south east currency union.pdf

Upload: sudeep-sahu

Post on 14-Apr-2018

260 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    1/25

    This article was downloaded by: [Indian Institute of Management - Lucknow]On: 09 January 2013, At: 06:02Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registeredoffice: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

    Global Economic Review: Perspectives

    on East Asian Economies and IndustriesPublication details, including instructions for authors and

    subscription information:

    http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rger20

    Is an Optimum Currency Area Feasible

    in East and South East Asia?Chandan Sharma

    a& Ritesh Kumar Mishra

    b

    a Department of Economics, National Institute of FinancialManagement (NIFM), Haryana, Indiab

    Department of Economics, GGS Indraprastha University, New

    Delhi, India

    Version of record first published: 20 Aug 2012.

    To cite this article: Chandan Sharma & Ritesh Kumar Mishra (2012): Is an Optimum Currency

    Area Feasible in East and South East Asia?, Global Economic Review: Perspectives on East Asian

    Economies and Industries, 41:3, 209-232

    To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1226508X.2012.709991

    PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

    Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

    This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any

    substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing,systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden.

    The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representationthat the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of anyinstructions, formulae, and drug doses should be independently verified with primarysources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings,demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly orindirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material.

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1226508X.2012.709991http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rger20http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditionshttp://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1226508X.2012.709991http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rger20
  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    2/25

    Is an Optimum Currency Area Feasiblein East and South East Asia?

    CHANDAN SHARMA* & RITESH KUMAR MISHRA***Department of Economics, National Institute of Financial Management (NIFM), Haryana, India &

    **Department of Economics, GGS Indraprastha University, New Delhi, India

    ABSTRACT In the backdrop of the recent economic crisis in the European Union, this studyattempts to assess the degree of regional integration and the suitability of a monetary union in the

    East and South-East Asian (ESEA) region. For this purpose, we analyse the issue in a variety ofways. First, a long-run linkage of real output of the countries is tested using the cointegrationanalysis. Results suggest that real output of most of the countries in the region is cointegrated andmove together in the long-run. To analyse the issue in detail, we focus on the impact of threedifferent shocks, namely global, regional and country-specific, on real output of the countries.Results of impulse response and variance decomposition analysis reveal that regional shocks donot dominate in the sample countries, which is an indication of unfavourable condition to form anoptimal currency area (OCA) in the region. These results are further confirmed by the outcome ofcomputation of the modified Bayoumi and Eichengreens Indices. Finally, we employ the conceptof Generalized Purchasing Power Parity (G-PPP), which however reveals that the bilateral realexchange rate of ESEA countries move together in the long-run and share a common stochastictrend, which in turn provides some empirical support for an OCA in the region.

    KEY WORDS: OCA; output shocks; G-PPP; East and South-East Asian; monetary union

    JEL CLASSIFICATION: F36, F42, F33, C32

    1. Introduction

    Exchange rate management has been the core of economic policy debate since the

    East Asian currency crisis. It is now widely recognized that the regime of soft-peg was

    the prime cause of the financial debacle in the Asian economies during the latter part

    of 1990s. In some sense, the crisis has exposed the inherent complications inmanaging the exchange rate individually and efficiently in a small open economy,

    especially in the presence of massive international capital inflows and outflows (see

    Wilson & Choy, 2007). The East and South-East Asian (ESEA) region is

    characterized by diverse, uncoordinated exchange rate arrangements. For instance,

    Japan and China, the two dominant countries in the region, have adopted an

    exchange rate regime akin to a pure float and a tightly managed US dollar-based

    regime, respectively. Most other economies in the region have adopted intermediate

    Correspondence Address: Chandan Sharma, Department of Economics, National Institute of Financial

    Management, Sector 48, Faridabad 121 001, Haryana, India. Email: [email protected]

    Global Economic Review

    Vol. 41, No. 3, 209232, September 2012

    1226-508X Print/1744-3873 Online/12/03020924

    # 2012 Institute of East and West Studies, Yonsei University, Seoul

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1226508X.2012.709991

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1226508X.2012.709991http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1226508X.2012.709991
  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    3/25

    regimes such as managed float. The presence of different exchange rate regimes and

    strategies in the region has made it difficult to maintain intra-regional exchange rate

    stability through the dollar pegging. Therefore, it has become increasingly important

    for the countries to work in the direction of a similar exchange rate regime and ensure

    the intra-regional exchange rate stability. Following this and taking lessons from the

    Asian crisis, a group of researchers have proposed for the formation of an optimalcurrency area (OCA) in the East Asian region (e.g. Williamson, 1998; McKinnon,

    2000; Mundell, 2003).1

    Currency union, as discussed in the literature, has numerous real and monetary

    effects on the trading and economic environment of member economies. For

    example, with the formation of currency union the trading costs are expected to

    decline, and therefore it leads to increase in both output and consumption. The loss

    of independent stabilization policy has costs and benefits of different magnitude and

    importance attached to it. For example, a country that sacrifices its currency actually

    loses a stabilization device targeted to domestic shocks. But the country is also

    expected to gain credibility, and in so doing reduces undesired inflation (see Alesina& Barro, 2002). Moreover, in a correctly defined OCA, the forward (intra-regional

    currency) market premium will disappear, which in turn may raise the relative

    advantage of intra-regional trade against cross-regional trade in the region.2

    A number of studies have investigated the economic and political feasibility of

    forming an OCA in the region in the post crisis period (19992008).3 Some studies

    have concluded that the economic and political benefits of adopting a single currency

    are far greater than the potential costs that its member economies are likely to incur.

    There is no denying of the fact that the degree of economic and financial

    integration among Asian countries has increased considerably, especially in the post-

    crisis (19992010) period. Over time the response to global shocks and symmetry in

    economic activities has also increased in the region. The recent American sub-prime

    crisis (2008) has provided some further confirmation in this concern. Most of the

    Asian countries experienced spillover effect of the crisis, and as a result they faced

    similar challenges such as capital outflows, currency depreciation, plunge in stock

    prices, credit crunch, and a sharp fall in export demand. The debate over formation

    of currency union in the Asian region has intensified and has taken on a new

    dimension, especially in the wake of the European Union debt crisis (20092010).

    Now a group of researchers are of the opinion that the crisis of Europe (20092010) is

    mainly the undesirable outcome of poor economic policies and heterogeneity of the

    monetary union (see Eichengreen, 2010), and it seems that the crisis is sowing the

    seeds of collapse of the union (Arghyrou & Tsoukalas, 2010). On the other side, agroup of researchers (e.g. Dolls et al., 2010) argue that the monetary union has

    provided better mechanism and power to the European countries in handling the

    crisis through automatic stabilisers. In this situation, the debate of the OCA in Asia

    has taken a new turn, and it has become relevant and important to test the feasibility

    from a different perspective using the most recent data-set.

