smith ostrander pope june 2011 - brown university · 2011-06-03 · ! 4!...

28
Senate Parties and Procedural Motions Steven S. Smith, Ian Ostrander, and Christopher Pope Washington University Prepared for the Congress and History Conference, Brown University, June 910, 2011.

Upload: others

Post on 08-Apr-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

                       

Senate  Parties  and  Procedural  Motions    

Steven  S.  Smith,  Ian  Ostrander,  and  Christopher  Pope  Washington  University  

                                                   

Prepared  for  the  Congress  and  History  Conference,  Brown  University,  June  9-­‐10,  2011.            

Page 2: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  1  

 

Senate  Parties  and  Procedural  Motions    

Steven  S.  Smith,  Ian  Ostrander,  and  Christopher  Pope  Washington  University  

      Affected  by  the  theoretical  treatment  of  parties  in  the  U.S.  House  of  Representatives,  legislative  scholars  appear  to  be  puzzled  by  the  Senate.    For  the  House,  there  has  been  ready  acceptance  of  two  basic  concepts—the  metaphor  of  House  parties  as  cartels  and  the  conditional  influence  of  parties.    As  cartels,  House  parties  seek  to  control  those  features  of  the  institution  that  affect  their  collective  goals  (Cox  and  McCubbins  2002,  2005,  2007).    For  the  most  part,  this  means  the  assignment  of  special  parliamentary  rights  to  certain  legislators  that  give  the  majority  party  additional  influence  over  what  is  placed  on  the  agenda.    Variation  in  majority  party  influence,  at  least  with  respect  positive  influence,  has  led  scholars  to  observe  the  importance  of  the  distribution  of  policy  preferences  within  the  parties  for  the  role  played  by  their  leaders  (Rohde  1991,  Sinclair  1983,  Smith  and  Deering  1984).        

For  the  Senate,  where  the  majority  party  cannot  readily  manipulate  the  rules  and  a  large  minority  can  block  legislation,  the  extension  of  the  cartel  and  conditional  party  government  has  not  been  easy.    The  application  of  House-­‐based  theory  to  the  Senate  has  been  questioned  (Gamm  and  Smith  2001),  but  several  scholars  have  argued  that  the  Senate  majority  party  has  a  set  of  procedural  advantages  that  are  functionally  similar  to  the  negative  agenda  control  enjoyed  by  the  House  party  through  the  speakership,  Committee  on  Rules,  and  special  rules  (Carson,  Madonna,  and  Owens  2011,  King,  Orlando,  and  Rohde  2010,  Marshall,  Prins,  and  Rohde  1999,  Monroe  and  Den  Hartog  2008).    The  focus  of  this  work  is  the  process  of  amending  legislation  on  the  floor,  where  the  Senate  majority  leader  has  the  right  of  first  recognition  and  the  option  to  dispose  of  amendments  through  a  nondebatable  motion  to  table  or  point  of  order.    With  these  tools,  Senate  majority  party  leaders  act  like  their  House  counterparts,  exercise  additional  influence  over  outcomes,  and  reflect  the  cartel  nature  of  the  parties  that  elect  them  to  office.  

 We  ask:    Does  the  motion  to  table  yield  negative  agenda  control?    Do  the  

micro-­‐foundations  of  the  existing  accounts,  which  emphasize  the  motion  to  table  is  a  procedural  motion  that  gives  senators  greater  freedom  from  constituency  pressure,  fit  what  we  know  about  politics  in  practice?    Does  the  motion  to  table  yield  special  party  influence  over  senators’  votes?    Has  the  motion  to  table  been  a  regular  component  of  the  procedural  toolkit  of  Senate  majority  parties?    Is  there  support  for  an  alternative  account  of  the  frequency  of  motions  to  table  amendments?  

 Our  answers  to  these  questions  (not  much,  not  often,  no,  no,  and  yes)  are  

considerably  different  than  the  arguments  of  recent  work  on  Senate  agenda  control.  

Page 3: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  2  

In  contrast  to  the  studies  of  party  effects  in  voting  that  are  limited  motions  to  table,  the  answers  are  informed  by  a  comparison  of  voting  across  types  of  votes.    The  perspective  allows  us  to  evaluate  the  distinctiveness  of  procedural  voting  in  the  Senate,  an  essential  feature  of  recent  arguments  about  the  motion  to  table.    More  important,  in  contrast  to  the  somewhat  timeless  nature  of  most  of  the  recent  analysis,  the  answers  are  informed  by  a  longer  historical  view  of  Senate  practice.    This  perspective  enriches  our  view  of  the  forces  that  motivate  procedural  innovations  on  the  part  of  majority  party  leaders.      

    We  conclude  that  the  Senate  majority  party  is  a  far  weaker  cartel  than  its  House  counterpart.    The  use  of  motions  to  table  amendments  demonstrates  this  weakness  as  reliance  on  them  represents  the  lack  of  viable  and  more  effective  alternatives.    Motions  to  table  are  not  comparable  to  House  special  rules  in  either  strength  or  utility.    We  find  that  senators  are  not  liberated  of  political  pressure  by  using  motions  to  table.    Motions  to  table  yield  little  special  party  influence  over  amendments  and  have  been  a  staple  of  floor  action  only  since  the  1970s.        

Efficiency,  not  picking  up  pivotal  votes,  motivates  most  use  of  motions  to  proceed.    Efficiency,  of  course,  is  a  serious  partisan  concern  for  leaders  charged  with  managing  a  large  legislative  agenda.    Historically,  the  burden  of  more  intense  amending  activity  and  obstructionism  since  the  late  1960s  motivated  majority  leaders  with  limited  parliamentary  tools  to  make  a  variety  of  tactical  adjustments.    Motions  to  table  are  among  those  adjustments.      

Theories  of  Parties,  Institutional  Context,  and  the  Senate       The  cartel  metaphor  for  legislative  parties  draws  upon  the  parallel  to  a  marketplace  in  which  firms  that  coordinate  output  and  price  decisions  can  maximize  their  profit.    In  a  smoothly  operating  cartel,  the  cartel  acts  as  a  monopolist  and  captures  the  same  profits  as  a  monopolist.    Because  there  is  an  incentive  for  a  firm  to  expand  production  beyond  agreed  upon  limits  to  reap  extra  profits  and  for  new  firms  to  arise  to  exploit  high  prices,  cartels  are  difficult  to  maintain  in  the  marketplace.        

In  a  legislative  body,  parties  seek  to  coordinate  the  production  of  legislation  by  giving  leaders  and  party-­‐based  units  the  tools  for  manipulating  the  legislative  process  and  limiting  defection.    This  means  internalizing  important  procedural  and  organizational  choices—the  election  of  a  presiding  officer  and  setting  parliamentary  rules—within  the  party.    Factions  and  individual  legislators  have  an  incentive  to  defect  when  independent  action  suits  their  political  interests  and  so  the  challenge  is  to  create  counter-­‐incentives  for  those  tendencies.    When  in  the  majority,  a  “cartelized”  party  has  the  option  of  adjusting  both  its  internal  organization  and  rules  and  the  chamber’s  organization  and  rules  to  strengthen  its  control  over  legislative  production  and  cartel-­‐maintaining  incentives.    These  rule-­‐based  advantages  give  the  majority  party  additional  influence,  perhaps  only  in  the  form  of  keeping  unfriendly  legislation  from  being  considered  (negative  agenda  control).  

Page 4: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  3  

 House  Versus  Senate       The  cartelization  of  a  legislative  party  evolves  with  time  and  is  affected  by  several  factors.    As  Jenkins  and  Stewart  emphasize,  the  net  benefits  from  collective  action  must  be  recognized  to  be  positive  (or  even  strongly  positive  to  overcome  transaction  costs),  as  in  the  internalization  of  the  choice  of  Speaker  in  the  mid-­‐nineteenth  century  House  of  Representatives  (Jenkins  and  Stewart,  forthcoming).    The  presence  of  majority  rule  in  all  key  features  of  the  legislative  process  is  necessary  to  empower  the  majority  party  to  control  choices  of  institutional  arrangements,  as  the  rules  instituted  under  Speaker  Reed  established  in  the  late  nineteenth  century  House  (Cox  and  McCubbins  2005,  Sinclair  1989).      Thus,  in  the  case  of  the  House,  agenda  control—the  Speaker’s  right  of  recognition  without  appeal,  the  control  of  the  Committee  on  Rules,  the  privileged  status  of  special  rules,  the  motion  on  the  previous  question,  and  other  features—have  been  created  by  majority  parties  to  allow  their  majorities  to  control  the  legislative  agenda.       The  Senate  is  another  matter.    Two  related  features  of  the  institution  condition  the  extension  of  the  cartel  metaphor  to  the  Senate.    First,  the  Senate  majority  party  has  not  established  the  institutional  context  that  guarantees  that  a  simple  majority  can  win  legislative  battles.    We  do  not  have  to  settle  the  debate  about  whether  Senate  majorities  prefer  to  keep  or  reform  Rule  XXII  (Binder  and  Smith  1997,  Wawro  and  Schickler  2006),  which  governs  cloture,  to  observe  that  Senate  majority  parties  usually  cannot  pass  legislation  without  the  support  of  at  least  some  minority  party  senators  if  a  minority  chooses  to  obstruct  action  by  conducting  extended  debate.    Effective  coordination  within  the  party  does  not  guarantee  a  Senate  outcome  favorable  to  the  party.         Second,  the  Senate  majority  party  has  not  internalized  the  choice  of  a  presiding  offer  or  the  provisions  of  key  rules  as  have  House  majority  parties.    The  presiding  officer  is  not  a  senator,  is  not  chosen  by  the  Senate  or  one  of  its  parties,  and  is  not  necessarily  of  the  same  party  as  the  Senate  majority.    From  the  majority  party’s  perspective,  it  makes  no  sense  to  empower  the  presiding  officer  as  the  House  has  done  (Binder  and  Smith  1997,  Wawro  and  Schickler  2006).      Key  chamber  rules—particularly  the  provisions  of  Rule  XXII—have  divided  the  majority  party  and  seldom  were  settled  through  intra-­‐party  resolution.      The  ease  with  which  a  minority  can  block  rules  changes,  particularly  if  there  is  even  minimal  dissension  with  the  majority  party,  limits  the  incentive  for  the  majority  party  to  devote  resources  to  significant  procedural  changes.       Nevertheless,  Senate  parties  are  certainly  coordinated  teams,  to  use  a  related  metaphor,  and  might  be  characterized  as  weakly  “cartelized.”1    Senators  sharing                                                                                                                  1  The  concept  of  teams  is  found  in  Alchian  and  Demetz  (1972),  who  contrast  two  conceptions  of  the  firm—a  unitary  authority,  common  to  the  traditional  theory  of  the  firm,  and  a  team.    A  team  is  characterized  by  the  presence  of  a  centralized  

