rm research report winter 2010

Upload: hikmet-kaya

Post on 06-Apr-2018

219 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    1/15Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1537652

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Risk Management Research Reportis publishedquarterly to serve the professional and academic riskmanagement communities by presenting extended

    summaries of recently published academic articlesof particular interest.

    RMRR seeks to select the best and most importantarticles in risk management and corporate governanceand to communicate the essential ideas of that researchto risk managers and risk management scholars in atimely manner and a convenient format.

    The editor ofRMRR, Robert W. Kolb, selectsthe articles for inclusion, writes the summary ofeach article, and bears sole responsibility for thecontent ofRMRR.

    Winter 2010

    http://www.RMRR.com

    Robert W. Kolb, Editor

    [email protected]

    Cindy Scheopner, Managing Editor

    [email protected]

    Our Sponsors

    RMRR is supported by the Center for Integrated Risk Management and Corporate Governance at Loyola University Chicago

    Contents

    Why Do U.S. Firms Hold SoMuch More Cash Than They Used To?Thomas W. Bates, Kathleen M. Kahle,

    and Ren M. Stulz 3

    Errors, Robustness, and the Fourth QuadrantNassim Nicholas Taleb 4

    Stock Market Liquidity and Firm ValueVivian W. Fang, Thomas H. Noe, and Sheri Tice 5

    Credit Contagion from Counterparty RiskPhilippe Jorion and Gaiyan Zhang 6

    Cross-Section of Option Returns and VolatilityAmit Goyal and Alessio Saretto 7

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    2/15Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=15376522http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    The Financial Crisis, Systemic Risk,and the Future of Insurance RegulationScott E. Harrington 8

    Risk Management Lessons from the Credit Crisis

    Philippe Jorion 9

    The Crisis in the Foreign Exchange Market

    Michael Mervin and Mark P. Taylor 10

    An Empirical Comparison of Option-PricingModels in Hedging Exotic OptionsYunbi An and Wulin Suo 11

    Quantifying the Interest RateRisk of Banks: Assumptions Do MatterOliver Entrop, Marco Wilkens, and Alexander Zeisler 12

    Currency Carry Trade Regimes:Beyond the Fama RegressionRichard Clarida, Josh Davis, and Niels Pederson 13

    Contents

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    3/15

    3http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Thomas Bates, Kathleen Kahle, and Ren Stulz(BKS), address a problem that has garnered signicantattention from the popular nancial pressthe large in-crease in cash holdings of U.S. rms over recent decades.BKS adopt 1980-2006 as their data period and use CRSP

    and Compustat for surviving and non-surviving rms;they exclude nancial rms and utility companies; andthey restrict the sample to rms incorporated in the U.S.This yields a data set of 13,599 unique rms with a totalof 117,438 annual observations.

    They document a large increase in cash holdings forU.S. rms from 1980-2006, noting that the average cash-to-assets ratio has more than doubled over this period. Onepotential explanation for increasing cash is the prevalenceof agency problems, but in the absence of agency issues, theneed for cash should have fallen given the improvements ininformation and nancial technology over this period. BKS

    set out to understand this anomaly.Measuring leverage as debt-to-assets or debt-to-equity,

    there has been little decrease in average leverage. But thenet debt ratio (debt minus cash, divided by book assets) hasfallen sharply: The fall in net debt is so dramatic that theaverage net debt for U.S. rms is negative in 2004, 2005,and 2006. (1986)

    In the nance literature, there are four well recognizedmotives for holding cash: transactional, precautionary, tax-oriented, and agency problem. BKS argue that cash man-agement systems have improved over their sample, so they

    discount the transactional motivation. Increasing robustnessof derivatives markets and improvements in forecasting andcontrol technologies should have reduced the precautionarymotive over this period. Offsetting these factors that predictreduced precautionary balances, there has been an increasein idiosyncratic risk for rms over this period, suggestinggreater problems with unhedgeable risks and an increasedneed for precautionary balances. U.S. rms with foreignprots hold cash to avoid repatriating funds and paying tax-

    es, which might increase cash balances. Finally, entrenchedmanagers might be inclined to hoard cash even when theylack good investment opportunities, so agency problemsmight account for increased cash holdings.

    BKS are able to discard some potential explanations.

    They nd that rms of different sizes all exhibit the in-crease in cash, with the average cash ratio increasing forall rm size quintiles. The sample period included the IPOsurge of the 1990s, and IPO rms might have more cashwhen they issue seasoned equity after the IPO. However,cash holdings of both IPO and non-IPO rms increase,leading BKS to conclude: the increase in cash holdingswe document is not due to the capital raising activities ofthe IPO rms in our sample. (1995)

    Further, contrary to the tax motivated hypothesis, BKSshow that rms without foreign income also exhibit in-creased cash holdings. The authors also nd that rms withmanagers that are most entrenched have the smallest in-crease in cash holdings, contrary to the agency explanation.

    BKS nd that the increased holding of cash is relatedto the disappearing dividends phenomenon. For non-div-idend paying rms there is a strong increase in the meancash ratio, and the net debt ratio falls for these rms as well.This is not observed for dividend-paying rms.

    Non-dividend rms are generally regarded as morecash-constrained, so this contrast suggests that a precau-tionary motivation is at play. BKS also nd that rms withhigher idiosyncratic risk hold more cash. In addition, the

    fall in capital expenditures, accompanied by increased re-search and development expenditures, is also related to in-creased cash holdings.

