rural electrification in indonesia: can the benefits of ... · 2 bottlenecks. this has left rural...

32
Rural Electrification in Indonesia: Can the Benefits of Micro Hydro Trickle Down to Rural Communities? A Case Study of Nias Island [DRAFT] Energy Economics & Policy Prof T. Rutherford Ratri Sryantoro 10-938-976

Upload: others

Post on 20-Sep-2019

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Rural Electrification in Indonesia:

Can the Benefits of Micro Hydro

Trickle Down to Rural Communities?

A Case Study of Nias Island

[DRAFT]

Energy Economics & Policy

Prof T. Rutherford

Ratri Sryantoro

10-938-976

1

1 Introduction

Over the past decade, Indonesia has shown remarkable growth following the deep financial crisis

which affected most of Asia during the period of 1997 – 1998. Recently, Indonesia’s economy again

proved its resilience in escaping relatively unscathed following the global financial crisis charting

phenomenal GDP growth rates of 6.2% in 2010, boosting it to become the region’s largest economy

1. However, this rapid growth did not come without a price. Despite increasing GDP levels, the

electricity sector has been unable to keep up with the rapidly growing demand. In the past five

years, the demand of electricity has grown by 6% across the country. In contrast, the aggregate

electricity generation capacity has only grown by 2% over the same period.

The state-owned power utility Perusahaan Listrik Negara (PLN) currently places Indonesia’s

electrification ratio at only 65%. This figure is amongst the lowest in the South East Asia region

(Jayawerdana & et al., 2005). In 2005, the World Bank with the Government of Indonesia (GOI)

commissioned a study to identify options for increasing electricity access in Indonesia. The report

identified three significant barriers to achieving a higher electrification: inability to recover costs of

distribution, lack of financing sources, and coordination and process streamlining (Jayawerdana & et

al., 2005).

To eradicate the nation’s energy poverty, the GOI has set an ambitious target of reaching an

electrification ratio of 90% by 2020. Many are sceptical of how realistic this is, given the vast spatial

dispersion of its population across 17,000 islands. Much of the population still live in remote rural

areas that are currently serviced by low-voltage (20kV) power lines. Such infrastructures are typically

very susceptible to adverse weather conditions, and they provide a poor quality of supply (Haanyika,

2005) . Furthermore, out of 70,192 villages across the country, 6,200 villages are technically very

difficult to reach through grid extension (Kusidana, 2008).

Rural electrification has long been a thorny issue in the electricity sector in Indonesia. The financial

strain on PLN due to the ballooning cost issues, has greatly limited their capacity to invest in high

capital cost projects with low economies of scale, such as rural electrification. In 2001, following a

corporate restructure the rural electrification division was disbanded. To worsen the matter, policy

landscape in the electricity sector is currently in a state of flux following a failed attempt to liberalize

the electricity market in 2002 (Jayawerdana & et al., 2005).

Most of PLN’s capital works projects are now focussed towards increasing generation capacity and

upgrading the busiest transmission grids in Java, Bali and Sumatra which often experience

1 Indonesia’s 2009 GDP is $540.7 billion according to The World Bank figures

2

bottlenecks. This has left rural electrification projects to be completed by various NGOs in a rather

ad hoc manner, without nationwide co-ordination. So, the critical question is, if high cost is the

primary barrier to rural electrification, is there an optimal mix of technologies that can be deployed

to ensure the least cost electrification program?

This paper aims to investigate the costs of achieving the 90% electrification target by 2020 based on

three options for rural electrification. These options include: grid extension, off-grid generation and

household solution using battery charging (Siemons, 2001). As a case study, we will look at a small-

scale example of rural electrification strategies and costs, based on the Island of Nias located in

North Sumatra province. The island was severely damaged by the 2004 tsunami and earthquake

events. The local government has spent much of the last 6 years rebuilding its infrastructure, but

power deficit remains the main barrier for inhabitants to return to their income-generating business

activities. We will focus on micro hydropower as an option for off-grid generation given presence of

large number of rivers across the island. Furthermore, the Ministry of Energy & Mineral Resources

claimed that there are 450MW potential for micro hydro power across Indonesia and have recently

identified it as a favoured solution for rural electrification (Kusidana, 2008).

In Section 2 a brief background on the electricity sector in Indonesia and the state of rural

electrification is presented. We visit the key challenges of rural electrification and possible

technological solutions. We also look into the potential of micro hydropower and its suitability for

remote area generation. In Section 3, we analyse the key needs of electricity sectors in Nias Island

and discuss previous studies concerning potential for micro hydropower generation in the area. We

then present a simplified economic model for calculating the lowest cost options for electrification

of Nias in Section 4. Section 5 will present a discussion of the results. Finally, Section 6 concludes

with a summary of the key findings, drawbacks and limitations of the study and recommendation for

future studies.

2 Background

2.1 Electrification in Indonesia: the enormous task of providing access to

230 million across 17,000 islands

In Indonesia, the 1945 State Constitution regulates that all vital utilities concerning the greater

population must be controlled by the state. Since 1985, the electricity sector in Indonesia is

controlled by the state-owned power utility business Perusahaan Listrik Negara (PLN). After its

formation, PLN became the sole responsible body for the provision of electricity across Indonesia.

3

The Ministry of Energy & Mineral Resources serves as the policy making body and regulator for PLN.

However, other ministries within the GOI also serve as stakeholders providing different governing

and support functions. In a bid to boost electricity generation capacity to keep up with demand

growth, the GOI recently opened up the generation market for competition. Independent Power

Producers can now produce electricity, but are required to sell the electricity back to PLN for

distribution. Figure 1 shows the schematic of key players in the Indonesian electricity sector.

Despite having significantly developed its generation, transmission and distribution network over the

years, the national electricity network remains significantly strained. Growth in generation capacity

has been unable to keep up with electricity demand growth. Since 2009, the Java-Bali transmission

grid is particularly congested, leading to “transmission bottlenecks” which often forced PLN to

impose rolling blackouts across the two islands.

Today, with an electrification ratio of 65%, more than 70 million people still do not have access to

reliable and affordable electricity services (Jayawerdana & et al., 2005). Of this figure 80% reside in

rural areas and almost all live outside of the most populated islands, Java and Bali. Figure 2 shows a

clear evidence of this situation, where the northern and eastern parts of Indonesia are particularly

suffering from lack of access to electricity.