Page 5: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  4  

party  labels  have  been  organized  through  most  of  the  Senate’s  history  and  exhibit  certain  shared  electoral  and  policy  goals,  like  House  parties.    Gradually  and  belatedly,  Senate  parties  have  created  organizations  or  internal  rules,  chosen  leaders  to  coordinate  party  activity,  and  acquired  limited  procedural  advantages,  often  through  the  adoption  of  new  precedents  rather  than  new  standing  rules,  that  are  considered  vital  to  the  majority  party’s  interests.       Senate  majority  parties  are  as  old  as  their  House  counterparts  and  yet  they  enjoy  more  limited  procedural  advantages.      With  important  exceptions  for  budget  and  other  “fast  track  measures,”  no  resolution  to  provide  the  terms  of  debate  for  a  measure  is  given  privileged  status  in  the  Senate.    Thus,  the  Senate  majority  generally  cannot  limit  debate  and  amendments  in  the  absence  of  cloture  or  unanimous  consent.    There  is  no  Committee  of  the  Whole  in  which  special  limits  on  debate  are  imposed.        

Still,  there  are  noteworthy  majority  party  advantages.    Properly,  sophisticated  observers  have  noted  the  importance  of  the  ability  of  the  majority  party  to  organize  Senate  committees,  although  that  power  is  subject  to  potential  obstruction  by  the  minority  and  forced  a  proportional  distribution  of  committee  seats  to  the  two  parties,  unlike  in  the  House.    Also  frequently  noticed  is  that  the  Senate  majority  leader  has  a  right  of  first  recognition—a  precedent  recognized  in  the  1930s,  more  than  a  half  century  after  the  Speaker’s  right  of  recognition  without  appeal  was  established  in  the  House.      The  right  of  first  recognition  creates  an  opportunity  to  attempt  to  set  the  Senate  agenda  for  the  majority  leader.    It  almost  goes  without  saying  that  the  ability  to  set  the  agenda  is  checked  by  the  possibility  that  cloture  will  be  required  to  gain  votes  on  the  motion  to  proceed,  the  measure  itself,  motions  to  go  to  conference,  or  a  conference  report.    The  Motion  to  Table       The  motion  to  table  is  the  emphasis  in  more  recent  political  science.    This  is  a  somewhat  misplaced  emphasis  given  the  importance  of  reducing  the  threshold  for  cloture  and  the  use  of  budget  reconciliation  and  other  measures  (trade  agreements,  executive  reorganization,  etc.)  for  which  the  Senate  has  accepted  simple  majority  rule.    Nevertheless,  the  motion  to  table  is  a  very  common  tool  of  the  majority  and  its  partisan  implications  warrant  careful  consideration.    

Under  precedents  that  date  to  the  mid-­‐nineteenth  century  and  codified  in  the  1868  rules,  the  motion  to  table  is  not  debatable  (Binder,  Madonna,  and  Smith  2007).                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                              contractual  agent  in  a  collective  production  process.    Such  a  production  process  involves  a  leader  (the  contractual  agent)  who  coordinates  joint  use  of  resources.    Individuals  are  motivated  by  gaining  better  results  than  the  sum  of  individual  action  and  the  cost  of  organizing  and  disciplining  team  members.    In  contrast  to  the  concept  of  cartels,  which  are  engaged  in  limiting  production,  teams  are  merely  a  form  of  collective  action  in  pursuit  of  common  goals.  

Page 6: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  5  

A  vote  on  a  motion  to  table  an  amendment  or  other  motion  takes  place  immediately  after  it  is  moved  and  so  cuts  off  further  debate.    An  amendment  sponsor  must  yield  the  floor  to  get  a  vote  on  the  amendment  so  the  majority  leader  can  always  exploit  the  right  of  first  recognition  to  offer  a  motion  to  table  the  amendment.    Requiring  only  a  simple  majority  to  pass,  motions  to  table  seem  to  be  an  ideal  way  to  kill  unfriendly  motions  and  amendments.       Except  by  unanimous  consent  (and  on  budget  measures  and  other  types  of  legislation  considered  under  statutory  fast-­‐track  procedures),  opportunities  to  offer  amendments,  germane  and  nongermane,  cannot  be  blocked  by  a  Senate  majority.    Cloture  imposes  a  germaneness  restriction.    The  majority  leader,  using  the  right  of  first  recognition,  may  offer  amendments  to  block  consideration  of  other  amendments  (blocking  amendments  or  fully  filling  the  amendment  tree),  but,  in  the  absence  of  cloture,  cannot  get  a  vote  on  a  measure  without  disposing  of  his  own  amendments  and  opening  the  door  for  unfriendly  amendments.       This  is  where  recent  political  science  takes  a  turn.    The  argument  goes  like  this:    The  motion  to  table  is  a  procedural  motion  that  gives  senators  greater  insulation  from  electoral  pressure  than  they  enjoy  on  direct  votes  on  bills  and  amendments.    That  leeway  creates  an  opening  for  party  or  leadership  influence,  which  leaders  would  care  most  about  on  close  votes.    This  influence  can  affect  how  at  least  a  few  votes  are  cast  and  give  the  majority  party  an  advantage  on  a  motion  to  table  beyond  whatever  influence  would  have  been  applied  on  direct  vote  on  the  amendment.    This  extra  ounce  of  party  influence  contributes  to  negative  agenda  control—blocking  votes  on  substantive  proposals—that  is  parallel  to  the  control  exercised  by  the  House  majority  party  through  special  rules.    The  extra  party  influence  explains  why  the  Senate  majority  party  uses  the  technique  so  frequently.    Challenges  in  Interpreting  the  Use  of  the  Motion  to  Table       We  advocate  a  broader  view  of  the  strategic  challenges  of  the  Senate  parties  and  the  historical  context  in  which  they  evolve.    Over  the  course  of  a  Congress,  majority  and  minority  party  leaders  must  address  a  large  agenda—pushing  or  blocking  legislation,  nominations,  and  treaties  and  setting  priorities  for  doing  so  in  a  process  that  involves  of  mix  of  policy  and  electoral  considerations.      The  legislative,  policy,  and  electoral  considerations  that  affect  leaders’  strategies  evolve.    For  the  majority  party,  the  size  of  the  agenda,  the  obstacles  to  accomplishing  it  within  a  variety  of  deadlines,  and  the  political  consequences  for  failing  to  do  so  vary  from  Congress  to  Congress,  but  also  may  exhibit  systematic  change  over  time.       Several  observations  about  the  state  of  our  knowledge  of  the  amending  process  are  in  order.    First,  the  direct  evidence  that  the  procedural  motion  to  table,  with  its  immediate  effect  on  the  associated  amendment,  reduces  the  influence  of  non-­‐party  influences  is  weak.    There  is  a  coherent  theory  here  that  is  consistent  with  evidence  about  procedural  voting  in  the  House  (Froman  and  Ripley  1965,  Sinclair  2002),  but  it  is  not  demonstrated  by  systematic  evidence  in  the  Senate.  

