remittances and the brain drain revisited: the microdata...

25
Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata Show That More Educated Migrants Remit More Albert Bollard , David McKenzie , Melanie Morten , and Hillel Rapoport Two of the most salient trends in migration and development over the last two decades are the large rise in remittances and in the flow of skilled migrants. However, recent lit- erature based on cross-country regressions has claimed that more educated migrants remit less, leading to concerns that further increases in skilled migration will impede remittance growth. Microdata from surveys of immigrants in 11 major destination countries are used to revisit the relationship between education and remitting behavior. The data show a mixed pattern between education and the likelihood of remitting, and a strong positive relationship between education and amount remitted (intensive margin), conditional on remitting at all (extensive margin). Combining these intensive and exten- sive margins yields an overall positive effect of education on the amount remitted for the pooled sample, with heterogeneous results across destinations. The microdata allow investigation of why the more educated remit more, showing that the higher income earned by migrants, rather than family characteristics, explains much of the higher remit- tances. remittances, migration, brain drain, education JEL codes: O15, F22, J61 Two of the most salient trends in migration and development over the last two decades are the large rise in remittances and in the flow of skilled migrants. Officially recorded remittances to developing countries have more than tripled over the last decade, rising from $85 billion in 2000 to $305 billion in 2008 Albert Bollard ([email protected]) is a PhD student at Stanford University. David McKenzie ([email protected]; corresponding author) is a senior economist in the Finance and Private Sector Research Unit of the Development Research Group at the World Bank. Melanie Morten ([email protected]) is a PhD student at Yale University. Hillel Rapoport ([email protected]) is professor of economics at Bar Ilan University and at EQUIPPE, University of Lille and is currently a visiting research fellow at the Center for International Development at Harvard University. The authors are grateful for funding for this project from the Agence Franc ¸aise de De ´veloppement (AFD). They thank all the individuals and organizations that graciously shared their surveys of immigrants, and they are grateful to Michael Clemens, participants at the 2 nd Migration and Development Conference held at the World Bank in September 2009, three anonymous referees, and the journal editor for helpful comments. All opinions are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of AFD or the World Bank. A supplemental appendix to this article is available at http://wber.oxfordjournals.org. THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW, VOL. 25, NO. 1, pp. 132–156 doi:10.1093/wber/lhr013 Advance Access Publication May 12, 2011 # The Author 2011. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / THE WORLD BANK. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: [email protected] 132 at International Monetary Fund on August 12, 2011 wber.oxfordjournals.org Downloaded from Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Upload: others

Post on 10-Jul-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: TheMicrodata Show That More Educated Migrants

Remit More

Albert Bollard, David McKenzie, Melanie Morten, andHillel Rapoport

Two of the most salient trends in migration and development over the last two decadesare the large rise in remittances and in the flow of skilled migrants. However, recent lit-erature based on cross-country regressions has claimed that more educated migrantsremit less, leading to concerns that further increases in skilled migration will impederemittance growth. Microdata from surveys of immigrants in 11 major destinationcountries are used to revisit the relationship between education and remitting behavior.The data show a mixed pattern between education and the likelihood of remitting, and astrong positive relationship between education and amount remitted (intensive margin),conditional on remitting at all (extensive margin). Combining these intensive and exten-sive margins yields an overall positive effect of education on the amount remitted for thepooled sample, with heterogeneous results across destinations. The microdata allowinvestigation of why the more educated remit more, showing that the higher incomeearned by migrants, rather than family characteristics, explains much of the higher remit-tances. remittances, migration, brain drain, education JEL codes: O15, F22, J61

Two of the most salient trends in migration and development over the last twodecades are the large rise in remittances and in the flow of skilled migrants.Officially recorded remittances to developing countries have more than tripledover the last decade, rising from $85 billion in 2000 to $305 billion in 2008

Albert Bollard ([email protected]) is a PhD student at Stanford University. David McKenzie

([email protected]; corresponding author) is a senior economist in the Finance and Private

Sector Research Unit of the Development Research Group at the World Bank. Melanie Morten

([email protected]) is a PhD student at Yale University. Hillel Rapoport ([email protected]) is

professor of economics at Bar Ilan University and at EQUIPPE, University of Lille and is currently a

visiting research fellow at the Center for International Development at Harvard University. The authors

are grateful for funding for this project from the Agence Francaise de Developpement (AFD). They

thank all the individuals and organizations that graciously shared their surveys of immigrants, and they

are grateful to Michael Clemens, participants at the 2nd Migration and Development Conference held at

the World Bank in September 2009, three anonymous referees, and the journal editor for helpful

comments. All opinions are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of AFD or the

World Bank. A supplemental appendix to this article is available at http://wber.oxfordjournals.org.

THE WORLD BANK ECONOMIC REVIEW, VOL. 25, NO. 1, pp. 132–156 doi:10.1093/wber/lhr013Advance Access Publication May 12, 2011# The Author 2011. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the International Bankfor Reconstruction and Development / THE WORLD BANK. All rights reserved. For permissions,please e-mail: [email protected]

132

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

wb350881
Typewritten Text
71887
Page 2: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

(World Bank 2008, 2009). The number of highly educated migrants fromdeveloping countries residing in Organisation for Economic Co-operation andDevelopment (OECD) countries doubled over 1990–2000 (Docquier andMarfouk 2005) and likely has grown since then as developed countries haveincreasingly pursued skill-selective immigration policies.1

However, despite this positive association at the global level between risingremittances and rising high-skill migration, there are concerns—stemming fromthe belief that more educated individuals may remit less—that increasinglyskill-selective immigration policies may slow or even end the rise in remit-tances. This belief is taken as fact by many; for example, an OECD (2007,p. 11) report says that “low skilled migrants tend to send more money home.”The main empirical evidence to support this assertion across a range ofcountries comes from two recent studies (Faini 2007; Niimi, Ozden, and Schiffforthcoming) whose cross-country macroeconomic analyses find that the highlyskilled (defined as those with tertiary education) remit less.

Yet there are many reasons to question the results of these cross-country esti-mations. Both studies relate the amount of remittances received at a countrylevel to the share of migrants with tertiary education, at best telling us whethercountries that send a larger share of highly skilled migrants receive less or morein remittances than countries that send fewer skilled migrants. The studies donot answer the factual question of whether more educated migrants remit moreor less. There are a host of differences across countries that could cause a spur-ious relationship to appear between remittances and skill level across countries.For example, if poverty is a constraint to both migration and education, richerdeveloping countries might be able to send more migrants (yielding moreremittances) and those migrants might also have more schooling. Faini (2007)treats the share of migrants who are skilled as exogenous. Niimi, Ozden, andSchiff (forthcoming) try to instrument for the education mix of migrants, buttheir instruments seem unlikely to satisfy the exclusion restrictions. Forexample, public spending on education is likely a function of a country’soverall institutional and economic development, which should independentlyaffect the incentive to remit; migrants might send money to overcome poorpublic spending or for investment when complementary infrastructure andinstitutions are in place.

This article revisits the relationship between remittances and education levelusing microdata that permit computing the association between a migrant’seducation level and remitting behavior. The authors assembled the most com-prehensive micro-level database on remitting behavior currently available, com-prising data on 33,000 immigrants from developing countries from 14 surveys

1. In contrast, the number of low-skill migrants (primary education or less) increased only 15

percent over the period. Immigration to OECD countries (as defined by the number of foreign born)

was estimated at 90 million in 2000, about half of total world migration. Of the 90 million immigrants,

60 million were ages 25 or older and were split equally across education categories (primary, secondary,

and tertiary; Docquier and Marfouk 2005).

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 133

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 3: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

in 11 OECD destination countries. The analysis begins by establishing thefactual relationship between the propensity to remit and education. No attemptis made to estimate the causal impact of education on remittances.2 From apolicy perspective, the concern is whether migration policies that shift the edu-cation composition of migrants affect remittances, not whether education pol-icies that change how much education individuals have affects remittances.Microdata enables asking whether more educated individuals are more or lesslikely to remit (the extensive margin) and whether they send more or less remit-tances if they do remit (the intensive margin). A mixed association is foundbetween education and remittances at the extensive margin, and a strong posi-tive relationship at the intensive margin. Combining both the extensive andintensive margins reveals that, at least in this large sample, more educatedmigrants do remit significantly more—migrants with a university degree remit$300 more yearly than migrants without a university degree, where the meanannual remittance over the entire sample is $730.

The article is organized as follows. Section I summarizes several theories ofremitting behavior and the predictions they give for the relationship betweeneducation and remittances. Section II then describes the dataset of immigrantsurveys with remittances. Section III provides results, and section IV drawssome implications.

I . T H E O R E T I C A L B A C K G R O U N D

Theoretically, there are several reasons to believe that there will be differencesin the remitting patterns of highly skilled and less-skilled emigrants. However,a priori, it is not clear which direction will dominate and thus whether thehighly skilled will remit more or less on average. On the one hand, severalfactors tend to lead highly skilled migrants to be more likely to remit and tosend a larger amount of remittances. First, highly skilled individuals are likelyto earn more as migrants, potentially increasing the amount they can remit.Second, their education may have been funded by family members in the homecountry, with remittances serving as repayment. Third, skilled migrants are lesslikely to be illegal migrants and more likely to have bank accounts, loweringthe financial transaction costs of remitting. On the other hand, several otherfactors might lead highly skilled migrants to be less likely to remit and to remitless. First, highly skilled migrants may be more likely to migrate with theirentire household, so they would not have to send remittances in order to sharetheir earnings with their household. Second, they might come from richerhouseholds, which have less need for remittances to alleviate liquidity con-straints. Third, they might have less intention of returning to their homecountry, reducing the role of remittances as a way of maintaining prestige andties to the home community.