    Against this background, the present study aims to empirically assess the degree of

    regional integration and examine the suitability of an OCA in the ESEA region. We

    mainly focus on the period between post-Asian crises (1999) and the pre-American

    crisis (2008). Our analysis covers South Korea, Singapore, Malaysia, Indonesia,

    Thailand, the Philippines, China, Japan, and India.4

    Most of the previous studies

    210 C. Sharma & R. K. Mishra

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    4/25

    have followed any one empirical framework to test the feasibility. In the present study,

    we implement three important but alternative analysis techniques simultaneously to

    examine the feasibility of the OCA. Specifically, following Sato and Zhang (2006), we

    first adopt the cointegration technique to test whether there is any evidence of long-

    run co-movements of real output among the ESEA economies. If the real output of

    the sample countries is not cointegrated, it indicates that each countrys outputmoves randomly over a period of time and follows a different growth path. This

    scenario would indicate the existence of a high economic divergence among these

    economies. In the next stage, following Chow and Kims (2003), we estimate the

    output growth function subject to three different types of shocks. In other words, we

    attempt to decompose external shocks into three different levels, namely global

    shock, regional shock, and country-specific shock. The origin of these different

    shocks has significant and relevant policy implications, and this may indicate towards

    some degree of inter-linkage among the countries as well as the inter-relationship

    with the rest of the world. Further, to check the robustness of the results, we have also

    applied a modified version of Bayoumi and Eichengreens Indices. In the final stage,we apply Generalized Purchasing Power Parity (G-PPP), introduced by Enders and

    Hurn (1994), which is expected to provide further evidence for OCA in the region by

    analysing the behaviour of exchange rate.

    Rest of the study is organized as follows: Section 2 reviews the related literature

    whereas Section 3 contains discussion on data-related issues. Section 4 presents

    empirical models, methodologies and their estimation results. Section 5 provides

    conclusion of this study.

    2. Review of the Related Literature

    The theory of OCA asserts that some crucial conditions should be satisfied for the

    formation and success of a common currency in a region. These conditions include:

    factor mobility and symmetry of shocks across countries (Mundell, 1961), openness

    of economies and trade integration (McKinnon, 1963) and well-diversified econo-

    mies, and regional production pattern (Kenen, 1969). Therefore, from this viewpoint

    it could be argued that countries of ESEA are in position to satisfy at least some

    minimum standard criteria to form an OCA.5 Further, McKinnon (1963) emphasized

    on international openness of the country as an important criterion for the OCA.

    According to McKinnon, trade between two countries is an important channel of

    interdependence of economic activities through which economic shocks of one

    country may be transmitted to the others. Also, reduction in various transaction costsin the OCA region would further lead to more trade.6

    Given that numerous economic merits of the OCA are theoretically well established

    in the literature, recently, a number of studies have tested the empirical viability of

    forming an OCA for various subsets of countries of the ESEA region using different

    econometric methodologies. The broad picture which emerges from the available

    literature is not very encouraging for the formation of an OCA in the near future in

    the region. Nevertheless, the favourable findings of some studies have kept the debate

    on scope for monetary cooperation among Asian countries still alive. Earlier studies

    by Frankel (1991, 1993) and Frankel and Wei (1994) show that a yen block does not

    exist in the East Asian region. They conclude that even though Asia has shown bias

    Currency Area in East and South East Asia 211

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    5/25

    towards intra-regional trade, but the degree of this intra-regional bias has not

    increased in the recent past. Similarly, Park and Park (1990) rejected the empirical

    viability of OCA, and raised doubt over the formation of a yen block between Japan

    and other East Asian economies. Chow and Kim (2003) investigated the feasibility of

    a common currency peg in the East Asian region with the context of Western

    European countries. Their findings suggest that domestic outputs of East Asiancountries are strongly influenced by country-specific shocks whereas in the case of

    European countries regional shocks play a dominant role. Also, it appears that the

    East Asian economies are structurally different from each other and thus they are

    more likely to experience asymmetric shocks. Therefore, a common currency peg in

    East Asia may not be economically advantageous and sustainable. Following the

    same empirical methodology, Soo and Choong (2010) reached the conclusion that

    most of the Asian economies look highly segmented especially in the pre-crisis

    period. However, findings of the study suggest that the degree of segmentation

    among these economies has declined and the influence of Japanese economy on the

    performance of some Asian countries has increased in the recent past.On the other hand, some recent studies have reported encouraging evidence bygiving

    some support to the proposition that a common currency union is feasible in Asia. For

    example, Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1994) reached the conclusion that a subset of nine

    East Asian countries satisfies the necessary economic criteria for the formation of an

    OCA almost similar to Western Europe. Zhang et al. (2004) investigated the suitability

    of East Asian economies for potential monetary integration. They find that empirical

    results do not offer any strong support for forming an OCA in the entire East Asian

    region. However, some small sub regions have the required qualities for becoming

    potential candidates of the OCA. By using the cointegration and common cyclical

    feature analysis, Sato and Zhang (2006) investigated the feasibility of a monetary union

    in East Asia and found that some pair of countries share synchronous movement of real

    output in both short- as well as long-run. Therefore, these countries are good

    candidates for forming a monetary union because their short-run dynamics is

    correlated and they share long-run output co-movements. Shirono (2008) focus on

    trade-creating and welfare effects of various common currency arrangements in East

    Asia. Interestingly, the study finds that formation of a single currency area in the region

    will stimulate the scale of regional trade considerably and regional currency

    arrangements that include Japan will create substantial welfare gains for the member

    countries. In another study, Shirono (2009) assessed the role of Japan, along with China

    and the USA, in the East Asian currency regime by estimating trade-creating effects

    and accompanying welfare gains of different currency arrangements in the region.Findings of the study suggest that currency union with China will generate higher

    average welfare gains for the East Asian countries than any other arrangement with

    Japan and China. Further, the study shows that the welfare gains of currency union

    associated with Japan are much higher than that of USA. Banik et al. (2009) investigate

    the feasibility of an OCA for South Asian countries and find that a small cluster of

    countries, namely Bangladesh, India, and Pakistan, appear to be good candidates for

    forming an OCA. Recently, Lee and Azali (2010) assessed the dynamic relationship

    between trade, finance, specialization, and business cycle synchronization for East

    Asian economies and reached the conclusion that there is good scope for formation of a

    monetary union. Similarly, on the basis of results of G-PPP Choudhry (2005) reached

    212 C. Sharma & R. K. Mishra

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    6/25

    the conclusion that evidences are supportive of an OCA only in the post-Asian crisis

    period. More recently, Mishra and Sharma (2010) also find some favourable evidence

    for formation of an OCA in East Asia. Their findings suggest that still the degree of

    economic integration among the countries needs to be enhanced further for formation

    of a currency union in the region.

    3. Data

    To examine the long-run co-movements of real output of the sample countries, we use

    real GDP series as a proxy for real outputs. The data on all variables are of quarterly

    frequency, expressed in natural logarithms and seasonally adjusted using the Census

    X-12 method. Nine countries, namely the South Korea, Singapore, Malaysia,

    Indonesia, Thailand, the Philippines, China, Japan, and India, are included in this

    study for the empirical investigation. Output series of the USA is also used for the

    analysis purpose. The sample period spans from 1999Q1 to 2008Q4 for all economies.

    To avoid the turbulent Asian crisis period (19971998) and the sub-prime crisis of

    20082009 in the US economy and subsequent European Union debt crisis (2010

    2011), we did not consider the period before 1999 and after 2008 for the analysis.

    Further, to test the G-PPP, we utilize monthly data of nominal exchange rate (defined

    as market rate per US dollar) and price level represented by consumer price index

    (CPI). In this case, the sample period spans from 1999:01 to 2008:12. All series are

    seasonally unadjusted and expressed in logarithms before any econometric analysis.

    We consider USA as the base country to calculate the real exchange rate. All data

    series are collected from the International Financial Statistics (IFS) database

    provided by the International Monetary Fund.

    4. Empirical Results

    4.1. Testing Co-movements of Output: Bivariate Cointegration Test

    To investigate whether there exists a stable linear steady-state relationship between

    the real output of the sample countries, we conduct the cointegration test. Testing of

    cointegration is important as it will indicate whether the real output series share

    synchronous long-run movements. For testing cointegration, it is required to test the

    stationarity of variables. If all variables in the system are non-stationary at the level

    and stationary at their first difference, that is I(1), we can apply the Johansen

    maximum likelihood (ML) method (Johansen & Juselius, 1990; Johansen, 1991) to

    test whether these variables are cointegrated.We begin our analysis by providing the univariate properties of the variables of

    interest using the standard Augmented DickeyFuller (ADF) and the Phillips

    Perron (PP) unit root tests to establish the order of integration of all variables.

