sustainable community forestry management in lombok, … · awlr automatic water level recorder...

261
Sustainable Community Forestry Management in Lombok, Indonesia Diswandi Diswandi Bachelor Economics STIE Kerjasama, Indonesia M.Sc. Economics Universitas Gadjah Mada, Indonesia This thesis is presented for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy of Murdoch University 2017

Upload: trinhminh

Post on 09-Jun-2019

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Sustainable Community Forestry

Management in Lombok, Indonesia

Diswandi Diswandi

Bachelor Economics STIE Kerjasama, Indonesia

M.Sc. Economics Universitas Gadjah Mada, Indonesia

This thesis is presented for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy of Murdoch

University

2017

i

For my wife Suzana Noviyanti Dewi

and

my daughters Syahfa Viandy Kamila and Marwa Viandy Madina

ii

Declaration

I declare that this thesis is my own account of research and contains as its main

content work which has not previously been submitted for a degree at any tertiary

education institution

--------------------------

Diswandi Diswandi

June, 2017

iii

Publication

A part of this thesis has been published in Ecosystem Services Journal:

Diswandi, D. (2017). A hybrid Coasean and Pigouvian approach to Payment for

Ecosystem Services Program in West Lombok: Does it contribute to

poverty alleviation? Ecosystem Services, 23, 138-145.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2016.12.005

iv

Abstract

Deforestation is a serious problem in Indonesia as a result of forest concessions that

were granted by the government to private companies. The forest destruction was

also caused by the encroachment by villagers during the political chaos and lack of

law enforcement following the collapse of the New Order regime in 1998. In

Lombok, villagers entered forests around their village, logged the trees and

occupied the forests to plant fruit trees. As a response to this encroachment, the

Indonesian government encouraged local participation by involving communities

in forest management, which eventually developed into a community forestry

management scheme. However, improper management by the forest farmers has

generated negative externalities, primarily a reduction in the quantity and quality of

water supply produced from the forest. To address the negative externalities

problem, the local government in West Lombok developed a system of Payment for

Ecosystem Services (PES). Importantly, the PES program in West Lombok was

integrated with the Community Forestry program, designed for forest conservation

and poverty alleviation.

This study investigates the impact of the integrated Community Forestry and PES

programs on local forest conservation and socio-economic improvement. The study

utilises “participatory econometrics” as a mixed quantitative and qualitative

research method. The research included in-depth interviews, field visits, surveys, a

focus group discussion and aerial photo analysis.

This thesis found that the PES program in West Lombok is a hybrid system that

combines Coasean and Pigouvian theory. In conjunction with the Community

Forestry program, the PES program could produce a sustainable outcome in the

long term. This is confirmed by empirical evidence, as integrated PES and the

Community Forestry program accommodates local needs, and can be used as a tool

for forest conservation and the improvement of socio-economic conditions in the

long term.

Keywords: Community forestry, Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES), Forest

conservation, Poverty alleviation.

v

Table of Contents

Declaration .............................................................................................................. ii

Publication ............................................................................................................. iii

Abstract .................................................................................................................. iv

Table of Contents .................................................................................................... v

List of Tables........................................................................................................ viii

List of Figures ........................................................................................................ ix

Abbreviations and Acronyms ................................................................................. xi

Glossary ............................................................................................................... xiv

Acknowledgement............................................................................................... xvii

Chapter 1 Introduction ......................................................................................... 1

1.1. Background and Context of the Study ......................................................... 1

1.2. Research Questions ...................................................................................... 8

1.3. Case Study Location ..................................................................................... 8

1.4. Research Methodology ............................................................................... 10

1.4.1. Data Sources ........................................................................................ 11

1.4.2. Survey Design ...................................................................................... 11

1.4.3. In-Depth Interviews ............................................................................. 12

1.4.4. Focus Group Discussion ...................................................................... 12

1.4.5. Field Visits ........................................................................................... 12

1.4.6. Data Analysis ....................................................................................... 13

1.5. Chapter Outline .......................................................................................... 13

Chapter 2 Theoretical Background and Literature Review ........................... 15

2.1. The Commons Resources ........................................................................... 15

2.2. Community Forestry ................................................................................... 25

2.2.1. Community Forests as Common Resources ........................................ 25

2.2.2. Impact of Community Forestry upon Local Economy and

Ecology .......................................................................................................... 27

2.3. Payment for Ecosystem Services ............................................................... 30

2.3.1. Definition of PES ................................................................................. 30

2.3.2. The Emergence of PES ........................................................................ 33

2.3.3. Two Paradigms Regarding PES ........................................................... 34

2.3.4. Alternative PES Schemes .................................................................... 36

2.3.5. PES and Poverty Alleviation ............................................................... 37

2.3.7. Guidance for PES System Development ............................................. 40

vi

2.3.8. PES Application in the World ............................................................. 41

2.4. Conclusion .................................................................................................. 45

Chapter 3 Forest Management, Community Forestry and Adat

Rules ..................................................................................................................... 48

3.1. Historical Forest Governance and Deforestation in Lombok ..................... 48

3.2. Community Forestry Management Scheme and Adat Rules ...................... 55

3.2.1. Case Study of Sesaot Community Forest ............................................ 57

3.2.2. Awiq-awiq and Sustainable Forest Management ................................. 63

3.3. Role of the Outsider in Community Forestry Management ....................... 67

3.4. Conclusion .................................................................................................. 69

Chapter 4 Integrated Payment for Ecosystem Services and

Community Forestry Management ................................................................... 71

4.1. Development of the PES Program in West Lombok .................................. 71

4.2. Intermediary Organization for the PES Program ....................................... 79

4.3. Demand Side of the PES Program ............................................................. 82

4.4. Supply Side of the PES Program ................................................................ 84

4.5. Contracts under the PES System ................................................................ 90

4.6. New Paradigm on PES Literature .............................................................. 93

4.7. Conclusion .................................................................................................. 94

Chapter 5 Community Forestry, Payment for Ecosystem Services

and Forest Conservation .................................................................................... 97

5.1. Community Forestry Development and Forest Conservation .................... 97

5.2. Forest Farmers’ Experiences and Views on the Impact of the

Community Forestry Program on Forest Conservation .................................. 104

5.3. Payment for Ecosystem Services Program and Forest Conservation ....... 111

5.4. Conclusion ................................................................................................ 117

Chapter 6 Community Forestry, Payment for Ecosystem Services

and Local Socio-Economic Conditions ............................................................ 121

6.1. Community Forestry Impacts on Local Socio-Economic Conditions ...... 121

6.1.1. Direct Socio-Economic Benefits of Community Forestry ................. 124

6.1.2. Indirect Socio-Economic Benefits of Community Forestry .............. 126

6.2. Villagers' Views on the Effect of Community Forestry on Their

Livelihoods and on Poverty Reduction ........................................................... 128

6.3. Socio-Economic Benefits from Integrating PES into a Community

Forestry Program ............................................................................................. 130

6.3.1. Villagers’ Views on the Effect of PES on Their Livelihood

and Poverty Reduction ................................................................................. 131

6.3.2. Welfare Index to Measure the Socio-Economic Impact of

Integrated PES and Community Forestry .................................................... 133

6.4. Conclusion ................................................................................................ 144

vii

Chapter 7 Statistical Analysis of Community Forestry and PES

Impact on Forest Conservation and Socio-Economic Conditions ................ 146

7.1. Data Sources and Classification ............................................................... 147

7.1.1. Community Forestry Index ................................................................ 149

7.1.2. Payment for Ecosystem Service Program .......................................... 150

7.1.3. Adat/Local institutions ....................................................................... 150

7.1.4. Property Rights .................................................................................. 151

7.1.5. Community Forest Land Size ............................................................ 152

7.1.6. Welfare Measure as Proxy for Socio-Economic Conditions ............. 152

7.1.7. Forest Cover ....................................................................................... 153

7.2. Regression Model ..................................................................................... 154

7.2.1. Model for Conservation ..................................................................... 154

7.2.2. Model for Socio-Economic Conditions ............................................. 155

7.3. Regression Process ................................................................................... 157

7.3.1. Ordinary Least Square Regression Analysis ..................................... 158

7.3.2. Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SUR) ........................................... 162

7.5. Conclusion ................................................................................................ 164

Chapter 8 Conclusion and Policy Recommendations .................................... 167

8.1. Thesis Conclusions ................................................................................... 169

8.2. Policy Recommendations ......................................................................... 177

8.3. Future Research ........................................................................................ 180

Appendixes ......................................................................................................... 182

Appendix 1.1. Questionnaire for Household Survey (Bahasa Indonesia

Version) ........................................................................................................... 182

Appendix 1.2. Questionnaire for Household Survey (English Version) ......... 197

Appendix 1.3 Indicative Interview Questions (Bahasa Indonesia

Version) ........................................................................................................... 211

Appendix 1.4 Indicative Interview Questions (English Version) ................... 213

Appendix 3.1 Awiq-awiq Forum Kawasan ...................................................... 215

Appendix 4.1 IMP Report Published on Local Media (Lombok Post, 30

May 2011) ....................................................................................................... 219

Appendix 5.1 Global Forest Watch - Forest Change Analysis ....................... 220

Appendix 5.2 T Test for Farmers’ Logging Practice before and after

establishment of Community Forestry Program ............................................. 221

Appendix 6.1 T test for House Ownership before and after establishment

of Community Forestry Program .................................................................... 222

Appendix 7.1 Regression Result ..................................................................... 223

Bibliography ...................................................................................................... 226

viii

List of Tables

Table 1.1 Sub-districts and Villages in Lombok ................................................... 10

Table 2.1 Institutional Design Principles for Sustainable Common

Resource Governance ........................................................................... 23

Table 2.2 Examples of PES Schemes ................................................................... 42

Table 3.1 Official HKm Forest Management in Lombok ..................................... 56

Table 3.2 Population of Villages around Sesaot Forest ........................................ 58

Table 4.1 Forest Area in Lombok Classified by Management Unit ..................... 75

Table 4.2 PES Fund Allocation ............................................................................. 80

Table 4.3 Distribution of PES Funding to CFFGs, 2010 - 2014 ........................... 88

Table 6.1 Summary of Welfare Indicators Before and After

Community Forestry and PES Programs were Established ............... 134

Table 7.1 Data Description ................................................................................. 148

Table 7.2 Community Forestry Effectiveness Indicators .................................... 149

Table 7. 3 Descripive Statistics of Model 1.1 ..................................................... 158

Table 7.4 Descriptive Statistics of Model 2.1 ..................................................... 160

Table 8.1 Summary of Statistical Influence of the Community

Forestry Index, Property Rights, Adat Rules, PES and

Community Forest Land Size on Conservation and Socio-

economic Conditions .......................................................................... 173

ix

List of Figures

Figure 1.1 The World’s Biggest Contributors to Global Warming and

Anthropogenic Climate Change (by % of CO2 emissions) .................... 2 Figure 1.2 Map of Lombok Island ........................................................................... 9

Figure 2.1 Guidance for PES System Development .............................................. 41

Figure 3.1 Chronological Story of Indonesia Forest Governance.......................... 55 Figure 3.2 Map of Sesaot Forest ............................................................................ 57 Figure 3.3 Villagers' Occupations in Surrounding Sesaot Forest .......................... 58 Figure 3.4 Farmers' Obedience to Awiq-awiq ....................................................... 64 Figure 3.5 Farmers Opinion that the Awiq-awiq Influences Forest

Condition .............................................................................................. 65

Figure 3.6 Farmers’ Opinion on the Importance of NGO Involvement ................ 68

Figure 4.1 Map of Forest Area in Lombok Island ................................................. 74 Figure 4.2 Timeline of PES Development in Lombok .......................................... 77 Figure 4.3 PDAM Water Use in West Lombok, 2009-2013.................................. 84 Figure 4.4 PES Payments from Water Consumers in West Lombok,

2009–2015 ............................................................................................ 84 Figure 4.5 Map of PES Program Location in Lombok .......................................... 86

Figure 5.1 Farmers’ Acknowledging Involvement in Timber Theft

Prior to Establishment of the Community Forestry Program ............. 105 Figure 5.2 Farmers’ Acknowledging Involvement in Timber Theft

Post Establishment of the Community Forestry Program .................. 106 Figure 5.3 Farmers’ Experience of Timber Theft in Their Community

Forest .................................................................................................. 106 Figure 5.4 Farmers’ Knowledge of Timber Theft by Others Including

Inside and Outside the Community Forest ......................................... 107 Figure 5.5 Farmers’ Assessment of Changes in the Number of Trees in

the Community Forest ........................................................................ 108

Figure 5.6 Farmers’ Opinion on the Impact of Community Forestry on

Reducing Deforestation ...................................................................... 108 Figure 5.7 Forest Cover Loss in Sesaot Forest, 2002 – 2014 .............................. 109 Figure 5.8 Satellite Photo of Sesaot Community Forestry and Illegal

Logging Location in 2015 .................................................................. 111 Figure 5.9 Farmers’ Perception of Change in Number of Trees on

Community Forest Land due to PES .................................................. 114 Figure 5. 10 Farmers’ Perception of Forest Cover Quality

Improvement due to PES .................................................................... 115 Figure 5.11 Degraded Forest Land Area in Narmada sub District

Including Sesaot, 2010 – 2014 ........................................................... 117

Figure 6.1 Comparison of House Ownership Before and After

Community Forestry and PES were Established ................................ 136

Figure 6.2 Comparison of House Wall Material Before and After

Community Forestry and PES were Established ................................ 137 Figure 6.3 Comparison of House Floor Material Before and After

Community Forestry and PES were Established ................................ 137

x

Figure 6.4 Comparison of Access to Electricity Before and After

Community Forestry and PES were Established ................................ 138 Figure 6.5 Comparison of Access to Water Supply Before and After

Community Forestry and PES were Established ................................ 139 Figure 6.6 Comparison of Energy Used for Cooking Before and After

Community Forestry and PES were Established ................................ 141

Figure 6.7 Comparison of Transport Ownership Before and After

Community Forestry and PES were Established ................................ 141 Figure 6.8 Comparison of Communication Facility Before and After

Community Forestry and PES were Established ................................ 142 Figure 6.9 Comparison of Education Level Before and After

Community Forestry and PES were Established ................................ 143

xi

Abbreviations and Acronyms

APBN Anggaran Pendapatan dan Belanja Negara / National

Budget Planning

AWLR Automatic Water Level Recorder

BAPPEDA Badan Perencanaan Pembangunan Daerah / Regional

Development Plan Agency

BKSDA Balai Konservasi Sumber Daya Alam/ Natural

Resources Conservation Unit

BPHLSW Badan Pengelola Hutan Lindung Sungai Wain / Sungai

Wain Protected Forest Management Unit

BPS Badan Pusat Statistik / Indonesian Statistics Agency

BTNGR Balai Taman Nasional Gunung Rinjani / Mount Rinjani

National Park Authority

CBFM Community Based Forest Management

CFFG Community Forest Farmer Group

CFIND Community Forestry Index

CI Conservation International

CO2 Carbon dioxide

CV Commanditaire Vennootschap (Limited Partnership)

DAK Dana Alokasi Khusus / Special Allocation Fund

DFID Department for International Development

DISHUT Dinas Kehutanan / Forest Agency

DPRD Dewan Perwakilan Rakyat Daerah / Regional

Assembly

FAO Food and Agricultural Organization of the United

Nations

FGD Focus Group Discussion

FORCOV Forest Cover

FWI Forest Watch Indonesia

xii

GWF Global Forest Watch

HPHH Hak Pemungutan Hasil Hutan / Forests Product

Harvesting Rights

HKm Hutan Kemasyarakatan / Community Forestry

HPH Hak Pengusahaan Hutan / Forest Concession Rights

ICDP Integrated Conservation and Development Projects

IMP Institutsi Multi Pihak / Multi stakeholders institutions

IUCN International Union for Conservation of Nature

KMPH Kelompok Mitra Pelestari Hutan / Partner Group for

Sustainable Forest

KONSEPSI Konsorsium untuk Studi dan Pengembangan Partisipasi

/ Consortium for Study and Participation Development

KPH Kesatuan Pengelolaan Hutan / Forest Management

Unit

MEA Millennium Ecosystem Assessment

MPTS Multi-Purpose Tree Species

NGO Non-Governmental Organization

NTB Nusa Tenggara Barat / West Nusa Tenggara

NTFP Non-Timber Forest Products

OLS Ordinary Least Square

PDAM Perusahaan Daerah Air Minum / District Water

Company

PERDA Peraturan Daerah / Regional Government Regulation

PES Payment for Ecosystem Services

PR Property Rights

PSA Pago por Servicios Ambientales (Payment for

Environmental Services)

PT Perusahaan Terbuka / Go Public Company

PUSKESMAS Pusat Kesehatan Masyarakat / Community health

centres

xiii

REDD+ Reducing Emission from Deforestation and Forest

Degradation

SLCP Sloping Land Conservation Program

SUR Seemingly Unrelated Regression

TAHURA Taman Hutan Raya / Botanical Park

TGHK Tata Guna Hutan Kesepakatan / Forest land use

planning

US United States

UU Undang Undang / Laws

UUD Undang Undang Dasar / Indonesian Constitution

VOC Vereenigde Oost-Indische Compagnie (The United East

India Company)

WTA Willingness to Accept

WTP Willingness to Pay

WWF World Wide Fund for Nature

xiv

Glossary

Terminology Meaning

Adat Local customary practices and tradition.

Awiq-awiq

A kind of adat rule, constructed and agreed upon

by a community to govern their activities and

relationship among the members.

CFFG (Community Forest

Farmer Group)

A group of forest farmers who manage a

community forestry together under one

coordinator.

Coasean

An economic theory proposed by Coase to address

the problem of externalities through the market

system.

Commons

Resources, natural and cultural, that are shared by

many people without any private property right

established over the resources.

Community Forestry

A system of forest management focusing on the

benefits of forests for the livelihoods of local

forest dependent communities.

Conservation Protection of natural resources to ensure

sustainable use.

Deforestation

A long-term reduction of the tree canopy cover

below the minimum ten percent threshold.

Externality

External benefits or costs that emerge as a result

of other people’s activity.

Forum Kawasan

A forum of CFFG in Lombok, that coordinates

CFFG in relation to community forestry

management.

Free rider

A condition where people take advantage of being

able to use a common resource without making

any contribution for its existence.

xv

Terminology Meaning

Goodness of fit

The extent to which observed data matches the

values expected by theory.

HKm (Hutan

Kemasyarakatan)

Indonesian terminology for community forestry.

IMP (Institusi Multi

Pihak)

A multi stakeholders entity that acts as

intermediary in the PES system in Lombok.

Lang-lang

Part of adat institutions in Lombok who are

responsible for awiq-awiq enforcement.

Lokaq

Part of adat institutions in Lombok who are

responsible for being a judge in regards to

offenders of awiq-awiq.

MPTS (Multi-Purpose

Tree Species)

Tree species that have both ecological and

economic benefits.

New Order

A period of Indonesian government under Suharto

presidency, between 1965–1998.

NTFP (Non Timber Forest

Product)

Forest products other than timber.

OLS (Ordinary Least

Square)

A method for estimating unknown parameters in a

linear regression model.

Open access A condition of a resource without clearly defined

property rights that allows everyone to utilize the

resource.

PDAM (Perusahaan

Daerah Air Minum)

Regional Water Corporation.

PERDA (Peraturan

Daerah)

Regional regulation issued by the local

government (district or provincial) in Indonesia.

PES (Payment for

Ecosystem Services)

A transaction where a well-defined ecosystem

service is bought by at least one service buyer

from at least one service provider with a condition

xvi

Terminology Meaning

that the provider continues to conserve the

resource in order to secure the service provision.

Pigouvian

An economic theory proposed by Pigou to address

the problem of externalities through government

intervention.

Property rights Rights to enter, occupy and utilize a resource.

Reforestation Planting trees in deforested forest.

Reformasi (Reformation) A period of Indonesian government between

1998–2002.

Regression A statistical process for estimating the

relationships among observed variables.

SUR (seemingly unrelated

regressions)

A linear regression that consists of several

regression equations where each equation has its

own dependent variable and potentially different

sets of exogenous explanatory variables.

Tumpang Sari

A planting method that allows forest farmers to

cultivate crops on forest land together with tree

plantations.

xvii

Acknowledgement

I am grateful to the many people who gave their help, support, advice and assistance during

the whole process of my study and writing up this dissertation. First, I would like to express

my profound gratitude and deepest appreciation to my supervisors, Professor Malcolm Tull

and Associate Professor Carol Warren, for their invaluable guidance, support, suggestions,

and comments. It was a privilege for me to work under their supervision. My thanks also

go to Doctor Xiaohui Zhang and Doctor Ranald Taylor for their advice and supervision on

the quantitative analysis.

I would like to extend my gratitude to Indonesian Government for providing me with the

DIKTI Scholarship which was managed by the Ministry of Research, Technology and

Higher Education (RISTEKDIKTI) of the Republic of Indonesia. In addition, I would like

to thank to Murdoch University for providing financial support to undertake fieldwork,

conference travel and, the most important support, a scholarship in the fourth year of my

study. Without this financial support, this work would not have been accomplished. I would

like to express my appreciation to the Asia Research Centre for the additional financial

support to conduct the fieldwork and for providing an editing fund.

I would like to acknowledge the support from the Asia Research Centre staff, members and

fellow PhD students for their encouragement, intellectual support, and friendship. My

thanks also go to my friends and colleagues in the Faculty of Economics and Business, the

University of Mataram. My study could not have been completed without generous help

and support from people in the case study area of Lombok, Indonesia. I would like to

acknowledge and express my gratitude to many people who voluntarily participated in my

research.

Above all, my greatest thanks go to my wife Suzana Noviyanti Dewi and my daughters

Syahfa Viandy Kamila and Marwa Viandy Madina for their love, support, inspiration and

encouragement in every step of my PhD journey. I am also grateful to my sister Ida Laely

for her support and love. Finally, my deepest love and gratitude go to my parents Haji Akil

and Hajjah Nuraeni, also to my parents in law Djoko Wiratmo and Sri Haryati for their

unconditional support, love and blessing.

1

Chapter 1

Introduction

This thesis is concerned with sustainable commons resources management

and a case study of a Community Forestry program that was followed by and

integrated with a Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) program in Lombok

Indonesia. It examines the development of these two programs as a response to

forest degradation that has caused water shortages across the island of Lombok. The

Lombok case study examines the impact of the integrated Community Forestry and

PES programs on forest conservation and local socio-economic conditions, and was

designed to assess how a common pool resource could be managed to achieve a

sustainable outcome.

1.1. Background and Context of the Study

Indonesia's forest area is the third largest in the world, following Brazil and

the Democratic Republic of Congo; it covers 124 million hectares, which is equal

to 65% of its land mass (BPS, 2015b). However, deforestation, which is defined as

“land cover conversion from forested to another land use or the long-term reduction

of the tree canopy cover below the minimum ten percent threshold” (FAO, 2005, p.

25), is a serious problem in this country. The size of forest cover in Indonesia has

been decreasing continually since the colonial era began in 1602, and became worse

in the period of the New Order regime (1966-1998) (Saman et al., 1993; Simon,

1994; Reed, 2006; Gultom et al., 2013; Bae et al., 2014).

Global Forest Watch (GFW) estimates that the average annual deforestation

rate in Indonesia from 2001-2015 is around 1.3 million hectares (GFW, 2017). As

figure 1.1 shows, Indonesia is the eight largest contributor to global warming in the

world, behind China, US, European Union, India, Russian Federation, Japan and

Brazil, and is responsible for 1.6% of global CO2 emissions (World Resources

Institute, 2017) predominantly by deforestation.

2

Regionally classified, the highest rate of deforestation in Indonesia has

occurred in Java and Bali-Nusa Tenggara. Forest Watch Indonesia (FWI) estimated

that between 2000-2009, forests in Java and Bali-Nusa Tenggara shrank by about

61% and 46% respectively (FWI/GFW, 2011, p. 15). FWI predicted that in 2030,

forests in both regions will be totally lost if the current rate of deforestation

continues. The forest in these areas is important for ecosystem services, since

Lombok and Bali are rapidly growing tourism development areas, which need a lot

of high quality water. The island of Lombok, located in West Nusa Tenggara

Province, is the most threatened area, since 4.6 million people on the island are

heavily dependent upon the ecological benefits of the forests, especially for water

supplies. Further, from a basic needs perspective, the issue of ecosystem services

in Lombok has become acute. Approximately 16% of people in the province of

West Nusa Tenggara are poor (BPS, 2016b). Sunderlin et al. (2000) found that most

of Indonesia's poor families live in remote villages surrounding forest areas, and

their livelihood relies on the forest. To support their livelihood, many of the rural

poor engage in illegal logging and illegal farming in the forest, which sets in motion

a vicious cycle linking resource degradation and impoverishment.

Figure 1.1 The World’s Biggest Contributors to Global Warming and

Anthropogenic Climate Change (by % of CO2 emissions)

Source: Constructed by the Author, data from World Resources Institute (2017)

Topographically, Lombok Island is dominated by Rinjani Mountain, the

second highest volcano in Indonesia, which is located in the centre of the island.

0.05.0

10.015.020.025.030.0

3

Most areas of the island are relatively fertile and 40% is covered by forest.

Wulandari (2011, p. 35) observed an average rate of deforestation in Lombok

during the decade 2000–2010 equal to 1,700 hectares a year. A GFW map shows

that during 2001–2015, forest cover in Lombok fell by about 19,202 hectares; or

1,280 hectares per annum (GFW, 2017). Gultom et al. (2013) suggested that

poverty is the major driver of deforestation in Lombok. Since poverty and forest

degradation are closely correlated phenomena (Wunder, 2001; Aggarwal, 2006),

the combination of socio-economic factors that contribute to underdevelopment and

environmental degradation must be considered in solving problems of poverty and

ensuring sustainable economic development (Agrawal, 2003).

Since the end of Suharto's New Order regime, the Indonesian government

officially began to encourage local people living around forest areas to contribute

to resolving the problem of deforestation by involving them in forest management.

In 1998 Community Forestry1 (Hutan Kemasyarakatan, HKm) was introduced in

Indonesia. A Community forest is defined in Indonesian forestry regulations as state

forest managed by a local community for the purpose of economic empowerment

and improvement without undermining forest functions (Menteri Kehutanan RI,

2014a).

Community Forestry is a relatively new scheme for forest co-management,

having been first introduced in the 1980s and 1990s in a number of countries

(Agrawal, 2001b; Bellinger and Gale, 2004; Charnley and Poe, 2007; Kubo, 2009;

Barsimantov and Kendall, 2012; Maryudi et al., 2012). The main characteristics of

Community Forestry are (1) management responsibility and authority is formally

vested by the government in local communities, along with specified

responsibilities and rights to sustainable use of the forest; (2) the aim is to provide

local communities with long-term social and economic benefits from the forest; (3)

there is a core management goal of ensuring ecologically sustainable forest use

(Sanwal, 1988; Charnley and Poe, 2007).

1 Community Forestry is also described in the literature as agro-forestry, social forestry and

community-based forest management.

4

Sesaot Forest, which is located on the western side of Mount Rinjani, is the

pilot Community Forestry project in West Nusa Tenggara Province. Sesaot Forest

is significant as it is the primary water catchment area for the residents of Lombok.

People in Mataram, the capital city of West Nusa Tenggara and of West Lombok

District, use water from this forest for their daily needs. Farmers in East and Central

Lombok also use the water from Sesaot forest to irrigate their land. Since 1998,

with the involvement of non-government organisations, local community

institutions have been formed around the forest with the aim of improving forest

management through a Community Forestry approach. Customary rules and values

(adat) have been employed in Community Forestry management in Sesaot and

adapted to accommodate local community initiatives to protect the forest.

Adat (customary) institutions played a significant role in local community

organization and in natural resource management before the colonial era. Adat

community authority, however, was marginalized especially during the Suharto era

(McCarthy, John, 2009), and was replaced by state control policies that were

designed to serve the political and economic interests of national and local elites

(Warren, 2005, p. 50). Warren (2005) points out that in that period, the Forestry

Law (UU 11/1967), Basic Mining Law (UU 5/1967) and Village Government Law

(UU 5/1979) were among the instruments used by the Indonesian central

government to control all natural resources in the country in the name of the ‘public

interest’.

Adat authority in the local domain has re-emerged in the reform era

following the collapse of the New Order regime's three decade long rule of

Indonesia (Warren and McCarthy, 2009). Adat rules have the potential to play an

important role in the successful introduction of Community Forestry programs,

since indigenous norms and values may have a greater perceived legitimacy than

formal law for many of the people of Lombok (SA, forest agency officer, interview,

5/6/2014). For example, an individual jailed for illegal logging may very well

reoffend after the arrest period. On the other hand, faced by local customary

punishment such as isolation from the community, the individual would be less

likely to repeat the offence in the future. Thus, adat rule enforcement by local user

5

groups could be a necessary condition for effective communal resource

management (Gibson et al., 2005, p. 282).

Ostrom (1999) argues that resource management by local communities

often delivered more sustainable outcomes than other forms of governance that rely

primarily on privatization and state control. Local communities are able to self-

organize on their common property, especially in the cases of Small-scale resources

systems, where they can employ their own rules and norms for sustainable

stewardship of the resource (Agrawal, 1996; Agrawal and Ostrom, 2001; Ostrom,

2005). However, collective action approaches employed in community based

resource management encounter a number of constraints, especially where open

access prevails in vast forest and marine areas (Ostrom, 1990). Most of these

limitations relate to the ways in which people cooperate, and to internal and external

conflicts of interest (Arnold, 1987). In forestry management, there are many

conflicts of interest among the different levels of government, commercial

stakeholders and local communities. For instance, successive governments of West

Nusa Tenggara promoted Sesaot Forest as a grand forest park (Taman Hutan Raya),

specifically designated for research, education, and tourism development. At the

same time, local people in the same location have been using the forest for decades.

Internal conflicts among community members also arise, due to competing socio-

economic and political interests. In this regard, Ostrom (2009) stresses the

importance of building trust and developing institutional rules that are well matched

to the local ecological needs, in order to solve such dilemmas.

Conflicts of interest also arise between the forest farmers and those who live

in the city who are dependent upon the protection of forest water catchments for

their water needs. Improper management of forests can cause severe decline in the

quantity and quality of water supply. Methods to address the problem of such

negative externalities related to poor resource management have been debated in

the policy literature, and focus largely on Coasean and Pigouvian theories. Coasean

economic theory emphasizes voluntary market based transactions among the related

parties to negotiate compensation in order to reduce externalities (Coase, 1960). On

the other hand, Pigouvian economic theory contends that government involvement

6

is important in addressing the externality problem, through exercising policy

instruments such as collecting tax or providing subsidies as incentives to reduce

externalities (Pigou, 1932).

In response to the externality problem resulting from inappropriate forest

management, the government of West Lombok district developed a system of

Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES), as a contribution from urban water

consumers toward proper management of the Sesaot forest. This PES program is a

hybrid system that combines Coasean and Pigouvian economic theory. Government

policy has enforced monthly payments from urban tap water consumers, which

compensate forest farmers in Sesaot forest through various conservation and

economic empowerment programs.

Payment for ecosystem services will operate as an economic incentive if

small payments to forest users can tip the balance in favour of desired land use, in

this case forest protection (Wunder, 2007). However, Muradian, R. et al. (2013)

argue that over-reliance on PES as win-win solutions might lead to ineffective

outcomes when the ecosystem services price does not follow the trend of rising

opportunity costs of ecosystem conservation. Thus, inadequate economic benefits

from PES could become a disincentive for the provider to maintain the PES

contract. Wunder (2013) emphasised that PES needs to be carefully customised to

essential preconditions2 in order to prevent negative outcomes and ensure cost-

effectiveness.

The PES program in Lombok is integrated with the Community Forestry

program through providing cash to buy seeds for multipurpose tree species that can

generate economic benefit for the farmers. The integrated PES and Community

Forestry program is designed not only for forest conservation but also for poverty

alleviation.

2 Preconditions to make a PES system work include: the existence of a ‘give and take’ culture among

services users and providers, trust between the services users and providers, and tenure clarity and

security among service providers (Wunder, 2013).

7

The economic and conservation goals of the Community Forestry and PES

programs have been addressed in a substantive body of academic literature3. Some

studies demonstrate the potential of Community Forestry programs for

deforestation mitigation and simultaneous improvement of the economic welfare of

surrounding communities. For instance, Bottazzi et al. (2013) found that sustainable

forest management through a Community Forestry approach in the Bolivian

Amazon provided income while maintaining low carbon emissions. Similarly,

Dhakal et al. (2007) conclude that Community Forestry could overcome the rural

unemployment problem and increase incomes while ensuring sustainable forest

resources in Nepal. Their findings were supported by Dhakal et al. (2012) who

demonstrated a positive outcome of Community Forestry for the poorest

households in Nepal.

In contrast, other scholars found unclear impacts of Community Forestry for

poverty alleviation. For example, Sunderlin (2006) found no empirical evidence for

poverty alleviation through Community Forestry in Cambodia, Laos and Vietnam.

Charnley and Poe (2007) reported that Community Forestry in America delivers

more ecological impact than economic benefit, which is not to say that economic

benefit is entirely lacking. Similarly, Thoms (2008) found that Community Forestry

in Nepal is better for resource management and conservation than for local

livelihood improvement. Within Indonesia, Maryudi et al. (2012) reported that

Community Forestry also has not yet achieved its high promise to alleviate poverty.

The emergence of Community Forestry and PES programs requires further

research, to provide a better understanding of why these programs do or do not

achieve their promise (Charnley and Poe, 2007). The aim of this present research is

to investigate the extent to which the Community Forestry and PES programs

introduced in Lombok have been able to impact upon both socio-economic

conditions and forest conservation, and to examine the features of these programs

3 See for example Sanwal (1988); Gunter and Jodway (2000); Sunderlin, William D. (2006);

Charnley and Poe (2007); Dhakal et al. (2007); Maryudi et al. (2012) for discussion on the impact

of Community Forestry, and Pagiola et al. (2005); Wunder (2005); Pagiola (2007); Bremer et al.

(2014) for discussion of the goals of PES.

8

and policy improvements that could contribute to achieving long-term sustainable

management goals.

1.2. Research Questions

As this study was designed to analyse whether, to what extent and under

what conditions the integrated Community Forestry and PES programs introduced

in Lombok have contributed to local ecological conservation and local socio-

economic improvement, the research questions that will be addressed are as

follows:

1. How were Community Forestry and PES programs developed in Lombok?

To what extent do they contribute to forest sustainability and poverty

alleviation in forest dependent communities?

2. What improvements are required to enable Community Forestry and PES

programs to further both environmental and socio-economic goals?

3. How is adat (customary law) employed in Community Forestry in

Lombok? What conditions are needed for adat to contribute to sustainable

forest management?

1.3. Case Study Location

Lombok was chosen as the focus of the case study research for this thesis

because this area is the location of a pilot Community Forestry management

program in Indonesia. In addition, the PES program adopted in Lombok differs

from most other PES programs in the world, due to the fact that its implementation

was superimposed upon a Community Forestry program. Lombok is an island

located in the southeastern part of the Indonesian archipelago (see figure 1.2).

Lombok borders the Java and Flores Seas to the north, the Indian Ocean to the

south, Lombok Strait and Bali Island to the west and Sumbawa Island to the east.

9

Figure 1.2 Map of Lombok Island

Source: Lemhanas (2013).

10

Lombok is part of West Nusa Tenggara (NTB) province, which comprises

two main islands, Lombok and Sumbawa, and 280 small islands; with a total land

area of 20,153.20 km2. Lombok itself covers 4,738.70 km2, or nearly one quarter of

the total land area of NTB province. Forests in Lombok cover 163,343 hectares that

are dominated topographically by Mount Rinjani, a volcano rising 3,726 meters

above sea level.

There are 53 sub-districts (kecamatan) and 598 villages (desa) in Lombok

(see Table 1.1). Lombok is home to the NTB provincial government as well as

NTB’s business centre. As a consequence, the island of Lombok is more densely

populated and more developed than the island of Sumbawa. Lombok has a

population of 3,228,654 people, spread over five districts. Of these five districts,

the city of Mataram, the capital city of NTB province, is the most heavily populated.

Table 1.1 Sub-districts and Villages in Lombok

Districts

(Kabupaten)

Number of Sub-

Districts

(Kecamatan)

Number of

Villages (Desa)

Population

Mataram 6 50 413,216

West Lombok 10 122 613,161

Central Lombok 12 139 875,231

East Lombok 20 254 1,123,488

North Lombok 5 33 203,564

Total 53 598 3,228,660

Source: BPS NTB (2014)

1.4. Research Methodology

A mixed research methodology was used in this study. A mixed method

approach has the ability to minimize the weaknesses of solely quantitative or

qualitative methods (Rao, Vijayendra and Woolcock, 2003; Creswell and Plano-

Clark, 2006). Integrating quantitative and qualitative methods provides a more

comprehensive evidence base for evaluating a conservation and development

program such as PES (Rao, Vijayendra and Woolcock, 2003; Creswell and Plano-

Clark, 2006). This study uses a mixed method approach called “participatory

econometrics” (Rao, Vijayendra and Woolcock, 2003; Ibáñez and Rao, 2005). The

11

participatory econometric approach incorporated the following steps in sequence:

(1) in-depth interviews to obtain a grounded understanding of the PES issue; (2)

survey instruments based on understandings developed from the interviews and

field visits; (3) hypotheses derived from qualitative work that were then tested using

survey data.

1.4.1. Data Sources

A variety of sources of data were used for this study: (1) documents: legal

documents, reports, and contracts between the PES intermediary agency (IMP) and

farmers' groups; (2) maps and satellite images, (3) interviews; (4) surveys. The data

was collected during two rounds of fieldwork in Lombok. The first period of

fieldwork was carried out in May–June 2014, and a second fieldwork period took

place in January–May 2015. The first fieldwork period aimed to collect documents,

interview officials and gain background information related to PES development

and practice; the second fieldwork period focused primarily on community based

data gathered from surveys and observations. Satellite images were collected from

Google Earth and Global Forest Watch interactive maps. This multiple data

collection technique allowed the researcher to perform triangulation (Burns, 1997)

to cross check, compare and contrast data among several different sources.

1.4.2. Survey Design

A survey instrument (questionnaire) was developed based on the results

from the first fieldwork. Respondents for the surveys were 200 forest farmer

households that were selected using a purposive random sampling technique

(Bryman, 2015). All respondents were classified into two different groups. The first

group consisted of 100 households that were randomly selected from enrolled

participants in the PES program. The second group consisted of another 100

households that were selected randomly from those that are not enrolled in the PES

program. This technique generates comparable data among respondents in relation

to their experience with the Community Forestry program only compared to those

who participated in the additional PES program.

12

The surveys were conducted during the second period of fieldwork in six

villages where PES funds were distributed, namely Sedau, Lebah Sempage,

Pakuan, Sesaot, Buwun Sejati and Batu Mekar. The surveys aimed to collect

information regarding forest farmer experiences with Community Forestry and PES

programs, including the impact of these schemes on the village economy as well as

the ecological impact of the programs in relation to forest management.

Every survey question in the survey related to Community Forestry and PES

practice offered a closed question, paired with an open-ended question, in order to

generate qualitative data to support the quantitative response. Respondents who

were enrolled in the PES program answered questions related to both Community

Forestry and PES. Those who were not enrolled in the PES program answered only

the questions related to the Community Forestry program.

1.4.3. In-Depth Interviews

Semi-structured interviews were conducted with 22 informants including

PES initiators, a water services officer, forest service agency officers, a regional

development plan agency officer, a regional environmental sector officer, a regional

assembly member, Non- Government Organisations, academics, Institusi Multi

Pihak (IMP) officers and local community leaders. The interviews were carried out

during the first fieldwork period.

1.4.4. Focus Group Discussion

In addition to the interviews, a focus group discussion was conducted with

IMP officers to obtain broader information about their experience in managing the

PES scheme. A focus group discussion (FGD) with community forest leaders was

also performed in the second fieldwork period. In addition, the researcher had the

opportunity to attend a community forest farmer group (CFFG) meeting and

workshop on PES related issues, which was organized by a local NGO.

1.4.5. Field Visits

Field visits to the villages were also conducted to obtain information about

Community Forestry and PES practice in the field. Transect walks to the

13

community forests were also conducted to clarify information that previously

collected from interviews and surveys. In addition, secondary data consisting of the

village profiles covering demographic and socio-economic information on each

community were collected during the field visits.

1.4.6. Data Analysis

All collected data were analysed using qualitative and quantitative

techniques. The NVivo software was used to analyse the qualitative data. The

quantitative data was analysed using Ordinary Least Square (OLS) regression and

Seemingly Unrelated Regression techniques. The STATA software was used for

this quantitative analysis. Results from combined quantitative and qualitative

analysis were than used to draw the thesis conclusions.

1.5. Chapter Outline

This thesis consists of eight chapters. This introductory chapter has provided

background information on the context of the study, identified the research

questions, case study location, and methodology used. Chapter two elaborates on

the theoretical and case study literature on commons resources management,

Community Forestry and PES. The history of forest governance in Indonesia,

including forests in Lombok, the cause of deforestation and forest degradation,

Community Forestry development, the use of adat in community forest

management, and the role of NGOs in forest governance are discussed in Chapter

three.

Chapter four focuses on the development of the PES program in Lombok,

including the establishment of the program, the role of intermediaries, the benefit

delivery system, and challenges and constraints affecting program implementation.

Chapter five critically examines the impact of the Community Forestry and PES

program on the ecology of the forest. This chapter also includes an assessment of

the effects of property rights on forest conservation. Chapter six examines the

Community Forestry and PES program impacts on local socio-economic

conditions, in particular, poverty alleviation.

14

Chapter seven employs a regression analysis to estimate the impact of the

Community Forestry and PES programs on the local economy and ecology, as a

comparison to the previous qualitative analysis. Finally, Chapter eight presents

conclusions and policy recommendations regarding Community Forestry and PES

programs that have evolved in Lombok, and identifies areas requiring further

research.

15

Chapter 2

Theoretical Background and Literature Review

This chapter surveys the literature on commons resources, Community

Forestry (CF), and Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES). The aim of this chapter

is to review theoretical and comparative studies relevant to the analysis in this

thesis. The organization of this chapter is as follows. Section 2.1 reviews debates

on the management of commons resources. Community Forestry management

programs are discussed in section 2.2. Section 2.3 focuses on the PES concept,

which is increasingly applied to the management of commons resources. Finally,

section 2.4 draws conclusions from this chapter and identifies the theoretical

approach applied in this thesis.

2.1. The Commons Resources

The utilization of resources is often subject to the type of property rights

embedded in the resource. There are four categories of property rights that define

the nature of access and utilization based on the type of resources ownership (Feeny

et al., 1990; Bromley, 1992). The first category is described as 'open access'

regimes. Resources without well-defined property rights fall into this category

(Bromley, 1992, p. 2). There is no regulation of access to the resource and so it is

free and open for everyone to utilize. Open access is the default condition in the

absence of institutions that are created through collective action to govern the use

of the resources (Cole et al., 2014, p. 365). Thus open access is not a management

regime at all (Persoon et al., 2003). The global atmosphere is an example of such a

resource.

The second category refers to private property regimes. Under these

regimes, the resource property rights are clearly defined and belong to an individual

or group of individuals like a company (Feeny et al., 1990; Persoon et al., 2003).

The owner of the resource regulates how it is used. This right is usually exclusive

and can be transferred to whomever the owner wants. Private goods such as private

16

land and vehicles are examples of resources that hold this characteristic. A private

property regime is commonly held to lead to the highest and most efficient use of

the resource (Bromley, 1992).

The third category is state property regimes. Under these regimes, the

property right to the resource is held by the state or government in its role as

representative of the interests of present-day and future citizens as well as other

interests (Bromley, 1992; Persoon et al., 2003). The use of the resource is subject

to regulation by the state, which determines the conditions of access by resource

users. The use of the resource is often exclusively reserved only for citizens of the

state. All users theoretically have equal rights to access and utilize the resource,

although the state may allocate those rights to utilize a resource through licensing

or concessions to individuals or groups (Bromley, 1992). The most significant

difference between this state property regime and other regimes is determined by

the state's powers of enforcement regarding the access and utilization of the

resource (Feeny et al., 1990). Examples of such resources include public goods

managed by the government, such as natural forests, roads and parks.

The fourth and last category is communal or common property regimes.

Under these regimes, the property rights on the resource are held by a clearly

defined community of interdependent users (Feeny et al., 1990, p. 4; Persoon et al.,

2003). The resource is also exclusive, meaning that the community can exclude

outsiders from accessing and utilizing the resource. As the property rights holder,

the community regulates how the resource is used. Bromley (1992, p. 12) argues

that if the community authority system breaks down, the common property will

degenerate into open access4. The right to the common resource is usually equal to

all community members. Examples of this type of resource right may include

inshore fisheries, range lands, irrigation systems and community forests. This type

of resource is often referred to as “the commons”. More specifically, Ostrom (1990,

4 This could also happen under state and private property regimes. For instance, some state forests

and private concessions effectively became open access following the collapse of the Suharto

regime in Indonesia.

17

p. 26) describes resources managed under such regimes as “common-pool

resources”.

The term “commons” originates from the type of right to shared land in

Medieval Europe that was held by a community (Anderies and Janssen, 2013).

Various definitions of “commons” are provided in the literature. Most of them

emphasize a shared use of particular resources that can be natural resources and/or

human made resources. According to Anderies and Janssen (2013, p. 3), the term

“commons” refers to a broad set of resources, natural and cultural, that are shared

by many people, but without any private property right established over the

resources. More specifically, Ostrom (1999) emphasized the importance of

communal governance in order to deal with the problems otherwise faced by open

access resource regimes. She defines “the common” as “a natural or man-made

resources system that is sufficiently large as to make it costly (but not impossible)

to exclude potential beneficiaries from obtaining benefit from its use” (Ostrom,

1990, p. 30). Dietz et al. (2002, p. 13) defines the term “commons” as a diversity

of resources, facilities or property institutions that involve joint ownership and

access.

According to Feeny et al. (1990, p. 3), common-property resources hold two

important characteristics which pose challenges to commons management: non-

excludability; and subtract-ability, also known as rivalry. Non-excludability means

that every potential user is able to access and utilize the resource without any

boundary. It may be costly or impossible to make the resource exclusive to only

certain users. Regulating access could be even more difficult for certain resources

like large bodies of water, the global atmosphere, forestland, and migratory

resources such as ocean fish, wildlife, and groundwater (Feeny et al., 1990).

Subtract-ability or rivalry means the use of the resource by someone will reduce

the opportunity of other people to utilize the resource and will subtract from their

welfare (Feeny et al., 1990). For example, in the case of ocean fisheries, if a

fisherman uses unsustainable methods in catching fish - such as using explosives or

chemicals - the fishing effort costs to other fishermen will increase due to the

decline of stock of fish in the area. It may also push the other fishermen to find new

18

fishing grounds, or drive the resource beyond sustainable limits or 'carrying

capacity'.

The non-excludability characteristic of the common resources is very

similar to the open access resources in which everyone can access the resources.

However, unlike the open access resources that are (apparently) non-rivalrous, the

use of common resources by a user will definitely reduce the resources availability

for other users. Thus there is confusion in defining common resources and the open

access resources. Following Anderies and Janssen (2013, p. 3), any resource that is

shared among the users in which private property rights have not been established

will be considered as a “ commons resource” in this thesis.

The focus on common resources became central to environmental policy

after a path-breaking article published by Garrett Hardin in Science (1968). Hardin

expressed concern that common resources will eventually become scarce due to

excessive human consumption, which tends to transgress the limits of a common

resource's capacity to replenish itself. The absence of clearly defined property rights

or of any binding rules in relaticolemanon to human consumptive patterns on these

commons resources lead to what Hardin famously described as the “tragedy of the

commons”. This situation of unregulated, competitive and self-interested resource

use causes a tragedy since everyone will ultimately suffer from losing the benefit

from these resources (Hardin, 1968, p. 1244). As mentioned, Hardin called this

situation a “tragedy” since the limited availability of the resource, in the absence of

good governance, could drive competitive use and lead to resource depletion. In the

absence of regulation, people continue to maximize their individual benefit at

collective expense, and access to the resource is not tied to responsibility for

maintaining it, a phenomenon which Mancur Olson called the “free rider” problem

(Olson, 1965, p. 76).

Freedom to access a resource without any control from the government or

the community will lead to resource destruction that ultimately affects everyone.

Hardin explained this tragedy of the commons in the English commons allegory as

follows:

19

“Therein is the tragedy. Each man is locked into a system that compels him

to increase his herd without limit – in a world that is limited. Ruin is the

destination toward which all men rush, each pursuing his own best interest

in a society that believes in the freedom of the commons. Freedom in a

commons brings ruin to all’ (Hardin, 1968, p. 1245).

According to Dietz et al. (2002), Hardin’s analysis was underpinned by

Adam Smith's notions about human selfishness. In addition, Hardin’s work was

significantly influenced by the work of Lloyd (1833) who argued that common pool

resources will tend to be overused due to a discount factor. I.e. the value of the

benefit from the commons in the present is higher than in the future, because of the

tendency to overexploit the resource (Dietz et al., 2002). Further, Lloyd (1833)

argued that resource use also depends on the institutions that define the benefits and

cost of the resource (Dietz et al., 2002). A “tragedy” is more likely if

communication, trust, the capacity to anticipate future interactions, and the ability

to make binding agreements and rules, are lacking or ineffective (Dietz et al., 2002).

In this context, “the tragedy of the commons” can be avoided by governance

mechanisms that compel people to act in the interest of the collective good rather

than narrow self-interest (Vayda and Rappaport, 1968).

Two of the solutions posed by (Hardin, 1968, p. 1245) for preventing the

tragedy of the commons –state management and privatization– have dominated

policy approaches. Regarding the first solution, state management can make it

costly to use the resources beyond carrying capacity, either by charging tax for the

use of the resources or restricting their use through regulation and sanctions. In this

context, the government’s role is to establish the regulation and enforce it as the

rules of the game for people who utilize these common resources (Dietz et al.,

2002). The problems with state management include that it is expensive to make

such management effective (Wade, 1987, p. 105), and it is open to elite capture. In

addition, state control of common resources often leads to (1) overriding indigenous

institutions; (2) poor monitoring of resource boundaries and harvesting practices

because many governments do not have sufficient resources or motivation to

monitor extensive common resources; (3) de facto open access conditions and a

race to use the resources (Dietz et al., 2002, p. 7).

