special economic zones (sezs)_ a critique based on nandigram experience

15
1 Special Economic Zones (SEZs) and Their Critique : A Case of Nandigram Struggle A. Venkateswarlu* Abstract Special economic zone (SEZ) concept has been introduced to expand export-oriented production. Attraction of foreign direct investment and export promotion are the two main purposes of the SEZs. The land acquisition is made by the governments (state and central), by exercising the “public purpose” provisions. The concessions, subsidies and exemptions being extended by the governments would certainly generate fiscal crisis for the state and central governments. A lot of land is being acquired by the governments to keep the lands at the disposal of the Developers of the SEZs. But, proper rehabilitation and resettlement (R&R) schemes have not been prepared and particularly the people being affected have not been involved to voluntarily surrender their lands. As a result, there is a lot of scope for the land being diverted to ‘real estate’ scams. It is a type of accumulation by dispossession, in favour of the foreign and domestic monopoly capitalists. As the people are not taken into confidence, the forceful evictions and involuntary surrender of lands occurred; and the people started struggling against the SEZs. In West Bengal, after people’s struggle the Nandigram SEZ was scrapped; and the Singur project has been declared withdrawal. 1. Context and Objective of the Study Special Economic Zone (SEZ) concept as a panacea for development has been highlighted in the recent past everywhere in the world. Export-led economic growth has been an important part of the economic strategy prescribed to developing countries for their progress and development especially since the 1970s. The first export processing zone (EPZ) was set up in Ireland in 1959 and the first EPZ in Asia was established in India at Kandla in 1965. Originally conceived as zones of experiments with the free market in an otherwise protected economy, these zones were implemented with increasing intensity and varying results in Asia since the 1970s (Sampat, 2008). The concept EPZ has been replaced by SEZ. Between 1975 and 2006, the number of Free Zones has shot up from 79 in 25 countries to 3500 in 130 countries. Over the last decade, many new zones have been developed in Africa, Eastern Europe and transitional economies. China’s Shenzen has been a success, which suggests that SEZ concept may work not only in small countries but also in large economies (Majumdar, 2007). The first export processing zone (EPZ) in India was established in Kandla in 1966. By 2003, the existing 8 EPZs had been converted into SEZs. There is a difference between EPZ and SEZ. EPZ was the nomenclature for enclaves that were meant for “processing” i.e. manufacturing. SEZs are allowed for mere warehousing/ trading. _______________________ * Associate Professor, Centre for Economic and Social Studies, Hyderabad. This is presented at the National Seminar on Special Economic Zones: Engines of Growth and Social Development for India, held at NIzam College, Osmania University, Hyderabad, October 16-17, 2008.

Upload: venkateswarlu51

Post on 27-Apr-2015

652 views

Category:

Documents


4 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

1

Special Economic Zones (SEZs) and Their Critique :

A Case of Nandigram Struggle

A. Venkateswarlu*

Abstract

Special economic zone (SEZ) concept has been introduced to expand export-oriented

production. Attraction of foreign direct investment and export promotion are the two main

purposes of the SEZs. The land acquisition is made by the governments (state and central), by

exercising the “public purpose” provisions. The concessions, subsidies and exemptions being

extended by the governments would certainly generate fiscal crisis for the state and central

governments. A lot of land is being acquired by the governments to keep the lands at the

disposal of the Developers of the SEZs. But, proper rehabilitation and resettlement (R&R)

schemes have not been prepared and particularly the people being affected have not been

involved to voluntarily surrender their lands. As a result, there is a lot of scope for the land

being diverted to ‘real estate’ scams. It is a type of accumulation by dispossession, in favour

of the foreign and domestic monopoly capitalists. As the people are not taken into confidence,

the forceful evictions and involuntary surrender of lands occurred; and the people started

struggling against the SEZs. In West Bengal, after people’s struggle the Nandigram SEZ was

scrapped; and the Singur project has been declared withdrawal.

1. Context and Objective of the Study

Special Economic Zone (SEZ) concept as a panacea for development has been

highlighted in the recent past everywhere in the world. Export-led economic growth has been

an important part of the economic strategy prescribed to developing countries for their

progress and development especially since the 1970s. The first export processing zone (EPZ)

was set up in Ireland in 1959 and the first EPZ in Asia was established in India at Kandla in

1965. Originally conceived as zones of experiments with the free market in an otherwise

protected economy, these zones were implemented with increasing intensity and varying

results in Asia since the 1970s (Sampat, 2008).

The concept EPZ has been replaced by SEZ. Between 1975 and 2006, the number of

Free Zones has shot up from 79 in 25 countries to 3500 in 130 countries. Over the last

decade, many new zones have been developed in Africa, Eastern Europe and transitional

economies. China’s Shenzen has been a success, which suggests that SEZ concept may work

not only in small countries but also in large economies (Majumdar, 2007).

The first export processing zone (EPZ) in India was established in Kandla in 1966. By

2003, the existing 8 EPZs had been converted into SEZs. There is a difference between EPZ

and SEZ. EPZ was the nomenclature for enclaves that were meant for “processing” i.e.

manufacturing. SEZs are allowed for mere warehousing/ trading.

_______________________ * Associate Professor, Centre for Economic and Social Studies, Hyderabad. This is presented at the

National Seminar on Special Economic Zones: Engines of Growth and Social Development for

India, held at NIzam College, Osmania University, Hyderabad, October 16-17, 2008.

