the economic aspects of operational reliability in …...the economic aspects of operational...

10
2007 iREP Symposium- Bulk Power System Dynamics and Control - VII, Revitalizing Operational Reliability August 19-24, 2007, Charleston, SC, USA The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, Urbana, IL, USA Abstract The implementation of electricity markets in various U.S. jurisdictions has resulted in multiple markets at different time scales for trading the same electricity commodity. This multi- settlement system allows the participation of players with physical resources and loads, as well as financial entities. Given the strong interactions of market and system operations, the multiple markets and the participation of financial players make the operational reliability management an increasingly challenging task. While the nature of the interactions between the system and market operations is well understood on a qualitative basis, the quantification of the operational reliability impacts on the overall economics of electricity markets is, typically, not performed. In this paper, we develop a general approach to quantify the market performance as a function of operational reliability criterion in a multi-settlement environment while taking into account the participation of players with physical resources and load, as well as financial entities. The quantification provides meaningful measures of the monetary and the resource dispatch impacts of the compliance with the operational reliability criterion in force. We illustrate the application of the proposed approach to the ISO-NE system in the quantification of the comparative impacts of two different security criteria for the 2005 - 2006 day-ahead and real-time markets. Through this study, we gain insights into the distinctions between day-ahead and real-time markets, as well as the impacts of participating financial entities in addition to those with physical generation assets or loads. Keywordselectricity market performance, social welfare maximization, consumer and producer surplus, congestion rents multi-settlement systems, day-ahead and real-time markets, financial entities, security assessment, operational reliability criterion. I. Introduction The recent blackouts around the globe have provided an impetus for creating improvements in the operational reliability of large-scale power systems. A direct outcome is the setup of NERC as the first the Electric Reliability Organization for the North American grid [1] in accordance with the 2005 Energy Policy Act [2]. Operational reliability management is a highly challenging task, and even more so in the presence of competitive electricity markets, with both financial entities and the physical load or asset owning players. Since system and market operations strongly interact, any change in the system operational reliability impacts the economics and vice-versa. While the nature of the interactions between the system and market operations is well understood qualitatively, the quantification of the operational reliability impacts on the overall economics of electricity markets is, typically, not performed. In this paper, we propose an approach to quantify the dependence of the performance of electricity commodity markets on the operational reliability taking into account the interactions of the electricity markets and the presence of the two types of participants – physical and financial. We illustrate the application of the proposed approach to the large-scale ISO-NE system for the study of the monetary impacts of changing current operational reliability criterion in force to two other criteria considered. A key issue in system operations is the specification of, and the compliance with the operational reliability criterion. Operational reliability and system security are synonymous terms and we use them interchangeably in this paper. System security is defined as the ability of the interconnected system to provide electricity with the appropriate quality under normal and contingency conditions [3]. The security criterion specification entails the construction of the set of the postulated contingencies together with the associated preventive and/or corrective control actions for each contingency [4]. For a given operating state, security assessment requires the verification that no violation occurs for any of the postulated contingencies taking fully into account the deployment of the associated security control actions. As these actions affect the economic utilization of the resources, there is a need to assess the monetary impacts of complying with the security criterion. This task is complicated further in the market environment since players may or may not have physical resources or loads and the markets are strongly interrelated over time. The typical electricity market structure employs a sequence of markets consisting of the hourly day-ahead markets, or DAMs, and the real-time markets, or RTMs, which take place every 5 to 10 minutes [4]. The RTMs are strictly physical markets and serve as the balancing mechanism to adjust real- time differences from the DAM outcomes. Such a structure is commonly referred to as a multi-settlement system [6]-[7] to underline the fact that there are multiple settlements at different points in time for the same commodity. Although the DAMs are financial markets in contrast to the purely physical RTMs, both markets are cleared using an identical approach. A key difference between these markets is the nature of the participants. While financial entities may participate in the DAMs, only players having physical resources or loads can participate in the RTMs. In addition, while the demand may be price responsive in the DAMs, the demand is, typically, fixed in the RTMs. 1-4244-1519-5/07/$25.00 ©2007 IEEE.

Upload: others

Post on 05-Apr-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in …...The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department

2007 iREP Symposium- Bulk Power System Dynamics and Control - VII, Revitalizing Operational Reliability August 19-24, 2007, Charleston, SC, USA

The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets

Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering

University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, Urbana, IL, USA

Abstract The implementation of electricity markets in various U.S. jurisdictions has resulted in multiple markets at different time scales for trading the same electricity commodity. This multi-settlement system allows the participation of players with physical resources and loads, as well as financial entities. Given the strong interactions of market and system operations, the multiple markets and the participation of financial players make the operational reliability management an increasingly challenging task. While the nature of the interactions between the system and market operations is well understood on a qualitative basis, the quantification of the operational reliability impacts on the overall economics of electricity markets is, typically, not performed. In this paper, we develop a general approach to quantify the market performance as a function of operational reliability criterion in a multi-settlement environment while taking into account the participation of players with physical resources and load, as well as financial entities. The quantification provides meaningful measures of the monetary and the resource dispatch impacts of the compliance with the operational reliability criterion in force. We illustrate the application of the proposed approach to the ISO-NE system in the quantification of the comparative impacts of two different security criteria for the 2005 - 2006 day-ahead and real-time markets. Through this study, we gain insights into the distinctions between day-ahead and real-time markets, as well as the impacts of participating financial entities in addition to those with physical generation assets or loads. Keywords— electricity market performance, social welfare maximization, consumer and producer surplus, congestion rents multi-settlement systems, day-ahead and real-time markets, financial entities, security assessment, operational reliability criterion. I. Introduction The recent blackouts around the globe have provided an impetus for creating improvements in the operational reliability of large-scale power systems. A direct outcome is the setup of NERC as the first the Electric Reliability Organization for the North American grid [1] in accordance with the 2005 Energy Policy Act [2]. Operational reliability management is a highly challenging task, and even more so in the presence of competitive electricity markets, with both financial entities and the physical load or asset owning players. Since system and market operations strongly interact, any change in the system operational reliability impacts the economics and vice-versa. While the nature of the interactions

