ssrn-id985716

Upload: imam-awaluddin

Post on 05-Jul-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    1/50

      Dynamics of Inflation Persistence in International Inflation Rates

    Manmohan S. Kumar

    International Monetary Fund

    and

    Tatsuyoshi Okimoto* 

    Associate Professor

    Faculty of Economics and IGSSS,

    Yokohama National University

    We are indebted to James Hamilton for his guidance and Katsumi Shimotsu for helpful

    discussion. We would also like to thank Takeo Hoshi, Bruce Lehmann, Masahito

    Kobayashi Laura Kodres Keiji Nagai Raghu Rajan Ken Rogoff Yixiao Sun Masahiko

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    2/50

    Abstract

    Characteristics of inflation play a key role in policy formulation and market

    analysis. Several studies have analyzed inflation persistence and reached diverging

    conclusions. In this paper we investigate the dynamics of inflation persistence using

    fractionally integrated processes and find that there has been a clear decline in inflation

     persistence in the U.S. over the past two decades. We also show that the presence of

    fractional integration in inflation successfully explains previous diverging results. Lastly

    we provide some international comparisons to examine the extent to which there has been a

    commensurate decline in inflation persistence in the other G7 economies.

    JFL classification: E31, C22, C14

    Key words: fractional integration, rolling window estimation, long memory

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    3/50

    Dynamics of Inflation Persistence in International Inflation Rates

    Introduction 

    In recent years, there has been an active debate regarding the extent to which

    dynamics of the inflation process in the world economy, particularly in the largest countries,

    have changed. The discussion has been especially intense regarding the extent to which

    inflation persistence has declined. This issue is important from both an analytical and a

     policy perspective, and it could be argued that changes in the degree of inflation persistence

    may reflect economies’ changing resilience to shocks.

    The issue of changes in the degree of inflation persistence is particularly relevant

    against the background of a striking change in the realm of macro policy making globally

    over the last few years. From a preoccupation with inflation over most of the post war

     period, there was a marked increase in concerns about deflation in the early part of the

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    4/50

    concerns abated somewhat as the effects of that crisis waned, but resurfaced in the

    aftermath of the bursting of the equity price bubble in early 2000, geopolitical uncertainties

    and the global slowdown.2  With the rebound in global activity since then, declining

    measures of economic slack, and sharply higher oil and non-oil commodity prices, markets

    and policymakers have again become preoccupied with inflation. Nonetheless, the

    turnaround still leaves a key issue unresolved: the extent to which there has been a change

    in the underlying characteristics of the inflation process, and its implications for policy

    design and financial markets.

    There have been a number of recent studies trying to empirically assess the

     persistence of inflation, especially in the United States, but they appear to reach quite

    diverging conclusions. These studies can be broadly divided into two methodological types,

    depending on the measure of persistence. Studies in the first category rely on order of

    integration as the measure of inflation persistence, using unit root tests to classify the

    inflation process as either an I(0) or I(1) process. MacDonald and Murphy (1989) found

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    5/50

    I(1) process during 1978 to 1992. On the other hand, Rose (1988) indicated that monthly

    U.S. inflation was an I(0) process from 1947 to 1986. Mixed evidence was provided by

    Brunner and Hess (1993). They concluded that the inflation rate was I(0) before the 1960’s

     but that it is characterized as I(1) since that time. Other studies include Barsky (1987), Ball

    and Cecchetti (1990), Kim (1993), and Culver and Papell (1997).

    A second category of studies uses AR model-based measures such as the largest

    autoregressive root (LARR) and the sum of the autoregressive coefficients (SARC). For

    instance, Taylor (2000) estimated the LARR and the SARC and concluded that U.S.

    inflation persistence during the Volcker-Greenspan era has been substantially lower than

    during the previous two decades. Similarly, Levin and Piger (2003) used the SARC, and

    showed that high inflation persistence is not an inherent characteristic of industrial

    economies over the period 1984-2002.3

      On the other hand, Batini (2002) found relatively

    little evidence of shifts in inflation persistence for the Euro area using the SARC.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    6/50

     permanent and temporary decline in inflation persistence. To our knowledge, there are only

    a few studies that systematically document the changes over time in the dynamics of

    inflation persistence. Cogley and Sargent (2001, 2005) estimated a Bayesian state-space

    VAR model of inflation dynamics and provided a time series of inflation persistence in the

    United States. They used the spectrum at frequency zero as the measure of inflation

     persistence and indicated that there has been an unambiguous decline in inflation

     persistence. Their finding was taken to mean that indeed there had been a change in the

    underlying characteristics of inflation reflecting both a change in the structural

    characteristics of the economy as well possibly in the efficacy and a greater forward

    looking nature of monetary policy. In complete contrast, as a comment on Cogley and

    Sargent (2001), Stock (2001) estimated the LARR using rolling window estimation method.

    He suggested that there is no indication of a marked decline in the persistence. Following

    these studies, Pivetta and Reis (2006) estimated the LARR and the SARC using both

    Bayesian and rolling window estimation methods. Their main conclusion is that inflation

     persistence in the United States has been high and approximately unchanged over the entire

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    7/50

      One possible explanation for this debate and divergent results of unit root tests is

    the presence of fractional integration in inflation rate,4  which is not consistent with either

    an I(0) or an I(1) process. If fractional integration exists, it is possible for AR model-based

    measures and unit root tests to reach diverging conclusions, as will be shown in this paper.

    In fact, a number of studies find the presence of fractional integration in inflation rates. For

    instance, Hassler and Wolters (1995) found that inflation is best characterized as the

    fractional integral of white noise, while Baillie, Chung, and Tieslau (1996) suggested that

    the ARFIMA-GARCH models best capture the dynamic properties of inflation in the major

    industrial countries. Following those studies, Baum, Barkoulas, and Caglayan (1999)

    estimated order of fractional integration using both CPI and WPI indices for a number of

    industrial and developing countries. They conclude that inflation is best characterized as a

    long memory process.5  See also Baillie, Han and Kwon (2002), Bos, Franses and Ooms

    (1999, 2002).

