road pricing assessment

4
UNCORRECTED PROOF History of thought and prospects for road pricing * Serge Pahaut a, * , Catharina Sikow b a Universite ´ Libre de Bruxelles, 50, Boulevard du Triomphe, B-1040 Brussels, Belgium b European Commission, Directorate General for Energy and Transport, B-1040 Brussels, Belgium Abstract Policy implications of the research program presented in this issue of Transport Policy are discussed according to their theoretical, historical and political origins. Problems related to government taxation are analysed in the light of the early literature on transport externalities pricing that began with Pigou [Pigou, A.C., 1920. The Economics of Welfare. MacMillan, London. (References are usually made to the 1932, 4th ed.)]. We then discuss decision-making processes in transport pricing implementation involving redistribution issues, acceptability, user’s satisfaction and equity. The article also briefly reviews the general agenda of EU transport policy q 2006 Published by Elsevier Ltd. JEL classification: B130; D620; D630; R480 Keywords: European Union; Negative externalities; Road pricing; Transport policy; Implementation; Acceptability; Decision-making 1. Introduction We discuss here some political perspectives related to the case studies presented in this special issue of Transport Policy. These studies were part of a research program 1 whose objective was to define optimal transition paths from a situation with inefficient, and generally too low, pricing of transportation, to a situation with socially optimal pricing in which users pay the marginal social cost of their trips. The study of (urban transport pricing) UTP has almost become an academic discipline. It has also inspired a large number of EU-funded research programs, such as (Mobility Impacts, Reactions and Opinions) MIRO, (Trans Modal Integrated Urban Transport Pricing for Optimum Modal Split) TransPrice, (Acceptability of Fiscal and Financial Measures and Organisational Requirements for Demand Management) AFFORD, (PRIcing Measures Acceptance) PRIMA, (Pricing Acceptability in the Transport Sector) PATS, (Co-ordinating Urban Pricing Integrated Demonstrations) CUPID, (Modelling TRansport, ENergy and ENvironment) TRENEN-II, (REal COst Reduction of Door-to-Door Intermodal Transport) RECORDIT. This program was designed to incorporate or cover: 1. all major modes (urban, interurban road, rail, air, water) and both freight and passenger transport; 2. all relevant levels of decision-making (local/regional, national, EU); and 3. intramodal implementation issues, intermodal issues (where conditions in one mode can affect the implementation in another), and also intersectoral issues relevant to the implementation. Our purpose is to present some observations about policy design and management. The case studies presented in this issue taught us how much the decision-making process itself deserves careful consideration. The research program pre- sented here was indeed the result of a shift in focus from the mere technical derivation of optimal pricing rules to the consideration of practical implementation problems of pricing policies. We will not discuss here how to fine tune the derivation of second-best prices from the point of view of economic theory, or how to solve technical problems related to modelling. It is our conviction that policymakers and analysts should take care Transport Policy xx (xxxx) 1–4 www.elsevier.com/locate/tranpol 0967-070X/$ - see front matter q 2006 Published by Elsevier Ltd. doi:10.1016/j.tranpol.2005.11.012 * We would like to thank Andre ´ de Palma, Stef Proost and Robin Lindsey for fruitful comments and discussions. * Corresponding author. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (S. Pahaut), catharina.sikow@dg7. cec.be (C. Sikow). 1 MC-ICAM: Implementation of Marginal Cost Pricing in Transport— Integrated Conceptual and Applied Model Analysis), funded by the European Union (Commission, DG TREN, 5th Framework Programme). MC-ICAM program is part of, and builds on, the results of a wider cluster of research projects on transport pricing, financed by the European Commission under the 4, 5 and 6th Framework Research Programmes. JTRP 769—5/1/2006—09:38—SWAPNA—194432—XML MODEL 5+ – pp. 1–4 + model ARTICLE IN PRESS 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100 101 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 109 110 111 112 113 114

Upload: espuma001

Post on 16-Dec-2015

8 views

Category:

Documents


4 download

DESCRIPTION

An economic discussion of road pricing

TRANSCRIPT

  • History of thought and pro

    Serge Pahaut a,*, C

    vard

    r En

    f T

    sed

    Mi

    atio

    por

    licy

    Transport Policy x

    + model ARTICLE IN PRESS

    1

    2

    3

    4

    5

    6

    7

    8

    9

    10

    11

    12

    13

    14

    15

    16

    17

    18

    19

    20

    21

    22

    23

    24

    25

    26

    27

    28

    29

    30

    31

    32

    33

    34

    35

    36

    37

    38

    39

    40

    41

    42

    43

    44

    45

    46

    47

    48

    49

    50

    51

    52

    53

    54

    55

    56

    57

    58

    59

    60

    61

    62

    63

    64

    65

    66

    67

    68

    69

    70

    71

    72

    73

    74

    75

    76

    77

    78

    79

    80

    81

    82

    83

    84

    85

    86

    87

    88

    89

    90

    91

    92

    93

    94

    95

    96

    97

    98

    99

    100

    101

    102

    103

    104

    105

    106

    107

    108

    109

    110

    111projects on transport pricing, financed by the European Commission under the

    4, 5 and 6th Framework Research Programmes.1CORR

    ECTE

    D P1. Introduction

    We discuss here some political perspectives related to the

    case studies presented in this special issue of Transport Policy.

    These studies were part of a research program1 whose objective

    was to define optimal transition paths from a situation with

    inefficient, and generally too low, pricing of transportation, to a

    situation with socially optimal pricing in which users pay the

    marginal social cost of their trips.

    The study of (urban transport pricing) UTP has almost

    become an academic discipline. It has also inspired a large

    number of EU-funded research programs, such as (Mobility

    Impacts, Reactions and Opinions) MIRO, (Trans Modal

    Integrated Urban Transport Pricing for Optimum Modal Split)

    TransPrice, (Acceptability of Fiscal and Financial Measures

    and Organisational Requirements for Demand Management)

    AFFORD, (PRIcing Measures Acceptance) PRIMA, (Pricing

    Acceptability in the Transport Sector) PATS, (Co-ordinating

    Urban Pricing Integrated Demonstrations) CUPID, (Modelling

    TRansport, ENergy and ENvironment) TRENEN-II, (REal

    COst Reduction of Door-to-Door Intermodal Transport)

    RECORDIT. This program was designed to incorporate

    or cover:

    1. all major modes (urban, interurban road, rail, air, water) and

    both freight and passenger transport;

    2. all relevant levels of decision-making (local/regional,

    national, EU); and

    3. intramodal implementation issues, intermodal issues (where

    conditions in one mode can affect the implementation in

    another), and also intersectoral issues relevant to the

    implementation.

    Our purpose is to present some observations about policy

    design and management. The case studies presented in this

    issue taught us how much the decision-making process itself

    deserves careful consideration. The research program pre-

    * We would like to thank Andre de Palma, Stef Proost and Robin Lindsey for

    fruitful comments and discussions.* Corresponding author.

    E-mail addresses: [email protected] (S. Pahaut), [email protected] Universite Libre de Bruxelles, 50, Bouleb European Commission, Directorate General fo

    Abstract

    Policy implications of the research program presented in this issue o

    and political origins. Problems related to government taxation are analy

    began with Pigou [Pigou, A.C., 1920. The Economics of Welfare. Mac

    then discuss decision-making processes in transport pricing implement

    equity. The article also briefly reviews the general agenda of EU trans

    q 2006 Published by Elsevier Ltd.

    JEL classification: B130; D620; D630; R480

    Keywords: European Union; Negative externalities; Road pricing; Transport poJTRP 7695/1/200609:38SWAPNA194432XML MODEL 5+ pp. 14ROOF

    spects for road pricing*

    atharina Sikow b

    du Triomphe, B-1040 Brussels, Belgium

    ergy and Transport, B-1040 Brussels, Belgium

    ransport Policy are discussed according to their theoretical, historical

    in the light of the early literature on transport externalities pricing that

    llan, London. (References are usually made to the 1932, 4th ed.)]. We

    n involving redistribution issues, acceptability, users satisfaction and

    t policy

    ; Implementation; Acceptability; Decision-making

    x (xxxx) 14

    www.elsevier.com/locate/tranpol112

    113

    114U consideration of practical implementation problems of pricingpolicies.We will not discuss here how to fine tune the derivation of

    second-best prices from the point of view of economic theory,

    or how to solve technical problems related to modelling. It is

    our conviction that policymakers and analysts should take care0967-070X/$ - see front matter q 2006 Published by Elsevier Ltd.