Despite having these official figures, it has been very difficult to quantify the real progress in rural

villages only since the disbandment of PLN’s rural electricity division. The Ministry of Energy &

Mineral Resources maintains that only 16.7% of rural villages have no electricity access. However,

the definition of ‘electrified’ means that at least one location within the villages are connected to

PLN’s low voltage grid. A clearer indication of true electrification ratio would be the number of

electrified households. Unfortunately to date this data has been unavailable.

4

Figure 1. Key players in the Indonesian Electricity Sector (Source: DE&P, 2008)

Figure 2 Percentage of electrification ratio per province (Source: DE&P, 2008)

.

2.2 Key challenges in Indonesia’s rural electrification

2.2.1 Oil Domination

One of the primary challenges in Indonesia’s energy sector is overcoming its high level of oil

dependency. Over the past three decades, the government has provided significant fuel subsidies in

a bid to increase access to cheap fuel to the whole population. This has resulted in the current

primary energy mix which is heavily dependent on oil (52.5% of primary energy source). Not only

5

does this subsidy come at a high cost ($11.5b per year it also discourages fuel efficiency and can

hamper the development and uptake of renewable energy technologies.

The negative effects of Indonesia’s reliance on fuel subsidies are clearly present in the electricity

sector. The current national generation capacity sits at 30,320 MW. 35% of these facilities are fossil

fuel thermal power plants located on the six main islands and fuelled by oil, coal and natural gas

(PLN data 2007). Smaller scale oil-fired diesel power plants are typically used in rural areas due to its

compactness and low investment costs. Despite their low efficiency and negative environmental

impact, diesel power plants remain the most attractive option given the levels of fuel subsidy. With

such high dependency on oil and petroleum products for energy generation, PLN’s operating costs

have blown up in recent years due to steady increases in oil prices.

2.2.2 Lack of investments

Lack of energy services often correlates with poverty particularly in rural areas. It hinders people

from performing efficient income generating activities, which may help break the poverty cycle

(Kemmler, 2006). This is reinforced by the lack of financing from PLN, and their inability to

incentivise the private sector to invest in the electricity sector.

Prior to the Asian financial crisis, PLN enjoyed full financial support from the government and were

still generating profits. This allowed PLN to significantly invest in high capital cost investments such

as rural electrification. Post crisis, government investments were significantly reduced yet PLN are

still obliged to maintain a positive margin as a corporation2. Under such constraints, PLN was forced

to disband non-profitable investments such as access maximization and rural electrification. PLN’s

current investments are primarily focussed on projects aimed at loss minimization in its existing

grids, mainly in Java, Bali and Sumatra. As a result, investments in rural electrification have taken a

back seat for many years and have only marginally improved from 60% in 2000 to 65% in 2010.

2.2.3 Inability to Recover Costs of Distribution

PLN’s largest issue to date still remains its inability to recover costs of distribution. Electricity theft,

low labour productivities and inefficient aging grid infrastructure are the main contributors towards

PLN’s growing losses.

In a bid to make electricity affordable to the greater population, the Ministry of Energy & Mineral

Resources set a low uniform tariff structure set (US$0.06 per kWh in 2010). However, given the

lower demand and customer densities in rural areas particularly outside of the Java-Bali grid, the

2 Under GOI Law 19/2003, State-Owned Enterprises must operate on a commercial basis and make a profit.

6

cost of distributing electricity in these areas is much higher than the set tariffs. These factors have

resulted in unsustainable revenue levels which are insufficient to cover PLN’s costs of distribution.

2.3 Moving forward: legislations and targets

The GOI recently set the 90% electrification target by 2020, as a subset of Vision 2025: Building New

Indonesia strategy3. To achieve this target, a clear framework needs to be implemented to reform

the electricity sector away from the PLN’s current inefficient and financially unsustainable business

model. To support this vision, a number of regulations have been in issued as a policy framework in

achieving this target.

Appendix 1 outlines a summary of current regulations relevant to rural electrification. The first key

piece of legislation was the (now annulled) Law 20/2002, which attempted to pursue the unbundling

of PLN’s services to introduce competition into the electricity sector. Following its annulment, this

was replaced by the Government Regulation 26/2006 which is a ‘reduced’ version of the previous

law, to allow local government and private parties to participate in rural electrification efforts.

In conjunction with 26/2006, under the Ministerial Decrees 1122/2002, 01/2006 and 02/2006, small

cooperatives and local enterprises are now permitted to operate small-scale (<1MW) and medium-

scale (up to 10MW) power plants and sell the produced electricity to PLN for distribution. However,

these regulations still do very little in incentivising private parties to participate. According to the

pricing structure under these decrees, PLN is only obliged to purchase the power at 80% utility

production cost when the plant is connected to medium voltage network and 60% when connected

to low voltage network.

Despite having not yet published a decree focusing on rural electrification, in 2008 the Ministry of

Energy & Mineral Resources published a draft Rural Electrification Program which proposes

guidelines for off-grid electrification in rural areas (Kusidana, 2008). The program proposes that

moving forward:

• The proportion of diesel power plant in rural electrification is to be reduced and priority is to

be given to locally available renewable energy resources specifically microhydro, wind and

solar photovoltaic

• Central and Local government are obliged provide a budget for rural electrification, including

establishment of local institutions to carry out operation and maintenance of plants

3 Vision 2025 Building New Indonesia is a long-term development plan published by the National Development

Planning Agency (Bappenas). It lists a set of targets to achieve by 2025 focusing in the areas of economics,

poverty eradication, and equal access to vital utilities across the nation.

7

• The GOI will commit a budget of US$43m towards renewables based rural electrification

Furthermore, the Directorate General of Electricity and Energy Utilisation are currently carrying out

ongoing discussions regarding financing and tariff structures for rural electrifications.

2.4 Potential for rural electrification

According to (Siemons, 2001) rural electrification is characterised by areas that are remotely located

from large-scale electricity grids and show a need for installation of small power capacities.

Furthermore, the consumers are typically quite dispersed and have low consumption pattern.

Hence, rural electrification generally requires generation facilities to be operated at low load factors

(Haanyika, 2005), with a capacity between 10 – 200kW.

