In Figure 9 it is shown that exports were high in the late 1960s, and as

already mentioned, Brazil became the third largest exporter in the world for a few years in the

late 1960s. In the beginning of the 1970s export fell as export restrictions were implemented.

When cotton trade liberalized in 1988, imports increased dramatically, indicating that

domestic production could not satisfy the textile industries‟ demand for cotton, which was

229

Tschirley et al (2010), p. 314. 230

Utkulu & Seymen (2004), p. 9.

64|84

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

19

60

19

62

19

64

19

66

19

68

19

70

19

72

19

74

19

76

19

78

19

80

19

82

19

84

19

86

19

88

19

90

19

92

19

94

19

96

19

98

20

00

20

02

20

04

20

06

20

08

20

10

Exp

ort

s an

d Im

po

rts

(th

ou

snd

to

ns)

Year

Figure 9. Exports & Imports Exports Imports

Source: USDA.

around 800 000 tons annually during the 1990s.231

In 1996, Brazil became the second largest

importer of cotton in the world. After two years without any exports, 1996 and 1997, Brazil

began exporting cotton again in 1998, as a result of expanded production in the Cerrado.

Since then exports have increased substantially and Brazil has grown to be one of the largest

exporters in the world.

Based on exports and imports shown Figure 9, the RCA index is calculated in order to

indirectly measure Brazil‟s comparative advantage in cotton production. As shown in Figure

10 the RCA value is close to or equal to -1 during the entire 1990s, indicating a comparative

disadvantage. As production moved to the Cerrado however, the new sector that emerged

managed to exploit the potential comparative advantage that Brazil indeed had in cotton

production. From that point onwards RCA value has increased and since 2003 the RCA has

been positive, indicating a comparative advantage.

231

CONAB (2011-08-01).

65|84

-1

-0,8

-0,6

-0,4

-0,2

0

0,2

0,4

0,6

0,8

11

98

7

19

88

19

89

19

90

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11R

CA

Year

Figure 10. RCA RCA

Source: USDA.

66|84

7. Summary and Conclusions

In the mid-1990s, cotton production in Brazil collapsed. A decade later nonetheless, Brazil

had become the fifth largest producer and fourth largest exporter of cotton in the world. The

aim of this thesis has been to gain knowledge about the underlying factors behind this recent

success. For that purpose, we have used a framework which links performance with sector

organization and the associated degree of co-ordination and competition.

We have shown that the Brazilian cotton sector underwent a profound structural

transformation in the 1990s. Prior to this change, cotton was mainly grown in the southern

regions by small-scale farmers. The market for purchase of seed cotton was dominated by a

few ginneries, which offered low prices to farmers. Co-ordination within the sector was low,

resulting in poor extension, quality control and research. In the late 1980s, a series of

accumulated problems in combination with decreasing world market prices and ceased

governmental support had an adverse impact on production. Subsequently, production fell

sharply. Coinciding with the ongoing crisis, a new phase in the Brazilian cotton production

began when producers in the Cerrado started to seek crop rotation alternatives for soy

produced in the region. At this time there were no seeds on the market adapted to the specific

agro-ecological conditions in the Cerrado. Responding to this situation, producers started to

organize and fund research that could contribute to new varieties adapted to the regions‟

specific conditions. When the breakthrough finally came in the 1997/98 season, cotton

production expanded rapidly. Thanks to the new varieties, the more favorable climate in the

Cerrado could now be exploited. Furthermore, the topography in the Cerrado allowed for

mechanized production. Production from this point on was on a large scale where many

producers took advantage of the associated economy of scale and vertically integrated

ginning in their production. Simultaneously, a competitive market to which producers could

sell their cotton gradually emerged. Producers started to organize in co-operatives and as a

result co-ordination within the sector increased which facilitated provision of public goods

vital for production. A new structure thus emerged on which, we argue, the later success

rested.

In the new structure, co-ordination improved significantly on several levels of the market,

among producers, private consultants and traders. Research, extension, quality control and

marketing improved considerably owing to enhanced co-ordination. The change in market

67|84

structure for purchase of producers‟ cotton from an oligopsony to a competitive market has in

the meantime resulted in an altered incentive structure which has stimulated cotton

production, as producers now receive higher prices for their cotton. Producers have also

benefited from governmental support that helps offset low market prices, and the new

minimum price policy in Brazil has become more sustainable by requiring less public funds

since the revision in 1996. Altogether, these changes have resulted in both increased yields

and production, and Brazil has currently the highest yields in the world of all rain-fed cotton

sectors. These changes have enabled Brazil to become a significant and competitive actor on

the world market.

Despite the recent success, the Brazilian cotton sector faces several challenges. The

availability of affordable credits is low and transportation costs resulting from the poor

infrastructure remain high. Furthermore, production costs have increased during the last

decade mainly due to increased costs of fertilizers. Also, research activities within the sector

have recently slowed down. Brazil does indeed have a huge potential in cotton production and

is currently one of a few countries in the world with the possibility of increasing the area of

cultivation. We thus believe that further success will depend on how these challenges are met

in the future.

68|84

References

Articles and Books

ABRAPA (2004), A Saga do Algodão: Das Primeiras Lavouras à Ação na OMC, ABRAPA, Brasília, Distrito

Federal.

ABRAPA (2007), Relatório de Atividades 2007, ABRAPA, Brasília, Distrito Federal.

ABRAPA (2008), Relatório de Atividades: Biênio 2006-2008, ABRAPA, Brasília, Distrito Federal.

ABRAPA (2010), Relatório de Gestão: Biênio 2008-2010, ABRAPA, Brasília, Distrito Federal.

Alves, Lucilio Rogério Aparecido (2006), A Reestruturação da Cotonicultura no Brasil: Fatores Econômicos,

Institucionais e Tecnológicos, Universidade de São Paulo, Escola Superior de Agricultura “Luiz de Queiroz”,

Piracicaba, São Paulo.