2. Convincing instruments are lacking to identify this impact.

134 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 4: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

Before turning to the empirical analysis, it is useful to clarify the theoreticalrelationship between education and remittances and the implied testable predic-tions about education. This will allow identifying the role of several variablesthat, once interacted with education and various possible motivations to remit,have the potential to explain differences in remitting behavior by educationlevel. The discussion is limited to three possible motives for remittances: altru-ism, exchange, and investment. These were selected for general empirical rel-evance and as the motives through which education is most likely to affectremittances.3

Altruism

Altruistic preferences are generally captured by weighting one’s own (themigrant’s) and others’ (relatives) consumption in an individual utility function,with weights reflecting the individual’s degree of altruism, which can itselfdepend on the closeness among the relatives considered (both family and geo-graphic proximity). For given weights and initial distribution of income,altruistic individuals maximize their utility by transferring (remitting) incomeso as to reach the desired distribution between themselves and the beneficiariesof their altruism. Altruistic transfers take place if pretransfer income differencesare sufficiently large or altruism is strong enough and increases with thedonor’s income (the extensive margin) and decreases with the recipients’income (the intensive margin)

What does this basic theoretical framework imply for the comparative remit-ting behavior of highly educated and less well educated migrants? First, edu-cated migrants tend to earn more, which all else equal should induce moreremittances (at both margins). Second, the conventional wisdom is that edu-cated migrants tend to have more family members with them because of ahigher propensity to move with their immediate family, which all else equalshould lower remittances.4 Methodologically, this suggests that the locationand composition of the family (which fraction of the family accompanies themigrant and which fraction stays in the country of origin) is jointly determinedwith remittances. This makes it difficult to estimate the causal impact of familycomposition on remittances. Instead, the analysis simply looks at whetherdifferences in remitting patterns by education level disappear when they areconditioned on family composition. Empirically, the analysis will show thatwhile less educated migrants have more relatives in the home country, they alsohave larger households and more relatives with them in the destinationcountry.

3. See Rapoport and Docquier (2006) for a comprehensive survey of the economic literature on

migrants’ remittances.

4. In this basic framework, education has no impact beyond its effect on the migrants’ income and

family size, composition, and location, and altruistic preferences are independent of education.

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 135

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 5: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

Exchange and Investment Motives

There are many situations of Pareto-improving exchanges in which remittances“buy” various types of services, such as taking care of the migrant’s assets (landand cattle, for example) or relatives (children, elderly parents) at home. Suchmotivations are generally a sign of temporary migration and signal a migrant’sintention to return. In such exchanges, there is a participation constraint deter-mined by each partner’s external options, with the exact division of the pie(or surplus) to be shared depending on each partner’s bargaining power.

How does education interact with such exchange motives? Two directionsemerge from the short discussion above: one through the effect of education onintentions to return, and another through education’s effect on threat pointsand bargaining powers.

The conventional wisdom is that migrants with higher education have lessintention (and propensity) to return than do migrants with lower education (seeFaini 2007), because they are better integrated or can obtain permanent residentstatus more easily. If that is the case, more educated migrants should transfer lessfor an exchange motive, reflecting their lower propensity to return.5 What aboutbargaining powers? Exchange models allow for different possible contractualarrangements reflecting the parties’ outside options and bargaining powers (see,for example, Cox 1987; Cox, Eser, and Jimenez 1998). This has two complemen-tary implications for education as a determinant of remittances in an exchangemodel. First, to the extent that education is associated with higher income, thisrelationship is likely to increase a migrant’s willingness to pay, leading to higherremittances; and second, to the extent that educated migrants come from moreaffluent families, this relationship is likely to increase the receiving household’sbargaining power, also leading to higher remittances. On the whole, an exchangemotive therefore predicts that education will have an ambiguous effect on remit-tances, with the sign of the effect depending on whether return intentions orbargaining issues matter more to remittance behavior.

The investment motive can be seen as a particular exchange of services in acontext of imperfect credit markets. In such a context, remittances can be seenas part of an implicit migration contract between migrant and family, allowingthe family access to higher income (investment motive) or less volatile income(insurance motive; Stark 1991). Since the insurance motive does not in theorygive rise to clear differences in transfer behavior between highly educated andless educated migrants, the focus here is on the investment motive. The amountof investment financed by the family may include the physical costs (such astransportation) and informational costs of migration, as well as educationexpenditures, and repayment of this implicit loan through remittances isobviously expected to depend on the magnitude of the loan. Thus, the

5. Again, as shown later in the article, this conventional wisdom is not supported by the data;

exchange motives are equally relevant for highly educated and less educated migrants as far as return

intentions are concerned.

136 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 6: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

investment motive clearly predicts that, all else equal, more educated migrantsshould remit more to compensate the family for the additional educationexpenditures incurred.

Summary of Predictions

Both the altruistic and the exchange motives for remittances yield uncleartheoretical predictions as to whether more educated migrants remit more orless than do less education migrants. Once migrants’ incomes are controlledfor, their education level should not play a role under the altruistic hypoth-esis (assuming preferences are exogenous to education) except for its effecton the spatial distribution of the family. As already noted, the conventionalwisdom here is that the highly educated tend to move with their immediatefamily, which would lower remittances. Similarly, education is expected tolower remittances under the exchange hypothesis if educated migrants havelower propensities to return; bargaining mechanisms work in the otherdirection and should translate into higher remittances, with the sign of thetotal expected effect being theoretically uncertain. Finally, education islikely to have a clear positive impact on remittances under the investmenthypothesis.

Given these expected mechanisms and the fact that the descriptive statisticsfor the sample do not support the conjecture that more educated migrants havea substantially higher propensity to move with their family or a substantiallylower propensity to return, the other forces at work should be expected todominate, so that migrants with more education would remit more, which isindeed what the analysis shows.

I I . D A T A

The micro-level database on remitting behavior created for this study is the mostcomprehensive available, comprising data on 33,000 immigrants from develop-ing countries derived from 14 surveys in 11 OECD destination countries thatwere the destination for 79 percent of global migrants to OECD countries in2000 (Docquier and Marfouk 2005). The focus on destination country datasources enables looking directly at the relationship between education and remit-tance sending behavior by analyzing the migrants’ decision to remit. It alsopermits capturing the remittance behavior of individuals who emigrate withtheir entire household; using household surveys from the remittance receivingcountries would typically miss such individuals. Since more educated individualsare believed to be more likely to emigrate with their entire household thanless educated individuals (Faini 2007), using surveys from migrant sendingcountries would not be appropriate for examining the relationship betweenremittances and education.

Most of the empirical literature on immigrants uses data from censuses orlabor force surveys, but neither contains information on remittances. That

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 137

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 7: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

requires special purpose surveys of immigrants. The authors pulled together allpublicly available datasets they were aware of6 and six additional surveys thatare not publicly available but that other researchers generously shared. Table 1provides an overview of the database of migrants, summarizing the datasets,sample population, and survey methodology. Full details of the source of eachdataset are in the supplemental appendix, available online at http://wber.oxfordjournals.org/. The database covers a wide range of populations. Itincludes both nationally representative surveys, such as the New ImmigrantSurvey (NIS) in the United States (drawn from green card recipients) and theSpanish National Survey of Immigrants (ENI), which draws on a neighborhoodsampling frame, as well as surveys focusing on specific migrant communitieswithin the recipient country, such as the Black/Minority Ethnic Survey (BME)in the United Kingdom and the Belgium International Remittance SendersHousehold Survey (IRSHS) of immigrants from the Democratic Republic ofCongo, Nigeria, and Senegal. In all cases, the database includes only migrantswho were born in developing countries.7

For each country dataset, comparable covariates were constructed tomeasure household income, remittance behavior, family composition, anddemographic characteristics. Remittances are typically measured at the house-hold rather than individual level. The level of analysis is therefore the house-hold, and variables are defined at this level whenever possible—for example,by taking the highest level of schooling achieved by any adult migrant in thehousehold. All financial values are reported in 2003 U.S. dollars. In addition,any reported annual remittances that are more than twice annual householdincome are dropped. While remittance data in surveys can be subject tomeasurement error, the use of survey fixed effects will capture any commonsurvey-level effects, and there is no strong reason to believe such measurementerror would be correlated with education status. Mean and median reportedremittances also seem to be of the right order of magnitude when comparedwith other surveys and migrant incomes.

The sample weights provided with the data are always used. Data are pooledby poststratifying by country of birth and by education, so that the combinedweighted observations match the distribution of developing country migrantsto all OECD countries in 2000 (Docquier and Marfouk2005). The supplemen-tal appendix provides further details.

Table 2 presents summary statistics for each country survey and the pooledsamples of all destination countries. Overall, 37 percent of migrants in thedatabase have completed a university degree, ranging from 4 percent in theSpanish Netherlands Interdisciplinary Demographic Institute (NIDI) survey to

6. Exceptions include longitudinal surveys of immigrants from Canada and New Zealand, which

can only be accessed through datalabs in these countries, and so are not included here.

7. High income countries are defined based on the World Bank Country Classification Code, April

2009.

138 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 8: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

TA

BL

E1

.M

igra

nt

Dat

ase

ts

Dat

ase

tN

am

eY

ear

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ionsa

Popula

tion

Met

hodolo

gy

Aust

ralia

LSIA

Longit

udin

al

Surv

eyof

Imm

igra

nts

toA

ust

rali

a1997

2,5

37

Pri

mary

applica

nt

mig

rant

arr

ivals

Sep

tem

ber

1993

–A

ugust

1995

Sam

ple

of

offi

cial

reco

rds

of

those

livin

gin

citi

esB

elgiu

mIR

SH

SIn

tern

atio

nal

Rem

itta

nce

Sen

der

sH

ouse

hold

Surv

ey2005

377

Imm

igra

nts

from

DR

Congo,

Nig

eria

,and

Sen

egal

Ref

erra

lsth

rough

Em

bass

ies.