    BKS conclude: We nd that the main reasons for theincrease in the cash ratio are that inventories have fallen,cash ow risk for rms has increased, capital expenditureshave fallen and R&D expenditures have increased. (2018)Thus, the precautionary motive to hold cash is a criticaldeterminant of the demand for cash. (2019)

    Why Do U.S. Firms Hold So

    Much More Cash Than They Used To?Thomas W. Bates, Kathleen M. Kahle, and Ren M. Stulz

    The Journal of Finance, October 2009, 64:5, 1985-2021.

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    4/15

    4http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Nicholas Taleb stresses that the use of forecasts shouldbe based on the estimate accuracy of the forecast, and as-serts that there is an interdependency about what weshould or should not forecastas some forecasts can beharmful to decision makers. (745) This general principle

    is related to the distribution about which a forecast is madeand turns on the nature of the tails of the distribution. Dis-tributions with thin tails make forecasting easy, but thicktails make forecasts more fragile, as it is harder to under-stand the forecast errors associated with forecasts aboutsuch distributions.

    Taleb uses empirical data as a basis from which to gen-eralize and to illustrate his theoretical points. He examinesdaily data for many years for 38 economic variables thatrepresent the vast majority of all tradable assets and includea variety of currencies, commodity futures, bonds, metals,exchange rates, and stock indexes.

    He computes daily logarithmic returns for non-over-lapping horizons of 1, 10, and 66 days and tests the returnsdistributions for non-normality using the fourth non-cen-tral moment, which captures the excess kurtosis of the test-ed distribution over the kurtosis of a normal distribution.

    Based on this analysis, he concludes that all of theseeconomic variables are patently fat-tailedwith noknown exceptions. (746) The departure from normalitypersists whether one considers 1, 10, or 66 day intervals.As a consequence, he argues that conventional methodssuch as linear regression and Gaussian copulas are un-

    workable, because they cannot capture the fat tails of theactual distributions.For forecasting, the main problem is that it is difcult

    to estimate small probabilities, so that forecast error ratesfor small probability events will be greater than those forhigher probability events. This can be disastrous when thesmall probability events have a large impact, a point thatTaleb illustrates by saying while it is acceptable to takea medicine that might be effective with a 5% error rate, but

    offers no side effects otherwise, it is foolish to play Russianroulette with the knowledge that one should win with a 5%error rate (748) Thus, low forecast error rates for eventsthat occur with low probability, but high impact, can lead toterrible decisions. So, forecast accuracy and decision qual-

    ity are interdependent. This leads Taleb to focus on what hecalls the fourth quadrantthe area in which both themagnitude of forecast errors is large and the sensitivity tothese errors is consequential. (748)

    Some types of decisions are easy, when they turn onthe zeroth moment, merely the probability of events andnot their magnitude. These arise in binary payoff situations,such as matters of truth or falsity or winning or losing anelection. Also manageable are those situations with linearpayoffs, such as predictions in nance generally, matters ofclimate, and the occurrence of epidemics. Problems arisewhen decisions turn on higher moments that have non-lin-ear payoffs, such as the payoffs of derivatives and leveragedportfolios.

    Forecasting is safe for binary decisions about thin-tailed (Type-1) distributions (rst quadrant), and is work-able for complex decisions about thin-tailed distributions(second quadrant). For simple decisions about fat-tailed(Type-2) distributions, normal statistical methods alsowork well, even though pitfalls are present. Even for simpledecisions about Type-2 distributions (third quadrant), fore-casting is valuable because the tails of the distribution havelittle impact on the payoff.

    The real problem arises in the fourth quadrant, com-plex decisions for Type-2 distributions. Here forecastingfails to lead to good decisions. In such situations, one mustavoid the fourth quadrant.

    Talebs main idea is to endogenize decisions, i.e.,escape the 4th quadrant whenever possible by changingthe payoff in reaction to the high degree of unpredictabil-ity and the harm it causes. (755) For example, one shouldtransact to cap potential losses of a transaction.

    Errors, Robustness,

    and the Fourth QuadrantNassim Nicholas Taleb

    International Journal of Forecasting, October 2009, 25:4, 744-759.

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    5/15

    5http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Vivian Fang, Thomas Noe, and Sheri Tice (FNT) ex-plore the relationship between stock market liquidity andrm performance. There have been a number of theoreticalanalyses of the effect of liquid markets on rm performance,including suggestions that liquid markets help promote

    more efcient management compensation, reduce manage-rial opportunism, and stimulate trading by informed inves-tors, which improves investment decision making throughshare prices that convey more information.

    In contrast to these theoretical studies, FNT offer anempirical examination of the effect of stock market liquid-ity on rm performance.

    FNT draw data for their study from numerous sourcesincluding CRSP, Compustat, Institutional Brokers Esti-mates System, Investor Responsibility Research Center(IRRC), and the Trade and Quote database. Because theyare interested in rm performance, FNT use annual rm

    data. Due to data limitations from IRRC, the authors re-strict their sample to six years: 1993, 1995, 1998, 2000,2002, and 2004. This yields a nal sample of 2,642 rmswith 8,290 rm-year observations.