Page 2: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

2

As the SEZs in India have recently turned out to be a political landmine as is evident

from the Tata’s project at Singur at present, it draws everybody’s attention. The main

objective of the study is to explore important aspects related to SEZ (Special Economic

Zone). However, the specific objectives are:

(i) to depict the theoretical background of the SEZs

(ii) to delineate the process of forming SEZs and the purposes of SEZs in India;

(iii) to analyse the role of government in establishing SEZs;

(iv) to present a critique of SEZ policy in India;

(v) to bring out the problems involved in SEZs; and

(vi) to examine the struggles against the SEZs in general and the struggle in

Nandigram of West Bengal as a specific case.

2. Theoretical Background of SEZs

The process of industrialization and economic development is always related to the

conversion of land for non-agricultural activities from agricultural purposes. The transition

may be gradual sometimes. The change in land-use is accompanied by large-scale

displacement sometimes. Thus, the issue of development requiring land acquisition has

always been one of the most contested policy, depending on social, political, economic and

cultural life of the people. Large-scale acquisition of land may trigger controversies and

conflicts (Sharma, 2007).

When neo-classical framework of Heksher-Ohlin trade theory model was applied in

regard to the policy of setting up of a free zone (SEZ), some studies arrived at a negative

welfare and some others showed welfare-enhancing character. However, the idea behind

SEZs was to promote and create hassle free territorial production complexes that could be

established to secure regional balance in development opportunities. The major contributions

of SEZs for the development of the economy be briefly accounted as follows (Majumdar,

2007).

1. Attracting Foreign and Domestic Investment in Enclaves: Because of the

provision of facilities and amenities on the one hand and incentives on the other,

the capital flows in.

2. Stimulating Exports: This is the major purpose of the SEZs.

3. Creation of Employment: The SEZs cannot be counted as a solution to the

unemployment problem, they are nonetheless a viable source of employment

creation.

4. Leading to Balanced Development: Though it is good to develop all the regions

simultaneously, such balanced development requires a lot of resources at a time.

So the regional development can be undertaken in stages. Thus, to develop certain

areas as leading areas like SEZs is a solution.

5. Fostering Linkages with the Economy: Deepening backward and forward

linkages with the rest of the economy may bring in technological development

and quality production of goods when SEZs interact with DTA (domestic tariff

Page 3: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

3

area). New production sectors and catalytic effect to export are induced into non-

SEZ area due to demonstration effect.

3. The Process of Forming SEZs and Purposes of SEZs in India

3. 1 The Process of Forming SEZs in India

Murasoli Maran Minister of Commerce, visited the Gwangdong Special Economic

Zone in China under NDA government in 2000. Impressed by the razzle-dazzle of Chinese

SEZs, Maran introduced a policy in India for SEZ on April 1, 2000. Immediately the

existing EPZs were converted into SEZs. In 2004, Bill was introduced under NDA

government. The intervening elections in 2004 and the change in government from the NDA

to the UPA, supported by CPI (M) and left parties, made no difference to process of steering

this bill. On May 10, 2005 bill was tabled in the parliament. It was passed by both the

houses, with in 2 days, by May 12, 2005. No proper deliberation and debate was made in

the parliament on such an important issue which was going to affect the future of agriculture,

agriculturally dependent population, the whole rural sector, land use, employment

generation, urbanization process and whole social fabric.

In India, SEZ Bill was passed in May 2005, and the Act received the Presidential

assent was given in June 2005. The Act and Rules were notified in February 2006. As per the

Act, a SEZ is “a specifically delineated duty free enclave and shall be deemed to be foreign

territory for the purposes of trade operations and duties and tariffs.” Special Economic Zone

comprises of both processing and non-processing areas.

3.2 Purposes of SEZs and Guidelines for Approval in India

In India government by law allows public enterprises, private persons and joint

ventures to build and develop SEZs, whereas in most countries SEZs are allowed to be run

by government but not by private agencies for their development The four purposes for

which SEZs can be sanctioned in India are:

(i) export promotion,

(ii) export oriented production of services,

(iii) export oriented production and services, and

(iv) free trade and warehousing.

There is no limit on the size of SEZ and for the number of SEZs. In regard to the

development of SEZ, it is not required to specify the purpose of SEZ and specify the area

where SEZ is to be set up; and if one developer has no minimum limit land required, more

than one developer can be given approval; but there is no binding on the developer to make

allotment for the four purposes(Sawant, 2007).

Originally, the cap on number of SEZs to be approved was put as 150 in July 2006.

But later the cap was removed. In a way this has given scope for the rush of getting approval

for SEZs (Ramachandran and Biswas, 2007).

The guidelines to be followed at the time of SEZ notification are: (i) generation of

additional economic activity, (ii) promotion of exports of goods and services, (iii) promotion

of investment from domestic and foreign sources, (iv) development of infrastructure

Page 4: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

4

facilities, and (v) maintenance of sovereignty and integrity of India, the security of the State

and friendly relations with foreign States (Gopalakrishnan, 2007). If these guidelines are

strictly followed, there may not be any possibility for misappropriation and misuse of the

land acquired for the SEZ.

4. Role of Government in Establishing SEZ in India

4.1 Acquisition of Land for the SEZ

No specification is made as to how the land for SEZ is to be acquired, as per SEZ

Act. The government acting as a broker, has to provide land by enforcing Land Acquisition

Act, 1894. As per Land Acquisition Act, 1894, land can be acquired by the government for

“public purpose”, as per section 44(B) (i) for Dams and (ii) for providing accommodation to

the public sector industry/services (Sawant, 2007).

As per Land Acquisition Act, 1894, acquiring land for private purpose development

is clearly illegal (i.e. not being public purpose), as section 44(6) has not been amended so

far. SEZ becomes almost a foreign territory, as every person should have an identity card

(like visa to foreigners).