Naturally, there are three options for rural electrification:

• Extension of existing grid. Usually associated with high capital cost and still associated with

electricity theft risks

• Small isolated grid, powered by small-scale generator. This is usually associated with high

initial investment cost, but the lowest ongoing annual maintenance cost and levelised cost

of energy (LCOE). A comparison of different technologies for small-scale local generation

technologies is given in Appendix 2 (Holland & Derbyshire, 2009).

• Provision of batteries at household levels, which can be charged at the local charging station

powered by the small-scale generator

2.4.1 Microhydro power: the perfect small-scale generator for rural communities?

Given the guidelines of the draft Rural Electrification Program, micro hydropower plants (MHPP)

have the potential to become the generator of choice for remote rural communities, as it is a

relatively mature and successful technology. Micro- and pico- hydro plants of various scales (5 –

100kW) have successfully been installed globally, particularly in rural communities in developing

countries such as China, Nepal, Vietnam and many South American countries. Hence, MHPP is

associated with a lower perception of investment risks and has the potential to attract a larger

number of investors than other generation technologies.

MHPP has the advantage of reducing the dependency on fossil fuels and reducing the negative

environmental and health effects associated with use of diesel power plants. It has relatively low

technological and infrastructure requirements as it does not require dam or reservoir storage as it

relies on minimal water flow typically available all year round. Construction of MHPP is also

8

relatively simple compared to larger hydro power plants, as it can be done by manual labour without

the need for complex engineering equipment or access roads to the site.

A typical size MHPP is 100kW and can be operated at low capacity factor, but would still be sufficient

to meet the electricity demand of an average Indonesian village 4. Furthermore, UNDP has identified

that Indonesia would have a capacity of 458MW, and only 4% has of this figure has been harvested

(UNDP Indonesia, 2009). . These theoretical figures make MHPP an attractive choice for use as small-

scale generator to serve both as an isolated grid and battery charging station. This paper aims to

assess the economic feasibility of constructing MHPPs at the identified potential sites and whether

it makes economic sense to solely rely on MHPPs for rural electrification? If not, what is the best

technology mix that will minimise the total cost of electrification to a rural community given the

spread of their location?

3 Nias Island: a case study

3.1 Rebuilding after the tsunami

Nias is the largest Island in a group of islands located off the west coast of Sumatra. It falls under the

jurisdiction of the North Sumatra province and is divided into two administrative areas: Nias and

South Nias. The island is home to 711,976 people living across its 21 regions. Following the

2004/2005 Boxing Day earthquake and tsunami events, Nias suffered extensive destruction with at

least 80% of its already weak infrastructure damaged (Bureau of Statistics of Indonesia, 2005).

The primary industries in Nias include agriculture (rubber and palm oil), livestock farming, tourism,

and fishery – all of which are dependent on electricity supply for production. Nias has long been

known internationally as a prominent cultural tourist and surfing destination. Hence following the

tsunami, a large number of international agencies poured into the island to aid reconstruction

efforts. Much has been achieved in the past six years, but yet thousands still live in refugee camps

throughout the island. The remoteness of the island proves to be the greatest challenge for the

reconstruction process, as supply of construction materials are difficult to obtain. Furthermore,

there is insufficient road network across the island preventing access to many of the damaged

villages.

Nias Island was selected as a case example for this paper due to a number of factors:

• The remoteness of the island allows a proper analysis of an ‘isolated electricity network’;

4 According to (Holland & Derbyshire, 2009) a typical Indonesian village would contain 155 households and

require 225kWh of electricity per day.

9

• There is scope to test the optimal reconstruction scenario since most of its electricity

infrastructure was damaged due to the 2005 earthquake;

• Reasonable amount of data is publicly accessible for the purposes of this study.

Figure 3 Nias Island geography and electricity supply profile

3.2 Current electricity grid

The PLN electricity network in Nias is split into two grids: Nias and South Nias, as depicted in Figure

3. The Nias grid is supplied by a diesel power plant located in the capital Gunung Sitoli (4.5MW),

whereas the South Nias grid is supplied by another diesel power plant in Teluk Dalam (2.3MW). The

electrification statistics in Nias Island are as follows:

Area Number of

cities / villages

Number of

households

Village electrification

ratio

Total electrification

ratio

Nias 443 83,276 70.33% 60.85%

South Nias 214 50,873 48.37% 59.06%

Table 1 Electrification statistics in Nias Island (PLN North Sumatra, 2007)

Nias is currently experiencing power deficit of 6.4 MW as the generation facilities are unable to meet

demand. The primary issue faced by PLN Nias is its inability to recover costs, caused by (Nias Online,

2008):

• Growing cost of maintenance on aging infrastructure as both plants have now been

operating for 30 years 5

5 Commercial lifetime is typically 18 years

10

• Increasing fuel costs due to increasing oil price, amounting to US$1m per month

• Electricity theft and a large number of customers that are unable to make electricity bill

payments, resulting in a monthly revenue of just US$250,000 6.

In 2008, PLN Nias was forced to start implementing rolling blackouts across the island. Total

blackouts across the island often occurred whenever any maintenance activities or equipment

outages were carried out. This significantly damaged the economy of Nias as many small businesses

were unable to maintain levels of income-generating production capacity. Some businesses reverted

to purchasing dirty and expensive diesel generators in order to maintain their electricity supply. As a

temporary quick fix, in 2010 PLN Nias engaged with Independent Power Producers to purchase

additional 8 MW of generation capacity. Additionally, PLN’s 2010 – 2019 capital expenditure plan

includes the addition of 2 x 3 MW coal-fired power plant in South Nias to accommodate for demand

growth. (PLN , 2010)

Electricity throughout the island is distributed using low-voltage (20 kV) power lines. The existing

transmission grid is depicted in Figure 4. It is visible that the grid in the South Nias and western parts

of Nias is still very sparse. Furthermore, with lack of access roads in these areas it is technically very

difficult for PLN to extend the existing grid.

6 However, typically a grace period of 3 months is still given before disconnection, thus accruing a backlog of

losses for PLN

11

Figure 4 Electricity Distribution Map in Nias Island

3.3 MHPP in Nias

With hundreds of rivers with sufficient heads flowing through the island and an annual rainfall of

2,930mm, Nias has great potential for installation of MHPP across the island to provide independent

local generation for remote rural communities. A study commissioned by UNIDO 2005 identified

potential sources for MHPP location at 11 points along rivers across the island (United Nations

Industrial Development Organisation, 2005) 7. Figure 5 shows the locations of these sites.