Barros, Geraldo Sant‟Ana de Camargo Barros (2008), Brazil: The Challenges in Becoming an Agricultural

Superpower,” in Lael Brainard and Leonardo Martinez-Diaz (eds.)(2009), Brazil as an Economic Superpower?

Understanding Brazil’s Changing Role in the Global Economy, Brookings Institution Press, Washington, DC.

Barros, Geraldo Sant‟Ana de Camargo Barros (2009), Brazil: The Challenges in Becoming an Agricultural

Superpower,” in Lael Brainard and Leonardo Martinez-Diaz (eds.)(2009), Brazil as an Economic Superpower?

Understanding Brazil’s Changing Role in the Global Economy, Brookings Institution Press, Washington, DC.

Barros, Geraldo Sant‟Ana de Camargo Barros, Lucilio Rogério Aparecido Alves, Humberto Francisco Spolador,

Mauro Osaki, Daniela Bacchi Bartholomeu, Andreia Cristina De Oliveira Adami, Simone Fioritti Silva,

Guilherme Bellotti de Melo & Matheus Henrique Scaglica P. de Almeida (2007), The Brazilian Cerrado

Experience with Competitive Commercial Agriculture: A Critical Review, Background Paper for the Competitive

Commercial Agriculture in Sub–Saharan Africa (CCAA) Study, CEPEA/ESALQ, Piracicaba, São Paulo.

Barros, Maria Auxiliadora Lemos & Napoleão Esberard de Macêdo Beltrão (2008), Comercialização, in

Napoleão Esberard de Macêdo Beltrão &.Demóstenes Marcos Pedrosa de Azevedo (eds.)(2008), O Agronegócio

do Algodão no Brasil, Embrapa, Brasília, Distrito Federal. Vol. 2. pp. 1269-1277.

Batista, Silas (2011), Embrapa Lança Duas Novas Cultivares para a Cotonicultura Brasileira, Portal do

Algodão.

69|84

Bayer (2008), Reforçando as Colheitas: Contribuindo com a Produtividade, Brochura Corporativa 2007/2008,

Bayer CropScience.

Bélot, Jean, Ivo Marcos Carraro, Patricia C. de Andrade Vilela, Osmério Pupim Jr., José Martin, Pierre Silvie &

Catherine Marquié (2005), Novas Variedades de Algodão Obtidas no Brasil: 15 Anos de Colaboração Entre A

COODETEC e o CIRAD, Cadernos de Ciência & Tecnologia, Vol. 22. No. 2. pp. 479-494.

Bitencourt, Mayra Batista, Silvio Silvestre Barczsz & Andrei Almeida Andrade (2008), Análise da PGPM no

Mercado Brasileiro de Algodão em Pluma, Milho e Trigo, Utilizando Como Instrumento de Intervenção a AGF,

Contrato de Opção, PEP e PEPRO, XLVI Congresso da SOBER, Rio Branco, Acre.

BNDES (1997), Algodão: Crise e Retomada, Informe Setorial, Agroindústria, No. 11.

Branco & Vieira (2007), Inovação e Proteção às Patentes no Agronegócio, Custo Brasil.

Brandão, A. & G.C. de Rezende (2004), Brazilian Agriculture in the 1990s and Ahead: The Role of Government

Programmes to Support Development and Challenges Ahead, Background Paper Prepared for the

OECD.

Buainain, Antônio Márcio & Mário Otávio Batalha (eds.)(2007), Cadeia Produtiva do Algodão, Serie

Agronegócios, BINAGRI, Vol. 4.

Chanselme, Jean-Luc, Paulo Vicente Ribas & Bruno Bachelier (2007), Melhoria do Processo e das Práticas de

Beneficiamento de Algodão no Brasil, VI Congresso Brasileiro do Algodão, Uberlândia, Minas Gerais.

Cia, Edivaldo, Imre Lajos Gridi-Papp, Ederaldo José Chiavegato, Nelson Paulieri Sabino, Júlio Isao Kondo,

Maria Angelica Pizzinatto, Nelson Bortoletto & Luiz Henrique Carvalho (2001), Melhoramento do Algodoeiro

no Estado de São Paulo: Obtenção da Cultivar IAC 21, Revista de Ciências Agronómicas, Campinas, São Paulo.

Vol. 60. No. 1. pp. 9-17.

CIB (2009), Guia do Algodão: Tecnologia no Campo para uma Indústria de Qualidade, Conselho de

Informações sobre Biotecnologia.

Cruz, Kelma Christina Melo dos Santos Cruz (2007), As Intervenções Públicas de Apoio à Comercialização do

Algodão em Pluma Brasileiro na Safra 2005/06, XLV Congresso da SOBER, Conhecimentos para Agricultura

do Futuro, Londrina, Paraná.

de Almeida, Anna Ozório (2009), Exports, Energy, Food: The Multiple Functions of Brazilian Agriculture,

CeSPI, Working Paper 61, Paper Prepared for Presentation at the 2009 LASA Congress, Rio de Janeiro,.

70|84

de Santana, João Cecílio Farias, José Claudio da Silva Santana & Napoleão Esberard de Macêdo Beltrão (2004),

Fibras do Algodão, in Embrapa (2004), Algodão – 500 perguntas, 500 Respostas: O Produtor Pergunta, a

Embrapa Responde, Embrapa, Brasília, Distrito Federal. pp. 213-220.

do Nascimento, Andressa Fernandes & Juliana Cristina da Silva (2010), Melhoramento Genéteico do Algodoeiro

no Brasil; Breves Considerações, Enciclopédia Biosfera, Centro Científico Conhecer, Goiânia. Vol. 6. No. 11.

pp. 1-12.

dos Santos, João Celso, Eliza Emília Rezende Bernardo Rocha & Rosângela Mazzia Inocêncio Rodrigues

(2005), As Cooperativas Diante do Desafio de Manterem-se Fiéis aos seus Princípios Fundamentais, XLIII

Congresso da SOBER, Ribeirão Preto, São Paulo.