    doi:10.1016/j.tranpol.2005.11.012

    Union (Commission, DG TREN, 5th Framework Programme). MC-ICAM

    program is part of, and builds on, the results of a wider cluster of researchIntegrated Conceptual and Applied Model Analysis), funded by the EuropeanN sented here was indeed the result of a shift in focus from themere technical derivation of optimal pricing rules to thecec.be (C. Sikow).MC-ICAM: Implementation of Marginal Cost Pricing in Transport

  • Tto identify key political, economic and social barriers to the

    pricing of transport, and how to confront the technical

    constraints related to these barriers.2 As we shall see later,

    the promotion of economic efficiency (as part of the broader

    goal of sustainable economic growth) is the driving force

    behind marginal social cost pricing; but its practical

    discussion that is still with us today: should congestion be

    of a producer. External economies are mentioned in Marshall

    (1890, p. 266).5

    In his Economics of Welfare (1920), Pigou argued that the

    existence of externalities was sufficient justification for

    government intervention. Pigouvian taxes and subsidies

    introduce prices to internalise the externalities of a given

    activity, both positive (in the case, say, of education) or

    S. Pahaut, C. Sikow / Transport Policy xx (xxxx) 142

    + model ARTICLE IN PRESS

    115

    116

    117

    118

    119

    120

    121

    122

    123

    124

    125

    126

    127

    128

    129

    130

    131

    132

    133

    134

    135

    136

    137

    138

    139

    140

    141

    142

    143

    144

    145

    146

    147

    148

    149

    150

    151

    152

    153

    154

    155

    156

    157

    158

    159

    160

    161

    162

    163

    164

    165

    166

    167

    168

    169

    170

    171

    172

    173

    174

    175

    176

    177

    178

    179

    180

    181

    182

    183

    184

    185

    186

    187

    188

    189

    190

    191

    192

    193

    194

    195

    196

    197

    198

    199

    200

    201

    202

    203

    204

    205

    206

    207

    208

    209

    210

    211

    212

    213

    214

    215

    216

    217

    218

    219

    220

    221

    222

    223

    224

    225

    226UNCO

    RREC

    regulated through government policy (taxes and regulation),

    through transactions among private stakeholders, or not at all?

    The underlying idea is that economic efficiency, which

    means optimal allocation of scarce resources, cannot be

    achieved if there is unconditional access for everybody. In

    the case of public roads market pricing of transportation

    resources (vehicles, fuel, insurance, etc.) does not result in

    efficient use of public roads if users (travellers) create

    congestion or other negative externalities. The solution

    advocated by Pigou, a specific price introduced by public

    authorities through tolls, should be understood in the way we

    look at the rationale behind every tax: as a means to increase

    the well-being of the population. Pigou built on the inaugural

    work by Sidgwick and Marshall and introduced what we now

    call externalities: indirect effect of a consumption activity or

    a production activity on the consumption set of a consumer,

    the utility function of a consumer or the production function

    2 For a presentation of this barriers-constraints dynamic approach, see the

    contribution of Rouwendal and Verhoef (submitted) in this issue.3 cf. the pragmatic motto of Montaigne: Par divers moyens on arrive a`

    pareille fin (1580, I, 1).4 cf. the classical references of this controversy: Pigou (1920) and Knight

    (1924). cf. the New Palgrave (quoted below as NP: cf. Eatwell et al. (1987),implementation also involves the effective pursuit of other

    goals such as social equity and local growth, in order to ensure

    balanced consideration of wider societal goals. A wide

    exchange of opinions among all concerned stakeholders is

    essential here.