Fra

nce

2M

OSurv

eyof

House

hold

s’T

ransf

erof

Funds

toth

eir

Countr

ies

of

Ori

gin

2007

713

Rem

itte

rsto

Alg

eria

,M

oro

cco,

Tunis

ia,

Turk

eyand

the

countr

ies

of

Sub-S

ahar

an

Afr

ica

Inte

rvie

ws

of

rem

itte

rsat

post

offi

ces

inhig

h-m

igra

nt

regio

ns

Fra

nce

DR

EE

SPro

file

and

Tra

ckin

gof

Mig

rants

Surv

ey2006

4,2

78

New

and

regula

rize

dm

igra

nts

wit

h1þ

year

resi

den

ceper

mit

sSam

ple

of

offi

cial

reco

rds

Ger

many

SO

EP

Ger

man

Soci

o-E

conom

icPanel

Stu

dy

2000

854

Res

iden

tpopula

tion

of

the

Fed

eral

Rep

ublic

of

Ger

many

in1984.

Sam

ple

of

offi

cial

reco

rds

Italy

NID

IN

ether

lands

Inte

rdis

cipli

nary

Dem

ogra

phic

Inst

itute

Inte

rnat

ional

Mig

rati

on

Surv

ey

1997

1,0

72

Egypti

ans

and

Ghanaia

ns

who

imm

igra

ted

wit

hin

past

10

years

Inte

rvie

ws

atm

igra

nt

mee

ting

pla

ces

Japan

IDB

Surv

eyof

Bra

zili

ans

and

Per

uvia

ns

inJa

pan

2005

846

Lat

inA

mer

ican

imm

igra

nt

adult

slivin

gin

Japan

Inte

rvie

ws

in15

citi

es

Net

her

lands

CSR

Consu

men

tenbond

Surv

eyof

Rem

itta

nce

s2005

648

Majo

rim

mig

rant

popula

tions:

Moro

ccans,

Turk

s,Suri

nam

ese,

Anti

llea

ns,

Som

alis,

and

Ghanaia

ns

Fac

e-to

-fac

ein

terv

iew

s

Norw

ayL

KI

Liv

ing

Condit

ions

of

Imm

igra

nts

Surv

ey1996

2,4

66

Imm

igra

nts

from

10

countr

ies:

Bosn

iaand

Her

zegovin

a,

Chile,

Iraq,

Iran,

Pakis

tan,

Ser

bia

,Som

alia,

Sri

Lanka,

Turk

ey,

and

Vie

tnam

Rep

rese

nta

tive

surv

eyof

imm

igra

nt

popula

tion

from

thes

eco

untr

ies

Spain

EN

IN

atio

nal

Surv

eyof

Imm

igra

nts

2006

9,2

34

Fore

ign-b

orn

who

(inte

nd

to)

live

inSpain

for

years

Sam

ple

of

offi

cial

nei

ghborh

ood

rost

ers

(Conti

nued

)

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 139

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 9: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

TA

BL

E1.

Conti

nued

Dat

ase

tN

am

eY

ear

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ionsa

Popula

tion

Met

hodolo

gy

Spain

NID

IN

ether

lands

Inte

rdis

cipli

nary

Dem

ogra

phic

Inst

itute

Inte

rnat

ional

Mig

rati

on

Surv

ey

1997

1,0

20

Moro

ccans

and

Sen

egale

sew

ho

imm

igra

ted

wit

hin

past

10

years

Geo

gra

phic

al

sam

pling,

&re

fere

nce

sfr

om

sam

ple

d

UK

BM

EB

lack

/Min

ori

tyE

thnic

Rem

itta

nce

Surv

ey2006

993

Mig

rant

min

ori

ties

who

hav

ere

mit

ted

inpast

12

month

sSam

pling

of

geo

gra

phic

al

blo

cks

U.S

.N

ISN

ewIm

mig

rant

Surv

ey2003

7,0

46

Mig

rants

rece

ivin

ggre

enca

rds

May

–N

ove

mber

1993

Sam

ple

of

offi

cial

reco

rds

Pew

Nat

ional

Surv

eyof

Lat

inos

2006

1084

Nat

ionally

repre

senta

tive

sam

ple

of

Lat

ino

resp

onden

tsages

18

and

old

er

Sam

ple

dphone

num

ber

sin

hig

h-L

atin

oare

as

U.S

.Pew

Pew

Nat

ional

Surv

eyof

Lat

inos

2006

1,0

84

Nat

ionally

repre

senta

tive

sam

ple

of

Lat

ino

resp

onden

tsages

18

and

old

er

Sam

ple

dphone

num

ber

sin

hig

h-L

atin

oare

as

Note

:N

um

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

use

dto

calc

ula

teth

efirs

tre

sult

inea

chco

lum

nof

table

2.

140 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 10: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

TA

BL

E2

.Surv

eyM

eans,

by

Educa

tion

Aust

rali

aB

elgiu

mFra

nce

Fra

nce

Ger

many

Italy

Japan

Net

her

lands

Norw

aySpain

Spain

UK

U.S

.U

.S.

Poole

dPoole

dPoole

d

Vari

able

and

educa

tion

leve

lL

SIA

IRSH

S2M

OD

RE

ES

SO

EP

NID

IID

BC

SR

LB

IE

NI

NID

IB

ME

NIS

Pew

Exte

nsi

veIn

tensi

veT

ota

l

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

2,6

56

451

717

4,2

80

900

1,1

53

1,0

65

836

2,4

66

10,2

82

1,1

13

1,1

52

7,3

52

1,3

04

33,0

22

28,9

81

26,2

76

Fra

ctio

nw

ith

univ

ersi

tyed

uca

tion

0.3

20.5

90.0

70.1

80.2

00.2

10.1

40.1

10.1

20.2

30.0

40.2

00.3

40.0

60.3

60.3

70.3

7

Tota

lre

mit

tance

s($

per

year)

No

univ

ersi

ty286

1,6

81

1,3

80

368

2,7

24

2,6

62

993

988

3,0

99

2,6

91

375

1,5

30

699

793

650

Univ

ersi

ty379

2,4

75*

1,6

52

511

2,2

27

2,9

20

1,4

05*

743**

2,8

35

2,6

29

1,1

45**

671**

868

897

874

Fra

ctio

nw

ho

rem

it

No

univ

ersi

ty0.4

10.9

10.2

30.1

80.6

00.8

00.3

40.4

90.7

80.1

50.5

40.3

10.3

20.3

2

Univ

ersi

ty0.3

70.8

60.2

30.2

00.4

5**

0.9

0**

0.2

90.3

7**

0.4

8**

0.1

70.4

30.2

7**

0.2

7**

0.2

7**

Log

rem

itta

nce

s

No

univ

ersi

ty5.7

86.9

26.6

26.9

77.8

97.7

66.4

97.1

57.9

96.7

77.0

17.3

46.9

66.8

26.9

1

Univ

ersi

ty6.2

3**

7.2

9**

6.9

27.0

18.1

17.7

06.8

1**

7.2

28.4

9*

6.9

27.4

0**

6.9

77.0

26.9

7*

7.0

0

House

hold

inco

me

($per

year)

No

univ

ersi

ty14,4

57

16,9

18

23,1

73

18,6

12

19,5

26

10,9

03

34,0

14

32,4

67

14,0

66

9,0

74

44,6

31

33,2

97

22,4

17

22,6

24

23,5

83

21,9

64

Univ

ersi

ty13,5

56

25,5

34**

31,3

01*

28,6

74**

21,9

84

13,3

02*

43,6

24**

41,9

95**

19,9

14**

10,1

68

50,5

65

61,0

84

34,7

29**

38,9

48**

38,6

69**

39,0

87**

Log

inco

me

No

univ

ersi

ty9.5

9.5

9.8

9.6

9.8

9.3

10.2

10.1

9.4

9.0

10.3

9.2

9.7

9.6

9.5

9.5

Univ

ersi

ty9.8

**

9.8

**

10.0

9.9

**

9.8

9.4

10.4

10.3

**

9.7

**

9.2

10.4

10.0

**

10.2

**

9.9

**

9.9

**

9.9

**

Work

ing

No

univ

ersi

ty0.4

80.7

00.8

70.8

00.6

30.8

20.9

30.4

80.6

80.8

10.8

20.6

60.6

60.6

50.6

60.6

4

Univ

ersi

ty0.6

7**

0.7

40.8

60.8

6**

0.6

70.8

70.9

30.7

0**

0.7

3**

0.6

60.9

0**

0.7

8**

0.7

7*

0.7

5**

0.7

4**

0.7

3**

House

hold

size

No

univ

ersi

ty3.8

11.8

82.5

12.9

01.8

01.5

33.8

21.8

43.3

34.1

03.4

43.7

33.7

6

Univ

ersi

ty3.4

4**

2.5

5**

1.9

0**

2.5

82.1

6**

1.7

6**

3.1

9**

1.9

53.0

4*

3.4

9**

3.1

7**

3.3

5**

3.3

6**

Marr

ied

No

univ

ersi

ty0.7

30.7

20.6

50.6

70.6

10.5

60.4

70.6

40.6

60.5

40.6

30.6

30.6

3

Univ

ersi

ty0.8

0**

0.5

1**

0.7

1*

0.5

90.6

00.4

8*

0.5

6**

0.5

10.8

6**

0.5

60.7

3**

0.7

4**

0.7

4**

Spouse

outs

ide

countr

y

No

univ

ersi

ty0.0

30.2

50.0

50.0

60.4

20.0

50.0

50.0

50.0

6

Univ

ersi

ty0.0

1*

0.1

90.0

1**

0.0

50.1

0**

0.0

3**

0.0

3**

0.0

3**

0.0

3**

Num

ber

of

chil

dre

n

No

univ

ersi

ty1.2

91.1

61.7

81.0

62.5

02.0

61.5

82.2

52.3

71.9

92.0

52.0

3

Univ

ersi

ty1.2

20.8

9**

1.2

7**

1.0

02.1

5**

1.8

5**

0.6

2**

1.3

5**

1.8

1**

1.3

7**

1.3

7**

1.3

7**

Chil

dre

nouts

ide

countr

y

No

univ

ersi

ty0.2

10.1

00.2

50.7

10.2

00.1

60.3

81.1

00.7

30.4

90.4

50.4

80.5

0

Univ

ersi

ty0.0

7**

0.0

60.1

7**

0.4

9*

0.1

50.0

90.2

6**

0.2

1**

0.3

1**

0.3

70.2

4**

0.2

5**

0.2

5**

Num

ber

of

pare

nts

No

univ

ersi

ty1.9

71.1

30.9

51.3

51.4

21.2

72.1

81.8

11.8

41.8

3

(Conti

nued

)

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 141

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 11: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

TA

BL

E2.