7 A feasibility study of four sites confirmed potential of 242 kW. A conservative estimate of the potential

generation capacity of the other seven sites is approximately 340 kW.

12

Figure 5 Identified potential locations for run-of-the-river micro hydro power plants in Nias Island

4 Model Specification

4.1 Analysis Framework

While efforts to maximise rural electricity access have long been undermined by PLN due to its

commercial unattractiveness, the GOI’s ambitious 90% target by 2020 has finally called for attention

to tackle this issue. Combined with the energy sector’s urgent need to reduce dependency on oil as

energy source, there is a real scope to finally propel the adoption of MHPP as small-scale generator

in rural communities and increase rural electrification ratio.

13

The objective of this analysis is to recommend a feasible power generation strategy to achieve 90%

electrification across Nias Island. The first analysis will look into the possible cost structures of the

island electrification, given the three options of electrification outlined in Section 2.4. For each of the

village to be electrified, they have to face the trade-off between the benefits of grid extension (lower

investment cost / higher operating cost), and MHPP (higher investment cost / lower operating cost).

Our hypothesis is that as costs of grid extension becomes too high with increasing distance, the cost

of generation with MHPP becomes more favourable and the villages will select the MHPP option. .

The objective function of this analysis is to minimise the aggregate cost of connection for all the

villages subject to the constraints of total available capacity from PLN generators, total available

capacity from all identified MHPP sites, and requirement to satisfy at least 90% of electricity demand

in the island. Several scenarios varying the capacity parameters are also carried out to observe the

model’s sensitivity.

In the second part of the analysis, we incorporate the household’s utility of consuming electricity

into the electrification strategy decision. The objective function here is to maximise relative utility of

consumption8, given their level of consumption or non-consumption

Due to the lack of data on household level, some assumptions needed to be made:

• Firstly, it is assumed that we only consider a scenario where a complete overhaul for the

electricity supply network in Nias is possible. We have not accounted a scenario where

households or villages that are already electrified can switch between types of generators.

• Secondly, as household data for electricity demand profile is also unavailable, the willingness

to pay for demanded electricity amount will be an exogenous variable arbitrarily assigned

depending on the size of villages 9.

• Thirdly, we assume that all present power plants, planned projects and MHPPs at previously

identified sites will be built. This assumption is further discussed in Section 4.2

• Finally, we have only assumed a one year scenario and have not included provision of

demand of growth or costs.

This electrification cost minimisation model should allow for a feasibility assessment on what would

be the best strategy for Nias’ electrification, by optimally selecting the right mix of electrification

options. The results of this model should be able to provide an insight of the significance of MHPP in

this electrification mix, and to what extent they can be utilised.

8 Relative utility of consumption is defined as utility of consumption of electricity per unit consumed [kW].

9 There will be two types of villages (small and large) based on the number of population, with each type of

village having a particular demand profile

14

4.2 Capacity constraints

The capacity constrains assume the available generation facilities available for the period of model

analysis are outlined in Table 2. We assume that all planned additional generation work and all

identified potential sites for MHPP will be realised.

Power Plant Capacity Owner Status

Diesel PP – Gunung SItoli 4.5 MW PLN Operating

Diesel PP – Teluk Dalam 2.3 MW PLN Operating

Diesel PP – Gunung Sitoli 5 MW IPP Lease (assume until 2020)

Diesel PP – Teluk Dalam 3 MW IPP Lease (assume until 2020)

Thermal PP (Coal) - Simanere 6 MW PLN In PLN’s capital expenditure plan for

2012 (PLN Sumatera Utara, 2010)

Total Capacity from PLN Grid 20.8 MW

MHPP – Nias & South Nias 0.6 MW PLN Feasibility studies completed

Total Capacity from Isolated Grid 0.6 MW

Total generation capacity for Nias 21.4 MW

Table 2 Assumed total generation capacity available to Nias Island

We will denote these capacity constraints as the following:

�����: is total capacity of all fossil fuel power plants (diesel and coal) [kW]

���� : is the capacity of MHPP j [kW]

���� = ∑ ��������� : is the total MHPP capacity of the island from all 11 identified sites [kW]

4.3 Demand profile for electricity

Using guidelines from studies of rural electrification in Laos and Phillipines, we create a demand

function based on the village size, assuming that villages with larger population are likely to have

higher demand for electricity as they have more access and need to non-critical electronic goods 10

(World Bank IEG, 2008). Therefore we assume demand per household ����������is given by:

���������� �65���ℎ !"#$%&ℎ', )* $ +,-&)$% ≥ 80042���ℎ !"#$%&ℎ', )* $ +,-&)$% < 800

We can thus deduce a total demand per village which is given by:

10

The most critical electronic good is lighting. The most common non critical electronic goods are TV, fan, rice

cooker, mobile phones.

15

��: total annual demand in village i based on the number of households annually (kW)

4$ � : population of village i

Assuming that each household consists of 5 people, we have �� = ��567 ∙ ���������� ∙ 12.We will

assess demand for the entire island which consists of n villages. Furthermore, for simplicity we

assume that each household uses electricity for 4 hours per day on average.

4.4 Cost of electrification options

The cost assumptions in this analysis rely on estimates from a study of rural electrification in four

provinces in Indonesia by (Holland & Derbyshire, 2009). We will use “Levellised Cost of Energy”

(LCOE) as a normalised measure of electricity cost for different electrification options. LCEO allows

for evaluation of life-cycle energy cost and life cycle energy production. It can be used to directly

compare the alternative technologies with different operating time, investment cost and scale of

operation. The cost of using each electrification option is then defined by LCEO multiplied by the

quantity consumed (;�) by the village using that electrification option, measured in kW.

4.4.1 Option 1: Cost of grid extension

The capital costs of electrifying a village by grid extension will involve upgrading the LV networks and

auxiliary equipment (transformers, service drops and meters). Using figures from (Holland &

Derbyshire, 2009), the LCOE of grid extension (USc/kWh) is a linear function of distance from grid.

Table 3 outlines the LCEO as a function of distance from the power line.

Cost per kwh (USc/ kwh) Distance from main grid (up to x km)

7.1 5

13.9 10

20.7 15

27.4 20

34.2 25

41.0 30

47.7 35

54.5 40

61.3 45

68.0 50

74.8 55 Table 3 LCOE 'ladder' for electrification cost by grid extension

Therefore, we have the following parameters:

<�=>6? is the total cost of connecting village i by means of grid extension, which already includes

production and distribution costs

16

@�=>6? is the perpendicular distance between village i and power line [km]

A<BC�����@�=>6?' is the LCOE for grid extension (USc/kWh), as a function of distance @�=>6?