    In order to cope with the various situations described in the

    case studies, paths of transportation pricing may differ with

    respect to the transient prices they adopt before final prices are

    settled, the schedule according to which prices are changed,

    and how revenues are used.3

    This paper should be considered as an exploration of the

    global political landscape of transportation pricing. We will

    start by discussing some aspects of the inaugural PigouKnight

    debate on congestion management as this is at the heart of the

    transport pricing debate. We then summarise the present state

    of European Union policy in the domain of urban transport, and

    draw some general conclusions.

    1.1. The PigouKnight debate on congestion management

    The fundamental question of transport pricing by govern-

    ment was formulated during the debate between Pigou and

    Knight.4 This debate is of interest as it not only produced some

    definitions and tools, but also opened the path to a fundamentalarticles on Pigou, Knight, Young, Allyn, Coase, Coase theorem,

    externalities, rising supply prices, external economies, transaction costs.

    JTRP 7695/1/200609:38SWAPNA194432XML MODEL 5+ pp. 14ED PR

    OOF

    negative (in the case, say, of pollution emission).

    In his famous 1924 paper, Some Fallacies in the

    Interpretation of Social Cost, Knight argued against Pigou

    that no government intervention was needed. He even

    dismissed the external economies of the Marshallian tradition,

    as he wrote (p. 597) External economies in one business unit

    are internal economies in some other, within the industry. He

    developed a symmetrical solution (pp. 5867): If the roads are

    assumed to be subject to private appropriation and exploitation,

    precisely the ideal situation which would be established by the

    imaginary tax will be brought about through the operation of

    ordinary economic motives. For a brief summary of the

    survival of the idea of technological externalities in the Pigou

    Knight discussion, cf. NP, article external economies. Some

    remarks usually associated to the 1924 paper by Knight were

    actually formulated by his teacher, Young, in a 1913 review

    (Young, 1913) of Pigous Wealth and Welfare.

    The divergence between Pigou and Knight is not a mere

    question of political preference concerning the means of

    congestion regulation. Pigou himself was not advocating a

    moralistic approach to economics. He firmly maintained that

    economic science should not itself be an art, or directly

    enunciate precepts of government.6 He explained that

    economics is a positive science of what is and tends to be,

    not a normative science of what ought to be. But he also knew

    very well, as he dared to say with Alfred North Whitehead, that

    in our most theoretical moods we may be nearest to our most

    practical applications.7

    This use of taxes and subsidies was for Pigou8 a

    principle.susceptible of general application. He added in aprophetic way that the application of the principle is

    incomplete, because the revenue from these taxes.must bedevoted.exclusively to the execution of new and specific roadimprovements, to the effect that in the main, the motorist

    does not pay for the damage he does to the ordinary roads, but

    obtains in return for his payment an additional service useful to

    him rather than to the general public. Pigou implicitly

    advocated here the use of earmarking.

    The general implications of this discussion still confront us.

    The distinction between public and private management

    5 The irrelevance of pecuniary externalities was demonstrated by Young and

    Knight, and only technological externalities have survived. See NP, article

    externalities, by J.-J. Laffont.6 We refer the interested reader to the first pages of his Economics of Welfare

    (1920, Part I, ch. I).7 We refer the interested reader to the first pages of his Economics of Welfare

    (1920, Part I, ch. I). For a discussion about this very remarkable reciprocity of

    theory and praxis, we refer the reader to the Magnum Opus of Isabelle Stengers,Penser avec Whitehead (2002).8 cf. Pigou, 1920, Part II, ch. IX.