20

Regarding the second solution, Hardin (1968, p. 1245) argued that private

management of commons resources will often produce more effective, but unjust,

management. Privatizing a commons resource means that the property right of the

resource belongs to a certain stakeholder, which could be a person or a company.

When someone holds property rights on a resource, the resource tends to be better

protected than without clearly defined property rights (Araujo et al., 2009; Poteete

et al., 2010). By privatizing the commons, every resources user who holds the

property right is assumed to take responsibility for their own resources. Private

ownership and use of common resources may lead to greater efficiency but often at

high social cost (Attwood, 1992, p. 15). The costs that arise from the utilization of

the resources, including overuse, are assumed to be met by the user. According to

some theorists, private ownership will theoretically determine the maximum

economic benefit and thus the resource owner will be encouraged to manage the

resource properly to gain that benefit (Dietz et al., 2002). For this reason, Hardin

argued privatization, however unfair because of its exclusion of others from

resource access, was preferable to its ruin (Hardin, 1968, p. 1245).

Hardin’s argument was soon broadly accepted due to the consistency with

predictions made by mainstream economists and increasing examples of

environmental depletion from unregulated commons (Feeny et al., 1990; Anderies

and Janssen, 2013). His thesis that “freedom in a commons brings ruin to all” due

to lack of correspondence between rights and responsibilities (Hardin, 1968, p.

1244), was often considered by policy makers to support the neoliberal preference

for privatization (McCarthy, J. F. and Warren, 2009, p. 9) or government ownership

and control over the common resources (Dietz et al., 2002, p. 7). This became a

widely accepted policy prescription in disciplines such as environmental studies,

resource management policy, economics, and political science (Feeny et al., 1990;

Cole et al., 2014).

However, many policies based on these assumptions have faced

contradictions (Ostrom, 1998). Privatization as suggested by Hardin can clearly

motivate the resources owner to use the resources without consideration of the

needs of other parties or the sustainability of the resource beyond its use to the

21

present owner. Rational choice theory (Coleman and Fararo, 1992; Scott, 2000)

accommodates this probability, by suggesting that people make their decisions

based on outcomes of alternative actions and calculate the best action for

themselves. Actors in either the state or private sector will utilize the resources

under their control to generate a maximum benefit for their perceived (usually short-

term) advantage (Coleman, 1973; Heath, 1976), and not necessarily for the longer-

term sustainability of the resource5.

Ostrom (1998) called the tragedy of the commons a “social dilemma”;

which is a situation that occurs when individuals choose to take an action that

maximizes their short-term self-interest, leaving other parties (including future

generations) worse off than by employing other alternatives. Ostrom (1999)

proposed an alternative option to deploy local institutions for governing common

resources for sustainable use. Instead of relying on the state or private property

control, it is argued that utilizing local institutions would be more effective in

avoiding the tragedy of the commons. As some theorists argue, local communities

are better able to create rules regarding the resource utilization in the common

interest and have the capacity to enforce these rules based on their knowledge and

past experiences (Agrawal, 1996; Ostrom, 1999). Their knowledge and skills often

cause them to be regarded as savers of the environment as well as victims of

degradation (Myers, 1976; Borrini-Feyerabend, 1996; WWF, 1996; Persoon et al.,

2003).

When a community holds ownership rights over a common resource, they

can more immediately align rights and responsibilities by determining the

conditions of access for their own members (Ostrom, 1990). However, local rules

are difficult to apply effectively if the number of users is large, the boundaries of

the common resources are unclear, when they live in a group scattered across a large

area, and when undiscovered rule-breaking is easy (Wade, 1987, p. 104). When

degradation of common resources cannot be avoided in a situation of weak local

5 A clear example of this in Indonesia is forest concessions, where the state granted property rights

to certain companies, which led to extensive deforestation (Ramli and Ahmad, 1994).

22

governance, policy-makers return to the argument for privatization, state

management or a range of co-management alternatives (Wade, 1987, p. 104).

Indeed Hardin himself recognized a third 'solution' to the tragedy, which he

described as 'mutual coercion, mutually agreed upon by the majority of the people

affected' (Hardin, 1968, p. 1247). However, it was only as a result of the work of

Ostrom and other 'commons' scholars that research into the conditions under which

collective action toward sustainable use by local communities or user groups began

to be treated as a serious, even necessary, option for managing common pool

resources.

Ostrom’s work provides insights into the conditions under which self-

governance over common pool resources can be used to avoid the tragedy of the

commons. She defined a self-governing common resource as “one where the major

users are involved over time in making and adapting rules within collective-choice

arenas regarding the inclusion or exclusion of participants, appropriation strategies,

obligations of participants, monitoring and sanctioning, and conflict resolutions’

(Ostrom, 2005, p. 2). Her findings can help to explain the ineffectiveness of many

policies and resource governance regimes (Anderies and Janssen, 2013). Ostrom

(1990) identified eight design principles that characterize successful self-

governance strategies: clearly defined boundaries, congruence between

appropriation and resource provision rules and local conditions, collective decision-

making, monitoring, graduated sanctions, conflict-resolution mechanisms, minimal

recognition of rights to organize, and nested enterprises (see table 2.1).

Cole et al. (2014) have criticized both Ostrom’s and Hardin’s assumptions.

According to Cole et al. (2014, p. 360), the tragedy of the commons is not because

of a lack of institutions, as presumed by Ostrom (1999), but is a direct consequence

of interactions between the various rules applied, which stimulates a risk of

excessive use. They explain that Ostrom ignored an important attribute of the

institutional environment, namely certain institutional conditions, especially

property rights, that contribute to causing the tragedy (Cole et al., 2014). The

tragedy of the commons in Hardin’s example “is the product of interactions among

institutions that assign individual rights over the cattle that convert unowned grass

23

from open access pasture into privately owned beef” (Cole et al., 2014, p. 361).

This is essentially a problem of coherence of nested property rights and

responsibilities. Lack of clearly defined property rights leads to self-interest of the

resource users (Margolis, 1982) to maximize their needs due to competitive use

over the resources. Clearly defined property rights on the commons resources

would be followed by responsibilities over the resources utilization, which may in

turn deliver a sustainable use of the commons resources (Agrawal and Ostrom,

2001; Engel et al., 2008).

Table 2.1 Institutional Design Principles for Sustainable Common Resource

Governance

Principles

Description

1. Clearly defined

boundaries

The boundaries of the resource system and

individuals or households who have rights to

utilize the resource must be clearly defined.

2. Congruence between

resource provision

rules and local

conditions

Rules specifying the amount of the resource that

a user is allocated must be related to local

conditions and to rules regarding labour,

materials, and/or money inputs.

3. Collective decision-

making

Individuals who are affected by the harvesting

and protection rules are accommodated in the

group and can participate in modifying the

operational rules.

4. Monitoring Monitors, who actively audit the common

resources and resource user behaviour, are

accountable to the resource users themselves.

5. Graduated sanctions Resource users who violate rules-in-use are

subject to graduated sanctions (depending on

the seriousness and context of the offense) from

other users, from officials accountable to these

resource users, or from both.

6. Conflict-resolution

mechanisms

Resource users and their officials have rapid

access to low-cost, local mechanisms to resolve

24

Principles

Description

conflicts among the resource users, or between

the resource users and their officials.

7. Minimal recognition

of rights to organize

The rights of resource users to devise their own

institutions are not challenged by external

governmental authorities, and resource users

have long-term tenure rights to the resources.

8. Nested enterprises

(for resources that are

parts of larger systems)

Appropriation, provision, monitoring,

enforcement, conflict resolution, and

governance activities are organized in multiple

layers of nested enterprises.

Source: Ostrom (1990, p. 90); Anderies and Janssen (2013, p. 75)

The establishment of community rights over common pool resources are

often a transformation of state property that was previously managed by the

community itself. In developing countries, environmental policy decentralization is

designed to manage resources better by granting property rights to local

communities (Agrawal and Ostrom, 2001). The state is often unable to manage the

resource due to ‘inadequate government staffing with inadequate equipment, poor

legislation and law enforcement, and the collusion between the policy maker and

private companies’ (Persoon et al., 2003, p. 3). If this is the case, the property rights

on the resources may be decentralized6 to the relevant local community (Agrawal

and Ostrom, 2001), in the form of so called ‘co-management’7 (Persoon et al.,

2003). Co-management is defined as ‘the sharing of power, responsibilities and

benefits with respect to the management of natural resources (including their

exploitation and conservation among government and individual or collective

users)’ (Persoon et al., 2003, p. 4). According to Persoon et al. (2003) co-

management has been promoted as a new form of environmental management that

6 In this context, decentralization can be defined as “any act by which a central government cedes

rights of decision making over resources to actors and institutions at lower levels in a politico-

administrative and territorial hierarchy” (Agrawal and Ostrom, 2001, p. 488). 7 The term co-management is also known as collaborative management, joint management, and

community-based resource management.

25

accommodates joint management of natural resources between environmental non-

government organizations working together with local communities, national

governments and transnational donor agencies.

It has been argued by a number of scholars that decentralization of property

rights over a common resource to a local community and associated governance

accountability may produce more sustainable use of the commons (Ostrom, 1990;

Agrawal, 1996; Baland and Platteau, 1996; Agrawal and Ostrom, 2001;

Bhattacharya and Lueck, 2009), which is examined in this thesis. Having discussed

the nature of common resources in general, we will now focus on the example of

co-management in the form of Community Forestry practices.

2.2. Community Forestry

2.2.1. Community Forests as Common Resources

Community Forestry is a form of Social Forestry, which is a system of forest

management that pays attention to the benefits of forests for the livelihoods of local

forest dependent communities (Simon, 1994; Shyamsundar and Ghate, 2014).

Social forestry is an alternative to conventional forestry, which is a forest

management system based on timber exploitation or protection, traditionally

managed in purely economic and/or ecological terms. The term Social Forestry was

introduced during the World Forestry Congress VIII that was held in Jakarta in

1978, which carried the theme "Forests for the People" (Arnold, 1987; Simon,

1994). At the Congress, Social Forestry was defined as “a system in which local

people are participating in the management of forests with the special emphasis on

the establishment of forest plantations”. The objective of the social forestry system

is a successful reforestation to attain optimum function of the forest and at the same

time to increase the social welfare of the local people” (Simon, 1994, p. 4).

In Community Forestry practice, local people are empowered to manage a

given forest area for the greater economic benefit for the local community

(Krogman and Beckley, 2002). The forest quality is expected to improve through

strengthening forest users' rights by granting formal rights to manage the forest

(Shyamsundar and Ghate, 2014). Community Forestry practice allows local people

26

to employ their local knowledge to manage the forest as long as their practices are

suitable for the sustainability of the forest resource. Decentralization of forest

resources from the central government to local community is widely regarded as a

tool for achieving sustainable development goals while contributing to

strengthening social capital in the communities (Shyamsundar and Ghate, 2014).

Agrawal and Ostrom (2001) emphasized that successful decentralization of

resources management from the state to local actors creates new common resources

at local level that allow the local actors to obtain the rights and power to make

decisions regarding the resource management. The creation of new commons is

significant for natural resource policies worldwide (Agrawal and Ostrom, 2001).

As experienced in Nepal and other South Asian countries (Adhikari, B. et

al., 2007), and also in the Indian Himalayas (Agrawal, 1996), devolution of natural

resources such as forests from central government to local communities can lead to

more efficient, equitable and sustainable management of resources. Local control

over nearby natural resources such as the forest generates greater benefits for

surrounding local communities (Wunder, 2001; Bullock and Hanna, 2012; Dhakal

et al., 2012) and better forest conditions at the same time (Gibson et al., 2005;

Anderson et al., 2009). Collective management of forest by local communities has

been proven to produce more efficient outcomes than either private or state

governance and control since transaction costs that are associated with forest

governance are likely to be lower under local collective management compared to

the other two management regimes (Agrawal, 1996).

Community Forestry is also categorized as community based forest

management (CBFM), which is a form of decentralized forest management that

seeks to improve the quality and stock of forests by strengthening user rights and

allowing users to manage the forest collectively (Krogman and Beckley, 2002).

Community Forestry programs are also considered as a “problem solver” for

mitigating conflicts of interest regarding forest resources. In this context, local

communities play the most important role to support decision making processes and

social conflict mitigation (Bullock and Hanna, 2012).

27

Community Forestry is designed to achieve sustainable forest management,

which could better contribute to poverty alleviation (Gunter and Jodway, 2000), as

well as serving ecological functions (Sanwal, 1988; Charnley and Poe, 2007),

including but not limited to, providing ecosystem services such as water, carbon

sequestration, erosion control, and oxygen production.

Sunderlin, William D. (2006, p. 387) suggests seven preconditions for

fulfilment of poverty alleviation through a Community Forestry approach:

1. There is strong commitment from the government for poverty

alleviation through the Community Forestry program.

2. The government is able to exercise its commitment because the goal is

consistent with other state goals.

3. The administrative apparatus, enabling legislation, rules and

regulations governing Community Forestry adequately support poverty

alleviation.

4. Sufficient financial means exist to support the establishment and

implementation of Community Forestry.

5. There is an adequate level of political and organization power at the

local level to enforce entitlements and to exclude unauthorized

claimants to forest resources.

6. Equity institutions at the local level are sufficiently strong to allocate

project benefits to those who are most in need.

7. There are sufficient forest resource endowments at project sites.

2.2.2. Impact of Community Forestry upon Local Economy and Ecology

In this section we explore empirical studies of Community Forestry impacts

on the local economy and ecology that have revealed a variety of outcomes. Some

studies demonstrate the potential benefits of Community Forestry for mitigating

deforestation and, simultaneously, improving the welfare of surrounding

communities. Other studies suggest that Community Forestry programs provide

more economic benefits than ecological benefits. On the other hand, several studies

did not find significant improvement of socio-economic conditions through

Community Forestry programs, in particular for poverty alleviation.

A study of Community Forestry impacts on economy and ecology in

Kathmandu valley in Nepal conducted by Birch et al. (2014) suggested that

Community Forestry provides positive impacts on people’s livelihoods as well as

contributing to biodiversity conservation. They conclude that in the absence of

28

Community Forestry programs, the forestland would be converted into a mixture of

degraded forest, cropland and urban areas that would result in degradation in the

quality and quantity of ecosystem services, especially of carbon stocks and water.

Water quality would decline due to sedimentation, resulting in increased pollution

and higher treatment costs. With good Community Forestry practice, however, local

people’s revenue from harvesting wild goods from the forest itself and from

recreational visitors to their area, is more sustainable (Birch et al., 2014).

Similarly, Dhakal et al. (2007) found that in Nepal, Community Forestry

could help overcome the rural unemployment problem, subsequently increasing

incomes while ensuring sustainable utilization of forest resources. Before the

Community Forestry program was established, the incomes of poor households

were below the minimum standard of living. Poor households could obtain

sufficient income from a combination of farm and community forest resource use,

with a condition that all policy constraints on land use were fully relaxed and user

groups were allowed to maximize their income (Dhakal et al., 2007). However,

relaxing utilization rules to maximize incomes is a return to something like an open

access regime that may have negative effect on ecosystem services from the forest.

It is possible that the forest users' exploitation of the forest beyond its capacity

would reduce its capability to produce ecosystem services.

The Community Forestry program in Nepal also reduces unemployment in

the project area. In terms of land use, there was a shift from timber production to

fodder (from leaf litter) production in this community forest since fodder became

more profitable than timber due to an increase of livestock farming which in turn

led to improved household incomes, as well as having little negative effect on

ecosystem services from the forest (Dhakal et al., 2007).

By contrast, in some countries such as Cambodia, Laos and Vietnam,

empirical evidence for poverty alleviation through Community Forestry is difficult

to find. As mentioned by Sunderlin, William D. (2006), Community Forestry

programs have not been established with poverty alleviation as a major goal in these

countries. Instead, pressure from donor agencies has led to a focus on reducing

environmental degradation. A major barrier to poverty alleviation through

29

Community Forestry programs in these countries has been the forest management

practices that were conducted by state owned enterprises (Sunderlin, William D.,

2006). It is the fact that some forest resources are still under the control of the state

forest enterprises that can prevent the delegation of forest management rights to

local communities.

Similarly, a study conducted in Indonesia by Maryudi et al. (2012) suggests

that Community Forestry is yet to achieve its promise to alleviate poverty. They

mentioned that benefits from Community Forestry in Indonesia were only sufficient

for the forest farmer household's subsistence economy and could not be used for

saving or asset building for permanent income growth. Crops produced from

community forests are seen as a complement to the yields from private farmland.

Declining agricultural yields as the forest canopy increases proved an obstacle to

gaining better outcomes from the community managed forests (Maryudi et al.,

2012).

Charnley and Poe (2007) emphasize the capacity of Community Forestry

programs in supporting forest conservation and community development. They

argue that the impact of Community Forestry on social economic conditions of local

people is dependent on the extent to which devolution or decentralization has

actually occurred in practice and what exactly has been devolved: rights of access

to forest products, forest management tasks, decision making powers, or property

rights. Products from community forests have helped local people meet their

subsistence needs, provide a safety net in emergencies and helped support

livelihoods during seasonal economic gaps (Charnley and Poe, 2007). Clearly,

further research that can provide a better understanding of why Community

Forestry does or does not achieve its promise is needed (Charnley and Poe, 2007).

This thesis aims to help fill this gap in the literature. Now we will turn to discuss

issues regarding payment for ecosystem services, as this has become a key issue in

sustainable forest resource management.

30

2.3. Payment for Ecosystem Services

The utilization of natural common resources such as forests has frequently

created both positive and negative externalities that affect people differentially, such

as when structural arrangements result in disproportionate allocation of costs and

benefits. Externalities are defined as external benefits or costs that emerge as a

result of other people’s activity. This means that the welfare of some depends on

factors that are determined by other users or authorities (van den Bergh, 2010).

Externalities can be positive if they come as benefits and can be negative if they

come as costs for the affected outside parties. An example of a positive externality

is where people can enjoy free clean and fresh air as a result of trees planted by a

land-owner. On the other hand, pollution as a consequence of the existence of a

chicken farm could be an example of a negative externality.

Positive externalities are not likely to be of concern since the affected parties

benefit from their existence. By contrast, negative externalities are often an issue

since they raise problems for those who are affected, and ultimately result in

disregard or damage to the natural resource itself. An example of a negative

externality related to natural resources utilization would be unregulated or illegal

logging in watersheds that ultimately threatens water quality and quantity, affecting

not only those who profit from illegal logging, but also local villagers and urban

water consumers as well.

Vatn (2010) reveals that biodiversity loss and climate change are also

examples on a global scale of how some people's use of natural resources can affect

others' lives and livelihoods. Thus internalizing these externalities may be an

important step in order to make fair and sustainable conditions for related parties

affected by resource use and conservation. This phenomenon is the well-known

issue of social cost (Coase, 1960) which we turn to discuss in the next section.

2.3.1. Definition of PES

To promote natural resource sustainability by reducing negative

externalities, a relatively new paradigm has been developed and has emerged as a

significant policy instrument, namely Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES). PES

31

is defined as a voluntary transaction where a well-defined ecosystem service is

bought by at least one service buyer from at least one service provider with a

condition that the provider continues to conserve the resource in order to secure the

service provision (Wunder, 2005, 2007). This paradigm is specifically designed to

reward those who manage natural resources through financial incentives to provide

an agreed level of ecosystem services.

Ecosystem services (also called environmental services)8 are defined as the

beneficial ecological components that are enjoyed by people directly or indirectly

from ecosystem or environmental protection (Costanza et al., 1997; MA, 2003;

Boyd and Banzhaf, 2007; Fisher et al., 2009). Examples of ecosystem services

include carbon sequestration, biodiversity conservation, watershed protection, and

landscape beauty (Ferraro, 2001; Wunder, 2005). These are commonly categorized

as public goods or quasi-public goods and typically are free to consume9. However,

the emerging scarcity of these goods causes them to become economic goods with

the potential to be commercialized (Wunder, 2005).

Coasean economics is the primary conceptual basis of the PES approach

(Muradian, Roldan et al., 2010; Sattler and Matzdorf, 2013). The Coasean theorem

is based on the assumption that the problem of externalities can be solved through

direct negotiation among related parties who cause and/or are affected by the

externality, regardless of the allocation of property rights (Coase, 1960; Engel et

al., 2008; Sattler and Matzdorf, 2013). In his influential article “The Problem of

Social Cost”, Coase (1960) challenged Pigou’s approach in “The Economics of

Welfare” to solving the problem of externalities.

Pigou (1932) argued that negative externality generates a social cost that

should be dealt with by government. He proposed a system of tax, which is well

8 The terms ecosystem services and environmental services are often used interchangeably in

academic and public policy literatures (Muradian, Roldan et al., 2010). 9 Public goods are defined as valued goods which everyone can access, that have characteristics of

non-rivalry and non-exclusion (Dietz et al., 2002; Anderies and Janssen, 2013). On the other hand,

goods that have characteristics of rivalry and exclusion are defined as private goods (Anderies and

Janssen, 2013). Quasi-public goods, which Ostrom (1990) called common-pool resources, hold both

characteristics of private and public goods including partial exclusion and partial rivalry (Anderies

and Janssen, 2013). Ostrom (1990, p. 30) defines common-pool resources as “a natural or man-made

resource system that is sufficiently large as to make it costly (but not impossible) to exclude potential

beneficiaries from obtaining benefits from its use”.

32

known as “Pigovian tax”, for resolving the social cost problem. Pigou’s solution

implies market failure and asserts that government authority is needed to correct

the market so that an appropriate level of compensation for externalities would

emerge (Yandle, 1997). Yandle (1997) argues that the Pigovian approach is likely

to be more appropriate, and should be applied in large-scale cases, where there are

many parties included in the system, and where it is too difficult to rely on contracts

and market solutions.

On the other hand, instead of taxing or subsidizing the parties who cause

externalities - to reduce or stop their harmful activity - Coasean economics suggests

market and quasi-market transactions can achieve a socially optimal level of

environmental externalities. Coase argues that those who produce externalities and

those who suffer from them should be left in an unregulated situation without

government intervention (such as Pigovian taxes or subsidies) and that a transaction

process will eventually be developed automatically regardless of who holds the

property rights (Turner et al., 1994). However, Sattler and Matzdorf (2013) argue

that in practice, the Coasean solution faces some obstacles regarding efficient

bargaining, in particular, high transaction costs, power imbalances, and poorly

defined property rights. Thus the Coasean solution itself required a clear definition

and allocation of property rights (guaranteed ownership of resources via the force

of state law) and low transaction costs, similarly requiring state intervention (Turner

et al., 1994; Muradian, Roldan et al., 2010).

In summary, in a Coasean style PES, the beneficiaries of ecosystem services

make a direct payment to the ecosystem services provider based on a mutually

agreed voluntary negotiated procedure. By contrast, in a Pigovian style PES, the

government undertakes an intervention, such as by providing a subsidy to pay the

ecosystem services provider in order to secure the ecosystem services provision

(Sattler and Matzdorf, 2013). It is possible that a hybrid Coasean and Pigovian

approach can lead to a new policy paradigm that combines elements of both a

voluntary market-based and mandatory policy-based system. An example of the

hybrid approach is the PSA program in Costa Rica that combine the Pigouvian and

Coasean approach to the sources of funding. The funding for this program comes

from a private hydroelectric producer, tax, and World Bank loans (Sánchez-

33

Azofeifa and Pfaff, 2007). The PES system in West Lombok Indonesia also

represents a hybrid approach that combines voluntary transactions on the supply

side and government regulation on the demand side. Based on Coase’s thesis,

ecosystem services supply should theoretically be optimal if there is payment from

beneficiaries of ecosystem services to its providers (Pattanayak et al., 2010). This

is the fundamental assumption behind the concept of PES proposed by some

scholars (see, for example, Wunder 2005, 2007). Pagiola (2007) defined PES as a

market-based mechanism centered on the mutual principles of buying and selling

of ecosystem services from beneficiaries to providers. Sommerville, M. M. et al.

(2009) stress, however, a principle of services provision as a condition for the

incentives transferred to ecosystem services providers. Featuring incentives as a

key aspect for the provision of ecosystem services, Muradian, Roldan et al. (2010,

p. 1205) define PES as “a transfer of resources between social actors, which aims

to create incentives to align individual and/or collective land use decisions with the

social interest in the management of natural resources”. A common assumption of

PES policies is that there must be contractual mutual obligations among service

providers and consumers (Kroeger, 2012).

2.3.2. The Emergence of PES

The concept of ecosystem services can be traced back to 1864 when Marsh

first introduced the modern concept of ecosystem services in his book Man and

Nature (Mooney et al., 1997). A century later, concern about ecosystem services

continues to draw scholars’ attention. For instance, in the late 1960s King,

Helliwell, Hueting, Odum and Braat published on the functions of nature in serving

human needs (Gómez-Baggethun et al., 2010). Following this, in the 1970s and

1980s, people’s dependence on natural ecosystems had been stressed by some

scholars through a consideration of ecological impacts on the economy and vice

versa, thus raising greater public interest in environmental protection and

biodiversity conservation (Westman, 1977; Pimentel et al., 1980; Ehrlich and

Ehrilch, 1981; Costanza et al., 1997). In the early 1990s, the research agenda on

ecosystem services was stimulated by the Beijer Institute’s Biodiversity Program

(Perrings et al., 1992). A paper presented by Costanza et al. (1997) was a landmark

34

in the development of the concept and awareness of ecosystem services (Gómez-

Baggethun et al., 2010). The concept of ecosystem services started to be employed

in the policy arena in the late 1990s and early 2000s; the Millennium Ecosystem

Assessment (MA, 2003) established a critical milestone that takes the ecosystem

services paradigm into account (Fisher et al., 2009). It has since been followed by

the introduction of PES programs in a number of countries.

Pagiola (2008) points out that Costa Rica’s country-wide program called

Pago por Servicios Ambientales (PSA) in 1997 was the first full-scale

implementation of the formal PES mechanism in a developing country. The PSA

was designed to address the problem of deforestation as Costa Rica had one of the

highest deforestation rates at the time10. As perhaps the best-known example of PES

(Pattanayak et al., 2010), Costa Rica’s PSA program succeeded in raising the

interest of many countries in introducing PES programs as a tool for environmental

protection. These included Brazil, Mexico, Colombia, Bolivia, Ecuador, China, and

Indonesia. Further impetus came when the Kyoto Protocol established Reducing

Emission from Deforestation and Forest Degradation (REDD+)11 programs as a

possible vehicle to articulate international PES schemes in the forestry sector

(Venter and Koh, 2012).

2.3.3. Two Paradigms Regarding PES

Tacconi (2012) explored two PES approaches called the environmental

economic perspective as summarized by Engel et al. (2008) and the ecological

economic perspective described by Muradian, Roldan et al. (2010). From an

environmental economics perspective, the main concept of PES is that external

ecosystem services beneficiaries directly benefit; contractual and conditional

financial transfers are made to local landholders and users in return for adopting

practices that secure environmental conservation and restoration (Wunder, 2005).

10 Costa Rica’s deforestation rate between 1973 and 1989 reached one of the highest levels in the

world, with yearly average logging of 32,000 hectares (Brown and Bird, 2010, p. 1). In the initial

introduction period of the PSA program, it had contributed to a reduction of about 1% of the yearly

deforestation rate (Robalino and Pfaff, 2013, p. 339). 11 REDD+ is a method for putting a price tag on the carbon storage and sequestration services

provided by forests (Venter and Koh, 2012).

35

The environmental economics perspective stressed the conditionality that providers

should maintain the provision of ecosystem services in return for payment.

Services providers commonly obtain more benefits from their ordinary

methods of managing or using the land than from that required by services buyers

for conservation purposes. Since the ordinary management practices produce

externalities that affect ecosystem services users, according to the environmental

economics perspective approach, ecosystem services users should transfer certain

endowments to the ecosystem services providers as compensation for managing the

land in an appropriate way that does not adversely affect them. The transfer of

endowments could be in the form of monetary or non-monetary (indirect approach)

compensation, such as through rural development projects. In order to represent an

affordable ecosystem services price, the payment should meet a minimum benefit

forgone (opportunity cost) condition by the ecosystem services providers and be

less than or equal to the value of the ecosystem services to the buyers (Engel et al.,

2008).

Wunder (2005) summarizes the five conditionality criteria underlying the

environmental economics perspective approach to PES:

1. It is a voluntary transaction.

2. The ecosystem services must be well-defined.

3. There must be a minimum of one ecosystem services buyer.

4. There must be a minimum of one ecosystem services provider.

5. The ecosystem services provider must secure the ecosystem services

provision.

The second approach to PES, the ecological economics perspective, is built

on a different set of principles. According to this approach, PES cannot be

considered as a voluntary market transaction especially from a buyer’s perspective,

even if private negotiation occurs (Muradian, Roldan et al., 2010; Vatn, 2010). To

execute a PES program, there is a need for engagement between state and

community (Vatn, 2010). So, state or government intervention is required. An

independent intermediary is also probably required to act as a broker to connect

providers and buyers of ecosystem services especially in the case of a large number

of both parties. The intermediary could also be a manager of the PES system. Its

36

role could be collecting payments from buyers and delivering them to providers,

monitoring the provision of ecosystem services, and ensuring the enforcement of

property rights among the parties.

The ecological economics perspective advocates that the conditionality

criteria and the assumption of complete information in PES transactions adopted by

the Coasean approach are, in practice, rarely met. Most PES practice in the world

follows the Pigouvian approach and includes some government intervention (Sattler

and Matzdorf, 2013). Government intervention can be in the form of regulator,

monitor and also provider of supporting subsidies.

2.3.4. Alternative PES Schemes

Wunder (2005) described several important distinctive approaches among

PES schemes: first, area-based versus product-based schemes; second, public

versus private schemes; and third, use-restricting versus asset building schemes.

We discuss each in turn.

Area-based versus Product-based Schemes

In area-based schemes, a certain number of pre-agreed land units are

stipulated in contracts. The agreed land then will be used to provide certain

ecosystem services which should be managed by providers. Examples of this

approach include conservation concessions, easements, protected catchments or

forest-carbon plantations (Wunder, 2005).

In contrast, product-based schemes are set to produce environmentally

friendly certified natural resource based products where buyers will pay “a green

premium” on top of the market price as compensation for the production process of

such products. This type of PES is usually designed to minimize the negative

impacts of related production processes to the environment (Wunder, 2005).

Certified timber, organic farming, and ecotourism are examples of this product-

based type of scheme.

37

Public versus Private Schemes

This kind of scheme is distinguished by who the buyers of the services are.

In public schemes, the state acts on behalf of buyers; they collect money in the form

of fees, taxes or grants from services consumers and deliver it to the providers

(Wunder, 2005). The REDD+ programs are examples of this type of PES scheme.

On the other hand, private schemes tend to be more locally focused where

there is a direct connection between services users as buyers and services providers

(Wunder, 2005). In this case, buyers pay directly to providers without any

intermediary body. A hydro-power company paying the land owner to keep their

trees in order to maintain river flow is a good example of this type of scheme.

Use-restricting versus Asset Building Schemes

In use-restricting schemes, providers are rewarded for their effort in

conservation-related activities such as restricting land development and protecting

natural resources (Wunder, 2005). In this scheme, the opportunity costs of

conservation are covered by the service users. Protecting forest for carbon

sequestration is an example of this scheme.

In contrast, asset-building schemes aim for ecosystem services area

restoration. Farmers are encouraged to participate in environmental conservation,

which aims to maintain or improve ecosystem services provision for which they

will be rewarded by the service users. Replanting trees on degraded land is an

example of this scheme (Wunder, 2005).

2.3.5. PES and Poverty Alleviation

Evidence that high levels of poverty are spatially correlated with remote

areas that provide ecosystem services suggests that PES programs could also

contribute to poverty alleviation (Pagiola et al., 2005; Wunder, 2005; Pagiola, 2007;

Bremer et al., 2014). However, the impact of PES programs on the livelihoods of

poor people is an empirical question. In this regard, Wang et al. (2009)

distinguished three categories of PES impacts on poor households: first, the impact

38

on poor providers; second, the impact on poor users; and third, the impact on poor

non-participants.

The impact of PES on poor providers can be divided into income effects and

non-income effects (Pagiola et al., 2005; Wang et al., 2009). The income effects are

obtained directly by the poor as soon as they participate in providing ecosystem

services, particularly in a cash-based payment approach. Payments from service

users could offer additional income for them that could potentially increase

livelihood benefits. Although theoretically a PES scheme is assumed to be

beneficial to poor ecosystem services providers (Wang et al., 2009), there is no

guarantee that payments will reach those most in need, or compensate for resource

benefits foregone (Pagiola et al., 2005). Distributional inequities might be related

to how resource rights are defined and distributed among ecosystem services

providers. In a condition of weak property rights where poor providers have little

or no access to other resources such as private farming land, they would probably

suffer welfare losses, as in general they are heavily dependent on natural resources

for their subsistence. Thus, PES would probably not be beneficial for poor providers

in areas where property rights are insecure and not clearly defined, since the PES

payment should be delivered to the ecosystem services providers who clearly hold

property rights upon the resources that produce the ecosystem services. In this

situation, a PES system is unlikely to be an adequate policy to increase welfare

(Engel and Palmer, 2008).

Non-income effects of PES commonly relate to social and cultural capital12

(Pagiola et al., 2005; Wang et al., 2009) and investment (Wang et al., 2009; Tacconi

et al., 2013). Effective implementation of PES programs often requires participants

to build an institution that would provide a forum for enhanced cooperation among

communities. It thus contributes to social capital building (Kerr, 2002; Pagiola,

2005). In terms of investment, in considering a PES program in South Africa as an

example, Wang et al. (2009) found that PES has created thousands of jobs, with a

12 Social or cultural capital refers to “features of social life—networks, norms, and trust—that enable

participants to act together more effectively to pursue shared objectives” (Putnam, 1995, pp. 664-

665).

39

strong emphasis on gender equity. They also found that PES provides other benefits

such as specific skills training and better health services for the participants.

Tacconi et al. (2013) argue that the impact of PES will be higher in a situation where

there is a collective fund component in which some payments are retained and used

for credit to individual households or for community level investment such as rural

infrastructure. They considered PES practice in West Java Indonesia as a positive

example, where 5% of individual payments were retained, to be invested in the

community water supply system. In this regard, the existence of local organizations,

which have the capability to manage funds and facilitate collective decision-making

by the community at large is necessary (Tacconi et al., 2013). However, undesirable

impacts on poor ecosystem services providers could still possibly occur. For

instance, users of local forest resources might lose access to non-timber forest

products as a result of PES agreements that exclude traditional uses.

The second category, the impact of PES on poor users, comes indirectly in

the form of better living conditions for the poor users as a result of environmental

quality amelioration (Wang et al., 2009). For instance, improvements in the quality

of water services will help the poor to reduce their cost of water consumption since

they can use clean water both for cooking and drinking without additional spending

on bottled water. However, PES could also be a burden for the poor users. If the

amount of payment is unaffordable, this will obstruct their opportunity to

participate, and thus will limit their access to these ecosystem services.

The last category, the impact of PES on poor non-participants, is via the

effect of land use and labor market change (Wang et al., 2009). Changing land use

could limit the access of landless poor people to natural resources, as poor people

often rely for their livelihood on natural resources such as gathering non-timber

products from the forests. The impact on labour demand could arise from land

management systems changed as a consequence of the land-owner participation in

the PES program. Landowners who previously employed workers to manage their

land could reduce their employees in order to meet the requirement of the PES

system to maintain the natural condition of the land. Thus PES could increase

unemployment rates in rural areas. In this case, PES will generate adverse impacts

for poor-non-participants. Regarding this situation, Pagiola et al. (2005) concluded

40

that PES is designed for natural resources management efficiency purposes and is

not the best instrument for poverty alleviation.

2.3.7. Guidance for PES System Development

In regard to developing a good system of PES, it is necessary to understand

the process of how ecosystem services are affected by land users and how the

provision of ecosystem services will affect the ecosystem services users. The World

Bank provides guidance for PES system development along these lines as illustrated

in Figure 2.1.

There are some key steps required to develop a PES program. Firstly, it is

important to understand the economic impact of land use on ecosystem and

ecosystem services users. For instance, land use could have implications for the

hydrological system, carbon sequestration, and/or biodiversity conservation.

Hydrological systems that generate water services could possibly affect farmers

who use water from irrigation systems, consumers of water companies and also the

hydropower electricity users. The core concept of PES based on the World Bank

model is that those who provide the ecosystem services should be rewarded in order

to maintain positive behavior related to the ecosystem services provision (Pagiola,

2006).

The second step is identifying ecosystem services users and setting up an

ecosystem services price. This step requires a long negotiation process with the

users to set the appropriate ecosystem services price, especially if the users are

private companies. The economic precondition of an acceptable ecosystem services

price is that service users' Willingness to Pay (WTP) should exceed services

providers' Willingness to Accept (WTA) and should ideally compensate the

minimum opportunity cost faced by services providers (Börner et al., 2010; Hoang

et al., 2013).

41

Figure 2.1 Guidance for PES System Development

Sources: Pagiola and Platais (2002) and Pagiola (2006).

After the negotiated price has been set up and the service users are charged,

the next step is paying the service providers. In order to make the PES system

transparent and accountable, one option is to employ an independent mediator who

can manage and monitor the mechanism, to make sure that all the processes of

ecosystem services delivery as well as the payments have been delivered to

appropriate parties. In this regard, the last step, establishing the institutional

framework, is critical (Pagiola, 2006).

2.3.8. PES Application in the World

PES systems have been introduced through various schemes in developing

and developed countries. Table 2.2 summarizes the main schemes. Most of the PES

schemes in the world are related to forest conservation with water and biodiversity

as the main object of ecosystem services protection. Local farmers in the ecosystem

services production areas are the sellers while the buyers come from governments,

private companies and water-user communities. Typically, PES practices are

organized by an independent management organization, usually supported by the

relevant government.

42

Table 2.2 Examples of PES Schemes

Country,

Case

Ecosystem

Services

Action Paid Buyer Seller Approach References

Costa Rica,

Pago por

Servicios

Ambientales

(PSA).

Water

Sustainable

forest

management13

Hydroelectric

power

producers,

bottlers,

municipal

water supplier,

irrigation water

users and

hotels

Private land

holders in

watershed

areas

Hybrid (Pagiola, 2008)

China, Sloping

Land

Conservation

Program

(SLCP)

Water Conversion of

cropland to

forest or

grassland14

China Central

Government

Rural farmer

households

Pigovian (Zhang et al.,

2008)

Madagascar,

PES for

biodiversity

conservation

in Menabe.

Biodiversity Good forest

governance15

Durrel

Community

members

Rural

Communities

Coasean (Sommerville,

M. et al., 2010)

Cambodia,

Payment for

Biodiversity

Protection.

Biodiversity Biodiversity

protection16

Communities Villagers

within the

boundary of

protected area

Coasean (Clements et

al., 2010;

Milne and

Adams, 2012)

Indonesia,

Payment for

hydrological

system

Water Forest

protection17

Local

government

and State

Owned Oil

refinery

Managers of

Sungai Wain

Protection

Forest (BP

HLSW)

Coasean (Prasetyo et

al., 2009)

13 Landowners have to plant timber and protect the forest from fires, illegal logging, and illegal

harvesting. They also have to do scheduled monitoring of the forest (Pagiola, 2008). 14 Farmers rewarded for planting trees on sloping land that was previously use for crops (Zhang et

al., 2008). 15 The PES participants were encouraged to maintain sustainable forest management through

avoiding illegal activities in the forest such as agricultural expansion, Lemur hunting, and Canoe

building (Sommerville, M. et al., 2010). 16 Villagers are paid for keeping the land-use plan and no-hunting rules, and for monitoring and

protecting birds' nesting sites. They were offered a reward for reporting nests, and are then employed

to monitor and protect birds until the chicks successfully fledge (Clements et al., 2010). 17 The BPHLSW were paid for protecting forest from deforestation to avoid sedimentation on the

Wain river (Prasetyo et al., 2009).

43

Country,

Case

Ecosystem

Services

Action Paid Buyer Seller Approach References

protection in

Balikpapan.

Company

(Pertamina)

Mexico,

Payment for

Hydrological

Environmental

Services.

Water Forest

Conservation18

Mexican

Federal

Government

Communal

and

individual

land owners

Pigouvian (Muñoz-Piña

et al., 2008)

Brazil, Bolsa

Floresta

Program.

Carbon

sequestration

Carbon

emission

reduction

through forest

conservation19

Government

and private

sector

Communities

living in the

Amazon

Pigouvian

(Pereira,

2010)

Australia,

payment for

tropical

savannas

protection.

Landscape,

habitats and

biodiversity

Savannas

protection20

Government People living

in tropical

savannas

Pigouvian (Greiner, R. et

al., 2009)

Australia,

Caring for our

Country

program

Biodiversity

and cultural

resources

Biodiversity

promotion and

cultural

conservation21

Government Aboriginal

ranger groups

Pigouvian (Greiner, R

and Stanley,

2013)

In summary, this review of the case study literature on PES found four major

types of PES schemes dominating global experiments to date (Pagiola et al., 2005;

Wunder, 2005; Engel and Palmer, 2008; Wunder et al., 2008; Greiner, R. et al.,

2009; Peskett et al., 2011):

1. Carbon sequestration and storage (e.g. an electricity company pays

farmers or landowners for planting and maintaining additional trees).

The Reducing Emission from Deforestation and Forest Degradation

18 Payment will be made if no land use change had occurred, no matter how small the change. If

deforestation occurs accidently for instance by forest fires or timber theft, participants will get paid

only for the remaining forest area (Muñoz-Piña et al., 2008). 19 Forest dwellers were rewarded for avoiding deforestation. They were still allowed to continue

carrying out sustainable productive activities such as agro-extractivism (Pereira, 2010). 20 Actions paid includes safeguarding the wild grunter fishery, safeguarding Aboriginal cultural

heritage and sustaining terrestrial biodiversity (Greiner, R. et al., 2009). 21 Participants were rewarded for undertaking coastal clean-up of discarded fishing nets and rescue

of marine wildlife caught up in the nets (Greiner, R and Stanley, 2013).

44

(REDD) program is an example of this PES type which aims to

compensate the effort of land owners in reducing carbon emissions from

deforestation and forest degradation (van Wilgen et al., 1998; Agrawal

et al., 2011; Venter and Koh, 2012);

2. Biodiversity protection (e.g. conservation donors pay local people for

restoring areas to create a biological corridor) (Clements et al., 2010;

Gardner et al., 2012; Ingram et al., 2014);

3. Watershed protection (e.g. downstream water consumers paying

upstream forest users for adopting land management practices that

control deforestation, soil erosion, flooding risk, etc.) (Kerr, 2002;

Prasetyo et al., 2009; Pirard, 2012);

4. Landscape embellishment (e.g. a tourism operator pays a local

community for maintaining landscape beauty or not hunting in a forest

being used for ecotourism) (Greiner, R. et al., 2009; Clements et al.,

2010; Sodhi et al., 2010).

These PES developments are supported by international development

institutions, such as the World Bank. The World Bank’s commitment to

environmental sustainability has been implemented via its support for PES

development in developing countries. For instance, the Costa Rica Ecomarkets

Projects were funded with US$ 33 million in 2001-2006 (Pagiola and Platais, 2002).

Some US$ 4.5 million was allocated for the Regional Integrated Silvopastoral

Management program, developed in Colombia/Costa Rica/Nicaragua during 2002-

2008 (The World Bank, 2008). In South Africa, the World Bank allocated an

amount of US$ 9 million for the Cape Action Plan for the Environment in 2004

(The World Bank, 2004). Other projects were also developed in EL Salvador,

Mexico, Venezuela, Kenya, and Panama (Pagiola, 2006). The World Bank not only

provided money for PES development, but it also provided capacity building in the

supported countries.

International conservation NGOs such as World Wide Fund for Nature

(WWF), Conservation International (CI) and The Nature Conservancy also have

important roles in PES programs development worldwide. WWF claims to be the

45

leader in developing PES schemes around the world (WWF, 2017). A number of

PES practices have been promoted by WWF, including Reducing Emissions from

Deforestation and Forest Degradation (REDD) programs in Colombia, Democratic

Republic of Congo, Indonesia, Nepal, Peru, Laos and Vietnam; watershed-based

PES in Madagascar, Serbia, Ukraine, Bulgaria, Romania; as well as the PES scheme

in West Lombok - the case study of this thesis. Most of the PES schemes promoted

by WWF applied a Coasean approach using voluntary systems. Conservation

International (CI) supports PES programs in some countries - the PES approach in

Costa Rica is one of the featured projects promoted by CI that also received funding

support from the German Development Bank through The Trust for the Sustainable

Biodiversity (TSB) Fund (Rodriguez, 2012). Other countries in which CI has been

engaged in developing PES programs include Caledonia, Ecuador, Brazil,

Cambodia, Madagascar, China and Indonesia (Forslund et al., 2009). The Nature

Conservancy instigated PES Water Funds, Water Producers and REDD+ programs

in Brazil and across Latin America including Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, and Mexico

(The Nature Conservancy, 2012, 2017). In contrast to WWF and CI, The Nature

Conservancy promoted PES programs that mostly applied a Pigouvian approach

where the funding comes from the relevant government. The vast majority of PES

programs that have been supported by these NGOs are concerned with forest

conservation.

2.4. Conclusion

Inadequate governance of commons resources that have caused

overexploitation have prompted scholars and policy makers to promote sustainable

ways to manage such resources. The consequences of unregulated exploitation were

highlighted by Garrett Hardin in his influential essay, as “the tragedy of the

commons”. In Hardin’s analysis, a state might address the ‘tragedy of the

commons’ by acting as the owner of common resources, providing regulations for

usage. Another alternative to govern the common resources proposed by Hardin is

privatization. He argues that by privatizing the commons resources, those resources

can be used in a sustainable manner. However, he believed privatization was unfair

due to the exclusive use of the resource. In addition, a private investor could obtain

46

private property rights, exploit the resource and transfer the capital gained from

overexploitation to a new field of operation that might threaten resource

sustainability. Hardin also proposed a third solution that he described as 'mutual

coercion, mutually agreed upon'. In this third solution, social arrangements that can

produce responsibility sharing are required. However, this third solution is often

ignored in the literature.

As early interpreters of Hardin ignored the institutional constraints on

resource use that often exist in the community, Elinor Ostrom and other commons

researchers argued that local communities have the potential within their traditional

institutions to manage common resources more sustainably than privatization or

state monopoly. Ostrom’s research focuses on practices of community based

management of common resources, which is an approach that accommodates local

people's experience, knowledge and institutions in governing the commons, but

which also faces limitations.

There is consequently an emphasis on co-management between state and

local communities in order to deal with the significant negative externalities arising

from commons resource mismanagement. One of the common resources that have

become the focus of co-management approach is forests. Because of their scale,

forests tend to be an open access resource that makes regulation of use rights

difficult. The government usually holds authority over these forests, but is often

unable to regulate use-rights effectively. Through co–management of forests, social

economic factors affecting local communities can prevent forest degradation caused

by local people’s activities in the forest for economic reasons. Accommodation of

local needs in forest management has been attempted mainly in the form of

Community Forestry. In Community Forestry practice, some conditional rights

over forest management are devolved from the state to the local community.

Studies suggest that Community Forestry has the potential to be a tool for a

win-win solution, to achieve a balanced outcome of forest management for both the

local economy and for ecological benefits. However, the effectiveness of local

institutions in relation to community forest management remains an open question,

with mixed results reported.

47

Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) is one important policy framework

aimed at controlling externalities in the management of common resources such as

forests. Pigou’s and Coase’s theories became the fundamental alternative

approaches for PES development and implementation. The Coasean approach

favours market transactions between those who cause the negative externality and

the ecosystem services users who suffer from it. Coase suggests that both parties

negotiate without any government intervention so that an optimal level of balance

can be achieved between cost and reward. On the other hand, the Pigouvian

approach accommodates the involvement of government to mitigate externalities

through regulatory mechanisms, and by exercising tax or subsidies. In practice,

most of the world’s applications of PES mainly follow the Pigouvian approach;

where the buyer of the ecosystem services is the government, or the government

provides cash on behalf of their citizens for rewarding resource protection. There

are also hybrid arrangements where market transactions are involved and

government intervenes through policy frameworks to make the PES system work.

PES has continued to develop globally since it was introduced in the late

1990s and early 2000s. Support from the World Bank and international

environmental based NGOs contributed to the rise of PES implementation in

developing countries. Debates among scholars emerged regarding the effectiveness

of the twin goals of PES, supporting environmental conservation as well as for

alleviating poverty in rural areas. The extent to which PES combined with

Community Forestry is able to simultaneously counteract poverty and achieve

environmental and social livelihood goals in a case study of Lombok, Indonesia

will be the key question to be addressed in this thesis. Theories of commons

resource management will be used as a framework to answer the question.

However, it is first necessary to provide background on forest governance in

Indonesia and particularly Community Forestry management in Lombok, a topic to

which we turn in the next chapter.

48

Chapter 3

Forest Management, Community Forestry and Adat Rules

The aim of this chapter is to explain how forests in Indonesia, especially in

Lombok, are managed. Historical forest management regimes from the era of the

pre-colonial kingdoms through the post-Suharto regional autonomy era are

reviewed in this chapter. The triggers of deforestation in Indonesian forests in each

era are elaborated, concluding with a discussion of contemporary Community

Forestry management and the role of adat rules in forest management in the case

study area.

This chapter is structured as follows. Section 3.1 discusses historical forest

governance in Indonesia and the triggers of deforestation; Section 3.2 focuses on

Community Forestry schemes and adat rules including the case study of Sesaot

community forest development, the use of adat to govern the forest and its impact

on sustainable forest management. The role of outsiders in Community Forestry

management is discussed in section 3.3. Finally, section 3.4 summarizes the main

points and concludes this chapter.

3.1. Historical Forest Governance and Deforestation in Lombok

The Indonesian Constitution of 1945 (UUD 1945) regulates the ownership

of Indonesian natural resources, including forests. Article number 33 of the

constitution mentions that “the earth, water and natural resources contained therein

shall be controlled by the state and are to be used for the welfare of the people”

(UUD 1945 article 33) . The Basic Agrarian Law -UU 5/1960 article 1(2) and 2(1)-

also emphasizes that all natural resources in Indonesia are national assets that

belong to all of the people and are managed by the state (UU 5/1960 article 2) .

Officially, forests cover 98 million hectares or about 52% of the total land

area in Indonesia (Menteri Kehutanan RI, 2014b, p. 3). Before the colonial era in

this country, kings and traditional communities controlled forests. At that time,

49

forests in Java were exploited for timber, especially teak, that was used as the raw

material for shipbuilding (Simon, 1994). Meanwhile, forests outside of Java,

especially in Lombok were communal property that could be accessed freely by

community members. The forests in Lombok were mainly used for subsistence until

the King of Bali conquered Lombok island in 1740 and took control of the forests

from the community (Van der Kraan, 1980, p. 8).