Page 7: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  6  

    Second,  only  indirect  evidence  has  been  offered  to  demonstrate  the  distinctiveness  of  party  influence  on  motions  to  table.    Existing  studies  (Den  Hartog  and  Monroe  2008,  King,  Orlando,  and  Rohde  2010)  show  party  effects  in  the  likelihood  of  adopting  motions  to  table  amendments.    They  do  so  by  estimating  the  effect  of  the  party  identity  of  the  senators  offering  amendments  and  motions  to  table.    No  study  demonstrates  party  influence  on  individual  senators  who  vote  on  amendments  and  motions  to  table.    Moreover,  no  study  compares  the  party  effects  on  motions  to  table  with  party  effects  on  other  types  of  votes.    We  do  not  know  whether  party  effects  for  voting  on  motions  to  table  amendments  are  distinctive.       Third,  existing  studies  of  party  effects  and  the  motion  to  table  cover  the  period  back  to  1977,  but  we  must  consider  the  historical  pattern  in  the  use  of  the  motion  to  table  over  a  longer  period  to  understand  how  the  Senate  majority  party  has  used  the  motion  to  table.    The  early  1970s  was  a  period  in  which  individualism  blossomed,  minority  obstructionism  intensified  (Binder  and  Smith  1997),  and  amending  activity  doubled  in  just  a  few  Congresses  (Sinclair  1989,  Smith  1989).      Our  expectation  is  that  majority  leadership  floor  tactics  reflected  these  conditions,  which  were  timed  with  Majority  Whip  Senator  Robert  Byrd’s  assumption  of  a  leading  role  in  managing  the  floor  under  Majority  Leader  Mike  Mansfield.    These  considerations  receive  no  mention  in  recent  discussions  of  the  majority  party’s  parliamentary  strategies  and  yet  they  suggest  that  the  frequency  with  which  the  motion  to  table  is  used  to  dispose  of  amendments  is  related  to  floor  management  challenges  beyond  defeating  unfriendly  amendments.       Efficiency  stands  as  an  alternative,  and  compatible,  account  to  the  view  that  partisan  advantage  in  killing  an  amendment  is  the  primary  motivation.    The  motion  to  table  does  more  than  dispose  of  an  amendment  by  a  procedural  motion.    It  prevents  amendments  to  the  amendment  from  being  proposed  and  cuts  short  debate  on  the  amendment  itself,  both  of  which  may  reduce  the  time  required  to  dispose  of  the  issue  at  stake.    In  a  Senate  in  which  time  is  scarce  (Oppenheimer  1985),  in  which  an  extended  and  uncertain  schedule  is  costly  to  individual  senators  and  the  majority  party,  and  which  confronts  a  variety  of  deadlines  for  enactment  of  legislation,  these  features  of  the  motion  to  table  may  more  commonly  motivate  the  use  of  the  motion  to  table  than  amendment-­‐specific  partisan  advantage.    

In  addition,  conditions  that  limit  time  for  the  consideration  of  amendments  may  put  a  premium  of  rapid  consideration  of  amendments  and  increase  the  use  of  motions  to  table.    In  the  presence  of  obstructive  minority  tactics,  such  as  extended  debate  and  amending  activity,  the  majority  may  seek  to  limit  the  time  devoted  to  any  one  amendment  and  use  parliamentary  tools  (unanimous  consent  agreements,  motions  to  table)  to  expedite  business  and  maintain  a  reasonable  schedule.    But  at  least  as  important  may  be  that  the  use  of  the  motion  to  table  speeds  consideration  of  amendments  and  allows  the  consideration  of  more  amendments  when  the  Senate  operates  under  a  times  constraint.    Post-­‐cloture  debate,  the  end  of  a  fiscal  year,  the  end  of  a  session,  and  other  fixed  deadlines,  and  even  weekly  scheduling  

Page 8: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  7  

considerations,  may  dictate  the  use  of  time-­‐saving  devices  like  the  motion  to  table.    The  larger  volume  of  legislation  with  sunset  provisions  and  the  delays  in  the  appropriations  and  budget  processes  surely  have  intensified  time  pressures  and  encouraged  the  use  of  time-­‐saving  devices.2      

 Efficiency  considerations  yield  additional  propositions  about    

the  cross-­‐sectional  and  longitudinal  variation  in  the  direct  amendment  and  motion  to  table  votes.    As  King,  Orlando,  and  Rohde  (2010)  suggest,  alternative  means  for  disposing  of  some  amendments  expeditiously  may  substitute  for  motions  to  table.    Specifically,  a  motion  to  waive  the  Budget  Act  (enabling  consideration  of  an  amendment  that  violates  budget  enforcement  rules),  usually  following  a  successful  point  of  order  raised  against  an  amendment  on  budget  grounds,  requires  a  three-­‐fifths  majority  of  senators  “duly  chosen  and  sworn”  to  protect  the  amendment  (for  most  parts  of  the  Budget  Act,  as  amended).    The  high  threshold  makes  it  easier  to  block  a  direct  vote  on  the  amendment  and  so  may  be  preferred,  when  available,  as  a  method  for  disposing  of  an  unfriendly  amendment.3    There  is  reason  to  question  whether  abiding  by  a  budget  constraint  is  nonsubstantive  and  procedural,  but  the  60-­‐vote  threshold  may  make  the  exercise  of  special  party  influence  to  kill  an  amendment  unnecessary.       Finally,  we  must  account  for  the  evolving  procedural  context  of  amending  activity  to  understand  the  use  of  the  motion  to  table.    In  particular,  the  more  central  role  of  cloture  in  recent  Congresses  means  that  time  constraints,  unanimous  consent  agreements,  and  leaders’  tactics  have  changed  (Smith  2010).    Majority  leaders  have  more  frequently  used  the  amendment  tree  to  control  the  amendments  that  are  offered  before  and  after  cloture  is  invoked,  which  gives  them  leverage  with  senators  who  might  not  otherwise  agree  to  the  number  of  amendments  to  be  offered  or  the  time  limits  for  debate  on  allowed  amendments.    Post-­‐cloture  debate  is  limited  so  that  amendment  sponsors  have  reason  to  agree  to  time  limits  that  enable  more  amendments  to  be  considered.    For  these  reasons,  majority  leaders  acquire  efficiency  gains  through  time  agreements  and  do  not  need  to  cut  off  debate  with  motions  to  table  as  often.    We  would  expect  an  increase  in  the  use  of  time  agreements  to  be  associated  with  an  increase  in  the  proportion  of  amendments  subject  to  a  direct  vote.                                                                                                                  2  On  July  31,  1969,  for  example,  the  Senate  faced  a  midnight  deadline  for  the  expiration  of  a  surtax  and  many  senators  wanted  to  offer  amendments.    Majority  Leader  Mike  Mansfield  explained  that  at  least  twelve  of  his  party  colleagues  wanted  to  offer  at  least  27  amendments  and  so  moved  to  table  the  first  to  come  up  that  seemed  likely  to  produce  lengthy  debate  (Congressional  Record,  July  31,  1969,  21561-­‐6).    It  is  notable,  however,  that  the  infrequency  with  which  the  motion  to  table  had  been  used  to  dispose  of  amendments  in  previous  years  produced  considerable  discussion  of  Mansfield’s  move  in  1969.  

3  Perhaps  equally  important,  the  debate  on  an  appeal  related  to  the  Budget  Act  is  limited  to  an  hour.    Appeals  are  not  considered  in  the  analysis  that  follows.  

Page 9: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  8  

 Our  findings  force  us  to  elaborate  on  our  understanding  of  the  partisan  

motivations  for  the  use  of  various  procedural  devices.    The  majority  party  faces  a  multitude  of  competing  demands  with  multiple  time  horizons.    Tactical  considerations,  such  as  the  disposal  of  an  amendment  on  hand,  must  be  weighed  against  the  strategic  considerations,  such  as  the  passage  of  an  entire  bill  or  legislative  agenda.    Amendment-­‐specific  partisan  advantage  is  just  one  of  these  considerations,  and  perhaps  a  relatively  modest  consideration,  in  the  larger  context  of  legislating  a  large  agenda  in  an  institution  that  empowers  both  individual  senators  and  organized  minorities  to  pursue  multifaceted  strategies  of  amendments,  dilatory  motions,  and  outright  obstructionism.    

Hypotheses         Our  exploratory  analysis  is  intended  to  provide  a  preliminary  evaluation  of  these  research  hypotheses  and  corresponding  null  hypotheses—    

HR1:    Votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  have  weaker  electoral  consequences  than  votes  on  amendments.  

H01:    Votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  have  the  same  electoral  consequences  as  votes  on  amendments.  

 HR2:    Votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  exhibit  stronger  party  influence  

than  votes  on  amendments.  H02:    Votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  exhibit  the  same  party  influence  

as  votes  on  amendments.    HR3:    The  frequency  of  votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  is  positively  

correlated  with  the  frequency  of  contested  amendments  that  concern  the  majority  leader.  

H03:    The  frequency  of  votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  are  not  correlated  with  the  frequency  of  contested  amendments  that  concern  the  majority  leader.  

 HR4:    The  frequency  of  votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  and  the  

frequency  of  votes  on  budget  points  of  order  vary  inversely.  H04:      The  frequency  of  votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  and  the  

frequency  of  votes  on  budget  points  of  order  are  uncorrelated.    HR5:    The  frequency  of  votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  is  positively  

correlated  with  the  severity  of  time  constraints.  H05:    The  frequency  of  votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  is  not  

correlated  with  the  severity  of  time  constraints.    

HR6:    The  frequency  of  votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  is  negatively  correlated  with  time  agreements  on  a  bill.  

