structures for nonhierarchical organizations

17
STRUCTURES FOR NONHIERARCHICAL ORGANIZATIONS by Barry O’Neill Northwestern University, Evanston Nonhierarchical organizations avoid the disadvantages in traditional organizations arising from the superior-subordinate relationship and from the unequal distribution of information in the group. They are discussed from the point of view of: (1) coordi- nation of some members by others, (2) efficient communication, (3) rational assignment of subtasks to parts of the organization, and (4) possibilities for organizational growth. Tree-shaped (hierarchical) organizations are popular because they allow these func- tions to be performed by a single structure, so that each function promotes the effec- tiveness of the others. A nonhierarchical organization with this advantage can be designed based on finite geometrical spaces. This paper deals with decision making at the level of the organization. KEY WORDS: organization, decision making, conflict resolution, communication networks, modularity, growth. 013 1. INTRODUCTION. Y A tree-structured organization we will B mean one in which every member ex- cept one has a unique immediate superior. The exceptional person is “at the top” and has no superior. Trees are simple and common types of hierarchical organizations. In theory most formal organizations are trees, since their organization charts show an authority structure in that shape, but in fact most are less extreme, containing superior-sub- ordinate relationships but not to the extent that almost everyone has only one super- visor. A nonhierarchically-structured organiza- tion is one in which the superior-subordi- nate relationship does not exist at all. “Nonhierarchical organization” may seem a contradiction: With no superiors and sub- ordinates, could an organization be any more than a homogeneous group of people? However we will see that organizations without hierarchy can be designed, and can fulfill the same functions as trees do. Three questions will be considered 1) What forms could a nonhierarchical organization have? 2) What advantages do tree structures have that make them so popular? 3) What organizational tasks and envi- ronments favor one type of structure or the other? 61 Behavioral Science, Volume 29, 19&1 The second and third questions are sub- sidiary to the first, in the sense that we can discuss the advantages of a tree only with a specific alternative in mind. As we look for substitutes for a tree, the difficulties encountered will clarify the relative bene- fits of tree-structures in particular environ- ments. Problems of trees will be discussed (sec- tion 2), along with the types of situations where nonhierarchical alternatives are likely to succeed (section 3). The essential problems for any organization are: coordi- nation of the members, communication among the members, and the logical assign- ment of members to tasks. These are the topics of the succeeding three sections, 4 to 6. Section 7 deals with the possibility of nondisruptive growth in each type of de- sign. Section 8 will discuss how trees inte- grate the various functions that an organi- zation must perform, and section 9 will show how the same functions can be inte- grated nonhierarchically using organiza- tions based on finite geometries. 2. PROBLEMS OF TREE STRUCTURES Why should we look for an alternative to trees? In many situations they do not ac- complish the organization’s goals, and have negative side effects as well. Problems arise from the superior-subordinate relationship and the consequent division of labor be-

Upload: barry-oneill

Post on 06-Jun-2016

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

STRUCTURES FOR NONHIERARCHICAL ORGANIZATIONS

by Barry O’Neill Northwestern University, Evanston

Nonhierarchical organizations avoid the disadvantages in traditional organizations arising from the superior-subordinate relationship and from the unequal distribution of information in the group. They are discussed from the point of view of: (1) coordi- nation of some members by others, (2) efficient communication, (3) rational assignment of subtasks to parts of the organization, and (4) possibilities for organizational growth. Tree-shaped (hierarchical) organizations are popular because they allow these func- tions to be performed by a single structure, so that each function promotes the effec- tiveness of the others. A nonhierarchical organization with this advantage can be designed based on finite geometrical spaces. This paper deals with decision making at the level of the organization.

KEY WORDS: organization, decision making, conflict resolution, communication networks, modularity, growth.

013

1. INTRODUCTION.

Y A tree-structured organization we will B mean one in which every member ex- cept one has a unique immediate superior. The exceptional person is “at the top” and has no superior.

Trees are simple and common types of hierarchical organizations. In theory most formal organizations are trees, since their organization charts show an authority structure in that shape, but in fact most are less extreme, containing superior-sub- ordinate relationships but not to the extent that almost everyone has only one super- visor.

A nonhierarchically-structured organiza- tion is one in which the superior-subordi- nate relationship does not exist at all. “Nonhierarchical organization” may seem a contradiction: With no superiors and sub- ordinates, could an organization be any more than a homogeneous group of people? However we will see that organizations without hierarchy can be designed, and can fulfill the same functions as trees do.

Three questions will be considered 1) What forms could a nonhierarchical

organization have? 2) What advantages do tree structures

have that make them so popular? 3) What organizational tasks and envi-

ronments favor one type of structure or the other?

61

Behavioral Science, Volume 29, 19&1

The second and third questions are sub- sidiary to the first, in the sense that we can discuss the advantages of a tree only with a specific alternative in mind. As we look for substitutes for a tree, the difficulties encountered will clarify the relative bene- fits of tree-structures in particular environ- ments.

Problems of trees will be discussed (sec- tion 2), along with the types of situations where nonhierarchical alternatives are likely to succeed (section 3). The essential problems for any organization are: coordi- nation of the members, communication among the members, and the logical assign- ment of members to tasks. These are the topics of the succeeding three sections, 4 to 6. Section 7 deals with the possibility of nondisruptive growth in each type of de- sign. Section 8 will discuss how trees inte- grate the various functions that an organi- zation must perform, and section 9 will show how the same functions can be inte- grated nonhierarchically using organiza- tions based on finite geometries.

2. PROBLEMS OF TREE STRUCTURES

Why should we look for an alternative to trees? In many situations they do not ac- complish the organization’s goals, and have negative side effects as well. Problems arise from the superior-subordinate relationship and the consequent division of labor be-

Page 2: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

62 BARRY O’NEILL

tween front-line work and administration: the operating staff at the bottom does the specific work of the organization, while the strategic planners at the top make long- range decisions. Ironically, those having the least contact with the daily activities of the organization make the most important decisions. The exclusion of those at the bottom from policy making produces a sense of alienation from their work and a lack of identification with the organiza- tion’s goals.

The superior-subordinate relationship also supports a system of unequal rewards in the form of differences in power, status, and remuneration. In large corporations some workers may be paid less than one- fiftieth as much as the high executives. This disparity has been criticized as an unjust and inefficient distribution of the benefits of the work, and one that has neg- ative consequences for all of society.