Embrapa (2003), Impacto das Novas Cultivares de Algodão sobre Área Plantada no Centro Oeste Brasileiro,

Embrapa Algodão (2000), 25 Anos: Gerando e Transferindo Tecnologia, Embrapa-CNPA, Campina Grande,

Paraíba.

Estur, Gérald (2006), Le Marché Mondial du Coton: Évolution et Perspectives, Macroéconomie et

Mondialisation, Cahiers Agricultures. Vol. 15. No. 1. pp. 9-16.

FACUAL (2003), Desenvolvimento de Novas Cultivares de Algodoeira para as Condições de Mato Grosso,

Safras 1998/1999, 1999/2000 e 2000/2001, Fundação MT & FACUAL.

FACUAL (2006), FACUAL: Ações Setoriais e Sociais 1998-2005, Cuiabá, Mato Grosso.

Farias, Francisco José Correia (2005), Índice de Seleção em Cultivares de Algodoeira Herbáceo, Universidade

de São Paulo, Escola Superior de Agricultura “Luiz de Queiroz”, Piracicaba, São Paulo.

Ferreira, Isaura Lopes & Eleusio Curvelo Freire (2007), Industrialização da Pluma, in Freire, Eleusio Curvelo

(ed.)(2007), Algodão no Cerrado do Brasil, ABRAPA. pp. 871-877.

Ferreira, Isaura Lopes, Eleusio Curvelo Freire, Armindo Bezerra Leão & Demóstenes Marcos Pedrosa de

Azevedo (2008), Industrialização, in Napoleão Esberard de Macêdo Beltrão &.Demóstenes Marcos Pedrosa de

Azevedo (eds.)(2008), O Agronegócio do Algodão no Brasil, Embrapa, Brasília, Distrito Federal. Vol. 2. pp.

1235-1268.

Fiedler, Hélvio Alberto (2007), Comercialização e Exportação do Algodão do Cerrado, in Freire, Eleusio

Curvelo (ed.)(2007), Algodão no Cerrado do Brasil, ABRAPA. pp. 821-852.

71|84

Filho, Joaquim Bento de Souza Ferreira Filho & Lucilio Rogério Aparecido Alves (2007), Aspectos Econômicos

do Algodão no Cerrado, in Eleusio Curvelo Freire (ed.)(2007), Algodão no Cerrado do Brasil, ABRAPA. pp.

53-89.

Filho, Joaquim Bento de Souza Ferreira, Lucilio Rogério Aparecido Alves & Luiz Cezar Bonfim Gottardo

(2010), Aspectos Econômicos do Algodão no Cerrado: Ajustes Estruturais e Consolidação, in Eleusio Curvelo

Freire (ed.)(2010), Algodão no Cerrado do Brasil, ABRAPA, Brasília, Distrito Federal.

Freire, Eleusio Curvelo (2004), Projeto: Estruturação Física do Campo Experimental de Primavera do Leste,

Primavera do Leste, Mato Grosso.

Freire, Eleusio Curvelo (2007), História do Algodão no Cerrado, in Freire, Eleusio Curvelo (ed.)(2007),

Algodão no Cerrado do Brasil, ABRAPA. pp. 21-52.

Freire, Eleusio Curvelo & Luiz Paulo de Carvalho (2004), Cultivares do Algodoeiro, in Embrapa (2004),

Algodão – 500 perguntas, 500 Respostas: O Produtor Pergunta, a Embrapa Responde, Embrapa, Brasília,

Distrito Federal. pp. 33-46.

Freire, Eleusio Curvelo, Joaquim Nunes da Costa & Francisco Pereira de Andrade & (1998), Recursos Genéticos

e Melhoramento do Algodão no Nordeste do Brasil, Recursos Genéticos e Melhoramento de Plantas para o

Nordeste Brasileiro, Campina Grande, Paraíba.

Freire, Eleusio Curvelo, João Luiz da Silva Filho, Francisco José Correia de Farias & Adelardo José da Silva

Filho (2007a), Ensaios Regionais de Competição de Cultivares do Cerrado Conduzidos no Mato Grosso na

Safra 2004/2005, VI Congresso Brasileiro do Algodão, Uberlândia, Minas Gerais.

Freire, Eleusio Curvelo, Camilo de Lelis Morello & Francisco José Correia de Farias (2007b), Melhoramento do

Algodoeira no Cerrado, in Eleusio Curvelo Freire (ed.)(2007), Algodão no Cerrado do Brasil, ABRAPA. pp.

267-317.

Gonçalves, José Sidinei & Simone Pereira Gonçalves (2007), Regulação e Progresso Técnico no Algodão

Meridional Brasileiro 1930-1990, XLV Congresso da SOBER, Conhecimento para Agricultura do Futuro,

Londrina, Paraná.

Guimarães, Alexandre Queiroz (2005), Historical Institutionalism and Economic Policymaking – Determinants

of the Pattern of Economic Policy in Brazil, 1930–1960, Bulletin of Latin American Research, Vol. 24. Issue 4.

Helfand, Steven M. & Gervásio Castro de Rezende (2001), The Impact of Sector-Specific and Economy-Wide

Policy Reforms on Agriculture, 1980-98, Working Paper 01-34, Department of Economics, University of

California, Riverside.

72|84

Hrapsky, Alan D. & Elizabeth Autry (2009), Cotton and Products Annual: 2009 Annual Cotton Report, Global

Agricultural Information Network Report, USDA.