    FNT use Tobins Q (broadly, the ratio of market valueto book value) to gauge rm performance. They measureliquidity as the relative effective spread, which is based onthe execution price and the mid-point of the prevailing bid-ask quote. The effective spread is the difference between theexecution price and this mid-point, with this quantity beingdivided by the mid-point. The relative effective spread is

    the effective spread standardized by the stock price level.FNT also use a number of control variables including ameasure of leverage, an index of shareholder rights, stockmarket momentum, rm size and age, Delaware incorpora-tion, S&P 500 inclusion, and so on.

    They regress Q on the liquidity measure and the con-trol variables for each year individually and for the pool ofsix years of data. The relationship between Q and liquidityis strongly positive in all cases, showing that higher stock

    market liquidity (a lower spread) is correlated with higherrm performance as measured by Q. The effect appearseconomically signicant as well, with an increase in liquid-ity of one standard deviation leading to an increase in Q of0.61. FNT also use alternative liquidity measures and nd

    their results to be robust.A number of control variables are also highly signi-

    cant showing that: weaker shareholder rights are correlat-ed with lower rm performance, small companies havehigher performance, S&P 500 companies have higherrm performance, younger rms tend to have higher rmperformance, and the more analysts following a stock thehigher the rms Q. (158)

    While the statistical correlation between liquidity andhigher rm performance, Q, is strong, there is a questionof the direction of causality. Does stock market liquiditycontribute to rm performance or are the stocks of stronglyperforming rms more liquid?

    FNT examine this issue by focusing on the decimal-ization of stock prices: The change in liquidity surround-ing decimalization is used as an instrument for liquidity todocument that stocks with a larger increase in liquidity fol-lowing decimalization have a larger increase in rm perfor-mance. (151) FNT regress the change in Q on the changein liquidity occurring at decimalization, which leads themto conclude: An increase in liquidity surrounding decimal-ization results in an increase in rm Q. (162)

    FNT conduct a number of sub-analyses based on de-

    composing Q into price-to-operating earnings, nancial le-verage, and operating protability. They nd that liquidityenhances rm performance through higher operating prot-ability, which leads to an enhanced value of performance-sensitive managerial compensation.

    Also, information feedback from stock prices to rmmanagers and other stakeholders is one mechanism respon-sible for better rm performance for rms with higher stockmarket liquidity. (167)

    Stock Market

    Liquidity and Firm ValueVivian W. Fang, Thomas H. Noe, and Sheri Tice

    Journal of Financial Economics,October 2009, 94:1, 150-169.

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    6/15

    6http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Philippe Jorion and Gaiyan Zhang (JZ) explore theproblem of historically observed clusterings of default orcredit contagion, which arises when the default of onerm causes nancial distress for its creditors. (2054) Thisempirically observed phenomenon of contagion exposes a

    signicant weakness of standard credit risk models whichare unable to explain such contagion.

    JZ examine a sample of 251 Chapter 11 bankruptciesfrom 1999-2005, which are drawn from 146 industries, in-volved 570 creditors, and represent a total credit amountin excess of $8 billion. JZ focus on the bankrupts largesttwenty creditors. Data for the study come from the websitewww.bankruptcy.com. Company and stock data sourcesare from CRSP and Compustat, while they drew informa-tion on the credit default swap (CDS) spreads from Markit.

    Importantly, this sample includes both industrial andnancial creditors. Industrial creditors are exposed to bank-

    ruptcies largely through the extension of unsecured tradecredit. But industrial creditors also have potentially impor-tant exposure due to business relationships, which can bedisrupted or even terminated by the bankruptcy. Thus, forindustrial creditors, a bankruptcy can mean not only theloss of value from the extension of credit, but also the lossof a business relationship.

    By contrast, nancial creditors, such as banks, havegenerally made loans to the rms that go bankrupt. Relativeto its own size, industrial creditors generally have greaterexposure to a bankrupt rm than do nancial creditors.

    This is due to the generally large size of banks and the lim-its on lending to a single borrower that banks face.The key analysis employs a standard event methodol-

    ogy. JZ analyze the effect of the announcement of a bank-ruptcy on the stock prices and CDS spreads of creditors. Toisolate the credit contagion effect of the bankruptcy, JZ also

    control for industry effects on the movement of stock pricesand for credit rating effects in the case of CDS spreads. Asthey expected, JZ nd that the announcement of the bank-ruptcy brings a negative stock price response and an in-crease in the CDS spread for creditors.

    For an 11-day window around the bankruptcy an-nouncement, JZ nd an abnormal equity return for credi-tors of -1.9 percent, after adjusting for industry and creditrating effects. This translates into a loss of $174 million forthe median creditor. (2056) For creditors, the CDS spreadincreases by ve basis points on average. This CDS spreadeffect is statistically signicant but small. (JZ note that theCDS spread difference between BBB and BBB- instru-ments is 28 basis points.)

    JZ also track the ongoing effects of the bankruptcy onthe creditors and nd that creditors with large exposuresare more likely to fail themselves. They further nd that

    these counterparty effects are reliably associated witha number of variables, including the relative size of the ex-posure, the recovery rate, and previous stock return correla-tions. (2056) The deeper the business relationship betweenthe failing rm and the creditor, the greater is the coun-terparty effect: the counterparty effect is considerablystronger when the debtor is a major customer of the creditor,and when the debtor liquidates rather than when it reorga-nizes because the creditor incurs a loss not only from itscurrent exposure but also from future business. (2056)

    Consistent with this nding, JZ discover that the overall

    wealth and distress effects are greater for industrial ratherthan nancial creditors. In sum, The results indicate thatcounterparty risk does affect the shape of the default dis-tribution, thus providing a potential explanation for the ob-served default clustering. (2056)

    Credit Contagion

    from Counterparty RiskPhilippe Jorion and Gaiyan Zhang

    The Journal of Finance, October 2009, 64:5, 2053-2087.