A further difficulty is that trees lead to compartmentalization of the organization’s members. Communication between differ- ent sections of the tree is low and they may work at cross-purposes. This is exacerbated as each department performs narrow tasks and acquires specialized knowledge differ- ent from the others. Toward the bottom the work becomes so narrow that it is ex- tremely monotonous and unsatisfying.

Past solutions to the problems of trees

These problems have been widely dis- cussed, and two general classes of solutions have been suggested. The first retains the basic tree structure but adds features to try to alleviate its drawbacks. Some examples are the human relations movement (Likert, 1961), and proposals to flatten organiza- tions (decrease the number of intermediate managers) with the goal of putting the stra- tegic planners into more direct contact with the operating staff. Another suggestion is to decentralize decision making (Jenner- gren, 1980) in order to increase workers’ commitment to the organization’s goals and improve the quality of the decisions. Systematically adding communication links beween departments has been pro- posed through the scheme of matrix orga-

nizations (Galbraith, 1973) and through li- aison people who connect specific groups.

Solutions in the second class are more basic: They eliminate the tree altogether and replace it with a group of equal mem- bers. These are “collectives” or “participa- tory democracies,” in which the formal structure of the organization is no longer defined by a set of roles, but by procedures which allow the organization to function efficiently in an egalitarian way. Rules of job rotation, group decision-making, and others are chosen so that inequalities in influence and specialization of skill or knowledge are avoided. Organizations of this type have multiplied in the last 20 years, and include food cooperatives, med- ical clinics, legal clinics, alternative schools, and political action groups (Mans- bridge, 1973,1976; Rothschild-Whitt, 1979; Swidler, 1979; Freeman, 1972).

This paper shares the goals of the second group of authors, and their commitment to egalitarian structures, with the difference that our organizations give the members specific roles.

3. RANGE OF APPLICATION OF NONHIERARCHICAL STRUCTURES.

These designs are not intended to replace trees in all situations. We believe that they would work best to the extent that the following conditions hold

1) The organization is small.

Most of the structures presented here involve more intense interaction among members than do trees, where members must deal only with those immediately un- derneath, i.e., those in their “span of con- trol,” which is usually deliberately limited. To avoid spending too much time on inter- nal interactions, the organizations we en- vision will have no more than about 50 members.

2) The environment and the task are complex, unpredictable, and call for in- novative solutions.

In a variable environment a tree-struc- ture tends to respond too slowly. Informa- tion about external contingencies comes

Behavioral Science, Volume 29,19&1

Page 3: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

NONHIERARCHICAL ORGANIZATIONS 63

from the various members, but is either stifled on the way up, or overloads the person at the top. Frequently organizations in this type of environment become “ad- hocracies,” a term introduced by Toffler (1970) and discussed by Mintzberg (1979). These groups have a structure that can shift in response to the demands of the task, and tend to arise in firms dealing in fast-changing technology. Communication is emphasized over control mechanisms or standardization of jobs. An administrative superstructure usually exists, but spends more time supporting than directing the staff. Adhocracies share many of the char- acteristics of collectives, and are one type of organization for which nonhierarchical structures are feasible.

3)

4)

In

The members are motivated by the goals of the organization, not by a de- sire for money, status, or power. The members understand and have a personal commitment to nonhierarch- ical structures.

traditional organizations inequality and’the gradient of benefits are used as incentives, and, therefore, an egalitarian structure would be less motivating to some- one oriented to that approach. That mem- bers share the organization’s goals is very much a feature of adhocracies and collec- tives, so nonhierarchical structures seem appropriate for these groups.

The schemes described here are not com- plete, in the sense that they define only the skeleton of a working entity. Our aim is to develop the models to a point where their basic form is clear and they can be evalu- ated as alternatives to trees.

4. EXOGENOUS COORDINATION- CONFLICT RESOLUTION

A basic organizational function is coor- dination of the members. Coordination of any subgroup can be done either by some outside party or the people in the subgroup themselves. First we discuss the former case, exogenous coordination and deal with the situation of members who left on their own would act in incompatible ways, and consequently a certain third member has

been given the duty of coordinating their activities. This could involve such tasks as dividing resources among departments, as- signing people to jobs, or planning mem- bers’ future activities. The situations here are those in which the members cannot reach an agreement themselves. Self-coor- dination through mutual adjustment or bargaining will be treated in section 5 under the topic of communication.

Conflict resolution in trees

Assuming that two people enter into a conflict any formal organization needs a rule for deciding who the conflict resolver will be. If the organization has a tree-struc- ture, we can reason as follows: the third party must have authority over both, and, therefore, should be above both in the tree. Also, the resolver should be the lowest per- son who is above both; that is, should be the least common superior of the two coor- dinatees. (Friedell, 1967, discusses these ideas, along with Boyle, 1969, and Pattison & Bartlett, 1975.)

The idea of going to the least common superior is reflected in the organizational norm of “Don’t go over the boss’s head.” If two members of the same department take their dispute directly to the president, this undermines the authority of the division director and uses the time of the president inefficiently. The disputants should be re- luctant to do this, and the president should be reluctant to hear a complaint. The one exception is for disputes involving the rights of the people vis-a-vis the organiza- tion, e.g., the case of a division head who assigns tasks that were not part of the member’s job description. However, for normal administrative matters, authority rests with the least common superior.

This is not to claim that the least com- mon superior will make the decision com- pletely independently. If the question is nonroutine and touches wider issues, it may be referred to someone higher up. That notwithstanding, for typical problems the primary responsibility rests with the least common superior.

The least common superior is easy to locate using the organization chart-one

Behavioral Science, Volume 29, 1984

Page 4: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

64 BARRY O’NEILL

2

3

4

5

simply starts at the two members, and fol- lows the two chains of command upward until they meet.

We will represent individuals by small letters x, y, z, etc., and specific individuals by numbers, 1, 2, 3, etc. It will be assumed that the number of members is finite. Fol- lowing Friedell, the operator * will mean the conflict resolver for the two members, i.e., x*y will be the individual whose duty it is to arbitrate between x and y.

Each organization will hve its own oper- ator, *, which can be specified by a “multi- plication table” showing the value of x*y for every pair x and y. A sample tree with its multiplication table is shown in Fig- ure 1.

What are the general properties of the operator * for a tree organization? First of all, for any two members, there is always some member responsible for coordinating them:

(Tl) For all x, y, there is a member z

such that x * y = z.

Also, * is idempotent, that is, for different actions by a single person that must be made mutually compatible, the responsibil- ity lies with that individual. (T2) x * x = x .