    Both the ADF and PP tests fail to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root for all

    variables at the levels. However, the null hypothesis is overwhelmingly rejected for all

    the series at first-differences. As all the variables are integrated of the same order, this

    allows us to conduct the JohansenJesulius cointegration test.7

    We next investigate the bivariate relations of real output co-movements between

    the ESEA economies. For this purpose, we conduct the Johansen cointegration test

    for 35 pairs of the economies and their results are reported in Table 1. It is clearly

    Currency Area in East and South East Asia 213

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    7/25

    Table 1. Co-movements of output: results of cointegration rank

    Trace test lmax Trace test lmax

    Country pair (country i&j) Deterministic components H0: r 00 H0: r51

    ChinSing No trend 19.61556** 19.46461** 0.150958 0.150958 ChinThai No trend 12.66725 12.32568 0.341573 0.341573ChinIndi No trend 19.39314** 19.33577** 0.057369** 0.057369*ChinIndon Trend 9.900251 7.283894 2.616357 2.616357ChinKorea No trend 12.05739 11.15827 0.89912 0.89912 Chin-Malay No trend 14.20491** 14.17597** 0.028937 0.028937 ChinPhilip No trend 38.39309** 38.38100** 0.012088 0.012088 IndiKorea No trend 10.07799 7.459153 3.618835 3.618835IndiMalay No trend 17.49231** 15.82437** 1.667937 1.667937 IndiPhilip No trend 35.26262** 33.05627** 2.206353 2.206353 IndiSing No trend 22.39943** 21.19035** 1.20908 1.20908 IndiThai No trend 11.42961 11.25822 0.171394 0.171394Indi-indon Trend 14.3445 13.3062 0.038296 0.038296IndonKorea No trend 22.33580** 4.423444** 17.91236** 4.423444*IndonMalay Trend 19.42353** 17.82656** 1.596977 1.596977 IndonPhilip No trend 33.96150** 32.61858** 1.34292 1.34292 IndonSing No trend 23.35268** 21.77221** 1.580476 1.580476 IndonThai Trend 29.40074** 29.30018** 0.100557 0.100557 Jap-Chin No-trend 21.4246** 0.392390** 2.492234 0.063481 JapIndi No trend 27.45547** 24.931221** 2.516939 2.514089 JapIndon No trend 22.62306** 19.98112** 2.641933 2.641933 JapKorea Trend 15.79471** 14.26460** 2.828426* 2.828426*

    JapMalay No trend 15.60576** 12.49700** 3.108751 3.108751 JapPhilip No trend 37.48481** 35.33011** 2.154704 2.154704 JapSing No trend 15.30830* 12.81346* 2.494838 2.494838 JapThai No trend 18.50924** 15.59674** 2.912503 2.912503 KoreaMalay No trend 13.72269** 11.153508** 5.569177** 5.569177*

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    8/25

    Table 1. (Continued)

    Trace test lmax Trace test lmax

    Country pair (country i&j) Deterministic components H0: r 00 H0: r51

    KoreaPhilip No trend 40.45201** 35.81763** 4.634388** 4.634388*KoreaSing Trend 7.987452 5.589537 2.397915 2.397915KoreaThai Trend 17.01554** 16.23392** 0.781615 0.781615 MalaySing No trend 17.19921** 14.94187** 2.257342 2.257342 MalayThai No trend 18.4608** 16.31003** 2.150771 2.150771 PhilipMalay Trend 36.98675** 35.46495** 1.521797 1.521797 PhilipSing No trend 39.52308** 18.27456** 37.69562 1.827456 PhilipThai No trend 31.78751** 31.76814** 0.019365 0.019365 Thai -Sing No trend 21.35249** 23.313827** 3.03866 3.313827

    Notes: (1) Asterisks (**) denote statistically significant at the 5% level.

    (2) Critical values are taken from Osterwald-Lenum (1992).

    (3) The following notations are applied: Jap, Japan; Indi, India; chin, China; Indon, Indonesia; Malay, Malaysia; Philip, Philippi

    South Korea.

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    9/25

    observable that the hypothesis of no cointegration is rejected by either the trace or

    maximum eigenvalue test at 5% level in 28 cases. Only in the case of seven country

    pairs, no evidence of cointegrating relationship is observed at conventional level of

    significance. Surprisingly, the output co-movements of China and India with other

    economies are not found to be very strong, as countries such as Indonesia, South

    Korea, and Thailand do not share a cointegrating relationship with both theeconomies. Nevertheless, both of the economies share a common trend with the rest

    of the sample countries including cointegrating relation between themselves.

    Furthermore, results also indicate that output of South Korea and Singapore does

    not share a similar movement. The last column of the table reports the estimated

    cointegrated coefficients, which suggest that most of the country pairs have

    significant impact on each other, and affect each other positively. Therefore, on the

    basis of these findings, we can argue that there is some evidence to conclude that

    the ESEA economies have long-run co-movements in their output, and therefore

    formation of an OCA in the region appears to be a possible economic event in the

    future.

    4.2. Analysis of the Symmetry of Response: Evidence from Impulse Response and

    Variance Decompositions

    After examining the bilateral cointegration relationship, it is now relevant to compare

    the response of economies to different types of shocks in terms of the magnitude and

    speed of adjustment. This can be done by analysing the impulse response functions

    (IRFs). The larger the size of the shock, more disruptive will be its effects on the

    economy. Similarly, if the adjustments after the disturbances are slow, larger will be

    the cost of maintaining a single currency. Therefore, we have applied the IRF to

    capture the response of different types of shocks for the analysis. In addition,the forecast error variance can be used to show the contribution of each shock to the

    movements in the output of countries. This is important because difference in the

    cause of variability in the countries could be an indicator of underlying difference in

    transmission mechanism and policy strategies of the countries in the region, which

    would be an obstacle to regional monetary integration. Keeping this issue in mind,

    we have also applied the variance decomposition (VD) analysis.

    Following Chow and Kim (2003) and Soo and Choong (2010), we estimate the

    output growth DyDt function subject to three different types of shocks, namelyglobal uW , regional uR , and domestic uD -specific:

    DyDt b1 b2LuW b3Lu

    R b4LuD (1)

    where bi L bi0 bi2 L bi3 L2 is a polynomial function of the lag

    operator, L. Generally, global shocks can potentially influence economies both

    inside and outside the regional boundary and regional shocks can affect economies

    within a certain region. For example, a shock in the yen-dollar exchange rate could

    synchronize and latter this could pass to other countries in the region (Kwan, 1994).

    On the other hand, country-specific shocks are generated in a country and can affect

    uniquely to that country only. Origin of these shocks could be from monetary or

    fiscal policy changes, demand or supply shocks on productivity, or terms of trade

    (Bayoumi & Eichengreen, 1993).

    216 C. Sharma & R. K. Mishra

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    10/25

    In this context, if it is observed that country-specific shocks are dominating in a

    country, and it is less correlated across the region, then losing the monetary

    independence for an OCA could be a costly affair for the country. At the same time,

    the occurrence of regional shocks or correlated local shocks may indicate for a

    similar monetary policy within the region therefore the OCA could be a feasible

    option in this scenario. In contrast, if it is detected that global shocks are dominatingand play a crucial role in determining the directions of movement of macro-economic

    factors of various countries in the region, then a more global arrangement might be

    more appropriate. Nevertheless, as long as shocks influence all economies in the

    similar pattern, a global rather than regional policy arrangement may be a more

    appropriate course of action in dealing with such shocks. Therefore, identification of

    different shocks could be crucial, as this may provide information regarding the inter-

    linkage among the countries.