This results in the grid extension cost equation

<�=>6? = A<BC���� D@�=>6?E ∙ ;�=>6? (1)

4.4.2 Option 2: Cost of micro hydro

Using a 14.7 kW micro hydro generator unit, we assume the LCOE is 15.9 USc/kWh. This assumes a

capital cost of US$37,852 and annual cost of US$5,188 (Holland & Derbyshire, 2009). As outlined in

Appendix 2, MHPP is the lowest cost option amongst other isolated grid generator options. We will

ignore the cost of distribution as it is assumed that it is very small compared to the capital and

annual costs. We define A<BC���as the LCOE for MHPP (USc/kWh), we obtain the annual cost

equation for village i using MHPP: Furthermore, to ensure that MHPP are optimally used for local

generation, we introduce a distribution cost which increases as a function of distance from village to

grid (@���).

<��� = A<BC��� ∙ ;��� + 1000@��� (2)

4.4.3 Option 3: Cost of charging battery

For cost estimation of battery charging option, we use guidelines from a study of PV battery charging

station for remote communities in Lao PDR (Asian Institute of Technology, 2005). We assume the

use of 85Ah / 12 V battery for each household, which results in A<BCGHII��J of 35.4 USc/kWh.

Appendix 4 outlines the derivation of LCEO for battery technology. For battery technology we

include an additional constraint that it can only be used by villages located less than 10 km than the

micro hydro power plant, which serves as the charging station. To model this constraint, we use a

step increase in LCOE if distance to the MHPP (@���) exceeds 10 km.

Therefore we derive the cost of electrification using battery as:

<�KLMM = A<BCGHII ∙ ;�KLMM where NA<BCGHII = 0.354, )*@��� ≤ 10A<BCGHII = 0.7, )*@��� > 10 (3)

17

4.5 Model Specification

We are interested in minimising the cost (∑ <�S��� 'of the electrification program. Therefore our

objective function becomes:

T)%)#)U! ∑ <� =S��� ∑ min�<�=>6? , <��� , <�KLMM'S��� (4)

Subject to constraints:

Y;�=>6?S

���+Y;���

S

���+Y;�KLMM

S

���≤Y0.9��

S

���

(5) At least 90% of the island’s total electricity

demand is met

Y;�=>6?S

���≤ ����� (6) Capacity constraint of fossil fuel power plants

Y;���S

���+Y;�KLMM

S

���≤ ���� (7) Capacity constraint of MHPPs

;�=>6? , ;���,;�KLMM ≥ 0 (8) Non-negativity

4.5.1 Scenario 1: Base Case

First we consider a base case scenario with 12 ‘artificial’ villages of Nias with similar population

profile to the real data. Figure 6 shows the illustration of this problem.

Using Excel Non-Linear Solver, we obtain the least cost electrification strategy which can achieve the

90% electrification ratio target, as outlined in Table 4. The least cost strategy involves 8 villages

connected by grid extension and 4 villages connected to MHPPs. This results in a total cost of

$344,097

In total there are 4 villages that can be connected to MHPPs either through an isolated grid

connection or using it as a battery charging station. In this analysis we see that Village #5 will not

have access to electricity, except with the small possibility of obtaining 0.8kW from MHPP1 by using

it as a battery charging station. However this may indicate that there is a potential for Village 5 to be

connected to the isolated grid of MHPP 1 should the plant have increased capacity. We also see that

the capacities of both MHPPs are fully depleted, suggesting that the optimal least-cost option

require the existence of MHPPs.

We specifically chose total generation capacities (1010kW) that is less than the total demand

(1043W) to mimic the current situation in Nias. The results show that with the installation of the two

18

typical – sized MHPPs, 90% of the demand can be met and even leaving remaining capacity on the

PLN grid which can provide a safety margin of operation.

Figure 6 Least Cost Electrification Strategy for Scenario 1

Vi-

llage

#

Population Total

Demand

[kW]

Quantity

Consumed

[kW]

Dist to

Grid [km]

Selected Option Cost of

electrification

[$]

V1 876 75.9 75.9 9.4 Grid Extension 18,995

V2 931 80.7 80.7 13.3 MHPP 1 - battery 51,414

V3 1078 93.4 93.4 18.0 Grid Extension 46,078

V4 340 19.0 19.0 30.2 MHPP 1 –grid 19,069

V5 1213 105.1 0.8 7.5 MHPP 2- battery 527

V6 913 79.1 79.1 14.1 Grid Extension 29,483

V7 2354 204.0 204.0 4.7 Grid Extension 26,073

V8 971 84.2 84.2 26.1 Grid Extension 62,105

V9 1065 92.3 92.3 17.8 Grid Extension 45,522

V10 1420 123.1 123.1 1.1 Grid Extension 15,728

V11 893 77.4 77.4 9.4 MHPP 2 23,725

V12 156 8.7 8.7 22.5 Grid Extension 5,378

TOTAL COST 344,097

19

Generator Capacity [kW] Capacity demanded with least

cost solution [kW]

Fossil fuel plants 830 760.74

MHPP 1 100 99.73

MHPP 2 80 78.22

Total Electricity Demanded [ 1043.0

Total Electricity Consumed [Qi] 938.69

Electrification ratio in area 90%

Table 4 Results with Scenario 1

4.5.2 Scenario 2: Scaling up the MHPP capacities

In this scenario, we attempt to analyse the effects of scaling up of the MHPP capacities on the total

cost. The capacities of MHPPs are doubled from the base scenario and become 200kW and 160kW

respectively. To keep the same capacity constraint as Scenario 1, we have reduced the PLN fossil fuel

plants capacities to 650kW. The least cost solution is illustrated in Figure 7. The full results of the

simulation are given in

Table 5.

We see that more villages have now opted for electrification by connection to the MHPPs (6

villages). We also start to see a pattern whereby grid extension is generally preferred up to about

18km, and from there MHPP becomes the cheaper option 11. One village (Village 3) is still left

unelectrified despite the achievement of 90% target electrification in the area overall.