When the Dutch company Vereenigde Oost-Indische Compagnie (VOC)

colonized Indonesia in 1602, the exploitation of forests increased without any

rehabilitation efforts (Simon, 1994, p. 5). Intensive forest management practices

began in 1796 when the Dutch Government took over control from the VOC. In

1808, Herman Willem Daendels was appointed as Governor-General of the Dutch

East Indies government with the mission to secure a Dutch monopoly on teak

forests in Java, forest labour, and the shipbuilding industry (Peluso, 1992, p. 45).

Bae et al. (2014) notes that there was limited control by the Dutch

government over forests outside of Java, including in Lombok, due to on-going

authority held by the kings (raja) who occupied the region. In 1865, the Dutch

government introduced the national forest service (Jawatan Kehutanan) to secure

greater control of forests in Indonesia. The authority of the kings and communities

over forests was recognized through The Basic Agrarian Law of 1870 which was

introduced by the Dutch government. However, the rights of the kings and local

communities in managing the forests, was now under the jurisdiction of the Dutch

government22. The forests were claimed as colonial state land with local customary

management rights called swapraja and an official Dutch colonial supervisor

appointed for forest management called Pamong Praja (Bae et al., 2014). The

establishment of Jawatan Kehutanan and Pamong Praja resulted in the

subordination of swapraja’s authority over the forest.

In 1942, the Japanese came to what is now Indonesia and took over colonial

control from the Dutch government. During the Japanese invasion in 1942-1945,

there was severe damage to the forests due to an absence of maintenance (Simon,

22 Local communities were employed as timber cutters by the Dutch colonial government (Gultom

et al., 2013).

50

1994). Most forest management activities that had been established by the Dutch

government were discontinued in this period (Bae et al., 2014).

Until the beginning of Indonesian independence, the degradation of

Indonesia's forest continued, although forests were managed by the National Forest

Agency that had been inherited from the Dutch government. In Lombok, forests are

governed by Forest Services for Eastern Indonesia (Bae et al., 2014). Saman et al.

(1993) argues that in the early days of Indonesian independence, deforestation

occurred because of an imbalance between an increasing number of people and

limited job availability, especially in the agricultural sector. The lack of

employment in rural areas forced villagers to “steal” wood in the forest to meet their

economic needs which further contributed to forest destruction (Saman et al., 1993).

During the New Order Government period in Indonesia, the Basic Forestry

Law (UU 5/1967) was introduced. This law was used by the government to centrally

control all forests throughout the country (UU 5/1967 article 5). In this period,

massive deforestation still occurred due to exploitation of the forests as a main

source of national revenue (Brockhaus et al., 2012). This law defines four types of

forests with different functions and restrictions23. These are: protection forests,

production forests, conservation forests and recreational/tourism forests. The

function of protection forests is to support the regulation of water, to protect

watersheds and prevent flooding and erosion, and maintain soil fertility. Production

forests are specifically managed to extract timber. Meanwhile, conservation forests

are used for biodiversity conservation. Finally, tourism forests are forests that are

used for recreational purposes, especially for wildlife hunting (UU 5/1967 article

3).

23 Based on article No. 3 of UU 5/1967, forests in Indonesia were classified as Hutan Lindung

(Protected Forest), Hutan Produksi (Production Forest), Hutan Suaka Alam (Conservation Forest)

and Hutan Wisata (Tourism Forest). The classification was then revised in Indonesian forestry law

no 41/1999, that classified Indonesian forest into three classifications based on forest function,

which are Hutan Konservasi (Conservation Forest), Hutan Lindung (Protection Forest) and Hutan

Produksi (Production Forest).

51

In 1984, forest land use planning (Tata Guna Hutan Kesepakatan, TGHK)24

was introduced to facilitate forest rehabilitation. Forests were then re-classified by

their function, as (1) protection forests that function as watershed protection; (2)

conservation forests that function as protected areas for biodiversity; (3) limited

production forests, where logging is allowed with restrictions to reduce soil erosion;

(4) production forests for commercial logging where clear felling was permitted

(UU 41/99: article 2). Among the types of forests, conservation forests are the most

protected forest with restriction on collection of forest products (UU 18/2013 article

21) . However, forest products from protection forests and production forests can

be collected for economic benefit. In production forests, trees can be logged with

certain terms and conditions. In protected forest, logging is prohibited, but other

forest products such as non-timber forest products still can be collected.

Article 14 of the 1967 Forestry Law also regulated forest concessions in

Indonesia. According to the act, the forest concessions policy aimed to increase the

production and harvest of forest products in order to support national economic

development and the prosperity of the people. Permits for forests management

could be granted to national, regional and private enterprises. The implementation

of this law has triggered massive forest destruction in Indonesia since most of the

concessions were given to irresponsible private enterprises as part of a pervasive

political patronage system (Barber, 1998; McCarthy, J. F., 2000; McCarthy, JF et

al., 2012)

During the period of Suharto’s Presidency, forest concessions were

distributed to Suharto’s family and business partners that in many cases had links

with the military through corruption, cronyism and nepotism (Reed, 2006; Anderies

and Janssen, 2013). Timber mafias also emerged at regional levels that were usually

assisted by the military and police (Gultom et al., 2013). Since the 1970s,

concession holders ignored agreements to replant the forests causing massive forest

degradation (Saman et al., 1993). In the 1970s the annual deforestation rate was

recorded as being 300,000 hectares, which then increased by 100% in the early

24 TGHK is based on the provincial level stakeholders' agreement to determine forest function

(Menteri Kehutanan RI, 2009b).

52

1980s (Saman et al., 1993, p. 1). This privileged elite contributed to the

deforestation of more than 22 million hectares of forest between 1985 and 1997

(Reed, 2006, p. 74).

Other New Order era policies and legislation that have contributed to the

destruction of forests in Indonesia are Law number 1/1967 concerning foreign

investment, and Law number 6/1968 concerning domestic investment. Both of

these laws reflected Indonesia's intention to open up opportunities for investment

in natural resource extraction including forests exploitation. Investment in the

forestry sector increased with the introduction of Government Regulation number

21/1970 on Forests Concession Rights (Hak Pengusahaan Hutan, HPH) and

Forests Product Harvesting Rights (Hak Pemungutan Hasil Hutan, HHPH) (Saman

et al., 1993). The regulation mentions that HPH allows the right holder to exploit

the forests including logging, regeneration and forests preservation, processing and

marketing of forests products (PP 21/1970, article 1) .

In general, deforestation in Indonesia was caused by many things, including

the conversion of forests to industrial plantations for providing raw materials for

paper and pulp, palm oil, and by fires, mining and illegal logging activities (Ramli

and Ahmad, 1994; Nawir et al., 2008). Illegal logging was recorded as the dominant

factor causing deforestation (Gultom et al., 2013). This thesis argues that forest

resource management policies during the New Order provided the basis for the

emergence of alliances between the government and businessmen that constructed

'mafias' in the timber business which were primarily responsible for deforestation

in Indonesia.

During the New Order, as timber enterprises obtained concessions to forests

throughout Indonesia, local communities’ access to forests became increasingly

limited due to tight control by forest rangers (RA, community leader, interview,

27/2/2015). Two timber companies that held concession permits in Lombok,

namely PT Tambora Buana Lestari and PT Angkawijaya Raya Timber, have

contributed to forest degradation in the northern part of Lombok (Bae et al., 2014).

PT Angkawijaya Raya Timber obtained forest concessions in 1990 with an area of

10,000 hectares in the northern part of Lombok (interview with a local NGO

53

officer). Lack of forest rehabilitation lead to massive degradation that caused a

crisis of water and drought in surrounding villages. When forest exploitation

reached about 6,000 hectares, villagers in the surrounding area protested against the

companies. The companies were expelled from the forest in 1999 and their licences

cancelled following the collapse of the Suharto government. Following this, the

provincial forestry agency took control over the forest to be recovered (AN, NGO

officer, interview, 24/9/2015). Just prior to this, PT Tambora Buana Lestari had

obtained a concession in 1998, with a total size of 200 hectares also in northern

Lombok. As was the case with PT Angkawijaya, PT Tambora did not conduct

rehabilitation after the trees were logged. In 2000, the University of Mataram

proposed to local government to occupy the forest land that was exploited by PT

Tambora, to be used for research. However, since the program was not working as

designed, local people occupied this forest land and planted coffee and Albizia (AN,

NGO officer, interview, 24/9/2015).

After the collapse of Suharto’s New Order regime in 1998, central

government control over the forests diminished. This period marks the return of

local communities’ access to forests. In Lombok, villagers entered forests around

their village, logged the trees and occupied the forests in order to plant fruit trees

and other agricultural crops such as coffee and cocoa (RA, community leader,

interview, 27/2/2015). As a response to this encroachment, the government started

to encourage local participation in forest management (Bae et al., 2014) which

eventually developed into a Community Forestry management scheme.

Faced with strong public pressure, the Indonesian Ministry of Forestry

introduced Ministerial Decree number 677/Kpts-II/1998 as a guide for Community

Forestry management over designated areas known as Hutan Kemasyarakatan

(HKm). The first experiments with establishing HKm in Lombok that provide

formal recognition of the community’s involvement in forest management were

implemented in two forest sites, namely Santong and Sesaot (Bae et al., 2014).

During the transition from a centralized to decentralized Indonesian

government system, between 1998–2002, forest degradation continued to occur.

Massive encroachment, illegal logging and forest occupation reached their peak due

54

to political instability, lack of law enforcement, unclear sanctions for offenders and

an increase in the number of people dependent on forest land for agricultural

expansion (Gultom et al., 2013; Bae et al., 2014).

New policies and programs were designed to rehabilitate the forests and to

achieve more sustainable outcomes. In 1999, the Indonesian government introduced

Forestry Law number 41/1999 to replace the Basic Forestry Law of 1967. This law

determined the new status and function of Indonesian forests, including a revised

management system. The law recognised the right of local people to be involved in

forest management. After regional autonomy was implemented in 2001, practical

control over forests shifted from the central government to district governments

while central government maintained ultimate authority (Wollenberg et al., 2006;

Fauzi and Anna, 2013). The chronological story on forest management in Indonesia

is illustrated in figure 3.1.

55

Figure 3.1 Chronological Story of Indonesia Forest Governance

Source: constructed by the author

3.2. Community Forestry Management Scheme and Adat Rules

As explained in Chapter 2 of this thesis, Community Forestry (HKm, Hutan

Kemasyarakatan) is part of social forestry, which is a system of forest management

that pays attention to the benefits of forests for the livelihoods of forest dependent

communities (Simon, 1994). Under the HKm forest management scheme, forest

farmers are allowed to grow fruits and vegetables with commercial timber

plantations25. In some areas in Lombok, coffee, cocoa and bananas are planted

under trees intended for timber production. Studies show that community

involvement in the management of common pool resources such as forests has

25 The law defines 'forest' as an ecosystem in the form of landscape containing natural resources

dominated by trees (UU 41/99 article 1), and therefore includes commercial timber plantations.

56

brought about better outcomes in terms of resource sustainability (Agrawal and

Chhatre, 2006; Agarwal, 2009), due to the benefits that local people obtain from

these commons resources. In terms of securing forests from illegal logging, the

forest is likely to be better protected under this governance scheme. As one of the

community leaders in Sesaot village remarked, when local people are involved in

forest management, they will contribute to protecting the forest from timber theft

(AN, community leader, interview, 21/3/2015).

Most of the forests in Lombok that are located near villages are managed

through the HKm forest management system. Currently, there are 9,589.5 hectares

of official HKm forest in Lombok spread over four districts (see Table 3.1).

Table 3.1 Official HKm Forest Management in Lombok

District

HKm size

(hectare)

Hkm with legal

permit (hectare)

West Lombok 2,688 411

North Lombok 2,042 758

Central Lombok 2,180 1,809

East Lombok 2,680 420

TOTAL 9,590 3,398

Source: Dinas Kehutanan Provinsi NTB (2014)

However, as of 2015, legal permits from the Indonesian Ministry of Forestry

covered only 35% of the HKm forest in Lombok. The rest are still in the process of

application. Although forest governance is under the control of local government,

HKm legal permits are issued by the central government through the forestry

minister, with recommendations from the relevant district heads.

Traditional customary law (Adat) is applied in HKm forest governance as a

complementary system to state regulations on forestry. The vast majority of forest

farmers in Lombok are ethnic Sasak who are respectful of their adat and tend to

obey their adat more than state regulations (SA, forestry agency officer, interview,

May 2014). The sanctions for not following adat law are relatively “more painful”

than state law sanctions. One example of adat sanctions is isolation from the

community. With respect to forest governance, adat law regulates forest security

and the relationships between forest farmers. This collaborative approach between

57

adat and state law has support from the local government. The forestry agency and

village government were involved in the formal recognition of adat law and of the

application of adat sanctions to violation of customary regulations.

3.2.1. Case Study of Sesaot Community Forest

The Sesaot forest, one of the pilots for the HKm forest management system

in Lombok, is an example of a forest that is governed through the collaboration of

adat and state law. The Sesaot forest is located in the western part of Rinjani Forest

and administratively under West Lombok District (see figure 3.2).

Figure 3.2 Map of Sesaot Forest

Source: Google (2015a).

58

The total size of Sesaot forest is 5,950 hectares. This forest functions as a catchment

area for the water needs of the City of Mataram and western part of Lombok. Six

villages are located nearby the Sesaot forest, namely Sedau, Lebah Sempage,

Pakuan, Sesaot, Buwun Sejati and Batu Mekar with a total of 32,786 residents (see

table 3.2).

Table 3.2 Population of Villages around Sesaot Forest

Source: Pemerintah Kabupaten Lombok Barat (2014)

Nearly half of the villagers around Sesaot forest are farmers. The second largest

occupation for local people is as rural labourers. Those who work as labourers

typically do not own private land; they work as labourers on private farming land

and in HKm forest land. Meanwhile, only 3% of the villagers work as office

workers.

Figure 3.3 Villagers' Occupations in Surrounding Sesaot Forest

Source: Pemerintah Kabupaten Lombok Barat (2014)

Villages Population Total Number of

households Male Female

Sedau 2,267 2,374 4,641 1,659

Lebah Sempage 2,130 2,060 4,190 1,364

Pakuan 1,553 1,530 3,083 1,018

Sesaot 2,279 2,341 4,620 1,718

Buwun Sejati 1,913 1,875 3,788 1,339

Batu Mekar 6,214 6,250 12,464 3,088

TOTAL 16,356 16,430 32,786 10,186

59

Before 1982, Sesaot forest was classified as a production forest, and was

controlled by the Indonesian central government. A document from Forum

Kawasan, the Community Forest Farmer Group (CFFG) Forum in Sesaot, clarified

that there were three local timber companies that had obtained concession rights to

exploit Sesaot forest when the status of this forest was still a production forest in

1975 (Forum Kawasan, 2009). The companies were CV Bangun Karya, CV Unggul

Jaya and CV Cipta Karya. Each company obtained 100 hectares concession rights.

The companies in Sesaot were not connected to PT Tambora Buana Lestari and PT

Angkawijaya Raya Timber (the two companies that held large concession permits

in Lombok) since they only worked in the northern part of Rinjani Forest (AN,

NGO officer, interview, 22/9/2015).

The exploitation resulted in forest degradation since there were no efforts

from the companies to replant the forest (HA, villager, interview, 29/9/2015). Reed

(2006) notes that the timber companies in Sesaot cleared over 1300 hectares of the

forest. Weak law enforcement allowed them to clear several times the granted

concession size (Reed, 2006, p. 75). In the early 1980s, when the concession areas

of Sesaot forest had been degraded, the government took control over the forest

from the companies and conducted a rehabilitation project. Local people were

employed for the land rehabilitation and afforestation project in the production

forest. Local people who were involved did not receive cash for this work. Instead,

they were allowed to cultivate crops, including coffee that was grown under the

trees, in lieu of wages through an intercropping (tumpangsari) system (RA,

community leader, interview, 27/2/2015).

Due to the crucial function of Sesaot forest for water catchment, its status

was changed from production forest to protected forest by the Indonesian Ministry

of Agriculture in 1982 (Menteri Pertanian RI, 1982). Local people were no longer

allowed to access the forest after the status change. A one hundred metre boundary

or buffer zone was created between the forest and the surrounding villages. As

compensation for the loss of access to forests, each household in the surrounding

villages was granted rights to manage 0.25 hectare of land for cultivating coffee in

60

the buffer zone area, through the tumpangsari26 system (AM, CFFG leader,

interview, 8/6/2014).

However, the availability of land in the proposed buffer zone area was not

adequate for the number of villagers who needed access to land. Those who did not

obtain land, often enter the protected forest to cultivate coffee, outside the buffer

zone area (Konsepsi, 2009). As a response to this situation, the Governor of West

Nusa Tenggara province issued regulation number 140/1986 to provide a legal basis

for coffee cultivation in protected forest areas. This was then followed up with a

decision by the Head of the Forestry Agency of West Nusa Tenggara number

522.21/5358/1986 that allowed 1,632 hectares of the total Sesaot Forest area of

5,950 hectares to be used for coffee cultivation. The policy allowed people to utilize

the forest for coffee cultivation through a revenue sharing system, where 50 percent

of crops are allocated to the farmer and 50 percent to the government (Konsepsi,

2009). This policy also stipulated that farmers were not allowed to log the trees, to

build dwellings on the land, and to sell or to rent out the land.

In 1995, with NGO assistance and support from the provincial forestry

agency, a trial of the Community Forestry system was implemented on 25 hectares

of the Sesaot forest (Forum Kawasan, 2011b). After five years, an evaluation of the

project was conducted and it was concluded that the project had generated positive

outcomes for people’s livelihoods and for forest conservation. The HKm size was

then expanded to 236 hectares (Forum Kawasan, 2011b). A farmers’ group namely

Kelompok Mitra Pelestari Hutan, KMPH (Partner Group for Sustainable Forest),

was created to manage the HKm. The KMPH was legally recognized by the

Indonesian Ministry of Forestry a decade after its establishment (AR, CFFG leader,

interview, 25/5/2015).

Since the decentralization era that began in 1999, forest governance in

Sesaot has been fully controlled by the West Nusa Tenggara provincial government.

The governor introduced regulation number 522.21/457/Prov/2000 to increase

26 Tumpangsari is a planting method that allows forest farmer to cultivate crops on forestland

together with forest plantation (Rosyadi et al., 2005).

61

regional income from the utilization of naturally-logged27 trees in Sesaot forest.

However, this policy was abused by some local people. Standing trees were logged

and sold to timber mafias creating massive deforestation (AM, CFFG leader,

interview, 8/6/2014). Forum Kawasan (2011b) reported that about 1,800 hectares

of Sesaot forest was cleared at the time. After the lands were cleared, local people

occupied the forest to plant fruit trees such as durian, mangosteen, candlenut,

rambutan and banana. Currently, there are 4,331 households occupying the forest

land (Forum Kawasan, 2014).

In 2003, the Government of West Lombok introduced regional regulation

(Perda, Peraturan Daerah) number 10/2003 to regulate Community Forestry in this

district. Based on this regulation, local people are allowed to manage the occupied

forest through the HKm scheme. The HKm management rules require forest

farmers to plant and maintain timber trees along with crop trees. However, the HKm

status of most of this forest is not clear since only 411 hectares of 2688 hectares of

the forest lands that are managed by communities have yet been granted a legal

permit from the Ministry of Forestry28.

Those who have not yet obtained legal permits, are still allowed to work in

the forest. The recognition of their rights is indicated by their obligation to pay a

form of retribution to the district government. The forest users are obliged to pay

annual retribution of 120,000 rupiah (equal to US $10) per hectare of forest land

that they occupied. This retribution is called “non-timber forest product retribution”

and is used for regional government revenue. As the number of farmers is large and

difficult to coordinate, all farmers were grouped together into a community forest

27 Naturally-logged refers to a condition where the tree falls due to death or strong winds. 28 The reason for the discrepancy between the large proportion of Hkm covered by permits

noted above in Table 3.2 is that there are two types of HKm; the HKm program and non-

program. An Hkm program is issued and designed under a government project. Non-

program Hkm were not designed by the government. Instead, they originated as a result of

forest encroachments by villagers. The HKm program obtained more assistance and

support from the forestry agency which issued the permit (SN, local government officer,

interview, 4/6/2014). HKm in Sesaot is categorized as non-program that obtained less

assistance from forestry agency.

62

farmer group (CFFG) based on the location of the forestland they occupy. The

retribution is then collected through each group’s leader and paid to the district

forestry agency. As well as collecting retribution, these CFFGs are used to manage

the forest collectively. Most of the members come from the same ethnic group that

share the same customary traditions (adat) which are used to govern their forest

management activities. Adat (customary) rules in this case are called awiq-awiq.

There are four CFFGs, with a total membership of 4,331 people that govern

the Sesaot forest. Leaders of CFFGs are elected by the members and act as the

representatives of the CFFG in every meeting and in coordination with outside

parties. However, there is asymmetric information access between the members and

the committee. According to some farmers, not all information is communicated to

all members. Information is usually controlled by the leaders or members who have

a close relationship with the CFFG leaders. This could be due to a lack of regular

meetings in the CFFG. They conduct a meeting only when there is a special case to

be discussed, such as a violation of the awiq-awiq or a new government program or

policy in relation to community forest management.

Recognition by local government itself would be insufficient to provide a

legal basis for Community Forestry practice. An official permit such as that given

to the KMPH is needed by all of the forest farmers (Author’s survey data, 2015). In

2006, a forum of CFFGs, the Forum Kawasan Hutan Sesaot, was created to

advocate for legal permits. This forum acts as an umbrella organisation of CFFGs

in the six villages around the Sesaot forest. Forum Kawasan coordinates four

CFFGs - KMPH, Wana Dharma, Wana Abadi and Wana Lestari. At the time this

thesis was written, Forum Kawasan was still struggling to obtain these legal permits

with the assistance of some NGOs. The forum acts as a mediator to advocate for

changes of government policy, in case it is not in line with the communities’ needs.

By grouping together in one formal organization, people tend to have a

stronger bargaining position with outsiders. In the case of Community Forestry in

Sesaot forest, forest farmers became more powerful after they organised themselves

in Forum Kawasan. Forum Kawasan is the first party that should be consulted by

63

the government to advise on any new policy related to Sesaot forest governance.

Forum Kawasan has experienced success in advocating for the interests of the forest

farmers that are in conflict with local government policies. In 1999, the Forest

agency of West Nusa Tenggara Province was going to build a Botanical Park

(TAHURA) in Sesaot forest. People’s occupation and use of the forest would be

threatened if this policy were applied since only certain parts of the forest will be

allowed to be managed by the local community in that circumstance. Forum

Kawasan advocated to government to change the policy. As the result, the

TAHURA was shifted to another location outside the community forest (AM,

CFFG leader, interview, 8/6/2014).

The Forum Kawasan was also created for the purpose of coordination and

communication among the forest farmer groups in relation to forest management

matters. The specific aims relate to the issue of forest management rights, assistance

to CFFGs, forest protection from illegal logging and other causes of forest

destruction. Adat law (awiq-awiq) that is used to govern each CFFG was then

compiled as a single awiq-awiq to govern the Forum Kawasan and all of its

members. The forum’s mission is to develop a model of community based

sustainable forest management that features gender equity, welfare, and

employment of local wisdom in forest governance.

The Forum Kawasan includes two key roles namely Lokaq and Lang-lang.

The Lokaq works as a judge for dealing with any offenders or mismanagement of

the forest. Meanwhile, the Lang-lang has the responsibility to enforce the awiq-

awiq, to monitor the observance of awiq-awiq rules, and to catch offenders of the

awiq-awiq. Lokaq and Lang-lang are selected by the CFFG members by

considering their experience in community leadership and forest management;

these are usually persons that have charisma in the community. For example, the

current Lokaq used to be a hamlet leader in Sesaot.

3.2.2. Awiq-awiq and Sustainable Forest Management

The awiq-awiq was established by CFFG leaders that represent their

members, under the coordination of the Forum Kawasan. Village leaders and forest

64

agency officers were involved in the process of awiq-awiq determination through

several community meetings. The agreed awiq-awiq was then signed by all meeting

participants. Each CFFG leader was then responsible to introduce the awiq-awiq

regulations to their members. However, based on the author’s survey results, not all

CFFG members understand all aspects of the awiq-awiq. Respondents are only

familiar with the most common prohibited activity in the forest that can cause them

to lose their rights to manage the forest land, logging trees. The author’s survey

results indicate that 77% of respondents claim to obey awiq-awiq29. The main

reason they give for respecting the awiq-awiq is that the respondents are part of the

community and the rule is agreed together by the community members. If they do

not obey the community’s agreement, then they will be excluded from the

community, which can cause them to lose the rights to manage the Community

Forestry land. Among the respondents, no one admitted to disobeying the awiq-

awiq. However, 23% of respondents gave a neutral response, which several

indicated was because they did not clearly understand the awiq-awiq rule due to a

lack of explanation from the CFFG leader.

Figure 3.4 Farmers' Obedience to Awiq-awiq

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

The author’s survey results indicate that 76% of respondents agree that

awiq-awiq influences the forests condition. The main reason is that awiq-awiq

29 The question asked “Apakah Anda mentaati aturan adat (awiq-awiq) dalam pengelolaan

hutan?” (Do you obey the Awiq-awiq regulation regarding forest management?)

23%

64%

13%

Neutral Obey StronglyObey

65

accommodates a participative, forest guard system. All CFFG members are

required to guard their forest land from timber theft and to prevent illegal logging.

Figure 3.5 Farmers Opinion that the Awiq-awiq Influences Forest Condition

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

The principle features of the awiq-awiq include (Forum Kawasan, 2006):

a. The plantation composition on HKm land must be 30% native tree

species and 70% multi-purpose tree species (MPTS)30;

b. It is acknowledged that the forest land belongs to the state and cannot be

sold for any reason;

c. Raising livestock is not permitted in the forest area;

d. Logging trees in the forest area is prohibited;

e. Collecting non-timber forest products on forestland is allowed.

In the case of violations against the awiq-awiq, the following mechanisms

are then pursued. Verbal reprimands will be given for the first two infringements

by the CFFG leader. If a third infringement occurs, a written warning will be given.

If a further infringement occurs, the offenders will appear in an awiq-awiq court.

The court is led by the Lokaq and attended by Lang-lang, the chairmen of the CFFG,

the chairmen of Forum Kawasan, a village government officer and the forestry

30 MPTS (Multi-Purpose Tree Species) refers to tree species that have both ecological and economic

benefits. They function to protect the water catchment and can produce yields that have economic

benefits. Examples of MPTS are fruit trees, candlenut and palm trees (Menteri Kehutanan RI,

2014a).

1%

23%

72%

4%

Disagree Neutral Agree Stronglyagree

66

agency officer representative (AM, CFFG leader, interview, 8/6/2014). If the

offender is unable to comply with the awiq-awiq due to his failure to manage the

land according to regulations, the land management rights will be taken by the

group and will be given to other members according to need, and in accordance

with the decisions made through group deliberation.31

The penalty for illegal logging is the most significant. A single logged tree

has to be replaced with twenty new trees which must be managed properly until

they are fully grown. If the logged trees cause destruction on a neighbour’s land or

plantation, the loss has to be compensated in line with the value of what has been

destroyed. The same penalty is applied for a second offense. The third penalty is

the heaviest. If illegal logging is conducted for a third time, the offender will face

social sanctions, that is, isolation32 from the community and termination of his

rights to manage the HKm land (DA, CFFG Leader, interview, 8/6/2014).

During 2007-2008, two years after Forum Kawasan was established, four

illegal logging and mismanagement of Community Forestry land cases had been

solved through the awiq-awiq enforcement. In 2007, one farmer was isolated from

Sesaot village due to a case of crop theft (Forum Kawasan, 2006). Another example

of the awiq-awiq enforcement was an illegal logging case that occurred in 2011. A

person who logged trees in his HKm land lost his right to manage the HKm after

being judged by the lokaq in an adat court (Forum Kawasan, 2011a).

However, the enforcement of the awiq-awiq faces several constraints. For

example, family, friendship and neighbourhood relationship are sometimes

considered when enforcing the awiq-awiq. Often the offender is a family member

or a friend of the CFFG committee. In this situation, awiq-awiq enforcement would

have a destructive impact on personal relationships. In this case, the awiq-awiq is

only enforced if the violation caused massive loss for many people or if the violation

created negative impacts on the community. In addition, there is resentment from

the convicted person towards the awiq-awiq enforcers. For instance, crops on a

31 Each household is allowed to manage a maximum 0.25 hectares. 32 Isolation refers to exclusion from the right to receive services and help from the community.

including in ceremonial matters.

67

lokaq’s land were damaged by an unknown person, an incident which may have

been connected to the enforcement of awiq-awiq (DA, CFFG leader, interview, 8/6/

2014).

3.3. Role of the Outsider in Community Forestry Management

Self-governing institutions as suggested by Ostrom (2005) would likely be

insufficient to ensure the success of community governance of common pool

resources. Other factors that might be important and could influence how the

community governs the commons are the existence and character of property rights,

and assistance from outsiders. In the case of Community Forestry management,

property rights of the forest farmer are widely regarded as important to ensure long-

term access to the forest as an incentive for forest farmers to conduct sustainable

forest governance. Assistance from outside parties such as NGOs or government

agencies would be needed to monitor and advise in the form of a co-management

practice on the commons (Baland and Platteau, 1996, p. 334). This is consistent

with Ostrom’s approach (1990), to nested governance, which recognizes the

importance of checks and balances between levels of governance to support and

monitor local community management. The Indonesian Community Forestry

approach is similar to co-management arrangements commonly practiced world-

wide, that can also be called ‘joint management’, ‘adaptive management’,

‘collaborative management’, ‘community-based or local management’ and

‘indigenous management’ (Jentoft, 2003; Persoon et al., 2003; Borrini-Feyerabend

et al., 2004; Carlsson and Berkes, 2005; Berkes, 2009; Ulvevadet and Hausner,

2011). Co-management means, “the sharing of power, responsibilities and benefits

with respect to the management of natural resources (including their exploitation

and conservation) among government and individual or collective users” (Persoon

et al., 2003, p. 4).

This thesis will argue that community forest outcomes and management

patterns such as logging practices in Sesaot forest are correlated with the

involvement of outside parties such as NGO and government agencies that monitor

and influence the behaviour of farmers in managing community forestland. As

68

argued by Gibson et al. (2005), regular monitoring and sanctions for infringements

are necessary for better forest management. Since 1984, two environment-based

NGOs have assisted community forest farmer groups (CFFGs) in Sesaot, namely

the Consortium for Study and Participation Development (Konsorsium untuk Studi

dan Pengembangan Partisipasi, KONSEPSI) and World Wide Fund for Nature

(WWF). They provide capacity building, training and assistance for the CFFGs.

The author’s survey found that 85% of survey respondents acknowledge the

importance of NGOs for Community Forestry management (see figure 3.6). The

NGOs also helped the CFFGs to advocate for the legal permit for community forest

management to the Indonesian government through the Ministry of Forestry. For

instance, in 2009, their assistance resulted in the issue of legal permits for CFFGs

to officially manage 185 hectares community forest (Menteri Kehutanan RI,

2009a). However, of the 3000 hectares of Sesaot forests that are occupied by

farmers who seek to apply for Community Forestry status, only 235 hectares have

been legalized (AM, CFFG leader, interview, 8/6/2014).

Figure 3.6 Farmers’ Opinion on the Importance of NGO Involvement

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

The NGOs also played an important role in the construction of adat rules

for forest management. Together with local village government, the NGOs

facilitated meetings and gatherings among CFFGs to draft the awiq-awiq. Funding

from international donor agencies were also distributed to the CFFGs in the form

0.5%

15%

73%

12%

Notimportant Neutral Important Stronglyimportant

69

of various capacity building programs. In addition, NGOs played a significant role

in monitoring community observance of the Ministry's Community Forestry and

local adat rules.

After 2013, NGO assistance to CFFGs in Sesaot was reduced due to limited

funds (TN, NGO officer, interview, 13/06/2014). This led to a situation where

community forest farmers no longer strictly follow Community Forestry rules (AN,

community leader, interview, 21/03/2015). For instance, plantation composition in

the community forest was significantly different from Community Forestry

regulation requirements. Furthermore, the situation has become worse since CFFG

leaders were no longer active in coordinating meetings and gatherings.

Monitoring from outside parties such as NGOs and related government

agencies is clearly important in influencing the level of improvement of forest cover

due to regulation enforcement. Farmers tend to manage the community forest more

appropriately if there is control from other parties who have stronger bargaining

power than the farmer. Thus in the case of Community Forestry practice in Lombok,

this thesis argues that the self-governing community as theorized by Ostrom (1990)

will work more effectively with support from outsider parties such as NGOs and

government agencies who work with the community in managing forest resources.

Thus a co-management approach, which involves collaboration between a

community and NGOs or related government agencies, can contribute to an

alternative solution for more sustainable common pool resource governance.

3.4. Conclusion

Natural resources, including forests in Indonesia are controlled by central

and local governments. The governance of the forests can be granted to private

companies as well as to local communities. However, deforestation is a problem

regardless of the type of the forest management, as a lack of regulatory enforcement

enables exploitation without imposing stewardship responsibilities. Deforestation

in Indonesia, including in Lombok, was mainly triggered by forest concessions to

timber companies, which did not require them to rehabilitate after the forest had

70

been exploited33. In addition, forest degradation was caused by encroachment by

villagers due to political chaos and the lack of law enforcement especially after the

collapse of the New Order regime in 1998.

In an effort to replant the forest, local government in Lombok encourages

local communities surrounding the forest to manage the forest through a

Community Forestry scheme. Villagers that are granted the forest management

rights establish Community Forestry Farmer Groups (CFFG) and employ

customary law (adat regulations called awiq-awiq) to govern the CFFG in relation

to forest security and relationships among CFFG members. Awiq-awiq is applied

together with state regulations on forestry.

Despite the fact that the enforcement of the awiq-awiq faces several

constraints due to the close relationships among CFFG members, most CFFG

members obey the awiq-awiq since violation could cause them to lose their rights

to manage the forest. Since the awiq-awiq introduced a participative forest guardian

system, this may ultimately lead to sustainable Community Forestry management.

As argued by Gibson et al. (2005), rule enforcement by a local community in a

group is significantly correlated with a better forest condition, regardless of how

the group is formed and how dependent the group’s members are on the forest

resources.

Assistance and monitoring from outsiders is needed to support a co-

management forest governance system. Such an approach could achieve forest

conservation as well as poverty alleviation. The extent to which Community

Forestry impacts upon forest conservation and poverty alleviation will be analysed

in Chapters 5 and 6 respectively. The next chapter will discuss the integration of a

Payment for Ecosystem Service program into the Community Forestry management

system in Sesaot Forest.

33 During the New Order regime, the reafforestation funds, which were financed by a volume-based

levy paid by forest concessionaries, were supposed to be used to support forest restoration and

rehabilitation, but they had been corrupted and misused. The funds were used to promote the

development of industrial timber and pulpwood plantations companies with close ties to political

elites, and other politically favoured projects (McLeod, 2000; Barr et al., 2010; Barr and Sayer,

2012; Hidayat, 2016).

71

Chapter 4

Integrated Payment for Ecosystem Services and Community

Forestry Management

This chapter reviews the development of Payment for Ecosystem Services

(PES) in West Lombok. The PES program in West Lombok is integrated into the

Community Forestry program to support forest conservation and poverty reduction

in rural areas. This chapter focuses on the way that PES was introduced and

integrated with the Community Forestry program. This chapter will elaborate on

the potential for a new approach to PES systems that combines the mainstream

Coasean approach and the alternative Pigouvian approach.

This chapter is organized as follows: Section 4.1 summarizes the process of

PES development in West Lombok. Section 4.2 discusses the establishment of a

multi-stakeholders entity called IMP that acts as an intermediary organization to

run the PES program in West Lombok. Section 4.3 considers the demand side of

the PES program including the payment collection scheme. Section 4.4 discusses

the supply side of the PES program, including coverage of the scheme of payment

delivery to PES providers. Section 4.5 discusses the contracts that are used in the

PES system. Section 4.6 focuses on a new paradigm in the PES literature. Finally,

section 4.7 concludes this chapter.

4.1. Development of the PES Program in West Lombok

Forest management in Lombok, and throughout Indonesia, is controlled by

the central government through provincial and district forest agencies. However, as

discussed in the previous chapter, there are several reasons why deforestation is

continuing. One of the major reasons is illegal logging activities (Gultom et al.,

2013). An inadequate number of forest rangers in proportion to the total forest area

exacerbates this condition (MM, forest agency officer, interview, 06/06/2014).

Forest Watch Indonesia (FWI) notes that, as of 2009, Java and Bali-Nusa Tenggara

have lost 61% and 46% of their forest cover respectively (FWI/GFW, 2011, p. 15).

72

Forest Watch Indonesia also estimates that by 2030 forests in both regions will be

totally lost at current rates of deforestation.

The 137,431 hectares of forest in Mount Rinjani, the 3,726 metre volcano

that dominates Lombok Island, is a significant catchment area for the supply of

water to the island’s four million residents. More than 175 springs in Rinjani forest

flow into 10 main rivers on the island, which support the water needs of the island’s

households, agricultural land, and industries. However, the World Wide Fund for

Nature (WWF) reports that 5% of Rinjani forest is deforested annually, leading to

a critical water shortage in three quarters of the watershed (WWF, 2014).

Water provision in Lombok strongly depends on the governance of the

Rinjani forest (AZ, Water corporation officer, interview, 10/6/2014). Most of the

watersheds on the island located in the forest are managed through a Community

Forestry scheme, as discussed in Chapter three of this thesis. The Rinjani forest is

surrounded by 90 villages and populated by approximately 600,000 people (BPS,

2015a). One part of Rinjani forest that has a significant role in watershed

management in Lombok is Sesaot forest. Most of the villagers in the area are poor

and own little or no private land and are thus highly dependent upon the forest for

their livelihood. They collect food, fodder, fuel-wood and timber from the forest

and farm in protected forest areas. This reliance on the forest’s resources and

expansion of agriculture into the forest is threatening forest functions especially in

regard to watershed management.

Economic disparity between communities in rural areas and those who

consume water in urban areas evokes a conflict of interest related to forest

governance. The poor villagers who live surrounding Rinjani forest are encouraged

to take part in the protection of the forest, which contradicts their economic

activities in the forest. Meanwhile, the relatively prosperous communities in urban

areas need water and are thus dependent on good governance of the forest. Lack of

benefit for the villagers from water extraction for urban use conducted by the

District Water Company (Perusahaan Daerah Air Minum, PDAM), triggered a

protest from the villagers in 2004 (SA, forestry agency officer, interview, 5/6/2014).

73

The provincial government could address the conflict of interest by

implementing a conservation program that includes empowerment and concrete

livelihood benefits for villagers - a ‘win-win’ solution for both parties. This,

however, proved beyond the fiscal capacity of regional government. Limited

government budgets for forest conservation motivated several NGOs, including the

international conservation agency, World Wide Fund for Nature (WWF) and

Consortium for study and participation development (Konsorsium untuk Studi dan

Pengembangan Partisipasi, KONSEPSI), together with academics from Lombok,

to propose a scheme to encourage urban water consumers to participate in collective

contributions to fund the conservation of these water catchment areas. This is to be

achieved via a Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) program (RH, NGO officer,

and PB, academic, interview, 6/6/2014, and 7/6/2014).

The PES program in Lombok was developed following an economic

valuation study of Mount Rinjani conducted by the WWF in 2003. The results of

the study indicated that the economic value of the mountain’s resources such as

water, timber, agriculture, tourism, and erosion control, were around 5.18 billion

rupiah (approximately US$388,597)34 per year (WWF, 2014). Ironically, as

mentioned above, approximately 87% of people around the Rinjani forest are below

the poverty line (WWF, 2014) and their livelihoods are heavily dependent on the

forest.

The Rinjani forest is divided into four classifications based on its function:

conservation, protected, limited production and permanent production (see Chapter

three for details of these classifications). Figure 4.1 presents the spatial distribution

of this forest based on the classifications. Six forest management units, called

Kesatuan Pengelolaan Hutan (KPH), control these forests regionally (see Table 4.1

for details of forest size in each KPH). The forest in KPH Rinjani Barat is the most

significant area since it is responsible for the water supply in the city of Mataram

and West Lombok District, the most densely populated region of the island and the

centre of government as well as business in the province. The forest also supplies

34 All currency conversions in this thesis are based on 2017 exchange rate, US$1 = Rp 13,300.

74

water for irrigation of agricultural land in Central Lombok and East Lombok

districts.

Figure 4.1 Map of Forest Area in Lombok Island

Source: Dinas Kehutanan Provinsi NTB (2013b).

75

Table 4.1 Forest Area in Lombok Classified by Management Unit

Source: Dinas Kehutanan Provinsi NTB (2013a)

Villagers’ activities in the water catchment area would undoubtedly

influence the forest's capability to supply water. A PES program was then promoted

as a response to the threat of water shortages. The PES program goals are 1) to

maintain water resource quality and quantity, 2) to improve the welfare of poor

people around the forests and 3) to conserve the forest resources (Sekretariat Daerah

Lombok Barat, 2007).

A Willingness to Pay (WTP) survey was conducted by KONSEPSI, the

Water corporation (PDAM) and academics in 2003. This survey was designed to

determine the capacity of Lombok’s residents to contribute to a water resources

conservation fund. PDAM customers were involved as respondents of the survey.

Based on a tradition that Lombok’s people are accustomed to donate for funding

public assets such as a worship center, the survey asked whether they are willing to

contribute for environmental restoration and, if so, how much they were willing to

pay (AZ, water corporation officer, interview, 10/6/2014). The result was that 83%

of the household respondents and 55% of corporate respondents were willing to

Name of Forest

Management Unit

Type of Forest

Protected

Forest

(hectare)

Production

Forest

(hectare)

Conservation

Forest

(hectare)

Total

(hectare)

KPH Rinjani Barat

28,911.00

12,072.00

40,983.00

KPH Rinjani Timur

31,987.00

5,602.00

37,589.00

KPH Mareje-

Aikbukak

12,562.00

4,967.00

17,529.00

KPH Pelangan

8,890.00

10,746.00

19,636.00

KPH TNGR

41,330.00

41,330.00

KPH Lombok

6,668.29

6,668.29

Total

82,350.00

33,387.00

47,998.29

163,735.29

Rinjani Area Only

73,460.00

22,641.00

41,330.00

137,431.00

76

contribute between Rp 500 and Rp 5,000 per month to the conservation of water

resources in the upstream area (KONSEPSI, 2003)35.

Following the WTP study’s results, a workshop on PES development was

organized in the same year. The West Lombok Forestry Agency, WWF, the Natural

Resources Conservation Unit (Balai Konservasi Sumber Daya Alam, BKSDA) and

Mount Rinjani National Park Authority (Balai Taman Nasional Gunung Rinjani,

BTNGR) were involved in the workshop. Further discussions with a broader group

for drafting local regulations on PES were then conducted as a follow-up to the

workshop. The details of the PES development stages are illustrated in Figure 4.2.

Between 2004 and 2005, the ecosystem services concept was introduced in

23 villages in the city of Mataram and West Lombok district. At the same time,

institutional strengthening of upstream communities through community

organizing and capacity-building was also conducted. In 2005, a team was formed

to draft regional regulations for establishment of a PES scheme. Furthermore,

widespread dissemination of information on ecosystem service initiatives was

organized, locally and nationally. In 2006, a declaration of agreement for PES was

signed by relevant stakeholders including the local government of West Lombok

and the city of Mataram, the Local Council of West Lombok and the city of

Mataram, PDAM, and other private sector and government agencies, as well as

upstream villagers, Department for International Development (DFID), WWF,

KONSEPSI, and the University of Mataram. Following this, a trial of PES

collection from PDAM customers in East Mataram, a sub-district in the city of

Mataram, was carried out and achieved positive responses from the participants

(IMP, 2014a).

35 However, the survey cannot be statistically validated due to the unavailability of the original

report.

77

Figure 4.2 Timeline of PES Development in Lombok

Source: IMP and WWF (2013, p. 12), translated from Bahasa Indonesia by the

author.

To ensure that all ecosystem resource users contribute, a compulsory

payment method would be required through government intervention enforced by

regional regulation. The West Lombok Regional Government Regulation

(Peraturan Daerah, Perda) number 4/2007 was enacted in 2007 as the fundamental

basis of the official PES program. This policy regulates the scheme of payment for

78

any individual and commercial use of water resources, excluding ground water. The

payment would be used for environmental protection especially for conservation of

the water catchment area.

However, two years after the Perda 4/2007 was enacted, it had still not been

implemented. Although the program received positive responses when the trial was

conducted, resistance arose from those who argued that people should not have to

pay for the provision of ecosystem services. To address this problem, advocacy was

carried out by IMP through the PDAM consumers’ association as the representative

of all water consumers. Water consumers were educated about the importance of

forests for maintaining a sustainable water supply. To avoid more resistance, water

quantity and quality were enhanced by developing a new source for water

extraction. PDAM were allowed by the West Lombok forest agency to access

another spring in a new location in order to increase the water volume. This effort

was conducted in order to demonstrate that a sustainable water supply is the result

of good forest governance (SA, forestry agency officer, interview, 7/6/2014). To

improve awareness of people on the importance of PES development, campaigns

on PES were mounted through various media, as well as through several discussion

forums.

Perda 4/2007 was finally implemented in 2009, four years after the PES

scheme was introduced. PDAM customers started to pay a PES contribution of Rp

1,000 and 2,000 per month (approximately US$ 0.08 and US$ 0.15) for domestic

and industrial water users respectively, in addition to their water bill. Initially, since

PDAM in West Lombok covers two districts, West Lombok and the city of

Mataram, PES was implemented in both districts36. Around 70% of water resources

from West Lombok are utilized by urban residents and industries in the city of

Mataram. However, the PES regulation could not be applied to the city of

Mataram’s jurisdiction, as the legal basis for collecting money from PDAM

36 The water authority in West Lombok and the city of Mataram is controlled by a district

government owned company, PDAM Giri Menang. Since the city of Mataram and West Lombok

used to be a single district (separated in 2009), PDAM Giri Menang is owned by the two districts,

with share proportions of 65% for West Lombok and 35% for the city of Mataram (PDAM Giri

Menang, 2013). As a government company, later on, PDAM Giri Menang was appointed to act as

the collector of PES payments along with the water bill since 2007.

79

consumers was produced by the West Lombok government. As a result, PES

contributions from Mataram residents have been discontinued since 2012. As

compensation, a Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) was negotiated between

the city of Mataram Mayor and the West Lombok Regent by which the city of

Mataram government agreed to contribute a lump sum as its contribution to PES in

West Lombok. The MoU has been in operation since 2013 (MN, member of IMP,

interview, 5/6/2014).

4.2. Intermediary Organization for the PES Program

Since it is challenging to equalize the interests of heterogeneous sellers and

buyers of ecosystem services, a trusted independent organization that takes a role

as mediator and manager of the PES scheme is needed to oversee the program. As

argued by Huber-Stearns et al. (2013), such an intermediary organization is

important for effective PES application. One key success factor of PES programs

in several countries, among other things, is the involvement of such intermediary

institutions (Vatn, 2010; Sattler et al., 2013). Intermediary organization plays a

significant role as agents of information exchange between related stakeholders,

program designers, through representation and mediation among buyers, sellers and

other participants, as well as providing administration and project coordination

(Huber-Stearns et al., 2013). They also may act to control, monitor and verify

ecosystem services delivery (Sattler et al., 2013).

For this purpose, Institusi Multi Pihak (IMP) was formed (WK, member of

IMP, interview, 11/6/2014). The IMP is officially working in coordination with the

West Lombok government that established the institution. The West Lombok

Regent’s decision letter (Keputusan Bupati) number 1072/207/Dishut/2009

appointed the IMP as an independent organization to manage the PES program.

The IMP consists of representatives from relevant government departments,

business, civil society, NGOs, academia and the PDAM consumer association, who

are chosen by the regent based on their experiences and strategic positions.

Unfortunately, multi stakeholder membership of IMP sometimes makes it difficult

to achieve a consensus (AP, forestry agency officer, interview, 4/6/2014). For

80

example, the current director of IMP also holds a position as a head of the

Environmental Governance Agency. This double position, which also applies to

other IMP members, could lead to conflicts of interest. Yet, their expertise is

considered an important contribution to the role.

The size of IMP membership that consists of 19 people on the steering and

supervisory board and 18 people on the management board is relatively large. The

steering and supervisory board includes the regent, 12 heads of related government

agencies, two heads of NGOs, university representatives, the head of PDAM, a

local community leader, and the upstream community representative. The large

number of IMP members leads to high operational costs (IJ, regional assembly

member, interview, 12/6/2014). About 20% percent of the ecosystem services fund,

is used for the operational costs of IMP (IMP, 2010, 2012, 2014b). Table 4.2

presents an example of PES fund allocation managed by IMP in 2013. Operational

costs would probably be reduced if the members of IMP were limited to those who

play a significant role in the PES program.

Table 4.2 PES Fund Allocation

Expenditures

Amount

(Rupiah)

Proportion

(%)

Payment to CFFG for conservation fund

346,267,500.00 73.23

Honoraria

83,760,000.00 17.71

Meeting and discussion

4,500,000.00 0.95

Publication

2,500,000.00 0.53

Monitoring and evaluation

5,040,000.00 1.07

CFFG assistance and identification

8,960,000.00 1.89

PES program campaign

3,000,000.00 0.63

CFFG Verification

3,750,000.00 0.79

Office facilities and stationaries

15,070,000.00 3.19

Total

472,847,500.00 100.00

Source: IMP (2014b)

81

It is a challenge for the IMP to obtain public trust in relation to fund

management (WK, member of IMP, FGD, 4/6/2014). To convince the public that

the collected funds will be used appropriately for water conservation is not an easy

matter. Efforts have been undertaken including a massive campaign through mass

media and direct meetings with communities, to build public trust. To maintain

accountability, an annual audited financial report is published through local media

(see Appendixes 4.1). On the other side, IMP also has to be able to persuade

upstream communities that the PES payment must be used for forest and watershed

conservation. Participatory monitoring and evaluation in upstream areas is

conducted in coordination with the CFFG forum and village governments, to ensure

that PES terms and conditions have been followed.