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    7/15

    7http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Much option speculation focuses on volatility, andthese trades imply that the markets expectation of futurevolatility is erroneous. Believing that volatility misesti-mation is the most obvious source of options mispricing(310), Goyal and Saretto (GS) focus on gaps between his-

    torical volatility (HV) and implied volatility (IV), and offera conjecture that large deviations of IV from HV areindicative of option mispricing. (311)

    To analyze such a strategy, GS sort stocks accordingto the difference between HV and IV, and they computereturns of straddles and delta-hedged call portfolios. Theyestimate HV using daily realized stock returns over the pri-or 12 months, and their measure of IV is the average of theimplied volatilities for the call and put contracts closest tothe money one month before expiration.

    GS draw their option data from the OptionMetrics IvyDB database, which includes daily bid and ask quotes for

    options and their IVs. Their sample period is 1996-2006and covers 4,344 stocks, yielding 75,627 month-pairs of calland put contracts. For their decile portfolios of options, thedifference between HV and IV ranges from -0.148 to 0.197.

    They report for their option straddle trades: We ndthat a zero-cost trading strategy involving a long position inan option portfolio of stocks with a large positive differencebetween HV and IV and a short position in an option port-folio of stocks with a large negative difference generatesstatistically and economically signicant returns. (311)Across their deciles, these monthly straddle returns range

    from -12.8 percent to 9.9 percent.They nd similar results for delta-hedged calls: we nd statistically and economically signicant positivereturns for high decile portfolios and negative returns forlow decile portfolios of delta-hedged calls. (311) While

    the returns from the hedge portfolios are lower than thoseof the straddles, they are still economically large.

    GS nd that their results are robust with respect tovarious sample periods and alternative volatility measures.They consider trading costs and take into account the capi-

    tal demands of margin requirements, but their strategy stillresults in economically important prots. GS nd that thereturns to their option strategies covary with some stockcharacteristics that help to explain stock returns, but theyjudge that this covariance is not enough to explain thehigh realized returns to our strategy. (311)

    GS seek to understand their unusual results by furtherexamining changes in volatility that lead to the deviationsbetween HV and IV. These large deviations between HVand IV are transitory and the emergence of these deviationsis driven by extreme patterns in stock returns. The patternof deviations is consistent with investors who overreact to a

    recent sharp stock price movement.Thus, they rapidly adjust their estimates of future vola-

    tility, causing the sharp divergence between HV and IV. Thequestion is whether these sharp divergences are rational.That is, do investors rapidly adjust their estimates of futurehistorical volatility (the new IV) to the correct level? GSnd that these large deviations are, in fact, short-lived. GSalso nd that future realized volatility does not changeby as much as predicted by IV. (325)

    This apparent overreaction is inconsistent with thetraditional nance view of rational investors, but it can be

    accommodated within a behavioral nance approach. GSrefer to a behavioral model by Barberis and Huang (Journalof Finance, 2001) in which investors form future volatilityestimates that are overreactions to recent stock price chang-es. For GS, their empirical results are broadly consistentwith the model of Barberis and Huang.

    Cross-Section of

    Option Returns and VolatilityAmit Goyal and Alessio Saretto

    Journal of Financial Economics,November 2009 94:2, 310-326.

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    8/15

    8http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Scott Harrington focuses on the role of AIG in the -nancial crisis of 2007-2009 and the surge of interest in in-creasing regulation of insurance companies. He examinesthe potential systemic risk posed by insurance companiesand the need for insurance companies to fall under the pur-

    view of a systemic risk regulator. After surveying some ofthe general causes of the nancial crisis, Harrington turnsto the role of the insurance sector in the crisis and concludesthat the insurance sector as a whole was largely and per-haps remarkably on the periphery of the crisis. (788)

    The apparent counterexample to this claim is AIG,which Harrington examines at some length, noting thatAIGs problems were not closely related to any insuranceactivity, but were largely conned to AIGs nancial prod-ucts division with its trading of credit default swaps alongwith its securities lending operation.

    Harrington notes that some life insurers have faced

    considerable distress and sought funding under TARP(Troubled-Asset Relief Program), but the participation ofthese rms in TARP was negligible. (788) Monolinemortgage and bond insurers suffered large losses and creditdowngrades, yet none has received bailout funding andnone has failed to date.

    In an extended examination of AIGs nancial prob-lems during the crisis, Harrington traces AIGs problemsto areas beyond the regulated insurance subsidiaries. None-theless, Harrington points out that all aspects of AIG weresubject to regulation: as a consequence of owning a sav-

    ings and loan subsidiary, AIG was subject to consolidatedregulation and oversight by the OTS [Ofce of Thrift Su-pervision]. . . (799) Further, Harrington quotes testimonyof OTS Acting Director Scott Polakoff, who said: OTSmaintained a contemporaneous understanding of all mate-rial parts of the AIG group, including their domestic andcross-border operations. (799)

    Harrington notes the considerable literature that agreesthat systemic risk is relatively low in insurance marketscompared to banking. This is especially true for property-

    casualty insurance, but holds well also for life insurers. Fur-ther, Harrington notes, problems with insurance rms donot threaten the nancial payments system. During 2009, avariety of policy proposals called for increased regulationof insurers as do some pieces of proposed federal legisla-

    tion. These include optional and mandatory federal char-tering, the designation and regulation of some insurers assystemically signicant, and the inception of active fed-eral regulation of the insurance industry. For example, theOfce of National Insurance Act of 2009 calls for the for-mation of an Ofce of National Insurance (ONI) to moni-tor all aspects of the insurance industry. (806) The Bean-Royce Federal Charter Bill would create an optional federalchartering system and lodge an ONI within Treasury.