    For this purpose, we move further to identify and analyse the nature and role of

    observed shocks in the countries. Results of our analysis can indicate for three

    exhaustive and exclusive outcomes. First, if global shocks are dominating in theregion, then we can conclude in favour of the formation of a Dollar bloc. Second, if

    the analysis observes that regional shocks are dominating in the region, then we can

    recommend forming a Yen bloc. Finally, the outcome of dominance of domestic

    shocks would compel us to recommend against any monetary arrangement among

    the countries.

    On the basis of these explanations, we apply the vector auto-regression (VAR)

    model to estimate the impact of these shocks. This framework generates the IRFs and

    VD, which helps in distinguishing the shocks on output (log of real GDP) of

    the sample countries. Given the size and impact of USA and Japanese economy on

    the sample countries, we consider the real GDP of the USA and Japan as proxiesfor the global shocks uW and regional shocks uR , respectively. Further, to test theimpact of regional shocks on the Japanese output, the Chinese GDP is used as a

    proxy, given the fact that China is the next most important country in this region.

    Figures 19 show the response of each of the nine countries real GDP growth over

    eight periods to innovations (shocks) in global and regional output growth. We use

    these results in recognizing the origin of shocks, which are observed by real output of

    the countries. The results can be understood in the VAR framework. Specifically, we

    are interested to know here that one standard deviation (SD) shock to the

    innovations in current and future values of endogenous variables (global, regional,

    and country-specific shocks) leads to what magnitude of change in output of thesample countries. The effect begins in t(quarter) 0 1, and it is observed until

    Figure 1. Response of China to Cholesky, One SD Innovations.

    Currency Area in East and South East Asia 217

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    11/25

    t(quarter) 0 8 in our analysis. Results of the analysis demonstrate that eight of the

    nine countries, namely China, Indonesia, Japan, South Korea, Malaysia, the

    Philippines, Singapore, and Thailand, have broadly symmetrical negative response.

    Among the sample countries, only India shows a positive response to both global and

    regional shocks. Response of the Chinese output growth is negative throughout the

    study period to both global as well as regional shocks. Response of the Indonesian

    output growth is slightly different, as it is sluggish in the initial period, however,

    intensified in the latter period (after five quarters). Further, it shows positive response

    to the regional shocks but negative response to global shocks. Response of South

    Korea is interesting, it is slow-moving in the initial quarters but negative in the

    medium period and stable in the long period to both types of external shocks. In the

    case of Malaysia, it has positive response to global shocks in initial periods, but after

    five quarters, it demonstrates steep negative response to both types of external

    shocks. The Philippiness output growth appears to be inversely correlated to the

    global as well as the regional shocks. Response of Singapores output is mixed

    towards global and regional shocks. Specifically, the response of both types of shockis estimated to be negative in initial quarters; however, it turns out to be positive after

    the third quarter. Thailands output growth shows a negative response throughout

    the observation period to the global as well as regional shocks. In the case of

    India the evidence is different. It has slow response in the initial quarters, however, it

    picks up in latter periods. Nevertheless, it consistently demonstrates positive response

    to regional as well as to global shocks. In the case of Japanese, response of global

    shocks is positive; however, regional shocks, proxied by Chinese shocks, are identified

    to be negative throughout the considered time horizon.

    Next, we discuss the results of orthogonalized forecast error VD, which is based on

    Choleski factorization with particular ordering, namely: global shock, regional

    Figure 2. Response of India to Cholesky, One SD Innovations.

    Figure 3. Response of Indonesia to Cholesky, One SD Innovations.

    218 C. Sharma & R. K. Mishra

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    12/25

    shock, and country-specific shock. The analysis is done up to eight-quarter horizon.

    The VDs are presented in Table 2. The results of the VD of global, regional, and

    country-specific shocks for eight-quarter ahead forecast errors are produced by their

    innovations. The table shows that, as expected, the variations in countries output in

    first two quarters are mainly because of country-specific shocks except in the cases ofIndia and South Korea, where it is mainly driven by global and regional shocks,

    respectively. In the latter quarters the impact of global and regional shocks has

    generally dominated across the countries. Only the case of Indonesia and Malaysia is

    identified to be different. In Indonesia the domestic effect is estimated to be above

    90% throughout the time horizon, and the impact of both regional and global shocks

    on the domestic output is found to be negligible. Similarly, in the case of Malaysia,

    domestic shocks are found to be most crucial as even in the longer period (eighth

    quarter) it has more than 50% impact. In the case of South Korea (56%), the

    Philippines (55%), Japan (47%), India (46%), and Singapore (44%), the regional

    effect is recognized to be most important in the long-term horizon. On the otherhand, Thailand (61%), China (59%), Singapore (41%), and India (37%) observe

    sizable impact from the global shocks in the long period.

    Overall, on the basis of these results, it can be inferred that the results do not offer

    a strong support of the proposition that Asian countries are economically integrated

    enough to form an OCA in the short-run. The main reason behind this inference is

    that these countries are strongly affected by their own country-specific shocks. The

    dominance of country-specific shocks may indicate towards the presence of different

    aggregate demand shock due to either monetary or fiscal policy changes or supply

    shocks on productivity or terms of trade (Bayoumi & Eichengreen, 1993).

    Figure 4. Response of South Korea to Cholesky, One SD Innovations.

    Figure 5. Response of Malaysia to Cholesky, One SD Innovations.

    Currency Area in East and South East Asia 219

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    13/25

    4.3. Robustness Check

    In order to test the feasibility of an OCA in the context of the European Union,

    Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1993, 1997) followed by Kim and Chow (2003) have

    introduced an index based on the degree of exchange rate variability, as measured bySD of the log of the bilateral exchange rate between a pair of countries. In this model,

    a high (low) correlation of aggregate supply shocks between two countries suggests

    that the economies are subject to symmetric (asymmetric) shocks and consequently

    likely (unlikely) candidates for an OCA. In the present study, we have computed SD

    of the log of the exchange rate and then constructed an index of their standard

    deviation (XSD).8 on the basis of XSD, we have constructed an index of rank (XSD

    Rank) of the sample countries. Further, the role of regional shocks as an important

    indicator of regional integration by measuring the extent of symmetric shocks, and

    thus suitability of countries in joining a currency area in the region, is well established

    in the literature. We consider Japan as the anchor and the prime source of regionalshock. With this viewpoint, we first construct an index based on results of VDs of the

    regional shock (RS Index). On the basis of RS Index, we rank (RS Rank) the sample

    countries. Table 3 reports computed values of indices for each country and their

    ranks. We have constructed both indices with India (panel A of the table) and without

    India (panel B of the table). In terms of exchange rate variability, Singapore is ranked

    1, as it has the lowest variability, while Indonesia has the largest variability in both

    panels. Focusing on the regional shocks in domestic output (RS Index), both panels

    suggest that South Korea has the largest value, while Indonesia has the lowest value.

    Next we estimate the Spearman rank correlations among the rank of indices and the

    values are reported at the bottom of Table 3. Confirming our previous results, the

    Figure 6. Response of the Philippines to Cholesky, One SD Innovations.

    Figure 7. Response of Singapore to Cholesky, One SD Innovations.