Capacity building, cooperation and assistance for IMP members are still

required. For instance, IMP lacks the capability to develop tools to measure the

ecological impact of the PES program (WK, member of IMP, FGD, 4/6/2014).

Support from WWF has been obtained especially to monitor the water supply.

WWF provides an automatic water level recorder (AWLR) that was installed near

the PES target location to measure the monthly water debit extracted from the

forest. Since this recorder had only been installed a few months before the fieldwork

for this thesis, it is still being evaluated and results of that evaluation have not yet

been published.

The major problem of this scheme is low participation from the private

sector and this is beyond the control of IMP; government intervention would be

needed to regulate in this area. As stated by the chair of IMP, “we need to expand

public trust to wider communities” (HM, member of IMP, FGD, 4/6/2014). A

workshop was conducted in May 2015 that aimed to encourage broader industry

participation in the PES scheme. However, most of the participants came from

related government agencies and very few participants from industry. The

workshop concluded that a further meeting will need to be conducted with more

participants from industries in order to set up a system of industry contributions to

the PES fund.

82

4.3. Demand Side of the PES Program

Setting up a system to collect the payments was another challenge for the

introduction of the PES scheme in Lombok. Fauzi and Anna (2013) argue that fiscal

regulations for water charges in Indonesia are conflicting. Law no 28/2009 states

that the government is able to charge for surface water and deep water, while Law

no 7/2004 stipulates that water used for basic needs and agricultural purposes is in

principle free of charge (Fauzi and Anna, 2013). There are two official schemes for

collecting money from the public in Indonesia - through tax and levy - the levy

scheme was chosen for PES payments in Lombok and PDAM was appointed to act

as the collector of the payment.

The rate of payment collected from water users was designed to be a flat fee

across all households. Every household pays Rp 1,000 per month (US $.08)

regardless of their water consumption. Thus, there is no distinction between the rich

and the poor; all consumers pay the same amount regardless of their economic

condition. This situation contradicts the criteria of fairness since people who

consume high volumes of water are paying the same as those who consume less,

and neither need nor disincentives to waste were central considerations in designing

the scheme. The purpose of this flat rate is to simplify the scheme and to reduce

resistance from all water users (PB, academics, interview, 7/6/2014). The initial

aim of the program was to build awareness among urban consumers about the

necessity for forest protection. It is possible, however, to increase the rate in the

future once this program is well established (WK, member of IMP, FGD, 4/6/2014).

Under this PES scheme, industries pay double the rate of households

regardless of how much water they use. This situation is inequitable, since big

industries such as hotels that use a lot of water are paying the same amount as small

shops, and are paying relatively little considering their water usage compared to

household consumers. The application of the Lombok PES scheme would be more

efficient if the amount charged was determined in accordance with the volume of

water used (PB, academic, interview, 7/6/2014). Ninety four percent of the total

water supply from PDAM is consumed by households, while industries only

consumed six percent (PDAM Giri Menang, 2016). Instead of using water from

83

PDAM, the vast majority of industries in Lombok extract water directly from

underground water sources. The amount of water extracted from underground by

industries in West Lombok is estimated at around 251,500 cubic meters a year

(Dinas Pertambangan dan Energi Kabupaten Lombok Barat, 2014) which is about

65% of the amount accessed through PDAM that reaches around 384,000 cubic

meters a year (PDAM Giri Menang, 2014). Despite the fact that underground water

provision is also influenced by the existence of forests on the island, industries

refuse to pay the PES levy due to an underground water extraction tax that has been

charged by the local government (district/kabupaten).

Figure 4.3 presents water usage by PDAM consumers in West Lombok. It

demonstrates that water use in the region increased significantly in the last six years.

The increase of water consumption was primarily caused by the expansion of

PDAM services. In 2006, PDAM services only covered around 60% of residents in

the city of Mataram and around 30% of residents in West Lombok (AZ, water

corporation officer, interview, 27/6/2015). In the period of six years since, the

services increased significantly due to increased demand from established residents

who are aware of the benefit of using clean piped water instead of well water. This

also indicates that the economic condition of urban consumers has improved (AZ,

water corporation officer, interview, 27/6/2015). In addition, the increase of new

water installments was caused by the expansion of residential areas due to migration

to the city. The increase in water consumption was later followed by an increase in

PES funding, as demonstrated in Figure 4.4.

84

Figure 4.3 PDAM Water Use in West Lombok, 2009-2013

Source: PDAM Giri Menang (2016).

Figure 4.4 PES Payments from Water Consumers in West Lombok, 2009–2015

Source: PDAM Giri Menang (2014, 2016).

4.4. Supply Side of the PES Program

As described in the previous section, the PES system in Lombok considers

water consumers in the city of Mataram and West Lombok district as the ecosystem

service buyers. Since the PES program was designed to reduce poverty as well as

to conserve the forest catchment, a logical means to achieve this goal is by

integrating PES into the Community Forestry program. Thus, the CFFGs who

85

manage the forest in the water catchment area are identified as the ecosystem

service providers.

The PES fund was distributed to CFFGs for funding conservation programs

in the water catchment area in Rinjani forest. Most CFFG members are poor as

indicated by the average expenditure per family member of $1.7 per day, which is

below the World Bank standard37. Based on interviews with farmers, they have

difficulty buying seeds for planting on community forest land since the price of

seed costs approximately 2.5% of their income (survey data, 2015. See Appendixes

6.2 for detailed survey results). Consequently, the concept of the payment for

ecosystem services program gained positive responses from CFFGs. Figure 4.5

illustrates the distribution area of PES programs in villages around the Sesaot forest

catchment.

The CFFGs were encouraged to apply for PES funds voluntarily by

submitting working proposals to IMP. The submitted proposal was then verified by

IMP who assessed the condition of the groups, including their management, their

activities, and whether the groups were well established or had just been formed to

obtain funding from the PES program. The most important aspect of the verification

was the significance of the project to water catchment conservation. Priorities were

given to those that were going to conserve degraded forestland and significantly

influence the condition of the water catchment (MF, IMP officer, interview,

4/5/2015). For this purpose, the IMP verification team traveled to the CFFG’s

secretariat as well as to the conservation site to assess and clarify the proposal. After

the proposal was determined to be technically and administratively feasible and

eligible to be funded, a Memorandum of Understanding (MoU) was then issued and

signed by the CFFG leader and the IMP director. As a contract between the CFFG

and IMP, the MoU contains agreement by both parties to conduct specified

conservation projects in a certain period of time. Later in this chapter, we will

consider the contract in more detail.

37 The poverty line for developing countries is currently set at $2 per day (World Bank Group,

2012).

86

Figure 4.5 Map of PES Program Location in Lombok

Source: IMP (2014b).

87

The payment delivery scheme for PES can be cash and/or in-kind. In-kind

payments are usually delivered through rural development programs, enabling the

benefits to be distributed, not only for the immediate ecosystem services providers,

but also for the wider benefit of resource dependent communities. Compared to in-

kind payments, however, cash payment is generally regarded as more effective to

increase welfare since cash payment allows the beneficiary to use the money

immediately for their financial needs (Tschakert, 2007). However, it can be seen as

a form of ‘bribery’ by wealthier communities for biodiversity protection (Ferraro

and Kiss, 2002). It is also possible that the payment will be spent on activities which

are not related to ecosystem services provision, and that in turn may result in failure

of the PES program to achieve its ecological goals.

The application of the PES program in Lombok is adapted to suit the

objectives of the Community Forestry program. Since CFFGs plant multipurpose

tree species (MPTS) such as durian, mangosteen and candlenut, the PES payment

is then used for funding MPTS and timber tree planting in the Community Forestry

location.

In the five years since PES in Lombok was implemented, Rp 1,051,810,500

(equal to approximately US$ 78,900) has been delivered to 22 CFFGs (IMP, 2010,

2011, 2012, 2013b, 2014b). Details of PES payments to CFFGs is presented in table

4.1. The money was used to plant trees on 405 hectares38 of degraded forestland in

West Lombok (HM, FGD, 4/6/2014). Although a modest start, at least 2.5% of

16,363 hectares of degraded forest in West Lombok has been restored (IMP,

2013a). The ecological and economic goals of PES would undoubtedly be more

substantial in further years after the trees have grown and produce yields.

38 Ideally, 400 seeds are needed in every one-hectare costing about $348 (Author’s survey data,

2015).

88

Table 4.3 Distribution of PES Funding to CFFGs, 2010 - 2014

Year CFFG Village

Amount

(Rupiah)

2010 Lebah Suren Sedau 83,115,000

Mule Paice Batu Mekar 50,000,000

Forum Ranget Suranadi 58,884,000

Sub Total 191,999,000

2011 Darma Lestari Sesaot 25,000,000

Sanggar Muda Tani Mandiri Batu Mekar 38,500,000

Emas Hijau Langko, Lingsar 35,000,000

Sari Mandiri Dasan Geria, Lingsar 39,000,000

Sub Total 137,500,000

2012 Ale-ale Sesaot 33,750,000

Giri Madia Giri Madia, Lingsar 37,500,000

Buwun Mas Buwun Sejati 15,000,000

Sutra Alam Langko, Lingsar 15,000,000

Lebah Suren Sedau 15,000,000

Sub Total 116,250,000

2013 Blok Slepang Sesaot 45,787,500

KMPH Pakuan 55,950,000

Blok Gontoran Sesaot 45,850,000

Petung Lestari Buwun Sejati 46,190,000

Bensue Lestari satu Buwun Sejati 46,190,000

Lebah Suren Sedau 59,662,500

Masyarakat Peduli Lingkungan Sedau 45,637,500

Sub Total 345,267,500

2014 Harapan Baru Sedau 50,205,000

Belantara Kreatif Sesaot 62,995,000

Pecing Lestari Buwun Sejati 48,020,000

Kepundung Lestari Buwun Sejati 49,452,500

Selen Aik Sedau 50,121,500

Sub Total 260,794,000

Grand Total39 1,051,810,500

Source: IMP (2010, 2011, 2012, 2013b, 2014b).

Payments to CFFGs as the PES providers are made in cash as transfers based

on their accepted proposals. The spending of this money is subject to the West

Lombok government policy that requires the money to be used for activities related

39 PES funding per capita during this period amounted to about Rp 2,200,000 (US$165), which is

considered to be relatively low as cash incentive.

89

to conservation and/or economic empowerment. Although the payment form is

cash, the money cannot be spent on other purposes that are not stated in the

proposal. For example, in 2011, the Kelompok Dharma Lestari CFFG, received Rp

25,000,000 (approximately US$ 1,875), which was used to conserve 50 hectares of

degraded forest land (Darma Lestari, 2011). Sixty seven percent of the fund was

allocated to pay labor for tree planting and maintenance wages that can be a direct

financial benefit of the PES for the farmer40.

The PES payments are set up on a system of terms-based withdrawals. The

first term will be allocated for initial project implementation and the next term will

be paid contingent upon the results of evaluation and monitoring by the IMP.

Monitoring and evaluation of the PES program in the upstream area is conducted

soon after the program has been started and again after it has completed. Monitoring

was done through direct visits to the PES target location to see if the tree planting

took place but no transect studies to guarantee the percentages.

Village heads also play a substantial role in PES implementation. Before a

CFFG’s proposal is submitted to the IMP, it must be approved by the village head.

Similarly, the payment withdrawal request has to be verified and approved by the

relevant village head. After the request has been approved by the IMP, the money

is ready to be withdrawn from the appointed bank. Although it seems a rather

bureaucratic process, this procedure is important as a control scheme to avoid abuse

of the money by CFFGs.

In addition to conservation purposes, as stated in PES regulations, the PES

funds are to be utilized for economic empowerment related activities. So far,

economic development activities that have been funded by PES include non-timber

forest product processing such as coffee, palm sugar and fruit-based foods, as well

as provision of micro credit. However, since 2013 priority is given to conservation

related activities. Meanwhile, economic development activities, especially micro

credit, were temporarily terminated due to a case of nonperforming loans and “elite

40 Not all CFFG provides planting wage. Most CFFG used the money that was supposed to be for

planting wage, to buy more seeds.

90

capture” (MF, IMP member, interview, 22/4/2015). The loans were distributed only

to a small number of people with links with the CFFGs’ leaders, such as their close

family, and were not available to broader CFFGs members (MF, member of IMP,

interview, 22/4/2015). There were no penalties imposed on the offending CFFG

leaders.

Ironically, PES funds, which are supposed to be used for conservation

related activities, are also used as source of revenue for local government. As

stipulated in Perda 4/2007, a quarter of the PES fund is allocated for regional

government revenue and three quarters of the collected funds are allocated to

activities related to the ecosystem services provision, such as forest conservation or

local people’s economic empowerment initiatives, and also for the operational costs

of the IMP. On the other hand, a large number of CFFGs that are potential

participants in the PES scheme are still on a waiting list since only around 10

CFFGs can be involved in any one year. Ideally all of the funds should be allocated

to water conservation related activities since the source of funds is the water

consumers. Thus, the more CFFG groups can be involved, the more water

catchment area can be conserved. As of 2014, only 12% of total CFFG members

have been included in the PES program (IMP, 2010, 2011, 2012, 2013b, 2014b).

4.5. Contracts under the PES System

A direct contract between the ecosystem services providers and buyers in a

PES system is important for its sustainability as well as to control its

implementation. A contract is required due to asymmetric information between

ecosystem services providers and sellers that can cause high implementation costs

and limit the effectiveness of PES (Ferraro, 2008). Asymmetric information can be

found in the form of hidden actions and hidden information. Service providers such

as the land owner or manager commonly have better information than services

buyers. They dominate the information related to the service conditions and the cost

of producing such services. Hidden information may come up when negotiating the

contract (Ferraro, 2008) and can be used in the bargaining process. Meanwhile,

91

hidden action (moral hazard41) may arise after the contract has been negotiated

(Ferraro, 2008, p. 811). A moral hazard could be any kind of act which contradicts

the rules stated in the contract; for example, farmers log the trees that are supposed

to be maintained for water provision. As the monitoring of contract compliance is

costly, ecosystem services buyers are rarely able to verify whether the condition has

been met by services providers as outlined in the contract. This may lead the

ecosystem services providers avoiding their contractual responsibilities (Ferraro,

2008).

Organising a contract between service providers and users in the PES

program in West Lombok is not easy due to the huge numbers of people in both

parties who are taking part in this system. Nevertheless, even without a formal

direct contract between providers and users, PES in West Lombok can work well

due to the intermediary role of the IMP. The IMP negotiates an agreement between

PDAM consumers on the demand side and CFFGs who provide ecosystem services

on the supply side. In this way, the IMP is also able to reduce asymmetric

information among providers and users, which could result in greater efficiency. To

reduce monitoring costs, integration of monitoring systems with mentoring and a

participative action plan, are incorporated into the agreement (WK, member of

IMP, interview, 11/6/2014).

However, there is no clear time frame stated in the contract. In addition,

there is no clear sanction for either CFFGs or water consumers if they fail to meet

obligations as stated in each contract. For instance, on the supply side, if the planted

trees that were funded from the PES were not growing, or if the trees were logged,

no action was required related to the CFFG’s responsibility for the failure. Although

in the long run, they will not have access to the PES funding, lack of clear reward

and punishment in the contract may lead to inefficiency and ineffectiveness in PES

implementation since it is possible for the service providers to break the rules of the

41 Moral Hazard is defined as a situation “where one party to a transactions may undertake certain

actions that (a) affect the other party’s valuation of the transaction but that (b) the second party

cannot monitor/enforce perfectly” (Kreps, 1990, p. 447).

92

game without any obligation to repay the PES fund. It seems that the contract needs

to be revised to make it fair for both parties.

On the demand side, water consumers as the ecosystem service buyers are

unable to avoid their obligation to pay the PES levy since it is embedded within

their water bills. They also cannot formally claim for any reduction of the quality

or quantity of the water. If they do not pay the water bill, which include the PES

levy, then their water service will be terminated by PDAM.

Another PES contract was signed by the West Lombok Regent and the

Mayor of the city of Mataram, whereby the West Lombok government acts as

provider of the ecosystem services and the city of Mataram government acts as the

consumer. As mentioned before, the city of Mataram residents consume water that

is supplied from West Lombok’s forests. West Lombok’s policies that govern the

PES program are unable to be applied across jurisdictions, such as the city of

Mataram. The contract between two governments requires that the city of Mataram

government allocates an annual contribution fund towards the PES program in West

Lombok (RH, NGO officer, interview, 6/6/2014). Since 69% of water from PDAM

is utilized in the city of Mataram (PDAM Giri Menang, 2016), such a payment

arrangement is essential to a fair distribution of water resources. However, there is

no clear amount of the contribution fund stated in the contract. The amount of the

contribution is decided annually based on the budget capability of the city of

Mataram and calculated based on the number of water consumers in the city (MF,

member of IMP, interview, 22/4/2015). In addition, there is no clear statement that

the city of Mataram residents will be charged by the government regarding the PES

levy. Instead, the government will allocate a conservation fund for this purpose in

their annual budget.

Since the amount and basis of the contribution is not clearly stated on the

contract42, it can lead to moral hazard by the city of Mataram government. It is

42 The contract states that West Lombok and the City of Mataram Governments agree to facilitate

and provide funding for environmental conservation, economic empowerment and strengthen of

communities around the watershed. However, There is no specific amount stated on the contract

(Bupati Lombok Barat and Walikota Mataram, 2011).

93

possible that they may argue to reduce or avoid payment for their contribution due

to budget capability. In fact, water from West Lombok is consumed continuously

by the city of Mataram’s residents regardless of the amount of contribution for the

conservation fund from their government. As mentioned above, 70% water supply

from West Lombok is consumed by the city of Mataram residents. In this case, a

free rider problem occurs as water consumers in the city of Mataram do not pay the

PES levy. The City of Mataram government could issue a similar PES regulation

to collect money from water consumers for the PES contribution to solve this

problem.

4.6. New Paradigm on PES Literature

Compared to other PES practices in Indonesia, to date the PES program in

West Lombok is the only one which is implemented through a mandatory system

(Heyde et al., 2012). The vast majority of PES schemes that have been introduced

in other parts of Indonesia, such as PES in Lake Toba and Sumberjaya in Sumatera,

PES in Cidanau, Citarum and Brantas in Java, and PES in Kapuas Hulu in

Kalimantan, employ voluntary-based PES systems. Most of the buyers come from

the private sector and the sellers are farmers located in the areas where the

ecosystem services are sourced. Both parties enter a contract to enable voluntary

transactions of certain ecosystem services (mostly related to water quantity and

quality). A similar situation can be found in the practice of PES around the world.

Most of the PES programs are based on voluntary systems where the contract is

either directly set up between sellers and providers or where an intermediary

organization is used (Pagiola, 2008; Clements et al., 2010; Matthew et al., 2010).

Pirard’s (2012) analysis of PES implementation through a public policy

approach considers the West Lombok PES program as a case study. He argues that

the West Lombok PES policy design is atypical compared to common PES

practices elsewhere with respect to the method of payment and the extent of

compulsory public participation (Pirard, 2012, p. 28). Commonly, most PES

practices employed Coasean economics theory that emphasizes a voluntary or

market-based transaction of ecosystem services. This ensures the payment meets

the minimum opportunity costs of the ecosystem services provider and may be less

94

than, or equal to, the Willingness to Pay (WTP) of the buyers (Wunder, 2005; Engel

et al., 2008).

The PES program in West Lombok has been officially mandated in Perda

4/2007 which is in line with Pigouvian economic theory. According to this

regulation, anyone who utilizes the specified ecosystem services is obliged to pay

the PES levy. This compulsory approach cannot meet the voluntary transaction

criteria of PES that is proposed by Wunder (2005)43 that has been a mainstream

assumption in much of the PES literature. A new expanded concept of PES is

required to encompass mandatory PES approaches that employ public policy in

their implementation (Pirard, 2012).

In the case of PES in West Lombok, there is a component of hybridity that

combines Coasean and Pigouvian economic theory. Pigouvian theory is applied on

the demand side to enforce compulsory participation from water consumers to pay

for the PES levy. On the supply side, Coasean theory is used to encourage voluntary

participation from forest farmers to enrol in the PES program. This hybrid PES

system leads to a new policy paradigm that combines elements of both a voluntary

market-based and mandatory policy-based system.

4.7. Conclusion

The Rinjani forest is significant for water catchment on Lombok Island.

Community forest farmer groups (CFFGs) who manage the Rinjani forest through

a Community Forestry management scheme help protect the water provision that is

supplied from the forest for household, industrial and agricultural needs on the

island. As a response to the critical importance of the water catchment area, and

considering the condition of inadequate government funding for forest protection,

43 Wunder (2005, p. 9) uses five criteria to describe the PES principles “A PES is: (1) a voluntary

transaction where (2) a well-defined ecosystem service (or a land-use likely to secure that service)

(3) is being ‘bought’ by a (minimum one) ecosystem services buyer (4) from a (minimum one)

ecosystem services provider (5) if and only if the ecosystem services provider secures the ecosystem

services provision (conditionality).”

95

Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) has been developed and integrated into the

Community Forestry management in West Lombok.

PES in Lombok aims to encourage broader public participation in forest

management through contributions to a conservation fund. Due to the scale and

complexity of the watershed conservation issue, a mandatory system, enforced by

government regulation, rather than the voluntary model was developed on the

demand side. The policy requires that all private and commercial water consumers

through the PDAM are obliged to pay a monthly PES levy. The money is then

allocated to related CFFGs as funding for conservation of the degraded water

catchment area. In this regard, the PES system established conditions for

collaboration between urban water consumers and rural forest users in conservation

of the water catchment area.

The Coasean approach, as a mainstream ecosystem economic perspective

on PES theory (Wunder, 2005), suggests that PES systems should be voluntary-

based and that ecosystem services provision should be transacted in a market. But

PES in Lombok diverges from this mainstream PES literature. The PES program in

West Lombok is a hybrid PES system that employs both Coasean and Pigouvian

economic theory. On the demand side, Pigouvian economic theory that considers

government intervention through a PES regulation is applied. Meanwhile, Coasean

economic theory is applied on the supply side to encourage forest farmer groups to

become voluntarily involved in the PES program. The atypical system of PES in

Lombok (Pirard, 2012) leads to a new paradigm in the PES literature, where PES is

not only voluntary–market based, but also mandatory, public-policy based - a

hybrid of voluntary and mandatory schemes. The PES definition that is often used

in the PES literature, which only considers voluntary market-based transaction

criteria, needs to be reviewed.

Ferraro (2008) suggests that a PES system needs a contractual agreement

between the suppliers and consumers of ecosystem services in order to make it

work. However, without a direct contract between the seller and the buyer of

ecosystem services, PES in West Lombok has been relatively effective due to the

existence of the Institusi Multi Pihak (IMP), a government partner organization that

96

governs the PES program. The IMP acts as a bridge to connect upstream and

downstream communities in a single system of water catchment protection. The

hybrid type of PES program in Lombok is a mutually beneficial compensating

mechanism for upstream and downstream communities. PES is used as a tool for

responsible sharing between urban water consumers and rural forest users to protect

the water catchment area for mutual benefit, with the IMP as a mediator. But, the

effectiveness of this approach compared to other schemes remains in need of further

research.

The flat PES levy that is collected from PDAM consumers leads to a

problem of inequity since small consumers are paying the same amount as larger

ones regardless the amount of water they consume. This flat fee problem can be

solved through designing a fair mechanism, such as a proportional PES levy that

depends upon the amount of water consumed by the PES buyers. Since industries

pay a very small amount of PES levy and not all industries contribute in the PES

program, the local government could modify the PES regulation to encourage

industries to participate in the PES program or restrict/prohibit water extraction and

divert a proportion of the PES to local government in lieu of current taxes.

However, a free rider problem exists in this PES system as the residents of

the city of Mataram, who also consume water from West Lombok, do not contribute

to pay for the PES fund. The government of the city of Mataram should introduce

a similar regulation as applied in West Lombok to encourage compulsory

participation of the residents to pay for the PES levy. The more contributors, the

more the PES levy could deliver broader benefits for forest conservation and

poverty alleviation. The impact of this hybrid PES and Community Forestry

program on forest conservation and poverty alleviation will be discussed in the next

chapters.

97

Chapter 5

Community Forestry, Payment for Ecosystem Services and Forest

Conservation

This chapter will analyse the impacts of integrated Community Forestry and

Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) programs on forest conservation. Forest

conservation in this thesis refers to any efforts aimed at forest protection or

restoration, including replanting forests that were destroyed before the Community

Forestry program was established in the area. Forest cover data will be used to

measure forest conservation. This chapter will also report my survey results, in

particular the forest farmers’ experiences on Community Forestry management in

regard to conservation activities and outcomes.

The structure of this chapter will be as follows: Section 5.1 reviews the

Community Forestry development and its impact on forest conservation in

Lombok; Section 5.2 elaborates on the survey data regarding forest farmers’

experiences and views on the impact of the Community Forestry program on forest

conservation. The contributions of PES programs to Community Forestry

development and thus the impact on forest conservation is the focus of section 5.3.

Finally, section 5.4 concludes this chapter.

5.1. Community Forestry Development and Forest Conservation

The ecological benefits of forests are multiple, in particular with respect to

ecosystem services such as watershed protection, oxygen production and carbon

sequestration. The forest’s ability to produce such ecosystem services is dependent

on how good forest management is. Other things being equal, the better the forest

management, the better the ecological benefits it produces. There are several

different schemes for forest management. These include state forestry management,

industrial or private forestry management, and community forestry management.

Community Forestry is a system of community based natural resources governance

(Krogman and Beckley, 2002), and is increasingly preferred by policy makers and

98

scholars, rather than full central state control or privatization through market

mechanisms (Agrawal, 2001a; Agrawal and Ostrom, 2001; Ostrom, 2005; Sikor,

2006; Warren and McCarthy, 2009).

The devolution of forest management to local people through Community

Forestry had resulted in both positive and negative ecological outcomes. With their

knowledge and experience of the forest and soil conditions, local people are often

able to manage the forest more appropriately (Conklin, 1954; Edmonds, 2002;

Gibson et al., 2005; Agrawal and Chhatre, 2006). Studies on Community Forestry’s

impact in many countries indicate that community involvement in forest

governance can generate positive outcomes in terms of reducing deforestation and

increasing biodiversity protection (Klooster and Masera, 2000; Araujo et al., 2009;

Barsimantov and Kendall, 2012; Pirard and Belna, 2012; Birch et al., 2014). Most

studies on Community Forestry emphasize the importance of recognition of

property rights that influence people’s behaviour towards forest governance

practices (Agrawal and Ostrom, 2001), which then impact on forest cover,

deforestation rates and biodiversity conservation (Araujo et al., 2009; Birch et al.,

2014). Lessons learnt from a number of studies indicate that Community Forestry

was able to contribute to reducing deforestation. Klooster and Masera (2000)

argued that a Community Forestry program implemented in Mexico was able to

avoid deforestation and increase forest cover. Araujo et al. (2009) conclude that a

Community Forestry program that provided security of property rights has been

beneficial in reducing deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon. Also, Birch et al.

(2014) found that secure use-rights upon community forest in Nepal lead to

biodiversity conservation and ecosystem services protection.

However, Community Forestry programs may also produce negative

impacts on forest cover in the short term. For instance, people may overuse the

forest resource if they treat access to the forest as a private property right.

Community forest management rights can be an incentive for local people to clear

the community forest, although the forest cover condition may improve in the long-

term (Pirard and Belna, 2012). Community forest management rights may also have

negative impacts on other forests outside the community forest area. This has been

99

seen in the case of Community Forestry practices in Ethiopia (Beyene and Koch,

2013). The villagers in this case had used wood for cooking collected from a local

forest, which was then converted to community forest. The use of fuel wood that

was collected from the surrounding natural forest increased when the Community

Forestry system was introduced. Forest farmers tended to maintain their community

forest and collect fuel wood in open access forest outside of the community forest

location (Beyene and Koch, 2013).

With regard to explaining Community Forestry practice, approaches to

common pool resource governance by Hardin (1968) and Ostrom (1999) have been

discussed in Chapter 2 of this thesis. This thesis attempts to elaborate on the theory

of common pool resource governance by considering a case study of Community

Forestry practice that is integrated with a Payment for Ecosystem Service (PES)

program.

Referring to Chapter 3 and 4 of this thesis, Community Forestry and

Payment for Ecosystem Services are two different policy approaches aimed at

effective and sustainable forest governance. Community Forestry is mainly

introduced to encourage local people who benefit from the existence of the forest,

to participate in sustainable forest management (Krogman and Beckley, 2002). PES

mainly aims to provide financial incentives for people to change their behaviour in

relation to resource governance, including forests (Wunder, 2005). Both approaches

are instruments to conserve natural resources as well as to alleviate poverty in rural

areas (Pagiola et al., 2005; Sunderlin, William D., 2006; Tschakert, 2007; Stringer,

R. et al., 2008; Dhakal et al., 2012; Stringer, L. C. et al., 2012; Bremer et al., 2014).

Therefore, it is hypothesized that a combination of these two approaches could

generate better outcomes in terms of sustainable forest management.

Following Ostrom (1990), this study emphasizes the role of local

institutions in common pool resource management. Local communities who depend

on a certain common resource for their livelihood and have some autonomy to

access and manage the common resource tend to achieve better outcomes from

common resource governance (Ostrom et al., 1999). The community often share

their experiences, values and norms, which are used to develop rules to govern the

100

common resource. Effective monitoring and appropriate sanctions would then be

required to achieve sustainable use of the common resource (Gibson et al., 2005).

As described in Chapter 3, Community Forestry was initially introduced in

Sesaot forest in Lombok, Indonesia in 1998. The local community were involved

in a reforestation project after the forest had been harvested by timber companies

and the rights to manage the forest were devolved to them through a Community

Forestry program. Before Community Forestry began, the forest area was mainly

covered by bush without many trees due to massive logging (BK and RE,

community’s leaders, interviews, 8/6/2014 and 27/2/2015). In that period, local

trees endemic to Lombok were very rare in that location. People replanted the land

with crops that provided economic benefit in a relatively short period, such as

coffee, cocoa, corn, and bananas, together with Albizia trees, supplied by the local

forestry agency. However, the Albizia trees were not sufficient to meet the

necessary tree coverage required to replenish the degraded land. The villagers were

then instructed by the local government through the forest agency to plant Multi-

Purpose Tree Species (MPTS), which are mainly fruit trees such as durian,

rambutan, mangosteen and candlenut as the complement to the Albizia (RE,

villagers, interview, 27/02/2015). MPTS are a variety of trees that can provide

economic benefits from their crops, as well as supporting conservation goals

through their ecological function.

Since Community Forestry management had been established in forest areas

that had already been destroyed, the practice of Community Forestry did contribute

to the replanting of the forest. The consequent plantation composition follows

multiple layers. At the first layer, tall trees such as Albizia, candlenut and durian

were planted. At the second layer, medium size trees were planted under the first

layer, for example rambutan and mangosteen. Cocoa and coffee were planted as the

third layer. Under the cocoa and coffee trees, vegetables were planted. This multiple

layer plantation technique (tumpang sari)44 was initiated by a villager who was the

leader of a forest farmer group. This technique was then followed by the other

44 Tumpang sari is a customary practice and is an example of the application of traditional

knowledge to efficient land use.

101

members and became a common technique in Community Forestry management in

Sesaot (RE, forest farmer leader, interview, 27/02/2015). However, the size of the

allocated forest for community management was not in balance with the needs of

local people on the land. Only 236 hectares were officially allocated by the forest

agency for some 3000 families who need land. This condition led to the illegal

expansion of Community Forestry into the protected core forest zone, by the

villagers without approval from the district forest agency.

In the short term, the enlargement of the Community Forestry area was

responsible for forest destruction since people occupied forest in the core zone area

that was still in good condition. As described in Chapter 3, encroachment on the

forest by local people occurred due to an imbalance between the size of the

permitted area and the number of people who needed land. People logged the forest

trees and then replanted with crops and MPTS. The land clearing caused a decrease

in forest cover at the time. However, forest cover began to increase after about five

years of Community Forestry (RE, forest farmer leader, interview, 27/02/2015).

Data from Global Forest Watch clarifies that in 2003, five years after the massive

encroachment, Sesaot forest cover increased by 616 hectares over a space that

included the Community Forestry area (GFW, 2016). However, forest lost was

recorded as 6.58 hectares in the same period for the same location (GFW, 2016, see

Appendix 5.1).

Forest restoration requires a relatively long period of time with high costs,

which were not comparable to the more immediate economic benefits that a forest

farmer obtained from crops and MPTS. Thus, from a purely ecological perspective,

Community Forestry “failed” to maintain forest health in the short term. Economic

benefits from crops that were harvested from the community forest alone would not

be in balance with the costs of conservation (AZ, water corporation officer,

interview, 10/6/2014). However, in the long term, Community Forestry could

provide balanced benefits for the local economy and ecology when mature MPTS

produce substantial sustainable yields.

102

In the case of Community Forestry practice in Sesaot, the impact of this kind

of forest management on forest conservation is varied, depending on the phase.

Based on the author’s interviews, surveys, secondary data and field visits, the

community forest development process can be divided into three phases that the

author labels rehabilitation, encroachment, and new forest vegetation phases. In the

rehabilitation phase, the forest condition had been degraded due to several reasons

including harvesting by timber companies and illegal logging. The degraded lands

were then replanted by the local community as “instructed” by the local government

through a conservation program, which was later developed as Community

Forestry. In this phase, Community Forestry contributed to forest rehabilitation

since people occupied degraded land and replanted the land with crops and MPTS.

Thus, the degraded land started to recover and forest cover began to increase once

the MPTS grew.

The second phase was the encroachment phase. During this phase, the forest

farmers began to obtain economic benefits from crops and MPTS. Other people in

the village saw the “success” of the forest farmers and were attracted to become

forest farmers themselves. However, as the degraded land has been fully occupied

by the initial group of farmers, new farmers began encroaching upon the core zone

of the forest that was still in good condition and well covered. People cut down

trees illegally and replaced the endemic species with crops and MPTS. This illegal

action caused a massive loss of forest cover, totalling 3,857 hectares (Forum

Kawasan, 2011b). The forest cover, however, did improve again and eventually

recovered, after the new trees planted had grown and matured which took around

five to ten years depending on the tree species.

The third phase was the new forest vegetation phase. During the third phase,

the forest condition improved as the new plantations reached their viable size to be

harvested and the forest cover reached a similar condition to its original state.

Although it can be argued that some of the forest’s ecological functions are similar

to those provided in its original condition, from an ecological perspective, the

replacement of native tree species caused a loss of biodiversity since some local

endemic species are rarely found in the community forest areas. In the absence of

103

strong law enforcement, this cycle could continue to occur as the population

increases until the entire forest has been converted to Community Forestry and no

core forest zone remains. Thus, strong control from government may be needed to

prevent massive forest conversion.

Whether Community Forestry can make a balanced contribution to both

ecological conservation and economic development in Sesaot forest or not, is an

open question since an economic orientation still dominates the Community

Forestry practice on this site. Forest farmers tend to be focussed on economic

benefits more than the ecological ones. Not all forest farmers fully complied with

the Community Forestry regulations. For instance, the Community Forestry rules

require that plantation composition must be 60% conservation trees and 40% MPTS

(Menteri Kehutanan RI, 2008). In the process of Community Forestry development

in Sesaot, the community forest farmer group (CFFG) negotiated with the local

forestry agency to set the plantation composition at 70% MPTS and 30%

conservation trees (Konsepsi, 2009). After the agreement was evaluated and gained

90% success in increasing forest cover (Konsepsi, 2009), the plantation

composition has continued as a guideline for all community forest farmers and is

now incorporated into adat law. However, the actual condition of plantation

composition on the study site averages 21% conservation trees and 79% MPTS

(Author’s survey, 2015), indicating that even the negotiated modification of

Community Forestry rules is not complied with by all forest farmers.

There were no official sanctions applied to the farmers who did not meet the

composition requirement. Whereas, it is clearly stated in the local adat law codes

that farmers who cannot meet 70% MPTS and 30% conservation trees rule will be

considered as having failed to manage the community forest properly (Forum

Kawasan, 2006). Thus the community forest land will be taken over by the CFFG

to be managed by another villager who has not been a community forest farmer. In

this situation, neither state nor adat law enforcement can be considered fully

effective.

A forest officer suggested that the plantation composition that does not meet

the regulation or the negotiated agreement is not a significant problem since MPTS

can also produce some of the same ecological benefits as officially designated

104

conservation trees and can be more sustainable compared to non MPTS (SA, forest

agency officer, interview, 5/6/2014), because of their greater economic benefit to

local communities. MPTS provides economic benefits which is an incentive for the

farmer to maintain this kind of tree. Since MPTS can be categorized as shade trees,

they are also ecologically beneficial in term of water supply, erosion control,

climate change mitigation, increased carbon storage and reduced greenhouse gas

emissions (Tscharntke et al., 2011). An interview with a forest farmer explicitly

indicated that forest farmers prefer MPTS rather than other trees because of the

expectation of income generation from the fruits. Also, it is likely that MPTS is

more secure from timber theft (AN, forest farmer, interview, 21/3/2015). However,

MPTS do not have the same biodiversity functions that were provided by original

forest trees. Thus how effective the Community Forestry program is for forest

conservation remains an open question.

5.2. Forest Farmers’ Experiences and Views on the Impact of the Community

Forestry Program on Forest Conservation

Forest cover is dependent on the behaviour of forest farmers in relation to

logging trees. As mentioned in Chapter 1, surveys were conducted with 200

community forest farmers to capture the farmers’ behaviour in forest management

including their experience in logging trees. This study found that of the 200 forest

farmers who were surveyed, 64% of respondents replied that they had never logged

trees before the Community Forestry program was established, while 36% had

logged trees mainly for domestic uses such as for firewood and material to build a

house (see figure 5.1). Those who never logged trees explained that this was due to

the degraded land condition largely covered by bush, without many trees. Those

who sometimes or often logged trees admitted that they logged some trees due to a

need for space on the land to plant MPTS and crops. Some endemic trees were

replaced with MPTS that were able to provide more economic benefits for them.

Farmers who logged trees were those who encroached on forest land that had not

been formally allocated by government to be managed as community forest. They

did this because they believed they had the same rights to community forest land as

had been officially granted by government to the other forest farmers.

105

This study has tried to capture the logging practice of the Sesaot forest

farmers post establishment of the Community Forestry in the case study location.

Ninety-five percent of survey respondents explained that they no longer engage in

logging activities since most of the trees in the community forest are categorized as

MPTS that could provide economic benefits (see figure 5.2). A statistical analysis

(Paired t test) was conducted to clarify this finding. The statistics analysis result

indicated that the probability of differences between logging practice conducted by

the farmers before and after the establishment of the Community Forestry program

is significant with the P value of 0.00 (see Appendix 5.2).

Some farmers also indicated that they were afraid of the adat rules that have

been agreed to by their CFFG. If they log trees, they face the risk of losing their

rights to manage the community forest land which could threaten their livelihoods.

On the other hand, at least some forest farmers disobey the adat rules in regards to

the plantation composition discussed above, without sanction to date. The current

effectiveness of adat law is thus, again, questionable.

Figure 5.1 Farmers’ Acknowledging Involvement in Timber Theft Prior to

Establishment of the Community Forestry Program

Source: Author's survey, 2015; n = 200

106

Figure 5.2 Farmers’ Acknowledging Involvement in Timber Theft Post

Establishment of the Community Forestry Program

Source: Author's survey, 2015; n= 200

Although the community forest farmers themselves may not all log the trees,

others can steal the trees when the forest is not attended. 9% of survey respondents

had experienced their trees being stolen (see figure 5.3). The stolen trees are mainly

categorized as non-MPTS. Thus the MPTS are more secure than non-MPTS trees

and can be more sustainable. Considering the unreliability of answers regarding the

respondents’ behavior in relation to illegal activities such as logging trees, as an

alternative approach, the Author questioned respondents' knowledge about other

people’s logging activities. 76% of survey respondents claimed that other people

never engaged in such illegal activities, while 24% of respondents admitted that

other people do log trees (see figure 5.4).

Figure 5.3 Farmers’ Experience of Timber Theft in Their Community Forest

Source: Author's survey, 2015; n = 200

107

Figure 5.4 Farmers’ Knowledge of Timber Theft by Others Including Inside and

Outside the Community Forest

Source: Author's survey, 2015; n = 200

The Community Forestry program also provides participative forest

guardianship as a responsibility tied to the property rights held by the farmers. Since

the farmers realize that they have property rights upon the Community Forestry

land, they have an incentive to maintain their tree plantings and prevent them from

destruction. In general, Community Forestry programs have contributed to

increasing the number of trees in the forest. 71% of survey respondents said that the

number of trees on their Community Forestry land increased after they took over

land management. However, 7% of survey respondents said that the number of trees

decreased as they replaced endemic trees with crops such as coffee, cocoa, and

banana due to the immediate economic benefits (see figure 5.5). This explains the

statements of some farmers that they often log trees on their community forest land.

When a question was asked regarding the impact of the Community Forestry

program on reducing the deforestation rate, most of the respondents (85%) agreed

that Community Forestry is able to reduce deforestation and none of them disagreed

(see figure 5.6).

108

Figure 5.5 Farmers’ Assessment of Changes in the Number of Trees in the

Community Forest

Source Author's survey, 2015; n = 200

Figure 5.6 Farmers’ Opinion on the Impact of Community Forestry on Reducing

Deforestation

Source: Author's survey, 2015; n = 200

When the fieldwork for this study was conducted in early 2015, the community

forest condition was relatively good with an average forest cover of 65% (Author’s

survey, 2015). There is no official data from relevant government offices such as

the forestry agency to verify this survey result. As an alternative, satellite data from

Google and Global Forest Watch45 were used. Satellite imagery data provided by

Google verifies that almost all of the Sesaot community forest area was well

45 Global Forest Watch is an interactive forest monitoring system that allows users to draw and

calculate a certain forest cover loss/gain in a particular area. The data is produced from combination

of a cutting edge algorithm technology that employs the most current and high-level IT development

with satellite technology, cloud computing and scientific modelling to monitor tree cover growth

and loss (http://www.globalforestwatch.org).

109

covered by trees as presented in figure 5.8. Unfortunately, the satellite imagery from

Google is unable to provide an exact measure of forest cover. Data from Global

Forest Watch also provides evidence that there was a significant change in rate of

forest cover lost in the period of 2002 - 2014, as can be seen in figure 5.7. It was

recorded that annual forest cover loss in Sesaot Community Forest decreased

significantly from 92 hectares in 2002 to below 20 hectares after 2003. The huge

forest cover loss before 2003 was caused by massive illegal logging due to political

instability after the Indonesian reformation era, as discussed in Chapter 3 of this

thesis.

Figure 5.7 Forest Cover Loss in Sesaot Forest, 2002 – 2014

Source: Global Forest Watch, www.globalforestwatch.org, accessed on 15/2/2015.

In late 2015, a massive reduction in forest cover due to illegal logging

practices again took place in Sesaot Forest. Illegal logging occurred in a new

location, in the core forest zone adjacent to the Community Forestry location (see

figure 5.8). The illegal logging resulted in the loss of about 300 hectares of forest

cover in the forest in only three weeks (AM, community leader, interview,

3/11/2015).

110

A community leader in the village argued that the offender, who is not a

member of any of the CFFGs, came from a nearby village (AM, community leader,

interview, 3/11/2015). The CFFG members could not do anything in regards to this

encroachment. They tend to protect only the Community Forestry land that they are

occupying and ignore any destruction outside of their land. The community leaders

asserted that this destruction occurred because of a lack of law enforcement of

illegal logging practices by government. A year before, the person who led the

illegal logging had been reported for the same case by the community to the local

forest agency. However, no rule enforcement was applied. This lax enforcement

then attracted other people to conduct illegal logging in other forest sites (AM,

community leader, interview, 3/11/2015). Adat law has proved difficult to enforce

on illegal logging activities due to social conflict that often emerges, followed by

threats and intimidation (DA, community leader, interview, 8/6/2014). A forest

agency officer explained that they could not control the forest properly due to an

insufficient number of forest rangers to guard the forest (MM, forest agency officer,

interview, 3/11/2015).

Corruption and collusion are undoubtedly another factor that cause these

illegal activities, which are common in the timber industry in Indonesia, and were

exacerbated after the collapse of the New Order regime (Smith et al., 2003). Dietz

et al. (2002) argued that corrupt forest officials have opportunities to receive bribes

from local forest users wishing to exploit the forest officially owned by the state.

As investigated by Gultom et al. (2013), illegal logging in Sesaot Forest has

involved collusion among villagers, local businessmen, members of the police,

army and state officers. The “timber mafia” has a strong network and is difficult to

break up (Gultom et al., 2013). Trees were logged in the night time and then the

timbers were transported from the forest to the villages using motorbikes that have

been designed to carry timbers (AN, community leader, interview, 21/03/2015).

The villagers involved in illegal logging were aware that their actions were against

the law and that there is risk of a jail sentence if they were caught and of social

punishment from the community (Gultom et al., 2013). However, poverty pushes

them to rely on illegal logging for their livelihood (Author’s survey, 2015).

111

Figure 5.8 Satellite Photo of Sesaot Community Forestry and Illegal Logging

Location in 2015

Source: Google (2015b), https://earth.google.com, retrieved on 26 July 2016

This situation illustrates the three phases of Community Forestry

development as discussed above. It is possible that the forest lands that were cleared

will be converted to community forest in the upcoming period, and enlarge the area

of the current community forest.

5.3. Payment for Ecosystem Services Program and Forest Conservation

Theory suggests that Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) can be used as

an incentive for forest farmers to manage forests properly (Wunder, 2005; Pagiola,

2006). The main goal of PES in West Lombok is to provide incentives for forest

farmers to manage the forest appropriately in order to protect water provision from

112

Sesaot forest. Bennett et al. (2011) argue that PES programs will be more capable

of achieving the program’s goals if they suit the needs of the targeted ecosystem

services providers. For example, in the case of China’s Sloping Land Conversion

Program, the program’s outcome was more effective because farmers were allowed

to select the kind of trees to be planted, although the farmers tended to create more

“economic” than “ecological” forests (Bennett et al., 2011). In the case of the PES

program in Lombok, it will be argued that the introduction of the PES scheme,

which is integrated into the Community Forestry program in Sesaot forest, could

deliver significant positive impacts on forest conservation by increasing the

incentives to protect forest cover.

The introduction of the PES program in West Lombok has helped forest

farmers to obtain free seeds. Farmers implied that they could not afford to buy seeds

using their income. The survey data indicates that the price of one seed is around

Rp 11,600 (US$ 0.87) which is less than 1% of farmers’ average monthly earning

from their forest products (Author’s survey, 2015). At the same time, the

government does not have sufficient budget for tree planting. For example, in 2012,

a very limited forest restoration budget of only US$ 4 per hectare (Neraca, 2013)

was annually allocated by the Indonesian government in their National Budget

Planning (Anggaran Pendapatan dan Belanja Negara, APBN). Only a small

amount of funding for forest restoration in a limited number of locations was

allocated through a Special Allocation Fund (Dana Alokasi Khusus, DAK) scheme

from central government. This indicates that the Indonesian forestry department

was having difficulty in managing forests properly. For this reason, the potential

for funding re-afforestation and forest conservation from the PES program was an

attractive option.

Since the seeds supplied from the PES program are mainly MPTS, it can be

an incentive for farmers to manage forests properly since they will obtain economic

benefits from the seeds in the future. Thus managing trees for economic benefits

also supports ecological benefits. However, compared to the original forest

condition, the current forest cover is dominated by MPTS and very few endemic

forest tree species are left. The forest farmers in Sesaot tend to plant more MPTS

113

than endemic trees as MPTS provides more short-term economic benefit to them

(Author’s survey, 2015) because forest farmers can obtain fruits from these kinds

of trees. Nonetheless, MPTS are ecologically beneficial for maintaining water

resources as well as other ecological forest functions such as carbon sequestration,

and protection from flood. Thus planting MPTS could be advantageous for both the

economy and ecology. However, the replacement of tree species that occurred in

native forest has not been good from the perspective of biodiversity since endemic

trees were replaced with MPTS that should not be planted in protection forest (AZ,

water utility company officer, interview, 10/6/2014).

The PES program was readily accepted by the forest farmers (SA, forest

agency officer, interview, 5/6/2014). Furthermore, MPTS trees will be maintained

by the forest farmers due to the long-term economic benefit from the yields, which

are higher than the short-term benefits from the price of timber if the trees were

logged. For example, the average price of a logged durian tree is around Rp 630,000

(US$ 50). Meanwhile a durian tree can produce fruit valued at around Rp 200,000

(US$ 15) per annum (Author’s survey, 2015). Although the value of the fruit in the

short term is lower than the value of the logged tree, it can be enjoyed by the farmers

in the long term which means the total value from the fruits would be higher than

the value of the logged tree.

However, there is no guarantee that the trees will be kept forever. The forest

farmers will log the trees if there is a need for wood (Author’s survey, 2015). For

instance, if there is a traditional ceremony that requires firewood for cooking,

people will log trees on their forest land with permission from and coordination

with the forest farmer community leaders (CFFG head and village head). Also, local

people tend to log trees if they need timber to build houses. However, it is very rare

that the farmers log trees for commercial purposes because this is against adat and

state law. Although this type of logging is rare and small in volume, these actions

still cause forest degradation. Collecting forest products –including timber– for

114

non-commercial purposes by adat communities is allowed under Indonesian

forestry law (UU 41/99 article 67)46.

The author’s survey results showed that 77% of respondents who are

enrolled in the PES program stated that there is an increase in the number of trees

on their Community Forestry land after the PES program was introduced (see figure

5.9). This is due to the conversion of the cash benefit from PES to seeds to be

planted on community forestland, as a conditionality of the program. The aim of

the conversion is to control the ecological outcome of the PES program. The seeds

are mainly planted on degraded land, which is then supposed to contribute to

increase the forest cover.

Figure 5.9 Farmers’ Perception of Change in Number of Trees on Community

Forest Land due to PES

Source: Author's survey, 2015; n = 100

On the other hand, not all respondents agree that the PES program increased

the number of trees on their Community Forestry land. Around 13% of respondents

who are enrolled in the PES program stated that there was no change in the number

of trees as a result of the PES program. They say this is due to the low quality of

the seeds provided that did not grow well. In addition, due to limited supply, the

seeds were planted in a small area of Community Forestry land. Each farmer who

46 This law does not clearly mention that timber collection is allowed in specific classifications of

forest. Another law (UU 18/2013 article 11) mentions that local people are allowed to log trees

except in conservation and protection forest.