Page 10: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  9  

H06:    The  frequency  of  votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  in  uncorrelated  with  time  agreements  on  a  bill.  

 For  HR1-­‐HR4,  confirming  the  research  hypothesis  supports  the  party  

influence  account  in  recent  studies.    HR2,  concerning  the  distinctive  party  influence  on  motions  to  table,  is  fundamental  to  this  account.    HR5  and  HR6,  if  confirmed,  would  provide  preliminary  support  for  an  alternative  account  that  emphasizes  the  broader  agenda  and  efficiency  considerations  of  the  majority  party.  

   

Methods    HR1:    Motions  to  Table  and  Electoral  Consequences       At  this  stage  in  our  work,  we  can  offer  only  circumstantial  evidence  on  the  question  of  whether  the  electoral  consequences  of  amendment  and  motion  to  table  votes  vary  systematically.    Ideally,  we  would  evaluate  the  salience  of  votes  in  the  general  public.    From  the  literature  (Clausen  1973,  Kingdon  1973,  Matthews  and  Stimson  1975),  we  would  expect  most  votes,  whatever  their  parliamentary  form,  to  have  low  salience  on  average.    Thus,  even  under  ideal  circumstances—measuring  public  response  to  individual  votes—finding  systematic  differences  between  types  of  votes  is  likely  to  be  difficult.    

A  more  tractable  empirical  question  is  whether  there  is  a  difference  between  procedural  and  substantive  votes  in  (a)  the  probability  that  a  future  opponent  or  opposing  will  exploit  a  vote  (Arnold  1990)  and  (b)  the  positive  use  of  the  vote  by  the  incumbent  senator.    Finding  that  motions  to  table  are  found  in  campaign  ads  or  in  interest  group  evaluations  of  senators  would  be  circumstantial  evidence  the  motions  to  table  are  not  free  of  electoral  consequences.  

 HR2:    Party  Effects  by  Vote  Type    

The  appropriate  comparison  of  party  effects  on  senators’  voting  is  an  amendment  and  its  paired  motion  to  table.    This  comparison  is  not  possible  whenever  the  motion  to  table  is  adopted  and  the  amendment  is  killed.    The  comparison  is  possible  only  in  the  very  few  cases  in  which  there  is  a  roll-­‐call  vote  on  the  motion  to  table,  that  motion  is  defeated,  and  a  roll-­‐call  vote  occurs  on  the  amendment.    These  are  uncommon  because  the  vast  majority  of  motions  to  table  are  adopted  and,  when  motions  to  table  fail,  are  often  followed  by  a  voice  vote  on  the  amendment  (the  outcome  on  the  amendment  is  obvious  to  everyone).      

 Nevertheless,  we  can  conduct  an  unpaired  analysis  of  voting  behavior  on  roll-­‐call  

votes.4    Our  unit  of  analysis  is  the  individual  vote  and  the  dependent  variable  is                                                                                                                  4  Note  that  a  voice  vote  is  the  method  of  disposition  for  the  vast  majority  of  amendments  (Smith  1989).  

Page 11: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  10  

support  or  opposition  to  the  majority  leader’s  position.    We  model  support  for  the  majority  leader’s  position  as  a  function  of  (a)  vote  type  (direct  amendment  vote,  motion  to  table  amendment,  etc.)  and  (b)  the  ideological  location  of  the  senator.      We  limit  the  analysis  to  majority  party  senators  on  contested  votes  (55-­‐45  split  or  closer),  the  senators  and  votes  on  which  party  influence  should  be  strongest.    The  expectation  is  that  support  for  the  leader  is  higher  for  the  procedural  motion  to  table  and  ideological  proximate  senators,  controlling  for  the  ideological  location  of  the  senator.5    H3-­‐H6:    The  Frequency  of  Motions  to  Table    

The  historical  pattern  in  the  use  of  motions  to  table  as  the  method  of  disposing  of  amendments  is  the  subject  of  the  last  four  hypotheses.    For  these  hypotheses,  the  ideal  method  is  to  estimate  an  amendment-­‐level  model  in  which  the  dependent  variable  is  the  use  of  a  motion  to  table  and  the  independent  variables  capture  the  presence  of  a  contested  amendment,  a  time  constraint  (bill-­‐  and  Congress-­‐specific  constraints),  and  cloture  on  the  measure.    We  reserve  that  estimation  for  another  report.    Here,  we  simply  count  the  number  of  votes  on  amendments  and  on  motions  to  table  amendments,  classify  the  parliamentary  conditions  under  which  they  occur,  and  observe  the  simple  relationships  between  the  relative  number  of  motions  to  table  amendments  and  Congress-­‐level  characteristics.    We  do  this  for  the  period  since  the  late  1960s,  when  the  number  of  motions  to  table  amendments  began  to  climb  (see  below).      

   

Findings    HR1:    Electoral  Consequences       We  cannot  confirm  HR1.    To  be  sure,  senators  have  expressed  an  awareness  of  their  colleagues’  sensitivity  to  direct  votes  on  some  amendments.    In  1971,  for  example,  Senator  Robert  Byrd,  the  bill  manager,  proposed  an  amendment  to  an  amendment  offered  by  Jacob  Javits.    The  Javits  amendment  increased  spending  for  a  program  funded  by  the  underlying  bill  by  $55  million  and  the  Byrd  amendment  increased  spending  by  only  $10  billion.    Javits,  of  course,  preferred  the  larger  increase,  but  he  realized  that  some  of  his  colleagues  might  not  want  to  be  put  in  a  position,  in  the  isolated  case  of  the  Byrd  amendment,  of  going  on  the  record  against  a  $10  million  increase.    The  safe  way  to  dispose  of  the  Byrd  amendment  was  to  table  it  and  that  is  what  Javits  did,  explaining  afterwards  that  he  “moved  to  table  the  amendment,  not  out  of  any  disrespect,  but  only  because  I  did  not  think  it  fair  to  ask  

                                                                                                               5  For  this  analysis,  we  do  not  distinguish  amendments  and  motions  to  table  amendments  by  the  party  of  their  author.    If  the  motion  to  table  creates  an  opportunity  for  greater  party  influence  because  it  is  a  procedural  vote,  the  author  of  the  motion  or  associated  amendment  should  not  matter.  

Page 12: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  11  

senators  to  vote  against  any  increased  figure  for  the  program”  (Congressional  Record,  June  19,  1971,  16592).    

Nevertheless,  we  find  circumstantial  evidence  that  calls  into  question  the  claim  that  motions  to  table  buffer  legislators  from  electoral  consequences  of  floor  voting.    Senators  are  forced  to  defend  votes  on  motions  to  table  and  even  use  motions  to  table  to  claim  credit  for  supporting  a  cause.    In  her  2010  campaign  against  Senate  Majority  Leader  Harry  Reid  (D-­‐NV),  Sharron  Angle  used  the  senator’s  vote  on  a  motion  to  table  an  amendment  denying  Social  Security  credit  to  someone  using  an  unauthorized  Social  Security  number.    Angle’s  claims  were  important  enough  to  warrant  journalistic  attention.6    In  the  same  election  season,  a  campaign  ad  of  incumbent  Patty  Murray  (D-­‐WA)  touted  her  support  for  women’s  right  to  choose  on  the  issue  of  abortion.    She  issued  a  press  release  that  cited  her  vote  on  a  motion  to  table  an  amendment  in  support  of  her  ad.7       Moreover,  interest  groups  frequently  use  motions  to  table  amendments  in  their  ratings  of  senators.    Figure  1  reports  the  relative  frequency  of  votes  on  amendments  and  motions  to  table  amendments  used  in  the  annual  ratings  of  Americans  for  Democratic  Action  and  the  American  Conservative  Union  for  the  1969-­‐2008  period,  which  stretches  to  the  early  Congresses  in  which  use  of  the  motion  to  table  became  more  common.    Each  data  point  shows,  relative  to  the  overall  voting  record,  the  difference  between  the  proportions  of  votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  and  votes  on  amendments  included  in  the  tabulation  .      Plainly,  motions  to  table  amendments  are  about  as  often  overrepresented  in  comparison  to  amendments  as  they  are  underrepresented  with  total  differences  only  in  the  range  of  0.1  and  -­‐0.1.    A  senator  can  expect  a  vote  on  a  motion  to  table  an  amendment  to  appear  in  these  interest  group  tabulations  about  as  often  as  a  vote  on  an  amendment.    HR2:    Party  Effects  and  Vote  Type       We  cannot  confirm  HR2.    The  model  of  support  for  the  majority  leader’s  position  is  estimated  for  all  majority  party  senators  on  contested  votes.    Over  the  1969-­‐2010  period,  the  likelihood  of  supporting  the  majority  leader  is  not  related  to  whether  the  vote  is  on  an  amendment  or  a  motion  to  table  (Table  1).    With  that  result,  it  is  not  surprising  that  the  sign  for  a  motion  to  table  vote  is  negative  for  many  Congresses,  the  opposite  of  the  research  hypothesis.8    There  are  party  effects  in  voting  on  motions  to  table,  but  this  evidence  indicates  that  these  effects  are  no  greater  than  those  found  for  amendment  votes.  9                                                                                                                    6  http://www.politifact.com/truth-­‐o-­‐meter/statements/2010/sep/17/sharron-­‐angle/sharron-­‐angle-­‐says-­‐harry-­‐reid-­‐wants-­‐give-­‐illegals-­‐/  7  http://www.pattymurray.com/news/releases?id=0081  8  Congress-­‐by-­‐Congress  results  available  upon  request.  9  Estimates  for  a  model  for  all  senators  that  includes  a  variable  for  party  status  shows  significant  party  effects,  controlling  for  vote  type  and  policy  positions.  