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    8/50

      The contributions of this paper are threefold. First, the paper provides new

    evidence on the dynamics of inflation persistence. Specifically, we suggest using order of

    fractional integration to measure inflation persistence, which can be considered as a

    generalization of the first type of method that simply tries to choose between an I(0) or I(1)

    representation. In addition, the method can also successfully provide an appropriate

    measure of persistence related to the LAAR when there is fractional integration. As a

    consequence, the method enables us to avoid possible confusion inherent in the second

    methodology. We find clear evidence in the U.S. of a decline in inflation persistence since

    the early 1980’s. Second, the paper reconciles the diverging results of unit root tests and

    AR model-based measures reported in previous studies. Third, we summarize the dynamics

    of inflation persistence for other G7 countries, to examine the extent to which there has

     been a commensurate decline in inflation persistence in other G7 countries. We find

    remarkable similarities between the dynamics of inflation persistence in the U.S and other

    G7 countries, with the exception of Italy.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    9/50

    Section V summarizes the dynamics of inflation persistence for other G7 countries. Section

    VI concludes the paper and discusses issues for further research.

    II. Fractionally Integrated Processes

    I. Fractionally integrated processes and measures of persistence

    In this paper, we propose using order of fractional integration to assess the level of,

    and changes in, inflation persistence. Fractionally integrated processes offer a

    generalization of the classical dichotomy between I(0) and I(1) processes, widely used in

    macroeconomic analysis, and allow us to describe long-run persistence with more

    flexibility. As a consequence, we can bypass many of the difficulties inherent in alternative

    approaches. Moreover, the use of fractional integration appears well justified both on

    conceptual and empirical grounds as discussed in the next subsection.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    10/50

    fractional difference operator d  L)1(   −   for can be defined by means of the gamma function

    )(⋅Γ   as

    ∑∞

    =   +Γ−Γ

    −Γ=

    ⎭⎬

    ⎩⎨

    ⎧+

    −−−

    −+−=−

    0

    32

    )1()(

    )(

    !3

    )2)(1(

    2

    )1(1)1(

    k d 

     Ld k 

     Ld d d  Ld d dL L  

     

    The parameter d is allowed to take any real value. The arbitrary restriction of d   to

    integer values gives rise to the standard integrated processes. The I( d ) process is stationary

    if 2/1

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    11/50

    slowly at a hyperbolic rate 1−d k  . Therefore, order of fractional integration is the key

    determinant of the decay rates of autocorrelations and the impulse response function. We

    note also that the nature of underlying I(0) process t d 

    t   X  Lu )1(   −=   does not affect these

    decay rates. For this reason, we view order of integration as the ideal measure of long-run

     persistence, while the persistence structure of the underlying I(0) process summarizes the

    rate of the slower geometric decay.

    A more fundamental attraction of using the value of d   as the measure of

     persistence is that it does not require the formulation of a specific model to estimate order

    of integration. In other words, since it only requires estimating order of fractional

    integration, it is not necessary to make assumptions regarding the specific model for the

    underlying I(0) process of inflation process or short-run persistence structure. Moreover,

    this measure will allow us to isolate persistence that is not consistent with either an I(1)

     process or an I(0) process. For these reasons, this method can be considered as a

    generalization of the I(0)/I(1) dichotomy. However, one important drawback of this

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    12/50

    change in the degree of inflation persistence. Thus, our measure is insensitive to a change

    in persistence of the underlying I(0) process and can capture only a change in long-run

     persistence. However, we also consider this as an advantage, because long-run persistence

    is more important for our purpose, if it exists, which is indeed the case for the U.S. inflation

     persistence, as we will see next.

    II. Evidence for fractional integration in the U.S. inflation

    Our study is based on monthly CPI data from Main Economic Indicators published

     by OECD,7  with the sample period from 1960:4 to 2003:4. Confirming the results of

    Hassler and Wolters (1995), Baillie, Chung, and Tieslau (1996) and so forth described in

    the introduction, we find abundant evidence in our U.S. inflation data of fractional

    integration. Figure 1 plots autocorrelations of US inflation, which show a clear pattern of

    slow decay. In fact, autocorrelations for all lags up to the 84 months (7 years) are positive

    and statistically significant. In addition, if we estimate order of fractional integration for

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    13/50

    asymptotic 90% confidence interval (0.32, 0.48) and a finite sample 90% confidence

    interval8  (0.31, 0.53). Thus we have good initial reasons for investigating the possible

    consequences of fractional integration.

    In addition to this empirical evidence, there are two important conceptual

    considerations weighing in favor of utilizing fractionally integrated processes to describe

    and analyze inflation. These relate to issues regarding aggregation and structural change.

    (i) Aggregation: Consider the case where a time series is a cross-sectional sum of a

    group of individual time series, each of which follows an AR(1) model with a common

    random-walk component:

    ⎩⎨⎧

    +=

    +=

    ,

    ,

    1

    1,

    t t t 

    t  jt  j j jt 

    W W 

    W  X  X 

    ε 

     β α  

    where theα  's and β  's are assumed to be drawn from independent distributions. Then under

    some fairly general conditions, in particular assuming that α  's have a form of beta

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    14/50

    has the persistence characteristics of a fractionally integrated process with qd    −< 2 .9

    Since an aggregate price index is simply a weighted sum of prices of individual goods and

    services, which can be modeled as above, it seems reasonable to expect fractional

    integration in an aggregate price index and hence in inflation.