115

was enrolled in the PES program obtained only thirteen seeds on average. This is

too few compared to the level of need for tree planting to support forest

conservation. Furthermore, the number of trees did not increase due to a lack of

water in the period of PES implementation, which did not take place in the optimal

planting season. The seeds should be supplied in the rainy season so they are easy

to grow with a sufficient supply of water. Instead, they were distributed in the dry

season. The effectiveness of the implementation of the PES program thus is open

to question.

However, the PES program has supported an increase in the quality of forest

cover. 79% of survey respondents who were enrolled in the PES program stated

that the quantity and quality of trees increased, especially due to the variety of seeds

that were planted (see figure 5.10). Although some respondents stated that the

quality of the seeds that they obtained was low, other CFFG members reported

obtaining better quality seeds that contributed to an increase in the variety and

quality of trees on their community forest land. The seed quality improved after the

program was evaluated three years following its inception.

Figure 5. 10 Farmers’ Perception of Forest Cover Quality Improvement due to

PES

Source: Author's survey, 2015; n = 100

The PES program in West Lombok was implemented 6 years before this

survey was conducted. During that time, conservation efforts had been undertaken

in some degraded forest areas. Fast growing tree species such as silk trees (Albizia

116

chinensis) were among the trees that were planted to achieve a rapid conservation

effect47. As a result, significant increases in forest cover in that project location are

evident. Data from the West Lombok district forest agency demonstrates that the

degraded forest land in Sesaot forest was reduced from 763.35 hectares in 2010 to

423.50 hectares in 2014 (see figure 5.11).

Up until 2014, money from PES in West Lombok has been allocated to fund

15 forest restoration activities involving 13 forest farmers' groups in seven villages

around Sesaot Forest (IMP, 2010; SBP, 2010; IMP, 2012; SBP, 2012; IMP, 2013b).

This includes 405 hectares of land where 361,744 trees have been planted (IMP,

2014a). However, as the PES budget is still limited, it can only be used for

complementary aspects of the conservation program and cannot be used for

mainstream schemes in forest resource governance. During five years of

implementation, the PES program only supported re-afforestation on about 1.3% of

the total degraded forest area in West Lombok, which requires funding for

restoration (IMP, 2010; SBP, 2010; IMP, 2012; SBP, 2012; IMP, 2013b). Although

small, this contribution to forest conservation is crucial to the effective development

of this program, which has had relatively limited impact to date. In the future, if

PES could be implemented in all areas of Lombok, it would undoubtedly deliver

significant outcomes for forest restoration. A similar PES regulation has already

been introduced in Central Lombok district and will be implemented in the coming

years.

In spite of the fact that the amount of PES funding is relatively small, the

distribution of the fund was running smoothly due to effective administration.

Unlike a project approach, all funds are handed over to the groups awarded funding,

and allocation procedures are designed and monitored by IMP to ensure proper use.

With this approach, villagers were enthusiastic about involvement in the program

(RN, community leader, interview, 10/06/2014). In regards to maintaining the

ecological quality of this program, discussions and consultations with the forest

service officers were conducted throughout the process, starting from the selection

47 Albizia chinensis is a very fast growing tree species and takes only 5 years from planting to

harvesting.

117

of seeds to be planted until the trees had grown significantly. This process resulted

in decent growth rates for the trees, which reached about 60-70% maturity over the

five years since they were planted (RN, community leader, interview, 10/60/2014).

Figure 5.11 Degraded Forest Land Area in Narmada sub District Including Sesaot,

2010 – 2014

Source: Dinas Kehutanan Kabupaten Lombok Barat (2014).

Theory suggests that a PES system that includes payments for more than

one ecosystem service can make it more attractive for land users to participate (in

this case, local communities), compared to single ecosystem services programs

(Montagnini and Finney, 2011). For the moment, only water services are traded in

the PES program in West Lombok although there are other potential ecosystem

services such as carbon sequestration, biodiversity and erosion control that could

be included. Schemes to consider carbon sequestration to be traded on the

international PES market such as through REDD+ are being initiated in the area

(Bae et al., 2014) and may contribute to further improvement in forest conservation.

5.4. Conclusion

It is clear that Community Forestry and payment for ecosystem services

have both positive and negative influences on the ecological function of the forest.

Data collected from interviews suggest that there will be a positive impact of

Community Forestry on the ecological function of the forest after the program has

118

been well established. Referring to the three phases of Community Forestry

development in Lombok, namely the rehabilitation phase, encroachment phase, and

a new forest re-vegetation phase, the positive outcomes occurred in the first and

third phases. There is a need to address the problem of encroachment on the forest,

which occurred in the second phase by those who had not been involved in the

established Community Forestry program.

Even where the Community Forestry program has resulted in improved

forest cover, it does not contribute to biodiversity conservation when endemic forest

trees have been lost and replaced with MPTS fruit producing tree species.

Community Forestry rules allow forest farmers to plant crops and MPTS together

with conservation trees. Similar to the endemic forest trees, MPTS can provide

ecological benefits such as water protection, carbon sequestration and flood control,

yet MPTS lack the benefits of biodiversity protection. MPTS are beneficial for the

livelihood of the forest farmers since they can produce fruits --as a non-timber forest

product-- that can be a source of income for the forest farmer. Thus planting MPTS

on community forest land generates dual benefits for the economy and watershed

conservation, which can be an incentive for the forest farmers to maintain the forest

cover. Although endemic species have the further environmental benefit of

enhancing biodiversity.

However, the forest farmers tend to prioritise economic benefits over

ecological benefits, as indicated by the plantation composition, which is very

different from the composition required by state regulation. The Community

Forestry regulation stipulates a proportion of 60% conservation trees to 40% MPTS

trees to be planted in a community forest. A negotiated modification codified in

local adat regulations with District approval permitted a drastic change to a 30/70%

composition in favour of MPTS instead. In fact, the actual proportion of

conservation trees to MPTS was 21% and 79% respectively according to the Sesaot

survey data. Although forest farmers pay more attention to economic benefit than

ecological benefit from the community forest, the contribution to ecological

outcome remains important, especially insofar as MPTS has the same function as

endemic conservation trees for watershed protection purposes.

119

Another factor which has influenced Community Forestry success is adat

which Community Forest Farmer Groups (CFFGs) believe play an important role

in sustainable community forest management, despite inconsistent enforcement. As

a self-governing institution, Adat rules regulate the terms and condition of

Community Forestry management to be followed by the CFFG members. Forest

farmers follow adat rules due to a threat of loss of property rights to the community

forest if they offend adat law. Adat also supports a participative forest guardianship

system. Forest farmers were encouraged to guard their plantation from illegal

activities such as timber theft. Failing to maintain their community forest properly

should cause the forest farmer to lose their rights to access and manage the

community forest, according to adat regulations. However, adat law is weakly

enforced, especially in regards to plantation composition. The lack of enforcement

suggests that if market conditions favoured planting species that do not serve

watershed protection function, farmers would likely shift, or if timber prices

reached levels that made short term logging more profitable, the forest could return

to a degraded condition.

Property rights play a significant role in maintaining forest cover. Property

rights granted by the government have changed the forest farmers’ behaviour with

respect to illegal logging. Since the right to manage the forest is now believed to be

secure, forest farmers tend to maintain their forest land for longer term economic

benefits.

The payment for ecosystem services (PES) program has a positive influence

on the ecological condition of forests. PES can help to increase forest cover,

although the contribution of the current program is relatively small, compared to

the conservation needs of the area. This is because the PES program is applied in a

way that suits forest farmers’ needs. The PES program is complementary to

Community Forestry management practices. Since this program supplies MPTS

seeds to be planted on degraded community forest land, it also provides an incentive

for forest farmers to maintain trees planted for the long term benefits. Thus, the

forest coverage increases, which affects the ecological function of the forest

120

positively. The extent to which the PES and Community Forestry programs impact

on farmers’ livelihoods will be discussed in the next chapter.

121

Chapter 6

Community Forestry, Payment for Ecosystem Services and Local

Socio-Economic Conditions

This chapter examines whether or not, and under what conditions, integrated

Community Forestry and Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) programs can

become a tool to improve local socio-economic conditions. The principal

hypothesis of this chapter is that, by better accommodating local communities’

needs; integrated Community Forestry and PES can be used as a tool to support the

improvement of socio-economic conditions, in particular for poverty alleviation in

the long-term.

This chapter is structured as follows: Section 6.1 discusses the impact of the

Community Forestry program on local socio-economic conditions; Section 6.2

describes the villagers’ views concerning the effect of Community Forestry on their

livelihoods and poverty reduction. The socio-economic benefits from integrating

PES into a Community Forestry program is the topic of section 6.3. Finally, section

6.4 concludes this chapter.

6.1. Community Forestry Impacts on Local Socio-Economic Conditions

Community Forestry and Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) programs

are designed to support poverty alleviation as well as natural resource conservation

(Ferraro and Kiss, 2002). As described in chapter 4 of this thesis, the PES program

in West Lombok Indonesia is integrated with the Community Forestry program to

support forest conservation in Sesaot forests, which are managed through a

Community Forestry approach. In this case, the PES program provides funds for

tree planting in the degraded forest.

Since ecosystem services are provided by nature, people might argue that

no payment is needed to consume the services. In fact, the existence of ecosystem

122

services is strongly influenced by the behaviour of people living in the areas where

ecosystem services are produced (Duncan, 2006). For instance, inappropriate land

management by farmers in an upstream watershed area would undoubtedly affect

the quality and quantity of water supply in a related downstream area. This situation

led to the proposition that payments should be made as an incentive to influence

upstream people’s behaviour in order to maintain the long-term provision of

ecosystem services (Duncan, 2006; Pagiola, 2006; Engel et al., 2008; Sommerville,

M. M. et al., 2009; Muradian, Roldan et al., 2010). PES has been applied as a tool

for connecting downstream and upstream communities, as an instrument for solving

conflict between two such groups of people (Kosoy et al., 2007). PES is also applied

as a wealth distribution strategy among rural and urban communities (Muradian,

Roldan and Rival, 2012).

PES practice is commonly applied as a single purpose program for

maintaining only one defined ecosystem service. In this case, the resource users are

paid by ecosystem services beneficiaries to ensure the ecosystem service is supplied

continuously from the particular natural resource. PES programs are often

introduced together with other development or conservation programs such as

integrated conservation and development projects (ICDP) for rural development

and forest conservation. An integrated PES program with rural development and/or

conservation programs is not only beneficial to ensure the supply of ecosystem

services from rural to urban communities, but also can be seen as a transfer of

human, financial and social capital from urban to rural communities (Torres et al.,

2013).

High levels of poverty are often spatially correlated with remote

conservation areas that provide ecosystem services (Pagiola et al., 2005). Therefore,

it is argued that PES can also be used as a tool for poverty alleviation (Duncan,

2006; Pagiola, 2007; Wunder and Albán, 2008). However, the reality of the impact

of PES programs on the livelihoods of poor households is an empirical question.

Muradian, Roldan et al. (2010) argue that the poverty alleviation goals of PES

programs are difficult to achieve, due to the maldistribution of PES benefits that

should go to the poor. They stressed that benefits were often disproportionally

123

distributed to the well-off landowners who hold formal land tenure. Similarly,

Pagiola et al. (2005) contend that PES has primarily been an instrument for

maintaining natural resource efficiency and not for poverty alleviation. They argue

that “PES programs are not a magic bullet for poverty reduction, but there can be

important synergies when program design is well thought out and local conditions

are favorable” (Pagiola et al., 2005, p. 248).

As described in chapter 4 of this thesis, the PES program in West Lombok

is designed to suit local conditions where the defined ecosystem service, which is

water, is produced from a forest that is managed through a Community Forestry

approach. Here, the PES fund is allocated for planting trees in the community forest

area. The types of trees planted are varied to suit the needs of the forest farmers. In

this case, the forest farmers need Multi-Purpose Tree Species (MPTS)48, which will

both serve the purpose of maintaining water provision from the forest, and at the

same time contribute to the forest farmers’ livelihoods.

Before explaining the impact of integrated Community Forestry and PES on

poverty, we will firstly discuss the general effects of Community Forestry programs

on socio-economic conditions in the villages surrounding Sesaot Forest, regardless

of whether or not PES has been integrated into their practices49. It will be argued

that the Community Forestry program in the Sesaot forest in West Lombok has

significantly improved the socio-economic conditions in the area. Community

Forestry is argued to provide a wide range of social and economic benefits for

villagers, including access to land, new job opportunities, new sources of income

and increased income for villagers, improved education levels, improved health

outcomes, better housing conditions and greater home ownership. Such benefits

will be considered in two categories, direct benefits and indirect benefits.

48 MPTS (Multipurpose Tree Species) are trees that have both economic and ecological benefit, for

example fruit trees such as durian, avocado, mango, jackfruit, hazelnut and others (Menteri

Kehutanan RI, 2014a). 49 A discussion of the debates amongst scholars regarding the impact of Community Forestry

practice on poverty alleviation in other countries was presented in the Chapter 2 of this thesis.

124

6.1.1. Direct Socio-Economic Benefits of Community Forestry

Direct benefits are the immediate benefits obtained by villagers who are

granted a property right to manage the community forest. These include access to

land and new sources of income.

Land access for landless families

Access to land is the greatest benefit that is enjoyed by villagers who

become forest farmers and obtain community forest management rights. This group

of people is made up principally of the villagers who do not own private farming

land, especially single parent women and the poor. As mentioned in the profile

description of the first community forest farmer group in Sesaot, KMPH,

participants in this program were selected on the basis of specific criteria, including:

willingness to voluntarily participate, non-ownership of private farming land, and

residence near Sesaot forest. Single-parent women with children were given first

priority. Based on these criteria, 165 households were selected at the beginning of

the Community Forestry program (Forum Kawasan, 2009).The landless families

obtain access to farming land, which is beneficial for their livelihoods. Thus the

Community Forestry program could be seen as a form of land distribution to the

poor.

Access to community forest land is bounded by government regulation. It is

clearly stated that the land remains state land. The granted right is not an ownership

right, so that the forest land cannot be sold or inherited (Menteri Kehutanan RI,

2014a). The forest farmers are only allowed to manage the land and carry out

farming with a composition of 70% MPTS (Multi-Purpose Tree Species) and 30%

forest trees, with a minimum 265 trees on a hectare of land. Land access is granted

for 35 years and can be renewed after evaluation, which is conducted every five

years (Forum Kawasan, 2006). In the absence of the Community Forestry program,

in 2015, based on the survey for this study, 45% of villagers did not have private

land for farming. Although the size of the Community Forestry plot that has been

125

granted to the villagers is relatively small (0.25 hectares per family50), it has helped

the villagers obtain cash from farming forest land, which they could not have done

legally in the past. The existence of Community Forestry has changed their lives,

from being landless families to families with conditional access to land.

Income generation

Another direct benefit of Community Forestry programs is the cash income

obtained from selling forest products, especially non-timber forest products

(NTFPs) such as coffee, cocoa, banana and other fruits and vegetables. Since the

Community Forestry program in Sesaot is located in a protected forest that is

significant for ecological needs, timber products are prohibited from being obtained

from the community forest (based on the Indonesian law on forestry, UU 41/1999).

As an alternative, non-timber forest products (UU 41/1999 section 26) can be

collected. Based on The Indonesian Ministry of Forestry regulation number

P.35/2007, Non-timber forest products refer to everything other than timber;

including, for example, rattan, resin, fruits, vegetables and honey (Menteri

Kehutanan RI, 2007). The situation would be different if the status of the Sesaot

forest was a production forest. Based on the Indonesian regulations on Community

Forestry, timber production is allowed in a community forest that is located in a

production forest.

The non-timber forest products, especially fruits, are the most significant

benefits that people obtain from the Sesaot community forest. Thus, to support both

economic and ecological needs, MPTS that can produce fruits are favoured for

planting in the community forest. Surveys for this study indicate that, on average,

80% of the trees planted in the community forests are categorized as MPTS. As

mentioned in Chapter 4, the Community Forestry program in Sesaot involved

conversion of degraded forest land which was replanted and developed as

community forest. Almost all community forests in Sesaot are secondary forest.

50 Although each household officially obtains only 0.25 hectares, in fact, some households occupy

more than 0.25 hectares that have been obtained through “buying” from others.

126

The community forest covers around 30% of the total size of the Sesaot forests

(Forum Kawasan, 2011b).

Based on surveys conducted by the author in 2015, the average community

forest farmer’s annual earnings per household from selling NTFPs is around Rp

15,200,000 (US$1,150) or about Rp 1,260,000 (US$95) per month. The highest

contributions to these earnings come from cocoa and banana crops, which reach an

average of Rp 5,816,100 (US$ 438) and Rp 3,466,125 (US$ 254) respectively per

year. This income can be used to cover about 48% of average family expenditure,

which reaches about Rp 32,150,000 (US$2,440) a year, or about Rp 2,600,000

(US$197) per month. To support their income from community forests, most

families have additional jobs, for example as small traders, labourers, livestock

farmers, ojek (freelance motorcycle) drivers and handymen.

For an average of four family members, the forest farmers’ per capita

expenditure is about Rp 650,000 per month. Of this, the highest proportions are

spent for food and education, at 54% and 13% respectively. The economic

conditions of the Sesaot community forest farmers are today well above the

Indonesian national poverty line, which is currently set at Rp 356,378 expenditure

per capita per month (BPS, 2016a). In addition, when considering the United

Nations poverty threshold, which is currently set at US$ 1.25 income per capita per

day (UN, 2015), the economic conditions of forest farmers in Sesaot, at about

US$1.80 per capita per day, is still above this international standard.

6.1.2. Indirect Socio-Economic Benefits of Community Forestry

Indirect benefits are the benefits from the existence of the Community

Forestry program that are enjoyed by villagers who do not work as forest farmers.

Community Forestry provides jobs for people in the villages, such as traders in

forest products, truck and ojek drivers, food processors, and labourers for crop

planting and harvesting the yields. Community forest farmers who manage a large

127

area of community forest land often employ other villagers to help them during

planting and harvesting seasons51.

Before Community Forestry was established, many people sought work

overseas, such as in Malaysia, since there was a lack of job opportunities in the

villages. As mentioned by one Sesaot villager, “Since Community Forestry has

been established, people have tended to stay in their village, and to work in the

forest either as a forest farmer, a labourer for planting and harvesting, or a

middleman trader…” (AN, villager, interview, 21/3/2016). The higher proportion

of people staying in the villages increases family connections, and may have long

term benefits in terms of social capital generation in the area, but on the other hand

the greater the population may put pressure on scarce forestland resources.

Women also gain benefits from Community Forestry. Previously in Sesaot,

women in the villages usually stayed in the home undertaking domestic jobs. Since

Community Forestry has been established, women now go to the forest to help their

husbands in managing the Community Forestry land, or to work as farm labourers

(AM, CFUG leader, interview, 8/6/2014). Some women also work as small traders

for forest products. They buy forest products directly from the farmer in the forest,

to be sold in markets in the city. Women's groups have also been created in the

villages to manage food processing businesses. The raw materials for food

production, such as banana, jackfruit and durian, are bought from community forest

farmers, and their products are sold to supply the tourism industry.

The indirect benefits of Community Forestry also flow to those who work

in related forest product businesses, such as transportation and small trading. The

author’s survey result demonstrated that some villagers have opened transportation

51 The community forest land size officially granted by government is 0.25 hectares per household.

However, some households manage up to 4.5 hectares – due to their capability to “take-over” the

land management rights of other households if the latter need cash and are willing to “hand over”

their rights although this is technically illegal. The survey data indicates 37% of households manage

0.25 hectares, while 63% manage more than 0.25 hectares. This is a big issue for the sustainability

of Community Forestry and PES. Ultimately, there will be more landless seeking to gain land or

income through illegal use of the forest as a result of these illegal transfers.

128

businesses to assist farmers and small traders to access the forest, and to transport

their forest products to market using trucks. Many young people work as ojek

(motorcycle) drivers, to transport non-timber forest products from forest areas that

are difficult to access by truck. Other villagers have opened small warung (coffee

shops) near the forest, to accommodate the needs of forest farmers, drivers and

middleman traders for lunch or coffee breaks. Significant change is also evident

with respect to the lower numbers of people whose livelihoods rely primarily on

timber products. Since the Community Forestry program has been established,

people in the villages are no longer so directly dependent on timber forest products

for their livelihoods; which is beneficial for the ecology of the area, as described in

Chapter 5 of this thesis.

Community Forestry is also able to provide revenue for the local

government, due to taxes and fees collected from the community forest farmers.

The forest farmers are mandated to pay a monthly fee, which is assessed based on

the area of community forest that they occupy. This fee costs the farmers Rp 10,000

(US$0.76) per month per hectare (AM, CFUG leader, interview, 8/6/2014). From

the total official Community Forestry area (2,668 hectares) in West Lombok

district, the local government can obtain Rp 320,160,000 (US$24,300) per annum.

In addition, the local government also generates revenue from the PES fund which

is integrated with the Community Forestry program. As stated in the PES

regulations, 20% of this fund is allocated for government revenue. In one example,

in 2013, the PES contribution from water consumers in West Lombok was Rp

343,641,500 (US$ 26,000) (PDAM Giri Menang, 2016). From this amount, it can

be estimated that government revenue earned from PES was Rp 68,728,000

(US$5,218).

6.2. Villagers' Views on the Effect of Community Forestry on Their

Livelihoods and on Poverty Reduction

This study involved surveys of 200 forest farmers in five villages bordering

the Sesaot community forest location. The primary focus of the survey was to

evaluate the impact of Community Forestry and PES programs on people’s

129

livelihoods and on poverty in the villages. The survey results indicate that 95.5%

of respondents agree that Community Forestry has increased the forest farmer

family’s quality of life. Respondents explained that after they obtained land through

the Community Forestry program, they were able to take up farming to increase

their income, so that they could fulfil their family’s economic needs.

A small minority of forest farmers reported holding a different view on the

impact of Community Forestry on the quality of their lives. From the survey, 4.5%

of respondents stated that they did not think that Community Forestry had increased

their family’s quality of life. The main reason provided was that they had only

started working as forest farmers a few years previously. Considering income as a

necessary, although not sufficient, condition for the quality of life, in these cases,

there had not yet been significant income generated from the land, because the tree

crops had not yet produced yields. This situation most commonly affects new

families who have recently married and obtained the land through informally

“buying” it from another farmer, or “inheriting” it from their parents52. Another

reason for the lack of reported life quality improvement from Community Forestry

was because the respondents were busy doing other jobs, so the income from the

Community Forestry land was not the respondent’s primary income source and was

not considered to be significant in meeting their family’s needs.

These farmers often “bought' the Community Forestry land management

right from those who needed cash. Although selling and buying a Community

Forestry land management right is illegal, the practice exists because some people

need cash, and the only option is to “sell” their management right from the

Community Forestry land. This study’s survey results showed that 29% of

respondents obtained rights to Community Forestry land through buying the right

from other farmers. To avoid contravening the regulations, the term the respondents

used was “ganti rugi” (compensate for loss). The forest agency and the forest farmer

community groups face difficulties in controlling these transactions. It seems that

transfer of the forest management right is not regarded as a problem as long as the

52 The right held by villagers upon forest land is not an ownership right. Instead, it is only an access

and management right.

130

land is not "sold" to people who come from outside of the villages. Thus, the

property rights on the community forest are circulated only among the targeted

households in the villages. As mentioned by one forest agency officer, “the forest

management rights should be distributed among people who live in the surrounding

villages where the Community Forestry is located’ (MM, forest agency officer,

interview, 6/6/2015). Nonetheless, the problem of the re-emergence of landless

households from among the recipients and of inequalities among landholders over

time is a potentially serious issue. There is no written contract for the transactions,

which are based only on oral agreements among the relevant parties; although these

transactions need to be approved by the CFFG leader to be locally accepted.

In general, the Community Forestry program has had a positive impact on

socio-economic conditions in the villages. The survey results indicate that 82% of

respondents agree and 13.5% strongly agree that Community Forestry helps to

reduce poverty in the villages. They argue that it is easier to make a living because

Community Forestry programs have established job opportunities in the villages.

The general economic conditions and welfare in the village have increased

significantly even though some people have not become community forest farmers.

Only 0.5% of respondents disagreed with the statement that Community Forestry

reduced poverty in the villages (and 4% of respondents were neutral). Those who

disagreed argued that the answer depends on the size of the community forest plots

awarded. The Community Forestry plot size is relatively small, and is arguably not

adequate for those who have large families. Thus, the benefit of Community

Forestry on socio-economic conditions is smaller for this group of families.

6.3. Socio-Economic Benefits from Integrating PES into a Community

Forestry Program

As mentioned in the introduction section, the PES program that has been

applied in West Lombok has been integrated with the Community Forestry

management program. The PES program provides funding for tree planting in

degraded community forest, in order to maintain water supplies from the forest. The

PES fund should be delivered to forest farmers as a conditional cash incentive, with

131

the aim of positively influencing their behaviour in forest management; specifically,

to keep trees standing and to contribute to the maintenance of water provision from

the forest. As argued by Adhikari, S. et al. (2014), incentives are necessary to

encourage people’s participation in natural resource management.

One obstacle in implementing the direct payment approach in developing

countries is the limited opportunities for non-agricultural investment (Ferraro and

Kiss, 2002). However, this obstacle does not exist in PES implementation in

Lombok, since the payment is not merely allocated for conservation purposes. In

addition to conservation, PES was also used to fund non-conservation activities

around the forest. In the beginning of this program, the funding was also allocated

for business activities, such as a food processing business run by a women’s group.

Due to the limited budget, there has only been one women’s group, involving 14

women, which has received benefit from the PES program to date. This group

received Rp 33,750,000 (equal to US$ 2,562) when the PES program was initiated,

to support their activities in processing non-timber forest products (SBP, 2012). So

far, around Rp 653,516,500 (equal to US$ 49,620) has been delivered to

communities in the Sesaot forest area (see table 4.1). However, non-conservation

activities are no longer funded, due to the high demands on the PES fund for

planting trees in degraded forests.

6.3.1. Villagers’ Views on the Effect of PES on Their Livelihood and Poverty

Reduction

Compared to villagers' responses concerning the impact of Community

Forestry on their livelihoods, where almost all respondents agreed that Community

Forestry has had a positive influence, they are less convinced of the positive impact

of PES on household livelihoods. It is likely that the goals of PES for poverty

alleviation may only be achieved in the long term. As mentioned in Chapter 4, the

initial goal of PES in Lombok was to serve as a tool to encourage the urban

community to contribute to funding both forest conservation and poverty alleviation

in rural areas.

132

Currently, PES funding is only sufficient for conservation purposes, and not

for poverty reduction. The PES program is integrated with Community Forestry to

help farmers obtain free seeds, which are mainly MPTS that are supposed to provide

economic benefit and thus contribute to poverty reduction. Such in-kind payment

which suits the needs of forest farmers tends to be accepted more easily by

recipients, and may stimulate more participation, as experienced in Western Mexico

(Torres et al., 2013). However, since the quantity of funds provided is relatively

small, this can only be used for additional capital for managing the community

forest. Only a small portion of the fund is allocated for planting and maintenance

wages that can provide direct financial benefits for the farmers. Nonetheless, Fauzi

and Anna (2013) argue that PES has been readily accepted by local people, since it

is based on a very different approach from the command and control system of

natural resources management that was applied previously under Indonesia's New

Order regime.

It is difficult to argue that PES will be able to solve poverty problems in

these villages in the short term. Since most of the planted trees are categorized as

MPTS, it can be assumed that more benefits will be enjoyed in the long term, once

the trees are ready to be harvested (RN, community leader, interview, 10 June

2014). The Author’s survey results indicate that 64% of survey respondents

reported that PES improves their family’s quality of life. There is expectation that

their incomes will increase in the future, once the MPTS seeds bought from the PES

fund have grown and produce yields (RN, community leader, interview,

10/6/2014). Some farmers do not get paid for planting the trees, since their

community has agreed to allocate the planting wage for buying more seeds; so that

more trees can be planted and future economic benefits can be achieved.

From the survey, 18% of respondents disagreed that PES improves their

family’s quality of life. The main reason for differential responses was that the trees

are not yet fully grown, and have not yet produced yields. Further, some

respondents explained that the number of seeds is limited and not adequate for their

needs. In addition, not all forest farmers are involved in the PES program. Some

farmers may have to wait several years to join the program, due to the limited PES

133

budget. Others who have recently become involved in the PES program have not

yet obtained direct economic benefits, except for the free seeds.

The survey indicates that around 17% of respondents are neutral with

respect to the benefits of PES; neither agreeing nor disagreeing with the statement

that PES improves their family’s quality of life. The main reason provided for this

answer, as for those who disagreed, was that the seeds have not yet grown. The

economic benefit may be achieved in the future, if the seeds grow well.

Overall, the survey revealed an expectation that the PES program may

reduce poverty in the future. About 83% of survey respondents indicated that PES

could potentially support poverty alleviation once all forest farmers become

involved and all seeds have grown and are producing yields. In such a situation,

money from PES could be used for economic activities other than forest

conservation; once the forest has been fully planted. For the time being, the current

direct economic benefit from PES is the value of the seeds that are distributed. If

the farmers have to buy the seeds using their own money, they need to spend on

average at least Rp 11,600 (US$ 0.88) per seed. The money from PES would be

more beneficial if it could be used for wages for planting.

6.3.2. Welfare Index to Measure the Socio-Economic Impact of Integrated

PES and Community Forestry

To measure the impact of Community Forestry and the PES program on

farmer households’ socio-economic condition, a welfare index was designed. Eight

basic indicators of welfare were surveyed to generate the welfare index. These

indicators of welfare were chosen based on the social economic survey standards

used by the Indonesian statistics agency. These indicators include: house

ownership, house wall material, house floor material, electricity, water supply,

energy for cooking, transportation and communication (Riyadi et al., 2015). A

summary of the welfare index is presented in table 6.1.

134

Table 6.1 Summary of Welfare Indicators Before and After Community Forestry

and PES Programs were Established

Indicators Criteria 1998 2015 Change

(%) (%) (%)

House Ownership Own house 40 97 +57

Live with family 60 3 -57

House wall material Bamboo 45 3 -42

Wood 34 9 -25

Brick 20 88 +68

House floor Material Soil 56 1 -55

Cement 43 61 +18

Tile 1 38 +37

Access to Electricity No Electricity 70 0 -70

Shared from neighbour 20 20 0

PLN grid 10 74 +64

Own generator 0 6 +6

Water Supply River/spring 77 1 -76

Private well 1 1 0

Public pipe 21 8 -13

Private pipe 1 91 +90

Energy for Cooking Wood/timber 100 34 -66

Oil 0 1 +1

Gas 0 65 +65

Transportation

Facilities No transportation 88 14 -74

Bicycle 10 14 +4

Motor bike 2 69 +67

Car 0 3 +3

Communication

Facilities Do not have a mobile phone 100 9 -91

Have one mobile phone 0 47 +47

Have more than one mobile

phone 0 44

+44

Education Level Primary School 67 35 -32

Junior High School 20 27 +7

Senior High School 12 26 +14

Undergraduate 1 12 +11

Postgraduate 0 0.00 0

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

135

Table 6.1 suggests that significant changes in household wellbeing occurred

after the Community Forestry and PES programs were established. However, of

course, correlation does not necessarily prove causation, and many factors can

impact on these observed changes. In particular, it must be noted that the 1998

baseline comparator is at the point of the greatest impact of the Asian Economic

Crisis53. Other contributing factors could be government investment in

infrastructure such as roads and health services; social safety net (cash transfer and

‘rice for the poor’ programs); the subsidy on fuel; and remittances from migrant

workers. At the least, data from this survey suggest there may be a positive

relationship between Community Forestry and the PES program and forest farmer

families’ welfare, despite the difficulty disentangling the impact of these policies

from other broader changes in the economy. Detailed analysis of each of the

indicators is provided in the following sections.

House Ownership

House ownership may be the most relevant indicator for measuring the

welfare of a household. Significant improvement in house ownership is evident in

the villages surrounding the Sesaot Community Forestry area, after the Community

Forestry program was established. Before Community Forestry and the PES

programs were introduced, only 60% of survey respondents had their own house.

Those who did not have their own house, lived with family and relatives54.

Currently, as of 2015, 97% of survey respondents have their own house. All

respondents attributed this improvement to the increases in their income as a result

of becoming community forest farmers, income from which enabled them to afford

to buy or build a house. Statistics test was performed to clarify this condition. The

statistics test (Paired t test) result indicated that the probability of differences

between house ownership before and after the Community Forestry program is

significant with the P value of 0.00 (See Appendix 6.1). This statistical analysis

53 The Asian economic crisis in 1998 led to a decrease in household wellbeing, due to hyper-inflation

increasing the cost of basic need items including food and fuel (Johnson, 1998). 54 It is common in Lombok that newly married couples live with their parents until they can afford

to buy their own house, or are able to rent from other family members.

136

confirms there is a significant improvement of housing condition after the

Community Forestry program established.

Figure 6.1 Comparison of House Ownership Before and After Community

Forestry and PES were Established

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

The materials used for house building are also indicators of a household's

prosperity. Those who live in a house that has walls made from bricks, and who use

tiles for the floors, are categorized as more prosperous than those who live in a

house made from wood or bamboo with cement or soil for the floors. A considerable

improvement was observed in house materials in the villages surrounding Sesaot

community forest, after the introduction and establishment of Community Forestry.

This appears to be one of the clearest indicators of the positive impacts of the

Community Forestry program on households’ economy.

In 1998, before the Community Forestry and PES programs were

established, 45% of respondents’ houses were made from bamboo, 34% from

wood55 and only 21% from bricks. By 2015, the vast majority of survey respondents

(88%) made their house from bricks. Nine per cent of survey respondents still used

wood for their house walls, and only 3% used bamboo. The conversion from wood

to bricks for house wall material has also reduced the pressure on taking wood from

the forest for house building.

55 Bamboo and wood are the cheapest materials for building houses in Lombok.

137

Figure 6.2 Comparison of House Wall Material Before and After Community

Forestry and PES were Established

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

A similar shift was observed for house floor materials. There are three types

of flooring used in the villages: earthen floor, cement, and tiles. The value of tiles

is higher than cement, while earthen floors are the cheapest material. Before

Community Forestry and PES programs were established, the majority of survey

respondents (56%) used soil for their house floor. Around 43% used cement and

only 1% used tiles. The current situation is markedly different. The majority of

survey respondents (61%) now use cement for their house floor material. Another

large proportion, about 38%, use tiles; and only 1% still have earthen floors.

Figure 6.3 Comparison of House Floor Material Before and After Community

Forestry and PES were Established

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

Electricity and Water

The welfare indicator categories that were measured included the

availability of utilities such as electricity and water. The ideal living standard is for

every house to have direct access to electricity and water. There are four categories

for electricity access in the villages: direct access from the electricity company

138

(PLN); shared access from a neighbour who has direct access to PLN; owning a

private generator; or no electricity. Although electricity infrastructure is sufficient

in the villages, not all villagers can afford to access the electricity service. The cost

to have direct access to the PLN grid is around Rp 2,500,000 (US$ 190) for

installation, and around Rp 100,000 (US$ 7.6) per month for the bill, depending on

usage.

Before the Community Forestry and PES programs were established, 70%

of survey respondents lived without electricity to their house. Another 20%

obtained electricity from a neighbour who had direct access to PLN supply. Only

10% of survey respondents had direct access to the PLN grid, and no one had their

own generator. This situation improved substantially after Community Forestry was

established. All survey respondents now have access to electricity through various

means. Most respondents (74%) have direct electricity access to the PLN grid; 20%

obtain electricity through their neighbour; and 6% now have their own generator.

Figure 6.4 Comparison of Access to Electricity Before and After Community

Forestry and PES were Established

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

Access to a water supply can be divided into four categories, in sequential

order of expense and reliability or convenience: direct private pipe to the house;

private well; public piped water facility that is shared with other households; and

the river. Households who have fresh water directly piped into their house are

considered more prosperous than those who only obtain the water from a public

pipe facility. Households that depend upon water collected from the river are

recognized as the least prosperous households.

139

As well as access to electricity, access to water supply has also increased

after the Community Forestry and PES programs were established. Before

Community Forestry and PES, the large majority (77%) of survey respondents

obtained water from the river. Only around 21% of survey respondents had access

to water from a public pipe. About 1% of survey respondents had a private well,

and only 1% had private piped water to their house. After the Community Forestry

and PES programs were established, the vast majority of survey respondents (91%)

now have private piped water to their house. However, there are a small portion of

respondents who still do not have direct access to water facilities in their house.

Instead, they obtain water from a public pipe (8%). The rest of the respondents still

access water from a private well and from the river. Respondents who do not have

direct access to water facilities to their house are mainly those who occupy a small

sized plot of community forest land. Seventy-six percent of this group occupy only

0.25 hectares, with a corresponding low monthly income; and only 58% of them

are involved in the PES program. Additional income from expanded community

forest land and from greater and more direct PES benefits would be important for

them to fund their access to water facilities.

Figure 6.5 Comparison of Access to Water Supply Before and After Community

Forestry and PES were Established

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

The expense for water utilities is relatively small at around $3 per household

per month. However, although some households may have been able to pay this

expense before they became community forest farmers, the lack of availability of

water infrastructure in the past has limited their access to private piped water.

Before 2005, only certain households had access to piped water utilities in their

house. The water was delivered using privately owned water pumps from the river.

140

Currently, the government supports water access for the whole village by providing

piped water infrastructure, although payment is still required for maintenance

purposes. Although the data shows there is increased access to water supplies before

and after the programs were established, access was not entirely as a result of the

Community Forestry and PES programs. At the least, it can be said that the

programs supported the forest farmer households' ability to pay their monthly water

bill.

Energy for Cooking

Energy used for cooking has also changed considerably since the

Community Forestry and PES programs were established. Prior to Community

Forestry, all respondents used wood for cooking. This was not only because wood

could be obtained easily and freely (albeit illegally) from the forest, but also because

use of other sources of energy for cooking, such as oil, gas and electricity, was more

expensive.

After the Community Forestry and PES programs were established, only

34% of survey respondents still used wood for cooking. The vast majority now cook

with gas (65%), and 1% use oil. This shift indicates that people’s economic situation

has improved and that cooking with alternative sources of energy is now affordable.

The average expenditure reported by forest farmer households on energy –

including gas or oil for cooking, fuel for motorbikes, and electricity – is US$29 per

household per month (survey data, 2015).

141

Figure 6.6 Comparison of Energy Used for Cooking Before and After Community

Forestry and PES were Established

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

Transportation

Ownership of motorised transportation, such as motorbikes and cars, is also

considered a welfare indicator. Before the Community Forestry and PES programs

were established, most survey respondents (88%) did not have private motorised

transportation. About 10% owned a bicycle, and only two percent had a motorbike.

The current situation is much improved. Most survey respondents (69%) have

motorbikes for transportation, which they use to access the community forest.

Around 14% of survey respondents use bicycles, and 3% now own a car. The other

14% of survey respondents do not have any private transportation. However, this

group uses public transport instead; and they are able to afford fare payments. This

finding indicates that Community Forestry and PES has contributed to improving

welfare conditions in terms of transportation for villagers.

Figure 6.7 Comparison of Transport Ownership Before and After Community

Forestry and PES were Established

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

142

Communication

Although communication facilities may arguably be less significant than

some other indicators for measuring welfare, communication is increasingly

considered to be a welfare indicator. Obtaining landline telephone facilities has

been difficult even in less remote areas in Lombok, because the telecommunications

infrastructure provided by the Indonesian Telecommunication Company is only

available in the metro area of the island. The introduction of mobile phones has

become an alternative for communication in the villages, and is important for

facilitating marketing of local products.

None of the respondents had mobile phones before the Community Forestry

and PES programs were established. Aside from the constraint of low incomes,

cellular phones had not yet become a commodity widely accessible to the broader

society at the time. Mobile phone ownership started to increase rapidly after 2000.

Currently, more than 80% of farmers use a mobile phone for communication.

Indeed, 44% of them own more than one mobile phone in their family. Only 9% of

survey respondents do not own mobile phones. The existence of cellular services

has become of increasing importance for the forest farmers to determine market

prices and contact traders; and for ojek or truck drivers to obtain customers.

Figure 6.8 Comparison of Communication Facility Before and After Community

Forestry and PES were Established

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

143

Education Level

Another social economic indicator for measuring welfare is the improved

education level in the Sesaot village households. The education level of villagers

ranges from primary school level to undergraduate. There has been a major change

in the level of education in the villages after the Community Forestry and PES

programs were established. Before Community Forestry, the average education

level in the villages was junior high school. Currently, many families are able to

send their children to study up to university level, incurring costs of around Rp 15

million (US$ 1200) for the annual tuition fee at undergraduate level; a capacity

which was very rare to find in the era before Community Forestry was established.

Figure 6.9 Comparison of Education Level Before and After Community Forestry

and PES were Established

Source: Author's survey; 2015; n = 200

Health services

Access to health services is recognized as an important indicator of welfare

in any society. In Indonesia, a more prosperous household will tend to go to a

private doctor when they have a health problem, while the least prosperous

households depend upon village health centres (Puskesmas) for health services.

Access to health services is much improved after the introduction of

Community Forestry. The majority of villagers used to go to the Puskesmas – which

offers only basic health services – when they experienced a health problem.

Currently villagers tend to visit a doctor in the city, although this is much more

expensive compared to Puskesmas. The average annual (2015) payment for health

services in the villages is Rp 727,750.00 (US$55.26), which is 2.26% of the annual

144

total expenditure for forest farmer households (survey data, 2015). Unfortunately,

comparison data for health costs in the village in 1998 are not available.

6.4. Conclusion

Although many factors influence poverty reduction in Indonesia, I argue

that the Community Forestry program in West Lombok, and to a lesser extent (to

date) the PES program, has been able to help villagers escape from poverty. Data

from the West Nusa Tenggara Province confirm that the poverty rate in the region

decreased from 27.75% to 17.24% during and after the establishment of

Community Forestry and the PES program (BPS, 2014). The main benefit of

Community Forestry has been felt by people who were previously landless and

mainly poor. This program provides access to land for this group of people. The

program also provides a source of income that derives largely from non-timber

forest production, such as fruit and other tree crops. Socio-economic benefits have

also been enjoyed indirectly by people who do not work as forest farmers, but who

work in other sectors related to the Community Forestry program, including as

traders, drivers, processed food producers and labourers.

Socio-economic conditions, such as housing conditions, transportation and

communication facilities, and access to health services indicate that there are

significant positive outcomes from the Community Forestry program in these areas.

For instance, as mentioned by an NGO officer who works in the village, “Now,

more people have motorcycles compared to the situation before Community

Forestry was established. Other evidence is the improvement in education and

health levels. There has been a significant change in people’s education and health

after they became community forest farmers” (TN, NGO officer, interview,

13/6/2014). Another NGO officer explained, “so far, Community Forestry is still

the best option for poverty alleviation programs for rural communities who live

near a forest” (BS, NGO officer, interview, 11/6/2014).

In contrast, the PES program that has been integrated with the Community

Forestry program has not yet contributed substantively to poverty alleviation,

largely because the benefits that the farmers obtain is in the form of MPTS seeds

145

that need years to produce yields. Thus the impact of the PES program in Lombok

on poverty alleviation cannot be evaluated in the short-term. Instead, PES providers

may be expected to enjoy the economic benefit from PES in Lombok in the

medium-term future, after the seeds obtained through the PES program have grown

and produced yields.

The immediate economic benefit of the PES program for the ecosystem

service providers is equal to the market value of the seed stock itself. The planting

wage, which should arguably be another immediate economic benefit, has mainly

been re-allocated to buy more seeds; to enable more MPTS trees to be planted in

anticipation of greater economic benefit in the future. In summary, Community

Forestry and PES can be beneficial for improvement of socio-economic conditions

in forest villages, once the programs have become fully established. To achieve the

goals of improved socio-economic conditions, these programs should be adjusted

to the specific needs of the local community. The empirical evidence confirms that

by accommodating local needs, integrated PES and Community Forestry programs

can be used as a tool for improvement of socio-economic conditions, and

particularly for poverty alleviation in the long term.

146

Chapter 7

Statistical Analysis of Community Forestry and PES Impact on

Forest Conservation and Socio-Economic Conditions

This chapter presents a statistical analysis that was conducted to capture the

magnitude of the relationship between Community Forestry, PES, and socio-

economic conditions as well as forest conservation. This analysis aims to help

answer the main research questions that have been addressed through qualitative

methods in the previous chapters. The aim is to provide additional empirical

evidence to support or refute the research findings that were produced from the

qualitative analysis. Use of an approach that combines both quantitative and

qualitative analysis is expected to reduce any potential risks associated with use of

solely quantitative or qualitative methods, by providing a more comprehensive

evaluation and wider range of evidence (Rao, Vijayendra and Woolcock, 2003;

Creswell and Plano-Clark, 2006).

As discussed in the previous chapters of this thesis, Community Forestry

and Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) programs have been introduced in

Sesaot Forest in Lombok. The focus of these programs is to support conservation

of the Sesaot Forest, together with improvement of socio-economic conditions of

villagers in the surrounding community who work as forest farmers. To

complement the qualitative analysis, this chapter will analyze the impact of the

Community Forestry and PES programs on socio-economic conditions and forest

conservation through a statistical analysis. The structure of this chapter is as

follows. Section 7.1 covers data sources and their classification. Regression model

development for this quantitative analysis is the focus of section 7.2, followed by

discussion about the regression process in section 7.3. Section 7.4 provides an

account of the limitations of this analysis. Finally, section 7.5 concludes this

chapter.

147

7.1. Data Sources and Classification

The Ordinary Least Square (OLS) regression method was used in this

econometric analysis, due to its powerful capability to accommodate some dummy

variables and categorical variables that exist in this analysis (Craven and Islam,

2011). The OLS was used rather than other regression techniques because OLS is

the simplest of the regression tests, and was suitable for answering the hypotheses

that were investigated. The aims of this econometric analysis are to test if:

1. The Community Forestry program influenced forest conservation and socio-

economic conditions.

2. The Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) program influenced forest

conservation and socio-economic conditions.

Some other variables that may have influenced forest conservation and socio-

economic conditions were considered as control variables in the regression models.

These include adat practices in community forest management, property rights of

the forest farmer upon the community forest land, and community forest land size.

Given the similarity of independent variables in both models, seemingly

unrelated regression (SUR) techniques (Fiebig, 2001; Moon and Perron, 2006) are

also used by incorporating the best models defined by the OLS estimation result. In

addition, the SUR regression method is used in consideration of the possibility of a

correlation between the error term in both conservation and socio-economic

models.

Data for the econometric analysis were primary data that were collected

through household surveys involving 200 respondents. All of the respondents are

forest farmers who managed the Sesaot community forest in Lombok. The

respondents were categorized into two groups, those who were enrolled in the PES

program and those who were not enrolled. The data used are described in Table

7.1.

148

Table 7.1 Data Description

Defined

Variables

Proxy Variable

Name

Variable

Category

Variable

Measurement

Expected

Sign

Community

Forestry

program

Community

Forestry Index;

composite

variable

constructed from

nine variables

cfind independent Continuous +

PES program The farmer’s

enrolled status in

PES program

Pes independent Categorical +

Adat practice The farmer’s

compliance with

adat rules

adat independent Categorical +

Property

rights

Legal status of

community forest

land

Pr independent Categorical +

Community

forest land

size

Size of the

community forest

that is managed

by the farmer

cfland independent Continuous +

Socio-

Economic

conditions

Welfare; a

composite

variable

constructed from

eight components

welfare dependent Continuous

Conservation Forest Cover;

percentage of

trees that cover

the related

community forest

land

forcov dependent Continuous

Source: Survey questionnaire (see Appendixes 1.2).

149

7.1.1. Community Forestry Index

The Community Forestry index variable was developed following Samad

(2012). Samad (2012) conducted a study on the effectiveness of the Community

Forestry program in Sesaot community forest in Indonesia. She employed three

aspects to measure the effectiveness of the Community Forestry program, namely

land governance, institutional governance and business governance. Each aspect

contained four indicators, which were then combined into a single variable to

measure the effectiveness of the Community Forestry program (see Table 7.2).

Table 7.2 Community Forestry Effectiveness Indicators

Aspect Indicators

Land governance - land size

- plantation composition

- land management skill

- ecological function of the land

Institutional governance - organization pattern

- organization management

- organization independency

- organization cooperation

Business governance - product volume

- product variation

- marketing pattern

- income generation

Source : Samad (2012).

In this thesis, the indicators used by Samad (2012) were modified into eight

indicators to suit the case study conditions. These include: community forest land

size; forest farmers’ capacity to manage the community forest land; Community

Forest Farmer Group (CFFG) accommodation of the forest farmers’ interests; the

activeness of the forest farmers measured by attendance at the CFFG meetings; the

ability of CFFG to solve the forest farmers’ problems; support from NGOs and

governments; stability of the products volume; and stability of the products price

(see Appendix 1.2 question B28). Each indicator was measured on a five Likert

scale (McIver et al., 1994). All the indicators’ scores were thus compounded into a

150

single number as a composite variable using the weighted average method (Nardo

et al., 2005). The highest the index, the better the community forest condition.

7.1.2. Payment for Ecosystem Service Program

Several studies were conducted to measure the impact of the PES programs

on forest conservation and improvement of socio-economic conditions, in particular

for poverty alleviation. As mentioned in Chapters 5 and 6, the PES program was

introduced as an incentive for forest dependent communities to guard and manage

the forest to achieve a sustainable outcome (Wunder, 2005; Pagiola, 2006). At the

same time, PES aims to benefit the poor forest farmers (Duncan, 2006; Pagiola et

al., 2007; Wunder, 2008).

In this thesis, the involvement of the community forest farmers in the PES

program introduced in Sesaot Forest is used as a variable to measure the impact of

the PES program on forest conservation, as well as its implication for the welfare

of forest farmers’ households. Since the enrollment status of the community forest

farmers in the PES program was only categorized into two categories – enrolled

and not enrolled – a dummy variable (Hill et al., 2008, p. 167) was employed to

accommodate this situation. Respondents who were enrolled in PES were coded as

1, and those who were not enrolled were coded as 0 (see Appendix 1.2 question

C1).

7.1.3. Adat/Local institutions

Ostrom (1990, p. 58) suggested that local users of a common resource often

use their own rules and norms to control the use of their common resources. They

may modify their local customary rules over time, based on their past experience

and knowledge in governing these common resources. The employment of local

institutions for norm enforcement has been observed to produce more sustainable

outcomes (Agrawal, 1996), as in the case of irrigation systems in Nepal (Lam, 1999;

Ostrom et al., 1999).