IAC (2008), Ciência da Terra: O Instituto e a Pesquisa em Benefício da Qualidade de Vida, IAC, Campinas,

São Paulo.

IAPAR (2010), Ciência, Tecnologia e Inovação na Agropecuária do Paraná, IAPAR, Londrina, Paraná.

ICAC (2002), Production and Trade Policies Affecting the Cotton Industry, Washington DC, USA.

ICAC (2011), Production and Trade Policies Affecting the Cotton Industry, Washington DC, USA.

IHARA (2010), Relatório de Sustentabilidade 2010, IHARA, Agricultura é Nossa Vida.

Junior, Sebastião Nogueira (1996), A Importância da Pesquisa na Modernização da Cotonicultura, Agricultura

em São Paulo, SP, Vol. 43. No. 1. pp. 155-166.

Kelly, Valerie & David Tschirley (2008), Seed Cotton Market Structure and Cotton Sector Performance: Many

Lessons but No Fixed Prescriptions, WACIP, USAID.

Kiawu, James, Constanza Valdes & Stephen MacDonald (2011), Brazil’s Cotton Industry: Economic Reform

and Development, A Report from the Economic Research Service, USDA Outlook.

Krieger, Milton (2006), Uma Crítica à Liberação Imediata e sem Maiores Cuidados dos Transgênicos, II Fórum

Ambiental da Alta Paulista, ANAP, Tupã, São Paulo.

Levy, Clayton (2010), Pesquisa da Embrapa com Transgênico tem Gene Nacional, Portal do Algodão.

Lunardon, Maurício Tadeu (2000), Algodão, Secretaria da Agricultura e Abastecimento, Governo do Estado,

Paraná.

Marquié, Catherine, Joaquim Bento de Souza Ferreira Filho, Augusto Hauber Gameiro, Carlos Eduardo Cameiro

Ballaminut, Shirley Martins Menezes & Jean-Louis Bélot (2004), Análise Prospectiva dos Mercados da Fibra

do Algodão, na Indústria Têxtil, em Relação com a Qualidade, FACUAL, Primavera do Leste, Mato Grosso.

Massuda, Ely Mitite (2005) , Produção e Consumo de Algodão e as Indústrias de Fiações de Algodão no

Paraná, Departamento de Administração, Faculdade Integrada de Campo Mourão, Campo Mourão, Paraná.

Monsanto (2010), Perfil Monsanto, Monsanto Imagine.

73|84

North, Douglass C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional change and Economic Performance, Cambridge University,

United Kingdom.

Nunes, Daiane Heloisa (2010), Efeitos do Algodoeiro Geneticamente Modificado (Bollgard®) em Organismos

Não-Alvo, Universidade de São Paulo, Escola Superior de Agricultura “Luiz de Queiroz”, Piracicaba, São Paulo.

OECD (2005), OECD Review of Agricultural Policies: Brazil, Organization for Economic Co-operation and

Development, OECD Publishing.

Pedrosa, Murilo Barros, João Luiz da Silva Filho, Camilo de Lelis Morello, Eleusio Curvelo Freire, Arnaldo

Rocha de Alencar, Francisco Pereira de Andrade, Luis Gonzaga Chitarra, Francisco José Correia de Farias &

Francisco das Chagas Vidal Neto (2009), BRS 286; Cultivar de Algodão com Alta Produtividade de Pluma e de

Porte Baixo, Para Cultivo no Estado da Bahia, VII Congresso Brasileiro do Algodão, Foz do Iguaçú, Paraná.

Pessa, João Luiz Ribas (2007), A Organização do Produtor de Algodão, in Freire, Eleusio Curvelo (ed.)(2007),

Algodão no Cerrado do Brasil, ABRAPA. pp. 91-140

Poulton, Colin; Peter Gibbon, Benjamine Hanyani-Mlambo, Jonathan Kydd, Wilbald Maro, Marianne

Nylandsted Larsen, Afonso Osório, David L. Tschirley & Ballard Zulu (2004), Competition and Co-ordination

in Liberalized African Cotton Market Systems, World Development. Vol. 32. No. 3. pp. 519- 536.

Praça, Lilian Botelho (2007), Anthonomus Grandis Boheman, 1843 (Coleoptera: Curculionidae), Embrapa,

Brasília, Distrito Federal.

Ribas (2009), Situações de Impacto ao Desempenho e Produtividade do Beneficiamento no Brasil, VII

Congresso Brasileiro do Algodão, Foz do Iguaçú, Paraná.

Sanchez, Guido Aguilar (2005), Viabilização do Manejo de Pragas do Algodoeiro: Eficácia, Gestão, Custos,

Benefícios e Interação com o Setor Produtivo, V Congresso Brasileiro do Algodão, Salvador, Bahia.

Sendin, Paulo Varela & Teodoro Stadler (2002), Gestão de Parcerias de Desenvolvimento Tecnológico; O

Projeto Trinacional de Manejo Integrado do Bicudo Algodoeiro na Argentina, Brasil e Paraguai –

CFC/ICAC/04, XXII Simpósio de Gestão da Inovação Tecnológica, Salvador, Bahia.

Sestren, José Antônio & Jorge José de Lima (2007), Característica e Classificação da Fibra de Algodão, in

Eleusio Curvelo Freire (ed.)(2007), Algodão no Cerrado do Brasil, ABRAPA. pp. 765-819.

Stadler, Teodoro (ed.)(2001), Integrated Pest Management of the Cotton Boll Weevil in Argentina, Brazil and

Paraguay, Technical Paper No. 16. SENASA.

74|84

Stefanelo, Eugênio Libreloto (2005), A Política de Garantia de Preços Mínimos no Brasil: Classificação e

Operacionalização dos seus Instrumentos no Período 1990-2004, Tese de Doutorado, Universidade Federal de

Santa Catarina, Florianópolis.

