resource economics: introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/introduction.pdf · monday, january...

37
Resource Economics: Introduction G Cornelis van Kooten University of Victoria

Upload: others

Post on 04-Aug-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Resource Economics: Introduction

G Cornelis van Kooten

University of Victoria

Page 2: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

x

g(x)

0 K

Logistic growth function: g(xt)

𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = g𝑥𝑡 1 −𝑥𝑡𝐾

ht=qutxt

q is a catchability coefficient

ut is effort (control variable)

g is intrinsic growth rate

K is ecosystem carrying capacity

Page 3: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

x

g(x)

0 K

𝑔 𝑥 = 𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = g𝑥𝑡 1 −𝑥𝑡𝐾

ht=qutxt

xSSxMSY

To find maximum sustainable yield:

Set g′ 𝑥 = g −2𝑔𝑥

𝐾= 0

This gives: xMSY = ½ K

To find steady state solution:

Set ht = xt+1 – xt

g 1 −𝑥𝑡𝐾

= 𝑞𝑢𝑡

Solving for xt gives: xSS = 𝐾 g−𝑞𝑢

g

Page 4: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Monday, January 13, 2020 4

The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

xt+1 = g xt (1 – xt)

where 0 ≤ x ≤ 1 is the proportion of a wildlife population or fish biomass, and g is the intrinsic growth rate

x=0 → extinction

x=1 → carrying capacity of system

Choose g = 2.7 and x0 = 0.5 → convergence to x=0.6296

As g increases to 2.9, 3.0, 3.5, 3.82, 3.83, 3.84, 3.85 one gets bifurcations and chaos

Non-linearity is problematic.

Page 5: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Logistics growth function (cont)

𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = g𝑥𝑡 1 −𝑥𝑡𝐾

• 0 < g ≤ 1: steadily approach K without overshooting

• 1 < g ≤ 2: overshoots K but approaches K with damped oscillations

• 2 < g ≤ 2.449: two-point cycles about K (bifurcation)

• 2.449 < g ≤ 2.570: stable cycles with 2n points, n≥1 (n depends on g)

• g ≥ 2.570: irregular, non-periodic behaviour that leads to dynamic chaos

Page 6: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

% Logistics bifurcation diagram

clear allN = 1000;x = zeros(1,N+1);x(1) = 0.2;% r = [2.7 2.9 2.95 2.99 3 3.1 3.5];g = 2.7:.001:4;figure;for i=1:length(r)% R = g(i)for t=1:Nx(t+1) = g(i)*x(t)*(1-x(t));end% X = x(N+1)hold on

plot(g(i)*ones(1,100),x(N-98:N+1),'.','LineStyle','none','MarkerSize',.1,'color', 'k')% figure;% plot(x,'.','LineStyle','none','MarkerSize',.1,'color', 'k')% xlim([0 1000])% ylim([0 1])% xlabel('# of iterations')% ylabel('x')% title([‘g = ' num2str(r(i))])endxlabel(‘g')ylabel('x')

MATLAB code for logistics growth function: bifurcation and chaos(Can also do this in Octave, which is free software.)

Page 7: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

# Logistics bifurcation diagram

N <- 199 #Number of iterationsK <- N+1x <- rep(0,N)x[1] <- 0.5 # Starting value for fish stockg <- 2.7 # values of intrinsic growth rate: 2.7, 2.9, 3.0, 3.5, 3.82, 3.83, 3.84, 3.85z <- c(1:K)

for (t in 1:N) {x[t+1] = g*x[t]*(1-x[t])

}

plot(z,x)

Simple R code for logistics growth function: bifurcation and chaos

Page 8: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

g=2.7

g=3.0

g=3.82

g=3.85

Page 9: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Monday, January 13, 2020 9

The logistics growth function can also be specified as follows:

xt+1 = xt + g xt (1 – xt)

where 0 ≤ x ≤ 1 is the proportion of a wildlife population or fish biomass, and g is the intrinsic growth rate

x=0 → extinction

x=1 → carrying capacity of system

Now the use of g = 1.7 and x0 = 0.5 → convergence to x=1.0

As g increases we again get bifurcations (g=2.1) and chaos (g=2.7)

Logistics growth and non-linearity (cont.).