    (ii) Structural Change: Granger and Hyung (1999) and Diebold and Inoue (2001)

    showed that processes with certain kind of structural changes in mean appear

    indistinguishable from long memory processes.10

      Given the significant shocks that have

     beset the world economy over the past three decades, as well as the likelihood of structural

    change occurring over this period, a measure that allows for such change is clearly

    desirable. This is reinforced by the oft discussed change in monetary policy regimes in

    many of the major industrial economies following the oil price shocks of the 1970s and

    early 1980s.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    15/50

    III. Estimation of order of fractional integration

    Order of integration d   plays a central role in the definition of fractionally

    integrated processes and has often been the focus of previous studies. Therefore a number

    of estimators are considered. Among these estimators, semiparametric estimators appear to

     be particularly attractive because they are agnostic about the short-run dynamics of the

     procss and hence robust to misspecification of these dynamics. Unfortunately, these

    estimators are still being developed. In particular, there are few semiparametric estimators

    that can be used to satisfactorily assess the nonstationary case.11

      However, recently

    Shimotsu and Phillips (2005) developed a new semiparametric estimator, the “Exact Local

    Whittle” (ELW) estimator. They considered the fractional integration process t  X   

    generated by the model

    { }  …

    ,2,1,0 ,11)1(   ±±=≥⋅=− t t u X  Lt t 

     

    where t u   is an I(0) process with mean 0 and spectral density )(λ u f    satisfying

    G f u ~)(λ    for 0~λ  , and }{1 ⋅   is the indicator function. We can rewrite this expression

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    16/50

      .)1()(

    )(1

    0

    ∑−

    =−

    +ΓΓ

    +Γ=

    k t t  uk d 

    d k  X   

    By defining the discrete Fourier transformation and the periodogram of a time series

    nt t u 1}{ =   evaluated at frequency λ   as

    2

    1

    )()( ,e2

    1)(   λ ω λ 

    π λ ω    λ  uu

    n

    it 

    t u  I un

    ==   ∑=

    ,

    the (negative) Whittle likelihood of t u   up to mλ    and up to scale multiplication can be 

    written

    n

     j 

     f 

     I  f   j

    m

     j  ju

     jum

     j

     ju

    π λ 

    λ 

    λ λ 

    2 ,

    )(

    )()(log

    11

    =+∑∑==

     

    where n   is sample size, and m   is some integer less than n   and called the bandwidth.12

     

    When G f u ~)(λ    for 0~λ  , the objective function is simplified to be data dependent,

    .)(1

    log(1

    ),(1

    )1(

    2∑=

    ⎥⎦

    ⎤⎢⎣

    ⎡+=

    m

     j

     j X  L

     jm d  I G

    Gm

    d GQ   λ λ   

    Concentrating ),( d GQm   with respect to G , the ELW estimator is defined as

    [ ])(minargˆ

    21 ,

    d  Rd d 

     ELW ΔΔ∈

    = ,

    where 1Δ   and 2Δ   are the lower and upper bounds of d   and

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    17/50

    Shimotsu and Phillips (2005) showed that under some conditions, in particular, for

    ( )21 ,ΔΔ∈d    with 2/912   ≤Δ−Δ ,

    ⎟ ⎠

     ⎞⎜⎝ 

    ⎛  ⎯→ ⎯ −

    4

    1,0)ˆ(  N d d m d 

     ELW ,

    where m   is chosen so that it satisfies as ∞→n  

    0 ,0log)(log1 221

    >∀ ⎯→ ⎯ +++

    γ γ 

     β 

    m

    n

    n

    mm

    m.

    Here β 

      represents the degree of approximation of the spectral density oft 

    u ,)(λ u

     f  ,

    around the origin by G . Shimotsu (2002) further developed these results so that it can

    accommodate an unknown mean and a linear time trend. Hereafter, following Shimotsu

    (2002), we call that estimator the “Feasible Exact Local Whittle” (FELW) estimator. He

    suggested estimating unknown mean by

    { } { }   ⎟ ⎠

     ⎞⎜⎝ 

    ⎛ ∈≥⋅+

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    18/50

    Since there are no satisfactory analytical results for deciding on the appropriate value of m  

    in finite sample, we choose m   based on simulation.13

      We simulate t d 

    t   L X    ε −−= )1( for

    t ε    Gaussian white noise with sample size14

      180 and compute the sample MSE for the

    several choice of m , i.e. 8.075.07.065.06.0 ,,,, nnnnnm = . The simulation results indicate that

    the sample MSE is minimized when 75.0nm =   for most of the cases.15  Therefore we

    choose 75.0nm = as the bandwidth.

    As a by-product of above simulation, we realized that the FELW estimator heavily

    depends on the value of c   used to define )(ˆ d  . More precisely the FELW estimator has

     probability mass at the value of c , which could likely distort our empirical results. To

    mitigate this problem, we use the following strategy16: If the estimate is greater than 1/2,

    we reestimate d   by estimating 1−d    using the differenced series and adding back one to

    13  All simulations and empirical applications are performed in Matlab. Matlab codes for

    the ELW and FELW estimators are available at Shimotsu’s web site

    (http://www.econ.queensu.ca/pub/faculty/shimotsu/).

    14

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    19/50

    the estimate of 1−d  . Using simulation techniques, we confirmed that this strategy could

    mitigate this problem without losing the good finite sample properties of the FELW

    estimator. We refer to this estimator as the modified FELW (MFELW) estimator. The

    simulation results indicate that also for the MFELW estimator the optimal choice of

     bandwidth is also 75.0nm = . Note further that this modification does not affect the

    asymptotic distribution of the FELW estimator under some further conditions on d .17

     

    Therefore we can construct the asymptotic confidence interval based on the asymptotic

    results of the FELW estimator discussed above.

