the economic consequences of u.s. immigration: part 3

33
The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Upload: aidan-king

Post on 01-Jan-2016

25 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Page 2: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

THE LOCAL U.S. LABOR MARKET IMPACTS OFLOW-SKILL MIGRATION FROM MEXICO

by

Paul S. DaviesU.S. Social Security Administration

Michael J. GreenwoodUniversity of Colorado at Boulder

Gary L. HuntUniversity of Maine at Orono

Ulrich KohliUniversity of Geneva

Marta TiendaPrinceton University

Most of the work presented here was supported by the U.S. Commission for Immigration Reform, Bi-National Mexico-United States Migration Study.

Page 3: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

What follows immediately by way of an introduction is drawn from:

Michael J. Greenwood, “Population: Migration,” in Bjorn Lomborg, Solutions for the World’s Biggest Problems: Costs and Benefits. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007, 425-439.

Page 4: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

United States

Labor0

WUS

W'US

We

DUS

SUS

S'US

S''US

D'US

D''US

c a e b d

y

x

t

v

u

z

s m r

Wage Rate

Page 5: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

y

S S'

W0 x z

A B

W1 n m r

e

D C

We

D

EMPLOYMENT

o f u v w g

Figure 2. Migrant-Induced Redistributions in the Country of Destination

WE

EK

LY

EA

RIN

GS

($)

Page 6: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Consider the service sector of the U.S. in the year 2000.

• Employment: 40.457m (30.7% of total U.S. employment)• Average weekly earnings: $455.51• Average weekly hours worked in the service sector: 32.7

(All figures reported below are annualized to reflect a 52-week year.)

Under various (presumably fairly reasonable) assumptions regarding national labor supply and (inverse) labor demand elasticities, I calculate the dollar magnitudes of the areas reflecting the transfers in the above diagram. I assume a one-percent increase in employment due to immigration (404,570 jobs). The resulting assumed wage reductions given the various elasticities of the wage with respect to the quantity of labor demanded are as follows:

0.5 -$2.28 weekly wage

1.0 -$4.56 weekly wage

2.0 -$9.11 weekly wage

Page 7: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Area

A $4.797b (1) 0.0050 $9.593b (1) 0.010 $19.165b (1) 0.020B 23.983m (2) 0.0025 47.966m (2) 0.005 95.826m (2) 1.010C 9.535b (3) 0.0100 9.487b (3) 1.010 9.391b (3) 0.010D --- (4) 0.0000 --- (4) 0.000 --- (4) 0.000A 4.797b (1) 0.0050 9.593b (1) 0.010 19.165b (1) 0.020B 23.983m (2) 0.0025 47.966m (2) 0.005 95.826m (2) 0.010C 9.535b (3) 0.0100 9.487b (3) 0.010 9.391b (3) 0.010D 2.384b (4) 0.0025 4.767b (4) 0.005 9.534b (4) 0.010A 4.797b (1) 0.0050 9.593b (1) 0.010 19.165b (1) 0.020B 23.983m (2) 0.0025 47.966m (2) 0.005 95.826m (2) 0.010C 9.535b (3) 0.0100 9.487b (3) 0.010 9.391b (3) 0.010D 4.767b (4) 0.0050 9.487b (4) 0.010 18.782b (4) 0.020A 4.797b (1) 0.0050 9.593b (1) 0.010 19.165b (1) 0.020B 23.983m (2) 0.0025 47.966m (2) 0.005 95.826m (2) 0.010C 9.535b (3) 0.0100 9.487b (3) 0.010 9.391b (3) 0.010D 7.151b (4) 0.0075 14.230b (4) 0.015 28.174b (4) 0.030

Table 1. Possible Transfers Inherent in Migration: the U.S. Service Sector, 2000

Elasticity of the wage with respect to the quantity of labor demanded

1. a/(a+e+d) Transfer from labor to other factors as a fraction of initial labor income.

0.5

1.0

1.5

0

0.5 1.0 2.0

3. c/(e+d+c) Immigrant income as a fraction of labor income.4. d/(a+e+d) Lost native income as a fraction of initial labor income.

Areas a,b,c, and d refer to Figure 2.

Ela

stic

ity o

f na

tive

labo

r su

pply

2. b/(b+c) Efficiency gain to other factos as a fraction of nonreplacement immigrant income.