between the system and market operations is well understood qualitatively, the quantification of the operational reliability impacts on the overall economics of electricity markets is, typically, not performed. In this paper, we propose an approach to quantify the dependence of the performance of electricity commodity markets on the operational reliability taking into account the interactions of the electricity markets and the presence of the two types of participants – physical and financial. We illustrate the application of the proposed approach to the large-scale ISO-NE system for the study of the monetary impacts of changing current operational reliability criterion in force to two other criteria considered. A key issue in system operations is the specification of, and the compliance with the operational reliability criterion. Operational reliability and system security are synonymous terms and we use them interchangeably in this paper. System security is defined as the ability of the interconnected system to provide electricity with the appropriate quality under normal and contingency conditions [3]. The security criterion specification entails the construction of the set of the postulated contingencies together with the associated preventive and/or corrective control actions for each contingency [4]. For a given operating state, security assessment requires the verification that no violation occurs for any of the postulated contingencies taking fully into account the deployment of the associated security control actions. As these actions affect the economic utilization of the resources, there is a need to assess the monetary impacts of complying with the security criterion. This task is complicated further in the market environment since players may or may not have physical resources or loads and the markets are strongly interrelated over time. The typical electricity market structure employs a sequence of markets consisting of the hourly day-ahead markets, or DAMs, and the real-time markets, or RTMs, which take place every 5 to 10 minutes [4]. The RTMs are strictly physical markets and serve as the balancing mechanism to adjust real-time differences from the DAM outcomes. Such a structure is commonly referred to as a multi-settlement system [6]-[7] to underline the fact that there are multiple settlements at different points in time for the same commodity. Although the DAMs are financial markets in contrast to the purely physical RTMs, both markets are cleared using an identical approach. A key difference between these markets is the nature of the participants. While financial entities may participate in the DAMs, only players having physical resources or loads can participate in the RTMs. In addition, while the demand may be price responsive in the DAMs, the demand is, typically, fixed in the RTMs.

1-4244-1519-5/07/$25.00 ©2007 IEEE.

Page 2: The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in …...The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department

The regional transmission organization, or the RTO, manages the market operations, as well as the system operations. The strong inter-relationships between system security management and market mechanisms imply that the ability of the RTO to ensure secure system operations is strongly dependent on, and also impacts, electricity markets. The price responsive nature of the buyers and the participation of the financial players in the DAMs are key factors in these relationships. In fact, such factors contribute to the tight coupling between system and market operations. The basic thrust of this work is to establish a concrete basis for quantifying the economic efficiency of electricity markets as a function of the system security criterion taking explicitly into account the presence of the financial players in addition to the physical asset participants. The economic efficiency of electricity markets is analyzed both empirically and analytically. The empirical studies investigate the adverse impacts of market participants’ behaviors on the performance of electricity markets [8]-[11]. The analytical studies, on the other hand, focus on the impacts of constrained system operations on markets to determine the unavoidable losses in the economic efficiency of electricity markets [12],[13]. The impacts of financial market participants and speculative trading are also analyzed with a focus on the relationship between day-ahead and real-time market prices. The study in [14] examines the relationship between day-ahead and real-time market prices in the “Mid-Atlantic Electricity Market” and illustrates that mean day-ahead prices are lower than mean real-time prices. The study on speculative trading in [15] suggests that financial entity participation would increase the market efficiency and decrease the so-called “average procurement cost” of electricity. In [6]-[7], it has been argued that the multi-settlement approach may also enhance the economic efficiency of electricity markets due to the improved price certainty, market liquidity and market power mitigation. The interactions between the system security criterion and the associated economics are investigated using the marginal costing information to determine the prices of system security and to evaluate expected system security costs [17]-[20]. The study in [23], for the first time, proposed a method to quantify the market performance as a function of system security criterion in single settlement environment in a way that appropriately reflects the RTO operations. However, there is a clear need to explicitly take into account the multi-settlement system and the different nature of the DAM participants and the RTM players. This work is intended as a step towards fulfilling this need. To that end, this work investigates the role of financial entities in electricity markets within a multi-settlement environment and extends the approach proposed in [23] to markets with financial entities in a multi-settlement environment. In this paper, we develop a general approach to quantify the monetary impacts of complying with a specified security criterion in a multi-settlement market environment. The basic building block of the proposed approach is the quantification of the market performance for a system snapshot under a specified security criterion. This quantification, based on the emulation of the way the RTOs currently operate the markets

and the systems, provides meaningful measures of the financial and the resource dispatch impacts. We extend the snapshot analysis and quantify the performance of both the DAM and the RTM taking into account the interrelationships among them. The evaluation of the impacts over a longer period requires an extension of the snapshot analysis. We develop such an extension so as to be able to capture the impacts of diverse system and market conditions – changes in the network parameters, the set of resources and the market participants’ behaviors. For a different criterion, we undertake this approach and quantify the corresponding market performance. Based on the market outcomes under different criteria, we carry out comparative market performance assessments. The proposed approach has a wide range of applications such as the justification by the RTO of the decision to modify the security criterion to be used and the costs/benefits analysis of network improvements to mitigate the market performance impacts of a set of specified contingencies. We illustrate the application of the proposed approach to the large-scale ISO-NE system to quantify the dollar impacts of changing from the current security criterion to two other ones using the actual 2005 - 2006 day-ahead and real-time data – the historical system model and the bids/offers submitted – with the actual market clearing methodology. These studies capture in a meaningful way the impacts of the changes with respect to the current security criterion. We analyze the impacts of the multi-settlement system on the social welfare attained in the RTMs and discuss in detail the role of financial entities and that of the security control actions. This paper contains five additional sections. The nature of the problem and the market performance quantification for a system snapshot are described in section II. We devote section III to the discussion of the interrelationships between a DAM and one of the corresponding RTMs. In section IV, we provide the proposed approach and discuss its possible applications. We illustrate the application of the proposed approach to the large-scale ISO-NE system in Section V and present the study results in detail. Section VI provides concluding remarks. II. Market Performance Assessment of a System Snapshot We introduce specific assumptions concerning unit commitment decisions, ancillary services and the market participants’ behaviors so as to allow the side-by-side comparison of different security criteria impacts for a given system. We assume that the unit commitment decisions fully reflect the requirements of the particular security criterion in force. As the focus of this investigation is limited to the energy commodity in the DAMs and the RTMs, we assume that the provision of ancillary services under the RTO framework do not impose additional constraints. For the purposes of this study, we furthermore assume that the bidding behavior of each market participant is independent of the security criterion in force. Since we replicate the RTO actions, we ensure compliance with the security criterion in

Page 3: The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in …...The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department

force, but implicitly ignore the probability of any contingency in the studies.