    227

    228

  • Tof transport is perhaps less important than the very

    fundamental question that we have to face now: which

    institutions are required, if any, to regulate the multiple

    interactions and transactions generated by transport? This

    question was not settled during the PigouKnight debate. Forty

    years later Coase (1960) presented his now famous Theorem: if

    transaction costs among private persons are nil and there are

    traffic from road to rail, development of liberalised railway

    management, etc. will have important and still unclear impacts

    instrument to strengthen the Single Market and the integration

    of national economies. More recently, transport pricing is

    increasingly seen as an important source of revenues for the

    development of the trans-European transport networks, and

    particularly for the 30 transnational projects declared of

    European interest.13

    S. Pahaut, C. Sikow / Transport Policy xx (xxxx) 14 3

    + model ARTICLE IN PRESS

    229

    230

    231

    232

    233

    234

    235

    236

    237

    238

    239

    240

    241

    242

    243

    244

    245

    246

    247

    248

    249

    250

    251

    252

    253

    254

    255

    256

    257

    258

    259

    260

    261

    262

    263

    264

    265

    266

    267

    268

    269

    270

    271

    272

    273

    274

    275

    276

    277

    278

    279

    280

    281

    282

    283

    284

    285

    286

    287

    288

    289

    290

    291

    292

    293

    294

    295

    296

    297

    298

    299

    300

    301

    302

    303

    304

    305

    306

    307

    308

    309

    310

    311

    312

    313

    314

    315

    316

    317

    318

    319

    320

    321

    322

    323

    324

    325

    326

    327

    328

    329

    330

    331

    332

    333

    334

    335

    336

    337

    338

    339

    340UNCO

    RRECon urban life and urban transport policy. It should be kept inmind that transport policy is related to the overarching concernof sustainable development. An overall strategic objective of

    EU transport policy is to achieve a decoupling of economic

    growth and transport growth. This decoupling is part of a large

    policy scheme, involving integration of social and environ-

    mental costs of transport and the publication of annual reports

    on sustainable development (the Gothenburg agenda).

    Transport pricing is also seen as a key to establish a level

    playing field and fair competition system between, and within,

    the different transport modes. It is therefore an important

    9 cf. NP, article transaction costs.10 For a description of the development of this policy, see Pahaut and Quinet

    (2005).11 A different interpretation of the subsidiarity principle is often taken in the

    context of environmental policy. In the CAFE (Clean Air For Europe) program,

    policy measures (including transport) will be proposed to ensure adequate air

    quality in all cities in the EU.no income effects, contracts among the parties involved may

    solve the externality problems without any government

    intervention. In most circumstances, however, multilateral

    transactions are very costly, and regulations may be more

    efficient.9

    As we can seen from this brief summary of a long, complex

    discussion, the mix of public intervention and private

    transactions was an open question from the very outset of the

    discussion in the 1920s. The suitable composition of this mix

    remains an open problem for European transport policythe

    subject of the following section.

    2. Current orientations of EU policy

    2.1. Transport pricing policy

    Space constraints preclude a comprehensive summary and

    history of transport pricing policy in the European Union.

    Suffice it to say that the approach of the White Paper adopted

    by the European Commission (EU, 2001) on transport policy is

    far more ambitious than it looks.10 Urban transport policy per

    se is not targeted in the White Paper because, in the ECs view,

    the subsidiarity principle dictates that urban transport matters

    should be dealt with by local politicians and decision-makers.11

    However, the implementation of reforms on heavy goods

    vehicle pricing and other European transport policy initiatives

    such as sea motorways12, rail/water integration, shifts of freight12 Sea links providing a way around bottlenecks, such as in the Alps or in the

    Pyrenees.

    JTRP 7695/1/200609:38SWAPNA194432XML MODEL 5+ pp. 14ED PR

    OOF

    If we are to understand the somewhat partial approach of the

    EU transport pricing policy, we have to keep in mind the

    current political state of affairs and the decision-making

    procedures of the EU, which make collective decisions difficult

    to reach, to say the least. As the White Paper of 2001 flatly

    states14: Several Member States contest the very principle of a

    general Community-wide ban to keep heavy goods vehicles off

    the roads on weekends. Member States have also taken

    diverging paths on taxation in response to the recent surges in

    oil prices. These comments reflect the equivocal nature of the

    subsidiarity principle.

    It is in this context that the Commission announced a series

    of measures ranging from pricing to revitalising alternative

    modes of transport to road and targeted investment in the trans-

    European network, while bearing in mind the historical

    imbalance in favour of road for the last 50 years. The

    ambitious objective of the Commission paper is to rebalance

    modal demand and prevent the modal share of road transport

    from growing further. Transport pricing is seen as one of the

    most powerful measures in achieving this goal.