    To investigate the stability of our estimates, we also compute the estimates by the

    GPH estimator and the ELW estimator with estimating unknown mean by the sample

    average. The GPH estimator is proposed by Geweke and Proter-Hudack (1983). The GPH

    estimator is also known as the log periodogram regression estimator, since it estimates the

    approximate rate of divergence of the spectrum at frequency around zero by regression of

    log periodogram. More precisely, d   is estimated from the following log periodogram

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    20/50

      m jn

     j d  I   j j

     j

     ju ,,1 ,2

     ,2

    sin4log)(log 2 …==+⎪⎭

    ⎪⎬⎫

    ⎪⎩

    ⎪⎨⎧

    ⎟⎟ ⎠

     ⎞⎜⎜⎝ 

    ⎛ −=

      π λ ν 

    λ α λ   

    where )(log  ju I    λ    is the periodogram defined above and m   is the bandwidth. The GPH

    estimator is defined as the OLS estimate of d   in the log periodogram regression. Künsch

    (1986), Robinson (1995), and Hurvich, Deo, and Brodsky (1998) rigorously analyzed its

    asymptotic properties. Specifically, Hurvich et al. (1998) showed that under some

    conditions,

    ⎟⎟ ⎠

     ⎞⎜⎜⎝ 

    ⎛  ⎯→ ⎯ −

    24,0)ˆ(

    2π  N d d m

    GPH  .

    Both the GPH and the ELW estimators also have the choice of bandwidth. Based on the

    simulation results we choose 8.0nm =   for the GPH estimator and75.0nm =   for the ELW

    estimator. Those simulation results also indicate that the MFELW estimator has the best

    finite sample properties among these three estimators.

    III. Empirical Results

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    21/50

    constant d   against the alternative of time-varying d . The discussion below makes clear

    that while the overall conclusion is unambiguous and unaffected by the sort of statistical

    considerations that beset other studies in the area, there are a number of important details

    that need particular attention.

    For each case, we compute the three estimates discussed above: the MFELW

    estimator, the ELW estimator with estimating unknown mean by sample average, and the

    GPH estimator. These three estimates allow us to test the robustness of the results over a

    range of priors regarding the parameters of the underlying process.

    We consider first the estimates for d   provided in Table 1. The table reports

    estimates and their asymptotic standard errors using three estimators for two subsample

     periods. The first estimate is for the subsample from May 1960 to April 1982; for this

     period, the MFELW estimator takes a value of 0.51. The second estimate is for the

    non-overlapping subsample from May 1982 to April 2003; for this period, d   has a value

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    22/50

     parameter is highly significant.18

      Results using alternative estimators (GPH and ELW)

     provide similar and equally unambiguous conclusions. The conclusion is that there has

     been a pronounced and marked decline in inflation persistence in the United States from

    early 1980’s onwards compared to the two decades before.

    We obtain additional insight and further support for these conclusions by estimating

    the d   parameter using a 15-year rolling window.19

      The basic procedure is to estimate the

     persistence parameter d   using the first 15 years of data (specifically, from May 1960 to

    April 1975). The data are then updated by 1 year increments, and the persistence parameter

    is re-estimated for the updated window (that is, for the period May 1961 to April 1976).

    18  We calculate asymptotic p-values based on the asymptotic theory in a conservative way.

     Namely, we compute asymptotic p-values by using upper bound of, for example,

    )ˆˆ(Var  21 d d   − , viz.

    )ˆ(Var )ˆ(Var )ˆ,ˆ(Cov2)ˆ(Var )ˆ(Var )ˆˆ(Var  21212121 d d d d d d d d    +≤−+=− ,

    since )ˆ,ˆ(Cov 21 d d    is expected to be positive. We also compute finite sample p-values

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    23/50

    This procedure is repeated until the end of the sample period; i.e., the last value of d   is

     based on the period May 1988 to April 2003.

    It is apparent that the fractionally integrated process implemented in this way can

    yield a significant amount of information about the underlying dynamics of the inflation

     process. It can also help highlight the periods over which there would likely have been

     pronounced changes in the persistence parameters. To get a flavor of the results and

    conduct formal tests, Table 3 reports results from estimates over the 15-year window for

    the three nearly non-overlapping subsamples.20

      For the MFELW estimator, with the period

    ending 1975, d   parameter has a value of 0.44. This increases slightly over the following

     period, so that by 1989, the parameter has a value of 0.53. However, the p-value for the null

    hypothesis 210 :H d d   =   against the alternative hypothesis 211 :H d d   ≠   shown in Table 3

    suggests this change is not statistically significant. This result illustrates that inflation

     persistence was high and approximately unchanged over the three-decade period before

    1989. As column 3 of the Table indicates, over the following period ending in 2003, there

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    24/50

    hypothesis 320 :H d d   =   against the alternative hypothesis 321 :H d d   ≠   shown in Table 3

    indicates, this difference between the two periods is statistically significant. Therefore, the

    conclusion is that a pronounced and marked decline in inflation persistence in the United

    States has begun the 1980’s. The other estimators further support the conclusion.

    Tables 1 to 3 provide further support for the results by giving point estimates for

    discrete periods. The methodology readily permits a generalization of the above by

    allowing computation of rolling estimates over contiguous periods. We present these

    estimates in Figure 2 with each graph showing three estimates of d   and the finite sample

    90% confidence interval of the MFELW estimates against the end year of an estimated

    sample, respectively.21  Figure 2 provides a striking illustration of the sharp decline in d  

    at the beginning of the last decade. It indicates that inflation persistence increased gradually

    during the first decade ending in 1985 and remained almost unchanged in the following

    decade ending in 1995, then declined rapidly and remained low until the present day. Note

    that Figure 2 is drawn against the end year of estimated samples. In other words, we detect

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    25/50

    we re-estimate the persistence parameter using other time windows, similar sharp declines

    are observed, in which all of them start with samples from the early 1980’s. These results

     provide further evidence for a decline in inflation persistence around early 1980’s.