Page 13: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  12  

     HR3-­‐HR6:    The  Frequency  of  Motions  to  Table  Amendments       Figures  3  and  4  set  the  context  for  evaluating  the  hypotheses  about  the  frequency  of  motions  to  table  amendments.      The  figures  show  two  periods  of  significant  change  in  the  use  of  motions  to  table—the  early  1970s  and  the  late  2000s.    The  figures  force  us  to  call  into  question  the  claim  that  the  motion  to  table  is  a  standard  tool  for  the  exercise  of  negative  agenda  control  in  the  Senate.    We  know  of  no  argument  grounded  in  cartel  theory  that  accounts  for  the  wide  variance  in  the  number  and  percentage  of  amendments  subject  to  a  motion  to  table.    

The  use  of  motions  to  table  was  uncommon  in  the  mid-­‐20th  century  and  became  somewhat  more  common  in  the  1960s,  but  the  practice  did  not  become  routine  until  the  1970s  (Figure  3).10    For  the  most  part,  majority  parties  lived  without  regular  use  of  the  motion  to  table  until  the  1970s,  when  something  changed.    It  appears  that  the  expanded  use  of  motions  to  table  is  timed  with  the  rapid  increase  in  the  number  of  floor  amendments  in  the  early  1970s  (Smith  1989)  and  so  may  support  the  thesis  that  efficiency  concerns  drove  the  majority  party  leadership  to  seek  to  limit  debate  on  amendments.    Ironically,  the  two  post-­‐cloture  filibusters  in  1976  and  1977,  the  first  conducted  by  majority  party  Senator  James  Allen  (D-­‐AL)  and  the  second  by  majority  party  Senators  James  Abourezk  (D-­‐SD)  and  Howard  Metzenbaum  (D-­‐OH),  spurred  the  use  of  motions  to  table  to  dispose  of  openly  dilatory  amendments—more  than  for  any  other  measures  in  the  1970s.       Figure  3  also  shows  that  the  use  of  the  motion  to  table  has  been  less  common  in  the  most  recent  Congresses.    Figure  4  again  demonstrates  that  motions  to  table  became  a  common,  although  not  dominant,  method  of  disposing  of  amendments  in  the  1970s.    In  Congresses  since  the  late  1990s  the  proportion  of  amendments  subject  to  a  motion  to  table  has  fallen—and  quite  sharply  between  the  108th  and  109th  Congresses,  both  with  Republican  Bill  Frist  as  majority  leader.    At  the  same  time,  the  proportion  of  amendments  receiving  a  direct  vote  was  higher  than  the  average  for  the  previous  two  decades.    In  fact,  there  is  an  increase  in  the  number  of  amendments  subject  to  a  direct  vote  and  that  the  there  is  a  nearly  one-­‐for-­‐one  tradeoff  between  the  number  of  amendments  defeated  by  a  direct  vote  and  to  a  motion  to  table.    

These  historical  patterns  help  us  sort  through  existing  arguments.    The  expanded  use  of  motions  to  table  in  the  early  1970s  appears  to  be  strongly  correlated  with  what  we  already  know  about  the  early  1970s—intensified  individualism,  the  demise  of  restrictive  norms,  increased  obstructionism,  and  rapidly  escalating  amending  activity  (Sinclair  1989,  Smith  1989).      Furthermore,  recent  trends  in  the  number  of  votes  on  amendments  and  motions  to  table                                                                                                                  10  Also  see  Carson,  Madonna,  and  Owens  (2010).  

Page 14: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  13  

amendments  do  not  appear  to  demand  that  we  find  a  substitute  for  motions  to  table.    Direct  votes  on  amendments  seem  to  be  the  substitute.    These  aggregate  patterns  at  least  call  into  question  the  need  to  explain  the  use  of  the  motion  to  table  by  the  need  for  amendment-­‐specific  party  influence  and  suggest  that  larger  agenda  management  concerns  were  at  work.       Contested  votes:    HR3  is  not  confirmed.  The  hypothesis  posits  that  motions  to  table  are  used  disproportionately  for  close  votes,  an  implication  of  the  theory  that  procedural  votes  are  used  by  partisan  leaders  to  exercise  influence  over  outcomes.    We  cannot  test  this  hypothesis  directly  because  we  would  need  to  test  amendment  vote  with  the  paired  votes  on  motions  to  table.    Instead,  we  can  compare  amendment  votes  with  votes  on  motions  to  table,  which  we  expect  to  see  more  closer  votes  on  motions  to  table.        

On  balance,  the  evidence  does  not  support  HR3.    Over  time,  the  number  of  motions  to  table  does  not  rise  or  fall  in  response  to  the  number  of  contested  votes.    For  the  1969-­‐2008  period,  using  the  Congress  as  the  unit  of  analysis,  the  simple  correlation  between  the  number  of  motions  to  table  amendments  and  the  number  of  contested  amendments  (motions  to  table  and  direct  votes  with  outcomes  that  are  55-­‐45  or  closer)  is  -­‐0.38  (p  =  0.10).    That  is,  the  sign  is  the  opposite  of  what  is  expected.       In  the  cross-­‐section,  the  relationship  between  type  of  vote  and  contestedness  varies  over  time.    Figures  5  and  6  illustrate  the  difference  between  voting  on  motions  to  table  amendments  and  directly  on  amendments.    In  Figure  5,  the  mean  vote  margin—the  absolute  value  of  the  difference  between  percent  voting  yea  and  percent  voting  nay—is  only  slightly  smaller  for  motions  to  table  than  for  amendments  in  the  1970s.    The  reference  line  in  the  figure  is  located  at  ten  percent  (55-­‐45).    After  the  late  1980s,  the  difference  in  margins  grew,  with  motions  to  table  becoming  more  contested.    This  is  related  to  an  increase  in  “party  votes”  (data  not  shown)  in  this  period.    Still,  even  in  a  more  partisan  era,  the  mean  motion  to  table  yielded  a  margin  of  over  20  percent  (60-­‐40).      Only  a  few  motions  to  table  are  close  votes  in  which  a  few  votes,  influenced  by  party,  could  have  made  the  difference  in  the  outcome.       Figure  6  shows  that  the  distribution  of  margins  for  the  two  types  of  votes  varies  widely  from  Congress  to  Congress.11    The  most  obvious  feature  of  the  distributions  is  that  there  are  no  significant  differences  between  the  two  types  of  votes  until  the  1990s  and,  even  then,  the  differences  are  not  consistent.    Reflecting  the  mean  differences,  the  differences  seem  to  be  highly  conditional,  with  a  more  skewed  distribution  for  motions  to  table  at  the  contested  end  during  the  last  two  decades.                                                                                                                        11  Margins  of  greater  than  90-­‐10  are  excluded.    This  excludes  “hurrah  votes”  that  occur  with  considerable  frequency  on  amendments.  

Page 15: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  14  

Budget  waivers:    HR4  is  confirmed.    Budget  enforcement  surely  is  a  contributing  cause  to  the  recent  decline  in  the  use  of  motions  to  table.    For  the  period  between  1985  and  2008,  the  simple  correlation  between  the  number  of  votes  on  motions  to  waive  the  Budget  Act  and  the  number  of  votes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  is  -­‐0.49,  which  means  that  the  increase  in  the  use  of  budget  waivers  accounts  for  up  to  25  percent  of  the  variance.      

 Nevertheless,  we  observe,  as  did  Smith  (2010),  that  there  is  an  increase  in  

the  number  of  amendments  subject  to  a  direct  vote  (see  Figure  4).    In  fact,  there  is  a  nearly  one-­‐for-­‐one  tradeoff  between  the  number  of  amendments  killed  on  a  direct  vote  and  the  number  killed  with  a  motion  to  table.    Thus,  while  budget  waivers  are  a  part  of  the  story,  the  primary  story  lies  elsewhere.  

 Votes  on  motions  to  waive  the  Budget  Act  are  more  contested  than  votes  on  

amendments  or  motions  to  table  (Figure  7),  at  least  in  the  period  since  1995  when  the  number  of  budget  waiver  votes  became  significant.    The  mode  is  within  the  55-­‐45  margin  even  when  there  must  be  60-­‐vote  majority  to  waive  the  Budget  Act  in  most  cases.    The  result  is  that  budget  waiver  votes  are  seldom  close  votes  with  the  outcome  in  doubt—and  seldom  a  vote  on  which  party  influence  is  likely  to  be  necessary.    