Conti

nued

Aust

rali

aB

elgiu

mFra

nce

Fra

nce

Ger

many

Italy

Japan

Net

her

lands

Norw

aySpain

Spain

UK

U.S

.U

.S.

Poole

dPoole

dPoole

d

Vari

able

and

educa

tion

leve

lL

SIA

IRSH

S2M

OD

RE

ES

SO

EP

NID

IID

BC

SR

LB

IE

NI

NID

IB

ME

NIS

Pew

Exte

nsi

veIn

tensi

veT

ota

l

Univ

ersi

ty2.3

2**

1.0

30.7

0**

1.3

21.3

5**

1.3

72.7

4**

2.1

8**

2.2

1**

2.2

3**

Pare

nts

outs

ide

countr

y

No

univ

ersi

ty1.4

80.8

10.4

20.9

41.0

31.0

11.2

30.8

80.9

80.9

81.0

0

Univ

ersi

ty2.0

0**

0.8

80.5

40.6

7**

1.1

7*

1.0

41.3

31.2

6**

1.3

0**

1.3

1**

1.3

1**

Yea

rssp

ent

abro

ad

No

univ

ersi

ty3.7

09.3

217.9

04.0

019.2

06.6

98.3

518.4

610.0

67.2

714.8

97.3

516.4

39.2

011.1

710.2

9

Univ

ersi

ty3.9

1**

12.2

8**

12.7

0**

4.2

113.5

1**

7.0

29.1

819.3

612.4

1**

6.7

414.6

67.0

518.3

48.0

6**

8.7

5**

8.4

0**

Leg

al

imm

igra

nt

No

univ

ersi

ty1.0

01.0

00.8

40.5

10.6

61.0

00.8

70.8

40.8

5

Univ

ersi

ty1.0

01.0

00.8

50.3

9**

0.8

2*

1.0

00.8

5**

0.8

40.8

4

Wil

lre

turn

hom

e

No

univ

ersi

ty0.0

20.4

50.0

60.2

30.3

90.0

10.0

80.3

50.6

30.0

90.1

90.0

90.1

60.1

1

Univ

ersi

ty0.0

40.6

5**

0.1

0*

0.1

70.5

3**

0.0

20.0

80.5

10.7

00.1

3**

0.1

40.0

90.1

2**

0.0

9*

*Sig

nifi

cant

atth

e5

per

cent

leve

l**

signifi

cant

atth

e1

per

cent

leve

l

Note

:Sig

nifi

cant

resu

lts

indic

ate

that

the

mea

nof

the

vari

able

isst

atis

tica

lly

dif

fere

nt

bet

wee

nuniv

ersi

ty-e

duca

ted

and

non-u

niv

ersi

tyed

uca

ted

house

-hold

s.See

table

1fo

rfu

llsu

rvey

nam

es.

Sourc

e:A

uth

ors

’analy

sis

base

don

dat

ades

crib

edin

the

text.

142 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 12: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

59 percent in the Belgium IRSHS. The table also summarizes the covariates bythe maximum educational attainment of all adult migrants in the household.Altogether, including both the extensive and intensive margins, more highlyeducated migrants send home an average of $874 annually, compared with$650 for less educated migrants. There are two opposing effects of education:negative on the extensive margin, and positive on the intensive margin. At theextensive margin, migrants with a university degree are less likely to remit any-thing than migrants without a degree: 32 percent of low-skilled migrants sendsome money home, compared with 27 percent of university-educated migrants.However, conditional on remitting (the intensive margin), highly educatedmigrants send about 9 percent more than do less educated migrants.

Characteristics that can affect remittance behavior differ between less andmore educated migrants. First, more skilled migrants are both more likely tolive in a household with working adults and to have a higher householdincome than are low skilled migrants. But contrary to conventional wisdom,household composition does not differ much for migrants by education level:on average, only 6 percent of low skilled migrants have a spouse outside thecountry, compared with 3 percent of high skilled migrants. Low skilledmigrants are significantly less likely to be married (63 percent) than are highskilled migrants (74 percent). Low skilled migrants have more children(an average of 2.03 compared with 1.37 for high skilled migrants), as well asmore children living outside the destination country (0.50) than do high skilledmigrants (0.25). However, low skilled migrants also have more family insidethe destination country than do high skilled migrants: the average householdsize for low skilled migrants is 3.76 people, statistically different from themean household size of 3.36 people for high skilled migrants.8

Another piece of conventional wisdom, that more educated people are lesslikely to return home, is also not supported by the microdata. Indeed, moreeducated migrants have spent less time abroad (mean of 8.4 years) than haveless educated migrants (10.3 years). Reported plans to return home are similarbetween the two groups: 9 percent of high skilled migrants report planning toreturn home, compared with 11 percent of low skilled migrants. While oneshould be cautious with treating both measures as truly reflecting return prob-abilities; at the very least, they do not indicate a strong tendency for the lowskilled to be more likely to return.

The simple comparison of means in table 2 shows differences in remittancebehavior by education status. However, these comparisons show only thatmore educated developing country emigrants remit more than less educateddeveloping country emigrants. This risks confounding differences in remittance

8. In some cases this might reflect households in which poorer, less skilled migrants live with other

immigrants who are not family members. The database can identify the presence of a spouse, child, or

parent in the home country household but cannot identify who migrants live with abroad or the extent

to which they share resources within the household abroad.

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 143

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 13: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

behavior among migrants from different countries with differences inremittance behavior by education level: the next section aims to separate thesetwo differences.

I I I . R E S U L T S : T H E R E L A T I O N S H I P B E T W E E N E D U C A T I O N A N D

R E M I T T A N C E S

Results are reported for regressions of three remittance measures on education:total remittances (both extensive and intensive margins), an indicator forhaving remitted in the previous year (extensive margin), and log total remit-tances conditional on remitting (intensive margin; table 3). All regressionsinclude country of birth fixed effects and dataset fixed effects.

The key result is that more educated migrants remit more. In the pooledsample, migrants with a university degree remit $298 more per year than non-university educated migrants (row last, last column), with a mean annual remit-tance for all migrants of $734. This overall effect is composed of a negative(statistically insignificant) effect at the extensive margin and a highly significantpositive effect at the intensive margin. The results are consistent when thesecond measure of education, years of schooling, is considered.

Results for individual countries are mixed at the extensive margin, with edu-cation significantly positively associated with the likelihood of remitting in twosurveys (the U.S. NIS and the Survey of Brazilians and Peruvians in Japan), sig-nificantly negatively associated with this likelihood in three surveys (the U.S.Pew survey and both Spanish surveys), and no significant relationship in theother six surveys, with three positive and three negative point estimates. Onegeneral observation is that a more negative relationship appears in surveys thatfocus on sampling migrants through community-sampling methods, such as theNIDI surveys, which take their sample from places where migrants cluster, andthe Pew Hispanic surveys, which randomly dial phone numbers in areas withdense Hispanic populations. One might expect that educated migrants who livein such areas (and who take the time to respond to phone or on-the-streetsurveys) would be less successful than educated migrants who live in more inte-grated neighborhoods and thus who would not be picked up in these surveys.

In contrast, at the intensive margin, 10 of 12 individual surveys show a posi-tive relationship between remittances and education, 5 of them statistically sig-nificant, and 2 show a negative and insignificant relationship. Thus it is notsurprising that when the data are pooled there is a strong positive associationat the intensive margin and that it outweighs the small negative and insignifi-cant relationship at the extensive margin in the total effect.

This point is made graphically on a log scale in figure 1, which plots thenonparametric relationship between total remittances and years of schooling,after linearly controlling for dataset fixed effects using a partial linear model(Robinson 1988), together with a 95 percent confidence interval. The verticallines demarcate the quartiles of years of schooling. Average remittances steadily

144 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 14: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

TA

BL

E3

:C

oef

fici

ents

from

Reg

ress

ions

of

Rem

itta

nce

Mea

sure

son

Educa

tion

Aust

rali

aB

elgiu

mFra

nce

Fra

nce

Ger

many

Italy

Japan

Net

her

lands

Norw

aySpain

Spain

UK

U.S

.U

.S.