Page 10: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

g=2.1

Page 11: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

DiscountingSuppose you receive $x from now into perpetuity. What is that worth? Further suppose the discount rate is δ(0 < δ ≤ 1). Let:

(1) 𝑉𝑛 = 𝑥 +𝑥

1+δ+

𝑥

1+δ 2 +⋯+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛

Page 12: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

DiscountingSuppose you receive $x from now into perpetuity. What is that worth? Further suppose the discount rate is δ(0 < δ ≤ 1). Let:

(1) 𝑉𝑛 = 𝑥 +𝑥

1+δ+

𝑥

1+δ 2 +⋯+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛

(2)1

1+δ𝑉𝑛 =

𝑥

1+δ+

𝑥

1+δ 2 +⋯+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛

Subtract (2) from (1):

(3) 𝑉𝑛 −1

1+δ𝑉𝑛 = 𝑥 −

𝑥

1+δ 𝑛+1 = 𝑥 1 −1

1+δ 𝑛+1

Page 13: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

DiscountingSuppose you receive $x from now into perpetuity. What is that worth? Further suppose the discount rate is δ(0 < δ ≤ 1). Let:

(1) 𝑉𝑛 = 𝑥 +𝑥

1+δ+

𝑥

1+δ 2 +⋯+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛

(2)1

1+δ𝑉𝑛 =

𝑥

1+δ+

𝑥

1+δ 2 +⋯+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛

Subtract (2) from (1):

(3) 𝑉𝑛 −1

1+δ𝑉𝑛 = 𝑥 −

𝑥

1+δ 𝑛+1 = 𝑥 1 −1

1+δ 𝑛+1

(4)δ

1+δ𝑉𝑛 = 𝑥 1 −

1

1+δ 𝑛+1

Page 14: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

DiscountingSuppose you receive $x from now into perpetuity. What is that worth? Further suppose the discount rate is δ (0 < δ ≤ 1). Let:

(1) 𝑉𝑛 = 𝑥 +𝑥

1+δ+

𝑥

1+δ 2 +⋯+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛

(2)1

1+δ𝑉𝑛 =

𝑥

1+δ+

𝑥

1+δ 2 +⋯+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛

Subtract (2) from (1):

(3) 𝑉𝑛 −1

1+δ𝑉𝑛 = 𝑥 −

𝑥

1+δ 𝑛+1 = 𝑥 1 −1

1+δ 𝑛+1

(4)δ

1+δ𝑉𝑛 = 𝑥 1 −

1

1+δ 𝑛+1

(5) V = lim𝑛→∞

𝑉𝑛 = lim𝑛→∞

𝑥 1+δ

δ1 −

1

1+δ 𝑛+1

0

Thus, 𝑉 = 𝑥1+𝛿

𝛿

Page 15: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Discounting #2Suppose instead you begin to receive $x one period from now and then into perpetuity. What is that worth? Let:

(1) 𝑉𝑛 =𝑥

1+δ+

𝑥

1+δ 2 +⋯+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛

(2)1

1+δ𝑉𝑛 =

𝑥

1+δ 2 +𝑥

1+δ 3 +⋯+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛+𝑥

1+δ 𝑛

Subtract (2) from (1):