Time  Constraints:    HR5  is  (tentatively)  confirmed.    Time  constraints  are  difficult  to  measure.    Many  time  constraints  are  specific  to  a  particular  piece  of  legislation  for  which  there  is  a  deadline  for  action.    Appropriations  bills,  tax  law  extensions,  debt  ceiling  increases,  and  fast-­‐track  measures  are  among  the  common  bills  with  deadlines.    Other  measures  are  considered  under  time  limitations.    Budget  measures,  bills  subject  to  cloture,  and  a  few  other  measures  are  subject  to  limited  debate  that  motivates  all  senators  seeking  to  have  amendments  considered  to  agree  that  expeditious  consideration  of  amendments  is  desirable.    For  this  report,  we  have  not  accounted  for  these  bill-­‐specific  constraints  and  so  cannot  relate  them  to  the  frequency  of  motions  to  table.    We  can  only  observe  that  measures  with  deadlines  appear  to  have  become  a  larger  part  of  the  Senate  agenda  and  may  be  an  important  factor  in  the  expanded  use  of  motions  to  table.    

In  practice,  the  use  of  motions  to  table  is  often  concentrated  in  a  few  bills.    An  early  case  is  the  post-­‐cloture  debate  on  the  1977  natural  gas  deregulation  bill.    In  this  famous  filibuster,  over  400  amendments  were  submitted  and  intended  to  be  offered  by  bill  opponents,  two  majority  party  senators,  to  delay  action  on  the  bill  indefinitely.    The  bill,  on  which  cloture  was  easily  invoked,  77-­‐17,  had  broad  support,  but  the  opponents  exploited  Rule  XXII,  which  did  not  count  the  time  devoted  to  quorum  calls  and  voting  against  the  100-­‐hour  post-­‐cloture  limit  on  debate.    To  abbreviate  the  debate  opponents  wanted  to  give  their  dilatory  amendments,  motions  to  table  were  offered  dozens  of  times.    In  fact,  81  motions  to  table  amendments  were  offered.    In  the  same  Congress,  nearly  50  motions  to  table  were  used  post-­‐cloture  to  overcome  obstructionist  amendments  on  the  Panama  Canal  Treaty  that  were  offered,  mainly  by  minority  party  senators.    In  that  context,  

Page 16: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  15  

expediting  business,  not  winning  votes  that  would  otherwise  be  lost,  motivated  the  use  of  the  motion  to  table.    These  two  filibustered  measures  account  for  over  a  40  percent  of  motions  to  table  in  the  95th  Congress.  

 The  two  measures  in  the  95th  Congress  are  extreme  cases,  but  the  general  

context—considering  amendments  under  some  bill-­‐specific  obstructionism  or  time  constraints—is  common  to  a  large  proportion  of  motions  to  table.    Of  the  five  measures  with  20  or  more  motions  to  table  amendments  in  the  1970s,  three  involved  motions  to  table  that  were  nearly  all  post-­‐cloture,  one  was  a  tax  bill  passed  at  the  very  end  of  a  Congress,  and  one  was  a  second-­‐session  budget  resolution  debated  under  a  time  limit.    The  motion  to  table  was  used  most  frequently  in  the  99th  Congress  (1985-­‐1986)  on  a  farm  bill  just  before  authorization  for  most  agricultural  subsidy  and  quota  programs  was  about  to  expire  at  the  end  of  1985.    

     More  generally,  we  know  that  the  use  of  motions  to  table  increased  as  the  

number  of  floor  amendments  expanded  in  the  early  1970s  and  senators  openly  complained  about  scheduling  pressures.    The  number  of  roll-­‐call  votes  per  day  more  than  doubled  between  the  91st  (1969-­‐1970)  and  94th  Congresses  (1975-­‐1976)  as  the  number  of  amendments,  most  subject  to  a  voice  vote,  doubled,  too.12    Leaders  continued  to  struggle  with  the  schedule  and  completing  the  Senate’s  work  through  the  remainder  of  the  20th  and  into  the  21st  century  (Smith  2010).        

 To  be  sure,  motions  to  table  amendments  are  spread  over  a  large  number  of  

measures.    In  the  95th  Congress,  for  example,  motions  to  table  were  associated  with  130  measures.    The  modal  number  of  amendments  per  bill  that  is  subject  to  a  motion  to  table  is  one.    It  is  possible  that  a  significant  part  of  these  motions  to  table  was  the  product  party  leaders’  efforts  to  kill  amendments  that  they  might  not  otherwise  kill.    We  have  found  little  evidence  for  this  and  instead  find  a  relationship  between  time  constraints  and  the  use  of  the  efficient  motion  to  table.    

 Time  Agreements:    HR6  is  confirmed.    The  increased  use  of  cloture  is  well-­‐

documented  and  need  not  be  reviewed  here.    Figure  8  demonstrates  that  the  use  of  cloture  has  reached  a  large  majority  of  the  most  important  measures.    This  is  likely  to  shape  the  procedural  context  under  which  amending  activity  occurs.    As  Figure  9  shows,  the  proportion  of  amendments  subject  to  a  direct  vote  has  increased  in  recent  Congresses  as  the  number  subject  to  a  motion  to  table  has  declined.    Moreover,  in  the  two  most  recent  Congresses  shown  in  the  figure,  which  exhibit  a  much  lower  frequency  of  motions  to  table  than  previous  Congresses,  a  higher  percentage  of  amendments  were  associated  with  a  bill  subject  to  cloture.        

                                                                                                               12  Calculated  from  the  Senate’s  “Resumé  of  Activities,”  Final  Calendar,  for  each  Congress.    Data  available  upon  request.    On  Senate  floor  amendments,  see  Smith  (1989).  

Page 17: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  16  

  In  the  111th  Congress  (2009-­‐2010),  over  three-­‐fifths  of  roll-­‐call  votes  on  amendments,  motions  to  table  amendments,  and  budget  waivers  occurred  on  a  measure  on  which  cloture  was  invoked  on  the  motion  to  proceed,  a  committee  or  leader  substitute  amendment,  or  the  measure.    This  represented  a  new  high,  but  reflected  a  continuation  of  the  pattern  established  in  the  previous  two  Congresses.    It  reflected  the  majority  leader’s  efforts  to  control  amending  activity,  which  was  essential  to  countering  what  was  perceived  as  a  minority  party  effort  to  slow  or  block  most  of  the  majority’s  agenda.      By  getting  time  agreements  whenever  possible,  invoking  cloture  and  early  if  possible,  or  placing  blocking  amendments  in  order  to  require  unanimous  consent  to  bring  up  other  amendments,  the  majority  leader  sought  to  gain  leverage  over  minority  partisans.    In  many  cases,  this  led  to  a  unanimous  consent  agreement  that  provided  for  the  disposition  of  amendments,  pre-­‐  or  post-­‐cloture,  and  a  final  passage  vote.    With  a  time  agreement  in  place  on  amendments,  the  majority  leader  no  longer  needed  to  abbreviate  debate  on  amendments  and  could  allow  direct  votes  on  them.    For  at  least  a  few  major  bills  that  would  have  attracted  a  disproportionate  share  of  amendments,  this  approach  probably  both  reduced  the  number  of  amendments  considered  and  receiving  a  recorded  vote  and  limited  the  number  of  motions  to  table  amendments.  

  Three  measures  considered  in  the  111th  Congress  illustrate  variations  on  this  process.    In  early  2009,  the  Senate  considered  an  omnibus  appropriations  bill  that  was  necessary  to  fund  most  domestic  agencies  for  the  remainder  of  the  fiscal  year.13    Republicans  allowed  the  Senate  to  proceed  to  the  consideration  of  the  bill,  but  instantly  began  an  amendment  spree.    Because  at  least  two  Democrats  opposed  the  bill,  Majority  Leader  Reid  found  that  he  lacked  the  votes  to  invoke  cloture  and  had  little  choice  but  to  negotiate  with  the  Republicans.    In  exchange  for  some  Republican  support  for  a  cloture  motion,  Reid  agreed  to  incorporate  virtually  all  Republican  amendments  in  a  unanimous  consent  agreement  (Senate  Order  26,  111th  Congress).    The  agreement  limited  debate  on  the  amendments  to  three  days,  protected  the  amendments  from  second-­‐degree  amendments,  and  dispensed  with  all  post-­‐cloture  debate.    With  a  time  agreement  in  place,  although  an  agreement  that  met  the  minority’s  demands,  Reid  allowed  direct  votes  on  17  of  20  amendments.    In  fact,  with  senators  interested  in  expediting  consideration  of  the  bill,  senators  agreed  to  stack  the  votes  on  the  last  few  amendments  at  a  specified  time  on  the  last  day.    Two  amendments  were  killed  with  motions  to  table  and  one  was  killed  on  a  Budget  Act  point  of  order.        

Late  in  the  process,  as  the  stacked  votes  were  progressing,  the  two  motions  to  table  were  offered  by  a  majority  bill  manager  or  the  majority  leader  and  yielded  reasonably  close  votes—50-­‐47  and  52-­‐45.    For  those  votes,  it  may  be  reasonable  to  argue  that  the  majority  sought  to  exploit  a  procedural  motion  to  kill  the  amendments.    The  latter  amendment  concerned  the  politically  delicate  issues  of  cost-­‐of-­‐living  increases  in  senators’  salaries  so  the  case  of  political  buffering  is  

                                                                                                               13  See  Congressional  Record  (Senate),  daily,  March  6,  9,  and  10,  2009.  

Page 18: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  17  

particular  strong  for  that  amendment.    Nevertheless,  85  percent  of  the  amendments  received  direct  votes,  including  an  amendment  killed  on  a  47-­‐50  vote.  