The least cost option has now increased to $464,984. This indicates that perhaps there still exists

diseconomies of scale with the MHPP technology with increasing capacity. Furthermore, similar to

the base scenario, the capacity of both MHPPs are almost fully exploited, leaving spare capacity in

the fossil fuel plants to allow for a safety margin.

11

An exception is Village 12, where it can be seen that the cheapest option for this village is to connect to the

grid. However we suspect this is caused by the small demand (8.7 kW), and given the very remote geographical

location it is still cheaper to connect to the grid rather than battery charging.

20

Figure 7 Least Cost Electrification Strategy for Scenario 2: Scaling up the MHPP Capacities

Vi-

llage

#

Population Total

Demand

[kW]

Quantity

Consumed

[kW]

Dist to

Grid [km]

Selected Option Cost of

electrification

[$]

V1 876 75.9 73.4 9.4 MHPP 2- battery 92,443

V2 931 80.7 80.7 13.3 Grid Extension 30,064

V3 1078 93.4 0.0 18.0 Grid Extension 0

V4 340 19.0 19.0 30.2 MHPP 1 – grid 19,069

V5 1213 105.1 96.8 7.5 MHPP 1 - battery 121,976

V6 913 79.1 79.1 14.1 Grid Extension 29,483

V7 2354 204.0 204.0 4.7 Grid Extension 26,073

V8 971 84.2 84.2 26.1 MHPP 1 – grid 29,933

V9 1065 92.3 92.3 17.8 Grid Extension 45,522

V10 1420 123.1 123.1 1.1 Grid Extension 15,728

V11 893 77.4 77.4 9.4 MHPP 2 - battery 49,315

V12 156 8.7 8.7 22.5 Grid Extension 5,378

TOTAL COST 464,984

Generator Capacity [kW] Capacity demanded with least

cost solution [kW]

Fossil fuel plants 650 587.93

MHPP 1 200 200.00

MHPP 2 160 150.76

21

Table 5 Results with Scenario 2: Scaling up MHPP capacities

4.5.3 Scenario 3: Observing effect of reduced LCEO

As we suspected that diseconomies of scale with increasing MHPP capacity may still exist, we wish to

analyse the effects of reduced LCEO. This reduction can be attributed from several sources including:

government subsidy, grants from NGOs or other private sources. We assume a reduction of 15% in

LCEO as suggested by (Jayawerdana & et al., 2005). The results are illustrated in Figure 8.

The cost of the optimal solution is now reduced to $331,296, which translates to $352.93/kW

consumed when compared to Scenario 2 [$495.3/kW]. It is also lower compared to the base

scenario with less capacity installed. Therefore we see that by reducing LCEO we can achieve

economies of scale with increasing capacity of MHPP.

Figure 8 Least Cost Electrification Strategy for Scenario 3: Reduced LCOE

22

Vi-

llage

#

Population Total

Demand

[kW]

Quantity

Consumed

[kW]

Dist to

Grid [km]

Selected Option Cost of

electrification

[$]

V1 876 75.9 75.9 9.4 Grid Extension 18,995

V2 931 80.7 80.7 13.3 Grid Extension 30,064

V3 1078 93.4 92.5 18.0 MHPP 1 – grid 47,027

V4 340 19.0 17.1 30.2 MHPP 1 – grid 17,398

V5 1213 105.1 105.1 7.5 Grid Extension 26,303

V6 913 79.1 - 14.1 MHPP 1 – battery -

V7 2354 204.0 204.0 4.7 Grid Extension 26,073

V8 971 84.2 63.7 26.1 MHPP 2 – battery 80,322

V9 1065 92.3 90.4 17.8 MHPP 1 – grid 45,508

V10 1420 123.1 123.1 1.1 Grid Extension 15,728

V11 893 77.4 77.4 9.4 MHPP 2 – grid 18,501

V12 156 8.7 8.7 22.5 Grid Extension 5,378

TOTAL COST 331,296

Generator Capacity [kW] Capacity

demanded with

least cost solution

[kW]

Fossil fuel plants 650 587.93

MHPP 1 200 200.00

MHPP 2 160 150.76

Table 6 Results from Scenario 3

4.6 Utility Maximisation Model

We now incorporate a measure of relative utility of consumption of electricity where we define that

the consumption of the first unit of electricity is much larger than the subsequent units. The model’s

objective function is then to maximise the aggregate utility of consumption of electricity for the

entire area. We will use relative utility as a measure of consumption (utility per kW consumed).

We define the objective function as:

T-[)#)U!Y\���

���]ℎ!"!\� = �0)*;� = 05 + ;�)*;� > 0

(9)

The other constraints as defined in (5) to (8) still hold.

Finally we obtain the following results

23

Vi-

llage

#

Population Total

Demand

[kW]

Quantity

Consumed

[kW]

Dist to

Grid [km]

Selected Option Cost of

electrification

[$]

V1 876 75.9 75.9 9.4 Grid Extension 18,995

V2 931 80.7 80.7 13.3 MHPP 1 – grid 30,032

V3 1078 93.4 93.4 18.0 Grid Extension 46,078

V4 340 19.0 0.0 30.2 Grid Extension 0

V5 1213 105.1 93.8 7.5 MHPP 2 – grid 31,160

V6 913 79.1 79.1 14.1 Grid Extension 29,483

V7 2354 204.0 143.1 4.7 Grid Extension 18,294

V8 971 84.2 84.2 26.1 MHPP 1 – grid 29,933

V9 1065 92.3 92.3 17.8 Grid Extension 45,522

V10 1420 123.1 123.1 1.1 Grid Extension 15,728

V11 893 77.4 65.3 9.4 MHPP 2 – grid 20,447

V12 156 8.7 7.8 22.5 Grid Extension 4,799

TOTAL COST 290,471

Generator Capacity [kW] Capacity

demanded with

least cost solution

[kW]

Fossil fuel plants 650 614.78

MHPP 1 200 164.84

MHPP 2 160 159.07

Table 7 Results from Utility Maximisation Model

It is interesting to note that this approach yields the lowest total cost for the optimal electrification

technology mix, compared to the previous scenarios where the objective function is to directly

minimise total cost. In this model, we see that one village also remains unelectrified (Village 4).

However, the optimal outcome of this model actually ‘favours’ MHPP less than the previous

scenarios, as the full capacity of the MHPPs are ‘less depleted’ .