Poole

dPoole

dPoole

d

Vari

able

LSIA

IRSH

S2M

OD

RE

ES

SO

EP

NID

IID

BC

SR

LB

IE

NI

NID

IB

ME

NIS

Pew

Exte

nsi

veIn

tensi

veT

ota

l

Educa

tion

mea

sure

dby

univ

ersi

tydeg

ree

Tota

lre

mit

tance

s($

per

year)

58.4

922.8

**

291.0

-526.6

237.5

-92.6

-168.8

769.5

**

-554.0

*298.0

*

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

2,5

37

377

854

1,0

72

846

9,2

34

1,0

20

7,0

46

1,0

84

24,0

33

Exte

nsi

ve:

Rem

its

indic

ator

20.0

19

-0.0

55

0.0

14

0.0

42

-0.0

65

0.0

91**

0.0

12

-0.0

49**

-0.2

32**

0.0

38**

-0.1

40*

-0.0

18

-0.0

10

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

2,6

54

451

4,2

78

854

1,1

53

1,0

30

2,4

66

10,2

82

1,1

12

7,1

13

1,2

96

32,6

51

25,9

07

Inte

nsi

ve:

Log

rem

itta

nce

s0.3

41*

0.4

33**

0.3

63

0.4

92

0.0

73

-0.0

57

0.3

33**

0.0

93

0.4

30*

0.1

68

0.3

97*

-0.1

99

0.2

49**

0.2

26**

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

958

317

713

184

545

690

648

3,9

66

761

993

1,1

18

514

11,3

92

9,0

38

Educa

tion

mea

sure

din

years

Tota

lre

mit

tance

s($

per

year)

19.0

8*

86.5

026.3

9-7

.56

-3.0

32.4

0-1

3.6

586.5

364.8

957.8

1

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

2,5

31

377

854

1,0

72

846

9,1

64

1,0

20

7,0

33

1,0

84

23,9

44

Exte

nsi

ve:

Rem

its

indic

ator

0.0

080

-0.0

042

0.0

018

0.0

145

0.0

010

0.0

024**

0.0

008

-0.0

023

-0.0

072**

0.0

034**

0.0

010

0.0

006

0.0

014

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

2,6

48

451

5,5

29

854

1,1

53

1,0

30

2,4

50

10,2

01

1,1

12

7,1

00

1,2

96

32,5

35

25,8

07

Inte

nsi

ve:

Log

rem

itta

nce

s0.0

441*

0.0

341

0.0

224*

-0.0

085

-0.0

032

-0.0

040

0.0

247*

0.0

199**

0.0

091

0.0

548*

0.0

329*

0.0

369

0.0

256**

0.0

229**

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

956

317

713

184

545

690

648

3,9

42

761

993

1,1

16

514

11,3

64

9,0

10

Mea

ns

Tota

lre

mit

tance

s($

per

year)

316

2,1

59

1,3

99

396

2,6

21

2,6

92

1,0

40

932

3,0

89

2,6

79

633

1,4

79

764

2,4

66

734

Fra

ctio

nw

ho

rem

it0.4

00.8

50.2

30.1

90.5

30.7

70.3

40.4

10.7

50.1

50.4

60.3

01.0

00.2

7

Fra

ctio

nw

ith

univ

ersi

ty0.3

20.6

00.0

70.1

80.2

00.2

10.1

20.1

10.1

20.2

30.0

40.2

00.3

30.0

60.3

60.3

10.3

8

Yea

rsof

educa

tion

13.4

14.2

7.7

12.0

11.5

14.1

13.3

10.7

12.2

11.4

7.5

13.4

13.4

9.4

12.9

12.3

13.0

*Sig

nifi

cant

atth

e5

per

cent

leve

l**

signifi

cant

atth

e1

per

cent

leve

lN

ote

:See

table

1fo

rfu

llsu

rvey

nam

es.

Sourc

e:A

uth

ors

’analy

sis

base

don

dat

ades

crib

edin

the

text.

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 145

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 15: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

increase from around $500 in the lowest education quartile to close to $1,000for those with university degrees. Moreover, the positive association increasesmost strongly for migrants with postgraduate education, which shows that notonly do migrants with some university education remit more than thosewithout, but also that migrants with postgraduate degrees remit more thanthose with only a couple of years of university.

Robustness

Although this database on remittances is the most comprehensive available,there are clear limitations, which make it important to see how sensitive theresults are to alternative ways of using these surveys.

First note that the results pertain only to migration in a sample of OECDcountries. The surveys cover a large share of OECD destinations, but they omitother important destinations for developing country migrants such as the Gulfcountries and South Africa. This is a limitation shared by the macro studies(Faini 2007; Niimi and others 2008), which also have data only for migrantsin OECD countries. Nevertheless, the same forces acting on migrants in theOECD countries are likely to apply in these other destinations: more educatedmigrants will earn higher incomes and therefore remit more. Although data arerare, there is some evidence to support this is in a study of Pakistani migrantsin the Gulf countries, which found that conditional on age and duration of

Figure 1. Total Remittances by Years of Schooling

Note: Figure depicts a semiparametric regression line from a partial linear model with datasetdummy variable evaluated at means; 95 percent pointwise confidence intervals shown from 500bootstrap repetitions. Vertical lines separate quartiles.

Source: Authors’ analysis based on data described in the text.

146 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 16: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

stay, more educated Pakistani migrants remitted more (Abbasi and Hashmi2000).

Moreover, it is still the case that there are a large number of low skilledmigrants in the OECD. A large majority of migrants in the pooled sample(63 percent) do not have a university education. A reasonable concern iswhether surveys like the U.S. NIS, which capture only legal immigrants, aremissing most of the low-skilled migrants. Comparing the skill distribution ofimmigrants included in the NIS with that of immigrants included in the U.S.Census (which is generally believed to do a good job surveying both legal andillegal migrants), does show a higher skill level in the NIS (12.26 mean years ofeducation) than in the Census (10.84 years). However, once Mexican immi-grants are excluded (the group with the largest number of illegal immigrants),the skill distributions of the NIS (12.96 mean years of education) and theCensus (12.21) are much closer, and16 percent of immigrants in both the NISand the Census have 8 years of education or less. The first two columns oftable 4 then show that the results for the association between remittances andeducation continue to hold in the NIS (and, if anything, are more strongly posi-tive) when Mexican immigrants are excluded (table 4, columns 1 and 2).Columns 3 and 4 show that this is also true for the pooled sample of allsurveys, which suggests that failure to capture illegal migrants in the survey isnot driving the main result.

A second potential concern is whether it is valid to pool so many differentsurveys with different sampling methods and differing degrees of representa-tiveness. Note that survey fixed effects are included in the regression analysis,so that only within-survey variation is used to identify the effect of education;the pooled estimate is thus a consistent estimate for the average associationamong the surveys. Nonetheless, as an alternative, the regressions are run onlyfor the five surveys based on representative sampling from a list of migrants:(Longitudinal Survey of Immigrants to Australia (LSIA), the French Profile andTracking of Migrants Survey (DREES), the German Socioeconomic PanelStudy (SOEP), and the Spanish ENI and the NIS). The results show point esti-mates and levels of statistical significance that are very close to those for thefull pooled sample (see table 4, column 5). This demonstrates that the resultsare not being driven by the specialized surveys of particular migrant groups,such as the Japanese and Belgian surveys.

Finally, one might query whether the results are being driven by students.That could influence the results based on university education if there weremany students studying for undergraduate degrees who do not send remittancesand do not yet have a college degree. There are several reasons to believe thatthis is not the main factor driving results. First, the LSIA and NIS surveys donot include students, which eliminates from the sample students in thecountries that are among the most popular destinations for international study.Second, many international students come for postgraduate education, so theywould be classified as having a college education and remitting little, which

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 147

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 17: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

TA

BL

E4

.R

obust

nes

sC

hec

ks U

.S.

New

Imm

igra

nt

Surv

ey(N

IS)

sam

ple

Poole

dsa

mple

Vari

able

Full

sam

ple

Excl

udin

gM

exic

ans

Full

sam

ple

Excl

udin

gN

ISM

exic

ans

Nat

ionally

repre

senta

tive

sam

ple

sO

nly

mig

rants

ages

25þ

Only

work

ing

mig

rants

Educa

tion

mea

sure

dby

univ

ersi

tydeg

ree

Tota

lre

mit

tance

s($

per

year)

769.5

**

839.7

**

298.0

*306.8

*318.5

*267.7

308.7

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

7,0

46

5,9

22

24,0

33

22,9

09

19,6

43

21,3

43

16,6

93

Exte

nsi

ve:

Rem

its

indic

ator

0.0

38**

0.0

46**

-0.0

10

0.0

00

-0.0

11

-0.0

23*

0.0

48**

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

7,1

13

5,9

84

25,9

07

24,7

78

20,8

75

23,0

43

18,1

47

Inte

nsi

ve:

Log

rem

itta

nce

s0.3

97*

0.4

58**

0.2

26**

0.2

36**

0.2

20**

0.1

92**

0.2

30**

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

1,1

18

982

9,0

38

8,9

02

6,2

20

8,3

03

7,3

60

Educa

tion

mea

sure

din

years

Tota

lre

mit

tance

s($

per

year)

86.5

3108.0

957.8

168.1

762.5

258.7

878.4

9N

um

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

7,0

33

5,9

09

23,9

44

22,8

20

19,5

54

21,2

63

16,6

39

Exte

nsi

ve:

Rem

its

indic

ator

0.0

034**

0.0

021

0.0

014

0.0

016

0.0

017

0.0

007

0.0

031*

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

7,1

00

5,9

71

25,8

07

24,6

78

20,7

75

22,9

54

18,0

83

Inte

nsi

ve:

Log

rem

itta

nce

s0.0

329*

0.0

391*

0.0

229**

0.0

260**

0.0

307**

0.0

235**

0.0

242**

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

1,1

16

980

9,0

10

8,8

74

6,1

92

8,2

79

7,3

35

Mea

ns

Tota

lre

mit

tance

s($

per

year)

633

719

734

813

614

772

935

Fra

ctio

nw

ho

rem

it0.1

50.1

60.2

70.2

90.2

40.2

80.3

3Fra

ctio

nw

ith

univ

ersi

ty0.3

30.4

00.3

80.3

80.3

80.3

80.3

8Y

ears

of

educa

tion

13.4

14.0

13.0

13.1

13.1

13.0

13.4

*Sig

nifi

cant

atth

e5

per

cent

leve

l**

signifi

cant

atth

e1

per

cent

leve

l.

Note

:N

atio

nall

yre

pre

senta

tive

surv

eys

are

Aust

ralia

LSIA

,Fra

nce

DR

EE

S,

Ger

many

SO

EP,

Spain

EN

Iand

U.S

.N

IS.

See

table

1fo

rfu

llsu

rvey

nam

es.

Sourc

e:A

uth

ors

’analy

sis

base

don

dat

ades

crib

edin

the

text.