Thirdly, the operator is symmetrical:

(7’3) x * y = y * x. Next, imagine a situation in which a

member enters a dispute with one of his or her own superiors. The boss will have the privilege of deciding the issue, by definition of the relationship of superiority. This is

1 1 1 1 1 1

1 2 1 1 1

1 1 3 3 3

1 1 3 4 3

1 1 3 3 5

/I? 4 5

1 2 3 4 5

FIG. 1. Organization chart and multiplication ta- ble for a tree.

what makes trees hierarchical. Noting that “x * y” designates a superior of both x and y, we can express this axiomatically:

(T4) x * (x * y ) = x * y.

Next, * is associative.

(T5) x * ( y * z ) = (x * y ) * z.

This can be understood most easily by conjoining it with (T3). The two imply that

(x * z ) , etc., so the order of appearance of individuals in the conflict is irrelevant. The identity of the resolver will depend only on the set of people in the conflict.

A final property is that there exists a single chain of command. If x is a subordi- nate of two people, here represented as x * y and x * z, then one of the two must be over the other.

(T6)

x * ( y * z ) = (x*y) * z = ( y * x ) * z = y *

(x * Y ) * (x * z ) = either x * y or x * z.

These six axioms are necessary and suf- ficient to characterize a tree, and are inde- pendent of each other in the sense that it is possible to define organizations that fol- low any subset. To show that they imply a tree-structure, define: x is a superior of y if and only if x * y = x. Since * satisfies (Tl) to (T5), the superiority relationship will be a partial order. To show that it will also be a tree, note that by (T6) no one can have two immediate superiors. There must be at least one greatest member, i.e., someone with no superior, since the structure is a finite partial order, but there can be no more than one greatest member. (If there were two who would resolve this pair’s con- flicts, as required by T l ? ) Therefore there is exactly one greatest member and the organization is a tree. The independence of the axioms can be shown by constructing a series of multiplication tables as counter- examples.

Coordination in nonhierarchical structures To design a nonhierarchical organization

we must specify its operator *, which is equivalent to filling in the multiplication

Hehavinral Science, Volume 29. 1984

Page 5: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

NONHIERARCHICAL ORGANIZATIONS 65

table. The number of possibilities is enor- mous, so we must explicate the concept of “nonhierarchical” and find tables consist- ent with that idea.

As in the case of trees we require that the operator be completely defined, sym- metrical and idempotent. For trees these were the axioms (Tl), (T2), and (T3). The new ones will be identical but labelled (Sl), (S2), and (S3).

A new assumption is that the resolver is never one of the parties in conflict:

(S4) x * y # x and # y.

This is exactly the opposite of the tree axiom (T4). Just as it was (T4) that made trees hierarchical by allowing one person to rule another consistently, it is (S4) that makes the present organizations nonhier- archical, since for no pair of members can one always prevail.

Many multiplication tables are consist- ent with (Sl) to (S4), but most of these have the objectionable feature that a two- person conflict tends to spread. Suppose that x and y are in conflict, that x * y = z, and that x is unhappy with z’s decision. Individual x now has a conflict with z, and it seems plausible that x would pursue this and go to x * z, who is, say, w. If w decides against x , then x has a conflict with w, etc., or alternatively, if w supports x , then the dispute is now between w and y, and also between w and z. The disagreement perco- lates through the organization.

In fact, this has been a problem for non- hierarchical groups: small disagreements tend to expand, cause divisions, and waste the time of the whole membership. Group meetings become tediously long, debating matters that are relevant to only a few people (Mansbridge, 1973; Kanter, 1972).

Trees deal with this problem very ele- gantly. If x is not content with x * y’s decision, then x could complain to x * ( x * y), but what would be gained? Since x * y is a superior of x , the decider of the second conflict will also be x * y, as follows from (T4), and the latter will of course decide in his or her own favor. In a tree, appealing a decision is useless.

We need to impose a requirement on the operator * that limits the spread of conflict, a substitute for the tree axion (T4). One way, the simplest we can think of, is to add the following:

(S5) x * ( x * y ) = y.

Given (S5), there will be no reason for x to press a complaint past its initial hearing. If x complains against y, define z = x * y and assume that z supports y. It would be fruitless for x to take the matter to x * z, since the latter person is y, and it is already clear that y stands with z in opposition to x’s position.

We must now ask if (Sl) through (S5) are contradictory, whether it is possible to satisfy all five simultaneously. In fact it is possible, and the first step in showing this is to make an inference about the structure of *. Any operator on pairs of a finite num- ber of elements can, of course, be repre- sented as a list of ordered triples, where for example the operator value for x and y yielding z appears on the list as the triple ( x , y, z) . This particular operator * has the special property that if (x, y, z ) appears on the list, so will ( x , z, y ) and all other order- ings of the three, as a consequence of (S3) and (S5). Thus * can be represented as a list of unordered triples.

The list gives a rule for finding the co- ordinator of any pair of members-we look up the unique triple containing both x and y, and the third element will be the coor- dinator of x and y. Since every pair of members appears in exactly one triple, the rule always works. An example of a list is given in Figure 2.

If a pair occurs in exactly one triple, this implies that such lists exist only for certain numbers of elements. This was demon- strated by Kirkman (1847) who showed that the total number of elements n must lie in the set 11, 3, 7,9, 13, 15, 19, 21, . . - 1, or in general n must give a remainder of 1 or 3 after division by 6. Such a list is called a Steiner triple system (Hall, 1967; Lindner & Rosa, 19801, and the mathematical entity of an abstract set and an operator satisfying (Sl) through (S5) is a Steiner quasigroup

Hehavioral Science, Volume 29. 1984

Page 6: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

66

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

BARRY ONEILL

r 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

FIG.

1 3 2 7 6 5 4

3 2 1 6 7 4 5

2 1 3 5 4 7 6

7 6 5 4 3 2 1

6 7 4 ’ 5 5 1 2

5 4 7 2 1 6 3

4 5 6 1 2 3 7

123 14 7 156 246 25 7 345 36 7

2. Multiplication table, list, and chart representations for

(Bruck, 1971; Quackenbush, 1976). It seems logical then to call organizations with con- flict-resolving structures specified by (S l ) through (S5), Steiner organizations.

An example of a multiplication table for a seven-member organization is shown in Figure 2. It is simpler to represent it as a list of triples, as shown there, and an even clearer way for the visually-oriented is to draw the individuals as points and indicate membership in a triple by joining the three points with a line or a curve, as shown in Figure 2. This is the “organization chart” of a Steiner organization.