  In  contrast,  the  health  care  reform  bill,  which  was  passed  on  Christmas  Eve,  2009,  was  an  instance  in  which  the  majority  managed  to  invoke  cloture.    Armed  with  the  60  votes  required  to  invoke  cloture,  the  majority  leader,  filed  three  cloture  motions:    on  the  motion  to  proceed,  a  leader  substitute  (compromise),  and  the  bill.14    He  then  filled  the  amendment  tree  by  offering  second-­‐degree  amendments  to  the  leader  substitute.    This  put  him  in  a  position  to  allow  time  to  expire  on  post-­‐cloture  debate  and  eventually  get  the  votes  required  on  the  three  motions  to  pass  the  bill  as  he  wanted.    With  the  holidays  approaching,  the  minority  proved  willing  to  accept  time  agreements  for  the  consideration  of  a  handful  of  amendments.    In  a  series  of  time  agreements,  debate  and  roll-­‐call  votes  on  19  amendments  and  four  motions  to  commit  the  legislation  to  committee  to  amend  certain  provisions  were  arranged.    On  the  amendments,  16  direct  votes  were  cast,  two  were  subject  to  motions  to  table,  and  one  to  a  budget  point  of  order.    One  of  the  motions  to  table  concerned  clearing  the  amendment  tree  that  the  majority  leader  had  filled.    In  order  to  complete  the  work  on  Christmas  Eve,  the  minority  agreed  to  no  post-­‐cloture  debate  on  the  bill.15  

Only  one  regular  amendment  was  subject  to  a  motion  to  table.    An  amendment  on  abortion  was  tabled,  54-­‐45.    No  one  doubted  the  outcome  because  head  counts  had  clarified  senators’  positions  before  the  vote.16    In  fact,  Congressional  Quarterly’s  reporter  noted  that  going  on  the  record  on  abortion  “offered  political  cover,  allowing  them  to  come  out  against  abortion  before  voting  for  the  final  measure.”17    Unfortunately,  there  is  no  way  to  determine  from  the  public  record  whether  the  procedural  vote  was  essential  to  the  outcome.    It  seems  unlikely  that  a  motion  to  table  would  give  a  senator  political  cover  on  such  a  highly  salient  vote.  

The  third  measure  was  the  reconciliation  bill  used  to  address  House-­‐Senate  differences  on  the  health  care  reform  legislation.    Reconciliation  was  used  to  avoid  having  to  seek  cloture  on  a  conference  report;  reconciliation  bills  are  limited  to  20  hours  of  debate.    With  the  time  limit  and  an  obstructive  minority,  gaining  unanimous  consent  to  structure  debate  and  limit  amendments  was  unnecessary.    Nevertheless,  Republicans  had  many  amendments,  none  of  which  they  expected  to  

                                                                                                               14  The  vote  of  Senator  Ben  Nelson  remained  in  doubt  over  the  issue  of  abortion.  15  In  addition,  the  time  agreements  provided  for  60-­‐vote  majorities  for  agreeing  to  several  of  the  amendments  and  motions  to  commit.    With  the  amendment  tree  filled  and  60  votes  for  cloture,  the  majority  leader  could  insist  on  the  high  threshold  as  a  condition  for  allowing  consideration  of  the  amendments.  16  Shailagh  Murray  and  Lori  Montgomery,  “Private-­‐Sector  Alternative:    Senate  May  Drop  Public  Option;  Reid  Says  He  is  Optimistic  about  Bill  After  Deal,”  Washington  Post,  December  9,  2009,  p.  A01.  17  Alex  Wayne  and  Drew  Armstrong,  “Despite  a  Deal,  More  Roadblocks  Ahead  for  Health  Bill,”  CQ  Weekly,  December  14,  2009,  p.  2884.  

Page 19: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  18  

receive  majority  support,  and  so  were  eager  to  expedite  action.    With  no  complaints  from  the  Republicans,  the  Democratic  leadership  moved  to  table  amendment  after  amendment.    The  outcome  was  not  in  doubt  on  any  vote.  

  In  the  first  two  cases,  and  many  others,  the  majority  leader  sought  to  firmly  control  time  so  that  the  minority  could  not  offer  dilatory  amendments  and  motions  as  part  of  a  large  effort  to  obstruct  the  agenda  of  the  majority  party.      The  effect  of  time  agreements  in  both  cases  was  to  reduce  or  eliminate  uncertainty  about  the  time  required  to  consider  and  vote  on  amendments  and  the  bill  and  to  eliminate  efficiency  as  a  motivation  for  the  use  of  the  motion  to  table.    Cloture  mattered.    In  the  first  case,  without  cloture,  the  majority  leader  had  little  bargaining  leverage  with  the  minority,  had  to  accommodate  minority  amendments,  and  yet  insisted  on  proceeding  with  a  structured  process  that  reduced  the  risk  that  the  minority  could  start  a  filibuster  that  he  could  not  end.    In  the  second  case,  with  the  votes  for  cloture,  the  majority  leader  could  exhaust  all  time  before  key  votes  by  filling  the  amendment  tree,  which  gave  him  leverage  to  negotiate  consideration  of  a  limited  number  of  amendments  that  posed  no  threat  to  his  bill.  

Nearly  40  percent  of  all  amendments  subject  to  a  motion  to  table  in  the  111th  Congress  were  Republican  amendments  on  the  health  care  reform  reconciliation  bill.    It  was  the  only  legislation  in  the  Congress  subject  to  ten  or  more  amendments  that  was  not  subject  to  a  unanimous  consent  agreement  that  limited  the  number  of  and  debate  on  amendments.    Nearly  all  significant  amending  activity  occurred  with  a  time  agreement  that  reduced  the  need  for  motions  to  table.    This  practice,  a  majority  response  to  minority  obstructionism,  is  new  to  recent  Congresses.  

 Conclusion  

    The  evidence  that  the  motion  to  table  is  used  to  gain  additional  influence  over  outcomes  on  amendments  is  weak.    Previous  studies  that  show  that  outcomes  on  motions  to  table  amendments  are  related  to  the  party  identity  of  amendment  and  motion  to  table  sponsors,  but  the  evidence  of  a  difference  in  party  influence  on  individual  senators  for  amendment  and  motion  to  table  votes  remains  elusive.    To  be  sure,  demonstrating  electoral  consequences  and  party  influence  on  individual  senators  is  difficult—and  has  challenged  political  scientists  for  decades  (Smith  2007)—but  we  are  obligated  to  question  intuitive  propositions  for  which  we  have  alternative  accounts.  

  Moreover,  the  wide  historical  variance  in  the  use  of  the  motion  to  table  suggests  that  majority  party  leaders  have  not  viewed  the  procedural  motion  to  table  as  essential.    To  the  contrary,  a  simpler  account  that  emphasizes  the  efficiency  gains  of  expeditiously  disposing  of  amendments  appears  to  fit  the  historical  record  better  than  an  account  that  emphasizes  the  acquisition  of  extra  party  influence  on  procedural  motions.    When  time  constraints  became  more  severe  in  the  1970s,  leaders  turned  to  motions  to  table  with  greater  frequency.  

Page 20: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  19  

  Rather  than  serving  as  a  source  of  Senate  majority  party  influence  that  parallels  the  House  majority  party’s  control  of  the  amending  process  through  special  rules,  the  motion  to  table  may  be  a  symptom  of  the  fundamental  disease  the  Senate  majority  party’s  suffer.    The  Senate  majority  party’s  leadership  lacks  control  over  the  issues  forced  to  a  vote  under  the  standing  rules.    For  most  legislation,  the  right  of  first  recognition  does  not  allow  the  majority  leader  to  avoid  unfriendly  amendments  except  by  unanimous  consent  or  by  gaining  cloture  and  filling  the  amendment  tree.    Obstructionism  and  a  flood  of  amendments  is  a  common  condition  for  the  Senate  majority,  which  often  responds  by  trying  to  abbreviate  debate  on  amendments  through  motions  to  table.        

The  historical  pattern  supports  the  view  that  efficiency,  not  vote  acquisition,  is  the  primary  motivation  for  the  frequent  use  of  the  motion  to  table  as  the  means  of  disposing  of  amendments.    Smith  (1989)  observes  that  the  surge  in  amending  activity  in  the  1970s  yielded  an  increase  in  the  percentage  of  amendments  subject  to  a  voice  vote.    We  now  see  that  the  motion  to  table  became  a  regular  tool  of  senators  at  the  same  time.    When  minority  obstructionism  became  a  more  serious  problem  in  recent  Congresses,  majority  leaders  turned  to  new  tactics  in  managing  floor  time  that  reduced  the  need  to  employ  motions  to  table.    This  pattern  of  surge  and  decline  appears  to  be  better  explained  by  the  need  to  manage  time  than  the  need  to  buy  votes.  