151

Following previous literature, this thesis uses adat practice in Community

Forestry management as a proxy for local institutions that could influence the

sustainable outcome of community forest management, for both conservation and

improvement of socio-economic conditions. The forest farmers were asked about

the extent to which they obey and practice adat rules in governing their community

forest land. The question was designed with a five Likert scale response set to

capture the forest farmers' experience. The more the respondents obey the adat rule,

the highest the score (see Appendix 1.2 question B23).

7.1.4. Property Rights

A previous study conducted by Beyene and Koch (2013) used land tenure

security as a proxy for property rights, to examine the relationship between property

rights, the strength of local institutions, and household preferences for fuelwood

sources in rural Ethiopia. They found that property rights influenced the choice of

fuelwood collection source. In the absence of clearly defined communal property

rights over the natural forest, households prefer to collect fuelwood from the open

access natural forest, which in turn contributes to forest degradation. An assumption

of property right recognition through land tenure security is that changing the status

of natural forest into community forest will lead households to avoid collecting

fuelwood from the community forest that they manage (Beyene and Koch, 2013).

However, this may deflect firewood collection and forest degradation to protected

areas unless sustainable use practices are introduced within the community forest.

Another study also conducted in Ethiopia by Mekonnen (2009) found that tenure

security, which reflects recognition of property rights56, has a significant positive

impact on tree growth in Ethiopian forests.

Another study conducted by Agrawal (2007) suggested that when local

communities were granted property rights to manage forests by the state, they tend

to govern the forest more effectively. In contrast, Gibson et al. (2002) found that in

56 Lands including forests in Ethiopia are owned by the state. The rural households only hold user-

rights to land, with a periodical land-redistribution among villagers. The land cannot be sold,

mortgaged, or exchanged. Villagers are only granted rights to work on the land, with an obligation

to plant trees; which will determine land re-distribution (Mekonnen, 2009; Beyene and Koch, 2013).

152

Guatemala, property rights were a less important factor in determining the quality

of forest management. Following these studies, this thesis considers land tenure

security, as reflected by the possession of a legal permit for the community forest

land, as a proxy for property rights. Since there are only two statuses of the

community forest: permit granted and not granted, a dummy variable was used to

capture this condition (Hill et al., 2008, p. 167). Respondents who have been

granted legal permission to manage the community forest were coded as 1, and

those who have not been granted were coded as 0 (see Appendix 1.2 question B3).

7.1.5. Community Forest Land Size

Land size is often considered as a factor that influences agricultural

outcomes (Rao, Vaman and Chotigeat, 1981; Cornia, 1985). A study by Cornia

(1985) analyzed the relationship between factor inputs, land yields and labor

productivity for farms of different land sizes in 15 developing countries.

Interestingly, she found that in 80% of the countries, there was a strong negative

correlation between farm size and factor inputs and yields per hectare of agricultural

land. However, Rao, Vaman and Chotigeat (1981) found a positive relation between

land size and productivity for the agricultural sector in India. In this thesis, the size

of community forest land, measured in hectares, is considered as one aspect that

could influence forest farmers’ welfare. Community Forestry land size refers to the

size of the community forest land that is managed by a forest farmer. Respondents

were asked about the size of the community forest that they managed (see Appendix

1.2 question B4). The value, which is a continuous number, is then transposed into

a logarithm to improve the goodness of fit and to make the variable more normally

distributed (Keene, 1995; Lütkepohl and Xu, 2012).

7.1.6. Welfare Measure as Proxy for Socio-Economic Conditions

Welfare improvement of the forest farmers who manage the community

forest is considered as a proxy for the improvement in socio-economic conditions.

The welfare variable is a composite variable constructed from seven components

which are the physical living standards as defined and reported yearly by the

Indonesian statistics agency (Riyadi et al., 2015). This data is collected through

153

surveys, including the national social economic survey and the national workforce

survey. The publication reports several measurable aspects of human welfare,

including health and nutrition, education, employment, consumption level and

patterns, housing and environment, poverty, and other social aspects (Riyadi et al.,

2015).

Following the Indonesian welfare indicators, this thesis considers seven

aspects to measure the socio-economic conditions of the forest farmers in Sesaot

community forest. These aspects include house ownership, house condition,

electricity supply, water supply, energy for cooking, transportation and

telecommunication facilities (see Appendix 1.2 Part D for detailed survey

questions). Scores for these aspects were compounded into a single number as a

welfare index variable, using the weighted average method (Nardo et al., 2005).

The highest the score, the better the welfare condition.

7.1.7. Forest Cover

Forest cover data is often used to measure the impact of a conservation

program. A study conducted by Calvo-Alvarado et al. (2009) uses forest cover

change to measure the social dynamics of deforestation and forest restoration

processes in Guanacaste, Costa Rica. Another study conducted by Daniels et al.

(2010) in Costa Rica measures the ecological impact of a PES program. The latter

authors used forest cover as a proxy for forest-based ecosystem services. That study

found that the PES program in Costa Rica contributed significantly to the

restoration of degraded lands.

In this thesis, forest cover is considered as the proxy for conservation

outcomes. The forest cover data was primary data generated from a survey of forest

farmers. Forest farmers were asked about the names of the tree species and their

number that are grown in their community forest land (see Appendix 1.2 question

B8). As a guide to assessing optimum forest cover in a particular land area, a

measure suggested by the Indonesian forest agency is used. The Indonesian forest

agency determines that there should be 400 trees planted in one hectare of forest

154

land, with a planting distance of five by five meters, to generate 100 percent forest

cover (Hendri, 2008).

7.2. Regression Model

The regression models were developed in two variations based on the

research objectives: a model for conservation and a model for socio-economic

conditions.

7.2.1. Model for Conservation

The success of the conservation goal of the Community Forestry and PES

programs in this study is measured by the extent of forest cover. The higher the

forest cover, the better the conservation outcome from forest management. Forest

cover is hypothesized to be influenced by the Community Forestry index, property

rights, forest farmer involvement in the PES program, and farmer’s reported

compliance with adat rules and the size of community forest land. This pattern of

associations is statistically estimated using the following regression:

forcov = β0 + β1cfind+ β2pr, + β3 pes+ β4adat+ β5lgcfland + ε (1.1)

where forcov refers to forest cover, cfind refers to Community Forestry index, pr

refers to property rights, pes refers to PES program, adat refers to adat rules,

lgcfland refers to community forest land size, ε refers to error term that represent

other factors that influence the dependent variable that are not included in this

model, and β0, β1, β2, β3, β4 and β5 refer to regression coefficient or the parameters

of the econometric model.

The expected influence of each independent variable on the dependent variable is

as follows:

1. Influence of Community Forestry index on forest cover

A high Community Forestry index indicates that the farmer practices community

forest management properly. It was hypothesized that the higher the Community

Forestry index, the more trees are planted, thus the higher the forest cover.

155

2. Influence of property rights on forest cover

Security of property rights could be an incentive for the farmer to manage the

forestland better and plant more trees. Thus property rights could positively

influence the forest cover.

3. Influence of PES on forest cover

The PES program provides seeds to be planted in the community forestland. It is

hypothesized that the involvement of forest farmers in the PES program will

increase forest cover.

4. Influence of adat on forest cover

Adat rules are used by the community forest farmer group to regulate the ways in

which the forest farmers manage the community forests. Adat regulations follow

the Ministry of Forestry's requirement that community forest lands have to be

managed properly by maintaining a specified ratio of plantation between endemic

trees and crops. In addition, adat rules prohibit farmers from logging trees in the

community forest. It is thus hypothesized that the more the forest farmers comply

with adat regulations, the higher the forest cover would be on their forestland.

5. Influence of community forest land size and forest cover

The larger the community forest land, the wider the area that forest farmers are able

to plant, thus the greater the proportion of forest cover. Community forest land size

is hypothesized to positively influence forest cover.

7.2.2. Model for Socio-Economic Conditions

As explained above, the welfare index is used as proxy for socio-economic

conditions. The welfare of community forest farmers was hypothesized to be

influenced by the Community Forestry index, the property rights of the forest

farmer over the community forest, farmer involvement in the PES program, farmer

compliance with adat rules, and community forest land size. Thus the regression

model for this situation is as follows:

welfare = β0 + β1cfind + β2pr + β3pes+ β4adat + β5lgcfland + ε (2)

where welfare refers to welfare growth as proxy for socio-economic conditions,

cfind refers to Community Forestry index, pr refers to property rights, pes refers to

156

the PES program, adat refers to adat rules, lgcfland refers to community forest

land size, ε refers to error term representing other factors that influence the

dependent variable that are not included in this model, and β0, β1, β2, β3, β4 and β5

refer to regression coefficient or the parameters of the econometric model.

The dependent variable in this model is welfare growth. This variable

measures the growth of the forest farmer’s welfare during two periods of time:

before the Community Forestry program was introduced in 1998; and after the

program had been well established in 2015. The expected influence of each

independent variable on the dependent variable in this model is as follows:

1. Influence of community forest index on welfare

The Community Forestry index refers to an index of Community Forestry

management practices that are applied by the forest farmers. This index is

constructed from nine factors that form three groups of governance indicators of

Community Forestry as described in section 7.1.1. The factors include land

governance, institutional governance and business governance. A high index

indicates a better Community Forestry practice, which will potentially lead to better

socio-economic outcomes, and thus higher welfare growth.

2. Influence of property rights on welfare

Farmers’ property rights, which are indicated by the legal status of the Community

Forestry land, will assure their security of land access. The survey conducted for

this thesis indicates that the more secure the access, the better the outcome for

farmers’ incomes and economic livelihood. More secure property rights could

impact positively on welfare growth.

3. Influence of PES on welfare

Farmer involvement in the PES program will generate economic benefits, since the

PES program provides cash that is used by the farmers’ group to buy multi-purpose

tree species (MPTS) seeds to be planted in the community forest land. The value of

the seeds could be an immediate economic benefit of the PES program. Further, the

yield produced by the MPTS will be the primary economic benefit for the farmer

in the future. Thus, involvement in the PES program is estimated to increase

welfare.

157

4. Influence of adat on welfare

Failure to follow adat rules may cause the forest farmers to lose their rights to

manage the community forest. They would then suffer economic disadvantage,

since income from the community forest would be decreased as well. Surveys for

this project indicate that farmers who follow adat rules believe they will be granted

secure rights to manage the community forest, thus ensuring their economic benefit

from the community forest. It is therefore hypothesized that if the farmers comply

with adat, welfare will improve.

5. Influence of Community Forestry land size on welfare

Community Forestry land size was estimated to influence welfare growth in regard

to the ability of the households to obtain money by farming on the community forest

land. It was assumed that the larger the land size per household, the more money

the household can obtain, thus the greater the improvement in welfare.

7.3. Regression Process

Several regression models were constructed in this analysis. The first model

includes all independent variables that are hypothesized to influence the dependent

variable. The estimation result of the first model determines whether the model is

the best model or not. To produce the best model, any insignificant variable as a

result of the regression was excluded from the model. After including only

significant variables, the model was tested again. The process was repeated until all

independent variables significantly influence the dependent variable. The criteria

for the best model is that all independent variables significantly influence the

variation of the dependent variable; that there is a high and significant value of F-

statistics; and that there is a high value of adjusted R2.

As mentioned above, this study employs the ordinary least square (OLS)

regression techniques on each model followed by seemingly unrelated regression

(SUR) techniques that combines both models.

158

7.3.1. Ordinary Least Square Regression Analysis

7.3.1.1. Model for Conservation

As mentioned previously, the model for conservation is as follows:

forcov = β0 + β1cfind+ β2pr, + β3 pes+ β4adat + β5lgcfland + ε (1.1)

Descriptive statistics for this model is presented in Table 7.3.

Table 7. 3 Descripive Statistics of Model 1.1

Variable Observation Mean Standard

Deviation

Minimum Maximum

forcov 200 0.65 0.41 0.09 2.51

cfind 200 4.45 0.69 2.59 6.12

pr 200 0.34 0.47 0 1

pes 200 0.49 0.50 0 1

adat 200 3.91 0.59 3 5

lgcfland 200 -0.37 0.25 -1 0.65

Source: Appendix 7.1

The OLS regression result for the above model is:

𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑐𝑜𝑣̂ = −0.277 + 0.071𝑐𝑓𝑖𝑛𝑑 + 0.154𝑝𝑟 − 0.021𝑝𝑒𝑠 + 0.116𝑎𝑑𝑎𝑡 − 0.297𝑙𝑔𝑐𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑

(-1.12) (1.69)* (2.33)** ( -0.37) (2.41)** (-2.57)**

F = 5.69***

Adj R2 = 0.1053

Numbers in the bracket is t statistics

* significant at α 10%

** significant at α 5%

*** significant at α 1%

The OLS result for model 1.1 estimates that all independent variables except

PES significantly influenced the forest cover which is indicated by the significance

value of t statistic, with confidence intervals of 95% and 90%. All of the

159

independent variables simultaneously influence the forest cover, as indicated by the

significant value of the F statistic. The adjusted R2 statistics indicate that the model

can explain the variation of forest cover by 10.53%.

To generate the best model, the insignificant variable, in this case is PES, was then

removed and the second OLS regression was run with the following model.

forcov = β0 + β1cfind + β2pr, + β3adat - β4lgcfland + ε (1.2)

The OLS regression result for the above model is as follows:

𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑐𝑜𝑣̂ = −0.283 + 0.071𝑐𝑓𝑖𝑛𝑑 + 0.147𝑝𝑟 + 0.115𝑎𝑑𝑎𝑡 − 0.301𝑙𝑔𝑐𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑

(-1.14) (1.69)* (2.33)** (2.40)** (-2.62)**

F = 7.1***

Adj R2 = 0.1093

Numbers in the brackets are the t statistics

* significant at α 10%

** significant at α 5%

*** significant at α 1%

All independent variables in Model 1.2 significantly influence forest cover,

partially and simultaneously. The F statistic indicates a stronger simultaneous

influence of all independent variables on forest cover, compared to the previous

model. This model produces an adjusted R2 value of 0.1093 which is higher than

model 1.1.

Model 1.2 is statistically more robust with better goodness of fit and therefore

considered as a better model to explain the variation of forest cover than the

model 1.1.

7.3.1.2. Model for Socio-Economic Conditions

The econometric model for socio-economic conditions is as follow:

welfare = β0 + β1cfind+ β2pr, + β3 pes+ β4adat + β5lgcfland + ε (2.1)

Descriptive statistics for this model is presented in Table 7.4.

160

Table 7.4 Descriptive Statistics of Model 2.1

Variable Observation Mean Standard

Deviation

Minimum Maximum

welfare 200 44.71 16.05 3.08 71.26

cfind 200 4.45 0.69 2.59 6.12

pr 200 0.34 0.47 0 1

pes 200 0.49 0.50 0 1

adat 200 3.91 0.59 3 5

lgcfland 200 -0.37 0.25 -1 0.65

Source: Appendix 7.1

The OLS regression result for this model is as follows:

𝑤𝑒𝑙𝑓𝑎𝑟𝑒̂ = 23.516 + 2.112𝑐𝑓𝑖𝑛𝑑 + 15.098𝑝𝑟 + 1.248𝑝𝑒𝑠 + 2.753𝑎𝑑𝑎𝑡 + 12.618𝑙𝑔𝑐𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑

(2.59)** (1.37) (6.22)*** (0.59) (1.55) (2.98)**

F = 12.21***

Adj R2 = 0.2198

Numbers in the brackets are t statistics

* significant at α 10%

** significant at α 5%

*** significant at α 1%

The OLS regression result for model 2.1 shows that only two independent variables

–property rights and community forestland size– significantly influence welfare,

which is indicated by the significance value of t statistic with confidence intervals

of 99% and 95% respectively. Meanwhile, PES and adat do not significantly

influence welfare. This model produces an F statistic of 12.21 with 99% of

confidence interval that indicates a simultaneous significant influence of all

independent variables on welfare. This model produces an R2 value of 0.2198 that

indicates the ability of this model to explain the variation of welfare by 21.98%.

The next regression removes the PES variable due to its smallest probability to

influence the welfare.

161

welfare = β0 + β1cfind+ β2pr, + β3adat + β4lgcfland + ε (2.2)

The OLS regression result for the model 2.2 is as follows:

𝑤𝑒𝑙𝑓𝑎𝑟𝑒̂ = 23.864 + 2.108𝑐𝑓𝑖𝑛𝑑 + 15.510𝑝𝑟 + 2.813𝑎𝑑𝑎𝑡 + 12.856𝑙𝑔𝑐𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑

(2.63)** (1.37) (6.70)*** (1.59) (2.63)**

F = 15.22***

Adj R2 = 0.2223

Numbers in the brackets are t statistics

* significant at α 10%

** significant at α 5%

*** significant at α 1%

The OLS regression result for model 2.2 shows that the Community

Forestry index and adat did not significantly influence welfare. Property rights and

community forest land size significantly influence farmers’ welfare with confidence

intervals of 99% and 95% respectively. This model produces a higher F statistic and

R2 value than model 2.1

The next model removes adat due to its smallest probability to influence welfare.

welfare = β0 + β1cfind+ β2pr, + β3lgcfland + ε (2.3)

The OLS regression result for model 2.3 is as follows:

𝑤𝑒𝑙𝑓𝑎𝑟𝑒̂ = 33.285 + 2.607𝑐𝑓𝑖𝑛𝑑 + 15.342𝑝𝑟 + 14.378𝑙𝑔𝑐𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑

(4.83)*** (1.73)* (6.61)*** (3.49)***

F = 19.30***

Adj R2 = 0.2162

Numbers in the brackets are t statistics

* significant at α 10%

** significant at α 5%

*** significant at α 1%

After the adat was removed, all independent variables in Model 2.3

significantly influence the welfare, partially and simultaneously, although the

adjusted R2 in this model is lower than the previous one.

162

7.3.2. Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SUR)

The next step is to conduct the seemingly unrelated regression (SUR). At the first

run of SUR, the original models (model 1.1 and model 2.1) were used to compare

the results to the best model (model 1.2 and model 2.3).

The result of the SUR for each model is as follows:

7.3.2.1. SUR for the Original Model of Conservation

𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑐𝑜𝑣̂ = −0.277 + 0.071𝑐𝑓𝑖𝑛𝑑 + 0.154𝑝𝑟 − 0.021𝑝𝑒𝑠 + 0.116𝑎𝑑𝑎𝑡 − 0.297𝑙𝑔𝑐𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑

(-1.13) (1.71)* (2.36)** ( -0.37) (2.45)** (-2.61)**

F = 29.30***

R2 = 0.1278

Numbers in the brackets are t statistics

* significant at α 10%

** significant at α 5%

*** significant at α 1%

The result of SUR analysis for the original model of conservation is similar

to the OLS regression. However, SUR produces higher F-statistics that indicates a

more robust estimation than the OLS regression.

7.3.2.2. SUR for the Original Model of Socio-Economic Conditions

𝑤𝑒𝑙𝑓𝑎𝑟𝑒̂ = 23.516 + 2.112𝑐𝑓𝑖𝑛𝑑 + 15.090𝑝𝑟 + 1.248𝑝𝑒𝑠 + 2.753𝑎𝑑𝑎𝑡 + 12.618𝑙𝑔𝑐𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑

(2.62)** (1.39) (6.32)*** (0.60) (1.58) (3.02)**

F = 62.93***

R2 = 0.2394

Numbers in the brackets are t statistics

* significant at α 10%

** significant at α 5%

*** significant at α 1%

Compared to the OLS regression, the SUR analysis for this model produces

higher F-statistics and higher t-statistics in some variables.

7.3.2.3. SUR for the Best Model of Conservation

𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑐𝑜𝑣̂ = −0.293 + 0.070𝑐𝑓𝑖𝑛𝑑 + 0.147𝑝𝑟 + 0.118𝑎𝑑𝑎𝑡 − 0.303𝑙𝑔𝑐𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑

(-1.20) (1.70)* (2.36)** (2.50)** (-2.67)**

F = 29.47***

163

R2 = 0.1272

Numbers in the brackets are t statistics

* significant at α 10%

** significant at α 5%

*** significant at α 1%

This analysis produce higher F and t statistics compared to the OLS

regression. This result shows that the SUR technique is better than the OLS

regression and produces a more robust estimation.

All independent variables significantly influence forest cover. The

Community Forestry index shows significant influences on forest cover with a

confidence interval of 90%. An increase of the Community Forestry index by 1 unit

will increase forest cover by 0.07%57. Property rights significantly influence forest

cover, with a 95% confidence interval. The farmers who hold inferred property

rights upon the community forestland will have better forest cover. The existence

of property rights will increase the forest cover by 0.147%.

Adat significantly influences forest cover, with a 95% confidence interval.

The farmers who follow adat rules in community forest management tend to have

a better forest cover. An increase of adat compliance by 1 unit will increase the

forest cover by 0.118%. Community forestland size significantly influences forest

cover with a 95% confidence interval. However, the influence goes into a negative

direction. An increase of community forestland size by 1 hectare will reduce forest

cover by 0.303%, which is contrary to the program goals.

7.3.2.4. SUR Estimation for the Best Model of Socio-Economic Conditions

𝑤𝑒𝑙𝑓𝑎𝑟𝑒̂ = 33.285 + 2.607𝑐𝑓𝑖𝑛𝑑 + 15.342𝑝𝑟 + 14.378𝑙𝑔𝑐𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑

(4.88)*** (1.74)* (6.67)*** (3.53)***

F = 59.09***

R2 = 0.2281

Numbers in the brackets are t statistics

* significant at α 10%

** significant at α 5%

*** significant at α 1%

57 All regression analyses in this thesis considers the ceteris paribus condition which is defined as

“other things being equal” (Boumans and Morgan, 2001, p. 13).

164

The SUR analysis for the best model of socio-economic conditions produces

higher F and t statistics compared to the OLS regression technique. Simultaneously,

all of the independent variables significantly influence welfare growth, as indicated

by the F statistic, which holds a value of 59.09 with a confidence interval of 99%.

The R2 value in this model implies that all of the independent variables can explain

the variation of welfare growth by 22.81%.

The Community Forestry index significantly influences welfare growth

with a confidence interval of 90%. An increase of the Community Forestry index

by 1 unit will cause an improvement of welfare growth by 2.6%.

Property rights significantly influence welfare with a confidence interval of

99%. A forest farmer who holds property rights upon community forestland will

have a welfare growth 15.34% higher than those who do not hold property rights.

Similarly, community forestland size significantly influences welfare with

a confidence interval of 99%. The larger the community forest land size, the higher

the welfare growth. An increase of community forestland size by one hectare will

cause an increase of welfare growth by 14.37%.

7.4. Limitation of this study

The quantitative aspects of this study have limitations. The regression

results are not very good in respect to the low R2 statistics. In addition, the number

of observations was limited to only 200 participants. The result would provide

stronger evidence if it accommodated more participants and was conducted in more

than one location.

7.5. Conclusion

Survey evidence suggests that the Community Forestry program has a

positive influence on socio-economic conditions, which is indicated by a positive

relationship between both Community Forestry land size and the Community

Forestry index and welfare improvement of the forest farmers. The larger the land

size, the higher the farmer welfare improvement. Also, the higher the Community

Forestry index, the higher the welfare improvement.

165

The other variable that has had a significant influence on the welfare of the

forest farmers after the establishment of the Community Forestry program is the

expectation of property rights granted to forest farmers upon community forest

land. The forest farmers’ property rights are indicated by the issuance of community

forest land permits. Forest farmers who hold legal permits tend to obtain more

economic benefit than those who have not obtained a legal permit.

Meanwhile, adat rules that are employed in the practice of Community

Forestry does not immediately influence the economic welfare of the forest farmers.

Similarly, the PES program does not yet directly influence the welfare of the forest

farmers.

The Community Forestry program has a positive influence on conservation,

as indicated by the positive relationship between the Community Forestry index

and forest cover. A high Community Forestry index leads to a higher forest cover.

The other factor that contributes to increased forest cover is property rights

of the forest farmer upon community forest land. Forest farmers who have obtained

their property rights, as indicated by holding a legal permit for managing

community forest, tend to foster forest sustainability by planting more trees on the

community forest land.

The employment of adat rules in Community Forestry practice has also

shown a positive influence on forest cover. Forest farmers who report compliance

with adat rules tend to have better forest cover. The more they reportedly obey the

adat rules, the better the forest cover they have.

The community forest land size significantly influences forest cover.

Surprisingly, the relationship is in a negative direction. The larger the land size, the

lower the forest cover. This finding supports the findings from the qualitative

analysis that forest farmers tend to prioritize economic benefits over the

conservation benefit from community forest. They plant more cash crops, such as

coffee, cocoa and banana, rather than conservation trees on their community forest

land.

166

The PES program does not yet demonstrate significant influence on forest

conservation. This is an interesting finding since this condition contradicts PES

theory and the PES program’s goal. This finding will be discussed in the next

chapter, where we consider the results of both the qualitative and quantitative

analysis.

167

Chapter 8

Conclusion and Policy Recommendations

This thesis reviews the development of Community Forestry (CF) and

Payments for Ecosystem Services (PES) programs in Lombok Indonesia and

examines the extent to which these programs impact on forest conservation and

local socio-economic conditions. This study also sought to find out whether local

customary law (adat) can create a positive impact on forest management. An

integrated Community Forestry and PES program in Sesaot Forest in West Lombok

was chosen as the case study location, since this site is one of the pilot Community

Forestry programs in Lombok. By considering the role of these two programs in

forest governance, this case study was designed to contribute to knowledge about

how a common pool resource could be managed to achieve a sustainable outcome.

This study employs a mix of quantitative and qualitative research methods

using an approach that Rao, Vijayendra and Woolcock (2003) called “participatory

econometrics”. It follows three steps in sequence: (1) in-depth interviews were

undertaken with stakeholders; (2) farmer surveys were conducted using instruments

based on the interviews and field visits; (3) hypotheses derived from qualitative

work were then tested using quantitative data. Two rounds of fieldwork were

conducted in the case study location. The first round of fieldwork was done in May–

June 2014, and aimed to collect information related to PES development and

practice through semi-structured interviews with 22 relevant stakeholders including

the PES initiators, a water corporation officer, forest service agency officers, a

regional development plan agency officer, a regional environmental sector officer,

the regional assembly, a Non-Government Organization activist, academics, the

PES program officers, and local community leaders58. The second fieldwork period

58 In Indonesian terms:

- Water corporation : Perusahaan Daerah Air Minum (PDAM)

- Forest service agency : Dinas Kehutanan (Dishut)

- Regional development plan agency : Badan Perencanaan Pembangunan Daerah

(BAPPEDA)

- Local council : Dewan Perwakilan Rakyat Daerah (DPRD)

168

was in January – May 2015, and aimed to clarify data gathered from the first

fieldwork, as well as to collect field data and further information through surveys

with 200 forest farmer households and forest observations in six villages where PES

funds were distributed.

This study is reported in eight chapters. The introductory chapter provides

background introduction and the context of the study, and identifies the research

questions, case study location and methodology. The second chapter deals with

theories and literature on common resources management, Community Forestry

and PES. Chapter three elaborates on the history of forest governance in Indonesia,

including forests in Lombok, the cause of deforestation and forest degradation,

Community Forestry program development, the use of adat in community forest

management, and the role of NGOs in forest management.

Chapter four discusses the development of the PES program in Lombok,

including the establishment of the program, the role of intermediaries, the benefits

delivery system, and challenges and constraints during the program's

implementation. Chapter five critically examines the impact of the Community

Forestry and PES programs on the ecological function of the forest. This chapter

also includes an assessment of the influence of property rights on forest

conservation. Chapter six focuses on the examination of Community Forestry and

the PES program impacts on local socio-economic conditions; in particular, poverty

alleviation.

Chapter seven employs regression analysis to estimate the impact of the

Community Forestry and PES programs on the economy and ecology of these forest

communities, as a complement to the qualitative analysis. Finally, Chapter eight

concludes this thesis. This last chapter presents conclusions and policy

recommendations regarding Community Forestry and the PES program, and

identifies areas requiring further research.

- PES program officers : Institusi Multi Pihak (IMP)

- Local community leaders : Tokoh Masyarakat

169

8.1. Thesis Conclusions

This thesis supports the frequently observed phenomenon that the limited

stocks of natural resources, compared to the number of people who need them, often

leads to resource depletion in the absence of regulations regarding the use of the

resources. The absence of regulations allows everyone to access these resources,

without considering long term sustainability. Unregulated access to the resource

may encourage competition among users, to utilise the resources to maximise their

benefits without assuming rehabilitation costs. Therefore, regulating the use of

natural resources – especially commons resources – becomes necessary to avoid a

situation that Hardin (1968) described as the “tragedy of the commons”, but is

perhaps better understood as the "tragedy of open access" (Fox, 1993). The lack of

control over common resources is often considered as a failure by the state to

maintain the use of these resources in a sustainable manner (Fox et al., 1993). Even

under state control, cooperation between authorities and entrepreneurs might occur

that allows the management of the common resources to be delegated to the private

sector (Reed, 2006; Anderies and Janssen, 2013). The management of common

resources by private enterprises often causes environmental degradation due to

over-exploitation and a lack of rehabilitation. This has been experienced in the case

of forest management in Indonesia, where massive deforestation has occurred as a

result of mismanagement by private enterprises that was not accompanied by

adequate restoration efforts (Saman et al., 1993; Reed, 2006).

This study found that deforestation in Indonesia, including in Lombok, has

occurred since the colonial era. During the developmentalist period of Suharto's

New Order rule between 1966 and 1998 extensive forest degradation occurred due

to corruption and collusion in the timber industry. Forest concessions were granted

by the government to private companies. Forest exploitation by private companies

in Lombok was not followed by adequate forest restoration, nor was the

preservation of high-value old-growth forest and associated biodiversity prioritised.

In addition to these factors, the destruction of forests in Lombok was also caused

by encroachment by villagers, particularly during the political chaos and lack of

law enforcement following the collapse of the New Order regime in 1998.

170

Since 1998, the Indonesian government has encouraged the people who live

in the forests in particular areas of Indonesia to participate proactively in forest

management. In the post-Suharto reform era villagers around the forest are granted

rights to manage forest land under certain terms and conditions. One form of forest

management that involves the local community is called the Community Forestry

management scheme (Hutan Kemasyarakatan, HKm). In the HKm scheme, the

community who reside in the surrounding forest are granted forest management

rights for a specific period. In the case of the Community Forestry program in

Sesaot Forest, the local community have been granted forest management rights for

35 years. Certain rules have been established to achieve both economic and

ecological benefits; for example, by regulating plantation composition. Farmers are

permitted to grow multipurpose tree species (MPTS); tree species that can generate

dual economic and ecological benefits. Indonesian regulations on Community

Forestry allows forest farmers to grow crops and fruit trees together with forest

trees, with a mix of 60% forest trees and 40% MPTS59.

This case study found that the Community Forestry program had a positive

impact on forest sustainability, an outcome that supports the research of Klooster

and Masera (2000), Araujo et al. (2009), Barsimantov and Kendall (2012), Birch et

al. (2014), and Dhakal et al. (2007). Some areas of the forest that were damaged as

a result of the forest concessions held by timber companies in Lombok have been

recovering after the Community Forestry program was developed on the site.

However, the Community Forestry program has also triggered destruction in the

core protected forest zone, often carried out by people who are not involved in the

established Community Forestry program. The destroyed core protected forest

zones were encroached upon and converted into forest farms. In the initial period

of development of the Community Forestry program, this has negatively impacted

on the forest condition, which is in line with the argument of Pirard and Belna

(2012). But after several years, the destroyed lands are replanted with different tree

species, mainly MPTS and other crops. From the perspective of biodiversity

59 The Community forest farmer groups (CFFGs) in Sesaot negotiated the plantation composition

with the regional government. A mix of 30% forest trees and 70% MPTS was agreed as opposed

to the official Forestry Department requirement of a 60 / 40 ratio of endemic forest to MPTS.

171

conservation, the Community Forestry program has made a negative contribution,

due to the elimination of endemic plants that are replaced by horticultural crops and

MPTS such as durian, mango, mangosteen, rambutan, candlenut, coffee, cocoa and

bananas.

On the other hand, the MPTS produce fruits that can serve as a source of

income for local people and at the same time provide ecological benefits such as

oxygen production, carbon sequestration, erosion control, hydrological and other

ecological functions of forests. However, competition between economic and

ecological interests continues to occur. In the case of the community forest practices

in Sesaot, farmers tend to grow plantations that produce more economic benefits.

As a result, the community forest land is dominated by crops and MPTS rather than

forest trees.

Nevertheless, planting MPTS in community forestland has contributed to

the reduction of illegal logging, and has reversed the decline of forest cover in areas

where the program has been established. Forest farmers have an economic incentive

to protect the MPTS. The long-term income from selling fruits that are produced

from MPTS is greater and more sustainable than income from selling timber if the

MPTS were logged. Thus this thesis argues that Community Forestry has

contributed to reducing rates of deforestation, provided that the program’s

application suits the economic needs of the local people.

Decentralised resource management from state to local communities could

contribute to the sustainability of these resources under certain conditions

(Agrawal, 1996; Klooster and Masera, 2000; Araujo et al., 2009; Barsimantov and

Kendall, 2012; Pirard and Belna, 2012; Birch et al., 2014). Local communities who

are well organised and have experience of common traditions in managing their

resources are often able to implement local rules that are agreed upon by members

of the community, to manage the common resource (Ostrom, 2005). Community

forest farmer groups (CFFG) in Sesaot Forest use their local rules (adat) to regulate

the governance of the community forest. Customary rules were adapted and applied

in addition to modified state rules in forest management. Under these adat rules the

172

forest farmers are prohibited from logging trees on community forest land. If this

rule is violated, then the maximum sanction to be imposed is the revocation of the

farmer’s community forest management right by the CFFG. In addition, the farmer

who violates the rule will lose his source of revenue from the community forest.

The adat rules also require farmers to prevent timber theft from their community

forest land. This thesis suggests that adat rules accommodate a participative forest

guardian system that can lead to sustainable forest management. The statistical

analysis shows that the use of adat in community forest governance has a very

modest but positive influence on forest sustainability. Farmers who adhere to the

adat laws tend to have better forest cover.

However, the author’s field research found that the adat rules are not strictly

enforced, especially those related to the tree composition of the plantation. Kinship

and friendship relations among CFFG members remain the biggest obstacles to adat

enforcement. The offenders are often family members and neighbours of CFFG

members, allowing for collusion between the offenders and the law enforcer. Also,

rule enforcers regularly experience intimidation when they attempt to apply

sanctions. Since adat principles stress the importance of harmonious relations, they

work both to encourage respect for commonly agreed rules and to allow a

considerable degree of leeway in their interpretation and application.

This study supports the work of Agrawal and Ostrom (2001), Agrawal

(2007), Araujo et al. (2009) and Birch et al. (2014), who argue that the existence of

property rights influences the behaviour of forest farmers in relation to land

management. The Lombok forest farmers who have gained property rights to

manage the forestland have been shown to be more likely to maintain the quality of

forest cover on their forest land. The statistical analysis confirms that farmers who

hold property rights tend to plant more trees than the farmers without property

rights. A summary of the statistical analysis results, showing that property rights

and adat rules were the factors that had the strongest positive impact on forest

conservation, although not very strong compared to impacts on improvement of

socio-economic conditions, is presented in table 8.1. Supporting Ostrom’s theory,

this thesis reveals that in addition to community self-governance, clearly defined

173

property rights are needed to assure sustainable management of the commons.

Local communities who are granted rights to manage the resources have better

incentives to manage the resources more wisely and sustainably.

Table 8.1 Summary of Statistical Influence of the Community Forestry Index,

Property Rights, Adat Rules, PES and Community Forest Land Size on

Conservation and Socio-economic Conditions

Variables

Influence on

Conservation Socio-economic conditions

Elasticity Confidence

Interval Elasticity

Confidence

Interval

Community Forestry

Index 0.07% 90% 2.60% 90%

Property Rights 0.15% 95% 15.34% 99%

Adat rules 0.12% 95% 2.75% Not

Significant

PES program -0.02% Not

Significant 1.25%

Not

Significant

Community Forest

land size -0.30% 95% 14.38% 99%

Source: Appendix 7.1.

In addition to the self-governing community approach (Ostrom, 2005), this

thesis suggests that external party involvement, which provides checks and balances

to community governance under current circumstances, is also required. The

external party can be a government agency or NGO that acts as the supervisor in

the practice of resource management, such as the community forest management in

this case study. Such a collaborative approach is often called co-management, joint

forest management or a community partnership management scheme (Jentoft,

2003; Persoon et al., 2003; Borrini-Feyerabend et al., 2004; Carlsson and Berkes,

2005; Berkes, 2009; Ulvevadet and Hausner, 2011). In the case of community forest

management in Lombok, the involvement of and assistance from an NGO or the

government has made the community forest farmers able to manage the forest

resources more appropriately, due to the monitoring and technical assistance

provided. The involvement of external parties has provided additional incentives

for the forest farmers not to log the trees, and to obey the state and adat rules.

174

Supporting Baland and Platteau (1996) regarding the role of external authority, this

thesis argues that community forest outcomes, and management patterns such as

logging practices, are correlated with the involvement of outside parties such as

NGOs and government agencies, which monitor and influence the behaviour of

farmers in managing community forestland. This study clarifies that local

community management under certain conditions—involving NGO engagement

and effective state supervision through nested co-management in Sesaot Forest

could be an alternative to state and private enterprise management, previously

regarded as the only viable solutions to Hardin’s tragedy.

In terms of socio-economic outcomes, this study clearly found that

Community Forestry has a positive impact on local socio-economic conditions in

the villages around the community forest site. The most significant socio-economic

benefit from the Community Forestry program is the provision of access to land for

the poor people who do not have private farming land. The Community Forestry

program has been successful in increasing the level of welfare for the forest farmers

involved in the program. The primary source of income for forest farmers is non-

timber forest products, such as crops and MPTS fruits, which are grown on the

community forest land. The Community Forestry program has also provided

indirect socio-economic benefits to people who are not forest farmers. The program

has created new job opportunities for the surrounding community, as traders,

entrepreneurs and in food processing.

The increase in the villagers’ welfare as a result of the Community Forestry

program can be seen in many respects, such as the improved housing conditions,

education level and supporting infrastructure. Housing conditions including home

ownership have improved since the Community Forestry program was established.

The level of education in the villages has also increased significantly following the

establishment of the Community Forestry program. The statistical analysis

confirmed that there is a positive relationship between the Community Forestry

program and farmers’ welfare. Therefore, this thesis supports Gunter and Jodway

(2000), Birch et al. (2014), and Dhakal et al. (2007), but contrasts with Sunderlin,

William D. (2006) and Maryudi et al. (2012), who found no such association.

175

However, there is a trade-off between conservation and livelihood goals, where

farmers tend to plant MPTS, which provide greater economic benefits but may

compromise conservation values, especially in regard to biodiversity. This could be

related to the weak enforcement of the conservation regulations, and has resulted in

the programs having so far tended to provide income benefits at the expense of

some conservation values. As we can see from the statistical data in table 8.1, a

larger land size was accompanied by an improvement in socio-economic conditions

but relatively a lower benefit for conservation.

Similar to the conditions arising from forest management by private

companies in Indonesia, community management can clearly also cause negative

externalities that impact negatively on the welfare of other people and the

environment. This study ascertains that payments for the ecosystem services

program (PES) can address these externalities. A PES program in Lombok has been

integrated with the Community Forestry program to overcome forest degradation

affecting watersheds by raising conservation funds from water users in urban areas.

The raised money is allocated for tree planting in the upstream area. In order to

enforce broad community participation, the government has created local

regulations on ecosystem services; requiring all water users in the city to contribute

to the provision of funding for forest conservation through the PES program. These

programs are often designed to balance the benefits between environmental

conservation and poverty reduction (Ferraro and Kiss, 2002; Pagiola et al., 2005;

Wunder, 2005; Pagiola, 2007; Bremer et al., 2014).

Payments for ecosystem services programs in many countries have been

developed primarily based on Coasean theory (Coase, 1960), where voluntary

transactions occur between ecosystem services buyers and sellers under market

conditions (Muradian, Roldan et al., 2010; Sattler and Matzdorf, 2013).

Alternatively, Pigouvian theory (Pigou, 1932) can also be used as a basis for

implementing PES programs in which the government plays a role, either by

providing subsidies or collecting taxes to fund the provision of ecosystem services

(Yandle, 1997; Sattler and Matzdorf, 2013).

176

Following Pirard (2012), this study found that the PES program in Lombok

is a hybrid PES system that combines Coasean and Pigouvian theory. Coasean

theory is applied on the supply side, where a voluntary transaction occurs between

forest farmers and the PES project manager. On the other hand, on the demand side,

Pigouvian theory is applied. In this case, government intervention exists to force

urban water users to pay contributions for the provision of ecosystem services and

long-term sustainability.

Regarding the impact of PES program on forest coservation, this study

found an interesting evidence. There is a contrast between the finding of qualitative

and quantitative analysis. The quantitative analysis found that the PES program in

Lombok does not yet demonstrate significant influence on forest conservation. On

the other hand, the qualitative analysis found that the PES program has a positive

influence on forest conservation. Considering the strongest evidence provided by

qualitative analysis, the conclusion was generated from this method.

This study sugests that PES programs have contributed positively to forest

conservation in Lombok, which supports the work of other scholars such as

Prasetyo et al. (2009), Clements et al. (2010), Wunder and Albán (2008), and

Matthew et al. (2010). After the PES program was established in Lombok for

several years, forest cover increased significantly in the project location.

Although the direct economic benefits of the PES program in Lombok have

yet to materialize, due to the regulatory requirement that money from PES has to

be used for tree planting, it can be assumed that there will be long-term economic

as well as ecological benefits. The long-term economic benefits of planting MPTS

will be seen after the MPTS produce fruit. The potential revenue generated from

the fruit motivates farmers to protect and maintain the MPTS trees. Thus this thesis

argues that the hybrid PES program in Lombok, in conjunction with the Community

Forestry program, could produce a sustainable outcome in the long term.

In general, PES programs can have a direct impact on the socio-economic

conditions of farmers who are enrolled in the program, if payments are made in

cash and are allowed to be used as extra income. However, there are no significant

177

short term direct economic benefits of PES schemes in Lombok, as the money from

PES schemes is still relatively limited and can only be used for conservation

activities.

8.2. Policy Recommendations

The high rate of deforestation in Indonesia clearly requires serious and

immediate attention from the Indonesian government. However, given the limited

capacity of both financial and human resources, an alternative solution is needed in

which forest management can produce conservation goals while also contributing

to the empowerment and wellbeing of local communities surrounding the forest.

The findings of this thesis, that the Community Forestry program has been

relatively successful in achieving sustainability as well as improvement of socio-

economic conditions, suggests that the Indonesian government should devote

greater consideration to developing effective Community Forestry and PES

programs to control deforestation.

At the same time, the Community Forestry program was found to produce

some negative impacts on the environment. This research found that the

Community Forestry program did attract forest farmers into areas of natural forest

previously degraded by commercial logging. In the Lombok Sesaot Forest case

some groups of people who were not previously involved in the program

encroached on primary forest areas in order to convert them into forest farms. Under

these conditions, the government faces a dilemma between its responsibility to

protect forest resources and the obligation to fulfil the people's welfare needs. It can

be argued that the government should exert strong controls when core protected

forest zones are converted into forest farms to prevent massive or excessive forest

conversion.

The local government needs to provide assistance and monitor the

community forest farmers to ensure adat and state rules on community forest

management are enforced. Additional interventions are required to build

community capacity to develop activities such as post-harvest processing

businesses that would enable the non-forest farmer villagers to also enjoy the

178

economic benefits of the Community Forestry program. For instance, the local

government could provide training programs for processing of forest products,

providing soft loans to support these businesses, opening markets for their products,

and improving rural infrastructure that would extend the success of Community

Forestry and its related businesses. Under the new Village Law (2014), local

communities themselves now have expanded budgets that could be used for these

purposes.

The major problem of protecting biodiversity lost due to the replacement of

endemic tree species with horticultural crops and MPTS also needs to be addressed.

This negative impact can be remedied through efforts that encourage community

forest farmers’ communities to replant tree species that have been lost; as well as

preventing further loss. Government can take a role in providing the seeds for

replanting; however, given that the community forest farmers have prioritized

economic benefits over ecological ones, rules related to the plantation composition

on community forest lands need to be re-enforced and effectively monitored. In this

case, the existing schemes of co-management need to be improved. The community

forest farmers' groups should be re-empowered by providing assistance from either

forestry agencies or related NGOs to enforce compliance with adat rules. The

potential economic consequence of strict enforcement could be compensated by

revising the PES scheme to enable more direct income benefits to be paid to

Community Forest members, with payments scaled according to the proportion of

endemic trees planted. To increase the benefits and coverage of the PES scheme, it

would be necessary to include industrial users and prohibit or increase charges for

ground water use.

There is an irony in the success of the Community Forestry program, given

the actual legal status of community forest management rights. In most cases the

official property rights for community forest management have not been formally

granted. Since clearly defined property rights to manage forests affect the

sustainability of the forest, it is recommended that the Indonesian Ministry of

Forestry should issue official licences, with clearly defined conditions, to the entire

community of forest farmers.

179

Indonesian government budget constraints with regard to supporting

community forest management could be addressed through expanding and revising

the PES programs. This study found that the PES program developed in West

Lombok has contributed to increased forest cover. Nevertheless, inequities exist

related to the PES retribution that is charged to water consumers. The PES rates are

equal for all households and industries regardless of the amount of water consumed

or its purpose. Small families or small industries that consume less water pay the

same flat fee as larger families or industries that consume more water, and there is

no differentiation between water use for basic needs and for luxury consumption,

for example in the tourism industry. Ideally, the PES retribution fee should be

specified proportionally, depending on the amount of water consumed. Revision of

PES rates along lines that address these inequities could also fund the expansion of

the scheme supporting Community Forestry program improvement.

Considering the large number of farmers who are willing to participate in

the PES program, it is necessary for the government of West Lombok to increase

the availability of PES funds to support them. This would be possible by increasing

PES contributions so that the PES fund is large enough to be distributed to more

Community Forest Farmers’ Groups (CFFGs). Funding an expanded and more

comprehensive CFFG scheme will enable more degraded forests to be restored. The

PES rate in West Lombok is currently very small and needs to be revised. The high

enthusiasm of the forest farmers to join the PES program is an opportunity for the

government to bring the conservation program and welfare goals into better

alignment.

The effectiveness of the current PES program in West Lombok clearly

requires review. Many industries do not consume water from the regional water

corporation (PDAM) and thus avoid contributing to the PES program. The

government should enforce a policy that requires them to participate. Even though

these industries do not use water delivered by PDAM, the underground water

supplies that they tap into are also influenced by the existence and quality of the

forest. If the forest is damaged, then supply of underground water may also be

disrupted. The local government could modify the PES regulation to restrict and

180

increase the tax on water extraction and divert a proportion of the PES funds to

local government for improving management, infrastructure, and public education

on water use and ecosystem services.

Because the PES regulation under study has been issued by the West

Lombok government, it cannot be enforced in other districts. This has led to a free

rider problem, where the residents of the City of Mataram, who are the largest

consumers of water from PDAM, do not contribute directly to the PES fund. This

problem can be solved through a PES regulation that is issued by a higher level of

government, enabling the policy to be enforced across districts – in this case at the

level of the provincial government of West Nusa Tenggara. This policy would

require that it is compulsory for all ecosystem services users in the province to pay

the PES fees.

The Community Forestry and PES programs should be adjusted to the

specific needs of the local community. The empirical evidence shows that by

accommodating local needs, integrated PES and Community Forestry programs, if

managed effectively, can be used as a tool for forest conservation and improvement

of socio-economic conditions in the long term.

8.3. Future Research

This research has several limitations. First, the thesis focused primarily on

the watershed protection dimension of forest conservation, rather than their

biodiversity functions; Second, surveys for this study were only conducted in

communities that have been involved in the Community Forestry and PES

programs. They are not compared with other communities where such programs

were not available. Third, the PES analysis is focused on the supply rather than the

demand side.

Considering the negative impact of the Community Forestry program on

biodiversity, research into the details and value of the biodiversity lost, and into

policy mechanisms for halting and reversing this loss, would enrich this research

181

finding greatly. Such a study would also help to fill the gap in biodiversity valuation

studies in less developed countries (Christie et al., 2012).

As this research has focused primarily on the supply side of the PES system,

further research which brings together both the supply and demand sides of PES is

desirable, to produce a comprehensive analysis of PES as a whole system. Research

is needed to investigate the differential capacity of domestic and industrial water

consumers to pay for these essential ecosystem services. Although such research

had been conducted before the PES program in Lombok was designed (Konsepsi,

2003), an up-to-date analysis is needed, as the price of goods and services has

increased significantly. This will enable the local government to increase the PES

contribution.

On the supply side, further research is needed to expand the funds available

and to determine the best method to increase and distribute PES payments, so that

some payments go directly to covering the full cost of planting and can create

immediate income to forest farmers. Research should also look at the best means of

linking payments to outcomes, and should take account of transaction costs in

monitoring these. It is concluded that with immediate evidence-based alterations to

improve effectiveness, and with appropriate ongoing evaluation and revision, the

Community Forestry and PES schemes offer the most promising option for

addressing forest conservation while improving long term socio-economic

conditions in rural areas across Indonesia.

182

Appendixes

Appendix 1.1. Questionnaire for Household Survey (Bahasa Indonesia

Version)

PENGELOLAAN HUTAN KEMASYARAKATAN YANG

BERKELANJUTAN DI LOMBOK, INDONESIA

DAFTAR PERTANYAAN

Disiapkan oleh:

Diswandi

Kandidat PhD

Pusat Studi Asia, Universitas Murdoch

Australia Barat

QUESTIONNAIRE FOR HOUSEHOLD SURVEY

Nomor Kuesioner………………………… (100)

PERNYATAAN

Partisipasi dalam survey ini bersifat sukarela. Penelitian ini akan sangat bermanfaat jika Anda

berpartisipasi. Dengan berpartisipasi dalam penelitian ini, Anda akan berkontribusi pada

pengembangan dan perbaikan kebijakan Pengelolaan Hutan Kemasyarakatan dan Program

Pembayaran Jasa Lingkungan yang diharapkan memberikan manfaat ekonomi dan ekologi bagi

masyarakat. Kami menghargai hak Anda untuk menolak. Anda boleh memilih untuk tidak menjawab

suatu pertanyaan manapun atau berhenti berpartisipasi kapanpun selama proses wawancara.

Dengan berpartisipasi dalam survey ini berarti Anda setuju bahwa kutipan pendapat dan pandangan

Anda akan digunakan dalam publikasi penelitian ini.