Another way to look at a Steiner orga- nization is as a collection of interlocking three-person committees, each of which functions by majority vote. Clearly the out- come of any two-person disagreement will be the same whether it is decided by a vote of the three or by asking the third member to arbitrate.

Steiner organizations do not exhibit the division of administration versus line-work found in trees, since everyone does both. This has its precedents in some business firms where coordination must be handled by those professionals doing the primary work of the group because only they possess the relevant knowledge. Khandwalla (1976, quoted in Mintzberg, 1979) states of such groups “the job of coordination is not left to a few charged with the responsibility, but assumed by most individuals in the organization, much in the way members of a well-knit hockey or cricket team all work spontaneously to keep its activities focused on the goal of winning.”

a seven-member Steiner organization.

So far we have assumed that only two people fall into a conflict simultaneously, but if more become involved the above sys- tem cannot be used. Notice that trees deal with many-person conflicts very effectively because of assumptions (T3) and (T5). Any group, however large, will have a well-spec- ified coordinator. Steiner organizations al- ready satisfy (T3) (which is the same as (S3)), and it is tempting to impose (T5) on them also, to solve the problem in the same way. However this is a dead end, since from (Sl) to (S5) and (T5), we can deduce for any members x andy, x = y * ( y * x) = ( y * y ) * x = y * x = y * (x * x) = ( y * x) * x = y. This means that a Steiner organization satisfying (T5) can have only one member.

Another approach to the problem of mul- tiperson conflicts is to make a list of quad- ruples (rather than triples), such that every triple appeared in exactly one quadruple. This would give a rule for choosing the resolver of three-person conflicts. These structures are known as Steiner quadruple systems (Lindner & Rosa, 1978), but they can be constructed only if n lies in the set {I, 2, 4, 8, 10, 14, 16, 20, - - - 1, which has no intersection with the possible sizes for triple systems except again for the one- member organization, so that no nontrivial organization can be given both structures.

For relatively small organizations a good policy would be to refer conflicts of more than two members to a general meeting. One would hope that these conflicts will be infrequent if the organization is basically united on its goals, and if the parties are discouraged by group norms from politick-

Behavioral Science, Volume 29, 1984

Page 7: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

NONHIERARCHICAL ORGANIZATIONS 67

ing for allies. Another way of solving the problem is to refer the conflict to the largest Steiner suborganization containing all the parties, as will be discussed in section 9.

Steiner organizations raise a traditional issue in organization theory, the question of unity of command. According to classical doctrine, an employee should have only one immediate supervisor, to avoid contradic- tory demands, whereas in a Steiner orga- nization there may be decsions coming from several other members and they may be mutually inconsistent. This may seem a serious flaw, but in fact many organiza- tions, including hierarchical ones, violate the principle of unity of command without serious problems. Contradictory demands are resolved by mutual discussion, and we would expect the same here.

5. SELF-COORDINATION- COMMUNICATION.

The focus is now on coordination that does not require a third party, but can be done by the members themselves. They are able to make voluntary adjustments given they have sufficient communication, so that the organization designer’s task is to invent a structure where communication is likely to happen.

We will regard an organization as a list of sets. Each set contains individuals, and a set appears on the list if those particular people meet regularly as a group. Thus if we have a four-person organization consist- ing of a boss 1 with three workers, 2,3 , and 4, who report singly to 1 and also meet among themselves, this would be repre- sented by the list (12, 13, 14, 234). These meetings are regarded as part of the formal structure, not as informal communication patterns. Members are expected to attend as part of the job, in order to report their own activities and exchange information.

Authority relationships are ignored in our description of the structures, so that if a supervisor and a subordinate meet, this is a symmetrical event as far as the list is concerned. For an organization to be non- hierarchical means something slightly dif- ferent than it did in the previous section. A member gains power not through formal

authority, but because he or she is in a better position informationally than an- other, either through having more contacts or through occupying a central place in the communication structure. To achieve an egalitarian organization, we will require that each member communicate directly with the same number of others.

Three features of an organization are:

1) n, the number of people in it;

2) m, the maximum number of meetings

3) s, the maximum size of any meeting.

We will refer to an (n, m, s)-organization, meaning one that has those three parame- ters. For example, the four-person system described above is a (4,3, 3)-organization.

Any organization has a fourth feature, which is harder to define:

any member attends;

4) d, communication distance.

Roughly, this means the degree to which members are far from one another, as meas- ured by their separation in communication links. The distance d will depend on n, m, and s and on how well the organization is designed. Several axiomatized definitions of d have appeared under the title of “index of centrality” (Sabudissi, 1966; Nieminen, 19741, but the exact meaning used here will change according to what seems tractable and appropriate a t a particular point in the discussion. The different concepts will be distinguished by notation: d ’ , d” , etc.

Our aim is to find organizations with an informationally egalitarian structure (all go to meetings of the same number and size), with the required membership (high enough n), with small and therefore effi- cient meetings (small s), with little time spent by each member in meetings (small m), and yet with a low value of d. Structures that minimize d for fixed values of the other three will be called communication-efficient or efficient.

Communication in trees Trees have the lowest possible meeting

size, s = 2. (We assume that there are no departmental meetings, but that a superior

Behavioral Science, Volume 29. I984

Page 8: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

68 BARRY O’NEILL

and subordinate meet in a pair.) They also score well on the average number of meet- ings per member. If a tree has n people, it will have n - 1 communication links, since everyone reports to his or her superior, except the person who reports to no one. The average number of meetings per person will be 2(n - l) /n, since each link counts for two attendances and there are n people in the tree. Although the maximum number of meetings rn for any person may be high, the average is low. In fact, of all (n, rn, 2)- organization only trees have this low an average, except for disconnected organiza- tions, i.e., those having some pairs of people without a communication path.

Unfortunately trees sacrifice other qual- ities: either maximum number of meetings per member, rn, or communication dis- tance, d. It is possible to design a very centralized tree by loading up one person with links to everyone else in the shape of a star. No two people would be more than two links away from each other, but the value of rn would rise to n - 1, which is the maximum possible. Alternatively, to make the number of contacts almost equal, a tree could be shaped like a chain. No person would meet with more than two others, but the communication distance d ’, defined as maximum number of steps that separate any pair of individuals, would be n - 1, the maximum possible.

A related difficulty is that communica- tion in trees is precarious, since the mal- functioning of any link makes the tree dis- connected. On the other hand, communi- cation is predictable, since for any pair of people there is exactly one shortest path between them. This allows an administra- tor in a tree to have a more repetitive and therefore narrower range of activities, and relates to the sharp division of labor found in these organizations.