    One concern regarding our empirical results is the robustness against the choice of

    the bandwidth m . We choose 75.0nm =   for the MFELW estimator based on simulation.

    The simulation, however, assumed that the true model is a Gaussian fractional white noise

    without short-run dynamics. Therefore in the presence of additional autoregressive serial

    correlation our estimates might have tremendous bias (as reported Agiakloglou, Newbod

    and Wohar (1993)) for the GPH estimator.22  As a robustness check Figure 3 provides the

    15-year rolling window estimates of the MFELW estimator using several bandwidth

    choices. Indeed there are some differences depending on the bandwidth, but the basic

    results are same. That is, we find the decline of inflation persistence around the early

    1980’s. More importantly, more striking results can be found, if we use smaller bandwidths,

    which are suitable for processes with short-run dynamics.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    26/50

    Another concern is that the decline in inflation persistence is due to ignoring

    effects of structural changes in mean. Even though most of the previous studies did not take

    into account this “spurious persistence” issue, it is important to know whether the decline in

    inflation persistence could be spurious or not. To investigate this, we allow for two

    structural changes in mean in our model. Following Hsu (2005), we estimated the timing of

    the breaks using the entire sample. The estimation result detects the structural changes

    corresponding with shortly before the first oil crisis (1973:1) and shortly after the second

    oil crisis (1981:9).23

      We construct a demeaned series using these structural changes and

    calculate 15-year rolling window estimates. Figure 4 shows estimation results of the

    MFELW estimator under two structural changes (MFELW2), along with our original

    MFELW estimates. As can be seen, these estimates indeed indicate that if we include

    structural changes, estimates will be smaller in most cases; however, these differences are

    notably small and do not change our main finding, i.e. a decline in inflation persistence.

    Our empirical results relate to many recent studies in macroeconomics which have

    found growing stability in the U.S. economy. This period roughly coincides with previous

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    27/50

    studies’ findings on the timing of a possible structural change towards stability in the U.S.

    economy. For instance, Clarida, Gali and Gertler (2000) estimated a forward-looking

    monetary policy function. They showed that there were indeed substantial differences in the

     parameters of Taylor rules between pre- and post- 1979. Goodfriend (2005) argued that the

    Fed adopted inflation targeting policy gradually and implicitly since the early 1980s. Also,

    Kim and Nelson (1999) and McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2000) found that there was a

    reduction in the volatility of output in 1984. Our empirical results suggest that there have

     been corresponding changes in inflation persistence toward stabilizing the U.S. economy.

    VI. Reconciliation with previous studies

    There is considerable disagreement in the previous literature regarding inflation

     persistence. Given our empirical findings, we will provide possible explanations for these

    differences and try to reconcile our findings with previous studies.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    28/50

    studies can be broadly divided into two methodological types, depending on persistence

    measures. Studies in the first category use order of integration as the measure of inflation

     persistence. More precisely, they use unit root tests and measure inflation persistence by

    classifying the inflation process as either an I(0) or I(1) process. One important and obvious

    drawback of this measure is the dichotomous nature of the statistic and the researcher’s

    inability to further distinguish between I(0) or I(1) process. Moreover, classification into an

    I(0) or I(1) process can be far too restrictive. In other words, it is hard to capture persistence

    that is not consistent with either an I(1) or an I(0) process. Indeed, as we discussed in the

     previous section, Figures 3 indicates that most of the estimates for order of integration are

    significantly different from either zero or one. This may account for the fact that previous

    studies provide divergent results depending on the particular sample periods and methods.

    In particular, Hassler and Wolters (1994) argued that, under the presence of fractional

    integration, ADF tests with large AR model have very low power to reject the I(1) null

    hypothesis. As a consequence, under the presence of fractional integration the ADF test

     based on a small AR model and a large AR model can provide inconsistent conclusions.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    29/50

    :H 0 inflation process is I(1), using three model specifications: AR(3), AR(6), and AR(12)

    models with a constant term to capture non-zero mean. The results using the whole sample

    and the range of subsamples used in the previous section are shown in Table 4 to 6. These

    tables illustrate the extreme dependence on the sample periods and testing model

    specifications. One interesting result in Table 4 is that if we use the AR(12) model, the US

    inflation rate is classified as an I(1) process, identical to the suggestions of MacDonald and

    Murphy (1989) and Evans and Wachtel (1993). On the other hand, if we use the AR(3) and

    AR(6) models, the US inflation rate is described as I(0) process, in accordance to what

    Rose (1988) indicated. Another disquieting result is that if we use the AR(6) and AR(12)

    models and two subsamples, there is evidence of a decline in the US inflation persistence as

    can be seen in Table 5; however, if we use the AR(3) model, the evidence disappears and

    US inflation rate is seen to be I(0) for both subsamples. In addition, Table 6 provides

    various results regarding the dynamics of inflation persistence. These inconsistent results of

    ADF tests can provide one reason for the divergent results of the previous studies.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    30/50

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    31/50

    an AR(12) model. Figure 5 shows estimates of the LARR and the SARC of AR(12) model

    using a 15-year window. As can be seen, both the order of fractional integration and the

    SARC declined dramatically at the beginning of the last decade, while the LARR remained

    high and unchanged. Stock (2001) and Pivetta and Reis (2006) found similar results using

    the LARR and concluded that inflation persistence in the U.S. was high and approximately

    unchanged over the past 40 years. Therefore, if one uses only LARR as a measure of

    inflation persistence, the conclusion would not be a decline in inflation persistence.