183

Nama Desa: ……………………………… (101)

Tanggal: ………………………….……. (102)

BAGIAN A: IDENTITAS RESPONDEN

A1. Kode rumah tangga : …………………………………… (103)

A2. Nama Responden utama: ……………………………………………... (104)

Nama Responden lain: …………………………………………………... (105)

A3. Usia

Responden

Utama

(106)

A4. Jenis

Kelamin

Responden

utama

(107)

A5. Etnis

Responden

Utama

(108)

A6.

Kepala

Rumah

Tangga

(responden

utama) (109)

A7. Tingkat

Pendidikan

tertinggi dalam

rumah tangga (110)

A8. Jumlah

Anggota

Rumah tangga?

(111)

………

tahun

a. Laki-laki

b. Perempuan

c. Laki laki

dan

Perempuan

a. Sasak

b. Bali

c. Samawa

d. Mbojo

e. Jawa

f. Bugis

g. Lainnya

h. Ya

i. Tidak

a. Sekolah Dasar

(SD)

b. Sekolah

Menengah

Pertama

(SMP)

c. Sekolah

Menengah

Atas (SMA)

d. Sarjana

e. Pasca Sarjana

……… orang

A9. Sudah berapa lama Anda tinggal di desa ini? (112)

…………………… tahun

A10. Apakah Anda memiliki atau mempergunakan lahan? (113)

a. Ya

b. Tidak

184

Jika Ya, jelaskan:

No Lokasi Digunakan Untuk Luas (ha) Tipe Hak

a b c d

1 (114) (115) (116) (117)

2 (118) (119) (120) (121)

3 (122) (123) (124) (125)

4 (126) (127) (128) (129)

185

BAGIAN B. PENGELOLAAN HUTAN KEMASYARAKATAN (HKm)

B1. Apa nama Kelompok HKm tempat Anda tergabung dan siapa nama ketua

bloknya? (200)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B2. Sudah berapa lama Anda menjadi anggota Kelompok HKm ini?

……………….. tahun (201)

B3. Apakah lahan HKm Anda memiliki ijin resmi? (202)

a. Ya

b. Tidak

B4. Berapa luas lahan HKm yang Anda kelola? ……………………… hektar (203)

Catatan: Tandai lokasi lahan HKm dalam peta

B5. Bagaimana Anda memperoleh lahan tersebut? (204)

a. Pembagian oleh pemerintah

b. tukar lahan (ganti rugi)

c. membeli

d. diwarisi

B6. Silahkan tentukan dan beri peringkat, manfaat yang Anda peroleh dari HKm! (205)

a. Penghasilan (uang)

b. Makanan

c. Bahan bakar

d. Air

e. Makanan ternak

f. Pembayaran Jasa Lingkungan

g. Penjualan Karbon (REDD)

h. Obat-obatan

i. Lainnya, sebutkan: ………………… (206)

B7. Siapakah yang menentukan jenis tanaman yang akan ditanam di lahan HKm? (207)

a. Suami

b. Istri

c. Kelompok HKm

d. LSM

e. Pemerintah

f. IMP

g. Lainnya, sebutkan: …………………………………….……. (208)

186

B8. Sebutkan berapa jumlah pohon yang ada dalam lahan Anda:

No Nama Pohon Jumlah Keterangan

(a. Kayu/b. MPTS)

1 Mahoni (209a) (209b)

2 Sengon (210a) (210b)

3 Bajur (211a) (211b)

4 Rajumas (212a) (212b)

5 Durian (213a) (213b)

6 Rambutan (214a) (214b)

7 Manggis (215a) (215b)

8 Kemiri (216a) (216b)

9 Pinang (217a) (217b)

10 Sawo (218a) (218b)

11 Melinjo (219a) (219b)

12 Aren (220a) (220b)

13 Kepundung (221a) (221b)

14 Jambu (222a) (222b)

15 Alpukat (223a) (223b)

16 Nangka (224a) (224b)

17 Kopi (225a) (225b)

18 Coklat (226a) (226b)

19 Matoa (227a) (227b)

20 Mengkudu (228a) (228b)

21 Lainnya (229a) (229b)

Jumlah (230a)

Proporsi Kayu (230b)

Proporsi MPTS (230c)

187

B9. Jelaskan secara rinci produk HKm Anda:

No Produk Volume Dikonsumsi

(%)

Dijual

(%)

Harga

Pasar

Periode

Panen

dalam

setahun

Nilai dalam

setahun

Penghasilan

dalam setahun

a b C d e f g

1 Kopi (231a) (231b) (231c) (231d) (231e) (231f) (231g)

2 Coklat (232a) (232b) (232c) (232d) (232e) (232f) (232g)

3 Kemiri (233a) (233b) (233c) (233d) (233e) (233f) (233g)

4 Durian (234a) (234b) (234c) (234d) (234e) (234f) (234g)

5 Rambutan (235a) (235b) (235c) (235d) (235e) (235f) (235g)

6 Cengkeh (236a) (236b) (236c) (236d) (236e) (236f) (236g)

7 Pisang (237a) (237b) (237c) (237d) (237e) (237f) (237g)

8 Kayu balok (238a) (238b) (238c) (238d) (238e) (238f) (238g)

9 Kayu bakar (239a) (239b) (239c) (239d) (239e) (239f) (239g)

10 Jahe, dsb. (240a) (240b) (240c) (240d) (240e) (240f) (240g)

11 Sayuran (241a) (241b) (241c) (241d) (241e) (241f) (241g)

12 Madu (242a) (242b) (242c) (242d) (242e) (242f) (242g)

13 Lainnya:

………….

(243)

(243a) (243b) (243c) (243d) (243e) (243f) (243g)

TOTAL (244) (245)

B10. Apa saja jenis sumber pendapatan lain dalam rumah tangga Anda? (246)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B11. Berapa total pendapatan rumah tangga Anda dalam sebulan? (247)

Rp ……………………………………

188

B12. Berapa penghasilan yang Anda belanjakan untuk:

No Jenis Pengeluaran Jumlah

Periode

Pengeluaran

Jumlah dalam

Setahun

a b c

1 Makanan (248a) (248b) (248c)

2 Rumah (sewa atau

cicil)

(249a) (249b) (249c)

3 Pendidikan (250a) (250b) (250c)

4 Kesehatan (251a) (251b) (251c)

5 Bayar hutang (252a) (252b) (252c)

6 Pakaian (253a) (253b) (253c)

7 Listrik, Telpon,

Bahan Bakar

(254a) (254b) (254c)

8 Upacara adat dan

keagamaan

(255a) (255b) (255c)

9 Tabungan (256a) (256b) (256c)

TOTAL (257)

B13. Apakah Anda setuju bahwa HKm berkontribusi meningkatkan kualitas nafkah

rumah tanga Anda? (258)

a. Sangat Tidak Setuju

b. Tidak Setuju

c. Netral

d. Setuju

e. Sangat Setuju

Kenapa? (259)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B14. Apakah Anda setuju bahwa HKm berkontribusi meningkatkan kualitas nafkah

masyarakat desa ini atau anggota Kelompok HKm pada umumnya? (260)

a. Sangat Tidak Setuju

b. Tidak Setuju

c. Netral

d. Setuju

e. Sangat Setuju

189

Kenapa? (261)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B15. Apakah Anda setuju bahwa HKm berkontribusi dalam menurunkan tingkat

kemiskinan di desa ini? ((262)

a. Sangat Tidak Setuju

b. Tidak Setuju

c. Netral

d. Setuju

e. Sangat Setuju

Kenapa? (263)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B16. Apakah Anda dulu pernah menebang pohon - pohon di lahan HKm Anda? (264)

a. Tidak Pernah

b. Jarang

c. Kadang-kadang

d. Sering

e. Sangat sering

Kenapa? (265)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B17. Apakah Anda sekarang masih menebang pohon - pohon di lahan HKm Anda? (266)

a. Tidak Pernah

b. Jarang

c. Kadang-kadang

d. Sering

e. Sangat sering

Kenapa? (267)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B18. Apakah pohon - pohon di lahan HKm Anda pernah dicuri? (268)

a. Tidak Pernah

b. Jarang

c. Kadang-kadang

d. Sering

e. Sangat sering

B19. Bagaimana dengan orang lain? Apakah mereka sekarang masih menebang

pohon - pohon di hutan ini? (269)

a. Tidak Pernah

b. Jarang

c. Kadang-kadang

d. Sering

e. Sangat sering

190

Kenapa? (270)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B20. Jenis aturan apa yang diterapkan dalam pengelolaan hutan di desa ini? (271)

a. Aturan adat

b. Aturan Negara

c. Keduanya

d. Aturan lainnya, sebutkan: ………………………………. (272)

e. Tidak tahu

B21. Apa contoh aturan tentang pengelolaan hutan yang harus ditaati, dan apa

sanksinya jika dilanggar? (273)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B22. Apa yang Anda ketahui tentang penerapan aturan adat (awiq-awiq) dalam

pengelolaan hutan? (274)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B23. Apakah Anda mentaati aturan adat (awiq-awiq) dalam pengelolaan hutan? (275)

a. Sangat Tidak Mentaati

b. Tidak Mentaati

c. Netral

d. Mentaati

e. Sangat Mentaati

f. Tidak tahu awiq-awiq

Kenapa? (276)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B24. Sejak Anda bergabung dalam kelompok HKm, bagaimana perubahan jumlah

pohon kayu dalam lahan HKm Anda? (277)

a. Sangat meningkat

b. Meningkat

c. Sama

d. Menurun

e. Sangat menurun

B25. Apakah Anda setuju bahwa HKm berkontribusi menurunkan/menghentikan

kerusakan hutan? (278)

a. Sangat Tidak Setuju

b. Tidak Setuju

c. Netral

d. Setuju

e. Sangat Setuju

Kenapa? (279)

……………………………………………………………………………………

191

B26. Apakah Anda setuju bahwa adat (awiq-awiq) berdampak positif dalam

pengelolaan hutan? (280)

a. Sangat Tidak Setuju

b. Tidak Setuju

c. Netral

d. Setuju

e. Sangat Setuju

Dalam hal apa? (281)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B27. Seberapa penting pendampingan LSM/Pemerintah terhadap kelompok HKm? (282)

a. Sangat tidak penting

b. Tidak penting

c. Netral

d. Penting

e. Sangat penting

Kenapa? Jelaskan bagaimana peranannya? (283)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B28. Silahkan berikan peringkat atas penilaian HKm berikut:

Kriteria Indikator Sangat

Tidak

Setuju

Tidak

Setuju

Netral Setuju Sangat

Setuju

Tata Kelola

Lahan

Luas lahan anda cukup

memadai (284)

Komposisi tanaman Anda

sesuai aturan HKm (70%

pohon kayu : 30% tanaman

serba guna/MPTS) (285)

Anda memiliki kemampuan

yang baik dalam mengelola

lahan (286)

Tata Kelola

Lembaga

Kelompok HKm

Kepentingan Anda

diakomodasi dengan baik

oleh kelompok HKm (287)

Anda sering menghadiri

pertemuan, rapat kerja dan

program pengembangan

kapasitas yang dilaksanakan

oleh Kelompok HKm (288)

192

Kriteria Indikator Sangat

Tidak

Setuju

Tidak

Setuju

Netral Setuju Sangat

Setuju

Kelompok HKm Anda

mampu menyelesaikan

permasalahan kelompok

secara mandiri (289)

Anda mendapatkan

dukungan yang memadai

dari pemerintah, LSM,

Universitas dan pihak

terkait lainnya (290)

Tata Kelola

Usaha

Lahan Anda memproduksi

/menghasilkan komoditas

dalam jumlah yang rata-rata

stabil (291)

Harga pasar komoditas

HKm yang Anda hasilkan,

stabil (292)

B29. Menurut Anda, apa hal negatif atau kekurangan dari program HKm? (293)

……………………………………………………………………………………

Kenapa? (294)

……………………………………………………………………………………

B30. Silakan memberi komentar atau saran untuk peningkatan program HKm. (295)

………………………………………………………………………………………

193

BAGIAN C. PROGRAM PEMBAYARAN JASA LINGKUNGAN (JASLING)

C1. Apakah Anda tergabung dalam program Jasling? (300)

a. Ya

b. Tidak Jika tidak, lanjutkan ke

pertanyaan C8

Jelaskan alasan kenapa Anda bergabung atau kenapa tidak bergabung? (301)

……………………………………………………………………………………

C2. Dalam program Jasling apa Anda terlibat? (302)

……………………………………………………………………………………

C3. Sudah berapa lama Anda bergabung dalam program Jasling ini? ……………….

tahun (303)

C4. Manfaat apa saja yang Anda peroleh dari program Jasling:

No Jenis Jumlah /

Kuantitas

Periode Total Nilai

dalam

setahun

a b c

1 Uang tunai (304a) (304b) (304c)

2 Bibit (305a) (305b) (305c)

3 Modal kerja (306a) (306b) (306c)

4 Non Material,

…………………….. (307)

(307a) (307b) (307c)

5 Lainnya,

……………………….(308)

(308a) (308b) (308c)

C5. Jelaskan penggunaan uang dari jasling, mayoritas untuk keperluan apa? (309)

………………………………………………..………………………………………

C6. Apakah Anda setuju bahwa program Jasling berkontribusi dalam meningkatkan

kualitas kehidupan rumah tangga Anda? (310)

a. Sangat Tidak Setuju

b. Tidak Setuju

c. Netral

d. Setuju

e. Sangat Setuju

Kenapa? (311)

……………………………………………………………………………………

194

C7. Apakah Anda setuju bahwa program Jasling berkontribusi terhadap peningkatan

kualitas kehidupan masyarakat desa pada umumnya? (312)

a. Sangat Tidak Setuju

b. Tidak Setuju

c. Netral

d. Setuju

e. Sangat Setuju

Kenapa? (313)

……………………………………………………………………………………

C8. Apakah Anda setuju bahwa program Jasling berkontribusi terhadap penurunan

tingkat kemiskinan di Desa ini? (314)

a. Sangat Tidak Setuju

b. Tidak Setuju

c. Netral

d. Setuju

e. Sangat Setuju

Kenapa? (315)

……………………………………………………………………………………

Untuk responden yang tidak terlibat dalam Jasling, lanjutkan ke pertanyaan

C11

C9. Sejak Anda terlibat dalam program Jasling, bagaimana perubahan jumlah

pohon kayu dalam lahan HKm Anda? (316)

a. Sangat meningkat

b. Meningkat

c. Sama

d. Menurun

e. Sangat menurun

C10. Apakah Anda setuju bahwa program Jasling membawa perubahan pada

peningkatan jumlah dan kualitas pohon di hutan ini? (317)

a. Sangat Tidak Setuju

b. Tidak Setuju

c. Netral

d. Setuju

e. Sangat Setuju

Kenapa? (318)

……………………………………………………………………………………

C11. Apakah Anda setuju bahwa aturan pengelolaan hutan sebagai syarat untuk

memperoleh kompensasi jasling (misalnya tidak boleh menebang kayu) sesuai

harapan Anda? (319)

a. Sangat Setuju

195

b. Tidak Setuju

c. Netral

d. Setuju

e. Sangat setuju

Kenapa? (320)

……………………………………………………………………………………

C12. Menurut Anda, hal negatif atau kekurangan apa yang ada dalam program

Jasling? (321)

….…………………………………………………………………………………

Kenapa? (322)

……………………………………………………………………………………

C13. Silahkan memberikan komentar atau saran bagi peningkatan program Jasling. (323)

……………………………………………………………………………………

BAGIAN D: KEADAAN EKONOMI RUMAH TANGGA

KRITERIA SEBELUM

1998

SEKARANG

2015

A B

D1. Kepemilikan

rumah

(400)

Menumpang

bersama keluarga

Menyewa

Memiliki rumah

(401)

Menumpang bersama

keluarga

Menyewa

Memiliki rumah

D2. Kondisi rumah Tembok: (402)

Bambu

Kayu

Bata

Lantai: (404)

Tanah

Semen

Keramik

Tembok: (403)

Bambu

Kayu

Bata

Lantai: (405)

Tanah

Semen

Keramik

D3. Saluran Listrik (406)

Tidak ada listrik

Berbagi (Mengalir

dari tetangga)

Jaringan PLN

Punya Genzet

(407)

Tidak ada listrik

Berbagi (Mengalir

dari tetangga)

Jaringan PLN

Punya Genzet

D4. Saluran Air bersih (408)

Sungai/Mata Air

(409)

Sungai/Mata Air

196

KRITERIA SEBELUM

1998

SEKARANG

2015

A B

Sumur bersama

Sumur pribadi

Pipa/Ledeng Umum

Pipa /Ledeng pribadi

Sumur bersama

Sumur pribadi

Pipa/Ledeng Umum

Pipa /Ledeng pribadi

D5. Bahan Bakar

untuk memasak

(410)

Kayu

Minyak

Gas

Listrik

Bahan bakar nabati

(411)

Kayu

Minyak

Gas

Listrik

Bahan bakar nabati

D6. Transportasi (412)

Tidak memiliki

kendaraan

Sepeda

Sepeda Motor

Mobil/Truk/bemo

(413)

Tidak memiliki

kendaraan

Sepeda

Sepeda Motor

Mobil/Truk/Bemo

D7. Telekomunikasi (414)

Tidak memiliki HP

Memiliki satu HP

Memiliki lebih dari

satu HP

(415)

Tidak memiliki HP

Memiliki satu HP

Memiliki lebih dari

satu HP

“Terima Kasih atas dukungan dan partisipasi Anda”

197

Appendix 1.2. Questionnaire for Household Survey (English Version)

SUSTAINABLE COMMUNITY FORESTRY MANAGEMENT IN

LOMBOK, INDONESIA

QUESTIONNAIRE

Prepared by:

Diswandi

PhD Candidate

Asia Research Centre, Murdoch University

Western Australia

QUESTIONNAIRE FOR HOUSEHOLD SURVEY

(COMMUNITY FORESTRY USER GROUP MEMBERS)

DISCLAIMER

Participation in this survey is entirely voluntary. This study would greatly benefit from your

participation. By participating in this research, you will contribute to policy development and

improvement of Community Forestry and Payment for Ecosystem Services system which is

intended to deliver economic and ecological benefit for the public. However, we respect your

rights to decline. You can choose not to respond to any question or to withdraw from

participation in this survey at any time during the interview.

Participating in this survey means you agree for any excerpt or quote of your opinions and

views to be used in publication of this research.

198

Questionnaire number: …………

Name of Village: ………………………… Date: ……………………………

PART A RESPONDENT IDENTITY

A1. Household code: ………………………………………………

A2. Main respondent’s name: …………………………………………

Others respondent’s name: ………………………………………...

A3. Main

Respondent’s

Age

A4. Respondents’

sex

A5. Main

Respondent’s

ethnicity

A6.

Household

leader

(main

respondent)

A7. The highest

education level in

the household

A8.

Number of

household

members

………

years

d. Male

e. Female

f. Male and

Female

a. Sasak

b. Bali

c. Samawa

d. Mbojo

e. Jawa

f. Bugis

g. Others

a. Yes

b. No

a. Primary School

b. Junior High

School

c. Senior High

School

d. Undergraduate

e. Postgraduate

………

people

A9. How long have you been living in this village?

……………………………….. years

A10. Do you have or use land?

a. Yes

b. No

If yes, please explain:

No Location Use for Size (ha) Type of right

a b c d

1

2

3

4

5

199

PART B. COMMUNITY FORESTRY (CF) MANAGEMENT

B1. What Community Forestry User Group (CFUG) are you involved in?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B2. How long have you been a member of this CFUG?

……………….. years

B3. Does your CF land have a legal permit?

a. Yes

b. No

B4. What is the size of your CF land? ……………………… hectare

Note: mark the location on map

B5. How did you get the land?

a. Granted by government

b. Swapped

c. Bought

d. Inherited

B6. Please specify and rate the benefits you obtain from CF.

a. Income

b. Food

c. Fuel

d. Water

e. Fodder

f. PES

g. Carbon/REDD

h. Medicine

i. Others, please specify: ……………

B7. Who decides the types of use of your land?

a. Husband

b. Wife

c. CFUG

d. NGO

e. Government

f. IMP

g. Others, please specify:

…………………………………………………….…….

200

B8. Please specify the name and number of trees on your land:

No Trees’ Name Total Remark

(a. Wood Trees / b. MPTS)

1 Mahogany

2 Sangon

3 Bajur

4 Rajumas

5 Durian

6 Rambutan

7 Mangoesten

8 Candlenut

9 Pinang

10 Sawo

11 Melinjo

12 Aren

13 Kepundung

14 Jambu

15 Avocado

16 Jackfruit

17 Coffee

18 Cocoa

19 Matoa

20 Mengkudu

21 Others

Total

Proportion of wood trees

Proportion of MPTS

201

B9. Please explain details of forest products of your land:

N

o Products

Volume

To be

consumed

(%)

To be

sold

(%)

Market

Price

Harvest

Period

Annual

Value

Annual

Earning

a b c d e f g

1 Coffee

2 Cocoa

3 Candlenut

4 Durian

5 Rambutan

6 Clove

7 Banana

8 Timber

9 Wood

10 Ginger, etc.

11 Vegetables

12 Honey

13 Others:…..

TOTAL

B10. What are the other sources of income for your household?

………………………………………………………………………………

B11. How much is your household’s monthly income?

Rp ……………………………………………………………………………

202

B12. How much of your household’s income is spent on:

No Expenses Amount

Expense Period Annual Amount

a b c

1 Food

2 Housing

3 Education

4 Health

5 Installment

payment

6 Clothing

7 Electricity, Phone,

Fuel

8 Ceremonies

9 Saving

TOTAL

B13. Does CF contribute to increasing your family’s quality of life?

a. Strongly disagree

b. Disagree

c. Neutral

d. Agree

e. Strongly Agree

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B14. Do you agree that CF contributed to increasing the community’s quality of

life?

a. Strongly disagree

b. Disagree

c. Neutral

d. Agree

e. Strongly Agree

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

203

B15. Do you agree that CF contributes to reducing poverty?

a. Strongly disagree

b. Disagree

c. Neutral

d. Agree

e. Strongly Agree

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B16. Have you logged trees on your land?

a. Never

b. Rarely

c. Sometimes

d. Often

e. Very Often

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B17. Do you log trees on your land now?

a. Never

b. Rarely

c. Sometimes

d. Often

e. Very Often

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B18. Does timber get stolen from your land?

a. Never

b. Rarely

c. Sometimes

d. Often

e. Very Often

B19. Do other people log trees in this forest?

a. Never

b. Rarely

c. Sometimes

d. Often

e. Very Often

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

204

B20. What kinds of rules are applied to forest management in this village?

a. Adat rules

b. State rules

c. Both adat and state rules

d. Other rules, please specify: ……………………………………

e. Do not know about rules

B21. What are the examples of the rules that should be followed in forest

management and what punishment is applied for not following the rules?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B22. What do you know about adat use in forest governance?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B23. Do you obey adat rules on community forestry management?

a. Strongly disobey

b. Disobey

c. Neutral

d. Obey

e. Strongly Obey

f. Do not know about rules

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B24. Since you joined CFUG, how has the number of trees changed on your land?

a. Increase much

b. Increase

c. The same

d. Decrease

e. Decrease much

B25. Do you agree that the implementation of CF has contributed to reducing

deforestation?

a. Strongly disagree

b. Disagree

c. Neutral

d. Agree

e. Strongly Agree

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B26. Do you agree that adat use has an impact on forest governance?

g. Strongly disagree

h. Disagree

i. Neutral

j. Agree

k. Strongly Agree

205

In what way?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B27. How important is NGO/Government’s assistance for the creation of CF and

PES?

a. Strongly not important

b. Not important

c. Neutral

d. Important

e. Strongly Important

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B28. Please rate for the following assessments of your CF:

Criteria Code Indicators Strongly

Disagree

Disagree Neutral Agree Strongly

Agree

CF’s Land

Governance

B26a Your land size is

sufficient

B26b Your plants

composition fit the CF

regulation (70% trees :

30% MPTS)

B26c You have strong

capacity and skills to

manage your land

CFUG’s

Governance

B26d Your interests are well

accommodated by

your CFUG

B26e You often attend

regular CFUG’s

meetings, CFUG’s

work plans and

capacity buildings

programs

B26f Your CFUG is able to

solve group’s

problems

independently

206

Criteria Code Indicators Strongly

Disagree

Disagree Neutral Agree Strongly

Agree

B26g You obtained support

from government,

NGOs, universities

and other related

parties

CF’s Business

Governance

B26h Your land produces a

stable volume of

commodities

B26i Your CF products’

prices are stable

B29. What do you think are the negative aspects of the CF program?

……………………………………………………………………………………

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

B30. Please give your comments or suggestions for improving the CF program

207

PART C. PAYMENT FOR ECOSYSTEM SERVICES (PES) PROGRAM

C1. Are you enrolled in a PES program?

a. Yes

b. No if No, continue to question

C8

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

C2. What PES program are you enrolled in?

……………………………………………………………………………………

C3. How long have you been involved in the PES program? ………………. Years

C4. Please specify the benefits you obtain from the PES program:

No. Type of Benefits Amount/

Quantity

Period Annual value

a b C

1 Cash Income

2 Seed

3 Working Capital

4 Non Material,

……………………..

5 Others,

……………………….

C5. What was your income from the PES mostly spent on?

……………………………………………………………………………………

C6. Do you agree that the PES program contributes to increasing your family’s

quality of life?

a. Strongly disagree

b. Disagree

c. Neutral

d. Agree

e. Strongly Agree

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

208

C7. Do you agree that the PES program contributes to increasing the quality of life in

the community?

a. Strongly disagree

b. Disagree

c. Neutral

d. Agree

e. Strongly Agree

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

C8. Do you agree that the PES program contributes to reducing poverty in the

community?

a. Strongly disagree

b. Disagree

c. Neutral

d. Agree

e. Strongly Agree

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

For non PES member, continue to Question C11

C9. Since you enrolled in PES, how has the number of trees changed on your land?

a. Decrease much

b. Decrease

c. The same

d. Increase

e. Increase much

C10. Has the implementation of PES led to an improvement in the quantity and

quality of trees in this forest?

a. Strongly disagree

b. Disagree

c. Neutral

d. Agree

e. Strongly Agree

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

209

C11. Do you think that the forest governance rules required to receive PES

compensation are reasonable?

a. Strongly agree

b. Disagree

c. Neutral

d. Agree

e. Strongly Agree

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

C12. What do you think are the negative aspects of the PES program?

…..…………………………………………………………………………………

Please explain why?

……………………………………………………………………………………

C13. Please give comments or suggestions for improving the PES program

210

PART D: HOUSEHOLD’S ECONOMIC CONDITION

CRITERIA BEFORE 1998 NOW

a b

D1. House ownership Live with family/relative

Rent

Own

Live with family/relative

Rent

Own

D2. House condition Wall:

Bamboo

Wood

Brick

Floor:

Soil

Cement

Tile

Wall:

Bamboo

Wood

Brick

Floor:

Soil

Cement

Tile

D3. Electricity Supply No electricity

Shared from neighbour

PLN grid

Own a generator

No electricity

Shared from neighbour

PLN grid

Own a generator

D4. Water Supply River/spring

Public Well

Private Well

Public Pipe

Private Pipe

River/spring

Public Well

Private Well

Public Pipe

Private Pipe

D5. Energy for Cooking Wood/timber

Oil

Gas

Electricity

Bio-fuel

Wood/timber

Oil

Gas

Electricity

Bio-fuel

D6. Transportation Don’t have transportation

Bicycle

Motor bike

Car/Truck/Bemo

Don’t have transportation

Bicycle

Motor bike

Car/Truck/Bemo

D7. Telecommunication Do not have cellular phone

Have one cellular phone

Have more than one

cellular phone

Do not have cellular phone

Have one cellular phone

Have more than one cellular

phone

“Thank you for your support and participation”

211

Appendix 1.3 Indicative Interview Questions (Bahasa Indonesia Version)

SUSTAINABLE COMMUNITY FORESTRY MANAGEMENT IN LOMBOK,

INDONESIA

PhD Thesis - Diswandi

School of Business and Governance, Murdoch University

INDICATIVE KEY QUESTIONS FOR IN-DEPTH INTERVIEWS

A. Pengelolaan Hutan Kemasyarakatan (HKm)

1. Seberapa efektifkah peranan Kelompok Tani HKm dalam pengelolaan hutan?

2. Jelaskan peranan pemerintah local (Kabupaten/Provinsi) dan Nasional dalam

pengembangan HKm dan dalam mendukung kelompok HKm.

3. Hambatan atau masalah apa saja yang ada dalam pengelolaan HKm? Menurut

Anda, bagaimana cara mengatasi permasalahan tersebut?

4. Apakah Kelompok HKm mampu bertindak sebagai institusi local yang netral

(independen) dan apakah mereka mempunyai kekuatan tawar menawar terhadapa

pihak luar? Jika Iya, jelaskan bagaimana peranan mereka.

5. Apakah program HKm berkontribusi terhadap pengentasan kemiskinan di

Sesaot?

6. Seberapa baik kepemimpinan dalam Kelompok HKm mewakili para anggotanya?

7. Menurut Anda, Kebijakan, Program atau Strategi apa yang harus dikenalkan

(dibuat) untuk memperkuat program HKm?

B. Penggunaan Adat dalam manajemen HKm

1. Bagaimana Anda melihat peranan peranan hukum adat dalam pengelolaan HKm?

2. Apa peranan pemerintah lokal atau nasional dalam penggunaan adat dalam

pengelolaan HKm?

3. Apakah ada kolaborasi atau konflik antara hukum adat dan peraturan Negara

dalam pengelolaan HKm? Berikan contohnya.

4. Seberapa efektifkah aturan adat dalam pengelolaan HKm yang berkelanjutan?

Berikan contohnya.

5. Seberapa bagus kepemimpinan secara adat mewakili ketertarikan komunitas yang

lebih luas dalam pengelolaan hutan, khususnya kaum perempuan dan orang

miskin?

C. HKm dan Kemiskinan

1. Dibandingkan dengan kondisi sebelum adanya HKm, bagaimana Anda melihat

kondisi perekonomian masyarakat di sekitar hutan Sesaot? Bisakah Anda

ungkapkan kontribusi HKm terhadap kehidupan ekonomi masyarakat local?

212

2. Menurut Anda, apakah kaum perempuan, dan golongan kurang mampu

memperoleh manfaat dari program HKm? Jika Iya, bagaimana? Jika tidak, apa

yang kurang dan apa yang harus dilakukan untuk meningkatkan manfaat bagi

mereka?

3. Menurut Anda apakah HKm bisa digunakan sebagai alat untuk mengatasi

kemiskinan? Kenapa?

4. Menurut Anda, bagaimanakah masalah kemiskinan bisa diatasi terutama di

daerah pedesaan di sekitar hutan?

D. HKm dan Deforestasi (Kerusakan Hutan)

1. Dapatkah anda ungkapkan kontribusi HKm terhadap konservasi lingkungan?

2. Apakah ada perubahan dalam kuantitas dan kualitas tutupan hutan dan

Keanekaragaman hutan setelah pelaksanaan program HKm? Bagaiamana

bedanya dengan kondisi sebelum HKm diperkenalkan? Bisa berikan contoh?

E. Pembayaran Jasa Lingkungan (Jasling)

1. Seberapa efektif keterkaitan antara Jasling dengan pengelolaan hutan?

2. Bagaimanakah Jasling memberikan manfaat bagi Kelompok HKm? Apa bentuk

manfaatnya? Jika tidak ada manfaat, kenapa?

3. Seberapa efektifkah Institusi Multi Pihak (IMP) dalam mengelola Jasaling?

4. Apa peranan pemerintah lokal dan nasional dalam pengembangan Jasling?

5. Bisakah Anda identifikasi jenis-jenis biaya (transaksi) yang muncul sebagai

upaya membuat program Jasling?

6. Apakah ada kontrak tertulis antara penyedia dan pengguna jasa lingkungan?

Bagaimana kontrak tersebut dinegosiasikan dan ditegakkan?

7. Seberapa efisienkah program Jasling sebagai upaya untuk mencapai tujuan

konservasi hutan? Menurut Anda, apakah Jasling bisa cukup untuk menjadi

insentif bagi “pengguna hutan” untuk mengelola hutan secara berkelanjutan

sampai dimasa yang akan dating?

8. Apakah Jasling bisa digunakan untuk mengatasi kemiskinan?

9. Apa dampak Jasling bagi pembangunan pedesaan di masyarakat Sesaot? APakah

Jasling memberikan kontribusi yang cukup bagi pembangunan pedesaan dimana

Jasa Lingkungan tersebut diproduksi?

10. Bentuk pembayaran yang bagaimanakah yang terbaik menurut Anda,

pembayaran dalam bentuk tunai atau disalurkan dalam bentuk program

pembangunan pedesaan? Jelaskan kenapa.

11. Bagaimanakah cara terbaik untuk memonitor dan mengevaluasi apakah jasa

lingkungan (air) sudah dirasakan dengan baik oleh “pembeli” seperti tertera

dalam kontrak?

12. Bagaiamanakah program Jasling mempertimbangkan kesetaraan gender?

213

Appendix 1.4 Indicative Interview Questions (English Version)

SUSTAINABLE COMMUNITY FORESTRY MANAGEMENT IN LOMBOK,

INDONESIA

PhD Thesis - Diswandi

School of Business and Governance, Murdoch University

INDICATIVE KEY QUESTIONS FOR IN-DEPTH INTERVIEWS

A. Community Forestry Management

1. How effective is the role of Community Forest User Group (CFUG) in forest

governance?

2. Describe the role of regional (district/provincial) and national governments in

Community Forest (CF) development and in supporting CFUG.

3. Are there any constraints on or problems with the management of CF? How do

you think these constraints should be addressed?

4. Is the CFUG able to act as an independent local institution and does it have

bargaining power with outside agencies? If yes, describe the role it plays.

5. Does the Community Forestry program contribute to poverty alleviation in Sesaot

communities?

6. How well does the CFUG leadership represent its membership?

7. In your opinion, what kind of policy, program or strategy should be introduced to

strengthen and improve the community forestry program?

B. Adat Development in Community Forestry Management

6. How effective is the role of adat in forestry management?

7. What is the role of local or national government in employing adat institutions in

CF management?

8. Is there any collaboration or conflict between adat and state regulation in CF

management? Please give some examples.

9. How effective is adat regulation in managing CF sustainably? Please give an

example.

10. How well does adat leadership represent the interest of the wider community in

forest management, in particular for women and the poor.

C. Community Forestry and Poverty

11. Compared to the condition before the introduction of the CF program, how do

you find the economic condition of people in the Sesaot Forest? Can you

elaborate on the contribution of CF to local people’s livelihoods?

214

12. Do you think the poor, women and other disadvantaged groups have benefited

from the CF program? If yes, how? If not, what is lacking and what can be done

to further enhance the benefits for them?

13. Do you think CF can be a tool for poverty alleviation? Why or why not?

14. In your opinion, how can the poverty problem be solved especially in rural areas

surrounding the forest?

D. Community Forestry and Deforestation

15. Can you elaborate on the contribution of CF to environmental conservation?

16. Are there any significant changes in the quality and quantity of forest cover and

forest diversity after the implementation of the CF program? How does it differ

from the period before the CF program was initiated? Can you please give some

examples?

E. Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES)

17. How effective is the relationship between PES and forest governance?

18. Does PES provide sufficient benefits to CFUG? What are the benefits and if they

are not adequate, why?

19. How effective is the mediating stakeholder body (Institusi Multi Pihak) in

managing PES?

20. What is the role of national/local government in PES development?

21. Can you define the types of transaction costs that emerge from the effort of

building the PES program?

22. Is there any written contract between ES providers and buyers? How is the

contract negotiated and enforced?

23. How efficient is the PES program in efforts to achieve forest conservation goals?

Do you think PES can be a sufficient incentive for forest users to manage the

forest sustainably into the future?

24. Do you think PES is useful for poverty alleviation?

25. What are the effects of PES on rural development in the Sesaot communities?

Does the PES program make a significant contribution to rural development

where PES is implemented?

26. Which one do you consider the best form of payment, cash payments or in-kind

contributions to the rural development program? Please explain why.

27. What is the best way to monitor and evaluate whether the ecosystem services

have been well delivered as required by the contract?

28. How does the PES program incorporate gender equity?

215

Appendix 3.1 Awiq-awiq Forum Kawasan

AWIQ–AWIQ

FORUM KAWASAN HUTAN LINDUNG SESAOT

Menyadari pentingnya keberadaan dan fungsi kawasan hutan Sesaot bagi keberlangsungan

kehidupan, maka kelompok-kelompok pengelolaan dan pemanfaatan sumberdaya hutan di

kawasan hutan Sesaot telah membangun kesepahaman dan kesepakatan bersama untuk

pengelolaan dan pemanfaatan sumberdaya hutan Sesaot ditingkat kawasan dalam bentuk

Awiq-awiq pengelolaan hutan oleh masyarakat di kawasan hutan Sesaot. Awiq-awiq yang

disepakati ini merupakan aturan-aturan ditingkat awiq-awiq kelompok yang disepakati

untuk kemudian diangkat menjadi kesepakatan bersama ditingkat kawasan, yaitu sebagai

berikut:

1. Lahan kelola kelompok adalah hutan Negara yang tidak boleh dijadikan Hak milik. dan

tidak boleh diperjualbelikan maupun digantirugikan / gantirugi lahan garapannya.

2. Penggarap bersama kelompok dan Forum kawasan wajib menjaga dan memelihara

lahan kelola kelompok dari tindakan-tindakan yang Merusak Kelestarian Hutan seperti

mengupas kulit pohon, mengambil akar, menebang, membakar, dll. dan melakukan

Perlindungan Kawasan serta mengamankan Kawasan huta.

3. Penggarap adalah warga masyarakat yang berada disekitar kawasan hutan sesaot yang

dikuatkan dengan Keterangan dari desa yang bersangkutan (Desa Sesaot, Lebah

Sempage, Sedau, Suranadi, Selat, Batu Mekar dan Batu Kumbung).

4. Bagi penggarap yang berada pada batas garis limit wilayah kelola, berkewajiban

menjaga batas tersebut dengan menanam pohon-pohon pinang,pada jarak tertentu guna

menghindari perambahan baru dan memelihara tanaman tersebut dengan melibatkan

semua penggarap dan ketua-ketua blok.

5. Batas antar lahan garapan harus jelas, dengan tanda yang disepakati bersama disetiap

kelompok dan tidak boleh dipindah-pindah.

6. Komposisi tanaman dilahan garapan dalam blok pengelolaan adalah 70% MPTs dan

30% kayu-kayuan dengan jenis yang disepakati oleh kelompok dan setiap penggarap

dalam blok tersebut berkewajiban menjaga dan mengamankan semua tanaman tersebut

dan semua tanaman dijaga bersama

7. Jarak tanam adalah 6 x 6 meter untuk tanaman MPTs dan jarak tanam kayu-kayuan 20

x 10 meter minimal 265 pohon/Ha atau 64 pohon/25 are dengan sebaran yang merata

dengan komposisi MPTs dan Kayu sesuai dengan kondisi lapangan.

8. Penggarap tidak boleh menelantarkan lahannya dengan tidak menanam MPTs dan

kayu-kayuan sesuai aturan yang disepakati atau tidak memelihara tanamannya sama

sekali.

9. Dilarang mengganggu, merusak, mencuri tanaman dan hasil-hasilnya yang berada

dilahan kelola kelompok yang akan mengakibatkan kerusakan kawasan atau

merugikan penggarap

216

10. Dilarang memindahkan lahan kelola kepada pihak lain tanpa melalui mekanisme

kelompok dan Pemindahan hak kelola lahan dari orang tua kepada anaknya harus

dilakukan melalui kesepakatan dan mekanisme kelompok.

11. Tidak boleh tinggal menetap di dalam kawasan hutan dan membuat pondok permanen

dalam kawasan hutan.

12. Dilarang beternak didalam kawasan hutan.

13. Untuk Penggarap yang lokasinya dekat mata air, daerah tebing, terjal, maka

berkewajiban menanam tanaman pelindung mata air dan pelindung tebing untuk

melindungi mata air dan menghindari longsor dengan tanaman yang telah disepakati

14. Dilarang melakukan galian C dalam kawasan hutan.

15. Bagi masyarakat yang menyaksikan pelanggaran di dalam kawasan, berkewajiban

melaporkan hal tersebut pada kelompok dan pelapor diberikan perlindungan dan

identitasnya dirahasiakan.

16. Seluruh penggarap bersedia mematuhi awiq-awiq yang telah disepakati bersama dalam

kelompok.

HAK PENGELOLA / PENGGARAP KAWASAN

1. Penggarap berhak mengelola Hasil Hutan Bukan Kayu (HHBK) dan Tanaman

Dibawah Tegakan.

2. Untuk penggerap yang berada di batas garis limit, berhak memperoleh pengurangan

pembayaran bagi hasil sebesar 50 %.

3. Jika terjadi kayu tumbang yang diakibatkan oleh peristiwa alam, maka kelompok dan

anggota penggarap melakukan koordinasi dengan pihak kehutanan dengan

memanfaatkan kayu yang tumbang tersebut.

4. Jika terjadi penebangan secara legal oleh pemerintah, maka kelompok dan penggarap

berhak mendapat bagian dari penebangan tersebut

5. Kelompok berhak mendapat bagian tertentu dari bagi hasil garapan untuk dijadikan

asset kelompok guna menegakkan awiq-awiq ini.

SANKSI BAGI PENEGAKAN AWIQ-AWIQ PENGELOLAAN KAWASAN

1. Barang siapa merubah/memindahkan batas garapan maka akan diberikan sanksi sesuai

dengan musyawarah di tingkat kelompok

2. Bagi penggarap yang tidak mencapai 30 % tanaman kayu dan 70 % tanaman MPTs

akan diberikan teguran 3 kali, teguran tertulis 1 kali, dan jika penggarap tidak mampu

memenuhinya karena ketidaksanggupannya maka lahan kelolanya akan diambil oleh

kelompok dan diserahkan kepada anggota yang memerlukannya sesuai dengan

musyawarah kelompok.

3. Barang siapa yang telah menelantarkan lahannya dengan tidak menanam MPTs dan

kayu-kayuan sesuai aturan yang disepakati atau tidak memelihara tanamannya sama

sekali, maka

a. Akan diberi teguran lisan, dan jika dalam jangka waktu 1 bulan tidak diindahkan

maka akan diberikan peringatan tertulis.

217

b. Jika dalam jangka waktu 1 bulan juga tidak diindahkan maka akan diberikan

peringatan tertulis kedua.

c. Jika dalam jangka waktu 1 bulan peringatan kedua tidak diindahkan maka akan

dilakukan pencabutan hak kelola lahan melalui mekanisme sidang Lokaq dan

selanjutnya lahan kelola lahan tersebut diserahkan kepada anggota yang berhak

menerimanya melalui mekanisme kelompok.

4. Barang siapa mengganggu, merusak, mencuri tanaman dan hasil-hasilnya yang berada

dilahan kelola kelompok yang akan mengakibatkan kerusakan kawasan atau

merugikan penggarap, maka :

a. Bagi yang punya lahan kelola maka lahannya akan dicabut atau membayar ganti

rugi atas lahan yang rusak sesuai kesepakatan kelompok.

b. Bagi yang tidak punya lahan kelola akan dilanjutkan ke proses penegakan awiq-

awiq berupa :

- Diproses secara hukum

- Membayar ganti rugi atas lahan yang rusak sesuai kesepakatan kelompok dan

besarannya akan diputuskan melalui mekanisme musyawarah kelompok

5. Bagi penggarap yang lalai memenuhi kewajibannya dalam bagi hasil / retribusi maka

:

a. Membayar tunggakannya dan ditambah denda 50 % ,

b. Jika kelalaian dilakukan 3 kali berturut-turut maka dikeluarkan hak

pengelolaannya dari kelompok dan selanjutnya akan dicabut hak kelolanya.

MEKANISME PENEGAKAN AWIQ-AWIQ

Jika terjadi pelanggaran berat atau pelanggaran ringan terhadap awiq-awiq ini maka

ditempuh mekanisme sebagai berikut:

PELANGGARAN BERAT :

1. Teguran lisan sampai 2 kali, dengan rentang antar waktu teguran maksimal 1 bulan.

2. Jika teguran lisan tidak diindahkan maka dalam waktu paling lama 1 bulan setelah

teguran kedua akan diberikan teguran tertulis.

3. Jika teguran tertulis juga tidak diindahkan maka paling lama 1 bulan setelah

teguran lisan, pelanggar awiq-awiq ini harus dihadirkan dalam siding awiq-awiq

yang dihadiri oleh pihak dinas kehutanan, pemerintah desa, ketua-ketua kelompok,

pemangku awiq-awiq serta lang-lang.

4. jika pelanggar adalah penggarap, maka sidang dapat memutuskan sanksi, dengan

sanksi maksimal berupa pencabutan hak atas lahan garapan

PELANGGARAN RINGAN :

1. diberikan peringatan sebanyak 3 kali dan apabila tidak diindahkan akan dilakukan

penanganan melalui mekanisme penyidangan Lokaq awiq-awiq

2. Keputusan sangsi akan diputuskan melalui mekanisme penyidangan dengan

meminta pertimbangan dari semua pihak.

218

Demi menjaga kelestarian hutan dan keberlangsungan pemanfaatan hasil hutan serta

kesepakatan yang telah terbangun untuk tujuan tersebut maka awiq-awiq ini harus

dilaksanakan secara tegas, konsisten dan tanpa pandang bulu.

Ditetapkan : Di Sesaot

Pada tanggal : Desember 2006

Penandatangan:

Ketua Forum Kawasan Hutan Sesaot

Ketua Kelompok Forum Ranget

Ketua Kelompok Wana Dharma

Ketua Kelompok Wana Lestari

Ketua Kelompok KMPH Mitra Sesaot

Ketua Kelompok Wana Abadi

Mengetahui

Kepala Desa Sesaot

Kepala Desa Sedau

Kepala Desa Lebah Sempage

Kepala Desa Batu Mekar

Kepala Desa Suranadi

Kepolisian Sektor Narmada

KRDKP Sesaot

KRDKP Lebah Sempage

Dinas Kehutanan

Kabupaten Lombok Barat

Dinas Kehutanan Prov NTB

219

Appendix 4.1 IMP Report Published on Local Media (Lombok Post, 30 May

2011)

220

Appendix 5.1 Global Forest Watch - Forest Change Analysis

221

Appendix 5.2 T Test for Farmers’ Logging Practice before and after

establishment of Community Forestry Program

222

Appendix 6.1 T test for House Ownership before and after establishment of

Community Forestry Program

223

Appendix 7.1 Regression Result

224

225

226

Bibliography

Adhikari, Bhim, Williams, Frances and Lovett, Jon C. (2007). Local benefits from

community forests in the middle hills of Nepal. Forest Policy and

Economics, 9(5), 464-478. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2005.11.002

Adhikari, Sunit, Kingi, Tanira and Ganesh, Siva. (2014). Incentives for

community participation in the governance and management of common

property resources: the case of community forest management in Nepal.

Forest Policy and Economics, 44(0), 1-9. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2014.04.003

Agarwal, Bina. (2009). Gender and forest conservation: The impact of women's

participation in community forest governance. Ecological Economics,

68(11), 2785-2799. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.04.025

Aggarwal, Rimjhim M. (2006). Globalization, local ecosystems, and the rural

poor. World Development, 34(8), 1405-1418. doi:

10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.10.011

Agrawal, Arun. (1996). The community vs. the market and the state: Forest use in

Uttarakhand in the Indian Himalayas. Journal of Agricultural and

Environmental Ethics, 9(1), 1-15.

Agrawal, Arun. (2001a). Common Property Institutions and Sustainable

Governance of Resources. World Development, 29(10), 1649-1672. doi:

10.1016/S0305-750X(01)00063-8

Agrawal, Arun. (2001b). Common property, forest management and the Indian

Himalaya. Contributions to Indian Sociology, 35(2), 181-212. doi:

10.1177/006996670103500202

Agrawal, Arun. (2003). Sustainable Governance of Common-Pool Resources:

Context, Methods, and Politics. Annual Review of Anthropology, 32, 243-

262.

Agrawal, Arun. (2007). Forests, Governance, and Sustainability: Common

Property Theory and its Contributions. International Journal of the

Commons, 1(1), 111-136.

Agrawal, Arun and Chhatre, Ashwini. (2006). Explaining success on the

commons: Community forest governance in the Indian Himalaya. World

Development, 34(1), 149-166. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.07.013

Agrawal, Arun, Nepstad, Daniel and Chhatre, Ashwini. (2011). Reducing

Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation. Annual Review of

Environment and Resources, 36, 373-396. doi: 10.1146/annurev-environ-

042009-094508

Agrawal, Arun and Ostrom, Elinor. (2001). Collective Action, Property Rights,

and Decentralization in Resource Use in India and Nepal. Politics &

Society, 29(4), 485-514. doi: 10.1177/0032329201029004002

Anderies, John M. and Janssen, Marco A. (2013). Sustaining the Commons.

Tempe, AZ: Center for the Study of Institutional Diversity.

227

Anderson, Candace, Beazley, Karen and Boxall, James. (2009). Lessons for

PPGIS from the application of a decision-support tool in the Nova Forest

Alliance of Nova Scotia, Canada. Journal of Environmental Management,

90(6), 2081-2089. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2007.08.031

Araujo, Claudio, Bonjean, Catherine Araujo, Combes, Jean-Louis, Combes Motel,

Pascale and Reis, Eustaquio J. (2009). Property rights and deforestation in

the Brazilian Amazon. Ecological Economics, 68(8–9), 2461-2468. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.12.015

Arnold, J. E. (1987). Community forestry. Ambio, 16(2), 122-128.

Attwood, DW. (1992). State vs. local control in common resource management: a

comparative analysis. Sociological bulletin, 41(1/2), 1-17.

Bae, J.S., Kim, C., Kim, Y.S., Latifah, S., Afifi, M., Fisher, L.A., . . . Kim, J.S.

(2014). Opportunities for implementing REDD+ to enhance sustainable

forest management and improve livelihoods in Lombok, NTB, Indonesia.

Bogor, Indonesia: Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR).

Baland, Jean-Marie and Platteau, Jean-Philippe. (1996). Halting degradation of

natural resources: is there a role for rural communities? Rome: Food &

Agriculture Organization.

Barber, Charles Victor. (1998). Forest resource scarcity & social conflict in

Indonesia. Environment: Science and Policy for Sustainable Development,

40(4), 4-9.