All of these considerations suggest that trees would be most successful when the work is especially routine and the environ- ment unchanging, when intense flexible communication is not needed. This idea has been supported theoretically and experi- mentally (Mintzberg, 1979; Alexander, 1965; Christie, Macy, & Luce, 1956; Glan- zer & Glaser, 1959, 1961), and explains the

fact that many of the ideas for modifying tree structures have been developed in or- ganizations that have to respond quickly to change.

Communication in nonhierarchical organizations: Pairwise meetings

Investigating nonhierarchical organiza- tions with s = 2 allows us to compare them directly to trees. If trees are suitable for doing routinized work, these organizations are just the opposite, as will be seen. Work- ers can go about their own tasks but be informed of new developments by setting up an efficient pattern of meetings.

For (n, rn, 2)-organizations, the smallest nontrivial value of rn is 2. The resulting groups are shaped like cycles, or “circles” as they are called in the literature of com- munication networks. Members interact as if they were sitting in a ring and talking only to their two neighbors. Communica- tion distance d ’ , the largest number of steps that separate any pair in the group, is clearly (n - 1)/2 if n is odd, and n/2 if n is even.

Better values of d’ can be achieved if we allow rn, the number of interactions per person, to rise to three. These (n, 3, 2)- organizations can be constructed only if the number of members n is even, since the total number of communication links is 3n/ 2, which is required to be an integer. What are the communication-efficient (n, 3, 2)- organizations? Some examples. are shown in Figure 3. They are drawn as undirected graphs where members are represented by points and a meeting by a line joining the nodes. The particular layout of the points is arbitrary, of course, so we have tried to draw each graph in a way that brings out its symmetries.

If we require that d’ = 1, i.e., that every pair meet face-to-face, then a four-person group is the largest possible.

For d’ = 2, i.e., when every pair either meets directly or has a common contact, then any even number of members of up to ten can be accommodated. The largest or- ganization with d’ = 2 has members ar- ranged in two connected pentagons, (or as drawn in Figure 3, an outer pentagon and

Behavioral Science, Volume 29, 1984

Page 9: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

NONHIERARCHICAL ORGANIZATIONS 69

n= 4

14 14 @

FIG. 3. Some efficient (n, 3, 2)-organizations.

an interior pentangle, which is equivalent a (10, 3, 2)-tree in that its communication to a pentagon in terms of the structure of distance d’ is no more than half that of a its connections). As a mathematical entity, tree, which would have d’ = 4 or more this is called the Peterson graph, and we depending on its shape. will borrow the name to call the group the The Peterson graph also has the elegant Peterson organization. It is a (10, 3, 2)- property that the shortest path between organization and compares favorably with any pair of points is unique. Thus, if mem-

Behavioral Science, Volume 29, 1984

Page 10: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

70 BARRY O'NEILL

bers adopted a rule that in meetings they would describe their own activities and those of their immediate contacts, then everyone would hear what everyone else was doing exactly once. The property that the shortest path is always unique holds trivially for the four-member organization in which everyone meets, but is otherwise rare in organizations with equal numbers of lines emanating from each member, as shown (in the context of graph theory) by Hoffman and Singleton (1960).

To accommodate larger numbers we must allow d' to go up to three, so that some pairs of people will be three links away from each other. Finding the efficient patterns is a difficult problem, which has been investigated in the study of computer networks and solved on a case-by-case basis for n up to 30 (Cerf, Cowan, & Mullin, 1974,1976; McKay & Stanton, 1978). Some of their graphs are shown in Figure 3, re- drawn to bring out the symmetries. For d' = 3 a carefully constructed organization can include as many as 20 members.

(These authors in fact solved the problem for a slightly stricter criterion of effi- ciency-if two graphs were alike in the maximum distance d ' , then the second, third, etc., greatest distances were exam- ined, and the graph first showing a greater distance than the other was eliminated. It follows that their graphs are some but not necessarily all of the graphs that are effi- cient by our definition.)

Efficient structures with larger values of m are harder to find, but a few have been described (McKay & Stanton, 1978). An interesting specimen is the Hoffman-Sin- gleton graph (Hoffman & Singleton, 1960; Bondy & Murty, 1976), whose correspond- ing organization has 50 members, each at- tending seven pairwise meetings in a pat- tern that achieves d' = 2.

Communication in nonhierarchical organizations: Three-person meetings

The problem of finding efficient (n, m, 3)-organizations seems difficult, but we can make some progress by changing the defi- nition of communication distance. Instead

of using d ' , the greatest number of steps between any pair of people, we will define d" as the greatest number of meetings through which a message must pass to go from one meeting to the other.

The requirement that every pair meet face-to-face (d" = 0) and that meetings occur in threes, are satisfied by the Steiner organizations of section 4 (regarding Stei- ner organizations as lists of three-person committees, rather than as conflict-solving multiplication tables). How many meetings must each person attend? Each must meet once with the other n - 1 people, but a single meeting takes care of two other mem- bers, so each person must go to (n - 1)/2 meetings. Thus Steiner organizations are [n, (n - 1)/2, 31-organizations with d" = 0.

One of the attractive properties of Steiner organizations is that they allow the coordination and communication functions to be handled by a single structure, since the same list of triples that gives the meet- ings can also be used to specify conflict- resolvers. This is sensible since a coordi- nator for a pair of people should meet them directly and simultaneously.

Some efficient (n, m, 3)-organizations are shown in Figure 4, which also depicts the Steiner organization for n = 7 and 9. The other organization for n = 9 can be con- structed in another way, by taking the first (6, 3, 2)-organization of Figure 3 and sub- stituting a line of three points for every point. If two nodes were connected in the original, then two points, one on each of the corresponding lines are made to be identical. Thus there will be 3/2 as many members in the new group, so that the six- member organization generates the present nine-member one. This operation can be performed for any (n, 3, 2)-organization. Since single people map into meetings here in the same way as they do changing from the definition of d' and d", then if the original organization was d '-efficient, the new one will be d "-efficient. It is easy to see that d" will equal d' - 1. Figure 4 shows two further designs constructed in this way, a (15, 2, 3)-organization with d" = 1 gen- erated from the Peterson graph, and a (30, 2, 3)-organization from the (20, 3, 2)-orga- nization of Figure 3.

Behavioral Science, Volume 29. 1984

Page 11: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

NONHIERARCHICAL ORGANIZATIONS 71

A

(Steiner) 7A FIG. 4. Some efficient (n, rn, 3)-organizations.