The modeling of the large-scale interconnected system operated by the RTO requires the explicit representation of the areas that make up the system as well the tie lines that inter-connect them in market and system operations. We consider a power system network consisting of K interconnected areas denoted by the set with each area { : 1, ,k k = LAA }K kA having a node set whose cardinality is . Each area

is connected to one or more other areas via tie lines. We associate a security criterion with a specific contingency list and a specified control action – preventive or corrective – for every contingency on that list. A preventive control action associated with a postulated contingency entails the modification of the pre-contingency or base case state, to eliminate any potential violation, if that contingency were, in fact, to occur. On the other hand, an associated corrective control action involves the deployment of generation re-dispatch/load curtailment to modify the post-contingency state after the contingency does occur.

kN |k|Nk ∈A A

CCJ

We carry out the analysis at a time t using the system snapshot. Under a specified security criterion, the RTO decision making problem takes explicitly into account the multi-area structure and the constraints imposed by the tie line limits. While the interconnected system has a single market operated by the RTO, the network structure and the other physical considerations necessitate that we consider the market players in each area separately. We denote by ( ), the collection of sellers (buyers) of area . Each seller (buyer) submits price and quantity offer (bid) function, indicating the willingness to sell (buy) the amount of energy for the duration represented by the snapshot to (from) the RTO. Bilateral transactions coexist with the RTO market operations. We represent a bilateral transaction

kSkB k ∈A A

wω by the

triplet { , , }w w wm n tω w . The from node is of kwm ∈N kA ,

the exporting area, the to node is of rwn ∈N rA , the

importing area, and the desired transaction amount is wt . The set of all the bilateral transactions is denoted by

1{ , , }Wω ω= KW . Each transaction submits a willingness to pay function, which specifies a willingness to pay for the requested transmission services as a function of the transaction amount delivered [23]. The RTO weighs the willingness to pay of the bilateral transactions with that of the individual market participants to determine the amount of transmission service provision to each player. For this purpose for the given snapshot of the system, the RTO solves a security- constrained market problem, with the objective to maximize the social welfare under the security criterion , whose contingency index set is denoted by J

CC.. We state the

security constrained market problem as:

( )( ) ( )( ) ( )(1 k k

K0 0

b b s s w wk b s

max p p tβ β α= ∈ ∈

⎛ ⎞− +⎜ ⎟

⎝ ⎠∑ ∑ ∑ ∑S

B S)

1

W0

w=(1)

subject to ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( )0 0 0 0 0 0 0= ↔s bg p , p , t , , 0χ γ λ (2)

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( )0 0 0 0 0 0 0h≤ ↔s bh p , p , t , 0χ ,γ μ (3)

and for every j ∈ CJ ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( )j j j j j j j= ↔s bg p , p , t , , 0χ γ λ (4)

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( )j j j j j j jh≤ ↔s bh p , p , t , , 0χ γ μ (5)

( ) ( ) ( ) ( )j jj 0s≤ ↔−s s s

pp p μΔ (6)

( ) ( ) ( ) ( )j jj 0b≤ ↔−b b b

pp p μΔ (7)

( ) ( ) ( ) ( )j jj 0t≤ ↔− tt t μΔ . (8)

Here, we use the superscript ( j ) to denote the contingency case j with the base case denoted by (0). We use sp ( dp ) to denote the injection (withdrawal) vector and t to denote the vector of the bilateral transaction amounts of the W transactions. χ is the vector of the system states or dependent variables and γ is the vector of the control or independent variables other than those for real power. We associate a vector with the right-hand side of each constraint, which we call the dual variable of that constraint. The relations in (2) and (3) represent the operational constraints for the base case, while those in (4)–(8) represent the operational constraints for each contingency case and associated control action. The equality constraints in (2) and (4) describe the nodal power balance equations for the base case and for each postulated contingency case, respectively, resulting in a total of power flow equations. The base case

1+CJ| |(3) and each contingency case (5) inequality

constraints state the system components’ operational limits, as well as the constraints arising from the physical, engineering and policy considerations. The constraints on the decision variables associated with the security control action for each contingency j ∈ JC. are expressed in (6)–(8). The preventive control actions have a zero range, in contrast to the corrective actions whose non-zero range reflects the additional flexibility to address the onset of the contingency. We use

( ), , ;W CSM B to represent the security-constrained market problem in (1)-(8). We distinguish explicitly between fixed demand buyers and those with price-responsive demand. The fixed demand bid is a special case of the price-sensitive bid in that a specified quantity is submitted without price information. Such a bid indicates an unlimited willingness to pay for the electricity purchases to meet the fixed quantity bid, i.e., the buyer is willing to pay any price to obtain the electricity amount in the bid. There are, however, difficulties in determining the appropriate value of the benefits of the fixed demand buyers. In order to include these buyers’ benefits in the objective function of ( ), , ;W CSM B , we use a constant τ per MWh

Page 4: The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in …...The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department

benefit value for the fixed demand. The market performance under the specified security criterion

for the snapshot system may be quantified from the market outcomes given by the solution of . We use the optimal value of the social welfare under as a measure for the economic performance of the market as a whole.