    220 C. Sharma & R. K. Mishra

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    14/25

    correlation coefficients appear to be negative, not sizable and statistically insignif-

    icant at the conventional level. Therefore, it seems that these economies are not very

    strong candidates for forming an OCA, at least in the present scenario. It is also

    noteworthy that inclusion or exclusion of India in the analysis does not alter these

    results considerably.

    4.4. Concept of G-PPP and OCA

    So far the analysis of output co-movement and their reaction to various shocks has

    produced mixed results. In this section, therefore, we move further to examine the

    issue in an alternative way by focusing on the movements of real exchange rates. To

    this end, we utilize the concept of G-PPP proposed by Enders and Hurn (1994),

    which is essentially an alternative way of evaluating exchange rate behaviour across

    countries. According to the G-PPP theory, even though bilateral real exchange rates

    are generally non-stationary, they might be cointegrated in the long-run, if the long-run fundamental macro-economic variables that determine real exchange rates are

    highly associated. If this is true in a suitably defined currency area, then the real

    exchange rates in the area may share common stochastic trends, and at least one

    linear combination of various bilateral real exchange rates may exist that is stationary

    (see Enders & Hurn, 1994). Now, in what follows, we discuss the G-PPP theory and

    the related empirical methodology in brief (see Enders & Hurn, 1994 and Ahn et al.,

    2006 for further details). Assume that a subset of m'1 countries in an n-country

    world constitute a currency area. Given that there are only m independent real

    Figure 8. Response of Thailand to Cholesky, One SD Innovations.

    Figure 9. Response of Japan to Cholesky, One SD Innovations.

    Currency Area in East and South East Asia 221

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    15/25

    Table 2. Results of forecast error VDs of domestic output

    Period SE Country-specific shock Regional shock Global shock

    China2 98.15782 0.042825 1.7993524 47.20221 7.233278 45.56451

    6 24.66158 10.43332 64.905108 27.77714 12.93339 59.28946

    India2 37.20035 42.50908 20.290574 24.93906 44.55575 30.505196 18.92287 46.22821 34.848928 16.40275 46.51138 37.08587

    Indonesia2 99.83353 0.030827 0.1356424 99.43193 0.364543 0.203525

    6 97.36585 2.268160 0.3659888 92.40364 4.709245 2.887116

    South Korea2 44.18149 54.92190 0.8966094 37.75420 61.18313 1.0626716 36.61644 60.98224 2.4013298 40.45731 56.83423 2.708456

    Malaysia2 88.15653 10.89798 0.9454874 75.13501 19.36502 5.499974

    6 64.60440 21.80383 13.591788 54.73248 21.18617 24.08135

    The Philippines2 96.72099 2.423169 0.8558444 68.17624 29.42664 2.3971216 40.27880 49.29285 10.428368 27.51751 55.92816 16.55433

    Singapore2 63.55096 26.54588 9.9031594 32.25324 36.84003 30.906746 19.08810 42.62098 38.290928 14.79469 44.11359 41.09171

    Thailand2 57.08141 18.69839 24.220194 18.07195 35.62152 46.306546 8.039384 33.88931 58.071318 4.875078 33.23685 61.88807

    Japan2 64.42786 25.32312 10.249014 38.92961 38.58159 22.488796 31.75629 44.77222 23.47149

    8 29.09604 47.68553 23.21844

    222 C. Sharma & R. K. Mishra

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    16/25

    Table 3. Results of Bayoumi and Eichengreens Indices

    XSD XSD Rank RS Index RS Rank XSD XSD R

    Panel A

    China 0.023752 3 7.67 8 0.023752 3 India 0.025722 5 44.95 2Indonesia 0.053678 8 1.94 9 0.053678 7 Japan 0.030296 6 39.0875 3 0.030296 5

    South Korea 0.035135 7 58.477 1 0.035135 6 The Philippines 0.059998 9 34.26325 5 0.059998 8 Malaysia 0.022505 2 18.3125 7 0.022505 2 Singapore 0.016597 1 37.5275 4 0.016597 1 Thailand 0.023858 4 30.355 6 0.023858 4

    Spearman coefficients of rank correlationXSD Rank 1.000 (0.116 (0.765) 1.00RS Rank 1.000

    Note: P-value in parentheses.

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    17/25

    exchange rates within the subset of m'1 countries, we can write the reduced form

    solution for the m independent real exchange rates as follows:

    Qt

    AXt

    a11 a12 . . . a1m1. . . . . . . . . . . .

    am1 am2. . .

    amm1

    2

    664

    3

    775

    x1tx2t

    ..

    .

    xm1t

    2

    6664

    3

    7775 (2)

    where Qt is the m )1 vector of real exchange rates, A is m )(m' 1) parameter matrix

    and Xt is the (m' 1) )1 vector of real fundamental variables such as output levels.

    As a matter of fact, the real exchange rate will be stationary and the empirical validity

    of PP will be confirmed, if all the elements of real fundamentals or Xt are stationary.

    Given the fact that the elements of Xt represent real shocks, each of the element is

    assumed to be non-stationary. Now, using the common trend representation

    developed by Stock and Watson (1988), we can express Xt as follows:

    Xt W/t; (3)

    where C is the (m' 1) )(m'1) matrix of the parameters and ft is the (m' 1) )1

    vectors of the non-stationary stochastic trends. Thus, the behaviour of the real

    exchange rates Qt is determined using Equations (2) and (3) as follows:

    Qt AW/t (4)

    The behaviour of real macro-economic shocks and therefore that of real exchange

    rates depend on the rank of the matrix C. As long as the rank (C)Bm, it is always

    possible to pre-multiply Qt by m)m matrix b to obtain at least one cointegrating

    vector of the real exchange rates as follows:

    bAW 0: (5)

    Equations (3) and (4) imply bQt00. If the rank (C) 0 1, all the elements of Xt share

    a single common trend and hence there exist m (1 linear combinations of the real

    exchange rates, which are stationary. Further, bQt00 can be rewritten as follows:

    b2q12t b3q13t b4q14t . . . bm1q1m1t 0: (6)

    where qt is the real exchange rate defined as qt et pt pt (where et is the natural

    logarithms of the national currency price of foreign currency, pt and pt are the naturallogarithms of the foreign domestic price levels, respectively). Equation (6) shows the

    long-run equilibrium relationship between the m bilateral real exchange rates within

    the group ofm'1 countries. In the next step, we apply the multivariate cointegration

    technique to test and estimate the cointegrating relations.

    Now we advance our analysis further to test the potential of an OCA in the ESEA

    region by examining the empirical validity of G-PPP. As a matter of fact, for the G-

    PPP to hold all the bilateral real exchange rates must be non-stationary individually

    and there should be at least one linear combination of all non-stationary real

    exchange rate which is stationary, that is I(0). As a prerequisite to cointegration

    analysis, we first test the order of integration of all nine real exchange rates. For this

    224 C. Sharma & R. K. Mishra

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    18/25

    purpose, we conduct the ADF and PP unit root tests and the results are reported in

    Table 4 which shows that all the real exchange rates are integrated of order one.