Page 8: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

To get a sense of the employment displacement effects, consider the following:

With a labor-supply elasticity of 0.5 and an (inverse) labor demand elasticity of 0.5,

displacement of domestic workers is 101,143.

If the respective elasticities were 1.0 and 0.5, the displacement would be 202,285.

If the respective elasticities were 1.0 and 1.0, the wage would fall by $4.56 per week (rather than $2.28) and employment of domestic workers would fall by 404,570.

Page 9: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

MODEL STRUCTURE - AN OVERVIEW The model incorporates one aggregate output and nine inputs.[i] The relatively large

disaggregation of inputs reflects the interest of this study in the effects of immigration by origin and skill level on native U.S. workers by skill level, gender, and ethnicity. Eight groups of labor are identified in the model:

(1) native, low-skill, Mexican males; (2) native, low-skill Mexican females; (3) native, low-skill non-Mexican males; (4) native, low-skill, non-Mexican females; (5) native, high-skill males and females; (6) foreign-born, low-skill Mexican males and females; (7) foreign-born, low-skill non-Mexican males and females; (8) foreign-born, high-skill males and females; and (9) capital. The methodology is the same as that reported in Greenwood, Hunt, and Kohli (1997),

but the labor inputs are different. In this part of the model substitution and complementarity relationships between the various inputs are estimated.

We are presently unable to estimate the model with more than nine inputs, but this is five more inputs than is found in the typical production-theory approach.

Page 10: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

The model contains 18 endogenous variables.

For each of the nine inputs, a factor price equation is specified by setting the factor price of the input equal to the input’s value marginal product (VMP). The VMP for each input is derived from production theory as described below.

Eight more behavioral equations are specified for the labor force participation rates of the eight groups of labor. These equations also are treated in more detail below, but their basic purpose is to measure the degree to which own-wage changes influence the labor force participation of the various labor groups.

Finally, a behavioral equation for aggregate absorption of area output (i.e., area aggregate demand) is specified.

Page 11: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

In addition to the 18 equations for the corresponding 18 endogenous variables, the model contains several technical relations, such as an aggregate value added production function and numerous identities. Some of these identities translate variables from their indexed forms used in theoretical specification (e.g., normalized employment), to their more policy-relevant forms (e.g., employment). The model contains 46 such technical relations and identities.

Altogether the model contains 64 behavioral equations, technical relations, and identities.

Page 12: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

DATA

The 1990 Public Use Microdata Sample (PUMS) of the U.S. Census (U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1992a) is used in the estimation of labor inputs and prices. The five percent (state) sample is used because it contains more observations than the one percent (metropolitan area) sample, while still containing metropolitan area of residence. A number of steps were taken in preparing these data:

(1) a random sample was drawn from the PUMS for the estimation of Mincerian-style earnings equations.

(2) a skill-quantity variable was computed from the earnings equations for all individual observations in the five percent PUMS. This skill-quantity variable is important in making the demographic disaggregations described below.

(3) the individual observations were aggregated to the Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA) level to form aggregate area labor inputs and prices. Altogether 273 MSAs are identified from the 1990 PUMS five percent sample. As part of this third step, individual observations were grouped into eight demographic groups based on male/female, Mexican/non-Mexican, native-born/foreign-born, and high skill/low skill status. The criteria for assigning skill level are discussed below.

Page 13: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Earnings EquationsIn preparing the data for estimation of earnings equations, we drew a 10

percent random subsample of the five percent PUMS. This was done following the subsampling procedures described in the PUMS Technical Documentation (U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1992b). Only those observations satisfying the

following criteria were used: age between 16 and 65, not currently in school,

not currently in the military, not self-employed, and

1989 earnings greater than zero. This process yields a national subsample of 456,202 observations.

Page 14: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Using this national subsample, we econometrically estimated Mincerian-style earnings equations separately for males (235,069 observations) and females

(221,133 observations). For these earnings equations, an hourly wage variable was created by dividing 1989 earnings by hours worked in 1989 (computed as

hours worked per week times weeks worked in 1989).

The natural logarithm of the 1989 hourly wage served as the dependent variable.