4.7 Discussions of model

The model and scenarios discussed this far has been implemented using ‘artificial’ village data that is

designed to mimic the real geographical and population dispersion in Nias Island. This approach was

selected due to the limitation of accurate population and geospatial data at village level. Most data

available for public access has been mainly on district or state level only.

Despite these limitations the model has been particularly useful in revealing the large potential for

MHPP in a rural electrification strategy. All scenarios under minimising cost model have shown that

the optimal strategy is highly dependent on the ability to exploit the full capacity of MHPP (see Table

8).

24

Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Scenario 4

Objective function Minimise cost Minimise cost Minimise cost Maximise utility

% ‘used’ capacity from

fossil fuel plants at

optimal solution

92% 90% 92% 95%

% ‘used’ capacity from

MHPPs at optimal

solution

99% 97% 95% 90%

Table 8 Required percentage of total plant capacities at optimal level

Aside from data limitation, there are also certain limitations with the models itself that can be

further improved:

• At present, the model is limited to ‘artificial’ villages and only considers very basic setup of

one grid and two sites for MHPP. An improved model which takes into account multiple

access to grids and larger number of MHPPs is required to get a better understanding of

costs of electrification strategy, and assess the scalability of such solution.

• The model only allows a static analysis (one point in time). A dynamic model which takes

into account growth of demand and other variables would be more useful in determining

the optimal path towards the 90% electrification target over a period of time.

• The subsidy level at present is a simple percentage reduction on the LCOE. Other subsidy

and financing structures associated with MHPP construction are available from examples of

other developing countries. Incorporation of this factor would be beneficial in determining

the true optimal least cost electrification strategy when financing sources other than from

PLN is available.

• The cost of distribution of MHPP is currently a linear function of distance. Further

refinement in quantifying this cost would be useful to get a better understanding of the

‘threshold’ distance for switching between grid and MHPP, if this exists.

• Finally, we have approached the analysis from a cost perspective and have not taken into

profitability of PLN and various pricing structures for the end consumer.

However, the immediate step in this study is of course to utilize real data of villages, grid and

MHPP potential sites in the island.

5 Further Considerations to Implementation of MHPP

The potential role of MHPP cannot be assessed on a basis of economics alone (least – cost). It is

important to consider external factors to economic feasibility to reflect the ‘true’ potential of MHPP.

25

There are several significant issues that PLN still has to overcome, which may call for the need of

additional policies to increase the attractiveness of MHPP adoption.

Firstly, as PLN is a state-owned company they are prone to political interference from politicians and

the government. Low labour productivity and over-employment may result from inefficient

government policies, implemented for example during election times to gain support from the

public. To prevent the risk of occurrence of this be, there is a need of separation between regulating

and policy making function, which is currently still held by the Ministry of Energy & Mineral

Resources alone. An accepted structure in most developed countries that may be transferrable to

Indonesia, is where an independent regulator exists which is responsible for balancing interests of

consumers, utility and government; and determines appropriate pricing structure to ensure fair and

optimal costs for rural consumers (Haanyika, 2005).

Secondly, the risk of indirect rebound effect associated with improvements in cost-effective energy

efficiency may result over time from the adoption of MHPP for rural electrification. Access to

electrification may have positive effects for rural communities such as increased income and

productivity, for example through the use of electrical equipment instead of manual labour for

agriculture purposes. There is a potential for the consumers to exploit the cost savings from these

benefits to purchase other high energy demand goods and purposes (indirect effect). Alternatively,

direct effects such as increased use of electricity for households that were already electrified may

also result from establishing a ‘cheaper’ generation option. In a case of backfire, it is possible that

the expected energy savings are entirely offset, leading to zero net savings (Sorrell, 2009). Such

scenario may result in a continued state of energy deficit as generation capacities can never keep up

with demand growth.

To prevent rebound effects, consumer education on ‘quality over quantity’ of electricity supply is

very critical. Hence, newly electrified households may need to be educated on energy saving

behaviours. Alternatively, using a stick approach, the regulator may choose to increase tariffs or

reduce subsidies on MHPP to force consumers to reduce consumption to sustainable levels.

Third, it is important to consider the most appropriate financing structure to reduce the financial risk

and burden on PLN and GOI. According to (Jayawerdana & et al., 2005), although the operations of

MHPP is typically fully commercial, subsidies on initial construction and connection costs are still

required, as such high costs remains the main hurdle to realisation of MHPP projects. Typical

subsidies can range between 15-20% of investment costs. But to further encourage adoption of

MHPP, it is possible to have higher levels of subsidies for off-grid projects compared to on-grid

26

projects. Furthermore, subsidies can be enhanced by micro-financing from private institutions,

development banks or NGOs. Such institutions have the right expertise and knowledge of the right

financing mix, risk profile, and credit enhancements for small rural-based based projects, which large

utilities (PLN) may have little knowledge in (Jayawerdana & et al., 2005). This will further reduce the

investment risk of MHPP projects.

Finally, it is important for PLN to start building the right technical knowledge and set of technical

standards for MHPPs to ensure successful and high quality project completion. Apart providing

technical education to engineers and technicians, standards of MHPP operations will need to be

developed as guidelines for users. Potential environmental issues such as safe battery disposal will

also need to be addressed.

6 Conclusion

This study set out to determine whether micro hydropower could become part of an effective

electrification strategy for rural Indonesia, and to explore the costliness of meeting Indonesia’s 90%

electrification target, with a specific focus on Nias Island. To date, a simplified model of this study

has been carried out using data of an ‘artificial environment’ consisting of a small number of villages

which have the option of either connecting to MHPPs or an electricity grid to gain electricity access.

Despite the simplified nature in which this model has been currently run, we believe the model

demonstrates some insights to the role of MHPP in rural electrification.

From our analysis, we have observed that MHPP can be an integral part of a low-cost rural

electrification strategy. Our findings suggest that electricity access using MHPP either as an isolated-

grid or battery charging station has the best potential for villages with significant electricity demand

but are located at a considerable distance from the grid (18km and above) and are technically

difficult to reach by extension of PLN’s grid

Despite demonstrating MHPP as a vital ingredient for an optimal low-cost electrification strategy for

rural communities, we expect there will be other non-economic barriers to accelerating the adoption

of MHPPs. We observed that there still exists diseconomies of scale (in terms of the overall

electrification costs) with increasing MHPP capacity. However, if the increase in capacity has an

associated reduction in MHPP to 15% below the current LCEO level, this effect was reversed and we

observed economies of scale with increasing generation capacity. Furthermore, the bulk of total cost

of electrification is due to construction and development costs, whereas the operation costs are

relatively low. It is unlikely that for a large-scale (non-ad hoc) rural electrification program, PLN

would have the sufficient capital to cover these initial investments, particularly given their current

27

financial struggle. Therefore a study on possible financing structure which incorporates a certain

level of support of NGOs, micro-financing, or even contribution from the rural community itself is

still required.