Suinaga, Fábio Akiyoshi (2003), Impacto das Novas Cultivares de Algodão sobre Área Plantada no Centro

Oeste Brasileiro, Embrapa-CNPA, Campina Grande, Paraíba.

Syngenta (2010), Alimentar Nosso Maior Desafio 2010-2050: Relatório de Sustentabilidade, Relatório de

Sustentabilidade 2010, Syngenta.

Torres, Jorge B. (2008), Controle de Pragas do Algodoeiro: Expectativas de Mudanças, Ciência Agrícola, Vol.

8. No. 1. pp. 37-49.

Tschirley, David L., Colin Poulton & Duncan Boughton (2006), The Many Paths of Cotton Sector Reform in

Eastern and Southern Africa: Lessons from a Decade of Experience, Working Paper No. 18. Food Security

Research Project.

Tschirley, David L., Colin Poulton, Nicholas Gergely, Patrick Labaste, John Baffes, Duncan Boughton & Gérald

Estur (2007), Comparative Analysis of Organization and Performance of African Cotton Sectors: Learning from

Experience of Cotton Sector Reform in Africa, World Bank.

Tschirley, David L. Colin Poulton, Nicholas Gergely, Patrick Labaste, John Baffes, Duncan Boughton & Gérald

Estur (2010), Institutional Diversity and Performance in African Cotton Sectors, Development Policy Review,

28 (3). pp. 295-323.

Tschirley, David L. Colin Poulton & Patrick Labaste (eds.) (2009), Organization and Performance of Cotton

Sectors in Africa: Learning from Reform Experience, The International Bank for Reconstruction and

Development.

UNICOTTON (2006), Melhoria do Beneficiamento de Algodão no Estado de Mato Grosso: Relatório Final,

Algodão de Mato Grosso, Projeto FACUAL, Processo 146/2004.

USDA (2011), Weekly Cotton Market Review, Memphis, Tenessee. Vol. 93. No. 3.

Utkulu, Utku & Dilek Seymen (2004), Revealed Comparative Advantage and Competitiveness: Evidence for

Turkey vis-à-vis the EU/15, European Trade Study Group 6th Annual Conference, Nottingham.

75|84

Web Sources

ALLCOTTON - Cooperativa dos Produtores de Acreúna, accessed 2011-08-24.

Homepage: http://www.connectradio.com.br/allcotton/index.php

Specific Link: http://www.connectradio.com.br/allcotton/coophist.php

ABAPA – Associação Baiana dos Produtores de Algodão, accessed 2011-08-27.

Homepage: http://www.abapaba.org.br/

Specific Link: http://www.abapaba.org.br/noticia/275/

ABRAPA – Associação Brasileira dos Produtores de Algodão, accessed 2011-08-27.

Homepage: http://www.abrapa.com.br/

Specific Links: http://www.abrapa.com.br/associadas.asp & http://www.abrapa.com.br/legislacao.asp &

http://www.abrapa.com.br/quemsomos.asp

ANEA – Associação Nacional dos Exportadores de Algodão, accessed 2011-08-21.

Homepage: http://www.aneacotton.com.br/

Specific Link: http://www.aneacotton.com.br/qualityprogram.html

BCB – Banco Central do Brasil, accessed 2011-08-27.

Homepage: http://www.bcb.gov.br/

Specific Link: http://www.bcb.gov.br/pre/bc_atende/port/scr.asp

BTNE – Brazil Travel North East, accessed 2011-08-28.

Homepage: http://www.brazil-travel-northeast.com/

Specific Link: http://www.brazil-travel-northeast.com/maps-of-brazil.html

Biotecnologia - Ciência e Desenvolvimento, accessed 2011-08-15.

Homepage: http://www.biotecnologia.com.br/

Specific Link: http://www.biotecnologia.com.br/revista/bio10/bio10.pdf

CLASPAR - Empresa Paranaense de Classificação de Produtos, accessed 2011-08-23.

Homepage: http://www.claspar.pr.gov.br/

Specific Link: http://www.claspar.pr.gov.br/modules/conteudo/conteudo.php?conteudo=4

COCAMAR - Cooperativa Agroindustrial Maringaense, accessed 2011-08-23.

Homepage: http://www.cocamar.com.br/

Specific Link: http://www.cocamar.com.br/historia.php

76|84

COODETEC - Cooperativa Central de Pesquisa Agrícola, acessed 2011-08-13.

Homepage: http://www.coodetec.com.br/

Specific Link: http://www.coodetec.com.br/site.php

COOPERBIO – A Cooperativa Mista de Produção, Industrialização e Comercialização de Biocombustíveis do

Brasil Ltda, accessed 2011-08-27.

Homepage: http://www.cooperbio.com.br

Specific Link: http://www.cooperbio.com.br/artigos/artigos.php

Cotton 24/7 – Meistermedia Worldwide.

Homepage: http://www.cotton247.com/

Specific Articles:

Macdonald, Andrew (2009), Learning from History, Cotton 24/7, accessed 2011-08-27.

Macdonald, Andrew (2010), A Sleeping Giant Stirs, Cotton 24/7, accessed 2011-08-27.

McCue, Mike (2010), Country Report Brazil, Cotton 24/7, accessed 2011-08-27.

EPAMIG – Empresa de Pesquisa Agropecuária de Minas Gerais, accessed 2011-08-20.

Homepage: http://www.epamig.br/

Specific Link: http://www.epamig.br/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=12&Itemid=51

FETAG-AL – Federação dos Trabalhadores e Trabalhadores na Agricultura do Estado de Alagoas, accessed

2011- 08-27.

Homepage: http://www.fetagal.org.br/

Specific Link: http://www.fetagal.org.br/links.asp?id=4

Fundação BA – Fundação Bahia, accessed 2011-07-28.