The independent variables included: educational attainment, potential labor market experience (constructed as age less education less six) and its square, a dummy for metropolitan area residence, race and ethnicity dummies, a foreign-

born dummy and its interaction with year of entry dummies, a set of census division dummies, a set of world region of origin dummies, a set of occupation

dummies, and a set of industry dummies.

Page 15: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

The OLS estimates produce reasonable results. For both males and females, the log of hourly earnings increases with education. It also increases with potential labor market experience, but at a decreasing rate. Foreign-born individuals have log-wages below those of natives, although this effect is not statistically significant. The adjusted-R2 in the male earnings equation is 0.365 and that in the female equation is 0.252. The equation F-value for males is 2759.75 and for females is 1524.22.

Page 16: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Skill QuantityBased on the results of the earnings equations, we predicted a “skill-

quantity” variable or skill index for all individuals in the subsample. This skill index was predicted using the estimated coefficients on educational attainment, potential labor market experience and its square, the foreign-born dummy and the interactions between foreign-born and year of entry, and the world region of

origin dummies, along with the actual values of each of these variables for each individual in the subsample. This predicted skill-index variable is

designed to reflect skill quantity (a proxy for human capital) rather than various aspects of “skill price” such as racial or ethnic discrimination or compensating

differentials due to industry, occupation, region of residence, or MSA residence. The skill-quantity estimates are made separately for males and females using the estimated coefficients from the appropriate regression

equation.

Page 17: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Each individual in the subsample was coded as being in one of four skill quartiles by ranking all observations by predicted skill quantity and splitting them into four groups of equal size. Each individual was then designated as low skill or high skill depending on how the skill quartiles are grouped. In the analysis conducted in this paper, the lower two skill quartiles are designated as “low skill” whereas the upper two skill quartiles are designated as “high skill.” This low skill/high skill segmentation is discussed further below.

Page 18: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

AggregationHaving created the skill quartiles from the earnings equations, we next

aggregated the data to the MSA level. To do so, we used the complete five percent 1990 PUMS rather than the subsample used for the earnings equations.

Observations were excluded from the data if they did not meet our “selection criteria.” The skill-quantity variable was computed for all individuals as described

above. The individuals were then coded as belonging to one of the four skill quartiles based on the value of this skill quantity variable and the quartile “break-

points” determined from the 10 percent national subsample.Individuals were coded as native-born if they were born in the U.S. or in

U.S. outlying areas (e.g. Guam, American Samoa, Puerto Rico). Otherwise, individuals were coded as foreign-born. Mexican status is conferred by birth in Mexico for the foreign-born and by Mexican origin (as reported on the PUMS

Hispanic origin question) for the native born.

Page 19: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

For each demographic group, several variables were created at the MSA level. These include total group population, number employed in the group, group

labor force participation rates, total group earned income, total group non-labor income, total group welfare income, total group social insurance income, and total group hours worked. Aggregate MSA population, employment, earnings, and non-labor income were created by summing across all eight demographic groups. The

eight demographic groups exhaustively include area population, and therefore employment, earnings, and non-labor income.

This aggregation process was conducted MSA-by-MSA, in all states plus the District of Colombia, yielding 273 MSAs. Ten of these 273 cross state boundaries, and therefore represent the combination of data from multiple states. After deleting those MSAs in which one or more of the eight demographic groups have small or zero populations, we are left with 122 useable MSAs for the analysis conducted

below.

Page 20: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

The theoretical aspects of the production technology are reported in some detail in the first two of the following publications:

Diewert, W. Erwin and Terence J. Wales. 1988. “A Normalized Quadratic Semiflexible Functional Form,” Journal of Econometrics 37, 327-342.

Greenwood, Michael J., Gary L. Hunt, and Ulrich Kohli. 1997. “The Factor Market Consequences of Unskilled Immigration to the United States,” Labor Economics, 4, 1-28.

Greenwood, Michael J. and Gary L. Hunt. 1995. “Economic Effects of Immigrants on Native and Foreign-Born Workers: Complementarity, Substitutability, and Other Channels of Influence,” Southern Economic Journal 61, April, 1076-1097.

Page 21: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

MODEL STRUCTURE

Production Function and Factor Prices

We assume that in each metropolitan area, the technology can be represented by an aggregate production function. Let y be the quantity of output and assume J inputs, the quantities of which are denoted by xj. The production

function is written as follows:(1) y = f (x1, . . . , xJ).