    Harrington concentrates on the desirability of bring-ing insurance markets under the purview of a systemic riskregulator. Harrington argues that designating an insurancecompany as systemically signicant would make it too-big-to-fail (TBTF), that such a designation would lead toimplicit or explicit government guarantees of the obliga-tions of such rms, that it would lead to competitive imbal-ances between the systemically signicant rms and theothers, and that systemically signicant rms would haveincentives to alter their nancial and operating decisions inundesirable directions.

    Further, Harrington believes that the urge for greaterregulation of insurers does not adequately consider thecosts and benets of such a regulatory regime, that it does

    not consider the failure of such regulators to prevent the -nancial crisis in the banking sector, that it ignores the mod-est role of the insurance sector in the recent crisis, and that itprovides no guidance for limiting the scope of discretionaryfederal authority.

    In sum: As a result of these considerations, creation ofa systemic risk regulatory for insurers and other nonbankinstitutions designated as systemically signicant wouldnot be good policy. It would instead illustrate the adage thatbad policy begets bad policy. (808)

    The Financial Crisis, Systemic Risk,

    and the Future of Insurance RegulationScott E. Harrington

    The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2009, 76:4, 785-819.

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    9/15

    9http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Philippe Jorion seeks to evaluate the role of risk man-agement systems in the nancial crisis of 2007-2009. Henotes that risk measures have typically been built usingreturns-based information, so they are backward-looking,easy and cheap to implement, and reect the dynamic

    trading of the portfolio. However, such measures offer noguidance for innovations in instruments, markets or man-agers, and they are slow to identify style drift. In short,returns-based risk measures give no insight into therisk drivers of the portfolio. (925) By contrast, all mod-ern risk management systems employ position-based riskmeasures, which use the most current information on abanks investment positions.

    As such they are immediately applicable to new in-struments, markets, and managers, and can be used for for-ward-looking stress tests. The drawbacks of position-basedsystems are that they are static over the risk management

    horizon and fail to reect dynamic trading. Also, they aresusceptible to data and modeling error and are expensive.Nonetheless, Jorion notes that all modern risk manage-ment architectures rely on position-level information. (925)

    In classifying risk management problems, Jorion re-fers to Donald Rumsfelds classication of risks as knownknowns, known unknowns, and unknown unknowns.Known knowns characterize a awless risk measurementsystem. (926) Large losses do not necessarily imply thefailure of such risk management systems. For example, arisk management system may assess risks perfectly, but

    managers may adopt positions of high risk that lead to largelosses, or they may simply experience bad luck. Similarly,experience may conform to the frequency of value-at-risk(VAR) estimates, but may just be extreme.

    For known unknowns, actual risk management systemsare susceptible to model errors, such as ignoring impor-tant known risks or measuring risks (such as correlationsand volatilities) inaccurately. These kinds of model errorsplayed a role in the crisis. For example, buying a corpo-rate bond and a related credit default swap (CDS) should

    be an arbitrage trade. However, mapping both instrumentsto the same risk factor ignores the basis risk. In 2008, thebasis widened substantially leading to large mark-to-marketlosses. Similarly, if the parameters of the risk model are es-timated with data from a low-risk period, the impression

    from these estimates may lead to a banks adopting highleverage that is unsuitable to a future higher risk environ-ment. Similarly, correlations among mortgage-based assetswere estimated from a long historical period with uniform-ly rising real estate prices, which led to thin capitalizationof mortgage-backed security positions.

    In addition, risk management systems are beset byunknown unknownsevents totally outside the scopeof most scenarios. (929) Even for a bank that knows itscounterparties, there can still be network externalities, be-cause a bank is implicitly exposed to the risk of the bankscounterparties counterparties. Thus, Understanding thefull consequences of Lehmans failure would have requiredinformation on the entire topology of the nancial net-work. (929) As a consequence, banks are exposed to sys-temic risk, for which they cannot possibly carry sufcientcapital. Jorion believes that these problems emphasize thedeciency of economic capital analysis.

    Jorion draws some lessons for future risk manage-ment. He believes that banks should develop forward-look-ing scenarios and stress test their models. For some banks(e.g., UBS) such a practice would have revealed aws intheir risk management systems. Firms with hierarchical

    management structures did not encourage feedback fromrisk management systems, and failed to develop their ownvaluation models, relying on credit ratings instead. For thefuture, Jorion advocates overweighting recent data in riskmodels, using stress tests, and developing broader scenar-io analysis. He points out that all such methods requirea position-based risk management system and concludesthat the crisis has reinforced the importance of risk man-agement. Risk management will not go away as a corefunction of nancial institutions. (933)

    Risk Management

    Lessons from the Credit CrisisPhilippe Jorion

    European Financial Management, November 2009, 5:5, 923-933.