C( , , ;W CSM B )

CS| C

We use the system social welfare given in (1) and decompose into area components. For each area kA , we evaluate

( )( ) ( )( )

k

k

0 0k b b s s

b bs s

p pβ β∗ ∗

∈∈

−⎡ ⎤⎣ ⎦∑SC

C

(9)

to determine the area kA contribution to the system social welfare1. In addition, we also evaluate the participant surplus for each player. The seller s with a generating unit at node i of the area kA has a producer surplus

( ) ( ) ( )( )0s k 0 0i s s sp pσ λ β∗ ∗ ∗⎡ −⎣C C

⎤⎦ , (10)

where, is the locational marginal price (LMP) at node i of the area k corresponding to the base case conditions. The consumer surplus for a buyer b with demand at node i in area

( )0iλ∗

kA is ( )( ) ( ) ( )b 0 0 0

b b i bp pσ β λ∗ ∗ ∗⎡ −⎣C C⎤⎦

. (11)

However, the LMP at each node may be different for a constrained grid. In fact, for lossless system, the nonzero LMP difference is an indication of congestion. Consequently, when congestion is present in the system, the LMP at each node may be different. Each LMP represents the costs to supply an additional unit of energy at the node. The LMP differences also yield nonnegative revenues for the RTO. The RTO also collects the revenues from the buyers and makes payments to the sellers for the energy traded in the pool. Absent congestion, in a lossless system, the revenues from the buyers exactly equal to the payments to all the sellers. When congestion occurs, however, the revenues from the buyers may exceed the payments to the sellers. We refer to the difference between the revenues and payments as the congestion rents of which the RTO collects. We also use metrics related to the demand served. We use the total dispatched load to evaluate the total cleared demand quantity under criterion and denote it by C

1 The contributions of the bilateral transactions are not included in (9) since it is arbitrary, as to what portion of the contributions are allocated to which area.

( ) ( )

1 ,k kw

K0 0

bk w i nb i

P p t∗

= ∈ =∈ ∈

⎛ ⎞+⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟

⎝ ⎠∑ ∑ ∑ ∑

WNC

CBw∗ . (12)

We compute the area-wide net injection to indicate amount of net power imported into to an area kA with

( ) ( )

k k

k k0 0s b

s b

P p p∗ ∗

∈ ∈

+ +∑ ∑CCBS

Wt (13)

where denotes the portion of the ktW

kA net imports due to the bilateral transactions in the set W . The values of the metrics in (9)-(13) are used in the performance quantification of the market for a given snapshot and constitute the basic building elements in the quantification. We conceptually represent this structure in Fig.1.

Fig. 1 Conceptual market assessment structure for a system snapshot

system operations

market operations C market performance

metrics under C

In a multi-settlement environment, the electricity market are interrelated. As such the market performance quantification needs to take into account such interrelationships. We next extend the analysis into such an environment.

III. Market Performance Assessment of a DAM and the Corresponding RTMs The actual system conditions may differ from the outcomes of a DAM. The RTO uses market forces to handle such deviation and runs RTMs every 5-10 minutes. For each hour h, the DAM

has M RTMs, ,R ,L ,R . We establish the linkage between D and

( )hD ( 1)h,R ( 2)h, (h,M )

h

{ }( ) : 1, ,h,m m M= LR . TT

)

he DAM is a voluntary bid-based, financially binding market which, typically, corresponds to a collection of 24 separate hourly energy markets, one for each hour of the following day. Due to its mostly financial nature, participation in the DAM is not limited to players with physical resources. For the hour h DAM, we assume that the snapshot used for hour h represents the system for that entire hour. We suppress the hourly notation in what follows. The analysis of the hour h DAM complying with the security criterion , i.e. D , uses the snapshot market problem M B , and we write shorthand:

C( , , ;W CS

( ), , ;↔ W CSD M B .

In this formulation, we explicitly take into account the entities

Page 5: The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in …...The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department

that constitute the set of sellers and the set of buyers at hour h. In terms of this set-based formulation, we have flexibility to consider the subset of the participants with physical resources and that of the financial entities. We use superscript r ( f ) to denote the participants with physical resources ( financial players ). Therefore, the set of sellers S is simply the union of and . rS fS By its very nature, the RTM participation is limited to the players with actual load and physical generation assets. We consider the RTM that complies with the security criterion C for the sub-period m in the hour h and denote it henceforth by

, . We use again the system snapshot approach to analyze the real-time market and formulate in an analogous manner to the snapshot market problem

to represent and write:

( )mR 1, ,m = L M

)

)

( )mR

( , , ;r r WSM B C ( )mR

( )( ) , , ;r rm ↔ WSR M B C .

Each uses the offers of the sellers with physical assets who participated in and the real-time fixed demand of the buyers of the subset of , the set of buyers. The solution

determines the market clearing of . The market outcomes specify the deviations from the corresponding outcomes for this sub-period. The market performance of each market, be it or D , may be quantified in terms of the metrics defined in

( )mRD

rB B

( , , ;r rM BS W C ( )mR

( )mRD

( )mR(9)-(13).

Fig. 2 Conceptual market assessment structure for the multi-settlement system The interrelated settlement, as shown in Fig.2, requires the introduction of additional measures of the surpluses of the individual participants. We present these metrics by focusing on the single RTM corresponding to the DAM . We use the notation “^” to denote the optimal values attained in the clearing of . The producer surplus of a seller s at node i with a generating unit is

( )mR D

( )mR

( ) ( )* * * * * *( ) ˆ1 ˆ ˆs i s i s s sm p p p pM λ λ β⎡ + − −⎣S s

⎤⎦ . (14)

Similarly, the consumer surplus of a buyer b with physical demand at node i is evaluated using ( ) ( )* * * * * *( ) ˆ ˆ1 ˆ ˆb i b i b b bm p p p pM λ λ β b

⎡ ⎤− − − +⎣ ⎦S . (15)

The producer surplus of a financial seller fs at node i is modified by the R outcome and is given by ( )m