Peasants are being displaced for SEZ, and lands are being kept fallow. The time

given to a developer is 3 years, for the establishment of SEZ, and it is extendable by 2

years, i.e., totally 5 years. Only if the developer fails to do so, then only government may

allocate to new developer. But, “what will be the stand of the government if the original

developer sells the land to the new developer at a price which is many times the price, which

he originally paid for?” These is no guiding principle in the SEZ Act as to how the surplus

land, due to insufficient industrialists and service producers, should be used by the developer.

How the developers have to allot land to the industrialists is also not clearly specified.

There are no guiding principles in SEZ Act about the rent on the basis of which the developer

will make available land to the private industrialists in respect of rate of rent, mode of rent

fixation and selection criteria of industrialists.

There is a clear discrimination between SEZ and non-SEZ areas because of tax

conceptions in SEZs and better amenities in SEZs. As a result, due to competitive market

conditions (national and international); industries functioning outside SEZ areas would prefer

to join SEZs, by relocation with in SEZs.

The land transferred to SEZs has geological content in it and so compensation

received by the government is not a real value, because: (i) nature spends many years to

create a layer of merely one inch of soil, and (ii) the fertile soil formed by protected labour to

make the land cultivable.

4.2 Incentives for SEZ Companies including SEZ Developer

The SEZ Act offers a highly attractive fiscal incentive package, which ensures (i)

exemption from custom duties, central excise duties, service tax, central sales taxes and

securities transaction tax to both the developers and the units; (ii) tax holidays for 15 years

(currently the units enjoy a seven year tax holiday), i e, 100 per cent tax exemption for 5

years, 50 per cent for the next five years, and 50 per cent of the ploughed back export profits

Page 5: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

5

for the next five years1; and (iii) 100 per cent income tax exemption for 10 years in a block

period of 15 years for SEZ developers (Aggarwal, 2006).

4.3 Labour Laws Not Applicable in SEZs

Labour laws are not applicable to SEZs, there is a greater possibility for the workers

to suffer from adverse working conditions, a type of wage slavery will take place from the so

called labour flexibility conditions (Sawant, 2007). As per SEZ Act many changes in the

existing laws of India are made particularly under section-50 of SEZ Act, which says: “ The state government may, for the purposes of giving effect to the provisions of this Act,

notify policies for developers and units and take suitable steps for enacting of any law:- a)

granting exemption from the state taxes, levies and duties to the developer or the

entrepreneur; b) delegating the powers conferred upon any person or authority under any State

Act to the Development Commissioner in relation to the developer or the entrepreneur”

(Singhvi, 2006).

Accordingly, in Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, Maharastra, Madhya Pradesh, and Uttar

Pradesh, the Development Commissioner has been delegated to amend many Acts relating to

labour undermining the authority of the Labour Commissioners of the respective states. In

Andhra Pradesh, the Industrial Disputes Act, Bonus Act, Payment of Wages Act and other

Acts have been made amendable. In Maharashtra, Contract Labour Act (for dividing labour

into core and non-core sectors), Public Utilities declaration, Bonus Act, Maharashtra

minimum HRA Act, Payment of Wages Act and Motor Transport Workers Act can be

amended. In Karnataka, Trade Union Act 1928, Industrial Employment Act, Industrial

Disputes Act, Inter-state Migrant Workers Act, Minimum Wages Act, Bonus Act , and The

Equal Remuneration Act are all kept under the purview of the Development commissioner.

In Uttar Pradesh, a short and clear notification has been issued giving the powers of

the Labour Commissioner under “all labour laws” to the Development Commissioner of the

SEZ. Here the provisions of Chapter VB (against illegal retrenchment, closure and lay-off)

have also been made inapplicable in SEZs. Similarly in Madhya Pradesh, besides making all

units “public utilities”, section 9A of the I.D.Act, (requiring agreement with the union before

effecting a change in service) has been made inapplicable to SEZs. Some Standing Orders

have been made inapplicable to the SEZs and even some sections of the Factories Act and the

Shops and Establishments Act, relating to hours of work and holidays. In this connection,

Singhvi (2006) says:

“It is not as if such Development Commissioners can have the least care for the welfare of

workers. They are primarily charged with the development and propagation of the SEZ. It is a

farce and a mockery of justice to also charge them with the supervision and implementation of

labour laws. It is known that they will sacrifice the workers at the altar of “profits” for the

units – that is why these powers of supervision and inspection under labour laws have been

given to them.”

4.4 Expected Benefits– Vs – Expected Losses

There are also doubts, and ifs and buts, on the expected fiscal gains or losses to the

government coffers. In UPA government, the Finance Minister says about losses and the

Commerce Minister says about benefits. The losses from the tax concessions to the SEZs

could be the order of Rs.1,60,000 crores, as per Finance Minister. In contravention of this,

the Commerce Minister says that the benefits are to the tune of Rs.6,44,000 crores, as

Page 6: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

6

distributed into (i) investment (Rs.1,00,000 crores), (ii) tax revenue (Rs. 44,000 crores) and

employment creation (Rs.5,00,000 crores). Raghuvansh Prasad, Central Minister from the

RJD party, criticized SEZ policy as a big land grabbing affair. Janatha Dal (V) asked the

Bill to be scapped. Mr. V.P. Singh, former Prime Minister of India, demanded to declare

moratorium on the SEZ Act.

5. Critique of SEZ Policy in India

5.1 Land Acquisition by the Government for the Private Developer.

The major problem in the establishment of the SEZs is the land acquisition by the

government for the private developer. The land acquisition is being made under the Land

Acquisition Act of 1894. The SEZ Act 2005 marks is the acquisition of land by the state for

“public purpose” and the transfer of the ownership of this land to private developers. The

trajectory of neoliberal corporate growth through accumulation by dispossession (as per

David Harvey) thus becomes clearer in this land-acquisition process. The phenomenon of

neoliberal growth in the “competitive” “free market” enclaves of SEZs in India that threaten

to dispossess and displace thousands of people of their livelihoods, cultures and lands, in the

exercise of “public purpose” handing their land over to private corporations for economic

growth and development that too in the name of “greater common good of all” (Sampat,

2008).