    However, if one chooses the SARC or order of fractional integration as the measure, the

    conclusion of declining persistence is borne out. Those results are also consistent with

    findings of Taylor (2000), Cogley and Sargent (2001, 2005).24

     

    V. Evidence for Other G7 Countries

    In the previous sections, we found that there has indeed been a significant decline

    in inflation persistence in the United States over the past two decades. It would be

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    32/50

    instructive to examine the extent to which there has been a commensurate decline in

    inflation persistence in other G7 countries.

    Each diagram in Figure 6 plots the MFELW estimates of the 15 year window for

    the United States (broken line) and other G7 countries (solid line). As can be seen, there are

    remarkable similarities between the dynamics of inflation persistence in the U.S. and other

    G7 countries except for Italy. In particular, the similarities between the dynamics of

    inflation persistence in the U.S. and France are striking. They are practically same overall

    four decades. Also exhibited are parallel behaviors between the dynamics of inflation

     persistence in the United Kingdom and Germany. Their dynamics of inflation persistence

    were similar to those in the U.S. for the first three decades, but their declines over the last

    decade were somewhat milder than that observed in the U.S. The dynamics of inflation

     persistence in Canada moved differently for the decade ending in 1995; however, otherwise

    it shifted similarly to that in the U.S. As a consequence of these observations, the degree of

    inflation persistence in those five countries became closer toward the end of sample period.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    33/50

     persistence in Japan seems to be increasing, which could reflect the concern about deflation

    experienced in Japan over the past five years.

    Lastly, the dynamics of inflation persistence in Italy are considerably different

    from those of other countries. In contrast to the decline observed in other countries,

    inflation persistence in Italy has been high and approximately unchanged over the past four

    decades.

    VI. Concluding Remarks

    There has been a significant interest in recent years in assessing the extent of a

     possible structural shift in the dynamics of the inflation process in the United States. A

    number of detailed and rigorous empirical studies regarding changes in inflation persistence

    have, however, reached conflicting results. Several studies suggest little or no change over

    the past four decades, while others suggest a pronounced decline over the same period.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    34/50

      This paper presented a variety of evidence for the existence of long-run persistence

    in the U.S. inflation. We argued that a fundamental reason for the divergence in previous

    results is inappropriateness of the econometric tools given that inflation does exhibit

    long-run persistence. Utilizing a more appropriate but quite general technique based on

    fractional integration yields the clear conclusion that there has indeed been a significant

    decline in inflation persistence in the United States over the past two decades. Moreover,

    this decline was preceded by a mild increase in the persistence parameter during the late

    1960s and 1970s. These conclusions are not overly sensitive to the sample period nor to the

     precise estimation procedure.

    The paper also investigated the extent to which there has been a commensurate

    decline in inflation persistence in other G7 countries. We found similar declines for France

    and Japan, and similar but milder declines for the United Kingdom and Germany. Inflation

     persistence in Canada experienced a decline only for the last decade. We also found

    inflation persistence in Italy had been high and approximately unchanged over the past four

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    35/50

    which a decline in the average rate of inflation and its volatility may reflect increasing

    globalization and competition (both domestic and international), the role of the

    informational technology revolution, increasing productivity growth, as well as improved

    monetary policy design.25

      These factors are probably also important in explaining the

    decline in inflation persistence. In general if the conclusions of this study are regarded as

    robust, and we believe they are, an analysis of the determinants of the decline in persistence

    in G7 countries would be a useful agenda for further research. In addition, it would be

    instructive to examine the extent to which there has been a commensurate decline in

    inflation persistence elsewhere in the other major industrial, as well as emerging market

    economies, and assess the importance of the common factors that might have led to such an

    outcome.

    As a final contribution to econometric methods, this study opens up several possible

    areas for future investigation. One of these is to consider the effect of structural changes

    more carefully. This paper treats structural changes in inflation as one of the source of

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    36/50

    formally in the fractional integration specification is an important future work. Hidalgo and

    Robinson (1996) and Bos, Franses and Ooms (1999) provide good starting points for this

     problem.

    Another avenue relates to the measurement of the short-run as well as the long-run

     persistence so that we can describe the persistence structure itself more precisely. One

     possibility is the ARFIMA modeling. As discussed in Section 2, we can capture the

    long-run persistence through order of fractional integration and the short-run persistence

    through ARMA model. A formal modeling of time-varying variance could also be useful.

    There is universal agreement on a reduction in variance and oftentimes it is misunderstood

    as a reduction in persistence. By explicitly modeling time-varying variance, this confusion

    can be clarified. ARFIMA-GARCH model proposed by Baillie, Chung and Tieslau (1996)

    is one attractive model for those topics.

    The final and perhaps the most important topic is to model the dynamics of inflation

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    37/50

    method could also be used in this context. Since the MCMC method provides a convenient

    framework to estimating complicated models, it might be particularly useful to estimate the

    time-varying order fractional integration model.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    38/50

    References 

    Agiakloglou, Christos, Paul Newbold, and Mark Wohar. (1993) “Bias in an Estimator of

    the Fractional Difference Parameter.” Journal of Time Series Analysis 14, 235-246

    Baillie, Richard T. (1996) “Long Memory Processes and Fractional Integration in

    Econometrics.” Journal of Econometrics 73, 5-59.

    Baillie, Richard T., Ching-Fan Chung, and Margie A. Tieslau. (1996) “Analysing Inflation

     by the Fractionally Integrated ARFIMA-GARCH Model.” Journal of Applied

    Econometrics 11(3), 23-40.

    Baillie, Richard T., Young W. Han, and Tae-Go Kwon. (2002) “Further Long MemoryProperties of Inflationary Shocks.” Southern Economic Journal 68(3), 496-510.