(3) 𝑉𝑛 −1

1+δ𝑉𝑛 =

𝑥

1+δ−

𝑥

1+δ 𝑛+1 =𝑥

1+δ1 −

1

1+δ 𝑛

(4)δ

1+δ𝑉𝑛 =

𝑥

1+δ1 −

1

1+δ 𝑛

(5) V = lim𝑛→∞

𝑉𝑛 = lim𝑛→∞

𝑥

δ1 −

1

1+δ 𝑛

0

Thus, 𝑉 =𝑥

𝛿

Page 16: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Problem of the mine

Suppose you need to determine the optimal production schedule {yt} for removing ore from a mine that is

to be shut down and abandoned at time t=10. Price of ore is p=1and the extraction cost is ct = yt2/xt. Here xt

refers to the reserves remaining at time t. Assume initial reserves of x0 = 1,000. What does the problem

look like?

max𝑦𝑡

𝜋𝑡 = 𝑝 𝑦𝑡 −𝑦𝑡2

𝑥𝑡= 1 −

𝑦𝑡𝑥𝑡

𝑦𝑡

𝑠. 𝑡. 𝑥𝑡+1−𝑥𝑡 = −𝑦𝑡

This problem assumes no discounting. The Lagrangian for the problem can be written as:

𝐿 =

𝑡=1

10

1 −𝑦𝑡𝑥𝑡

𝑦𝑡 + λ𝑡+1 −𝑦𝑡 − 𝑥𝑡+1 + 𝑥𝑡

It is much simpler to write the Hamiltonian as:

𝐻 = 1 −𝑦𝑡𝑥𝑡

𝑦𝑡 − λ𝑡+1𝑦𝑡

Page 17: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

The first-order conditions are:

0)('and0

)3(

)2(

02

10)1(

10100

1

1

1

2

2

11

1

xSx

yxxH

xx

x

y

x

H

x

y

y

H

ttt

t

tt

t

ttt

t

tt

t

t

t

t

What does the value of λ10 tell us?

Page 18: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Mine problem (cont.)

This is a problem with 31 equations in 31 unknowns: yt for t = 0, 1, …, 9; xt for t = 0, 1,

…, 10; and λt for t = 1, …, 10

You can solve this problem in GAMS, say, or in Excel using the solver

You can also solve it by defining zt = yt/xt.

From (1) on the previous slide: 1 – 2zt = λt+1. Given λ10 = 0, z9 = ½.

Then, from (2) λt = λt+1 + zt implies λ9 = λ10 + z9 = ½.

In this way we can find all of the values for λ and z.

Finally, we can unravel the values of x and y using yt = xt×zt:

x0 = 1,000, so y0 = 1000×z0. Since we found z0 = 0.1389, then y0 = 138.9.

Then, using equation (3), xt+1 = xt – yt, so x1 = x0 – y0 = 1000 – 138.9 = 861.1

Now write a program in R to solve this problem.

Page 19: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

The fishery problem can be specified as follows:

)given(

)(1s.t.

)(),(Max

0

1

1

0

xx

uhK

xgxxx

xSuxRZ

tt

ttt

T

T

tt

T

t

t

• xt is the stock of fish at time t (measured as a mass, say in kg or tons)

• β = 1/(1+r) with r the discount rate is the discount factor

• Growth is modeled as a logistics function

• h(ut) is harvest as a function of effort u at time t

Page 20: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Re-write the growth equation (dynamic constraint or equation of motion) as:

K

xgxuhxx t

tttt 1)(1

We can refer to xt – h(ut) as escapement.

Escapement plus net growth gives the mass of

fish available in period t+1.

Page 21: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

1

0

11

1

00

1

0

1

)()(),(

T

t

ttt

tt

t

T

T

tt

T

t

t

xxK

xgx

xxxSuxRL

The lagrangian for the above problem can be written as follows:

How to solve this problem analytically is the subject of a discrete dynamic optimization video:

http://web.uvic.ca/~kooten/video/DiscreteDynamicOptimization.mp4

(A continuous time version: http://web.uvic.ca/~kooten/video/ContinuousDynamicOptimization.mp4)

We can solve the problem numerically as a constrained optimization (a nonlinear mathematical

programming) problem using GAMS if we are provided values of the parameters g, K, β (or r), T,

and the range of controls available to the decision maker.