    After establishing that all variables are I(1), in order to assess whether the sample

    ESEA countries constitute an OCA using the concept of G-PPP, we perform the

    Johansen multivariate cointegration test. We have examined the cointegration test for

    all the sample countries with and without India and results are reported in panels Aand B of Table 5. At the group level, the results of cointegration test confirm the

    presence of cointegrating relationship among the real exchange rate of the countries,

    as the results reveal that the null hypothesis of no cointegration is strongly rejected in

    favour of significant cointegrating relation among Asian real exchange rates. Trace

    statistics confirm the presence of 7 and 4 cointegrating vectors for full sample and the

    sample excluding India, respectively. This is a supportive evidence for the validity of

    G-PPP and OCA in the region. The presence of cointegration among real exchange

    rates of the ESEA countries implies that macro-economic fundamentals that drive

    real exchange rates are sufficiently interrelated, and hence bilateral real exchange

    rates of these countries share common stochastic trends in the long-run.Table 6 presents the result of normalized coefficients (panel A) and speed of

    adjustment parameters (panel B). We use Chinese currency (Renminbi) to obtain the

    normalized equations in the model. It is, however, noteworthy that there is no specific

    reason for the choice of Renminbi to create the normalized equations of real

    exchange rates, and any bilateral real exchange rate could have been utilized for the

    purpose. In our case the normalized vectors provide information on the interrelation

    among real exchange rates included in the study. These normalized coefficients can be

    interpreted as long-run elasticities between the real exchange rates. There seems to be

    some asymmetries in exchange rate adjustment process in response to any

    disequilibrium in the system. For full sample countries (row 1), while consideringthe US dollar-based real exchange rates a 1% rise in the Renminbi (real depreciation)

    leads to a real depreciation of around 4% in the Indian Rupees, 3% in Indonesian

    Rupiah, 1% in Korean Won, 14% in Singapore dollar, and 1.3% in Thai Bhat.

    Japanese Yen, Malaysian Ringgit, and the Philippines Peso have opposite movement,

    Table 4. Results of unit root test

    US dollar-based real exchange rates

    Countries ADF (Level) PP (Level) ADF (1st Diff.) PP (1st Diff.)

    China 0.008020 3.833434 (3.252968t' (5.684161t*India (2.610610 (2.366308 (8.207679* (8.143852*Indonesia (2.793979 (2.730168 (9.307610* (13.98435*Japan (1.327378 (1.327378 (10.03211* (10.03031*Malaysia 0.325310 (0.360682 (4.650030* (7.439881*The Philippines (0.750142 (0.881662 (10.01815* (10.01150*Singapore (1.200614 (1.061091 (4.512639* (10.85103*South Korea (1.450274 (1.474180 (4.194101* (8.799987*Thailand (1.594813 (1.624233 (7.333349* (10.72266*

    Notes: (1) Asterisks (*) denote rejection of the null hypothesis at 5% significance level.

    (2) For the ADF and PP the null hypotheses are series contain unit root.

    (3) The optimal lag of respective model is determined based on modified SBC.

    (4) t donates inclusion of trend.

    Currency Area in East and South East Asia 225

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    19/25

    which implies depreciation (appreciation) in Renminbi lead to appreciation

    (depreciation) in these currencies. It is noteworthy that results for other exchange

    rate do not change considerably when we exclude Indian exchange rate from the

    analysis, which reflects neutrality of India in the framework.

    Now we shift our attention on the results of speed of adjustment (panel B, Table 6).

    We utilize this result to explain how quickly a change in the real exchange rates in the

    system is inclined to correct itself in the VAR framework. For the US-based real

    exchange rate system, the largest coefficients are found in the case of Korea and the

    Philippines. The estimated coefficients for Korea ( (0.143) and the Philippines

    ( (0.093) imply that US dollar-based real exchange rate adjusts at the rate of 14.3%and 9.2% per month towards the long-run equilibrium (see row 3, Table 6). The

    adjustment coefficients in the case of Indian Rupees, Singapore Dollar, and Thai

    Bhat are moderate as they vary from 1% to 5%, whereas adjustment movement in

    Renminbi and Ringgit is estimated to be very small (below 1%). We also report

    results of speed of adjustment for the sample excluding India. The exclusion has

    affected the speed of adjustment of most of the currencies, nevertheless, their signs

    remain unaffected (see row 4, Table 6). On the basis of these results, we can conclude

    that the speed of adjustment is relatively high. However, some of the adjustment

    coefficients are small, which indicate that these currencies are weakly exogenous in

    the system. To some extent our results are in agreement with the results reported byChoudhry (2005) and Wilson and Choy (2007).

    Now we focus on two major emerging economies in the region China and India,

    and make an attempt to examine their suitability to become members in the possible

    OCA in the ESEA. For this purpose, we test the effect of other countries real

    exchange rate on the movement of Renminbi/US dollar and Rupees/US dollar real

    exchange rate in the cointegration framework. For this purpose, we utilize the fully

    modified OLS (FMOLS) estimator of Phillips and Hansen (1990). The technique is

    appropriate in the present case as it eliminates the problems caused by the long-run

    correlation between the cointegrating equation and stochastic regressor innovations,

    which is likely the case here. The FMOLS estimates are asymptotically unbiased and

    Table 5. Test of G-PPP: results of cointegration rank

    Eigenvalue Trace stat. Eigenvalue Trace stat.

    Rank All sample countries (Panel A)All sample countries excluding

    India (Panel B)

    r 00 0.495810 316.4463** 0.439109 231.7385**r51 0.410439 238.3788** 0.360521 165.8203**r52 0.381687 178.1437** 0.287150 114.8508**r53 0.273358 123.3370** 0.224714 76.26354**r54 0.228662 86.93440** 0.151357 47.24789r55 0.175822 57.33681** 0.117148 28.53864r56 0.139892 35.29280** 0.088564 14.33443r57 0.091288 18.11325 0.032468 3.762756r58 0.061208 7.200388

    Notes: (1) Asterisks (**) denote statistically significant at the 5% level.

    (2) Critical values are taken from Osterwald-Lenum (1992).

    226 C. Sharma & R. K. Mishra

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    20/25

    Table 6. Test of G-PPP: results of normalized equations and speed of adjustmen

    China Indonesia Korea MalaysiaThe

    Philippines Singapor

    Normalized coefficients (A)All sample

    countries (1)1 2.8394

    (0.446)1.0301

    (0.518)(6.3869

    (1.548)(8.1868

    (0.997)14.20126(2.66796

    All sample countriesexcluding India (2)

    1 3.259031(0.63932)

    2.735173(0.73620)

    (4.360977(1.75860)

    (8.614644(1.29675)

    14.40280(3.43588

    Speed of adjustment parameters (B)All sample

    countries (3)0.000564

    (0.01115)(0.014747

    (0.01447)(0.143135

    (0.03275)(0.001630

    (0.01886)(0.092515

    (0.01643)0.00231

    (0.01104All sample countries

    excluding India (4)(0.008

    (0.00813)(0.11731

    (0.02375)(0.06444

    (0.01237)(0.00044

    (0.00816)(0.02407

    (0.01171)(0.02325

    (0.00697

    Note: Standard errors are in parentheses.

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    21/25

    has fully efficient mixture of normal asymptotics allowing for standard Wald tests

    using asymptotic x2 statistical inference.

    Results of the estimation are reported in Table 7. Column 1 reports results

    regarding India, which suggests that the real exchange rates of China, Indonesia,

    Japan, and the Philippines have significant impact on the Indian Rupee. However, the

    impacts of the first three countries exchange rate are observed to be negative, whichindicate for their inverse relationship with India. Only the Peso and Ringgit have

    positive and significant impact on the movement of Indian Rupees. Therefore, the

    case of India as a member of possible OCA in the ESEA region appears to be

    somewhat weak on empirical grounds. Column 2 of the table reports results of China,

    which suggest that except Thailand, all other sample countries real exchange rate

    have significant impact on Chinas exchange rate movement. However, only

    Singapore and the Philippines currency have positive impact on the Renminbi.

    Therefore, we can conclude that results of the FMOLS analysis indicate that both

    China and India are not very likely candidates for the possible OCA in the region.