    Ball, Lawrence, and Stephen G. Cecchetti. (1990) “Inflation and Uncertainty at Short and

    Long Horizons.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 215-254.

    Batini, Nicoletta. (2002) “Euro Area Inflation Persistence.” Working Paper No.201,

    European Central Bank, December.

    Barsky, Robert B. (1987) “The Fisher Hypothesis and the Forecastability and Persistence of

    Inflation.” Journal of Monetary Economics 19, 3-24.

    Baum, Christopher F., John T. Barkoulas, and Mustafa Caglayan. (1999) “Persistence in

    International Inflation Rates.” Southern Economic Journal 65(4), 900-913.

    Beran, Jan. (1994) Statistics for Long-Memory Processes. Chapman and Hall: Yew York.

    Bernanke Ben S (2002) “Deflation: Making Sure “It” Doesn’t Happen Here ” Speech to

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    39/50

     

    Brainard, William, and George Perry. (2000) “Making Policy in a Changing World.” In

     Economic Events, Ideas, and Policies: The 1960s and After , edited by George Perry and

    James Tobin. Brookings Institution Press.

    Brunner, Allan D. and Gregory D. Hess. (1993) “Are Higher Levels of Inflation Less

    Predictable? A State-Dependent Conditionl Heteroscedasticity Approach.” Journal of

     Business and Economic Statistics 11(2), 187-197.

    Chambers, Marcus J. (1998) “Long Memory and Aggregation in Macroeconomic Time

    Teries.” International Economic Review 39, 649-662.

    Cioczek-Georges, Renata, and Benoit B. Mandelbrot (1995) “A Class of Micropulses andAntipersistent Fractional Brownian Motion.” Stochastic Processes and their Applications 

    60, 1-18.

    Clarida, Richard, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler. (2000) “Monetary Policy Rules and

    Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 

    115(1), 147-180.

    Cogley, Timothy, and Thomas J. Sargent. (2001) “Evolving Post-World War II U.S.

    Inflation Dynamics.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 16, 331-373.

    Cogley, Timothy, and Thomas J. Sargent. (2005) “Drifts and Volatilities: Monetary

    Policies and Outcomes in the Post WWII US.” Review of Economic Dynamics 8, 262-302.

    Culver, Sarah E. and David H. Papell. (1997) “Is There a Unit Root in the Inflation Rate?

    Evidence From Sequential Break and Panel Data Models.” Journal of Applied

     Econometrics 12, 435-444.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    40/50

    Geweke, John F. and Susan Porter-Hudak. (1983) “The Estimation and Application of

    Long Memory Time Series Models.” Journal of Time Series Analysis 4, 221-238.

    Goodfriend, Marvin. (2005) “Inflation Targeting in the United States? In The

     Inflation-Targeting Debate, edited by Ben S. Bernanke and Michael Woodford. The

    University of Chicago: Chicago IL.

    Granger. Clive W. J. (1980) “Long Memory Relationships and the Aggregation of Dynamic

    Models.” Journal of Econometrics 14, 227-238.

    Granger, Clive W. J. and Zhuanxin Ding. (1996) “Varieties of Long Memory Models.”

     Journal of Econometrics 73, 61-78.

    Granger. Clive W. J. and Roselyne Joyeux. (1980) “An Introcuction to Long Memory Time

    Series Models and Fractional Differencing.” Journal of Time Series Analysis 1, 15-39.

    Granger, Clive W. J. and Namwon Hyung. (1999) “Occasional Structural Breaks and Long

    Memory.” Discussion Paper 99-14, University of California, San Diego.

    Hassler, Uwe, and Jürgen Wolters. (1994) “On the Power of Unit Root Tests Against

    Fractional Alternatives.” Economics Letters 45, 1-5.

    Hassler, Uwe, and Jürgen Wolters. (1995) “Long Memory in Inflation Rates: International

    Evidence.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 13(1), 37-45.

    Hidalgo, Javier, and Peter Robinson. (1996) “Testing for Structural Change in aLong-Memory Environment.” Journal of Econometrics 70, 159-174.

    Hosking, Jonathan. R. M. (1981) “Fractional Differencing.” Biometrika 68(1), 165-176.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    41/50

    Kim, Chang-Jin. (1993) “Unobserved-Component Time Series Models with

    Markov-Switching Heteroscedasticity: Changes in Regime and the Link between Inflation

    Rates and Inflation Uncertainty.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 11(3),

    341-349.

    Kim, Chang-Jin, and Charles R. Nelson. (1999) “Has the U.S. Economy Become More

    Stable? A Bayesian Approach Based on a Markov-Switching Model of the Business

    Cycle.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 81, 608-616.

    Kumar, Manmohan S., Taimur Baig, Jörg Decressin, Chris Faulkner-MacDonagh, and

    Tarhan Feyzioğlu. (2003) “Deflation: Determinants, Risks, and Policy Options.” IMF

    Occasional Paper 221, Washington: IMF.

    Künsch, Hans R. (1986) “Discrimination between Monotonic Trends and Long-Range

    Dependence.” Journal of Applied Probability 23, 1025-30.

    Levin, Andrew T. and Jeremy Piger. (2003) “Is Inflation Persistence Intrinsic in Industrial

    Economies?” Working Paper 2002-023B, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, February.

    Lippi, Marco, and Paolo Zaffaroni. (1998) “Aggregation of Simple Linear Dynamics: Exact

    Asymptotic Results.” Discussion Paper 98-350, London School of Economics.

    MacDonald, Ronald, and P. D. Murphy. (1989) “Testing for the Long Run Relationship

     between Nominal Interest Rates and Inflation Using Cointegration Techniques.” Applied

     Economics 21, 439-47.