(* * *( ) ˆ1

f f i is sm pM λ λ⎡ −⎣S )⎤⎦ . (16)

Similarly, the consumer surplus of a financial buyer at node i is evaluated using

fb

(* * *( ) ˆ1

f f i ib bm pM λ λ⎡ − +⎣S )⎤⎦ . (17)

The surplus of a bilateral transaction wω is evaluated by ( ) ( ) ( )* * * * *( ) 1 ˆ ˆ

w w ww n m w w w mm t t t tM λ λ λ α w w⎡ ⎤− − − − +⎣ ⎦S .(18)

The second term disappears unless In addition to the market participants, the RTO may have a surplus due to the difference between revenues from the buyers and payments to the sellers. It can shown that the surplus S of the RTO is given by

*ˆwt t≠ w

( )R m

( )

( )

( ) ( )

( )

( )

* * * * *

( ) ˆ1 ˆ

ˆ1

1 ˆ

ˆ1 ˆ

ˆ1 .

r

ff f

w w w

r

ff f

R i b i b bb

i ibb

n m w w w mw

i s i s ss

i iss

m p p pM

pM

t t tM

p p pM

pM

λ λ

λ λ

λ λ λ

λ λ

λ λ

⎡ ⎤= + −⎣ ⎦

⎡ ⎤+ − − +⎣ ⎦

⎡ ⎤+ − + −⎣ ⎦

⎡ ⎤− + −⎣ ⎦

⎡ ⎤− −⎣ ⎦

W

S

S

S

B

B

(19)

≡ market settlement

D

(1)R

( )mR

market performance

metrics

( )MR

Taking into account the surplus of RTO, and M RTMs we express the social welfare attained by the multi-settlement system for the mth sub period by

( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

( ) ( ) ( ) ,

fr r f f

ff f

total s b ss b s

w Rbwb

m m m

m m m

∈ ∈ ∈

∈∈

= + +

+ + +

m∑ ∑ ∑

∑ ∑W

S S S

S S S

S SB

B

S

(20)

then, from the relations in (14) - (17), it follows that

( ) ( ) ( )1 1

( ) ˆ1 ˆˆ ˆk k

K W* *

total b b s s w wk wb s

m p pM β β α= =∈ ∈

t⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞

= − +⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦

∑ ∑ ∑ ∑SSB

(21)

which is the social welfare S attained in R . The outcome in

( )ˆ m ( )m

(21) indicates that the social welfare attained in

Page 6: The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in …...The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department

multi-settlement system is

. (22) 1

( )ˆ ˆM

mm

=

= ∑S S

In fact, the mere presence of the DAMs, results in surplus transfers of the social welfare attained under RTMs between market participants.

IV. Quantification of the Security Criterion Change on the Market Performance in a Multi-Settlement Environment Under a different security criterion , the RTO solves the problem at each system snapshot in which the constraints in

′C( , , ; ′W CSM B )

(4)–(8) reflect the contingency set JC and the corresponding security control actions associated with each contingency in . We measure the impacts on market performance due to the change in the security criterion from

to by the relative performance of each metric defined in terms of the values under and . In particular, the relative social welfare metric is

′C

C ′C′C C

′ ′Δ = −S S SC C C (23)

and quantifies the change in economic efficiency of the electricity market to the change in the security criterion from

to . We use analogous expressions for each metric in C ′C(9)–.(13) to define the corresponding relative performance metric in response to the security criterion change. These relative measures have practically useful interpretations. For example, the relative metric of the contribution to the social welfare of area kA indicates how the market participants located in kA are impacted by the change in the security criterion from to . We interpret in a similar way the changes in the producer/consumer surpluses, the total dispatched load and the area-wide net injection. In a similar manner, we define the relative performance metrics for the multi-settlement system taking into account both the DAMs and RTMs outcomes.

C ′C

To quantify the overall performance of the multi-settlement system, we introduce additional metrics. From (22), the change in the total social welfare attained under the multi-settlement system is equal to the change in social welfare attained under RTMs ˆ ˆtotal ′′Δ = −S S SCC C . (24) To assess the impacts of the DAM outcomes on the market participants, we define area-wide surpluses of market participants. For example, to evaluate the change in the area-wide surplus of the sellers with generating resources, we define

k,r k,r

ks s

s s′

∈ ∈

Δ = − s∑ ∑S S SS S

C C (25)

We deploy analogous expressions for the financial market participants. We evaluate in a similar manner the changes in the producer/consumer surpluses taking into account the related settlements of the DAMs and the RTMs. Under a given security criterion, snapshots corresponding to different system and market conditions may result in markedly different market performance outcomes. Such differences arise for many reasons including changes in the load, the set of available units, and the offers/bids submitted. Consequently, these assessments must be carried out over a period to correctly capture the impacts of the different conditions that exist during that period. Conceptually, we assess the market performance at each hour of a given study period that is the DAM and the corresponding RTMs at each hour of that period. In effect, we apply the framework shown in Fig. 2 to each hour of the period for the specified security criterion. To assess the market performance impacts due to a change in the security criterion, the entire multiple snapshot procedure must be repeated for the security criterion under consideration. The hourly values of the relative performance metrics are summed to obtain the daily values which, in turn, are used to compute the relative performance metrics for the entire study period. However, for a large–scale system, such an approach may impose a large burden on computing resources. One way to deal with this complication is to perform the assessments for a smaller representative sample of the hours. In this work, we use the scheme introduced in [23] to systematically construct the set of sample days for the DAMs. The proposed approach provides a useful tool to the RTO to analyze the interdependence between market performance and the system security in a multi-settlement environment. The ability to quantify the monetary impacts of compliance with a specified security criterion makes the approach highly useful in regulatory studies, as well as longer–term planning and near–term investigations with the explicit representation of financial and physical asset owning players. The proposed approach has a wide range of applications. These include the studies for the justification by the RTO of the security criterion selection and for and the cost/benefit analysis of network improvements to mitigate the market performance impacts of a set of specified contingencies. V. Application Study: The ISO-NE System We illustrate the application of the proposed approach to the study of the ISO-NE system and markets. The objective of this study is to quantify the economic efficiency of the ISO-NE electricity markets as a function of the security criterion in force. For this purpose, we assess the market performance as a function of three distinct security criteria and perform a comparative analysis of the observed impacts. We measure the changes with respect to the outcomes under the current ISO-NE security criterion.