Matrix organizations

The other nine-person organization in Figure 4 is of interest because it has the well-known form of a matrix organization. A (two dimensional) matrix organization is one in which the members can be laid out as the rows and columns of a matrix, and a meeting occurs of every row and also of every column. This idea has been used fre- quently in corporations, where the rows are the projects on which the member is work- ing (calculators, home computers, elec- tronic watches), and the columns are the type of function he or she performs (re- search and development, manufacturing, advertising). The aim is to set up a rational

relationship between the task structure and the communication structure to promote interaction among those doing similar jobs. Matrix organizations are not intended to be nonhierarchical, but have an executive superstructure. More generally a p-dimen- sionul matrix organization can be defined, where typically the third dimension corre- sponds to the geographical area of the member. These are clearly (n , m, p)-orga- nizations with a value of m at least the p'th root of n, and with d" = p - 1.

Some organizations accommodate more members than matrix organizations for the same d". For example, Figure 4 shows one with fifteen members and with d" = 1, as good as the nine-member matrix structure.

Behavioral Science, Volume 29. 1984

Page 12: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

72 BARRY O’NEILL

However, matrix organizations are optimal for a stronger condition of communicative proximity-if we attend one meeting and want to find out about another, then not only is there someone at the other meeting who is no more d” meetings from someone or other at ours, but everyone there is no more than d meetings from someone at ours.

We have surveyed a range of possibilities for nonhierarchical communication struc- tures and illustrated the tradeoffs of meet- ing size, membership size and communica- tion proximity. Very little has been said about the relationship of organization and task structures however, and this will be the subject of the next section.

6. MODULARITY

Modularity means that if we have iden- tified a desirable quality for organizations, we can choose a subset of members, and considering only at the roles prevailing among them, have a suborganization with that quality. Modularity is significant for work organizations because most tasks are not unitary, but can be divided into sub- tasks, subsubtasks, etc. (The guiding prin- ciple for the division is that people working on a subtasks require more coordination by virtue of the activities required by the sub- task (Thompson, 1967).) If a certain feature of organizational design is desirable for the whole task, often it will be desirable for the subtasks, so that with a modular organiza- tion, the suborganizations, or modules, can be assigned to the subtasks and the work will proceed smoothly in the large and in the small. Trees are excellent examples of modularity since any nontrivial tree con- tains proper subtrees.

The efficient (n, m, 2)-organizations are frequently modular. For example, the Pe- terson organization contains 12 pentagons as components, which are themselves effi- cient (n, m, 2)-organizations. Likewise in the Hoffman-Singleton graph (Section 5), a 50, 7,2)-organization, there can be found no less than 525 Peterson graphs (Benson & Losey, 1971).

Modularity in Steiner or in efficient (n , m, 3)-organizations seems less common but some striking examples can be produced,

one of which will be discussed in Section 9. I t involves a fifteen-member Steiner orga- nization containing 15 seven-member Stei- ner suborganizations.

7. GROWTH

An organization must be able to adapt if the tasks grows or shrinks. Ideally growth should be possible while maintaining desir- able properties and without disrupting many, of the existing.

Types of organizational growth Three types of growth will be examined:

incremental, modular, and structural. Zn- cremental growth means growth in small steps by the addition of small numbers of members. The feasibility of this type of growth is a matter of degree: a business consisting of a boss and a group of imme- diate underlings can grow by single units, whereas a bridge tournament increases by four’s.

The second type is modular growth, where two or more groups join together in a merger.

The third possibility has membership re- maining constant but internal structure in- creasing. Interaction becomes more in- tense, the organization becomes more or- ganized. If this can happen with the new structure still in the desirable class, it is termed structural growth.

For either incremental or structural growth, we can ask a further question: Is growth localizable? That is, can it occur with minimum revision of the existing structure? An example of an incrementally but nonlocalizably growing structure is the pattern of stars on the American flag, where as a new state joins all stars in the past layout are repositioned.

The various organizational structures- trees, Steiner organizations, matrix and communciation-efficient organizations- will now be examined and the same ques- tion will be asked for each, whether growth can occur smoothly while the organization stays in its class. Incremental and localizable growth

Trees allow incremental and localizable growth without restriction. A new member can be added anywhere as an extra branch,

Behavioral Science, Volume 29, 1984

Page 13: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

NONHIERARCHICAL ORGANIZATIONS 73

changing only one part of the old structure, the place where the newcomer is added.

The nonhierarchical structures allow in- cremental growth to a more limited extent. Fore example, a p by q matrix organizations can grow to a p + 1 by q structure but must add a complete team of q people.

The efficient (n , 3, 2)-organizations of Figure 3 allow for localizable growth in some instances. This is illustrated in Figure 5, where two new members are added to change a (n, 3, 2)-organization into a (n + 2, 3, 2)-organization. The smaller organi- zation is drawn on the left in Figure 5, with a correct position for the two members as heavier points. The larger organization is drawn on the right using the same layouts of points as appear in Figure 3. In each case a relatively small amount of disruption is necessary: Two carefully chosen links are disconnected and the new members are in- serted into the breaks. It is not always possible to do this however-one cannot go from a (16, 3, 2)-organization to an (18, 3, 2) one.

Steiner organizations are inflexible in this regard. Incremental growth is possible to a degree, in that people can be added in two’s or four’s because of the set of possible sizes, but with each increase the existing structure must be disrupted. If we wish to add people without changing old relation- ships, the best guarantee is that the size must be approximately doubled (Doyen & Wilson, 1973). For example, for any 7- member Steiner organization, we can find a 15-member one that contains it as a proper part.

Modular growth

Modular growth allows organizations to merge or divide without revision of the subparts. Some of its advantages have been discussed by Simon (1962). It is closely related to the concept of modularity dis- cussed in section 6, but here the modularity must be of a certain type: The subparts that join will generally have no common members, so the modules must be disjoint.

Trees allow for perfectly modular growth, since two trees can always be joined to form a third, by making the head of one a sub- ordinate of someone in the other. Modular-

FIG. 5. Incremental growth in (n, 3, 2)-organiza- tions. New members are indicated by heavier dots.

ity is also a feature of p-dimensional matrix organizations since two can join to form a third, given the two have the same number of rows or columns. For the class of efficient (n, m, 2)-organizations, disjoint modularity is common. An example is the Peterson organizations which comprises two penta- gons.