    5. Conclusion

    The present article empirically assesses the level of regional integration and suitability

    of a monetary union in the ESEA region. For this purpose, we performed three

    alternative analyses to provide empirical evidence for an OCA. Estimation results of

    the bivariate relations of real output co-movements between the Asian economies

    suggest that out of 35 pairs of the sample economies the hypothesis of no

    cointegration is rejected for 28 cases, and only 7 country pairs do not show any

    cointegration relationship. Furthermore, the estimated cointegration coefficients

    suggest that most of the pairs have significant impact on each other, and therefore

    affect each other positively. On the basis of these results, it appears that the realoutput of these Asian countries move together in the long-run which in turn provides

    some support for the feasibility of monetary union in the region. Subsequently, to

    analyse the issue in more detail, we focus on the impact of three different shocks,

    namely global, regional and country-specific, on real output of the countries. To this

    end we employ techniques of impulse response and VD in the VAR framework.

    Table 7. Determinants of India and Chinas real exchange rate: results of FMOLS regression

    Variable India (1) China (2)

    Constant 1.498443** (0.451162) 13.66282 (1.513921)China (0.069086** (0.027344)India (1.880656** (0.762671)Indonesia (0.2265** (0.068643) (1.767560** (0.287743)Japan (0.0002** (0.096359) (1.316032** (0.415085)Korea 0.059222 (0.066442) (1.073086** (0.294884)Malaysia 0.157144 (0.205031) (2.914759** (0.877313)The Philippines 0.324965** (0.135986) 3.151909** (0.593309)Singapore 0.039597 (0.317782) 3.197531** (1.450594)Thailand 0.230701* (0.176189) (0.180981 (0.880054)

    Notes: (1) Standard error is in parenthesis.

    (2) Asterisks (**) and (*) denote statistically significant at the 5% and 10% level.

    (3) R2

    00.972386.

    228 C. Sharma & R. K. Mishra

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    22/25

    Results of the analysis reveal that regional shocks do not have dominant roles in the

    sample countries, which is an indication of unfavourable condition to form an OCA

    in the region. These results are further confirmed by the outcome of computation of

    the modified Bayoumi and Eichengreens Indices. Nevertheless, results based on G-

    PPP are found to be somewhat supportive for the validity of G-PPP and OCA in the

    region. The existence of cointegration among real exchange rates of ESEA countriesimplies that macro-economic fundamentals that drive real exchange rates are

    sufficiently interrelated, and therefore, bilateral real exchange rates of these countries

    share common stochastic trends in the long-run. Finally, to investigate the

    candidature of India and China in the proposed OCA, we have tested the effect of

    other real exchange rates on the movement of both countries real exchange rate using

    FMOLS estimator. Results of the analysis indicate that there is no strong evidence to

    support the view that both India and China are likely candidates of the monetary

    union in the ESEA region.

    Overall results suggest that the degree of economic integration has increased

    among the ESEA countries in the post-Asian crisis period. However, considering themixed results of this study and the recent European experience, it appears that the

    right time for the OCA has not come yet. And a still higher degree of economic

    integration is required to achieve to build a sound economic platform for the OCA.

    Thus, in the presence of a poor level of integration, presently these countries can

    pursue only a limited monetary cooperation. In addition, for structural convergence,

    which is extremely critical for the OCA, these countries can initiate further reforms in

    important areas, such as industry, financial sector development, capital account

    openness, and institutional and regulation. These measures may bring them a little

    closer in near future than now. Our results are somewhat not very favourable for

    China and India in the analysis. Perhaps the de facto exchange rate policy of China isthe reason behind this scenario, and it is becoming one of the biggest hurdles in the

    process of integration in the region. Therefore, for a coordinated process to begin in

    the region, China needs to increase its exchange rate flexibility, and accepts the

    market-driven appreciation of its currency and abandon its existing stabilization

    policy. On the other hand, the policy suggestion for India is straightforward. If it is

    looking forward to be a possible candidate of the OCA, then it should consider

    integrating itself more intensely with other economies in the region in the near future.

    In this concern, the central bank of the country needs to abandon some its excess risk

    averse strategies and initiate long waiting reforms in capital account convertibility

    and financial market.

    Acknowledgements

    We thank two anonymous referees of this journal for their useful comments and helpful suggestions on the

    previous version of this article. Any errors or omission are solely ours.

    Notes1 OCA and monetary union is used interchangeably in this study.2 It is also argued that with greater regional monetary and exchange rate stability, the region may become

    more attractive for foreign investment (Benassy-Quere, 1999). However, the formation of OCA would

    lead to the loss of monetary autonomy. This will restrict countries to follow export-led catch-up strategy,

    which worked effectively before the 1990s (see Fabella, 2000). Another problem is the great diversity (in

    Currency Area in East and South East Asia 229

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    23/25

    terms of culture and religion, etc.) among countries in the region which could potentially create some

    serious problems in the formation of the OCA (see Kawai & Takagi, 2000). The historical facts also

    suggest that the pattern of use of stabilization policies in the region varies significantly.3 See, for example, Park and Park (1990), Frankel (1991, 1993), Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1994), Taguchi

    (1994), Kwan (1998), Chow and Kim (2003) and Shirono (2007), just to name a few in the long list of

    recent studies.4

    In the last decade ASEAN countries have increased their trade and financial relationship with China,Japan, and India. Many agreements have been signed between these economies in direction of free trade

    zone and monetary cooperation, for instance, ASEAN-China free trade zone, Tokyo Declaration,

    ASEAN-India Trade in Goods Agreement (TIG) and other AIFTA-related Agreements.5 Further, in a relatively narrow sense some other important conditions for the formation of an OCA are

    (1) a large market size, (2) high degree of openness in trade, (3) high degree of intra-regional economic

    interdependence, (4) symmetry between shocks across countries, and (5) less dependence on exchange

    rate as an instrument for correcting macro-economic imbalances (Kwan, 1998). Further, some authors

    have also argued for a supra-national government body able to conduct interregional transfers (see De

    Grauwe, 1997).6 Although the idea is theoretically appealing, empirical literature on trade and international finance has

    not reached a consensus as to whether a large degree of trade relationship between countries will result in

    correlated business cycles (see Hallett & Richter, 2006). In this regard, evidence presented by Kose et al.(2003) reveals that international trade relationship does not necessarily lead to the synchronization of

    business cycles.7 To conserve space, we do not report results of unit root test here but would be made available upon

    request.8 It is noteworthy that Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1993, 1997) have consider four factors the SD of

    relative output growths, the dissimilarity of the composition of exports, the extent of bilateral trade, and

    the average size of the economy for constructing the index of exchange rate variation. We have broadly

    followed Kim and Chow (2003) and have taken the variation of exchange rates.

    References

    Ahn, C., Kim, H. B. and Chang, D. (2006) Is East Asia fit for an optimum currency area? An assessment ofthe economic feasibility of a higher degree of monetary cooperation in East Asia, The Developing

    Economies, XLIV-3, pp. 288305.

    Alesina, A. and Barro, R. J. (2002) Currency unions, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(2), pp.

    409436.

    Arghyrou, M. and Tsoukalas, J. (2010) The escalating Greek debt crisis: What has been happening and

    where is it going? EconoMonitors: Europe EconoMonitor, May 6, 2010.

    Banik, N., Biswas, B. and Criddle, K. R. (2009) Optimum currency area in South Asia: A state space

    approach, International Review of Economics and Finance, 18, pp. 502510.