Page 7: The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in …...The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department

We make use of the system and market data from the years 2005 and 2006 and the actual market clearing software used for the ISO-NE DAM for the simulations in this study. The simulation of the RTMs is also performed using the ISO-NE system DAM system model to represent the RTMs and use the DAM clearing methodology. The large-scale ISO-NE system has a multi-area structure. Each area of the ISO-NE system is characterized as either import or export. The import areas are

A.1 : Boston/NE Massachusetts A.2 : Connecticut A.3 : SW Connecticut A.4 : Norwalk/Stamford

We treat rest of the system as a single export area and denote it by A.5. The detail description of the multi-area structure of the ISO-NE system is provided in [23], [24]. The study is performed for 40 representative DAMs and the corresponding RTMs selected from the years 2005 and 2006. This study period was chosen to allow the use of market and system data that reflects the most up-to-date ISO-NE procedures and rules. In this paper, we focus on the four peak demand hours of each selected market day and discuss the results for these 160 hours. The ISO-NE operates the system under the security criterion

which is a modified (n-2) security criterion 0C [23]. While the single element contingencies in are associated with

preventive control actions, the double element contingencies are associated with corrective control. We select the criterion

as the reference criterion and consider two specific criteria

0CJ

0C

1C , a modified (n–1) security , and , another modified (n–2) security. For the criterion , we consider the single element contingencies in and associate each

contingency with preventive control action. For the criterion , the contingency list ; however, the corrective

control actions are replaced by the preventive control actions for the double element contingencies.

2C

1C

0CJ

2C2 0=C CJ J

For each specified security criterion, we perform market clearing for the DAMs and the corresponding RTMs over the selected hours. We first focus on market performance quantification under the reference criterion . Since the demand in real-time is fixed, the cleared demand values are the same regardless of the security criterion in force. We compare the RTM demand with the corresponding cleared DAM demand in Fig. 3 and analyze the differences in the amount of commodity traded in the two markets. Fig. 3 indicates that the cleared RTM demand values are slightly higher than those in the DAM, except for a few days. Such an outcome indicates that market participants effectively utilize the multi-settlement system in a way so as to decrease the impacts of price volatility observed in the RTMs. In other words, by procuring most of the demand from the DAMs, the buyers remain subject to price volatility in the RTMs for only a fraction of their demand. Similar arguments may be made also for the sellers.

0C

0

5,000

10,000

15,000

20,000

25,000

30,000MW

hour

DAMRTM

Fig.3 Cleared Demand in the DAMs and in the corresponding RTMs Although Fig.3 illustrates comparable cleared demand levels in the two markets, the utilization of the generating resources may differ considerably. In Figs. 4-6 we compare the imports and exports of the areas with respect to those in the DAM. The comparison indicates that there is less utilization of the tie lines interconnecting the areas in the real time than in the day ahead, implying that the real-time demand needs of the import areas’ are met more by those areas’ generation units. Therefore, there is a decrease in the generation by the economic resources of the export area. We may conclude that the RTMs are more “area centric” than the DAMs.

Fig. 4. Imports of area A 1 in the DAMs outcomes and the corresponding RTMs results

0

500

1,000

1,500

2,000

2,500

3,000MW

hour

RTM DAM

0

500

1,000

1,500

2,000

2,500

3,000MW

hour

DAMRTM

Fig. 5. Imports of area A 2 in the DAMs outcomes and the corresponding RTMs results

MW

ng

Fig. 6. Exports of area A in the DAMs outcomes and the correspondi RTMs results

5

Since the benefits of the buyers with fixed demand is unknown, we assign the benefit of constant τ to be 1,000 $/MWh/h for each MW of fixed demand in order to define a proxy benefit values. Such a value may be rationalized in terms of the bid/offer price cap used in the ISO-NE markets. The social welfare results for the DAMs and the

0500

1,0001,5002,0002,5003,000

hour

3,5004,0004,5005,000 DAMRTM

7/25

7/27 8/

28/

58/

99/

29/

149/

209/

2910

/610

/910

/11

10/2

511

/811

/15

11/1

811

/28

12/5

12/1

31/

91/

171/

231/

25 2/9

2/13

2/14

2/28 3/

13/

33/

63/

16 4/4

4/6

4/10

4/12 5/

35/

125/

165/

19

7/25

7/27 8/

28/

58/

99/

29/

149/

209/

2910

/610

/910

/11

10/2

511

/811

/15

11/1

811

/28

12/5

12/1

3 1/9

1/17

1/23

1/25 2/

92/

132/

142/

28 3/1

3/3

3/6

3/16 4/

44/

64/

104/

12 5/3

5/12

5/16

5/19

7/25

7/27 8/

28/

58/

99/

29/

149/

209/

2910

/610

/910

/11

10/2

511

/811

/15

11/1

811

/28

12/5

12/1

3 1/9

1/17

1/23

1/25 2/

92/

132/

142/

28 3/1

3/3

3/6

3/16 4/

44/

64/

104/

12 5/3

5/12

5/16

5/19

7/25

7/27 8/

28/

58/

99/

29/

149/

209/

2910

/610

/910

/11

10/2

511

/811

/15

11/1

811

/28

12/5

12/1

3 1/9

1/17

1/23

1/25 2/

92/

132/

142/

28 3/1

3/3

3/6

3/16 4/

44/

64/

104/

12 5/3

5/12

5/16

5/19

Page 8: The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in …...The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department

corresponding RTMs are presented in Fig. 7. To provide a comparison basis, we normalize the results using the average social welfare attained in the RTMs as the base value. Note that for a given hour, the RTM social welfare is higher than that of the DAM due to two factors. First, more demand is cleared in RTMs and second, the cleared demands have fixed demand nature and as such their proxy benefits are higher than those of the price responsive demand.