Homepage: http://www.fundacaoba.com.br/

Specific Link: http://www.fundacaoba.com.br/index.php?p=cultivares-algodao

Fundação GO – Fundação Goiás, accessed 2011-07-28.

Homepage: http://www.fundacaogo.com.br/

Specific Link: http://www.fundacaogo.com.br/cultivares.html

G1 – O Portal de Notícias da Globo, accessed 2011-08-27.

Homepage: http://g1.globo.com/

Specific Link: http://g1.globo.com/economia/noticia/2011/05/com-safra-recorde-exportacao-de-algodao-do-pais-

dobra-em-1112-2.html

77|84

GBCA – Grupo de Consultores de Algodão, accessed 2011-08-12.

Homepage: http://www.consultoresdealgodao.com.br/

Specific Links: http://www.consultoresdealgodao.com.br/sobre/conheca-o-gbca.php &

http://www.consultoresdealgodao.com.br/agenda/detalhe-agenda.php?id=9

IAC – Instituto Agronômico de Campinas, accessed 2011-07-29.

Homepage: http://www.iac.sp.gov.br/

Specific Link: http://www.iac.sp.gov.br/Centros/Graos_Fibras/

IAPAR – Instituto Agronômico do Paraná, accessed 2011-07-29.

Homepage: http://www.iapar.br/

Specific Link: http://www.iapar.br/arquivos/File/zip_pdf/cult_iapar1980_2008.pdf

MDIC – Ministério do Desenvolvimento, Indústria e Comércio Exterior, accessed 2011-08-27.

Homepage: http://www.mdic.gov.br/

Specific Link: http://www.mdic.gov.br/sistemas_web/aprendex/cooperativismo/index/popup/id/330

Monsanto Algodão, accessed 2011-08-01.

Homepages: http://algodaomonsanto.com.br/ & http://www.monsanto.com.br

Specific Links: http://algodaomonsanto.com.br/novamarca.asp &

http://www.monsanto.com.br/institucional/monsanto-no-brasil/historia/historia.asp

SEFAZ-MT – Secretaria de Estado de Fazenda, accessed 2011-08-27.

Homepage: http://www.sefaz.mt.gov.br/

Specific Link:

http://app1.sefaz.mt.gov.br/Sistema/Legislacao/legfinan.nsf/709f9c981a9d9f468425671300482be0/ebe2436b373

cf3c404256da400741c41?OpenDocument

UNICOTTON – Cooperativa dos Produtores de Algodão, accessed 2011-08-27.

Homepage: http://www.unicotton.coop.br

Specific Link: http://www.unicotton.coop.br/site/site.html

US Department of State – Background Note: Brazil, accessed 2011-08-28.

Homepage: http://www.state.gov/

Specific Link: http://www.state.gov/r/pa/ei/bgn/35640.htm

USDA – United States Department of Agriculture, accessed 2011-08-27.

Homepage: http://www.ers.usda.gov/

Specific Link: http://www.ers.usda.gov/AmberWaves/November06/Features/Brazil.htm &

http://www.ers.usda.gov/Briefing/Brazil/domsupport.htm

78|84

Data Sources

BM&F – Bolsa de Mercadorias e Futuros, accessed 2011-08-13.

Homepage: http://www.bmfbovespa.com.br/

CEPEA/ESALQ – Escola Superior de Agricultura, Luiz de Queiroz, accessed 2011-08-15.

Homepage: http://www.esalq.usp.br/

Specific Link: http://www.cepea.esalq.usp.br/english/cotton/

CONAB – Companhia Nacional de Abastecimento, accessed 2011-08-01.

Homepage: http://www.conab.gov.br/

Specific Links: http://www.conab.gov.br/conteudos.php?a=1252&t= &

http://www.conab.gov.br/conteudos.php?a=518&t=2

Ministério da Agricultura, Pecuária e Abastecimento – Ministry of Agriculture, accessed 2011-07-29.

Homepage: http://www.agricultura.gov.br/

Specific Link: http://extranet.agricultura.gov.br/php/proton/cultivarweb/cultivares_registradas.php

Portal Brasil, accessed 2011-08-25.

Homepage: http://www.portalbrasil.net/

Specific Link: http://www.portalbrasil.net/ipc.htm

USDA – United States Department of Agriculture, accessed 2011-08-15.

Homepage: http://www.usda.gov/

Specific Link: http://www.usda.gov/oce/commodity/wasde/index.htm

79|84

Interviews & Meetings

These references are divided into two parts, where the first part presents interviews conducted

in person, and the second part presents interviews conducted over the phone. Due to

geographical distances in Brazil, we could not visit all stakeholders of interest, and that is why

we decided to conduct some of our interviews over the phone. When language is not

mentioned, interviews were carried out in Portuguese. Although we have not referred to all

interviews in our thesis, we have benefited a lot from all information provided during the

interviews.

Meetings

2011-06-21 IMAmt – Primavera do Leste, Mato Grosso.

2011-07-01 IMAmt – Cuiabá, Mato Grosso.

2011-07-01 IAS – Cuiabá, Mato Grosso.

2011-07-04 John Deere – Primavera do Leste, Mato Grosso.

2011-07-05 Multigrain – Primavera do Leste, Mato Grosso.

2011-07-06 COOALESTE – Primavera do Leste, Mato Grosso.

2011-07-07 Algodoeira Nativa – Primavera do Leste, Mato Grosso.

2011-07-08 UNICOTTON – Primavera do Leste, Mato Grosso.

2011-07-08 Ceres Consultoria Agronômica – Primavera do Leste, Mato Grosso.

2011-07-13 Libero Commodities – Cuiabá, Mato Grosso. (in English)

2011-07-13 IMEA – Cuiabá, Mato Grosso.