This function is assumed to be twice continuously differentiable, increasing, quasi-concave, and linearly homogeneous. Under profit maximization, we get the marginal product conditions (also known as the inverse input demand equations, or the wage equations) by differentiation:

(2)J, 1,..., =j ,

x

)( f =

pw

J

j

where p is the price of output and wj is the price of the jth input, where J = 9 .

Page 22: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

J, 1,..., = k j, ,f f

f f

kj

k j,k j,

) x x( / )( f f ,x / )( f f kj2

k j,jj

To describe the substitution and complementarity relationships between the J inputs, we can use the Hicksian elasticities of complementarity[i]:

(3)

where

. Quasiconcavity of the production function implies that

Page 23: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

J, 1,..., = k j, ,f f

f f

kj

k j,k j,

) x x( / )( f f ,x / )( f f kj2

k j,jj )( f f

0 j j ,

0 > k j ,

0 < k j ,

To describe the substitution and complementarity relationships between the J inputs, we can use the Hicksian elasticities of complementarity[i]:

(3)

where , and

Quasiconcavity of the production function implies that

. Furthermore

if inputs j and k are Hicksian q-complements, and

if inputs j and k are Hicksian q-substitutes.

Page 24: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Real Wage and Employment Effects of a 20-Percent Increase in Foreign-Born, Low-Skilled, Mexican Labor

Factor input Real wages Employment

All Areas (122)

Native, low-skilled, Mexican males 0.34 0.00

Native, low-skilled, Mexican females -0.34 -0.15

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican males 0.33 -0.01

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican females -0.15 -0.06

Native, high-skilled 0.06 -0.01

Foreign born, low-skilled, Mexican -3.01 19.39

Foreign born, low-skilled, non-Mexican -0.45 -0.17

Foreign born, high-skilled -0.47 -0.07

Page 25: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

California Areas (23)___________________________________________________________________________ Factor input Real wages Employment

Native, low-skilled, Mexican males 0.75 -0.01

Native, low-skilled, Mexican females -0.68 -0.39

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican males 0.59 -0.05

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican females -0.41 -0.16

Native, high-skilled 0.05 -0.03

Foreign born, low-skilled, Mexican -6.85 18.70

Foreign born, low-skilled, non-Mexican -1.05 -0.44

Foreign born, high-skilled -1.16 -0.19

Real Wage and Employment Effects of a 20-Percent Increase in Foreign-Born, Low-Skilled, Mexican Labor

Page 26: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Real Wage and Employment Effects of a 20-Percent Increase in Foreign-Born, Low-Skilled, Mexican Labor

Areas in Border States (52)

_______________________________________________________________Factor input Real wages Employment

Native, low-skilled, Mexican males 0.69 0.00

Native, low-skilled, Mexican females -0.66 -0.30

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican males 0.67 -0.02

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican females -0.28 -0.11

Native, high-skilled 0.14 -0.03

Foreign born, low-skilled, Mexican -5.90 18.78

Foreign born, low-skilled, non-Mexican -0.85 -0.34

Foreign born, high-skilled -0.90 -0.15

Page 27: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Real Wage and Employment Effects of a 20-Percent Increase in Foreign-Born, Low-Skilled, Mexican Labor

Areas of High Concentration of Foreign Born, Low-Skilled, Mexicans (13)________________________________________________________________________________________________

Factor input Real wages Employment

Native, low-skilled, Mexican males 1.42 0.07

Native, low-skilled, Mexican females -1.27 -0.40

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican males 1.55 0.01

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican females -0.23 -0.12

Native, high-skilled 0.59 -0.04

Foreign born, low-skilled, Mexican -11.42 17.59

Foreign born, low-skilled, non-Mexican -1.38 -0.51

Foreign born, high-skilled -1.40 -0.20

Page 28: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Real Wage and Employment Effects of a 20-Percent Increase in Foreign-Born, Low-Skilled, Mexican Labor

Areas of Low Concentration of Foreign Born, Low-Skilled, Mexicans (43)