In the Chinese case, which the government is so fond of citing, land for SEZs was

acquired by the state, whose agencies then developed the infrastructure and invited the

private sector to set up their export-oriented businesses, even while the state continued to

own the land. But in India, land for SEZs will now be acquired and owned by private

promoters/developers (EPW, 2007).

In India, the central and the state governments should rush into forcibly acquiring

hundreds of thousands of hectares of arable lands in huge chunks and dole them out to

powerful industrial houses and real estate dealers at throw-away prices. (Sarma, 2007).

5.2 Loss of Agricultural Land- Food Security Problem

What land is to be acquired for the SEZ is again a problem. When government

acquires land, under provision of the Land Acquisition Act 1894, it is generally accepted

principle that as far as possible, cultivable land and land under crops is not acquired. But for

SEZs land under crops and even double and treble cropped land is under threat of acquisition

(Sawant, 2007). As SEZs will be built on prime agricultural land with serious implication for

food security (Aggarwal, 2006).

In fact today’s struggles in West Bengal at Singur; in Andhra Pradesh at Polepalli,

Visakhapatnam, Coastal Corridor and Nizampatnam are really the struggles of farmers and

people who are losing agricultural lands.

5.3 Rehabilitation and Resettlement Policy

Central to the SEZ scheme is the facile assumption that handing over thousands of

hectares of land cheaply to promoters of industry would automatically promote

industrialization and solve the nagging unemployment problem of the country overnight.

Page 7: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

7

Thus, the displacement is both physical and occupational. In coastal states like Andhra

Pradesh, some SEZs are located along the sea coast, cutting off fishermen’s access to the sea

from which the latter eke out their livelihood. In many places, agriculturists, artisans and

rural workers who have also lost their lands and homes face livelihood problems. The

government should recognise the inherent rights of the local communities to resources such

as land, water, minerals, forest wealth, etc. All these call for a paradigm change in the attitude

of the government (Sarma, 2007).

Though are some details about the approvals of SEZ etc., there is no mention of the

number of people to be displaced by these zones, leave alone how the government intends to

attend to the issues of displacement (Sampat, 2008).

5.4 SEZs become Centres of Real Estate

Misuse of land for real estate is easy. Promoters will get land cheaply and will make

their fortune out of real estate development and speculation indiscriminately. The minimum

required processing area is 35 per cent. The rest will be for residential, recreational facilities

(Aggarwal, 2006).

The real estate activity is regarded as integral to SEZ area, because the key concept of

an SEZ is the creation of a space rather than any particular activity. From the Central

government’s list of permitted activities in the non-processing areas of SEZs, we can gain a

sense of what is expected from the use of this space. This list includes restaurants, housing

and apartment, club houses, gymnasiums, shopping arcades and retail space, multiplexes,

schools, convention or businesss centres. And oddly enough swimming pools. Hotels are

allowed in all SEZs except , IT, biotech and gems SEZs (Gopalakrishnan, 2007).

5.5 Relocation of non-SEZ COs

There is a lot of difference in regard to tax concessions, several exemptions and

labour laws between SEZ area and non-SEZ area. Therefore, the companies of non-SEZ areas

shift to SEZ area to take advantage of the tax concessions etc. being offered there. From this

relocation, little net activity will be generated (Aggarwal, 2006).

5.6 Governance of the SEZs

The power over all three arms of the state – executive, elected institutions, and

judiciary – are centralised in the hands of the Development Commissioner and or the

developer company, as per the SEZ Act. The executive powers lie with Development

Commissioner and so again there is scope for bureaucratic red tape and corruption. As

regards judicial powers, there will be special courts set up for SEZs for both civil and

criminal matters. Legislative powers are diluted as there is no elected local government.

Local governance institutions are dissolved. Only industrial township authority is formed as

declared in Andhra Pradesh, Gujarat, Jharkhand, Karnataka, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Orissa,

Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal. (Gopalakrishnan, 2007).

5.7 Uneven Growth

There is a strong possibility that SEZs will be set up in states where there is already a

strong tradition of manufacturing and exports (Table). This will aggravate regional

Page 8: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

8

disparities. The trend is already seen in the initial approvals. The share of the four most

industrialised states (TN, Karnataka, Gujarat and Maharashtra) in total approvals is 49.5 per

cent. Andhra Pradesh, Kerala and Haryana account for another 31.1 per cent of total

approvals. Thus seven states account for 80.6 per cent of approvals. Their share of in-

principle approvals is 63.8 per cent. On the other hand, industrially backward states of Bihar,

north-east and J and K do not have a single approval (Aggarwal, 2006).

List of SEZs as on 11th August 2008

S.No. State No. S.No. State No.

1 AP 56 19 Mizoram

2 Arunachal 20 Nagaland

3 Assam 21 Orissa 4

4 Bihar 22 Punjab 2

5 Chhattisgarh 23 Rajasthan 5

6 Delhi 1 24 Sikkim

7 Goa 3 25 TN 42

8 Gujarat 22 26 Tripura

9 Haryana 20 27 UP 12

10 Himachal 28 Uttarakhand 2

11 J & K 29 WB 8

12 Jharkhand 1 30 A & N

13 Karnataka 23 31 Chandigarh 2

14 Kerala 8 32 Dadra

15 MP 4 33 Daman

16 Maharashtra 35 34 Lakshadweep

17 Manipur 35 Pondicherry

18 Meghalaya

Total Approved 250

Source : www.sezindia.nic.in

5.8 Power of Private Finance and Investment Capital

SEZs enhance power of finance and investment capital direct and indirect ways. The

incentives being given to SEZs will add to the fiscal crisis of both the central and state

governments. The SEZs in certain sectors of capital, such as real estate, construction and

finance, will attract the speculative and volatile capital of Foreign Iinstitutional Investors

(FIIs), subjecting Indian economy to the ups and downs in the world. SEZ companies

practice the high degree of speculative, fraudulent or repressive activity to compete with non-

SEZ companies and so the survival of the latter is a problem.