2011-07-19 Ministry of Agriculture – Brasília, Distrito Federal. (in English)

2011-07-20 OCB – Brasília, Distrito Federal.

2011-07-21 ABRAPA – Brasília, Distrito Federal.

2011-07-21 Ministry of Agriculture – Brasília, Distrito Federal.

2011-07-22 IBA – Brasília, Distrito Federal.

2011-07-22 CONAB – Brasília, Distrito Federal.

2011-07-25 Universidade Federal de Mato Grosso – Cuiabá, Mato Grosso.

2011-08-01 AMPA – Cuiabá, Mato Grosso.

Phone Interviews

2011-07-25 Embrapa Algodão – Campina Grande, Paraíba.

2011-07-26 Cargill – São Paulo, São Paulo.

2011-07-27 Cotton Consultoria – Campina Grande, Paraíba.

2011-07-28 CATI – Campinas, São Paulo.

80|84

2011-07-29 Monsanto Algodão – São Paulo, São Paulo.

2011-08-02 FBET – Blumenau, Santa Catarina.

2011-08-02 IAPAR – Londrina, Paraná.

2011-08-02 IAC – Campinas, São Paulo.

2011-08-09 Instituto Biológico – Campinas, São Paulo.

2011-08-10 COOPERFIBRA – Campo Verde, Mato Grosso.

2011-08-10 BM&F – São Paulo, São Paulo.

2011-08-10 AGOPA – Goiânia, Goiás.

2011-08-10 AMIPA – Patos de Minas, Minas Gerais.

2011-08-10 AMPASUL – Chapadão do Sul, Mato Grosso do Sul.

2011-08-10 ABAPA – Luis Eduardo Magalhães, Bahia.

2011-08-12 EISA Interagrícola – São Paulo, São Paulo.

2011-08-12 Kuhlmann – Paranaguá, Paraná.

2011-08-17 COABRA – Cuiabá, Mato Grosso.

2011-08-22 COCAMAR – Maringá, Paraná.

2011-08-23 COAMO – Campo Mourão, Paraná.

2011-08-24 CEPEA/ESALQ – Piracicaba, São Paulo.

2011-08-24 ABIT – São Paulo, São Paulo.

81|84

1 1 1 2 2

4

1 1 3

2 1 1 1

2 1 1 1 1

2 1

2 2 3

1 1

2

1 1

2 1

2

5

3

4

5

1 2

6

2 4

1 1 2

2

1

5

1

2

4 3

2

3

1

2 3

2 2

1

4

6

2

1

7 7

3 2

4

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

19

70

19

71

19

72

19

73

19

74

19

75

19

76

19

77

19

78

19

79

19

80

19

81

19

82

19

83

19

84

19

85

19

86

19

87

19

88

19

89

19

90

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

Am

ou

nt

of

Var

ieti

es

Year

Figure 11. Amount of Varieties Developed, 1970-2011 Public Private Partnerships Public Private & Multinational Companies Private Foundations

Source: Batista (2011), Bélot et al (2005), Branco & Vieira (2007), Cia et al (2001), Embrapa Algodão (2000), FACUAL (2003), Farias (2005), Freire (2004), Freire & de Carvalho (2004), Freire et al (1998), Freire et al (2004), Freire et al (2007a), Freire et al (2007b), Pedrosa et al (2009), Suinaga (2003), Ministry of Agriculture (2011-07-29), IAPAR (2011-07-29), IAC (2011-07-29), Fundação BA (2011-07-28), Fundação GO (2011-07-28), Monsanto Algodão (2011-08-01).

Appendix 1

82|84

Appendix 2

This appendix serves to present how we have calculated costs and quality. As data was not

available for all regions in Brazil, we weighted available data in order to obtain as

representative a result as possible. In order to calculate the costs, we used a composition of

costs exemplified by the data in Table 2. The years for when cost data was available are

further presented in Table 3. Since the cost data was in current values, we calculated a

Table 2. Estimated Production Cost of Cotton Summer Harvest - 2009/2010

Location: RONDONÓPOLIS

Average Productivity (Seed Cotton): 3 750 kg/ha

PRICES IN: 2009-05-31 SHARE OF

COMPOSITION OF COSTS

PRODUCTION COSTS

(R$/ha) R$/15 kg (%)

I - FARM COSTS

1 - Airplane operations 0.00 0.00 0.00%

2 - Machinery operations 413.51 1.50 7.60%

3 - Rental of machinery / services 0.00 0.00 0.00%

4 - Labor (temporary) 257.60 1.04 4.74%

5 - Labor (fixed) 51.16 0.20 0.94%

6 - Seeds 86.25 0.44 1.59%

7 - Fertlizers 1 777.90 7.12 32.68%

8 - Pesticides 1 630.25 6.56 29.97%

9 - Others 28.92 0.11 0.53%

TOTAL FARM COSTS (A) 4 245.59 16.97 78,04%

II - POST-HARVEST COSTS

1 - Insurance costs 165.58 0.66 3.04%

2 - Technical assistence 84.91 0.34 1.56%

3 - External transport 37.50 0.15 0.69%

4 - Ginning 212.50 0.85 3.91%

5 - Wharehousing 15.48 0.06 0.28%

Total post harvestCosts (B) 515.97 2.06 9.48%

III - FINANCIAL COSTS

1 - Interest 231.81 0.93 4.26%

Total financial costs (C) 231.81 0.93 4.26%

VARIABLE COSTS (A+B+C = D) 4 993.37 19.96 91.78%

IV - DEPRECIATION

1 - Depreciation of installations and benefactors 76.25 0.31 1.40%

2 - Depreciation of implements 19.58 0.08 0.36%

3 - Depreciation of machinery 59.10 0.24 1.09%

Total costs of depreciation (E) 154.93 0.63 2.85%

V - OTHER FIXED COSTS

1 - Periodic maintenance of machinery/implements 56.33 0.23 1.04%

2 - Social taxes 30.18 0.12 0.55%

3 - Insurances for immovables 4.12 0.02 0.08%

Total costs for other fixed costs (F) 90.63 0.37 1.67%

Custo Fixo (E+F = G) 245.56 1.00 4.51%

OPERATIONAL COSTS (D+G = H) 5 238.93 20.96 96.30%

VI - RETURNS OF PRODUCTION FACTORS

1 - Expected return on fixed capital 36.36 0.15 0.67%

2 - Land 165.00 0.66 3.03%

Total Returns of Production Factors (I) 201.36 0.81 3.70%

TOTAL COSTS (H+I = J) 5 440.29 21.77 100.00%

Source: CONAB. Note: The authors’ translation.