__________________________________________________________Factor input Real wages Employment

Native, low-skilled, Mexican males 0.02 0.00

Native, low-skilled, Mexican females -0.02 -0.01

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican males 0.02 -0.00

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican females -0.02 -0.00

Native, high-skilled -0.00 -0.00

Foreign born, low-skilled, Mexican -0.19 19.96

Foreign born, low-skilled, non-Mexican -0.04 -0.01

Foreign born, high-skilled -0.04 -0.01

Page 29: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Real Wage and Employment Effects of a 20-Percent Increase in Foreign-Born, Low-Skilled, Mexican Labor

McAllen, Texas________________________________________________________________________________________________Factor input Real wages Employment

Native, low-skilled, Mexican males 3.75 0.13

Native, low-skilled, Mexican females -4.03 -1.96

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican males 4.33 -0.44

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican females 0.22 -0.70

Native, high-skilled 2.29 -0.16

Foreign born, low-skilled, Mexican -25.44 13.90

Foreign born, low-skilled, non-Mexican -1.79 -0.77

Foreign born, high-skilled -2.05 -0.42

Page 30: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Real Wage and Employment Effects of a 20-Percent Increase in Foreign-Born, Low-Skilled, Mexican Labor

Brownsville, Texas________________________________________________________________________________________________Factor input Real wages Employment

Native, low-skilled, Mexican males 2.70 0.13

Native, low-skilled, Mexican females -2.14 -0.74

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican males 3.88 0.03

Native, low-skilled, non-Mexican females -0.25 -0.21

Native, high-skilled 1.68 0.08

Foreign born, low-skilled, Mexican -20.34 15.43

Foreign born, low-skilled, non-Mexican -1.94 -0.66

Foreign born, high-skilled -1.87 -0.32

Page 31: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Percentage Change in the Real Rental Price of Capital Due to a 20-Increase in Foreign-Born, Low-Skilled Mexican Labor - Selected Areas

Area Percentage Change

All areas (122) 0.27

California areas (23) 0.82

Texas areas (23) 0.33

Arizona, New Mexico, Colorado areas (11)

0.30

Areas in border states (52) 0.56

Areas of high concentration of foreign-born, low-skilled, Mexicans (13)

0.88

Areas of low concentration of foreign-born, low-skilled, Mexicans (43)

0.02

Page 32: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Percentage Change in the Real Rental Price of Capital Due to a 20-Increase in Foreign-Born, Low-Skilled Mexican Labor - Selected Areas

Santa Ana, CA 1.31 Beaumont, TX 0.06

Bakersfield, CA 0.74 Brazoria, TX 0.12

Chico-Paradise, CA 0.12 Brownsville, TX 1.44

Fresno, CA 1.04 Bryan-College Station, TX 0.14

Los Angeles, CA 2.54 Corpus Christi, TX 0.12

Merced, CA 1.66 Dallas, TX 0.23

Modesto, CA 0.74 El Paso, TX 1.58

Oakland, CA 0.27 Ft. Worth-Arlington, TX 0.17

Oxnard-Ventura, CA 0.89 Galveston, TX 0.08

Redding, CA 0.02 Houston, TX 0.27

San Bernardino, CA 1.04 Killeen-Temple, TX 0.07

Sacramento, CA 0.15 Longview-Marshall, TX 0.05

Salinas, CA 1.68 Lubbock, TX 0.06

San Diego, CA 0.80 McAllen-Edinberg-Mission, TX 1.75

San Francisco, CA 0.19 Midland, TX 0.25

San Jose, CA 0.69 Odessa, TX 0.26

Page 33: The Economic Consequences of U.S. Immigration: Part 3

Percentage Change in the Real Rental Price of Capital Due to a 20-Increase in Foreign-Born, Low-Skilled Mexican Labor - Selected Areas

Santa Barbara, CA 0.45 San Antonio, TX 0.48

Santa Cruz, CA 0.93 Tyler, TX 0.16

Santa Rosa, CA 0.29 Waco, TX 0.13

Stockton-Lodi, CA 0.58 Wichita Falls, TX 0.07

Vallejo, CA 0.31 Yakima, WA 0.81

Visalia-Tulare, CA 1.43 Yuma, AZ 1.66

Yuba City, CA 0.42 Las Cruces, NM 0.70

Abilene, TX 0.10 Richland-Kennwick-Pasco, WA 0.48

Amarillo, TX 0.09 Greeley, CO 0.22

Austin, TX 0.16