  We  conclude  that  the  Senate  majority  party  is  a  far  weaker  cartel  than  its  House  counterpart.    The  use  of  motions  to  table  amendments  reflects  this  weakness.    Reliance  on  them  represents  the  lack  of  viable  and  more  effective  alternatives;  they  are  not  comparable  to  House  special  rules.    Senators  are  not  liberated  of  political  pressure  on  motions  to  table.    Motions  to  table  yield  little  special  party  influence  over  amendments  and  have  been  a  staple  of  floor  action  only  since  the  1970s.        

 

   

Page 21: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  20  

References  

Alchian,  A.  and  H.  Demsetz.  1972.  "Production,  Information  Costs,  and  Economic  Organization."  American  Economic  Review  62:777-­‐795.

Arnold,  R.  Douglas.  1990.  The  Logic  of  Congressional  Action.  New  Haven:  Yale  University  Press.  

Binder,  Sarah  and  Steven  S.  Smith.  1997.  Politics  or  Principle:    Filibustering  in  the  Senate.  Washington,  D.C.:  Brookings  Institution  Press.  

Carson,  Jamie  L.,  Anthony  J.  Madonna,  and  Mark  E.  Owens.  2011.  "Defensive  Agenda  Control:    The  Evoluation  of  Tabling  Motions  in  the  U.S.  Senate,  1865-­‐1947."    Paper  delivered  at  the  Annual  Meeting  of  the  Southern  Political  Science  Association.  New  Orleans,  LA.  

Clausen,  Aage.  1973.  How  Congressmen  Decide.  New  York:  St.  Martin's  Press.  

Cox,  Gary  W.  and  Mathew  D.  McCubbins.  2002.  "Agenda  Power  in  the  US  House  of  Representatives,  1877-­‐1986."  in  Parties,  Procedure  and  Policy:  Essays  on  the  History  of  Congress,  edited  by  D.  B.  a.  M.  McCubbins.  Stanford:  Stanford  University  Press.  

Cox,  Gary  W.  and  Mathew  D.  McCubbins.  2005.  Setting  the  Agenda:  Responsible  Party  Government  in  the  U.S.House  of  Representatives.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Cox,  Gary  W.  and  Mathew  D.  McCubbins.  2007.  Legislative  Leviathan  :  Party  Government  in  the  House.  Cambridge  ;  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Gamm,  Gerald  and  Steven  S.  Smith.  2001.  "The  Dynamics  of  Party  Government  in  Congress."  in  Congress  Reconsidered,  edited  by  L.  Dodd  and  B.  Oppenheimer.  Washington,  D.C.:  CQ  Press.  

Jenkins,  Jeffrey  A.  and  Charles    Stewart  III.  forthcoming.  Fighting  for  the  Speakership.  Princeton,  NJ:  Princeton  University  Press.  

King,  Aaron  S.,  Frank  J.  Orlando,  and  David  W.  Rohde.  2010.  "Beyond  Motions  to  Table:  Exploring  the  Procedural  Toolkit  of  the  Majority  Party  in  the  United  States  Senate."  paper  delivered  at  the  Annual  Meeting  of  the  Midwest  Political  Science  Association.  Chicago,  IL.  

Kingdon,  John  W.  1973.  Congressmen's  Voting  Decisions.  New  York:  Harper  and  Row.  

 Marshall,  Bryan  W.,  Brandon  C.  Prins,  and  David  W.  Rohde.  1999.  "Fighting  Fire  with  Water:    Partisan  Procedural  Strategies  and  the  Senate  Appropriations  Committee."  Congress  and  the  Presidency  26:114-­‐132.  

Matthews,  Donald  R.  and  James  A.  Stimson.  1975.  Yeas  and  nays  :  normal  decision-­‐making  in  the  U.S.  House  of  Representatives.  New  York:  Wiley.  

Page 22: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  21  

Monroe,  Nathan  W.  and  Chris  Den  Hartog.  2008.  "Agenda  Influence  and  Tabling  Motions  in  the  U.S.  Senate."  in  Why  Not  Parties?,  edited  by  N.  W.  Monroe,  J.  M.  Roberts,  and  D.  W.  Rohde.  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press.  

Rohde,  David  W.  1991.  Parties  and  Leaders  in  the  Postreform  House.  Chicago:  University  of  Chicago  Press.  

Sinclair,  Barbara.  1983.  Majority  Leadership  in  the  U.S.  House.  Baltimore:  Johns  Hopkins  University  Press.  

Sinclair,  Barbara.  1989.  The  Transformation  of  the  U.S.  Senate.  Baltimore:  Johns  Hopkins  University  Press.  

Sinclair,  Barbara.  2002.  "Do  Parties  Matter?"  Pp.  36-­‐63  in  Party,  Process,  and  Political  Change  in  Congress,  edited  by  D.  W.  Brady  and  M.  D.  Mccubbins.  Stanford:  Stanford  University  Press.  

Smith,  Steven  S.  2010.  "The  Senate  Syndrome."  in  Issues  in  Governance  Studies,  Brookings  Institution.  

Smith,  Steven  S.  and  Christopher  J.  Deering.  1984.  Committees  in  Congress.  Washington,  D.C.:  CQ  Press.  

Wawro,  Gregory  and  Eric  Schickler.  2006.  Filibuster  :  Obstruction  and  Lawmaking  in  the  U.S.  Senate.  Princeton,  NJ:  Princeton  University  Press.  

 

 

   

Page 23: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  22  

 

 

 

   

   

-1-.8-.6-.4-.2

0.2.4.6.81

Diffe

renc

e in

Pro

porti

on

1970 1980 1990 2000 2010Year

ADA Ratings ACU RatingsNote: Difference between the proportion of all votes on motions to table amendments and all votes on amendments included in group rating.

Motion to Table Votes in ADA and ACU Ratings, 1970-2008.Figure 1. Difference in the Representation of Amendment and

Page 24: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  23  

   

 

 

0

100

200

300

400

1949 1959 1969 1979 1989 1999 2009First Year of Congress

Source: Roll-call vote codebooks, Voteview.com.

Figure 3. Number of Motions to Table Amendments, 1949-2010.

0

200

400

600

800

1969 1971 1973 1975 1977 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007

and First Year of Congress, 1969-2008.Figure 4. Number of Amendments, by Method of Disposition

Amendment, Agreed to Amendment, RejectedMotion to Table, Agreed to Motion to Table, RejectedBudget Waiver, Agreed to Budget Waiver, Rejected

Page 25: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  24  

 

 

 

standard deviation = distance between shaded lines

dark lines: absolute value of difference of percent yea and percent nay

0

20

40

60

80

100

91 93 95 97 99 101 103 105 107 109Congress

Motions to Table Amendments Amendments

Motions to Table Amendments, 1969-2008.Figure 5. Mean Vote Margin for Amendments and

Page 26: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  25  

 

0 50 100 0 50 100 0 50 100 0 50 100 0 50 100

1969-1970 1971-1972 1973-1974 1975-1976 1977-1978

1979-1980 1981-1982 1983-1984 1985-1986 1987-1988

1989-1990 1991-1992 1993-1994 1995-1996 1997-1998

1999-2000 2001-2002 2003-2004 2005-2006 2007-2008

Motions to Table Amendments Amendments

x

Note: Kernel density plots for vote margin (absolute difference between percent yea and percent nay). Reference line at 10 (55-45).

Figure 6. Distribution of Vote Margins, by Type of Vote and Congress.

Page 27: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  26  

 

   

   

0

.01

.02

.03

.04

.05

dens

ity

0 20 40 60 80 100Margin (Percent Yea - Percent Nay)

motions to waive Budget Act amendmentsmotions to table amendments

Note: Kernel density distribution. Reference line at 10 (55-45).

Figure 7. Distribution of Vote Margins, by Type of Vote, 1995-2008.

0

20

40

60

80

1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010First Year of Congress

Note: Measures associated with Congressional Quarterly key votes, excluding nominations and treaties.

Subject to a Cloture Petition, 1961-2010.Figure 8. Percent of Key-Vote Measures

Page 28: Smith Ostrander Pope June 2011 - Brown University · 2011-06-03 · ! 4! partylabelshavebeenorganized!through!most!of!the!Senate’s!history!and!exhibit! certainsharedelectoralandpolicygoals,likeHouseparties

  27  

     

 Table  1.    Estimates  of  the  Effect  of  Vote  Type  on  Support  for  the  Position  of  the  

Senate  Majority  Leader,  Majority  Party  Senators,1969-­‐2010.    intercept   1.636***  

(0.013)  cloture  vote   -­‐0.102***  

(0.027)  final  passage  vote   0.120***  

(0.047)  motion  to  table  amendment   0.026  

(0.016)    distance  from  majority  leader   -­‐3.137***  

(0.068)  ***  p  >  0.001;    motion  to  table  amendment:    p  >  0.05.  Estimates  for  majority  party  senators  on  contested  votes  (55-­‐45  or  closer).    Missing  vote  category:  direct  vote  on  amendment.      GLM  estimates;  AIC:  121550.  Source:    Senate  roll-­‐call  votes.    voteview.com.    

0

200

400

600

800

91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110

Parliamentary Situation, and Congress, 1969-2008.Figure 9. Number of Amendments, by Method of Disposition,

Am., No Cloture MtT, No ClotureAm., Cloture MtT, Cloture