Finally, a firm policy framework is urgently required to eliminate inefficiencies in the electricity

sector to ensure PLN can build the right financial and technical capacity to focus on access

maximisation. Such a policy will reduce the uncertainties in the electricity sector, which could serve

to incentivise investments from the private sector and alleviate the financial responsibilities for rural

electrification from the public sector alone.

28

Bibliography

Abdullah, S., & Jeanty, P. W. (2006). Demand for Electricity Connection in Rural Areas: The case of

Kenya. Department of Economics, University of bath.

Asian Institute of Technology. (2005). Renewable Energy Technology Promotion in Asia: Case Studies

from Six Asian Countries. Pathumtani: Regional Energy Resources Information Center

(RERIC).

Bureau of Statistics of Indonesia. (2005). Penduduk Nias dan Nias Selatan pasca gempa dan tsunami

menurut desa (Census of Inhabitants of Nias and South Nias post earthquake and tsunami).

Indonesia: Bureau of Statistics of Indonesia.

Haanyika, C. M. (2005). Rural Electrification Policy and Institutions in a Reforming Power Sector.

Lusaka: Resources for Infrastructure Development and Energy Studies.

Holland, C. W., & Derbyshire, W. (2009). Electrifying 20 Million Households: An Indonesian Rural

Electrification Strategy. EEA Conference & Exhibition. Christchurch: Maunsell, AECOM, and

Economic Consulting Associates.

Jayawerdana, M., & et al. (2005). Electricity for All: Options for Increasing Electricty Access in

Indonesia. Jakarta: The World Bank.

Kemmler, A. (2006). Regional disparities in electrification in India - do geographic factors matter?

CEPE Working Paper Series.

Kusidana, D. (2008). Implementation of Rural Electrificaiton by Renewable Energy in Indonesia,

Summary from Workshop on Rural Energization. Workshop on Rural Energization. Paris:

Directorate General of Electricity and Energy Utilization, Ministry of Energy and Mineral

Resources.

Nias Online. (2008, October 27). Nias Online. Retrieved April 10, 2011, from

http://niasonline.net/2008/10/27/listrik-di-nias-semakin-meresahkan/

PLN . (2010). Rencana Usahaa Penyediaan Tenaga Listrik PT PLN (Electricity Supply Development

Plan) : 2010 - 2019.

29

PLN North Sumatra. (2007). Ratio of Electrification and Ratio of Village Electrification by

administrative districts 2007.

PLN Sumatera Utara. (2010). Site Selection for Planned Construction of Thermal Power Plant 2 x 3

MW in South Nias. Medan: PLN Sumatera Utara.

Siemons, R. V. (2001). Identifying a role for biomass gasification in rural electrification in developing

countries: the economic perspective. Biomass and Bioenergy, 271-285.

Sorrell, S. (2009). The Rebound Effect: Definition and Estimation. International handbook on the

economics of energy, 199-233.

Sukarsono, A. (2010, February 25). Retrieved April 18, 2011, from Bloomberg Online:

http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=newsarchive&sid=a5wk_YzsBXU0

UNDP Indonesia. (2009). Rural development with renewable energy: Project Facts. Jakarta: UNDP

Indonesia.

United Nations Industrial Development Organisation. (2005). The Options to Develop Micro Hydro

Power Projects: Rural Electrification in Nias and Aceh. UNIDO.

World Bank IEG. (2008). The Welfare Impact of Rural Electrification: A Reassessment of Costs and

Benefits. Washington DC: The World Bank.

30

Appendices

Appendix 1 – Policies Relevant to Rural Electrification

Decree & Law Reference / Year Description

Issued by Government of Indonesia

State Constitution 33/1945 Provision of vital utilities must be controlled by the state

Law 15/1985 PLN status as sole institution with full authority in electricity

provision

Law 20/2002 PLN’s role as the sole electricity provider is reduced. The

function is to be partly delegated to Central and Local

Government in a bid to accelerate electrification access.

Status: annulled due to violation of State Constitution 33/1945

Government Regulation

26/2006

A ‘reduced’ version of 20/2002, allowing central and local

government to grant licenses to cooperatives and businesses if

no PLN services are present in the area. Obligates central and

local government to provide funds towards rural electrification.

Issued by Ministry of Energy & Mineral Resources

Ministerial Decree 1122 / 2002 Provision of small scale distributed renewable energy power

generation

Ministerial Decree 10/2005 Procedures for Electric Power Business Licenses for Inter-

Provinces, Regions or for National Grid Connections

Ministerial Decree 01/2006 Procedures for Electric Power Purchasing and/or Rental of

Transmission Lines

Ministerial Decree 02/2006 Provision of medium scale distributed renewable energy power

generation Table 9 List of regulations relevant to rural electrification in Indonesia (Source: Directorate General for Electricity and

Energy Utilization, Ministry of Energy & Mineral Resources, 2007)

31

Appendix 2 – Comparison of energy costs on isolated grids

Appendix 3 – Cost of grid extension

Cost breakdown Rp ('000) US$

LV line

Unit cost per km 77,790 8,972

Units per connection (km) 0.0094 0.0094

Cost per connection 731 84

Transformer (50 kVA)

Unit cost per km 55,197 6,366

Units per connection 0.0024 0.0024

Cost per connection 132 15

Service drop

Unit cost per km 1,023 118

Units per connection 1.0000 1.0000

Cost per connection 1,023 118

Total supply cost per connection 1,887 218

Estimated cost of wiring and metering at household

level

32

Total cost of grid extension per household 250

Note: 1US$ = Rp 8,760

Appendix 4 – Cost of battery

Battery cost (85Ah/1kWh, 12V) US$ 100

Charging subscription cost ($2 per month) over lifetime of 10 years,

allowing up to 8 charges per month US$240

Usage per lifetime (kWh) 960

LCOE (USc/kWh) 35.4