As the government provides infrastructural facilities like water and electricity in

higher quantities as demanded by the developer in SEZ area, non-SEZ firms and companies

have to downsize their economic activities and collapse. SEZ companies adjust to more and

more concessions. Therefore future governments cannot reduce such concessions. A fragile

situation for the governments. Reduction in tax concessions and effective enforcement of

labour or environmental law lead to either withdrawal of capital in the case of speculative

investors or to slowdowns in activity.

Privatisation and disinvestment of public sector corporations – seizing resources

through increasing use of land acquisition powers to forcibly seize land or other resources in

favour of private foreign and domestic monopolists. Thus, the regime of accumulation under

neoliberalism is a combination of two processes: (i) a laissaiz faire economics that implies

greater freedom for capital to expand and for concentration of capital to occur; and (ii)

Page 9: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

9

accumulation through encroachment, driving accumulation through the use of force, state

policy and coercion(Gopalakrishnan, 2007).

The government becomes a ruthless promoter of the corporate entities in search of

higher growth, irrespective of how it affects the interests of the ordinary people. This is a case

of state-led corporatism, strengthening foreign capital and domestic monopoly capital

(Bhaduri, 2007).

In this context, David Harvey’s two concepts are relevant, viz., ‘accumulation by

dispossession’ and ‘imperialism of the capitalist sort’, as they may be realized through the

operation of SEZs. Harvey defines accumulation by dispossession as “What accumulation

by dispossession does is to release a set of assets (including labour power) at very low (and in

some instances zero) cost. Overaccumulated capital can seize hold of such assets and

immediately turn them to profitable use.”

Further, Harvey defines’ imperialism of the capitalist sort’ as a ‘contradictory fusion’

of two components: ‘territorial logic of power’—a logic, that is, in which command over a

territory and its human and natural resources constitutes the basis of the pursuit of power; and

‘capitalist logic of power’—a logic, that is, in which command over economic capital

constitutes the basis of the pursuit of power (Arrighi,2005).

6. Suggestions for Improving Situation in Land Acquisition

Forcible acquisition of land should be done away with. The land acquisition law itself

should be revoked, in view of its potential misuse. Decisions that involve displacement of

people should not be taken without prior consultation with the local communities. The

Constitution requires the gram sabhas to be fully involved whenever decisions that might lead

to dislocation of people are taken. Accumulation through encroachment is seen as classic

instance: The huge increase in mining activity, an extractive industry where policies ensure

that companies receive both land ore either for free or at very low royalty rates (Sarma 2007).

Wherever allocation of government acquired land to private developers is involved,

land should be leased-out not sold. As part of the compensation package, it would be useful

to ensure that the displaced persons are provided with the option of augmenting their human

capital and skill-set, so that they could be absorbed directly or indirectly as workers or

entrepreneurs in and around the SEZs (Majumdar, 2007).

We must oppose high growth that justifies developmental terrorism by the state on

behalf of the corporations. An alternative path of development can be evolved. Pro-people

growth in India has to be employment-driven. This can be achieved by programmes like

National Rural Employment Guarantee Act. For effective implementation of such

programmes, the panchayats are to be strengthened by genuinely decentralizing powers

(Bhaduri, 2007).

7. Struggles against SEZs in General

Karl Polyani, the perceptive commentator on 19th century capitalism described this as

a process of “great transformation” driven by the “double movement” of the market and the

state, a process in which the rules for the market were set mostly by the state. When the state

Page 10: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

10

fails to play this role, the result is not a freer market and more freedom but growing

desperate rage of the poor, which must engulf all sooner or later (Bhaduri, 2007).

This is exactly what is happening in India. The people some states are fighting

against the SEZs. There were and have been struggles in Orissa (Kaling Nagar), Kerala,

Tamil Nadu, Karnataka, Andhra Pradesh, West Bengal and Maharashtra.

Very recently there has been struggle against the Singur SEZ project of Tatas in West

Bengal, which has led to Tata’s declaration of withdrawal from Singur on 3rd

October, 2008.

In Visakhaptnam Bauxite Mining zone also there has been going on struggle of the people

not all responding to the so-called public hearing (Eenadu, 4th

October, 2008).

On 26th

September, Mr. Chiranajivi, Praja Rajyam Party, visited Polepalli village,

which is under proposed SEZ where the lands of the farmers were acquired by the AP

government. The farmers who lost land reported that the acquisition of land was forcefully

done (Eenadu, 27th

September, 2008). On 27th

September,2008, four political parties - Telugu

Desam Party (TDP), Communist Party of India-Marxist (CPI-M), CPI, and CPI (ML) - rallied

against Odarevu Nizam Patnam Industrial Corridor (ONPIC), as an SEZ, which covers

26,000 acres of land along the coastal belt in Coastal Andhra region (Eenadu, 28th

September,

2008). On 29th

September, 2008, TDP leader, Sri Yerram Naidu, MP, gave a statement that

they are opposed to take the cultivated land (Eenadu, 30th

September, 2008).