Fig. 7. Social welfare attained in the DAMs and the corresponding RTMs We next examine the monetary impacts of the changes in the

e next examine the monetary impacts of the changes in the

Fig. 8. Social welfare impacts

On the other hand, we observe nearly the opposite impacts on

he corresponding impacts of changing the security criterion

security criterion. We use the hourly social welfare as the basic metric in this investigation. We normalize the social welfare values using the average value of the hourly social welfare under the reference criterion 0C as the base value. We first consider the economic impa of the increased import capabilities arising from changing the security criterion from 0C to 1C . The analysis of the ISO-NE system during the study perio indicates that the replacement of the security criterion 0C by the criterion 1C results in the increased import capabilities of the import areas for each hour. The increased import capabilities are utilized leading to higher social welfare. We may view these improvements as a measure of the “costs” of not violating the constraints due to the double element contingencies in the reference criterion. Due to the fact that the system operations under the criterion

2C are more constraining than those under the criterion 0C , security change from 0C to 2C results in the decreased

import capabilities of the import areas for every hour of the study period. Such decreased import capabilities may lower the social welfare. We interpret these reductions to be a measure of the “costs” of replacing corrective for preventive control actions. There are also a number of days during in which the change in security criterion from 0C to either 1C or

2C has no impacts on the social welfare. For such ys, ing into account the double element contingencies has no

economic impacts. In fact, the market clearing is such that either the double element contingency case constraints are not binding or the impacts to the social welfare value are insignificant. The plots of the changes

1Δ CS and

2Δ CS of the

social welfare arising from a change of the security criterion are given in Fig. 8.

cts

d

the

datak

Wsecurity criterion on the area surpluses of the market participants. The change of security criterion from 0C to 1C has diverse impacts on the different market participants. For illustration purposes, we focus on five representative days and

indicate the impacts for these days. The security criterion change results in more utilization of the export area generation resources and, therefore, decreases the production of the import area units. Thus, there is a corresponding change in the surpluses of the areas. In Fig. 9, we give the plot of the changes in the surpluses sellers with generating resources for areas A.

.1, A.2 and A.5.

Fig. 9 Changes of the total area sellers’ surpluses ( physical asset owning sellers) in response to the change from 0C to 1C

the surpluses of the buyers. While the surpluses of the export area buyers are decreasing, those in the import areas are increasing. The buyers within the import areas are able to procure their demand from more economic resources in the export area, and thereby decrease their payments. In fact, the changes in the surpluses are particularly more pronounced for the import area A.

.2 buyers, as shown in Fig. 10.

Fig. 10 Changes of the total area buyers surpluses (physical buyers) in response to the change from 0C to 1C

Ton the surpluses of the financial entities are plotted in Figs. 11 and 12. The results indicate that the change of the security criterion has minor impacts on the total area surpluses of the financial entities – be they buyers or sellers. Such impacts are insignificant when compared to the ones of the players with physical assets and loads.

-

1CSΔ2CSΔ

7/25

7/27 8/

28/

58/

99/

29/

149/

209/

2910

/610

/910

/11

10/2

511

/811

/15

11/1

811

/28

12/5

12/1

31/

91/

171/

231/

25 2/9

2/13

2/14

2/28 3/

13/

33/

63/

16 4/4

4/6

4/10

4/12 5/

35/

125/

165/

19

7/27 8/05 11/28 1/17 1/23

hour

A 1 A 2 A 5

7/27 8/05 11/28 1/17 1/23-0.12

-0.10 -0.08 -0.06 -0.04 -0.02 0.000.02 0.04 0.06

A 1 A 2 A 5

hour

0 0.20.40.60.81.01.2

hour

1.4 1.6 1.8 2.0

DAMRTM

/25

/27

8/2

8/5

8/9

9/2

/14

/20

/29

0/6

0/9

/11

/25 1/8

/15

/18

/28 2/5

/13 1/9

/17

/23

/25

2/9

/13

/14

/28

3/1

3/3

3/6

/16

4/4

4/6

/10

/12

5/3

/12

/16

/19

7 7 9 9 9 1 1 10 10 1 11 11 11 1 12 1 1 1 2 2 2 3 4 4 5 5 5

-0.03 -0.02

0.010.020.030.04

-0.04

-0.01 0.00

hour

0.050.06

0.015

0.010

0.005

0

-0.005

-0,010

Page 9: The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in …...The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department

Fig. 11 Changes of the total area sellers’ surpluses (financial sellers) in response to the change from to 0C 1C

Fig. 12 Changes of the total area buyers surpluses (financial buyers) in response to the change from to 0C 1C

Due to the fact that the system operations under the criterion

are more constraining than those under the criterion , the security change from to results in impacts of exactly opposite nature on the market participant surpluses than those for the security criterion change from to . The decreased import capabilities of the import areas for every hour of the study period result in the increased surpluses of the import areas’ generating units and the export area’s buyers. In contrast, the surpluses of the export area generating units and the import areas’ buyers are decreasing.

2C 0C

0C 2C

0C 1C

The ISO-NE study indicates that the electricity markets become more “area centric” in real time due the impacts of reduced participation and the fixed demand nature of the buyers. Therefore the impacts of changing security criterion from to are more pronounced for the RTMs than for the DAMs.

0C 2C

VI. Concluding Remarks In this paper, we propose an approach for the quantification of the market performance as a function of the security criterion. We explicitly consider the interactions between the hourly DAM and the corresponding RTMs and the presence of financial players in the DAMs. The proposed approach also provides an important tool to analyze the ramifications of changing the security criterion on a solid quantitative basis. As such, the proposed approach establishes a concrete linkage between the economic efficiency of the electricity markets and the system security. We illustrate the application of the

proposed approach to the ISO-NE electricity markets to analyze the market efficiency impacts of the current security criterion in force. Our investigation provides important insights into the interrelationships of the DAMs and the RTMs, as well as the role of financial entities and that of the security control actions.