Structural growth Structural growth involves adding new

role relationships. Trees completely disal-

Behavioral Science, Volume 29, 1984

Page 14: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

74 BARRY O’NEILL

low this since any additional connection destroys the tree property. They are char- acterized by extreme sparseness in their role relationships which makes them una- daptable when communication needs in- crease. If two separate departments must engage in a joint activity they must go up and down the chain of command, increas- ing information load on to the management and generating discontent about red tape.

The possibility of structural growth oc- curs in (n, m, 3)-organizations as shown in Figure 6. There a (9, 2, 3)-Steiner organi- zation has meetings added and becomes a (9, 4, 3)-Steiner organization.

8. TREES AS INTEGRATED SYSTEMS

We will now summarize the various fea- tures that have been attributed to trees and show how they interrelate. The conclusion will be that they are mutually reinforcing, which helps to explain why trees are effec- tive in some contexts, but also suggests that it would be difficult to modify trees to save the good features and eliminate the more troublesome ones.

Some of the properties of trees are:

1) Exogeneous coordination: Clear rules based on the superior-subordinate re- lationship, which limit the spread of conflicts of any size.

2) Communication: Sparsity of links and predictability of paths.

3) Modularity: The existence of many disjoint subtrees.

4) Growth: The possibility of localizable incremental and modular growth, but no possibility of structural growth.

A unifying principle behind all of these features is that trees follow a sharp division of labor. This is made possible by (3), the existence of disjoint subtrees, which be- come the various departments assigned to the subtasks.

The division of labor promotes the su- perior-subordinate relationship in that it makes it more crucial to integrate the var- ious subtasks. No one has the total picture except for the higher administrators who can demand more rewards for their work.

The limited and predictable communi- cation paths also support. the superior-sub- ordinate relationship. Since any nonrou- tine information tends to flow through a higher administrator, the latter gains unique knowledge and thereby power.

If greater internal communication is needed, the tree cannot grow structurally and still remain a tree, but it has an alter- native, to grow incrementally. In concrete terms, a manager who becomes overloaded can hire an assistant. The implicit philos- ophy of tree organizations holds this pref-

FIG. 6. Modular growth: two (5, 2, 2)-organizations become a (10, (10, 3, 2)-organization. Structural growth: A (9, 2, 3)-matrix organization adds meetings to become a (9, 4, 3)-Steiner organization.

Behavioral Science, Volume 29. 1984

Page 15: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

NONHIERARCHICAL ORGANIZATIONS 75

erable to increasing links among depart- ments. Although the organization might function quite well with more communica- tion, from the point of view of the manager it would be moving out of control.

The administrative elite have the burden of communication and coordination, so it is important that their time and attention be protected from unnecessary chores. Since many communication paths flow through them and conflicts have a tendency to move toward them, it is necessary to have an effective system of limiting conflict as described in point (1).

Division of labor is thus the key that explains how the four features listed to interact and reinforce one another. This adds to the stability of the way trees per- form their tasks, and accounts for their wide use.

9. INTEGRATING FUNCTIONS NONHIERARCHICALLY: PROJECTIVE

SPACE ORGANIZATIONS

In past sections, separate nonhierarchi- cal structures for conflict resolution, com- munication and modularity were developed. For a truly effective alternative to trees these functions must be combined in a sin- gle organization. The class to be defined now resolve conflict in the pattern of Stei- ner organizations, are communication effi- cient, and are highly modular.

An example will be given, in the form of a (15,7,3)-organization, i.e., 15 people each attending seven meetings of three people.

To describe how the meetings are pat- terned, we imagine that the members are placed on and in a tetrahedron (Figure 7). There is one at each vertex (members 1, 2, 3 and 4), one at the midpoint of each edge (5 , 6, 7, 8, 9, lo), and one at the midpoint of the four triangles forming each face (11, 12, 13, 141, and one at the center of the tetrathedron (15). We next identify ten tri- angles: four are the triangles constituting the faces, and the other six are formed by taking a cross-section of the tetrahedron through an edge and midpoint of the op- posite edge. Each of these triangles will contain seven members laid out in the pat- tern of the Steiner organization of Figure 2. Meetings are held within each of these

FIG. 7. Front view of the fifteen-member projec- tive space organization.

seven-member groups according to the pat- tern of the seven-member Steiner organi- zation.

There will be 35 meetings in all:

1 - 2- 5 2 - 3 - 9 3 - 5 -11 4 -11 -15 6 -13 -14 1 - 3 - 6 2 - 4 - 8 3-7-12 5 - 6 - 9 7-9-15 1 - 4 - 7 2-6-11 3-8-14 5 - 7 - 8 7-11-14 1 - 8 -13 2 - 7 -13 3 -13 -15 5 -10 -15 8 - 9 -10 1 - 9 -11 2 -10 -14 4 - 5 -13 5 -12 -14 8 -11 -12 1 -10 -12 2 -12 -15 4 - 6 -12 6 - 7 -10 9 -12 -13 1 -14 -15 3 - 4 -10 4 - 9 -14 6 - 8 -15 10 -11 -13

Every pair meets exactly once so the organization is communication efficient with d’ = 0, and two-person conflicts can be solved by refemng them to the third member.

The organization is isomorphic to a known mathematical entity, the three-di- mensional projective space with three points per line, PG (3, 2) (Coxeter, 1964). Members correspond to points, meetings to lines, seven-person suborganizations to planes, and the entire organization to a three-dimensional space. The isomorph- ism, with a geometrical space holds since every pair of points determines a unique line, every two intersecting lines generate a unique plane, and every pair of intersecting planes generates the entire space. (“Gen- erate” here means to form by aumenting the two lines or planes with all lines con- necting points in the original pair.)

Behavioral Science, Volume 29, 1984

Page 16: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

76 BARRY O’NEILL

As a consequence of its having a geomet- rical structure, the organization is highly modular, the subparts being the one- and two-dimensional subspaces. Every pair of three-person meetings with a common member generates a seven-member Steiner organization. It can be calculated that there are 15 such suborganizations, ten of which are the triangles described in the construc- tion, and five more arise indirectly from the pattern of meetings. The 15 suborganiza- tions are

12 3 569 11 12 45 78 13

1 2 5 10 12 14 15 13 4 6 7 10 12

1 3 6 8 13 14 15 1479111415

1 8 9 10 11 12 13

2 34 8 9 10 14 2 3 7 9 12 13 15 2 4 6 8 11 12 15 2 6 7 10 11 13 14 34510111315 3 5 7 8 11 12 14 4 5 6 9 12 13 14 5 6 7 8 9 10 15.