    Bayoumi, T. and Eichengreen, B. J. (1993) Shocking aspects of European Monetary Unification, in:

    F. Giavazzi and F. Torres (Eds.) Adjustment and Growth in the European Monetary Union, pp. 193229

    (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    Bayoumi, T. and Eichengreen, B. (1994) One money or many? Analyzing the prospects for monetary

    unification in various parts of the world, Princeton Studies in International Finance, 76, pp. 154.

    Bayoumi, T. and Eichengreen, B. (1997) Ever closer to heaven? An optimum-currency Area index for

    European countries, European Economic Review, 41(35), pp. 761770.

    Benassy-Quere, A. (1999) Optimal pegs for east Asian currencies, Journal of the Japanese and International

    Economies, 13, pp. 4460.

    Choudhry, T. (2005) Asian currency crisis and the generalized PPP: Evidence from the Far East, Asian

    Economic Journal, 19(2), pp. 137157.

    Chow, H. K. and Kim, Y. (2003) A common currency peg in East Asia? Perspectives from Western Europe,

    Journal of Macroeconomics, 25, pp. 331350.

    De Grauwe, P. (1997) The Economics of Monetary Integration, 3rd edn (London: Oxford University Press).

    Dolls, M., Fuest, C. and Peichl, A. (2010) Automatic stabilisers and economic crisis: US vs Europe,

    EUROMOD working papers EM2/10 EUROMOD at the Institute for Social and Economic

    Research, University of Essex, Essex.

    230 C. Sharma & R. K. Mishra

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    24/25

    Eichengreen, B. (2010) Irelands rescue package: Disaster for Ireland, bad omen for the Eurozone,

    EconoMonitors: Europe EconoMonitor, Dec 6, 2010.

    Enders, W. and Hurn, S. (1994) Theory and tests of generalized purchasing-power parity. Common trends

    and real exchange rates in the Pacific Rim, Review of International Economics, 2, pp. 179190.

    Fabella, R. (2000) The texture of competition in the first decade of the new century, in: D. Canlas and

    S. Fujisaki (Eds.) The Philippine Economy: Alternatives for the 21st Center, chapter 1, pp. 429

    (Tokyo: Institute of Developing Economics/Japan External Trade Organization).Frankel, J. A. (1991) Is a yen bloc forming in Pacific Asia? in: R. OBrien (Ed.) Finance and the

    International Economy: 5, The AMEX Bank Review Price Essays, pp. 227270 (London: Oxford

    University Press).

    Frankel, J. A. (1993) Is Japan creating a yen bloc in East Asia and the Pacific? in: J. Frankel and

    M. Kahler (Eds.) Regionalism and Rivalry: Japan and the US in Pacific Asia , pp. 5385 (Chicago:

    University of Chicago Press).

    Frankel, J. A. and Wei, S. J. (1994) Yen bloc or dollar bloc? Exchange rate policies of the East Asian

    economies, NBER chapters, in: Macroeconomic Linkage: Savings, Exchange Rates, and Capital Flows,

    NBER-EASE Volume 3, pp. 295333 (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    Hallett, A. and Richter, C. (2006) Measuring the degree of convergence among European business cycles,

    Computational Economics, 27(2), pp. 229259.

    Johansen, S. (1991) Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in Gaussian VectorAutoregressive Models, Econometrica, 59(6), pp. 15511581.

    Johansen, S. and Juselius, K. (1990) Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on cointegration with

    application to the demand for money, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 52, pp. 169210.

    Kawai, M. and Takagi, S. (2000) Proposed strategy for a regional exchange rate arrangement in post-crisis

    East Asia. World Bank working paper international economics: Trade, capital flows, World Bank,

    Washington, DC.

    Kenen, P. (1969) The theory of optimum currency areas: An eclectic view, in: R. Mundell and A. Swoboda

    (Eds.) Monetary Problems of the International Economy, pp. 4160 (Chicago: University of Chicago

    Press).

    Kim, Y. and Chow, H. K. (2003) Optimum currency area in Europe: An alternative assessment, Economics

    Letters, 81, pp. 297304.

    Kose, M. A., Prasad, E. and Terrones, M. (2003) Volatility and comovement in a globalized world

    economy: An empirical exploration. IMF Working Papers 03/246, International Monetary Fund,

    Washington, DC.

    Kwan, C. H. (1994) Economic Interdependence in the Asian Pacific Region Towards a Yen Bloc (London

    and New York: Routledge).

    Kwan, C. H. (1998) The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas and the Possibility of Forming a Yen Bloc in

    Asia (Mimeo: Nomura Research Institute).

    Lee, G. H. Y. and Azali, M. (2010) The endogeneity of the Optimum Currency Area criteria in East Asia,

    Economic Modelling, 27, pp. 165170.

    McKinnon, R. I. (1963) Optimal currency areas, American Economic Review, 53, pp. 125.

    McKinnon, R. I. (2000) The East Asian dollar standard, life after death? Economic Notes, 29(1), pp.

    3182.

    Mishra, R. K. and Sharma, C. (2010) Real exchange rate behavior and optimum currency area in East

    Asia: Evidence from Generalized Purchasing Power Parity, International Review of Financial Analysis,19(3), pp. 205213.

    Mundell, R. (1961) A theory of optimum currency areas, American Economic Review, 51, pp. 657665.

    Mundell, R. (2003) Prospects for an Asian currency area, Journal of Asian Economics, 14, pp. 110.

    Osterwald-Lenum, M. (1992) A note with quantiles of the asymptotic distribution of the

    maximum likelihood cointegration rank test statistics, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics,

    54, pp. 461471.

    Park, Y. C. and Park, W. A. (1990) Exchange rate policy for the East Asian NICs, KDI Working Paper No.

    9010, Korea Development Institute, Seoul.

    Phillips, P. C. B. and Hansen, B. E. (1990) Statistical inference in instrumental variables regression with

    I(1) processes, Review of Economics Studies, 57, pp. 99125.

    Sato, K. and Zhang, Z. (2006) Real output co-movements in East Asia: Any evidence for a monetary

    union? The World Economy, 29(12), pp. 16711689.

    Currency Area in East and South East Asia 231

  • 7/27/2019 south east currency union.pdf

    25/25

    Shirono, K. (2007) Real effects of common currencies in East Asia, IMF Working Paper No. WP/07/166,

    International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    Shirono, K. (2008) Real effects of common currencies in East Asia, Journal of Asian Economics, 19(3),

    pp. 199212.

    Shirono, K. (2009) Yen bloc or Yuan bloc: An analysis of currency arrangements in East Asia,

    IMF Working Papers No. 09/3, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    Soo, S. C. and Choong, C. K. (2010) An emergence of a common currency area in the selected East Asianeconomies: A revisit, The Singapore Economic Review, 55(2), pp. 353376.

    Stock, James H. and Watson, Mark W. (1988) Testing for common trends, Journal of the American

    Statistical Association, 83(404), pp. 10971107.

    Taguchi, H. (1994) On the internationalization of the Japanese yen, in: T. Ito and A. O. Krueger (Eds.)

    Macroeconomic Linkage, pp. 335355 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    Williamson, J. (1998) The case for a common basket peg for East Asian currencies, in: S. Collignon,

    J. Pisani-Ferry and Y. C. Park (Eds.) Exchange rate policies in emerging Asian countries, pp. 327342

    (London: Routledge).

    Wilson, P. and Choy, K. M. (2007) Prospects for enhanced exchange rate cooperation in East Asia:

    Some preliminary findings from generalized PPP theory, Applied Economics, 39(8), pp. 981995.

    Zhang, Z., Sato, K. and McAleer, M. (2004) Is a monetary union feasible for East Asia? Applied

    Economics, 36, pp. 10311043.

    232 C. Sharma & R. K. Mishra