148 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 18: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

would offset any effect of undergraduates.9 As a final check, the analysis isrestricted to individuals who are working (table 4, last column). Since moreeducated individuals are more likely to be working, this eliminates one channelthrough which the more educated can earn more and thereby remit more.Nevertheless, even with this restriction, there is a significant positive coefficientat both the extensive and intensive margins, and the point estimate for totalremittances is similar in magnitude, although it is not statistically significant.

Taken together, these results indicate that the basic finding of a positiverelationship between total remittances and education appears reasonablyrobust to alternative ways of combining the surveys.

Channels

This section uses these microdata to explore some of the channels throughwhich education might influence remittances. Proxies are added to the modelto control for differences in household income and work status, in householddemographics and the presence of family abroad, in time spent abroad, in legalstatus, and in intentions to return home.

Table 5 shows the results of adding this full set of variables to the pooledmodel, using years of education as the measure of educational attainment. Thesechannels operate as theory would predict. Households with more income andwith adults who work more are more likely to remit: households where a migrantmember is working send $345 more annually, with an extra $38 remittedannually for each 10 percent increase in income. As expected, family compositionvariables are also strongly significant both overall and for the extensive and inten-sive margins: a spouse outside the country is associated with a colossal additional$1,120 remitted each year, approximately one and a half times the mean annualremittance for all migrants. Each child living outside the destination country isassociated with an additional $340 remitted annually and each parent for anadditional $180. Residing in the destination country legally is associated with anadditional $400 annually, providing no evidence that legal migrants lose theirdesire to remain in contact with their home country. Migrants who plan to moveback home also remit significantly more, but this effect is primarily through theextensive margin rather than the intensive margin.

Which channels account for the association between education and remit-tance behavior? Tables 6, 7, and 8 report how the coefficient on education inan ordinary least squares regression changes as controls are added for totalremittances, the extensive margin, and the intensive margin. Each panel of eachtable first shows the baseline education coefficient from regressing remittancesonly on education and country of birth and dataset fixed effects (from table 3).Each succeeding row then shows changes in this coefficient when controls are

9. In the United States, 47 percent of international students are studying for postgraduate degrees,

compared with 12 percent for associate degrees and 32 percent for bachelor degrees (http://opendoors

.iienetwork.org/?p=150827).

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 149

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 19: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

added for income and work status, family composition, and all controls fromtable 5 (income and family controls, as well as legal status, time spent abroad,and intent to return home).

Remittance behavior is accounted for primarily by income and not by differ-ences in family composition. The baseline result for total remittances fromtable 3, controlling only for country of birth and dataset fixed effects, is thatmigrants with a university degree remit $300 more than migrants without one.Controlling for the full set of covariates (the all row) reduces the coefficient onuniversity degree by two-thirds, and it becomes statistically insignificant. Thethird row adds just the family composition variables to the baseline

TA B L E 5. Remittances on Years of Education for Pooled Sample with AllControls

Total Extensive IntensiveVariable remittances Remits Log remittances

Years of education 37.81 20.002* 0.017**(29.64) (0.001) (0.005)

Log income 384.59** 0.023** 0.364**(105.37) (0.003) (0.034)

Working 345.06** 0.113** 0.514**(90.80) (0.010) (0.065)

Household size 28.14 20.002 0.015(17.67) (0.002) (0.016)

Married 289.77 0.004 20.097(68.78) (0.010) (0.061)

Spouse outside country 1,120.95** 0.145** 0.568**(236.04) (0.020) (0.097)

Number of children 2121.56** 20.006 20.099**(36.44) (0.003) (0.027)

Children outside country 337.78** 0.048** 0.228**(75.14) (0.006) (0.039)

Number of parents 247.07 20.020** 20.125**(53.56) (0.005) (0.045)

Parents outside country 182.58** 0.063** 0.243**(38.02) (0.006) (0.045)

Years spent abroad / 100 2,539.77 0.251** 1.744**(2,533.08) (0.095) (0.656)

Years spent abroad squared / 100 231.43 20.010** 20.033*(27.14) (0.002) (0.015)

Legal immigrant 398.79** 0.096** 0.167**(121.36) (0.018) (0.061)

Will return home 692.30** 0.095** 0.085(201.83) (0.021) (0.072)

Number of observations 23,944 32,535 11,364

*Significant at the 5 percent level ** significant at the 1 percent level.

Note: Includes dummy variables for missing covariates and fixed effects for country of birthand survey. Trimmed remittances greater than twice income. Pooled samples poststratified bycountry and education.

Source: Authors’ analysis based on data described in the text.

150 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 20: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

TA

BL

E6

.E

duca

tion

Coef

fici

ent

as

Contr

ols

Are

Added

:T

ota

lA

nnual

Rem

itta

nce

s(U

.S.

dollar

s)

Aust

rali

aB

elgiu

mG

erm

any

Italy

Japan

Spain

Spain

U.S

.U

.S.

Poole

dV

ari

able

LSIA

IRSH

SSO

EP

NID

IID

BE

NI

NID

IN

ISPew

tota

l

Univ

ersi

tyed

uca

tion

Base

line

58.4

922.8

**

291.0

2526.6

237.5

292.6

2168.8

769.5

**

2554.0

*298.0

*(6

1.1

)(3

51.4

)(2

75.6

)(4

11.6

)(3

74.1

)(6

2.8

)(7

49.4

)(2

54.4

)(2

27.2

)(1

37.6

)In

com

e2

10.1

557.0

*238.5

2623.9

166.5

2189.3

**

24.7

396.6

*2

741.5

**

102.3

(62.4

)(2

81.4

)(2

62.2

)(4

07.2

)(3

59.8

)(6

3.5

)(7

29.0

)(1

74.4

)(2

63.8

)(9

2.8

)Fam

ilya

29.8

534.7

237.8

2306.7

317.5

2112.8

26.9

623.6

**

2698.6

**

228.2

*(6

1.4

)(3

10.5

)(2

43.5

)(3

94.7

)(3

80.3

)(5

7.6

)(7

25.9

)(2

04.7

)(2

41.9

)(1

03.1

)A

ll2

16.5

475.8

144.6

2539.6

328.7

2181.7

**

266.2

402.2

**

2835.7

**

99.9

(62.1

)(2

72.7

)(1

79.8

)(3

83.3

)(3

65.3

)(5

8.6

)(6

98.6

)(1

54.3

)(2

69.9

)(7

1.6

)N

um

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

2,5

37

377

854

1,0

72

846

9,2

34

1,0

20

7,0

46

1,0

84

24,0

33

Yea

rsof

educa

tion

Base

line

19.0

8*

86.5

026.3

92

7.5

62

3.0

32.4

02

13.6

586.5

364.8

957.8

1(9

.01)

(45.1

1)

(29.3

7)

(34.0

5)

(7.9

2)

(7.3

6)

(19.9

5)

(46.5

0)

(44.9

7)

(37.0

8)

Inco

me

7.9

947.8

03.5

12

32.4

42

2.5

92

13.3

92

26.9

544.9

849.1

832.1

2(8

.69)

(38.2

8)

(27.3

3)

(33.3

9)

(11.5

0)

(7.4

1)

(19.6

8)

(40.0

0)

(45.0

9)

(31.9

8)

Fam

ilya

17.0

329.2

825.5

647.3

12

1.8

63.9

310.3

280.7

847.9

555.4

3(8

.98)

(38.4

5)

(27.7

9)

(34.9

3)

(8.6

2)

(6.8

4)

(19.9

8)

(44.7

5)

(46.3

7)

(34.2

4)

All

8.8

633.7

79.6

622.6

41.9

92

7.5

74.5

054.8

127.0

137.8

1(8

.91)

(36.9

4)

(22.8

2)

(32.7

9)

(10.6

3)

(6.8

4)

(19.3

2)

(37.3

2)

(46.3

8)

(29.6

4)

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

2,5

31

377

854

1,0

72

846

9,1

64

1,0

20

7,0

33

1,0

84

23,9

44

*Sig

nifi

cant

atth

e5

per

cent

leve

l**

signifi

cant

atth

e1

per

cent

leve

l.

Note

:B

ase

line

row

incl

udes

only

countr

yof

bir

thand

dat

ase

tfixed

effe

cts.

Inco

me

row

adds

work

ing

dum

my

and

log

inco

me

tobase

line.

Fam

ily

row

adds

seve

nfa

mil

ym

ember

contr

ols

tobase

line.

All

row

isfu

llsp

ecifi

cati

on

from

table

3.

Tri

mm

edre

mit

tance

sgre

ater

than

twic

ein

com

e.Poole

dsa

mple

spost

stra

tified

by

countr

yand

educa

tion.

See

table

1fo

rfu

llsu

rvey

nam

es.

a.

Incl

udes

house

hold

size

,dum

my

vari

able

ifm

arr

ied,

dum

my

vari

able

ifsp

ouse

isouts

ide

the

countr

y,num

ber

of

childre

n,

num

ber

of

childre

nouts

ide

the

countr

y,num

ber

of

pare

nts

,and

num

ber

of

pare

nts

outs

ide

the

countr

y

Sourc

e:A

uth

ors

’analy

sis

base

don

dat

ades

crib

edin

the

text.

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 151

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 21: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

TA

BL

E7

.E

duca

tion

Coef

fici

ent

as

Contr

ols

are

Added

:R

emit

sIn

dic

ator

Aust

ralia

Bel

giu

mFra

nce

Ger

many

Italy

Japan

Norw

aySpain

Spain

U.S

.U

.S.