8. Struggle against SEZ in Nandgram of West Bengal

In West Bengal, the government of Bengal had to scrap the SEZ at Nandigram after

the violence witnessed in Nandigram in the state of West Bengal (a Communist Party of India

(Marxist) ruled state) is a case in point. The people struggled protesting notification of land

acquisition of 25,000 acres of land under the LAA 1894 for an SEZ towards a chemical hub

slated for the Salim group of Indonesia. Now, we present the struggle against Nandigram

SEZ in some detils.

8.1 Protest at Nandigram SEZ

On 3rd

January, 2007, Laxman Seth, MP (Lok Sabha) of CPI (M) party, the

chairman, Haldia Development Authority (HAD), sent notices to villages identified to be

acquired for Nandigram SEZ. CPI (M) cadres who possessed land in those villages submitted

consent letter to the HDA. Meeting at Kalicharanpur (District Administration) Nandigram

turned into protest.

8.2 Villagers Protest at Panchayat Kalicharanpur - 3rd

January 2007

Block officials were present on 3rd

January 2007. The meeting was intended to serve

notice to the peasants or pass on information about the acquisition of land. 25-30 villagers

gathered around the Panchayat. They got agitated as nothing was clear to the villagers. They

questioned the purpose of the meeting – also abused the intention of acquiring the land. They

raised queries. They questioned the officials but no satisfactory answers could be received.

The villagers came in crowds. Police began to beat them. Police opened fire and 3 people

injured. When the crowd increased, police fled from the place. But WB government did not

come out with a statement that there was no intention to acquire land.

Page 11: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

11

On 4th

January 2007, the villagers and members of Bhumi Uched Birodh Committee

(BUBC) wanted to breach all roads into Nandigram interior. Boulders were placed at many

places. Sharp branches were placed in some narrow lanes. Seeing this CPI (M) cadre feared

and went out of the villages. People requested the CPI (M) cadre to come back and stay with

them inside the village, as they did not intend to harm them (CPI-M cadre). But people or

agitating peasants took pledge not to allow any state machinery and revenue, police, and

panchayat raj officials to enter the interior of Nandigram Block. People kept vigil round the

clock. On 4th

and 6th

January 2007, people were on vigil.

8.3 Incidents of 6-7 January 2007

Benay Konar, Senior CPI (M) leader; Laxman Seth, MP, CPI (M); Ashok Guria,

Secretariat Member, CPI (M) of East Midnapore District, propagated that TMC and other

political forces were involved in this event. They decided for an armed attack.

Sonachura (one side) and Tekhali (other side) are the opposite sides of the Bonga Bari

canal near Talpathi Bridge. About 15,000 people of BUBC were gathered on Sonachura side.

A camp of CPI (M) cadre was there on Tekhali side. CPI (M) cadre started hurling bombs

toward the people gathered at Sonachura outskirts. The people of BUBC wanted to beat back

the CPI (M) cadre and police, if they dared to cross the bridge.

Around 3.30 am on 7th

January , i.e., 6th

January night, guns of CPI (M) cadre in

police uniform start blasting which killed 3 of the vigilants and injured not less than 20

according to some people, who claimed to have seen. But some said, only 6 killed and some

said only 8 killed. CPI (M) central weekly organ 8-14 January, claimed that 5 of its cadre

were killed: (1) Biswajt Maity (belonged to people agitating), (2) Sankar Samanta (people

killed him, but CPI (M) reported as murdered by TMC-Maoist combine), (3) Bhunder

Mandal (not a correct statement), (4) Sudeb Mandaql (not a correct statement), and (5)

Fahim Bhule (not a correct statement). Sankar Samanta was chased, caught and axed to death and the body was burnt down

by the people on 6th

January night. Sankara Samanta, with AK 47 rifle in his hand, led 250

CPI (M) cadre opened fire on the 15,000 strong persons (agitating) where 3 killed, 20

injured. As per the people’s report to AIFFC (2007), the fact is that the following three (3)

persons among the agitating people of BUBC were killed in the guns blazing attack by CPI

(M) cadre: (1) Bharat Mandal, aged 35 years - agricultural labour, 2) Sheik Saleem, aged

21 years - tailor, and (3) Biswajit Maity, aged 14 years - 8th

class student.

8.4 Looting on 18th

February 2007

CPI (M) cadre, nearly 200, holding CPI (M) flags looted many shops in Tekhali

village bazaar in broad day-light, while 100 police were silent spectator on 18th

February,

2007. On enquiry by the AIFFC (on the day of their visit), SHO, Nandigram reported that

on 18th

February, 2007, there were no sufficient police force, as police were sent to some

other place (AIFFC, 2007).

.

8.5 Medha Patakr’s Visit on 25th

February, 2007 - Desperate Intolerance of CPI (M)

On 25th

February, 2007, Binay Konar (a senior CC member of CPI-M) gave a call to

the women to show their naked buttocks to Medha Patkar, when she would be visiting

Page 12: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

12

Nanidigam. It is a clear sign of desperate intolerance. Women rejected this indecent call but

young male CPI (M) cadre at Hulnimore lowered their pants and under-wears and showed

their nasty buttocks to Medha Patkar. Not only this, Medha Patkar was physically pushed

from all sides. Patkar said that it was a great degeneration. In her 15 years Narmada Bachao

Andolan , she had never faced such an ugly experience even from Sangh Pariwar forces

(AIFFC, 2007).

8.6 Firing at Nandigram on March 14, 2007

After 7

th January 2007, the government also intended to strike back on the Nandigram

people. It was planned to take place on 13th

March. Governor of the state, who was in

Chennai, came to know about the imminent aggression and asked the government officials to

show restraint. On 14th

March the operation started at 9.45 am, with indiscriminate firing by

the armed police and armed goons and nobody from outside could go to Nandigram in the

next 72 hours. On March 14th

, 244 persons, including 57 women, suffered serious physical

injuries; 348 women suffered sexual atrocities of different kinds, including 11 rape cases; 14

persons including 2 women were killed; and 4 persons had been missing since March 14th

(Bandyopadhyay, 2007).