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    10/15

    10http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Michael Mervin and Mark Taylor (MT) examinethe behavior of the foreign exchange market during thenancial crisis that began in 2007. Their aim is tocatalogue all that was truly of major importance in thisepisode. (1317) They also construct an index of nancial

    stress for foreign exchange (FX) and use this as a basisto compare dislocation in the FX market across severalcrisis episodes. Finally, they discuss whether it might havebeen possible to predict the dislocations that occurred inthe recent crisis.

    MT provide a chronicle of events in the FX marketassociated with the crisis and portray the FX market ashaving been beset by four special crisis episodes from2007 to early 2009. These occurred in August 2007 withcontagion from other asset classes, a major unwinding ofthe carry trade and large deleveraging in FX in November2007, a sharp reaction in March 2008 that accompanied

    the demise of Bear Stearns, and, most spectacularly, anextreme reaction in September 2008 as Lehman Brothersfell into bankruptcy.

    The nancial crisis beset the FX market rather late,after the equity markets had already suffered large losses.MT date the beginning of the crisis for FX to August 2007,and more particularly to August 16, 2007: on this datea major unwinding of the carry trade occurred and manycurrency market investors suffered huge losses. (1318) Inthe run up to August, currency volatilities increased froma typical annualized standard deviation of around 8 per-

    cent to 28 percent.Focusing on the Australian dollar (a high interest ratecurrency) and the Japanese yen (the premier low interest ratecurrency), MT note: the 1-day change in the JPY priceof the AUD on August 16, 2007 was -7.7% (1318) whichcompares to a normal one-day uctuation of 0.7 percent.

    The market then enjoyed relative calm for several months.From November 7 to November 12, 2007, the AUD/

    JPY exchange rate fell about 9 percent, and volatilitysurged. MT trace this episode to dislocation in credit mar-kets, which resulted in forced liquidations of some posi-

    tions to reduce leverage. A comparable surge in FX dislo-cation occurred in March 2008, but the resolution of BearStearns calmed markets: Once it was clear that Bearwould be sold and not go bankrupt, credit risk recededand remained fairly low through the summer. (1321)

    The largest shock to the FX market paralleled thedeath throes of Lehman Brothers in September 2008.Compared to November 2007 and March 2008, volatilitywas more than double, as was the TED spread (the yielddifference between U.S. treasuries and LIBOR). MT de-scribe these volatility levels as incredible (1322), andthey mince no words in assessing the policy decision of

    the Federal Reserve and the U.S. Treasury that allowedLehman to go into bankruptcy: This ultimately turnedout to be a disastrous decision that imposed losses on oth-er rms across the industry and created turmoil not seenbefore. (1322)

    MT also create a nancial stress index in the spiritof a proposal by the International Monetary Fund. The in-dex is based on 17 major currencies and reects risk mea-sures from the banking sector, the securities market, andthe FX market. They show that from 1982-2008 the twogreatest periods of stress occurred with the Russian de-

    fault in 1987 and with the Lehman episode, with Lehmantaking honors by a relatively small degree. MT also showthe returns to the carry trade from 2000 through the cri-sis. In spite of being consistently protable for most of theperiod, the strategy earned a negative cumulative return ifheld for the entire period.

    The Crisis in the

    Foreign Exchange MarketMichael Mervin and Mark P. Taylor

    Journal of International Money and Finance,December 2009, 28:8, 1317-1330.

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    11/15

    11http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Since the development of the Black-Scholes optionpricing model (BS), a number of other models have beendeveloped, including jump diffusion models (JD), sto-chastic volatility models (SV), and models that incorpo-rate both stochastic volatility and jump diffusion features

    (SVJ). As applied to plain vanilla options, some of thesuccessors outperform BS on pricing, but all seem to per-form similarly in hedging effectiveness.

    Yunbi An and Wulin Suo (AS) test the hedging ef-fectiveness of these four models in hedging exotic options,such as barrier and compound options. Testing exotic op-tions to assess hedging effectiveness presents these mod-els with a higher hurdle, because exotic options are more sensitive to model misspecications and could beseriously mispriced or mishedged by a model that mightotherwise accurately value European options. (890)

    As exotic options trade over-the-counter, historical

    data are not available, so AS test a synthetically createdexotic option. For a given option and its price, AS use thevarious models to infer the parameters of the model, andthey measure hedging effectiveness from the perspectiveof a trader seeking to minimize risk through dynamichedging. For barrier options, AS focus on up-and-outcalls, and for compound options they concentrate on call-on-call options.

    Data for the study were downloaded from the websiteof the British Bankers Association and include the EUR/USD Currency Option Volatility Index and LIBOR rates

    for the dollar and euro from 2002-2007. AS use these datato generate 23,307 option prices, with 17 observations perday. To test hedging effectiveness, AS use two dynamichedging strategies, a minimum variance strategy and adelta-vega neutral hedging strategy.