    A careful selection of complementary policy instruments

    will be necessary to achieve this goal. Cross-financing and

    revenue hypothecation, for example, will require political

    decisions consistent with the subsidiarity principle. The

    proposal to develop corridors of European interest15

    (transport corridors relevant to European integration) will

    benefit from a transfer of resources from the road sector to

    alternative modes. A first step in this direction was reached in

    the recent transport Council, which agreed on the possibility to

    add, under certain conditions, a 12% mark-up on top of

    allocated infrastructure costs for heavy goods vehicles to be

    earmarked to non-road modes in the same corridor.

    Intercity truck tolls were recently introduced in the form of a

    heavy goods vehicle (HGV) kilometre-charging scheme on

    German and Austrian motorways. And in several countries

    passenger vehicle tolls are common on intercity motorways.

    But few urban roads are tolled despite the considerably higher

    external costs or urban driving.16 Bold and innovative policies

    will also be required to introduce tolls on urban roads. It can be

    hoped that the toll rings in the major Norwegian cities and

    Londons congestion charging scheme have paved the way

    13 Decision 884/2004/EC14 EU (2001), see the introduction on Policy Guidelines.15 Decision 884/2004/EC declared 30 priority projects to be of European

    interest (listed in its Annex III). These projects, and particularly their cross-

    border components, will be prioritized when allocating EU subsidies.16 See the RECORDIT program, which calculated the marginal external costs

    of a 40-ton lorry on three long distance transport corridors. The differencebetween external costs in urban and interurban varies typically from 5 to

    60 Euro cents/km.

    341

    342

  • Tfor a more widespread use of pricing to allocate urban road

    capacity as a complement to access restrictions and clean

    S. Pahaut, C. Sikow / Transp4

    + model ARTICLE IN PRESS

    343

    344

    345

    346

    347

    348

    349

    350

    351

    352

    353

    354

    355

    356

    357

    358

    359

    360

    361

    362

    363

    364

    365

    366

    367

    368

    369

    370

    371

    372

    373

    374

    375

    376

    377

    378

    379

    380

    381

    382

    383

    384

    385

    386

    387

    388

    389

    390

    391

    392

    393

    394

    395

    396

    397

    398

    399

    400

    401

    402

    403

    404

    405

    406

    407

    408

    409

    410

    411

    412

    413

    414

    415

    416

    417

    418

    419

    420

    421

    422

    423

    424

    425

    426

    427

    428

    429

    430

    431

    432

    433

    434

    435

    436

    437

    438

    439

    440

    441

    442

    443

    444

    445

    446

    447

    448

    449

    450

    451

    452

    453

    454UNCO

    RREC

    zones.

    Road pricing has still not reached the policy agenda at the

    worldwide level. The European Commission is taking strong

    positions on this point since the publication of the 1995 Green

    Paper on fair and efficient pricing: .while transport may beheavily taxed, it is above all badly and unequally taxed. Users

    are all treated alike, irrespective of the infrastructure damage,

    bottleneck and pollution they cause. This failure to spread the

    burden fairly between infrastructure operators, taxpayers and

    users causes considerable distortion of competition both

    between transport operators and between modes of transport.

    (CEC, 1995).

    The White Paper of 2001 considered more precise

    objectives (CEC, 2001): The thrust of Community action

    should be to replace gradually existing transport system taxes

    with more effective instruments for integrating infrastructure

    costs and external costs [in the price of transport]. These

    instruments are, firstly, charging for infrastructure use, which is

    a particularly effective mean of managing congestion and

    reducing other environmental impacts, and, secondly, fuel tax,

    which lends itself well to controlling carbon dioxide

    emissions.17 For two reasons the distinction between charging

    and taxation as political instruments is of particular interest and

    importance. First, because of the need to use different

    instruments to tackle different problems. And second because

    the Community decision-making rules differ for the two cases:

    taxation falls under the unanimity rule whereby any EU

    member State can block a proposal, whereas decisions on

    charging can be taken by qualified majority.

    2.2. Acceptability

    Transport policy reform is bound to relate social, economic,

    fiscal and political agenda that are notoriously difficult to

    manage. Indeed, this is the central political question. The

    discussion of equity in matters such as transport policy cannot

    be an isolated subject.18 In the context of the European Union,

    in addition to distribution of income between citizens or

    households, equity has also another dimension, which is often

    called regional cohesion in the EU jargon. The implications of

    a policy upon certain regionsconsidering oppositions among

    poor/rich; peripheral/central; big/small country; old/new

    member statesare of interest for the policymaking process.