Poole

d

Vari

able

LSIA

IRSH

SD

RE

ES

SO

EP

NID

IID

BL

BI

EN

IN

IDI

NIS

Pew

Exte

nsi

veT

ota

l

Univ

ersi

tyed

uca

tion

Base

line

20.0

19

20.0

55

0.0

14

0.0

42

20.0

65

0.0

91**

0.0

12

20.0

49**

20.2

32**

0.0

38**

20.1

40*

20.0

18

20.0

10

(0.0

32)

(0.0

29)

(0.0

27)

(0.0

48)

(0.0

43)

(0.0

34)

(0.0

30)

(0.0

15)

(0.0

81)

(0.0

11)

(0.0

60)

(0.0

10)

(0.0

10)

Inco

me

20.0

52

20.1

12**

20.0

27

0.0

23

20.0

74

0.0

82*

20.0

20

20.0

62**

20.1

85*

20.0

00

20.1

65**

20.0

43**

20.0

33**

(0.0

32)

(0.0

29)

(0.0

27)

(0.0

47)

(0.0

42)

(0.0

35)

(0.0

30)

(0.0

15)

(0.0

78)

(0.0

11)

(0.0

58)

(0.0

10)

(0.0

11)

Fam

ilya

20.0

62

20.0

69*

0.0

15

0.0

39

20.0

46

0.0

88*

20.0

04

20.0

67**

20.2

34**

0.0

22

20.1

48*

20.0

31**

20.0

26*

(0.0

32)

(0.0

32)

(0.0

27)

(0.0

48)

(0.0

41)

(0.0

35)

(0.0

30)

(0.0

13)

(0.0

81)

(0.0

12)

(0.0

60)

(0.0

10)

(0.0

11)

All

20.0

80*

20.1

13**

20.0

27

0.0

28

20.0

65

0.0

83*

20.0

31

20.0

73**

20.1

77*

0.0

06

20.1

61**

20.0

43**

20.0

33**

(0.0

31)

(0.0

30)

(0.0

27)

(0.0

48)

(0.0

38)

(0.0

35)

(0.0

30)

(0.0

14)

(0.0

75)

(0.0

12)

(0.0

59)

(0.0

10)

(0.0

11)

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

2,6

54

451

4,2

78

854

1,1

53

1,0

30

2,4

66

10,2

82

1,1

12

7,1

13

1,2

96

32,6

51

25,9

07

Yea

rsof

educa

tion

Base

line

0.0

080

20.0

042

0.0

018

0.0

145

0.0

010

0.0

024**

0.0

008

20.0

023

20.0

072**

0.0

034**

0.0

010

0.0

006

0.0

014

(0.0

043)

(0.0

040)

(0.0

025)

(0.0

084)

(0.0

040)

(0.0

005)

(0.0

025)

(0.0

018)

(0.0

021)

(0.0

012)

(0.0

060)

(0.0

009)

(0.0

010)

Inco

me

0.0

014

20.0

117**

20.0

016

0.0

071

20.0

027

0.0

035**

20.0

027

20.0

049**

20.0

074**

20.0

015

20.0

035

20.0

027**

20.0

018

(0.0

042)

(0.0

040)

(0.0

025)

(0.0

084)

(0.0

037)

(0.0

011)

(0.0

026)

(0.0

018)

(0.0

021)

(0.0

012)

(0.0

057)

(0.0

010)

(0.0

010)

Fam

ilya

0.0

018

20.0

060

0.0

050*

0.0

152

0.0

062

0.0

019**

20.0

006

20.0

040*

20.0

054*

0.0

029*

0.0

006

0.0

000

0.0

006

(0.0

044)

(0.0

042)

(0.0

025)

(0.0

087)

(0.0

041)

(0.0

006)

(0.0

026)

(0.0

017)

(0.0

021)

(0.0

012)

(0.0

060)

(0.0

009)

(0.0

010)

All

20.0

025

20.0

115**

0.0

012

0.0

130

0.0

031

0.0

034**

20.0

037

20.0

061**

20.0

046*

0.0

002

20.0

059

20.0

019*

20.0

011

(0.0

041)

(0.0

041)

(0.0

024)

(0.0

087)

(0.0

037)

(0.0

010)

(0.0

026)

(0.0

017)

(0.0

020)

(0.0

012)

(0.0

055)

(0.0

010)

(0.0

010)

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

2,6

48

451

5,5

29

854

1,1

53

1,0

30

2,4

50

10,2

01

1,1

12

7,1

00

1,2

96

32,5

35

25,8

07

*Sig

nifi

cant

atth

e5

per

cent

leve

l**

signifi

cant

atth

e1

per

cent

leve

l.

Note

:B

ase

line

row

incl

udes

only

countr

yof

bir

thand

dat

ase

tfixed

effe

cts.

Inco

me

row

adds

work

ing

dum

my

and

log

inco

me

tobase

line.

Fam

ily

row

adds

seve

nfa

mil

ym

ember

contr

ols

tobase

line.

All

row

isfu

llsp

ecifi

cati

on

from

table

3.

Tri

mm

edre

mit

tance

sgre

ater

than

twic

ein

com

e.Poole

dsa

mple

spost

stra

tified

by

countr

yand

educa

tion.

a.

Incl

udes

house

hold

size

,dum

my

vari

able

ifm

arr

ied,

dum

my

vari

able

ifsp

ouse

isouts

ide

the

countr

y,num

ber

of

childre

n,

num

ber

of

childre

nouts

ide

the

countr

y,num

ber

of

pare

nts

,and

num

ber

of

pare

nts

outs

ide

the

countr

y

Sourc

e:A

uth

ors

’analy

sis

base

don

dat

ades

crib

edin

the

text.

152 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 22: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

specification. The main hypothesis for why less skilled migrants remit more isthat they are more likely to have family members outside the country.Therefore, controlling only for this variable would be expected to increase thecoefficient on education, but the opposite occurs: the coefficient on educationdrops from $300 to $230 and remains statistically significant. This casts doubton the idea that low skilled migrants remit more because of their family com-position. One explanation is the earlier observation that low skilled migrantsare not only likely to have more family abroad, but they are also likely to livein larger households in the host country. The second row of the table adds justthe income variables (a dummy variable for working and log income) to thebaseline specification. The coefficient on university degree falls by more thanhalf and is no longer statistically significant. This suggests that the incomeeffect is a key channel through which education affects remittances—more edu-cated people send more money because they have higher incomes.

Although education becomes insignificant after controlling for income in thepooled sample, this result masks the heterogeneity in the individual surveys. Forexample, the education coefficient remains statistically significant even after con-trolling for all available covariates for three datasets: the Spanish ENI survey,the U.S. Pew dataset, and the U.S. NIS survey. There are several reasons why theeducation coefficient might remain significant in some datasets and not in othersthat cannot be examined with the dataset. One key variable that cannot be con-trolled for is the socioeconomic status of the family in the home country. Moreeducated individuals might come from better-off families and therefore not needto send back as much money. This could explain the negative coefficient in theENI and the Pew datasets.10Or more educated individuals might have fewer tiesto their home country. Time spent away from the home country and desire toreturn home are used to control for this, but they may not fully capture thestrength of the ties. Also lacking are data on whether migrants are using remit-tance to repay family loans—for example, for education. One additional keyissue is that the use of cross-section data does not yield any information abouteconomic shocks that affect the migrant or the migrant’s family.

Table 7 examines the extensive margin. In the baseline specification, moreeducated migrants are less likely to remit anything, but this result is not statisti-cally significant. The negative effect of education on the decision to remit any-thing is strengthened by the inclusion of different sets of covariates. Thecoefficient on education (measured by university degree) is negative and signifi-cant once any covariates are included. The alternative measure of education,years of schooling, is not statistically significant. Table 8 examines the intensivemargin result, which again appears to be driven by the income effect. Adding

10. An alternative explanation may be that the high-earning highly educated migrants are less likely

to respond to surveys. Survey methods that draw a sample from areas known to have a high

concentration of migrants (such as the Pew survey) or from locations where migrants tend to congregate

(such as the NIDI surveys) are especially likely to miss highly educated high-income individuals, who

may be living in areas where there are fewer of their countrymen.

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 153

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 23: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

TA

BL

E8

.E

duca

tion

Coef

fici

ent

as

Contr

ols

Are

Added

:L

og

Rem

itta

nce

s

Aust

ralia

Bel

giu

mFra

nce

Ger

many

Italy

Japan

Net

her

lands

Spain

Spain

UK

U.S

.U

.S.

Poole

dPoole

d

Vari

able

LSIA

IRSH

S2M

OSO

EP

NID

IID

BC

SR

EN

IN

IDI

BM

EN

ISPew

Inte

nsi

veT

ota

l

Univ

ersi

tyed

uca

tion

Base

line

0.3

41*

0.4

33**

0.3

63

0.4

92

0.0

73

20.0

57

0.3

33**

0.0

93

0.4

30*

0.1

68

0.3

97*

20.1

99

0.2

49**

0.2

26**

(0.1

45)

(0.1

31)

(0.2

11)

(0.4

50)

(0.1

71)

(0.1

46)

(0.1

16)

(0.0

66)

(0.2

02)

(0.1

33)

(0.1

69)

(0.2

16)

(0.0

60)

(0.0

71)

Inco

me

0.2

37

0.2

43*

0.3

06

0.4

08

0.0

21

20.0

86

0.3

33**

0.0

40

0.3

67

0.0

97

0.0

23

20.2

78

0.1

43*

0.1

14

(0.1

38)

(0.1

16)

(0.2

03)

(0.4

45)

(0.1

65)

(0.1

40)

(0.1

16)

(0.0

64)

(0.2

00)

(0.1

23)

(0.1

68)

(0.2

10)

(0.0

58)

(0.0

67)

Fam

ilya

0.2

88*

0.2

58*

0.3

90

0.4

23

0.1

05

20.0

33

0.3

33**

0.0

92

0.4

95**

0.2

06

0.3

64*

20.2

53

0.2

46**

0.2

20**

(0.1

39)

(0.1

28)

(0.2

07)

(0.3

68)

(0.1

78)

(0.1

50)

(0.1

16)

(0.0

61)

(0.1

87)

(0.1

32)

(0.1

66)

(0.2

18)

(0.0

57)

(0.0

66)

All

0.1

79

0.2

25

0.3

18

0.2

93

20.0

15

0.0

03

0.3

23**

0.0

54

0.4

09*

0.1

27

0.0

71

20.3

47

0.1

57**

0.1

18

(0.1

34)