These suborganizations would be as- signed to subtasks and since each pair of suborganizations intersects in a three-per- son meeting, the latter would have the re- sponsibility of liaison for coordinating the subtasks.

If a conflict occurs among three or more members all belonging to one seven-mem- ber suborganization, it should be solved by the suborganization rather than by the en- tire group. There are then three levels of conflict resolution, within groups of three, seven, and fifteen, and the intermediate level protects the time and cohesion of the whole group.

The organization has 15 members and 15 suborganizations. (This is not a coincidence given its structure as a geometrical space.) Each member can be assigned a unique seven-member suborganization for which he or she has the special role of chairperson. Likewise the seven-member subgroups con- tain seven meetings, allowing a one-to-one assignment of a chairperson to each meet- ing. The organization is symmetrical among the members as a group, but these equalities of people and subcommittees al- low us to include the institution of chair- person in a nonhierarchical setting.

Unfortunately the organization is inflex- ible in its size. The possible sizes for pro- jective spaces with three-person meetings

are 11, 3, 7, 15, 31, 63, . . .), or 2 D + 1 - 1, where D is the dimension of the space. A possible remedy is to allow fewer than 15 members but continue to have exactly 15 roles, which are rotated through the group.

This organization and its relatives are just the opposite of trees in the four aspects described in the last section, but like trees, their features are mutually reinforcing. This suggests that if one wanted the advan- tages of no hierarchy, the best policy would not be to modify a tree little by little, but to start anew with the type of organization described here.

REFERENCES

Alexander, C. A city is not a tree. Architectural Forum, 1965,122, April, 58-62; May 58-61.

Benson, C. T. & Losey, N. E. On a graph of Hoffman and Singleton. Journal of Combinational Theory (Series B ) , 1971, 11, 67-79.

Bondy, J. & Murty, U. Graph theory with applications. New York: American Elsevier. 1976.

Boyle, J. P. Algebraic systems for numerical and hi- erarchical sociograms. Sociometry, 1969,32,99- 119.

Bruck, R. A suruey of binary systems. Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag. 1971.

Cerf, V., Cowan, D., & Mullin, R. A partial census of trivalent generalized Moore graphs. Proceed- ings of the Third Australian Combinatorial Con- ference (Brisbane). New York: Springer-Verlag. 1974.

Cerf, V., Cowan, D., & Mullin, R. Some extremal graphs. Ars Combinatoria, 1976,1, 119-157.

Christie, L., Macy, J., & Luce, R. Information han- dling in organized groups. In J. McCloskey & J. Coppinger, (Eds.), Operations Research for Management ( Vol In. Baltimore: Johns Hop- kins, 1957.

Coexeter, H. S. M. Projectiue geometry. New York: Blaisdell, 1964.

Doyen, J. & Wilson, R. Embeddings of Steiner triple systems. Discrete Mathematics, 1973, 5, 229- 239.

Freeman, J. The tyranny of structurelessness. Berke- ley Journal of Sociology, 1972, 17, 151-164.

Friedell, M. Organizations as sernilattices. American Sociological Review, 1967,32,46-53.

Galbraith, J. Designing complex organizations. New York: Addison-Wesley, 1973.

Glanzer, M. & Glaser. P. Techniques for the study of . ~ O U D structure. Pvschological Bulletin. 1959.

5f53’17-332. -

Glanzer. M. & Glaser. P. Techniaues for the studv of &oup structure. Psycholoiical Bulletin, 1661,

Hall, M. Combinatorial theory. Waltham, Massachu-

Hoffman, A. & Singleton, R. On Moore graphs with

58, 1-27.

setts: Blaisdell, 1967.

Behavioral Science, Volume 29, 1984

Page 17: Structures for nonhierarchical organizations

NONHIERARCHICAL ORGANIZATIONS 77

diameters 2 and 3. IBM Journal, 1960,4, 497- 504.

Jennergren, P. Decentralization in organizations. In P. Nystrom & W. Starbuck, (Eds)., Handbook of organizational design ( Vol. I ) . Oxford Oxford University Press, 1980.

Kanter, R., Commitment and community: Communes and utopias in sociological perspective. Cam- bridge: Harvard University Press, 1972.

Khandwalla, P. Organizational design for change. Learning systems, conceptual reading 5. New Delhi, 1976.

Kirkman, T. P. On a problem in combinations. Cam- bridge and Dublin Mathematical Journal, 1847,

Likert, R. New patterns of management. New York: McGraw-Hall, 1961.

Lindner, C. & Rosa, A. Steiner quadruple systems, a survey. Discrete Mathematics, 1978, 21, 147- 181.

Lindner, C. & Rosa, A., (Eds.). Topics in Steiner triple systems. Annals of Discrete Mathematics 7. New York: North Holland, 1980.

Mansbridge, J. Time, emotion and inequality, three problems of participatory groups. Journals of Applied Behavioral Science, 1973,9,351-368.

Mansbridge, J. The limits of friendship. In J. R. Pen- nock & J. W. Chapman, (Eds.), Participation in politics (Nomos X V I ) . New York: Lieber-Ath- erton, 1976.

McKay, B. & Stanton, R. Current status of the gen- eralized Moore graph problem. In E. Dold & B. Eckmann, (Eds.), Combinatoriul mathematics

2, 191-204.

(VZ). New York Springer-Verlag, 1978. Mintzberg, H. The Structuring of organizations: A

synthesis of the research. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1979.

Nieminen, J. Graph-theoretic measures of centrality. Scandinavian Journal of Psychology, 1974, 15,

Pattison, P. E. & Bartlett, W. K. An algebraic ap- proach to group structure: The organization semilattice. Melbourne Psychology Reports (No. 16), 1975.

Quackenbush, R. Varieties of Steiner loops and Stei- ner quasigroups. Canadian Journal of Mathe-

Rothschild-Whitt, J. The collective organization: An alternative to rational-bureaucratic model. American Sociological Review, 1979, 44, 509- 527.

Sabidussi, G. The centrality index of a graph. Psy- chometrih, 1966,31,581-603.

Simon, H . The architecture of complexity. Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society, 1962,

Swidler, A. Organization without authority: Dilemmos of sochl control in free schools. Cambridge: Har- vard University Press, 1979.

Thompson, J. D. Organizations in action. New York: McGraw-Hill 1967.

Toffler, A. Future shock. New York Bantam Books, 1970.

332-336.

matics, 1976,28,1187-1198.

106,467-482.

(Manuscript received September 20, 1982)

Behavioral Science, Volume 29, 1984