Page 22: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

)()(1),( 00

1

0

11 T

TT

t

ttt

tttt

t xSxxxxK

xgxuxRL

Another way to write the Lagrangian is as follows:

Here it is clear that the term βλt+1 refers to the present value of the shadow price (marginal

cost of leaving the fish unharvested). The term βλt+1 is also known as the user cost or

discounted shadow price of remaining reserves in period t+1.

Page 23: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

0

11

00

1

0

)(),(L

bygiven is Lagrangian

given

)(s.t.

),(max

t

ttttttt

t

tttt

t

t

t

t

hxfxxhxR

xx

hxfxx

hxR

Also the transversality condition

lim𝑡→∞

𝛽𝑡λ𝑡𝑥𝑡 = 0

is assumed to hold.

Discrete-time, current-value Hamiltonian (h is the control variable harvest and f(x) is the growth equation)

Page 24: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Current-value Hamiltonian

0

11

1

)(L

bygiven is Lagrangian

)(),(

t

tttt

t

tttttt

xxH

hxfhxRH

Weitzman refers to the optimized Hamiltonian as the properly accounted income because

the 1st term on the RHS is the dividend from optimal management of the resource (fish

stock) while the 2nd term is the capital gain from the optimal management of the resource

today and in the future. Together then they are the properly accounted income.

To find the optimal levels of xt and ht, however, we first solve for the first-order conditions

(FOC). This is shown on the next slide.

Page 25: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

tttt

t

tt

t

t

t

t

t

tt

t

tt

hxfxxL

xx

x

f

x

R

x

H

h

R

h

H

)()(

1

0

:conditionsorder -1

1

1

1

11

1

st

Page 26: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

The value function of dynamic programming:

Dynamic Programming

ts

ss

ts

ts

ss

ts

ht hxRhxRxV

s

),(),(maximize )( **

}{

The forgoing procedure leads to the following recursive equation, known as Bellman’s Equation:

tttt

tttth

ttt

hxfxx

xVhxRhxVt

)(where

)(),(max),(

1

11

Page 27: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Dynamic Programming (cont):

0)2(

)1(

:conditionsorder 1

1

1

1

1

1

1

st

t

t

t

t

tt

t

t

t

t

t

tt

t

h

x

dx

dV

h

R

h

V

x

x

dx

dV

x

R

x

V

Consider equation (2):

1

t

th

R

1

1

1

1

1 0)1(

t

t

t

tt

t

t dx

dV

h

R

dx

dV

h

R

Notice dVt+1/dxt+1 = V′(xt+1) is the marginal value of an increase in xt+1, which is

simply λt+1. Then, we need to discount the marginal value to the present time, so:

β V′(xt+1) = β λt+1. (equation 2)

We can also show that equation (1) leads to the co-state equation as with the

Hamiltonian and Lagrangian methods.

Recall result from Lagrange method above:

Page 28: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Note: The above two results are exactly the same as those one gets from discrete-time Lagrangian and from the discrete-time Hamiltonian. Further, in a competitive, arbitrage-free economy (where r is the discount rate):

rV(xt) = H*t

0

:as (2) Rewrite

)1(

:as (1) Rewrite

1

11

111

t

t

t

t

t

t

tt

t

tt

t

t

t

t

t

t

h

f

h

R

x

f

x

R

x

f

x

R

x

f

x

R

Page 29: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

1 𝐺 𝑥 = g𝑥 1 −𝑥

𝐾

Schaefer Model of the Fishery (1954)

From (3) with (1) and (2), and assuming steady state dynamics, we get:

h = rx(1 – x/K) = qEx

Solving for x gives:

(4) x = K(1 – qE/r)

so that

(5) h = qEx = qKE(1 – qE/r)

Equation (1) is the growth of the fish stock in the absence of harvest and (2) is the

production function (with E = effort). Assume that the equation of motion is given by:

3Δ𝑥

Δ𝑡= 𝐺(𝑥) − ℎ

2 ℎ 𝐸, 𝑥 = 𝑞𝐸𝑥

Page 30: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

Schaefer Model of the Fishery (cont)

• Equation (5) has exactly the same form as the logistics growth function that we

encountered previously, except E (effort) is on the horizontal axis and h (harvest) is

on the vertical axis.