    For the minimum variance strategy, AS nd that theSV model generally outperforms the BS model in hedgingmost up-and-out calls. This suggests that incorporatingthe stochastic volatility into the model framework signi-

    cantly improves the performance of hedging these typesof barrier options (904) However, the BS model per-forms about the same for hedging long-term out-of-the-money options. AS document wide variation in hedgingeffectiveness as the moneyness and maturity of the barrier

    options vary. In general, they conrm that model per-formance depends on the degree of path dependence ofthe exotic option considered. (906)

    Not surprisingly, hedging performance is worse thelower the knock-out price, and AS nd that for in-the-money options hedging performance also deterioratesas the maturities increase for any given barrier level.(906) Call-on-call options with low strike prices and lon-ger maturities are easier to hedge. That is, the hedgingerrors are smaller for these options. AS nd similarly di-verse results for delta-vega hedging strategies.

    One of the main conclusions reached by AS is thatthe performance of the alternative models relative tothe BS model depends on how exotic the hedged optionis. Barrier options are more path dependent than com-pound options; therefore, the models relative performanceof hedging barrier options is quite different from that ofhedging compound options. (912) For most up-and-outcalls, the SV outperforms the BS model, but the JD andSVJ perform poorly. But for hedging call-on-call options,these alternative models perform better.

    They also conclude that choosing a suitable modelis particularly important for hedging different types of

    exotic options. (912) Further, the hedging effectivenessof all models deteriorates the more exotic the options be-come: For hedging up-and-out calls, both the barrier lev-el and the maturity have a great impact on the hedging ef-fectiveness. It is most risky to hedge up-and-out calls witha very low barrier level, and the hedging errors increasewith the maturities for ITM [in-the-money] up-and-outoptions. (912)

    An Empirical Comparison of

    Option-Pricing Models in Hedging Exotic OptionsYunbi An and Wulin Suo

    Financial Management, Winter 2009, 38:4, 889-914.

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    12/15

    12http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Entrop, Wilkens, and Zeisler (EWZ) analyze thestandardized framework (SF) proposed by the BaselCommittee on Banking Supervision in 2004, which seeksto quantify the interest rate risk of banks. While Basel IIestablishes mandatory capital requirements for credit and

    operational risk, there are no mandatory capital require-ments for interest rate risk.

    In contrast to credit and operational risk, interestrate risk falls under pillar 2 of Basel II, the supervisoryreview process. These principles for managing and su-pervising interest rate risk call for particular attention tooutlier banksthose whose economic value in relationto regulatory capital declines by more than 20% if a stan-dardised interest rate shock occurs. (1002) This shockis a parallel shift in the yield curve of 200 basis points ineither direction. This approach has been incorporated intolaw in many countries including Germany. If assumptions

    incorporated in the SF are inadequate or too simplistic,poor supervision and faulty risk management may result.EWZ seek to test the adequacy of the SFs assumptions.

    The SF operates via the bucketing of interest-rate sen-sitive assets and liabilities into 13 time bands of remain-ing time to maturity for xed-rate instruments and for therepricing period of oating rate instruments. Bands rangefrom less than one month, up to a period in excess of 20years. The SF then uses duration technology to calculateinterest rate risk.

    EWZ generalize the SF to allow them to analyze the

    models assumptions on the estimation of interest raterisk, and they test the effect of these assumptions usingdata on the German universal banking system providedby the Deutsche Bundesbank. These data cover more than90 percent of all assets and liabilities, but do not reectderivatives positions.

    As German banking supervisors use only four timebands, EWZ develop a model to allocate assets and liabili-ties to the more ne-grained time bands of the SF. Usingtheir simulation of the SF, EWZ nd that the interest raterisk of the German universal banking system is 30.9 per-

    cent, meaning that the standard interest rate shock (200basis points) would cause a gain or loss of 30.9 percentof the banking systems capital. (Derivatives are omitted,which would presumably have cushioned this sensitivity.)

    EWZ nd that even slight modications of the

    SFs assumptions make the measured sensitivity of thebanking system change radically. For example, the SFassumes that the relevant modied duration of savingsdeposits is 2.5 years, but changing this to either ve orzero years makes the interest rate risk swing from 40.9to 20.9 percent, respectively.

    The SF assumes that all of the instruments in a giventime band are concentrated at the mid-point of the band.(The same is true of the system used by the Federal Re-serve in the U.S.) Varying assumptions about how instru-ments are distributed within each time band can have verylarge effects on the measured interest rate risk. For ex-ample, Assuming actual German reporting practices, theestimation of the interest rate risk may vary by up to 28percentage points. (1012)

    Beyond assuming that maturities are located at thecenter of the various time bands, the SF assumes thatamortization rates are zero and that coupon rates equalmarket interest rates. EWZ nd that these assumptionsare also singly important, and that varying these assump-tions strongly affects interest rate risk estimates. Varyingconditions of maturities within time bands, number andbreadth of time bands, amortization rates, and coupon

    rate divergences from market rates have very large effectstaken together.EWZ conclude that the standardised framework

    can misjudge the level of interest rate risk of banks bya considerable amount if a banks structure differs fromthe Committees assumptions. (1016), that the Com-mittees model cannot be expected to appropriately distin-guish between low-risk and high-risk banks, (1016) andthat the standardized model cannot reliably identifythe outlier banks that supervisors should pay special at-tention to. (1016)

    Quantifying the Interest Rate

    Risk of Banks: Assumptions Do MatterOliver Entrop, Marco Wilkens, and Alexander Zeisler

    European Financial Management, November 2009, 15:5, 1001-1018.