    McConnell, Margaret M. and Gabriel Perez-Quiros. (2000) “Output Fluctuations in the

    United States: What Has Changed Since the Early 1980’s?” American Economic Review 

    90(5), 1464-1476.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    42/50

    Robinson, Peter M. (1994) “Log-Periodgram Regression of Time Series with Long Range

    Dependence.” Annals of Statistics 23, 1048-1072.

    Rogoff, Kenneth. (2004). “Globalization and Global Disinflation.” In Monetary Policy and

    Uncertainty: Adapting to a Changing Economy, Federal Reserve Board of Kansas City.

    University Press of the Pacific.

    Rose, Andrew K. (1988) “Is the Real Interest Rate Stable?”  Journal of Finance 43,

    1095-1112.

    Shimotsu, Katsumi. (2002) “Exact Local Whittle Estimation of Fractional Integration with

    Unknown Mean and Time Trend.” Department of Economics Discussion Paper No. 543,

    University of Essex.

    Shimotsu, Katsumi. (2006) “Exact Local Whittle Estimation of Fractional Integration with

    Unknown Mean and Time Trend.” Economics Department Working Paper No. 1061,

    Queens University.

    Shimotsu, Katsumi, and Peter C. B. Phillips. (2005) “Exact Local Whittle Estimation of

    Fractional Integration.” Annals of Statistics 33(4), 1890-1933.

    Stock, James. (2001) “Comment on Evolving Post World War II U.S. Inflation Dynamics.”

     NBER Macroeconomics Annual 16, 379-387.

    Taylor, John B. (2000) “Low Inflation Pass-Through, and Pricing Power of Firms.”

     European Economic Review 44, 1389-1408.

    Taqqu, Murad S, Walter Willinger, and Robert Sherman. (1997) “Proof of a Fundamental

    Result in Self-Similar Traffic Modelling.” Computer Communication Review 27, 5-23.

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    43/50

    Table 1: Estimates of order of integration (two subsamples)

    Estimator 1960.5-1982.4 1982.5-2003.4 asy. p-values f.s. p-values

    MFELW 0.509 0.2680.000 0.057

    (asy. s.e.) (0.062) (0.063)

    GPH 0.587 0.2670.000 0.022

    (asy. s.e.) (0.069) (0.070)ELW 0.566 0.268

    0.000 0.015(asy. s.e.) (0.062) (0.063)

    Table 2: Estimates of order of integration (15-year window)

    Estimator 1960.5-1975.4 1974.5-1989.4 1988.5-2003.4

    MFELW 0.439 0.532 0.252

    GPH 0.517 0.539 0.297

    ELW 0.515 0.565 0.252

    Table 3: P-values for changes in order of integration (15-year window)

    Hypothesis d1=d2 d2=d3

    asy. p-values f.s. p-values asy. p-values f.s. p-values

    MFELW 0.514 0.437 0.050 0.029

    GPH 0.848 0.850 0.033 0.077

    ELW 0.725 0.663 0.028 0.011

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    44/50

      44

    Tables 4: Results of ADF unit root tests for US inflation (whole sample)

    Sample period 1960.5-2003.4

    Model AR(3) AR(6) AR(12)

     ADF statistics -4.650** -3.136* -2.573

    P-values 0.000 0.025 0.099

    Tables 5: Results of ADF unit root tests for US inflation (two subamples)

    Sample period 1960.5-1982.4 1982.5-2003.4

    Model AR(3) AR(6) AR(12) AR(3) AR(6) AR(12)

     ADF statistics -2.896* -2.059 -1.955 -6.573** -4.682** -3.182*

    P-values 0.047 0.262 0.307 0.000 0.000 0.022

    Tables 6: Results of ADF unit root tests for US inflation (three subsamples)

    Sample period 1960.5-1975.4 1974.4-1989.5 1988.5-2003.4

    Model AR(3) AR(6) AR(12) AR(3) AR(6) AR(12) AR(3) AR(6) AR(12)

     ADF statistics -2.503 -1.393 -1.654 -3.238* -2.283 -1.838 -4.551** -3.270** -2.539

    P-values 0.117 0.585 0.453 0.019 0.179 0.361 0.000 0.018 0.108

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    45/50

      45

    Figure 1: Autocorrelations of the US CPI inflation

    -0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    0.8

    0 20 40 60 80 100 120

    Lag

         A   u    t   o   c   o   r   r   e

         l   a    t     i   o   n

     

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    46/50

      46

    Figure 2: Dynamics of persistence in US inflation rate

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    0.8

    0.9

    1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002

    MFELW

    GPH

    ELW

    f. s. lb of 

    MFELW

    f. s. ub of 

    MFELW

     

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    47/50

      47

    Figure 3: Robustness check of the MFELW estimates

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002

    m=n0.6

    m=n0.65

    m=n0.7

    m=n0.75

    m=n0.8

    m=n0.6

    m = n0.65

    m=n0.7

    m = n0.75

    m = n0.8

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    48/50

      48

    Figure 4: Dynamics of persistence in US inflation rate under structural changes

    0.25

    0.3

    0.35

    0.4

    0.45

    0.5

    0.55

    0.6

    0.65

    1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002

    MFELW

    MFELW2

     

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    49/50

      49

    Figure 5: Dynamics of persistence in US inflation rate based on the LARR and SARC

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    0.8

    0.9

    1

    1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 2002

    MFELW

    LARR 

    SARC

     

  • 8/16/2019 SSRN-id985716

    50/50

      50

    Figure 6: Dynamics of persistence in inflation rates for other G7 countries

    Germany

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    1975 1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999 2003

    Canada

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    1975 1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999 2003

    France

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    1975 1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999 2003

    Italy

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    1975 1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999 2003

    Japan

    -0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    1975 1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999 2003

    United Kingdom

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    0.7

    1975 1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999 2003