• Now, if you multiply this by a fixed price for fish, then you essentially get a total

revenue function that looks like a logistics.

Page 31: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

E

$

0 K

Fishery model:

C = c×E

p is price of fish ($/kg)

h is harvest

E is effort

E∞ is open access effort

c is cost per unit effort

K is ecosystem carrying capacity

R = p×h

E∞Eπ Emsy

Page 32: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

x

g(x)

0 K

Logistic growth function: g(xt)

𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = g𝑥𝑡 1 −𝑥𝑡𝐾

ht=qutxt

q is a catchability coefficient

ut is effort (control variable)

g is intrinsic growth rate

K is ecosystem carrying capacity

Page 33: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

x

g(x)

0

M is minimum

viable population

K =

carrying

capacity

𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = g𝑥𝑡𝑥𝑡 −𝑀

𝑥𝑡 +𝑀1 −

𝑥𝑡𝐾

Red line:

𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = g𝑥𝑡 1 −𝑥𝑡𝐾

Black line:

ht=qutxt

Growth Functions:

Page 34: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

x

g(xt)

0

M is minimum

viable population

ht=qutxt

K

𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = g𝑥𝑡𝑥𝑡 −𝑀

𝑥𝑡 +𝑀1 −

𝑥𝑡𝐾

Red line:

𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = g𝑥𝑡 1 −𝑥𝑡𝐾

Black line:

𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = g𝑥𝑡𝑥𝑡𝑀− 1 1 −

𝑥𝑡𝐾

Blue line:

Page 35: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

M=5000; K = 100000 # minimum viable population and carrying capacity

r1 = 0.08

r2 <- seq(0.01, 0.1, 0.01)

r3 <- seq(0.001, 0.008, 0.001)

clrs <-c('red', 'red4', 'tan4', 'skyblue4', 'chartreuse', 'blueviolet','darkorchid', 'forestgreen','gold3','yellow’)

# Plot the initial logistics function

curve(r1*x*(1-x/K), 0, K, xlab = 'Fish stock', ylab='Growth', col='black’)

# Plot the function (1) on top of it

for (i in 1:10) { curve(r2[i]*x*((x-M)/(x+M))*(1-x/K), add=TRUE, col=clrs[i]) }

# After re-running the logistics function, plot the function (2) on top of it

for (i in 1:8) { curve(r3[i]*x*(x/M-1)*(1-x/K), add=TRUE, col=clrs[i]) }

R code for two functions compared to logistics:

(1) 𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = 𝑟2𝑥𝑡𝑥𝑡−𝑀

𝑥𝑡+𝑀1 −

𝑥𝑡

𝐾

(2) 𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = 𝑟3𝑥𝑡𝑥𝑡

𝑀− 1 1 −

𝑥𝑡

𝐾

Page 36: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = g𝑥𝑡𝑥𝑡 −𝑀

𝑥𝑡 +𝑀1 −

𝑥𝑡𝐾

0.01 ≤ g ≤ 0.1, where g = 0.08 for logistics

5,000

100,000

Page 37: Resource Economics: Introductionweb.uvic.ca/~kooten/resource/Introduction.pdf · Monday, January 13, 2020 4 The logistics growth function (usually specified as a constraint in bioeconomics):

0.001 ≤ g ≤ 0.008, where g = 0.08 for logistics 𝑥𝑡+1 − 𝑥𝑡 = g𝑥𝑡𝑥𝑡𝑀− 1 1 −

𝑥𝑡𝐾