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    13/15

    13http://www.RMRR.com Winter 2010

    A publication of the School of Business at Loyola University Chicago

    Richard Clarida, Josh Davis and Niels Pederson (CDP)explore the persistent failure of uncovered interest rateparity: In a risk-neutral world the forward exchange rateshould be an unbiased predictor of the future spot exchangerate. (1375) Instead, this is a prediction that has consistent-

    ly failed: Today, just as 25 years ago, papers continue tond that currencies with high interest rates tend on averageto appreciate relative to currencies in countries with low in-terest rates. (1375)

    This stylized fact constitutes the forward rate biaspuzzle. (1375) The persistence of this stylized fact hasdriven a consistently successful investment strategy, thecarry trade: investors can make systematic prots byshorting the low yielding currency and taking a long posi-tion in the high yielding currency. (1376)

    Using data from Bloomberg, CDP rst document thepersistent protability of the carry trade. Focusing on the

    period from 1992-2009 and restricting the analysis to thecurrencies of G10 countries, CDP form long/short currencyportfolios by shorting the low interest rate currency andtaking a long position in the high interest rate currency.

    They do this for one-currency portfolios (lowest inter-est rate currency vs. highest interest rate currency), two-currency portfolios (two lowest vs. two highest), and soon up to ve currency portfolios, which exhausts the G10.These portfolios exhibit strong positive returns, on average,over the entire period. This is true even omitting portfoliosformed with the Japanese yen, which has had extremely low

    interest rates for the last few decades.CDP nd that forming multi-currency portfolios pro-vides a signicant diversication benet, but that there is acost in terms of achieved returns. They also nd: Overall,the returns to currency carry portfolios are positive with

    Sharpe ratios that are comparable or superior to those onequity investments (1378), and that this is true both withand without the yen and the dollar in the portfolios. Howev-er, against the background of overall large positive averagereturns from the carry trade strategy, CDP also document

    signicant periods of sharp losses for such strategies.This leads to a consideration of the relationship between

    carry trade returns and exchange rate volatility, for whichthey conclude: The implication of this co-movement is thatwhen the carry returns are high, return volatilities are lowand vice versa. (1380) Dividing the days in their sampleinto quartiles based on exchange rate volatility, CDP ndthat the high volatility days are associated with negativecarry trade returns, while low volatility days generate posi-tive carry trade returns.

    The Fama regression relates changes in the spot ex-change rate to a constant and the lagged differential in ex-

    change rates implied by covered interest rate parity betweena high and low interest rate currency. If uncovered interestrate parity holds, the coefcient in this regression shouldequal unity. Numerous studies have found a signicantlynegative coefcient for this regression, which CDP conrm.

    However, for separate samples of high and low vola-tility days, CDP nd: the estimated coefcient on theinterest differential changes from being signicant and verynegative for the low volatility state to signicant and verypositive in the high volatility state. (1384)

    Finally, CDP also examine the relationship between

    returns on the carry trade and the yield curve for the twocurrencies. We showed that yield curve level factors arepositively correlated with carry trade excess returns whileyield curve slope factors are negatively correlated with car-ry trade excess returns. (1388)

    Currency Carry Trade

    Regimes: Beyond the Fama RegressionRichard Clarida, Josh Davis, and Niels Pederson

    Journal of International Money and Finance, December 2009, 28:8, 1375-1389.

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    14/15

    CME Group Foundations mission is to enhance economic

    opportunity by supporting academic initiatives and

    activities, primarily in the Chicago region, that:

    Promote research, teaching and learning in nancial

    markets, futures and derivatives;

    Promote the education of disadvantaged children

    and youth; and

    Promote the health and education of young children.

    CME GROUPFOUNDATION

    |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||

  • 8/3/2019 Rm Research Report Winter 2010

    15/15

    PRMIA Expands

    Complete Course in Risk Management Program

    Offering Program in Six Locations During 2010

    Due to ongoing demand from risk managers around the world, PRMIA, in conjunction with several of its University Partners,is now offering members six opportunities to participate in the Complete Course in Risk Management.This executive education program gives risk professionals the tools they need to help advance their careers in risk manage-

    ment and was developed to meet the demands of risk professionals by bridging the gap between theory and practice in financial

    risk management. In addition, it provides the opportunity to network and learn with other risk professionals who share common

    challenges and goals.

    Click on the city names below to learn more about each course or to register.

    New YorkColumbia Business School

    Meets one evening per week for 20 weeks, January 13 June 2, 2010

    Washington, DC

    George Washington University School of Business

    Meets one evening per week for 20 weeks, January 14 June 3, 2010

    Miami

    Kellogg School of Management

    Meets for five full consecutive days, March 9 13, 2010

    London

    University College London

    Meets for five full consecutive days, June 14 18, 2010

    Chicago

    Kellogg School of Management

    Meets for five full consecutive days, July 19 23, 2010

    Cairo

    American University Cairo

    October 2010

    Please do not hesitate to contact Jill Fisher at [email protected]

    with any questions you may have about these courses.

    |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||

    An essential course for those who pursueRisk Management as a career.

    This short course on risk management crams more into it than many other certificate oreven degree level courses. The professors are excellent and the material ensures a solid

    foundation in the subject. I would unhesitatingly recommend this course.

    Best professors,

    best material,

    best people;

    this course was

    time well spent.

    http://prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3598http://prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3629http://prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3723http://prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3797http://prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3724http://www.prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3593http://prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3598http://prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3629http://prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3723http://prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3797http://prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3724http://www.prmia.org/events/view_events.php?eventID=3593