-0.015

-0.01

-0.005

0

0.005

0.01

A 1 A 2 A 5

7/27 8/05 11/28 1/17 1/23

hour

References [1] NERC, http://www.nerc.com/about/ero.html. [2] U.S. Department of Energy, http://thomas.loc.gov/cgi-bin/bdquery/z?

d109:h.r.00006: [3] NERC,

http://www.nerc.com/~filez/standards/Reliability_Standards.html. [4] T. E. D. Liacco, “The adaptive reliability control system,” IEEE Trans.

Power App. and Sys., vol. PAS-86, pp. 517-531, May 1967.

7/27 8/05 11/28 1/17 1/23

A 1 A 2 A 5

-0.015

-0.01

-0.005

0

0.005

0.01

0.015

hour

[5] ISO-NE, “The Multi-Settlement System,” http://www.iso-ne.com/nwsiss /grid_mkts/how_mkts_wrk/multi_settle/ index.html.

[6] K. W. Cheung, “Standard market design for ISO New England wholesale electricity market: An Overview,” Proc. of IEEE Int. Conf. Electric Utility Deregulation, Restructuring Power Tech., vol.1, pp. 38-43, 2004.

[7] R. Kamat and S. S. Oren, “Multi-settlement systems for electricity markets: zonal aggregation under network uncertainty and market power,” Proc. of 35th Hawaii Inter. Conf. Syst. Sci., pp. 739-748, Jan. 2002.

[8] R. Kamat and S. S. Oren, “Two-settlement systems for electricity markets under network uncertainty and market power,” Journal of Regulatory Economics, vol. 25, pp. 5-37, Jan. 2004.

[9] R. Green and D. M. Newbery, “Competition in the British electric spot market,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 100, pp. 929-953, Oct. 1992.

[10] C. D. Wolfram, “Strategic bidding in a multi-unit auction: an empirical analysis of bids to supply electricity in England and Wales,” RAND Journal of Economics, vol. 29, No. 4, pp. 703-725, 1998.

[11] E. T. Mansur, “Pricing behavior in the initial summer of the restructured PJM wholesale electricity market,” University of California Energy Institute, PWP-083, Apr. 2001.

[12] S. Borenstein, J. B. Bushnell and F. A. Wolak, “Measuring Market Inefficiencies in California’s Restructured Wholesale Electricity Market,” American Economic Review, vol. 92, pp. 1376-1405, Dec. 2002.

[13] S. D. l. Torre, A. J. Conejo and J. Contreras, “Simulating oligopolistic pool based electricity markets: a multi-period approach,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 18, pp. 1547-1555, Nov. 2003.

[14] R. Baldick, R. Grant and E. Kahn, “Theory and application of linear supply function equilibrium in electricity markets,” Journal of Regulatory Economics, vol. 25, pp. 143-167, Nov. 2004.

[15] F. Longsta and A. Wang, “Electricity forward prices: A high-frequency empirical analysis,” Journal of Finance, vol.59, pp. 1877-1900, Aug. 2004.

[16] C. Saravia, “Speculative trading and market performance: the effect of arbitrageurs on efficiency and market power in the New York electricity market,” Center for the Study of Energy Markets (CSEM), Working Paper -121, Nov. 2003.

[17] R. J. Kaye, F. F.Wu and P. Varaiya, “Pricing for system security,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. vol. 10, pp. 575–583, May 1995.

[18] T. Wu, M. Rothleder, Z. Alaywan and A. D. Papalexopoulos, “Pricing energy and ancillary services in integrated market systems by an optimal power flow,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 19, pp. 339-347, Feb. 2004

[19] J. M. Arroyo and F. D. Galiana, “Energy and reserve pricing in security and network-constrained electricity markets,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 20, pp. 634-643, May 2005.

[20] F. Alvarado, Y. Hu, D. Ray, R. Stevenson, and E. Cashman, “Engineering Foundations for the Determination of Security Costs,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 6, pp. 1175-1182, Aug. 1991.

[21] D. S. Kirschen, K. R. W. Bell, D. P. Nedic, D. Jayaweera, and R. N. Allan, “Computing the value of security,” IEE Proc. Generation, Transmission and Distribution, vol. 150, pp. 673-678, Nov 2003.

[22] T. Guler, G. Gross, E. Litvinov and R. Coutu, “Quantification of Market Performance as a Function of System Security,” accepted for publication in IEEE Trans. Power Syst.

Page 10: The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in …...The Economic Aspects of Operational Reliability in Electricity Markets Teoman Guler, George Gross and Rajesh Nelli Department

[23] M. Liu and G. Gross, "Generalized transmission scheduling problem: scheduling of nondiscriminatory transmission services in the mixed pool-bilateral systems," Proc. of PowerTech 2005 St. Petersburg, Russia, June 2005.

[24] ISO-NE, “Operating Reserves White Paper,” http://www.iso-ne.com/pubs/whtpprs/operating_reserves_white_paper.pdf, June 2006.

Biographies

Teoman Güler received the B.S. degree in Electrical Engineering from Bogazici University, Istanbul, Turkey in 1999 and M.S. degree in Electrical Power Engineering from Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute, Troy, New York, in 2001. He is currently a Ph.D. candidate in the Electrical and Computer Engineering department at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign. George Gross is Professor of Electrical and Computer Engineering and Professor, Institute of Government and Public Affairs, at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign. His current research and teaching activities are in the areas of power system analysis, planning, economics and operations and utility regulatory policy and industry restructuring. His undergraduate work was completed at McGill University, and he earned his

graduate degrees from the University of California, Berkeley. He was previously employed by Pacific Gas and Electric Company in various technical, policy and management positions.

Rajesh Nelli received the B.S. degree from National Institute of Technology Karnataka, India in Electrical and Electronics Engineering in 2005. He is currently working towards his M.S. degree in Electrical and Computer Engineering at the University of Illinois Urbana-Champaign.