    There is some concern that those who will be negatively

    impacted by pricing will not benefit from the increased

    revenues; e.g. some existing legislation may not let urban

    authorities decide how revenues from congestion charging can

    be used. This would need to be addressed for urban pricing

    to be more widely present on the policy agenda in the EU.

    Acceptability of pricing will depend not only on relevant

    17 cf. CEC, 2001.18 A discussion of equity and social choice is beyond the scope of this article.Readers are referred to the seminal formulation by Gevers (1986), and Trannoy

    and Fleurbaey (2003).

    JTRP 7695/1/200609:38SWAPNA194432XML MODEL 5+ pp. 14ED PR

    OOF

    macroeconomic relations, but also on investments that confer

    benefits to users of transportation systems.

    3. Concluding remarks

    In conclusion it is our view that the orientation of European

    transport policy is relatively well defined and theoretically

    grounded. However, the policy will only come into practice if

    national and local authorities cooperate. It is impossible to tell

    now if, and how, this integration will develop. We have shown

    that the present transformation of transport calls not only for

    technical management, but also for political decisions. The

    multiplicity and diversity of interest groups, users, taxpayers,

    local authorities, etc. requires political arbitration. It will be up

    to decision-makers at all levels of government to fulfil these

    expectations.

    4. Disclaimer

    The views expressed here are not to be considered as the

    views of the Commission.

    5. Uncited reference

    de Palma and Quinet (2005).

    References

    CEC, 1995. Green Paper: Towards Fair and Efficient Pricing in Transport

    Policy-Options for Internalizing the External Cost of Transport in the

    European Union.

    CEC, 2001. White Paper: European Transport Policy for 2010: Time to Decide.

    Coase, R., 1960. The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics

    3, 1.

    de Palma, A, Quinet, E., 2005. La tarification des transports, Enjeux et defis.

    Economica, Paris.

    Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., Newman, P., 1987. The New Palgrave: A Dictionary

    of Economics. Macmillan, London.

    EU, 2001. White Paper on European Transport Policy for 2010: Time to

    Decide. European Commission, DG TREN, Brussels.

    Gevers, L., 1986. Walrasian social choice: some simple axiomatic approaches.

    In: Heller, W.P. (Ed.), Social Choice and Public Decision Making Essays in

    Honor of K.J. Arrow, vol. 1. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,

    pp. 91114.

    Knight, F., 1924. Some fallacies in the interpretation of social cost, Quarterly

    Journal of Economics, 38. Reprinted in The Ethics of Competition and

    Other Essays. Allen and Unwin, London.

    Marshall, A., 1890. Principles of Economics. Macmillan, London (References

    are to the 3rd edition of 1920).

    Montaigne, M., 1580. Essais, Bordeaux.

    Pahaut, S., Quinet, E., 2005. Doctrines dans lUnion europeenne. In: de

    Palma, A., Quinet, E. (Eds.), La Tarification des Transport. Pourquoi? Pour

    Qui? Les Defis daujourdhui et de Demain. Economica, Paris, pp. 6989.

    Pigou, A.C., 1920. The Economics of Welfare. MacMillan, London

    (References are usually made to the 1932, 4th ed.).

    Rouwendal, J., Verhoef, E., Submitted for publication. Basic economics of

    roads pricing: From theory to applications.

    Stengers, I., 2002. Penser Avec Whitehead. Gallimard, Paris.

    Trannoy, A., Fleurbaey, M., 2003. The impossibility of a paretian dominant.

    In: Social Choice and Welfare, 21, 2 (issue in honour of Louis Gevers).

    ort Policy xx (xxxx) 14Young, A.A., 1913. Pigous wealth and welfare. Quarterly Journal of

    Economics 27, 672686.455

    456

    History of thought and prospects for road pricingIntroductionThe Pigou-Knight debate on congestion management

    Current orientations of EU policyTransport pricing policyAcceptability

    Concluding remarksDisclaimerUncited referenceReferences