82|84

83|84

deflator based on CPI in order to make the values constant and indexed to 2010.232

When the cost data had been deflated, we weighed the data according to shares of total

production each year. This method was also used to calculate quality as data for all regions

was not available. Consider the following example of how the data was calculated:

During a certain year, Mato Grosso had 30 % and Bahia had 20 % of total production, and

quality and cost data are only available for these regions. Mato Grosso and Bahia must thus

represent all cotton produced in Brazil during this year. We know that Mato Grosso and Bahia

together represented 50 % total production, and weights for each region are thereby calculated

as follows:

Mato Grosso thus represents 60 % of the sample during this year, and Bahia 40 %. These

weights are then used to calculate quality and costs. Suppose that the fiber length in Mato

Grosso and Bahia was 30 mm and 20 mm respectively. The average fiber length for the whole

country would then be calculated as follows:

232

Portal Brasil (2011-08-25).

Table 3. Regions Represented in Costs City Rondonópolis Campo Novo do Parecis Sorriso Rio Verde Chapadão do Sul Barreiras Campo Mourão

State Mato Grosso Mato Grosso Mato Grosso Goiás Mato Grosso do Sul Bahia Paraná

1999/2000 x

x x x 2000/2001 x

x x x

2001/2002 x

x x x 2002/2003 x

x x x

2003/2004 x x

x x x 2004/2005 x x

x x x

2005/2006 x x

x x x x

2006/2007 x x x x x x x 2007/2008 x x x x x x x 2008/2009 x x x x x

2009/2010 x x x x x

Source: CONAB.

84|84

The average fiber length was thus 26 mm during this year. All quality and cost data was

calculated using this method, and by these means we maximize the representativeness of the

data available.

85|84

MINOR FIELD STUDY SERIES (A complete list can be ordered from Department of

Economics, University of Lund, Box 7082, S-220 07 Lund, Sweden)

191 Joakim Persson The Impact of a Quota System on Women‟s

Empowerment – A Field Study in West Bengal, India.

2009:5

192 Erudita Hoti Remittances and Poverty in Albania. 2009:6

193 Anna Andersson Made in Madagascar – The Impact of Rules of Origin

on the Textile and Clothing Industry. 2009:7

194 Sigrid Colnerud

Granström

The Informal Sector and Formal Competitiveness in

Senegal. 2009:8

195 Elin Jönsson

Elin Åkerman

Direct Cash Transfer and Food Security in Georgia.

2009:9

196 Ylva Kalin FDI in Colombia – Policy and Economic Effects.

2009:10

197 Lisa Curman Ownership of the Poverty Reduction Strategy in

Rwanda. 2009:11

198 Helena Lundstedt

Sara Pärssinen

Cocoa is Ghana, Ghana is Cocoa – Evaluating

Reforms of the Ghanaian Cocoa Sector. 2009:12

199 Johan Fredborn

Larsson

The Transition in Kazakhstan – From Command to

Market Economy. 2010:1

200 Gustaf Salomonsson

Oscar Sandberg

Assessing and Remedying the Natural Resource Curse

in Equatorial Guinea. 2010:2

201 Hanna Nilsson Structure, Reforms and Performance of the Ugandan

Cotton Sector. 2010:3

202 Annika Marking Trade Liberalization and Tax Reforms in

Cape Verde. 2010:4

86|84

203 Karin Göransson

Anna Östergren

Is Trust a Necessity? A Case Study of Group Lending

within Microfinance in the Mbarara District, Uganda.

2010:5

204

Ylva Wide

Assessing the Competitiveness in Mozambique.

2010:6

205

Martin Larsson

Sofie Sjöborg

The Effects of Growth and Inequality on Poverty in

Honduras. 2010:7

206 Karl McShane

Johan Nilsson

Determinants of Corruption – A Study of Zambian

Ministries. 2010:8

207

208

209

210

211

Emma Lindqvist

Ebba Littorin

Martin Eriksson

Fredrika Cruce

Erik Bustad

Linn Glimeus

Linnéa Ödén

The Way the Cookie Crumbles? A Study of the

Relationship Between Gender and Corruption in Ghana.

2010:9

Reciprocity, Nepotism or Costly Signaling – Evidence

from Mobile Phone Money Transfers in Nairobi. 2010:10

Evaluating Value Added Tax in Morocco. 2011:1

Evaluating Fiscal Decentralization in Peru. 2011:2

Efficiency of the Rice Market Channel in the Office du

Niger. 2011:3

212

Annie Emilsson

The Impact of Remittances on Labor Supply – The Case

of Jordan. 2011:4

213

John Svending

The Institutional Channels of the Resource Curse – A

Case Study of Bolivia. 2011:5

214

Christopher Wingård

Tariffic Tuna – A Study on the Impact of Rules of Origin

on Thailand‟s Tuna Trade. 2011:6

215

Johannes Lissdaniels

Fredrik Saïd Madsen

The Fall and Rise of the Brazilian Cotton Sector – An

Institutional Analysis of the Recent Success. 2011:7