On PIL petition, the Calcutta High court directed CBI enquiry, which found ample

evidence of indiscriminate firing from both the police firearms and civilian firearms. They

also recovered 315 sporting rifles. Further, it was demonstrated by the CBI’s limited enquiry

that all the miscreants were CPI (M) supported or hired by them. But High Court also could

not deliver judgement till November 16th

2007, though formal hearing ended in July. This

delay ultimate led to further attack on Nandigram people on 10-11th

November, 2007.

8.7 Protests against March 14 Killings from Intellectuals and Activists

In regard to Kaling Nagar violence, Navin Patnaik simply expressed his apologies.

But, Budha Dev after the violence of March 14, 2007, began to say that the incidents in

Nandigram were instigated by the other political parties and so they were responsible. But

there are lot of protests from the intellectuals and activists.

1. Historians Sumit Sarkar, Tanika Sarkar, and Pradip Kumar Datte, refused to keep the

Ravindra Puraskar that was awarded by Paschim Vanga Bangla Academy. 2. Prof.

M.N.Vijayan criticized capitalist path of CPI (M) (He was topmost Journalist of CPI (M) till

2004 when he resigned). 3. Nabaroon Bhattacharya eminent novelist and cultural activist

refused the Bankim Award due to Nandigram. 4. Bratya Basu (eminent play wright and

director) compared Nandigram incident as another ‘Jalianwalabag’, a genocide. 5. Amar

Deo Sharma and Sanjoy Tyagi, President and Secretary (respectively) of Delhi University

Teachers Association, said “Nandigram is part of a pattern of events in India where

‘industrialization’ is taking place for the benefits of the corporate houses.” 6. Totally 48

teachers of Jadavpur University said “We find this action planned and executed in tandem by

the state machinery and the ruling party, to be a betrayal of the trust the people of West

Bengal put in the elected authorities.”

A People’s Tribunal consisting of a retired high court chief justice and social activists,

documented this, after recording 174 depositions by the victims. Its chilling conclusions

show close Police-CPI (M) collusion.. The motive was to ‘teach SEZ opponents a lesson.

Page 13: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

13

Mr. C. Bhaskar Rao, who is the Genral Secretary, OPDR-AP, as convener of All India Fact

Finding Committee (AIFFC) visited Nandigram on February 28, 2007 and Singur on March

1, 2007 gave its report, on the same lines.

Editorial Main Stream, March 16-22, 2007 (p.2) reported: “Indeed March 14 at

Nandigram has few parallels in independent India and it is no exaggeration to compare it with

“Jalianwalabag.” “ The police cold-bloodedly killed many people by firing not on the feet,

but chest upwards and even on the head.”

Further, Governor, Gopal Gandhi (Mainstream, March 16-12, 2007; p.3) expressed

his view as “Force against anti-national elements, terrorists, extremists, insurgents is one

thing. The receiving end of the force used today does not belong to that order”.

8.8 Operation Reconquest of Nandigram by CPI (M) – 10th

November, 2007

Calcutta High Court acted upon Public Interest Litigation and completed its hearings

by July 2007, on the violence of March 14, 2007, at Nandigram. Judgment was given on

November 16, 2007. It ordered that police firing on March 14, was unjustified and violative

of article-21 of Indian constitution. Court asked CBI to complete comprehensive report.

Court rejected all the arguments of the state government and rejected stay order on HC’s

order and enquiry. It is said, “ if the order had come prior to the autumn recess of the High

Court perhaps the second wave of the more horrendous bloody events could have been

avoided.” BUPC did not cow down. It stiffened their resistance. The CPI (M) and

government of West Bengal could not tolerate such impudence from the unarmed organized

peasants who were their loyalists for so many decades.

The party and government planned to “reconquest” Nandigram. From late

September, 2007, party leaders at all levels started planning a bloody offensive to recapture

Nandigram, in collusion with the police, and the preparations made are:

1. The CPI (M) propagated that their supporters (to the extent of 15,000) were driven

(though scaled down to 3,500), by the BUBC, TMC, and Jamat-e-Hind (which was

dropped later, not willing to face resentment from the minorities). Maoist

involvement was falsely propagated.

2. Mobilization of known assassins, killers and murderers on payment: (i) Rs, 12000 per

night and (ii) Rs. 2,00,000 per kith and kin if life lost.

3. Six pronged attack executed to avoid resistance of the BUBC.

4. The whole area was cordoned off to prevent ingress or engress any “out siders”

5. Deadly weapons AK 47s and AK 56s, Ichapore rifles were supplied.

6. Gang leaders in charge of different sectors, some CPI (M) leaders were deployed as

“political commissars.”

The operation conquest was well planned and executed accordingly. On November 3-

4, 2007, all roads leading to Nandigram were blocked, by slogan shouting CPI (M) cadres.

TMC leader, Mamata, had to be kept 70 kms. away from Nandigram. Medha Patkar was not

allowed to travel into the block. No media person was allowed except their TV channel.

The operation was being resisted by BUPC volunteers. Here the BUBC made a major

tactical error. BUPC wanted to take procession on November 10, 2007 with their supporters

without any arms (not even lathis) towards the peripheral villages. Just as in absolutely

Page 14: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

14

military manner, CPI (M) cadres ambushed these two processions, by killing nearly 100

persons, injuring over 150 persons and capturing about 800 villagers. Dead bodies were

carried to a community funeral pyre, and even injured persons were carried and burnt alive.