Barr, Christopher, Dermawan, Ahmad, Purnomo, Herry and Komarudin, Heru.

(2010). Financial governance and Indonesia’s Reforestation Fund during

the Soeharto and post-Soeharto periods, 1989–2009: A political economic

analysis of lessons for REDD+ (Vol. 52): CIFOR.

Barr, Christopher and Sayer, Jeffrey. (2012). The political economy of

reforestation and forest restoration in Asia–Pacific: Critical issues for

REDD+. Biological Conservation, 154(0), 9-19. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.biocon.2012.03.020

Barsimantov, James and Kendall, Jake. (2012). Community Forestry, Common

Property, and Deforestation in Eight Mexican States. Journal of

Environment and Development, 21(4), 414-437. doi: 10.1605/01.301-

0021015068.2012

Bellinger, Sarah and Gale, Fred. (2004). Models of Community Forestry.

Australasian Journal of Environmental Management, 11(1), 65-77. doi:

10.1080/14486563.2004.10648599

Bennett, Michael T., Mehta, Aashish and Xu, Jintao. (2011). Incomplete property

rights, exposure to markets and the provision of environmental services in

China. China Economic Review, 22(4), 485-498. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.chieco.2010.12.002

Berkes, Fikret. (2009). Evolution of co-management: Role of knowledge

generation, bridging organizations and social learning. Journal of

Environmental Management, 90(5), 1692-1702. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2008.12.001

Beyene, Abebe D. and Koch, Steven F. (2013). Property rights, institutions and

choice of fuelwood source in rural Ethiopia. Forest Policy and Economics,

30(0), 30-38. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2013.02.002

228

Bhattacharya, Haimanti and Lueck, Dean. (2009). The role of property rights in

determining the environmental quality–income relationship. Ecological

Economics, 68(10), 2511-2524. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.04.023

Birch, Jennifer C., Thapa, Ishana, Balmford, Andrew, Bradbury, Richard B.,

Brown, Claire, Butchart, Stuart H. M., . . . Thomas, David H. L. (2014).

What benefits do community forests provide, and to whom? A rapid

assessment of ecosystem services from a Himalayan forest, Nepal.

Ecosystem Services, 8(0), 118-127. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2014.03.005

Börner, Jan, Wunder, Sven, Wertz-Kanounnikoff, Sheila, Tito, Marcos Rügnitz,

Pereira, Ligia and Nascimento, Nathalia. (2010). Direct conservation

payments in the Brazilian Amazon: Scope and equity implications.

Ecological Economics, 69(6), 1272-1282. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.11.003

Borrini-Feyerabend, Grazia. (1996). Collaborative Management of Protected

Areas: Tailoring the Approach to the Context. Gland: IUCN.

Borrini-Feyerabend, Grazia, Farvar, M Taghi, Renard, Yves, Pimbert, Michel P

and Kothari, Ashish. (2004). Sharing power: A global guide to

collaborative management of natural resources throughout the world.

Cenesta, Tehran: IIED and IUCN/CEESP/CMWG.

Bottazzi, Patrick, Cattaneo, Andrea, Rocha, David Crespo and Rist, Stephan.

(2013). Assessing sustainable forest management under REDD: a

community-based labour perspective. Ecological economics, 93, 94-103.

doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2013.05.003

Boumans, Marcel and Morgan, Mary S. (2001). Ceteris paribus conditions:

materiality and the application of economic theories. Journal of Economic

Methodology, 8(1), 11-26.

Boyd, James and Banzhaf, Spencer. (2007). What are ecosystem services? The

need for standardized environmental accounting units. Ecological

Economics, 63(2), 616-626. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.01.002

BPS. (2014). Jumlah dan Persentase Penduduk Miskin Di Provinsi NTB 2002-

2014. Retrieved 23 February 2017, from http://ntb.bps.go.id/linkTabelStatis/view/id/72

BPS (Cartographer). (2015a). Desa di Sekitar Rinjani.

BPS. (2015b). Luas Kawasan Hutan dan Perairan Menurut Provinsi. Retrieved

23/11/2016, 2016, from https://www.bps.go.id/linkTabelStatis/view/id/1716

BPS. (2016a). Garis Kemiskinan Menurut Provinsi. Retrieved 29/06/2016, 2016,

from https://www.bps.go.id/linkTableDinamis/view/id/1120

BPS. (2016b). Persentase Penduduk Miskin Provinsi NTB, 2010 - 2016: Badan

Pusat Statistik.

BPS NTB. (2014). Nusa Tenggara Barat Dalam Angka 2013. Mataram: Badan

Pusat Statistik.

Bremer, Leah L., Farley, Kathleen A., Lopez-Carr, David and Romero, José.

(2014). Conservation and livelihood outcomes of payment for ecosystem

services in the Ecuadorian Andes: What is the potential for ‘win–win’?

Ecosystem Services, 8(0), 148-165. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2014.03.007

229

Brockhaus, Maria, Obidzinski, Krystof, Dermawan, Ahmad, Laumonier, Yves

and Luttrell, Cecilia. (2012). An overview of forest and land allocation

policies in Indonesia: Is the current framework sufficient to meet the needs

of REDD+? Forest Policy and Economics, 18(0), 30-37. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2011.09.004

Bromley, Daniel W. (1992). The commons, common property, and environmental

policy. Environmental and resource economics, 2(1), 1-17.

Brown, Jessica and Bird, Neil. (2010). Costa Ricas's Sustainable Resource

Management : Successfully Takling Tropical Deforestation. United

Kingdom: Overseas Development Institute.

Bryman, Alan. (2015). Social research methods. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Bullock, Ryan CL and Hanna, Kevin S. (2012). Community forestry: local values,

conflict and forest governance: Cambridge University Press.

Bupati Lombok Barat and Walikota Mataram. (2011). Kesepakatan Bersama

Bupati Lombok Barat dengan Walikota Mataram tentang Kerjasama

Program Pelestarian Sumberdaya Alam di Wilayah Kabupaten Lombok

Barat dan Kota Mataram. Mataram.

Burns, Robert Bounds. (1997). Introduction to research methods. New South

Wales: Addison Wesley Longman.

Calvo-Alvarado, J., McLennan, B., Sánchez-Azofeifa, A. and Garvin, T. (2009).

Deforestation and forest restoration in Guanacaste, Costa Rica: Putting

conservation policies in context. Forest Ecology and Management, 258(6),

931-940. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.foreco.2008.10.035

Carlsson, Lars and Berkes, Fikret. (2005). Co-management: concepts and

methodological implications. Journal of environmental management,

75(1), 65-76.

Charnley, Susan and Poe, Melissa R. (2007). Community Forestry in Theory and

Practice: Where Are We Now? Annual Review of Anthropology, 36, 301-

336. doi: 10.1146/annurev.anthro.35.081705.123143

Christie, Mike, Fazey, Ioan, Cooper, Rob, Hyde, Tony and Kenter, Jasper O.

(2012). An evaluation of monetary and non-monetary techniques for

assessing the importance of biodiversity and ecosystem services to people

in countries with developing economies. Ecological Economics, 83(0), 67-

78. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2012.08.012

Clements, Tom, John, Ashish, Nielsen, Karen, An, Dara, Tan, Setha and Milner-

Gulland, E. J. (2010). Payments for biodiversity conservation in the

context of weak institutions: Comparison of three programs from

Cambodia. Ecological Economics, 69(6), 1283-1291. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.11.010

Coase, Ronald H. (1960). The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and

Economics, 3, 1-44.

Cole, D. H., Epstein, G. and McGinnis, M. D. (2014). Digging deeper into

Hardin's pasture: the complex institutional structure of 'the tragedy of the

commons'. Journal of Institutional Economics, 10(3), 353-369. doi:

10.1017/S1744137414000101

Coleman, James S. (1973). Mathematics of collective action. New Jersey:

Transaction Publishers.

230

Coleman, James S. and Fararo, Thomas J. (1992). Rational Choice Theory:

Advance and Critique. London: SAGE Publications.

Conklin, Harold C. (1954). Section of anthropology: An Ethnoecological

approach to shifting agriculture. Transactions of the New York Academy of

Sciences, 17(2 Series II), 133-142.

Cornia, Giovanni Andrea. (1985). Farm size, land yields and the agricultural

production function: An analysis for fifteen developing countries. World

Development, 13(4), 513-534. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0305-750X(85)90054-3

Costanza, Robert, Paruelo, Jose, Raskin, Robert G., Sutton, Paul, Van Den Belt,

Marjan, D'Arge, Ralph, . . . O'Neill, Robert V. (1997). The value of the

world's ecosystem services and natural capital. Nature, 387(6630), 253-

260. doi: 10.1038/387253a0

Craven, BD and Islam, Sardar MN. (2011). Ordinary least-squares regression:

Sage Publications.

Creswell, John W and Plano-Clark, VL. (2006). Understanding mixed methods

research. London: Sage Publications.

Daniels, Amy E., Bagstad, Kenneth, Esposito, Valerie, Moulaert, Azur and

Rodriguez, Carlos Manuel. (2010). Understanding the impacts of Costa

Rica's PES: Are we asking the right questions? Ecological Economics,

69(11), 2116-2126. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.06.011

Darma Lestari. (2011). Proposal Perlindungan Sumber Mata Air di Kawasan

Hutan Sesaot. Darma Lestari. Gerung.

Dhakal, Bhubaneswor, Bigsby, Hugh and Cullen, Ross. (2007). The Link between

Community Forestry Policies and Poverty and Unemployment in Rural

Nepal. Mountain Research and Development, 27(1), 32-39.

Dhakal, Bhubaneswor, Bigsby, Hugh and Cullen, Ross. (2012). Socioeconomic

Impacts of Public Forest Policies on Heterogeneous Agricultural

Households. Environmental and Resource Economics, 53(1), 73-95. doi:

10.1007/s10640-012-9548-4

Dietz, Thomas, Ostrom, Elinor, Dolsak, Nives and Stern, Paul C. (2002). The

drama of the commons. In Thomas Dietz, Elinor Ostrom, Nives Dolsak,

Paul C Stern, Susan StonichandElke U Weber (Eds.), The drama of the

commons: National Academies Press.

Dinas Kehutanan Kabupaten Lombok Barat. (2014). Luas Hutan dan Lahan Kritis

di Kabupaten Lombok Barat: Dinas Kehutanan Lombok Barat.

Dinas Kehutanan Provinsi NTB. (2013a). Data Luas Kesatuan Pengelolaan

Hutan (KPH) NTB. Mataram: Dinas Kehutanan Provinsi NTB.

Dinas Kehutanan Provinsi NTB (Cartographer). (2013b). Peta KPH NTB.

Dinas Kehutanan Provinsi NTB. (2014). Statistik Dinas Kehutanan Provinsi NTB

Tahun 2014. Mataram: Dinas Kehutanan NTB.

Dinas Pertambangan dan Energi Kabupaten Lombok Barat. (2014). Pemakaian

Air Bawah Tanah Tahun 2014 Kabupaten Lombok Barat. Gerung: Dinas

Pertambangan dan Energi.

Duncan, E. (2006). Payments for environmental services: An equitable approach

for reducing poverty and conserving nature. WWF-World Wide Fund for

Nature (Formerly World Wildlife Fund), Gland, Switzerland.

231

Edmonds, Eric V. (2002). Government-initiated community resource management

and local resource extraction from Nepal's forests. Journal of Development

Economics, 68(1), 89-115. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3878(02)00007-X

Ehrlich, P.R. and Ehrilch, A.H. (1981). Exctinction: the cause and consequences

of the disappearance of species. New York: Random House.

Engel, Stefanie, Pagiola, Stefano and Wunder, Sven. (2008). Designing payments

for environmental services in theory and practice: An overview of the

issues. Ecological Economics, 65(4), 663-674. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.03.011

Engel, Stefanie and Palmer, Charles. (2008). Payments for environmental services

as an alternative to logging under weak property rights: The case of

Indonesia. Ecological Economics, 65(4), 799-809. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.028

FAO. (2005). Global forest resource assessment update 2005. Rome: FAO.

Fauzi, Akhmad and Anna, Zuzy. (2013). The complexity of the institution of

payment for environmental services: A case study of two Indonesian PES

schemes. Ecosystem Services, 6(0), 54-63. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2013.07.003

Feeny, David, Berkes, Fikret, McCay, Bonnie J and Acheson, James M. (1990).

The tragedy of the commons: twenty-two years later. Human ecology,

18(1), 1-19.

Ferraro, Paul J. (2001). Global Habitat Protection: Limitations of Development

Interventions and a Role for Conservation Performance Payments.

Conservation Biology, 15(4), 990-1000. doi: 10.1046/j.1523-

1739.2001.015004990.x

Ferraro, Paul J. (2008). Asymmetric information and contract design for payments

for environmental services. Ecological Economics, 65(4), 810-821. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.029

Ferraro, Paul J. and Kiss, Agnes. (2002). Ecology. Direct payments to conserve

biodiversity. Science (New York, N.Y.), 298(5599), 1718-1719. doi:

10.1126/science.1078104

Fiebig, Denzil G. (2001). Seemingly unrelated regression. A companion to

theoretical econometrics, 101-121.

Fisher, Brendan, Turner, R. Kerry and Morling, Paul. (2009). Defining and

classifying ecosystem services for decision making. Ecological

Economics, 68(3), 643-653. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.09.014

Forslund, Anna, Renöfält, Birgitta Malm, Barchiesi, Stefano, Cross, Katharine,

Davidson, Sarah, Farrell, Tracy, . . . Meijer, Karen. (2009). Securing water

for ecosystems and human well-being: The importance of environmental

flows. Swedish Water House Report, 24.

Forum Kawasan. (2006). Profil dan Awiq-awiq Forum Kawasan Hutan Lindung

Sesaot: Forum Kawasan.

Forum Kawasan. (2009). Profil Sesaot: Forum Kawasan.

Forum Kawasan. (2011a). Kronologis Kasus Illegal Logging di Kawasan Hutan

Sesaot: Forum Kawasan.

232

Forum Kawasan. (2011b). Sejarah Pengelolaan Kawasan Hutan Lindung Sesaot

Mataram: Forum Kawasan.

Forum Kawasan. (2014). Rekapitulasi Data Penggarap HKm Sesaot. Mataram:

Forum Kawasan.

Fox, Jefferson. (1993). The Tragedy of Open Access. In Harold Brookfield and

Yvonne Byron (Ed.), Southeast Asia’s Environmental Future: The Search

for Sustainability. Tokyo: Oxford University Press

Fox, Jefferson, Lynch, Owen, Zimsky, Mark, Moore, Erin and Takeuchi, Helen.

(1993). Legal frameworks for forest management in Asia: Case studies of

community/state relations.

FWI/GFW. (2011). Potret Keadaan Hutan Indonesia Periode Tahun 2000-2009.

Bogor and Washington DC: Forest Watch Indonesia

Gardner, Toby A., Burgess, Neil D., Aguilar-Amuchastegui, Naikoa, Barlow, Jos,

Berenguer, Erika, Clements, Tom, . . . Vieira, Ima C. G. (2012). A

framework for integrating biodiversity concerns into national REDD+

programmes. Biological Conservation, 154(0), 61-71. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.biocon.2011.11.018

GFW. (2016). Forest Change Analysis. Retrieved 02/08/2016 http://www.globalforestwatch.org/map/10/-8.45/116.26/ALL/grayscale/loss,forestgain?tab=analysis-tab&begin=2001-01-01&end=2017-01-01&threshold=30&dont_analyze=true

GFW. (2017). Country Profiles: Indonesia. Retrieved 24/03/2017, from http://www.globalforestwatch.org/country/IDN

Gibson, Clark C, Lehoucq, Fabrice E and Williams, John T. (2002). Does

privatization protect natural resources? Property rights and forests in

Guatemala. Social Science Quarterly, 83(1), 206-225.

Gibson, Clark C, Williams, John T and Ostrom, Elinor. (2005). Local

Enforcement and Better Forests. World Development, 33(2), 273-284. doi:

10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.07.013

Gómez-Baggethun, Erik, de Groot, Rudolf, Lomas, Pedro L. and Montes, Carlos.

(2010). The history of ecosystem services in economic theory and

practice: From early notions to markets and payment schemes. Ecological

Economics, 69(6), 1209-1218. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.11.007

Google (Cartographer). (2015a). Map of Lombok Island.

Google (Cartographer). (2015b). Map of Sesaot Forest.

Greiner, R and Stanley, O. (2013). More than money for conservation: Exploring

social co-benefits from PES schemes. Land Use Policy, 31(0), 4-10. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2011.11.012

Greiner, R., Gordon, I. and Cocklin, C. (2009). Ecosystem services from tropical

savannas: economic opportunities through payments for environmental

services. Rangeland Journal, 31(1), 51-59. doi: 10.1071/RJ08067

Gultom, Magdalena, Lawrence, David, Filer, Colin, Potter, Lesley and

Resosudarmo, Budy. (2013). Local Management Arrangements in Sesaot

Forest, Lombok Indonesia. International Journal of Environmental

Technology and Management, 4(1).

233

Gunter, Jennifer and Jodway, Shawn. (2000). Community-Based Natural

Resource Management: a Strategy for Community Economic

Development. Burnaby: Simon Fraser University.

Hardin, Garrett. (1968). The Tragedy of the Commons. Science, 162(3859), 1243-

1248. doi: 10.1126/science.162.3859.1243

Heath, Anthony. (1976). Rational choice and social exchange: A critique of

exchange theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Hendri, Alfian. (2008). Laporan Hasil Monitoring dan Evaluasi Pembangunan

HKm di Prov NTB Tahun Anggaran 2008. Mataram: Balai Pengelolaan

DAS Dodokan Moyosari.

Heyde, Jill, Lukas, Martin C and Flitner, Michael. (2012). Payments for

Environmental Services in Indonesia: A Review of Watershed-related

Schemes: Artec.

Hidayat, Herman. (2016). Forest resources management in Indonesia (1968-

2004): A political ecology approach: Springer.

Hill, R Carter, Griffiths, William E and Lim, Guay C. (2008). Principles of

econometrics (Vol. 5): Wiley Hoboken, NJ.

Hoang, Minh Ha, Do, Trong Hoan, Pham, Minh Thoa, van Noordwijk, Meine and

Minang, Peter A. (2013). Benefit distribution across scales to reduce

emissions from deforestation and forest degradation (REDD+) in Vietnam.

Land Use Policy, 31(0), 48-60. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2011.09.013

Huber-Stearns, Heidi R., Goldstein, Joshua H. and Duke, Esther A. (2013).

Intermediary roles and payments for ecosystem services: A typology and

program feasibility application in Panama. Ecosystem Services, 6(0), 104-

116. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2013.09.006

Ibáñez, Ana María and Rao, Vijayendra. (2005). The social impact of social funds

in Jamaica: a 'participatory econometric' analysis of targeting, collective

action, and participation in community-driven development. The journal of

development studies, 41(5), 788-838. doi: 10.1080/00220380500145297

IMP. (2010). Laporan Institusi Multi Pihak Jasa Lingkungan Kabupaten Lombok

Barat. Gerung: Institusi Multi Pihak.

IMP. (2011). Laporan Institusi Multi Pihak Jasa Lingkungan Kabupaten Lombok

Barat. Gerung: Institusi Multi Pihak.

IMP. (2012). Laporan Institusi Multi Pihak Jasa Lingkungan Kabupaten Lombok

Barat. Gerung: Institusi Multi Pihak.

IMP. (2013a). Handout Pengelolaan Jasa Lingkungan. Mataram: IMP.

IMP. (2013b). Laporan Pertanggungjawaban Dana Hibah APBD II Program Jasa

Lingkungan Kabupaten Lombok Barat Tahun 2013. Gerung: Institusi

Multi Pihak.

IMP. (2014a). Focus Group Discussion Gerung: Institusi Multi Pihak.

IMP. (2014b). Laporan Institusi Multi Pihak Jasa Lingkungan Kabupaten Lombok

Barat. Gerung: Institusi Multi Pihak.

IMP and WWF. (2013). Jasa Lingkungan: Inisiatif Pendanaan Berkelanjutan

Untuk Kawasan Rinjani. Mataram: WWF Indonesia.

Ingram, Jane Carter, Wilkie, David, Clements, Tom, McNab, Roan Balas, Nelson,

Fred, Baur, Erick Hogan, . . . Foley, Charles Andrew Harold. (2014).

Evidence of Payments for Ecosystem Services as a Mechanism for

234

Supporting Biodiversity Conservation and Rural Livelihoods. Ecosystem

Services, 7(0), 10-21. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2013.12.003

Jentoft, Svein. (2003). Co-management-the way forward. Fish and Fisheries

Series, 26, 1-16.

Johnson, Colin. (1998). Survey of Recent Developments. Bulletin of Indonesian

Economic Studies, 34(2), 3-60. doi: 10.1080/00074919812331337320

Keene, Oliver N. (1995). The log transformation is special. Statistics in medicine,

14(8), 811-819.

Kerr, John. (2002). Watershed Development, Environmental Services, and

Poverty Alleviation in India. World Development, 30(8), 1387-1400. doi:

10.1016/S0305-750X(02)00042-6

Klooster, Daniel and Masera, Omar. (2000). Community forest management in

Mexico: carbon mitigation and biodiversity conservation through rural

development. Global Environmental Change, 10(4), 259-272. doi:

10.1016/S0959-3780(00)00033-9

Konsepsi. (2003). Laporan Studi Proses Jasa Lingkungan di Lombok. Mataram:

Konsepsi.

Konsepsi. (2009). Sejarah Sesaot. Mataram: Konsepsi.

Kosoy, Nicolas, Martinez-Tuna, Miguel, Muradian, Roldan and Martinez-Alier,

Joan. (2007). Payments for environmental services in watersheds: Insights

from a comparative study of three cases in Central America. Ecological

Economics, 61(2–3), 446-455. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2006.03.016

Kreps, David M. (1990). A course in microeconomic theory (Vol. 41): JSTOR.

Kroeger, Timm. (2012). The quest for the “optimal” payment for environmental

services program: Ambition meets reality, with useful lessons. Forest

Policy and Economics. doi: 10.1016/j.forpol.2012.06.007

Krogman, Naomi and Beckley, Tom. (2002). Corporate "Bail-Outs" and Local

"Buyouts": Pathways to Community Forestry? Society & Natural

Resources, 15(2), 109-127. doi: 10.1080/089419202753403300

Kubo, Hideyuki. (2009). Incorporating Agency Perspective into Community

Forestry Analysis. Small Scale Forestry, 8(3), 305-321. doi:

10.1007/s11842-009-9085-3

Lam, Wai Fung. (1999). Governing irrigation systems in Nepal: institutions,

infrastructure, and collective action: ICS Press Institute for Contemporary

Studies.

Lemhanas (Cartographer). (2013). Peta NKRI. Retrieved from http://www.lemhannas.go.id/portal/in/peta-resmi-nkri.html

Lloyd, William Forster. (1833). Two lectures on the checks to population. The

University of Oxford, Oxford.

Lütkepohl, Helmut and Xu, Fang. (2012). The role of the log transformation in

forecasting economic variables. Empirical Economics, 42(3), 619-638.

MA. (2003). Millenium Ecosystem Assessment 2003 Ecosystem and Human

Well-being. A Framework for Assessment.

Margolis, Howard. (1982). Selfishness, Altruism, and Rationality: A Theory of

Social Choice. Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press.

Maryudi, A., Devkota, R. R., Schusser, C., Yufanyi, C., Salla, M., Aurenhammer,

H., . . . Krott, M. (2012). Back to basics: Considerations in evaluating the

235

outcomes of community forestry. Forest Policy and Economics, 14(1), 1-

5. doi: 10.1016/j.forpol.2011.07.017

Matthew, Sommerville, E.J, Milner-Gulland, Michael, Rahajaharison and Julia

P.G, Jones. (2010). Impact of a Community-Based Payment for

Environmental Services Intervention on Forest Use in Menabe,

Madagascar. Conservation Biology, 24(6), 1488. doi: 10.1111/j.1523-

1739.2010.01526.x

McCarthy, JF, M, Moeliano and R, Robison. (2012). The post-authoritarian

politics of agrarian and forest reform in Indonesia. Routledge handbook of

Southeast Asian politics. Routledge.

McCarthy, John. (2009). Where is justice? Resource entitlements, agrarian

transformation and regional autonomy in Jambi, Sumatra. In Carol Warren

and John McCarthy (Ed.), Community, Environment and Local

governance in Indonesia: Locating the Commonweal. London and New

York: Routledge.

McCarthy, John F. (2000). The Changing Regime: Forest Property and Reformasi

in Indonesia. Development and change, 31(1), 91-129. doi: 10.1111/1467-

7660.00148

McCarthy, John F and Warren, Carol. (2009). Communities, environments and

local governance in Reform Era Indonesia. Community, Environment and

Local Governance in Indonesia: Locating the Commonweal, 22, 1.

McIver, John P, Carmines, Edward G and Sullivan, JL. (1994). Unidimensional

scaling.

McLeod, Ross H. (2000). Soeharto's Indonesia: a better class of corruption.

Agenda: A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform, 99-112.

Mekonnen, Alemu. (2009). Tenure Security, Resource Endowments, and Tree

Growing: Evidence from the Amhara Region of Ethiopia. Land

Economics, 85(2), 292-307.

Menteri Kehutanan RI. (2007). Peraturan Menteri Kehutanan Nomor:

P.35/Menhut-II/2007 tentang Hasil Hutan Bukan Kayu. Jakarta:

Kementerian Kehutanan.

Menteri Kehutanan RI. (2008). Peraturan Menteri Kehutanan Nomor

P.70/Menhut-II/2008 tentang Pedoman Rehabiltasi Hutan dan Lahan.

Jakarta.

Menteri Kehutanan RI. (2009a). Keputusan Menteri Kehutanan RI Nomor

Sk.445/Menhut-II/2009 tentang Penetapan Areal Kerja Hutan

Kemasyarakatan Jakarta: Kementerian Kehutanan.

Menteri Kehutanan RI. (2009b). Peraturan Menteri Kehutanan Republik

Indonesia No P.50/Menhut-II/2009 tentang Penegasan dan Fungsi

Kawasan Hutan.

Menteri Kehutanan RI. (2014a). Peraturan Menteri Kehutanan RI Nomor:

P.88/Menhut-II/2014 tentang Hutan Kemasyarakatan. Jakarta:

Kementerian Kehutanan.

Menteri Kehutanan RI. (2014b). Statistik Kementerian Kehutanan 2013. Jakarta:

Kementerian Kehutanan RI.

Menteri Pertanian RI. (1982). Keputusan Menteri Pertanian Nomor

756/Kpts/Um/1982 tentang Penunjukan Areal Hutan di Wilayah Propinsi

Dati I NTB Jakarta: Departemen Pertanian RI.

236

Milne, Sarah and Adams, Bill. (2012). Market Masquerades: Uncovering the

Politics of Community‐level Payments for Environmental Services in

Cambodia. Development and change, 43(1), 133-158. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-

7660.2011.01748.x

Montagnini, Florencia and Finney, Christopher. (2011). Payments for

Environmental Services in Latin America as a Tool for Restoration and

Rural Development. Ambio, 40(3), 285-297. doi: 10.1007/s13280-010-

0114-4

Moon, Hyungsik Roger and Perron, Benoit. (2006). Seemingly unrelated

regressions. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 1-9.

Mooney, Harold A, Ehrlich, Paul R and Daily, GE. (1997). Ecosystem services: a

fragmentary history. Nature's Services: societal dependence on natural

ecosystems, 11-19.

Muñoz-Piña, Carlos, Guevara, Alejandro, Torres, Juan Manuel and Braña,

Josefina. (2008). Paying for the hydrological services of Mexico's forests:

Analysis, negotiations and results. Ecological Economics, 65(4), 725-736.

doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.031

Muradian, R., Froger, G., Garcia‐Frapolli, E., Gómez‐Baggethun, E., Gowdy, J.,

Kosoy, N., . . . Farley, J. (2013). Payments for ecosystem services and the

fatal attraction of win‐win solutions. Conservation Letters, 6(4), 274-279.

doi: 10.1111/j.1755-263X.2012.00309.x

Muradian, Roldan, Corbera, Esteve, Pascual, Unai, Kosoy, Nicolas and May,

Peter H. (2010). Reconciling Theory and Practice: An Alternative

Conceptual Framework for Understanding Payments for Environmental

Services. Ecological Economics, 69(6), 1202-1208. doi:

10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.11.006

Muradian, Roldan and Rival, Laura. (2012). Between markets and hierarchies:

The challenge of governing ecosystem services. Ecosystem Services, 1(1),

93-100. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2012.07.009

Myers, Norman. (1976). An expanded approach to the problem of disappearing

species. Science, 193(4249), 198-202.

Nardo, M., Saisana, M., Saltelli, A., Tarantola, S., Hoffman, A. and Giovannini,

E. (2005). Handbook on Constructing Composite Indicators: Methodolgy

and User Guide. France: OECD Publishing.

Nawir, A.A., Murniati and Rumboko, L. (2008). Rehabilitasi hutan di Indonesia:

akan kemanakah arahnya setelah lebih dari tiga dasawarsa? Bogor,

Indonesia: Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR).

Neraca. (2013). Biaya Konservasi Hutan Masih Rendah. Retrieved 25 August,

2014, from http://www.neraca.co.id/article/23642/Biaya-Konservasi-Hutan-Masih-Rendah

Olson, Mancur. (1965). The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory

of collective action: Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

Ostrom, Elinor. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for

collective action. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Ostrom, Elinor. (1998). A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory of

collective action presidential address, American Political Science

Association, 1997. The American Political Science Review, 92(1), 1-22.

237

Ostrom, Elinor. (1999). Coping with tragedies of the commons. Annual Review of

Political Science, 2(1), 493-535. doi: 10.1146/annurev.polisci.2.1.493

Ostrom, Elinor. (2005). Self-Governance and Forest Resources. CIFOR

Occasional Paper No. 20.

Ostrom, Elinor. (2009). A general framework for analyzing sustainability of

social-ecological systems. Science, 325(5939), 419-422. doi:

10.1126/science.1172133

Ostrom, Elinor, Burger, Joanna, Field, Christopher B, Norgaard, Richard B and

Policansky, David. (1999). Revisiting the commons: local lessons, global

challenges. Science, 284(5412), 278-282.

Pagiola, Stefano. (2005). Payments for Environmental Services and the Poor:

Initial Lessons and Guidelines (Diaporama). Paper presented at the

Workshop on Environmental Services for Poverty Reduction and Food

Security, FAO, Roma.

Pagiola, Stefano. (2006). Payments for Environmental Services: An Introduction.

Washington: World Bank.

Pagiola, Stefano. (2007). Guideline for "Pro-Poor" PES. Washington: World

Bank.

Pagiola, Stefano. (2008). Payments for environmental services in Costa Rica.

Ecological Economics, 65(4), 712-724. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.07.033

Pagiola, Stefano, Arcenas, Agustin and Platais, Gunars. (2005). Can Payments for

Environmental Services Help Reduce Poverty? An Exploration of the

Issues and the Evidence to Date from Latin America. World Development,

33(2), 237-253. doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2004.07.011

Pagiola, Stefano and Platais, Gunars. (2002). Payments for Environmental

Services. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.

Pagiola, Stefano, Ramírez, Elías, Gobbi, José, de Haan, Cees, Ibrahim,

Muhammad, Murgueitio, Enrique and Ruíz, Juan Pablo. (2007). Paying for

the environmental services of silvopastoral practices in Nicaragua.

Ecological Economics, 64(2), 374-385. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.04.014

Pattanayak, Subhrendu K.;, Wunder, Sven ; and Ferraro, Paul J. (2010). Show me

the money: do payments supply environmental services in developing

countries? Review of environmental economics and policy, 4(2), 254-274.

doi: 10.1093/reep/req006

PDAM Giri Menang. (2013). Profil PDAM Giri Menang 2008-2013. Mataram:

PDAM Giri Menang.

PDAM Giri Menang. (2014). Data Penggunaan Air dan Pembayaran Jasa

Lingkungan. Mataram: PDAM Giri Menang.

PDAM Giri Menang. (2016). Rekap Pembayaran Jasa Lingkungan yang disetor ke

Kas Pemda Lobar. Mataram: PDAM Giri Menang.

Peluso, Nancy Lee. (1992). Rich forests, poor people: resource control and

resistance in Java: Univ of California Press.

Pemerintah Kabupaten Lombok Barat. (2014). Profil Desa. Gerung: Badan

Pemberdayaan Masyarakat dan Pemerintahan Desa Kabupaten Lombok

Barat.

238

Pereira, Simone NovotnyCouto (2010). Payment for environmental services in the

Amazon Forest: how can conservation and development be reconciled?

The journal of environment & development, 19(2), 171-190. doi:

10.1177/1070496510368047

Perrings, Charles, Folke, Carl and Mäler, Karl-Göran. (1992). The ecology and

economics of biodiversity loss: the research agenda. Ambio, 201-211.

Persoon, Gerard, Est, Diny M.E. van and Sajise, Persy E. (2003). Co-management

of Natural Resources in Asia: A Comparative Perspective (Vol. no. 7.).

Copenhagen: NIAS.

Peskett, Leo, Schreckenberg, Kate and Brown, Jessica. (2011). Institutional

approaches for carbon financing in the forest sector: learning lessons for

REDD+ from forest carbon projects in Uganda. Environmental Science

and Policy, 14(2), 216-229. doi: 10.1016/j.envsci.2010.10.004

Pigou, Arthur Cecil. (1932). The economics of welfare. London: Palgrave

Macmillan.

Pimentel, David, Littman, S., Garnick, E., Berkowitz, A., Jacobson, S.,

Napolitano, S., . . . Hudes, E. (1980). Environmental Quality and Natural

Biota. BioScience, 30(11), 750-755.

Pirard, Romain. (2012). Payments for Environmental Services (PES) in the public

policy landscape: “Mandatory” spices in the Indonesian recipe. Forest

Policy and Economics, 18(0), 23-29. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2011.09.002

Pirard, Romain and Belna, Karine. (2012). Agriculture and Deforestation: Is

REDD+ Rooted In Evidence? Forest Policy and Economics, 21(0), 62-70.

doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2012.01.012

Poteete, Amy R, Janssen, Marco A and Ostrom, Elinor. (2010). Working together:

collective action, the commons, and multiple methods in practice:

Princeton University Press.

Prasetyo, F. A., Suwarno, A., Purwanto and Hakim, R. (2009). Making Policies

Work for Payment for Environmental Services (PES): An Evaluation of

the Experience of Formulating Conservation Policies in Districts of

Indonesia. Journal of Sustainable Forestry, 28(3-5), 415-433. doi:

10.1080/10549810902791531

Presiden RI. (1970). Peraturan Pemerintah Nomor 21 Tahun 1970 tentang Hak

Pengusahaan Hutan dan Hak Pemungutan Hasil Hutan.

Putnam, Robert D. (1995). Tuning In, Tuning Out: The Strange Disappearance of

Social Capital in America. PS: Political Science and Politics, 28(4), 664-

683.

Ramli, Rizal and Ahmad, Mubariq. (1994). Rente ekonomi pengusahaan hutan

Indonesia. Jakarta: Wahana Lingkungan Hidup Indonesia.

Rao, Vaman and Chotigeat, Tosporn. (1981). The Inverse Relationship Between

Size of Land Holdings and Agricultural Productivity. American Journal of

Agricultural Economics, 63(3), 571-574.

Rao, Vijayendra and Woolcock, Michael. (2003). Integrating Qualitative and

Quantitative Approaches in Program Evaluation. In F. Bourguignon and

L.P. da Silva (Ed.), The Impact of Economics Policies on Poverty and

Income Distribution: Evaluation Techniques and tools (pp. 165-190). New

York: Oxford University Press.

239

Reed, David. (2006). Escaping Poverty's Grasp: The Environmental Foundations

of Poverty Reduction. UK and USA: Taylor & Francis.

Riyadi, Riyadi, Hartini, Sri, Rudyansah, Zulhan, Anam, Chairul, Hastuti, Adwi,

Setiyawati, Nia, . . . Aprilia, Ira. (2015). Welfare Indicators 2015. Jakarta:

Badan Pusat Statistik.

Robalino, Juan and Pfaff, Alexander. (2013). Ecopayments and deforestation in

Costa Rica: a nationwide analysis of PSA's initial years. Land economics,

89(3), 432-448.

Rodriguez, Carlos Manuel. (2012). Costa Rica Leading the Way in Incentivizing

Protection for Nature. Retrieved 17/03/2017, from http://blog.conservation.org/2012/03/costa-rica-leading-the-way-in-incentivizing-protection-of-nature/

Rosyadi, Slamet, Birner, Regina and Zeller, Manfred. (2005). Creating political

capital to promote devolution in the forestry sector—a case study of the

forest communities in Banyumas district, Central Java, Indonesia. Forest

Policy and Economics, 7(2), 213-226. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1389-9341(03)00027-3

Samad, Samsyiah. (2012). Efektivitas Program Hutan Kemasyarakatan di Pulau

Lombok Provinsi Nusa Tenggara Barat (Studi Kasus pada Kawasan

Hutan Lindung Sesaot Kabupaten Lombok Barat dan Kawasan Hutan

Lindung Batukliang Utara Kabupaten Lombok Tengah). Master Thesis.

Magister Pengelolaan Sumberdaya Lahan Kering. Universitas Mataram.

Mataram.

Saman, Effendi, Hutapea, Anthony L. P., Wailayatiningsih and Hasannudin, Lili.

(1993). Politik hukum pengusahaan hutan di Indonesia. Jakarta: Wahana

Lingkungan Hidup Indonesia.

Sánchez-Azofeifa, G. Arturo and Pfaff, Alexander. (2007). Costa Rica's Payment

for Environmental Services Program: Intention, Implementation, and

Impact. Conservation Biology, 21(5), 1165-1173. doi: 10.1111/j.1523-

1739.2007.00751.x

Sanwal, Mukul. (1988). Community Forestry: Policy Issues, Institutional

Arrangements, and Bureaucratic Reorientation. Ambio, 17(5), 342-346.

Sattler, Claudia and Matzdorf, Bettina. (2013). PES in a nutshell: From definitions

and origins to PES in practice—Approaches, design process and

innovative aspects. Ecosystem Services, 6, 2-11. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2013.09.009

Sattler, Claudia, Trampnau, Susanne, Schomers, Sarah, Meyer, Claas and

Matzdorf, Bettina. (2013). Multi-classification of payments for ecosystem

services: How do classification characteristics relate to overall PES

success? Ecosystem Services, 6, 31-45. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2013.09.007

SBP. (2010). Laporan Akhir Kegiatan Pengembangan Hasil Hutan Non Kayu

(Pengembangan Jasa Lingkungan) Tahun Anggaran 2010 (Subdin Bina

Produksi, Trans.). Gerung: Dinas Kehutanan Lombok Barat.

SBP. (2012). Laporan Akhir Kegiatan Pengembangan Hasil Hutan Non Kayu

(Pengembangan Jasa Lingkungan) Tahun Anggaran 2012 (Subdin Bina

Produksi, Trans.). Gerung: Dinas Kehutanan Lombok Barat.

240

Scott, John. (2000). Rational choice theory. Understanding contemporary society:

Theories of the present, 129.

Sekretariat Daerah Lombok Barat. (2007). Peraturan Daerah Kabupaten Lombok

Barat No 4 Tahun 2007 Tentang Pengelolaan Jasa Lingkungan. Gerung:

Kabupaten Lombok Barat.

Shyamsundar, Priya and Ghate, Rucha (2014). Rights, Rewards, and Resources:

Lessons from Community Forestry in South Asia. Review of

Environmental Economics and Policy, 8(1), 80-102. doi:

10.1093/reep/ret022

Sikor, Thomas. (2006). Analyzing community-based forestry: Local, political and

agrarian perspectives. Forest Policy and Economics, 8(4), 339-349. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2005.08.005

Simon, Hasanu. (1994). Merencanakan pembangunan hutan untuk strategi

kehutanan sosial. Yogyakarta: Aditya Media.

Smith, Joyotee, Obidzinski, Krystof, Subarudi, Subarudi and Suramenggala,

Iman. (2003). Illegal logging, collusive corruption and fragmented

governments in Kalimantan, Indonesia. International Forestry Review,

5(3), 293-302.

Sodhi, Navjot S., Koh, Lian Pin, Clements, Reuben, Wanger, Thomas C., Hill,

Jane K., Hamer, Keith C., . . . Lee, Tien Ming. (2010). Conserving

Southeast Asian forest biodiversity in human-modified landscapes.

Biological Conservation, 143(10), 2375-2384. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.biocon.2009.12.029

Sommerville, M. M., Jones, J. P. G. and Milner-Gulland, E. J. (2009). A Revised

Conceptual Framework for Payments for Environmental Services. Ecology

and Society, 14(2), 400-434.

Sommerville, Matthew, Milner-Gulland, EJ, Rahajaharison, Michael and Jones,

Julia PG. (2010). Impact of a Community‐Based Payment for

Environmental Services Intervention on Forest Use in Menabe,

Madagascar. Conservation Biology, 24(6), 1488-1498.

Stringer, L. C., Dougill, A. J., Thomas, A. D., Spracklen, D. V., Chesterman, S.,

Speranza, C. Ifejika, . . . Kopolo, G. (2012). Challenges and opportunities

in linking carbon sequestration, livelihoods and ecosystem service

provision in drylands. Environmental Science & Policy, 19–20(0), 121-

135. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.envsci.2012.02.004

Stringer, R., Zilberman, D., Lipper, N. L., Bulte, E. H. and McCartney, L. (2008).

Payments for ecosystem services and poverty reduction: concepts, issues,

and empirical perspectives Environment and Development Economics

(Vol. 13, pp. 245-254). New York: Cambridge Univ Press.

Sunderlin, W. D., Resosudarmo, I. A. P., Rianto, E. and Angelsen, A. (2000). The

effect of Indonesia’s economic crisis on small farmers and natural forest

cover in the Outer Islands CIFOR Occasional Paper (Vol. 28(E), pp.

36p). Bogor: CIFOR.

Sunderlin, William D. (2006). Poverty alleviation through community forestry in

Cambodia, Laos, and Vietnam: An assessment of the potential. Forest

Policy and Economics, 8(4), 386-396. doi: 10.1016/j.forpol.2005.08.008

241

Tacconi, Luca. (2012). Redefining payments for environmental services.

Ecological Economics, 73(0), 29-36. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2011.09.028

Tacconi, Luca, Mahanty, Sango and Suich, Helen. (2013). The Livelihood

Impacts of Payments for Environmental Services and Implications for

REDD. Society and Natural Resources, 26(6), 733-744. doi:

10.1080/08941920.2012.724151

The Nature Conservancy. (2012). Sustainable Agriculture: Efficient and

Responsible Use of Natural Resources. Brazil: The Nature Conservancy.

The Nature Conservancy. (2017). Water funds help to provide fresh water today

and into the future. Retrieved 17/03/2017, from https://www.nature.org/ourinitiatives/regions/latinamerica/water-funds-of-south-america.xml

The World Bank. (2004). Project Appraisal Document on a Proposed Grant from

The Global Environment Facility Trust Fund in the Amount of US$9.0

Million to The Republic of South Africa for The Cafe Biodiversity

Conservation and Sustainable Development Project (Rural and Social

Development Environmental, Trans.).

The World Bank. (2008). Implementation Completion and Result Report

(Environmentally and Socially Sustainable Development, Trans.): World

Bank.

Thoms, Christopher A. (2008). Community control of resources and the challenge

of improving local livelihoods: A critical examination of community

forestry in Nepal. Geoforum, 39(3), 1452-1465. doi:

10.1016/j.geoforum.2008.01.006

Torres, Arturo Balderas, MacMillan, Douglas C., Skutsch, Margaret and Lovett,

Jon C. (2013). Payments for ecosystem services and rural development:

Landowners' preferences and potential participation in western Mexico.

Ecosystem Services, 6(0), 72-81. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecoser.2013.03.002

Tschakert, Petra. (2007). Environmental services and poverty reduction: Options

for smallholders in the Sahel. Agricultural Systems, 94(1), 75-86. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.agsy.2005.07.010

Tscharntke, Teja, Clough, Yann, Bhagwat, Shonil A, Buchori, Damayanti, Faust,

Heiko, Hertel, Dietrich, . . . Perfecto, Ivette. (2011). Multifunctional

shade‐tree management in tropical agroforestry landscapes–a review.

Journal of Applied Ecology, 48(3), 619-629.

Turner, R.K., Pearce D. and Bateman, I. (1994). Environmental Economics, An

elementary Introduction. United Kingdom: Prentice Hall Press.

Ulvevadet, Birgitte and Hausner, Vera H. (2011). Incentives and regulations to

reconcile conservation and development: Thirty years of governance of the

Sami pastoral ecosystem in Finnmark, Norway. Journal of Environmental

Management, 92(10), 2794-2802. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2011.06.026

UN. (2015). We Can End Poverty. Millenium Development Goals and Beyond

2015. from http://www.un.org/millenniumgoals/poverty.shtml

Undang Undang Dasar Negara Republik Indonesia (1945).

242

Undang-Undang RI Nomor 5 Tahun 1960 tentang Peraturan Dasar Pokok-Pokok

Agraria (1960).

Undang Undang RI Nomor 41 Tahun 1999 tentang Kehutanan (1999).

Undang-Undang RI Nomor 18 tahun 2013 Tentang Pencegahan dan

Pemberantasan Perusakan Hutan (2013).

van den Bergh, Jeroen C. J. M. (2010). Externality or sustainability economics?

Ecological Economics, 69(11), 2047-2052. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.02.009

Van der Kraan, Alfons. (1980). Lombok: conquest, colonization, and

underdevelopment, 1870-1940 (Vol. 5.). Singapore: Published for the

Asian Studies Association of Australia by Heinemann Educational Books

(Asia).

van Wilgen, B. W., Le Maitre, D. C. and Cowling, R. M. (1998). Ecosystem

services, efficiency, sustainability and equity: South Africa's Working for

Water programme. Trends in Ecology & Evolution, 13(9), 378-378. doi:

10.1016/S0169-5347(98)01434-7

Vatn, Arild. (2010). An institutional analysis of payments for environmental

services. Ecological Economics, 69(6), 1245-1252. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2009.11.018

Vayda, Andrew P and Rappaport, Roy A. (1968). Ecology, cultural and

noncultural. Introduction to cultural anthropology, 477-497.

Venter, Oscar and Koh, Lian Pin. (2012). Reducing emissions from deforestation

and forest degradation (REDD+): game changer or just another quick fix?

Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences, 1249(1), 137-150. doi:

10.1111/j.1749-6632.2011.06306.x

Wade, Robert. (1987). The management of common property resources: collective

action as an alternative to privatisation or state regulation. Cambridge

journal of economics, 11(2), 95-106.

Wang, Li-an;, Zhong, Fang-Lei; and Guo, Xiao-dong. (2009). A Research

Framework of the Relationship Between Payments for Environmetal

Services and Poverty Alleviation in China. Paper presented at the The !st

International Conference on Information Science and Enginering (ICISE

2009).

Warren, Carol. (2005). Mapping Common Futures: Customary Communities,

NGOs and the State in Indonesia's Reform Era. Development and Change,

36(1), 49-73. doi: 10.1111/j.0012-155X.2005.00402.x

Warren, Carol and McCarthy, John. (2009). Community, Environment and Local

Governance in Indonesia: Locating the Commonweal (Vol. 22). London

and New York: Routledge.

Westman, Walter E. (1977). How Much Are Nature's Services Worth? Science,

197(4307), 960-964. doi: 10.1126/science.197.4307.960

Wollenberg, Eva, Moeliono, Moira, Limberg, Godwin, Iwan, Ramses, Rhee,

Steve and Sudana, Made. (2006). Between state and society: Local

governance of forests in Malinau, Indonesia. Forest Policy and

Economics, 8(4), 421-433. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2005.08.012

World Bank Group. (2012). World development indicators 2012: World Bank

Publications.

243

World Resources Institute. (2017). CAIT Climate Data Editor. Retrieved

02/06/2017, from http://cait.wri.org/

Wulandari, Rizka. (2011). Pemodelan Spasial Deforestasi di Pulau Lombok, Nusa

Tenggara Barat, Periode 2000 - 2010. Institut Pertanian Bogor, Bogor.

Wunder, Sven. (2001). Poverty Alleviation and Tropical Forests—What Scope for

Synergies? World Development, 29(11), 1817-1833. doi: 10.1016/S0305-

750X(01)00070-5

Wunder, Sven. (2005). Payment For Environmental Services : some nuts and

bolts. CIFOR Occasional Paper No. 42.

Wunder, Sven. (2007). The Efficiency of Payments for Environmental Services in

Tropical Conservation. Conservation Biology, 21(1), 48-58. doi:

10.1111/j.1523-1739.2006.00559.x

Wunder, Sven. (2008). Payments for environmental services and the poor:

concepts and preliminary evidence. Environment and Development

Economics, 13(3), 279-297. doi: 10.1017/S1355770X08004282

Wunder, Sven. (2013). When payments for environmental services will work for

conservation. Conservation Letters, 6(4), 230-237. doi:

10.1111/conl.12034

Wunder, Sven and Albán, Montserrat. (2008). Decentralized payments for

environmental services: The cases of Pimampiro and PROFAFOR in

Ecuador. Ecological Economics, 65(4), 685-698. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2007.11.004

Wunder, Sven, Engel, Stefanie and Pagiola, Stefano. (2008). Taking stock: A

comparative analysis of payments for environmental services programs in

developed and developing countries. Ecological Economics, 65(4), 834-

852. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2008.03.010

WWF. (1996). Indigenous People and Conservation. WWF Statements and

Principles. Gland: World Wildlife Fund for Nature (WWF).

WWF. (2014). Jasa Lingkungan: Inisiatif Pendanaan Berkelanjutan Untuk

Kawasan Rinjani. Mataram: World Wildlife Fund for Nature

WWF. (2017). WWF and Payments for Ecosystem Services. Retrieved

17/03/2017, from http://wwf.panda.org/what_we_do/where_we_work/black_sea_basin/danube_carpathian/our_solutions/green_economy/pes/

Yandle, Bruce. (1997). Common Sense and Common Law for the Environment:

Creating Wealth in Hummingbird Economies. Lanham: Rowman &

Littlefield Publishers.

Zhang, L., Tu, Q. and Mol, A. P. J. (2008). Payment for Environmental Services:

The Sloping Land Conversion Program in Ningxia Autonomous Region of

China. China & World Economy, 16(2), 66-81. doi: 10.1111/j.1749-

124X.2008.00107.x