(0.1

18)

(0.2

10)

(0.3

09)

(0.1

76)

(0.1

38)

(0.1

17)

(0.0

59)

(0.1

93)

(0.1

23)

(0.1

65)

(0.2

06)

(0.0

55)

(0.0

63)

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

958

317

713

184

545

690

648

3,9

66

761

993

1,1

18

514

11,3

92

9,0

38

Yea

rsof

educa

tion

Base

line

0.0

441*

0.0

341

0.0

224*

20.0

085

20.0

032

20.0

040

0.0

247*

0.0

199**

0.0

091

0.0

548*

0.0

329*

0.0

369

0.0

256**

0.0

229**

(0.0

194)

(0.0

174)

(0.0

112)

(0.0

783)

(0.0

163)

(0.0

038)

(0.0

100)

(0.0

076)

(0.0

063)

(0.0

237)

(0.0

146)

(0.0

221)

(0.0

061)

(0.0

071)

Inco

me

0.0

266

0.0

103

0.0

105

20.0

387

20.0

077

20.0

041

0.0

247*

0.0

114

0.0

021

0.0

313

20.0

008

0.0

294

0.0

135*

0.0

112

(0.0

199)

(0.0

164)

(0.0

115)

(0.0

770)

(0.0

164)

(0.0

048)

(0.0

100)

(0.0

075)

(0.0

062)

(0.0

220)

(0.0

126)

(0.0

216)

(0.0

053)

(0.0

062)

Fam

ilya

0.0

383*

0.0

101

0.0

344**

0.0

053

0.0

098

20.0

042

0.0

247*

0.0

247**

0.0

146*

0.0

612**

0.0

392**

0.0

194

0.0

272**

0.0

243**

(0.0

187)

(0.0

167)

(0.0

111)

(0.0

649)

(0.0

168)

(0.0

037)

(0.0

100)

(0.0

072)

(0.0

066)

(0.0

235)

(0.0

144)

(0.0

231)

(0.0

060)

(0.0

070)

All

0.0

227

0.0

060

0.0

268*

20.0

183

0.0

009

20.0

020

0.0

274**

0.0

179*

0.0

086

0.0

319

0.0

172

0.0

128

0.0

169**

0.0

139*

(0.0

193)

(0.0

165)

(0.0

124)

(0.0

511)

(0.0

159)

(0.0

050)

20.0

1(0

.0070)

(0.0

064)

(0.0

224)

(0.0

123)

(0.0

213)

(0.0

052)

(0.0

060)

Num

ber

of

obse

rvat

ions

956

317

713

184

545

690

648

3,9

42

761

993

1,1

16

514

11,3

64

9,0

10

*Sig

nifi

cant

atth

e5

per

cent

leve

l**

signifi

cant

atth

e1

per

cent

leve

l.

Note

:B

ase

line

row

incl

udes

only

countr

yof

bir

thand

dat

ase

tfixed

effe

cts.

Inco

me

row

adds

work

ing

dum

my

and

log

inco

me

tobase

line.

Fam

ily

row

adds

seve

nfa

mil

ym

ember

contr

ols

tobase

line.

All

row

isfu

llsp

ecifi

cati

on

from

table

3.

Tri

mm

edre

mit

tance

sgre

ater

than

twic

ein

com

e.Poole

dsa

mple

spost

stra

tified

by

countr

yand

educa

tion.

a.

Incl

udes

house

hold

size

,dum

my

vari

able

ifm

arr

ied,

dum

my

vari

able

ifsp

ouse

isouts

ide

the

countr

y,num

ber

of

childre

n,

num

ber

of

childre

nouts

ide

the

countr

y,num

ber

of

pare

nts

,and

num

ber

of

pare

nts

outs

ide

the

countr

y

Sourc

e:A

uth

ors

’analy

sis

base

don

dat

ades

crib

edin

the

text.

154 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 24: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

only family variables to the baseline specification reduces the coefficient on uni-versity education by approximately 3 percent, but it remains highly significant.However, if only income variables are added to the baseline specification, thecoefficient becomes statistically insignificant, with approximately the samepoint value as the full specification with the full set of covariates.

I V. C O N C L U S I O N S

The key advantage of this analysis over that in other papers in this literature(Faini 2007; Niimi and others 2008) is the ability to link the remittancedecision of migrants with their education level and therefore directly answerthe question of whether more educated migrants remit more. Cross-countrymacroeconomic analyses that relate the amount of remittances received at acountry level to the share of migrants with tertiary education can at best tell uswhether countries that send a larger share of highly skilled migrants receiveless or more remittances than countries that send fewer skilled migrants,without accounting for the other differences between countries that couldunderlie such a relationship.

This new database on migrants allows direct examination of the relationshipbetween education and remittance decisions. Results for the extensive margin(the decision to remit at all) and the intensive margin (the decision on howmuch to remit) combined show that, at least in this combined sample, moreeducated migrants remit significantly more: migrants with a university degreeremit $300 more yearly than migrants without one. Nonetheless, there is someheterogeneity across destination countries, with negative point estimates in afew of the surveys used—mainly in surveys that sample migrants only in areaswhere migrants cluster, thereby missing more educated, higher earningmigrants who may live outside of the immigrant clusters.

The data also allow analysis of several competing theoretical channels thathelp to explain this result. Differences in household composition between highand low skilled migrants do not explain the observed remittance behavior. Oneexplanation may be that although low skilled migrants are more likely to havea spouse and children in the home country, they have larger families onaverage than do high skilled migrants and tend to live in larger households inthe host country. In contrast, there is considerable support for an income effectas the dominant channel through which education operates. More educatedmigrants earn more money and therefore remit more than low skilled migrants.

The article also highlights the clear limitations of existing microdata on remit-tances. While some basic information on migrants can be obtained from censusmicrodata and government immigration records, there are no comparablyreliable sources for remittances. The new database relies on specialized one-offsurveys of migrants. Given the importance of remittances for many developingcountries, it would be beneficial for migrant-receiving countries to include ques-tions on remittances in their regular labor force or household budget surveys.

Bollard, McKenzie, Morten, and Rapoport 155

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from

Page 25: Remittances and the Brain Drain Revisited: The Microdata ...documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/431521468147547260/pdf/718… · the belief that more educated individuals may remit

This would be a first step to being able to analyze how remittance patternschange as countries pursue more skill-selective immigration policies.

Policy debates on migration often raise concerns about the potential negativeeffects of the “brain drain” on developing countries. However, the mainfinding that remittances increase with education illustrates one beneficialdimension of high skilled migration for developing countries. High skilledmigrants work in better jobs and earn more money than low skilled migrantsand in turn send more money back home in remittance flows. This suggeststhat the fear that remittances will fall as the migrant skill level rises is not sup-ported by existing empirical evidence.

RE F E R E N C E S

Abbasi, Saif-Ur-Rehman Saif, and Arshad Hussain Hashmi. 2000. “Migrants Earning at Overseas Job

and Extent of Remittances Transferred to their Families in Pakistan.” International Journal of

Agriculture and Biology 2 (3): 222–25.

Cox, Donald. 1987. “Motives for Private Transfers.” Journal of Political Economy 95 (3): 508–46.

Cox, Donald, Zekeriya Eser, and Emmanuel Jimenez. 1998. “Motives for private transfers over the life

cycle: An analytical framework and evidence for Peru.” Journal of Development Economics 55: 57–80.

Docquier, Frederic, and Abdeslam Marfouk. 2005. “International Migration by Education Attainment,

1990–2000.” In International Migration, Remittances and the Brain Drain, ed. C. Ozden, and M. Schiff,

151–99. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

Faini, Riccardo. 2007. “Remittances and the Brain Drain: Do more Skilled Migrants Remit More?”

World Bank Economic Review 21 (2): 177–91.

Groenewold, George, and Richard Bilsborrow. 2004. “Design of Samples for International Migration

Surveys: Methodological Considerations, Practical Constraints and Lessons Learned from a

Multi-Country Study in Africa and Europe.” Paper presented at the Population Association of

America 2004 General Conference, Boston, MA, April 1–3.

IDB (Inter-American Development Bank). 2005. “Survey of Brazilians and Peruvians in Japan” Survey

commissioned by the Multilateral Investment Fund.

Miotti, Luis, El Mouhoub Mouhoud, and Joel Oudinet. 2009. “Migrations and Determinants of

Remittances to Southern Mediterranean Countries: When History Matters.” Paper presented at the

2nd Migration and Development Conference, Washington, DC, September 10–11.

Niimi, Yoko, Caglar Ozden, and Maurice Schiff. Forthcoming. “Remittances and the Brain Drain:

Skilled Migrants Do Remit Less.” Annales d’Economie et de Statistique.

OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development). 2007. Policy Coherence for

Development 2007: Migration and Developing Countries. Paris: OECD.

Rapoport, Hillel, and Frederic Docquier. 2006. “The Economics of Migrants’ Remittances.” In

Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, ed. S.-C. Kolm, and J. Mercier

Ythier, 1135–98. Amsterdan: North-Holland.

Robinson, Peter M. 1988. “Root-N Consistent Semiparametric Regression.” Econometrica 56: 931–54.

Siegel, Melissa. 2007. “Immigrant Integration and Remittance Channel Choice.” Working Paper 2007/

09. Maastricht Graduate School of Governance.

Stark, Oded. 1991. The Migration of Labor. Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell.

World Bank. 2008. Migration and Remittances Factbook 2008. Washington, DC: World Bank.

———. 2009. “Migration and Development Brief No. 9.” http://siteresources.worldbank.org/

INTPROSPECTS/Resources/MD_Brief9_Mar2009.pdf. Accessed July 10, 2009.

156 T H E W O R L D B A N K E C O N O M I C R E V I E W

at International Monetary F

und on August 12, 2011

wber.oxfordjournals.org

Dow

nloaded from