“Their savagery far exceeded any recorded incident of cruelty and brutality of the middle

ages.” Captured 800 persons were used as human shield by the CPI (M) cadre and as a token

of reconquest they planted red flags all over the area. Major Aditya Bera (rtd.) was killed

brutally because he was suspected as the planner of BUBC volunteers.

9. Conclusion

Special economic zone (SEZ) concept has been introduced to expand export-oriented

production. Attraction of foreign direct investment and export promotion are the two main

purposes of the SEZs. Thus, SEZs are geographical spaces of free trade and warehousing.

For this, governments have to offer tax concessions and many other incentives through

provision of land, water, electricity and other facilities at subsidized prices. The land

acquisition is made by the governments (state and central), by exercising the “public

purpose” provisions.

The concessions, subsidies and exemptions being extended by the governments would

certainly generate fiscal crisis for the state and central governments. Further, the non-SEZ

companies demand for the extension of benefits on par with SEZ area. Further, to attract the

SEZs, labour laws are being amended by incorporating flexible laws (without minimum

wage, AND with fire and hire clauses) which can reduce the SEZs into places of wage

slavery in new forms.

A lot of land is being acquired by the governments to keep the lands at the disposal of

the Developers of the SEZs. But, proper rehabilitation and resettlement (R&R) schemes have

not been prepared and particularly the people being affected have not been involved to

voluntarily surrender their lands. It is possible only when there is a participatory role for the

farmers and villagers, if they have to be convinced. The developers are simply being

provided with space without proper mechanism to regulate them so as to make the land

properly utilized. As a result, there is a lot of scope for the land being diverted to ‘real

estate’ scams. It is a type of accumulation by dispossession, in favour of the foreign and

domestic monopoly capitalists.

As the people are not taken into confidence, the forceful evictions and involuntary

surrender of lands occurred. The people are badly affected and have started struggling either

with the support or without the support of opposition political parties. Throughout many

states people’ struggles were launched or are still being continued. In West Bengal, after

people’s struggle the Nandigram SEZ was scrapped; and the Singur project has been

declared withdrawal.

Andhra Pradesh, which has 56 approved SEZs, stands at the top among all the states

in India. In AP, the struggles are going on in Polepalli, Rajamundry, Viasakhapatnam and

throughout coastal corridor (inclding Nizampatnam Port). Yet, the struggles have not taken

such dimension as in West Bengal. The reason for not being succeful in struggle against the

SEZs in AP is rightly pointed out by the TDP leaders, when were asked why they were not in

a position to fight against SEZs as was fought in in Nandigram and Singur. They replied that

in West Bengal there were only a few SEZs and so the opposition parties could concentrate

and fight against the government and ultimately the government gave up the SEZ at

Page 15: Special Economic Zones (SEZs)_ a Critique Based on Nandigram Experience

15

Nandigram on its own and by the developers themselves at Singur (Eenadu, 30th

September,

2008).

References

Aggarwal, Aradhana (2006), “Special Economic Zones: Revisiting the Policy Debate”, Economic and

Political Weekly , November 4.

All India Fact Finding Committee (AIFFFC) (2007), Repression and Massacre instead of Dialogue and Democracy, Vijayawada, March.

________ (2007), “Budha’s Killing Fields of Nandigram!”, Mainstream, November 30-December 6.

Arrighi, Giovanni (2005), “Hegemony Unravelling - I”, New Left Review, Vol. 32, March-April.

Basu, Subrata (2007), “Nandigram Carnage: Budhadeb Shows his Fascist Face Donning the mantle of Sidhartha

Sankar Ray of the Emeergency Days”, Red Star, December.

Bhaduri, Amit (2007), “Development or Developmental Terrorism?”, Economic and Political Weekly , Feb. 17.

Bidwai, Praful (2007), “Blood on Their Hands”, Mainstream, November 23-29.

Chowdhury, Neerrja (2007), “Nandigram: CPM Exposed”, Mainstream, November 30-December 6.

EPW (2007), “Piemeal Tinkering” , Economic and Political Weekly , April 21.

Gopalakrishnan, Shankar (2007), “Special Economic Zones and Neoliberalism in India”, Man and

Development, Vol.29, No.4, December.

Mainstream (2007), “Naked Terror and Massacre of Democracy”, Mainstream, March 16-22.

Majumdar, Manab (2007), “Approaching Special Economic Zones: The Debate, Dimensions and

Determinants”, Man and Development, Vol.29, No.4, December.

Rajagopalan, T.N.C (2008), “SEZ Policy Sould be Allowed a Reasonable Run”, Business Standard,

September 29.

Ramachandran, H and Debatosh Biswas (2007), “Locating Land for Special Economic Zones”, Man and

Development, Vol.29, No.4, December.

Sampat, Preeti (2008), “Special Economic Zones in India”, Economic and Political Weekly, July 12-18.

Sarma, E.A. S (2007), “Help the Rich, Hurt the Poor:Case of Special Economic Zones” Economic and

Political Weekly, May 26.

Sawant, P.B (2007), Special Economic Zones Act and What It Means, Speech at a Seminar at Arthagyan

Prabodhini, Pune, January 28.

Sharma, Vineeta (2007), “Implications of A Special Economic Zone on Project Affected People”, ”, Man and

Development, Vol.29, No.4, December.

Singh, Mahi Pal (2007), “Nandigram: A Dangerous Chapter in the Hostory of Human Rights”, Mainstream,

November 30-December 6.

Singhvi , Sanjay (2006), “Special Exploitation Zones”, Red Star, March.

______ (2008), “SEZs as a New Form of Colonial Urbanisation: A Study Based on Mharashtra’,

Red Star, January.