references n lemaire et al: pricing term insurance in the presence of a family history of breast or...

59
References Lemaire et al: Pricing Term Insurance in the Presence of a Family History of Breast or Ovarian Cancer. North American Act. J., 2000, 75-87 Subramanian et al: Estimating Adverse Selection Costs From Genetic Testing for Breast and Ovarian Cancer: The Case of Life Insurance. J. of Risk and Insurance, 1999, 66, 531-550

Upload: judith-barton

Post on 17-Dec-2015

214 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

References

Lemaire et al: Pricing Term Insurance in the Presence of a Family History of Breast or Ovarian Cancer. North American Act. J., 2000, 75-87

Subramanian et al: Estimating Adverse Selection Costs From Genetic Testing for Breast and Ovarian Cancer: The Case of Life Insurance. J. of Risk and Insurance, 1999, 66, 531-550

Adverse Selection from Genetic Testing for BRCA in a Term Life Insurance Market. Inelastic and Elastic Demands

Jean LemaireThe Wharton School

Krupa SubramanianTemple University

Genetic Tests and their Implications in Insurance

Jean Lemaire

Wharton School

Krupa Subramanian

Temple University

Genetic Testing in the News

Humane Genome Project Clinton Executive Order DNA testing on death row UAE require testing prior to marriage Greek Orthodox Church requires testing Pre-marital counseling in Sardinia Alzheimer-free embryos Fear of job and insurance discrimination in public

Genetic Diseases (% of carriers)

Huntington’s Disease Cystic Fibrosis

– 1/2,500 US whites– 1/17,000 US African-Americans

Tay-Sachs Disease– 1/27 US Ashkenazi Jews– 1/250 US Sephardic Jews– High Accadians, Cajuns

Sickle-Cell Anemia– 1/4 Central Africa

BRCA– 1/43 US Ashkenazi Jews– 1/833 US whites– High Iceland, Thailand

Six-fingered Drawfism– High Amish, Pennsylvania

Genes impact other diseases

Alzheimer’s Disease Diabetes Manic Depression Schizophrenia Multiple Sclerosis Rheumatoid Arthritis Thalassemia Haemophilia and over 1,100 others Over 800 tests offered

Genetic Testing Issues

Privacy concerns Voluntary testing Job and insurance discrimination Regulation addressing genetic testing Adverse selection in insurance markets

Existing Legislation

1. Laissez-faire (Australia, Canada, Japan, Ireland, Portugal, Spain)

2. Disclosure Duty (Germany, New Zealand)

3. Consent Law (Netherlands, Switzerland) Strict Prohibition (Austria, Belgium,

Denmark, France, Italy, Norway)

In the absence, or in addition to, legislation

Voluntary agreement with state (Sweden) Moratorium (Germany, Finland, Greece,

Netherlands, Switzerland, UK) Code or conduct or guidelines (Australia,

South Africa) United States: Laws in 44 states UK: Moratorium, approval of specific tests

Breast Cancer Ovarian Cancer

One woman in nine will develop breast cancer (BC) in her lifetime - one in forty will die from the disease

1.8% of women will develop ovarian cancer (OC) - over 60% will die from it. Family history multiplies the risk by 5.4

A very small percentage of women have either BRCA1 or BRCA2 mutations.

95% of BC are not inherited

They result from diet, lifestyles, environment, social exposures, and many other factors, known and unknown

Early menarchy Late menopause First pregnancy past 30 years of age Hormone replacement therapy Birth control pills

Tests for the BRCA mutation

About 5% of BC and OC are the results of a gene mutation (BRCA 1 or BRCA 2)

Since late 1997, commercial tests are available to detect the gene mutation

Full-length screening of BRCA: $2,400 Test of four mutations in BRCA1: $295

(“Ashkenazi test”)

Breast Cancer Ovarian Cancer

Lifetime Cancer Risks for BRCA1/2:

- breast (female): 56-85%- breast (male): 6%- ovarian: 10-60%- prostate, colon, pancreas cancers

Without the mutation, the age at onset is Normal(68, 225).

With the mutation, the age at onset is Normal(55, 225).

Estimates from Claus et al

Cumulative Probability of developing BC for a woman who has one First-Degree relative affected with BC, by age of onset of the affected relative

Age ofwoman age of onset in affected relative

20-29 30-39 40-49 50-59 60-69 70-7929 .007 .005 .003 .002 .002 .00139 .025 .017 .012 .008 .006 .00549 .062 .044 .032 .023 .018 .01559 .116 .086 .064 .049 .040 .03569 .171 .130 .101 .082 .070 .06279 .211 .165 .132 .110 .096 .088

Double Decrement Model for BC

Alive, without BC

Alive, with BC

Death, affected with

BC

Death, from causes other

than BC

Double Decrement Model for BC

1k

0j

BC

kx

BC

1jx1jk

)2(

jx

)(

xj

BC

xk)j(q)j(pqpq

Double Decrement Model for OC

1k

0jOC

2/1kx2/1)3(kx

)(xk

OCkx

OC2/1jx2/1jk

)3(jx

)(xj

OCxk

)k(qqp

)j(q)j(pqpq

BC Survival Probabilities

Exponential Decay, with 3.6% annual death probability

OC Survival Probabilities

1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 191973 59.9 40.8 36.0 34.9 33.1 32.5 32.1 31.6 30.2 30.11978 67.7 44.5 38.4 35.8 34.6 34.3 33.2 32.81983 70.1 47.8 42.5 39.0 37.01988 73.6 55.5 48.31992 78.3

The Separation Method

Cij = pi Ii+j-1

OC Survival Probabilities

1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 191973 59.9 40.8 36.0 34.9 33.1 32.5 32.1 31.6 30.2 30.11978 67.7 44.5 38.4 35.8 34.6 34.3 33.2 32.81983 70.1 47.8 42.5 39.0 37.01988 73.6 55.5 48.31992 78.3 58 50.6 43.7 42 42.3 39.4 40.7 39.6 41.6

Mortality Ratios for 30 year old woman, according to family history

AGE 1 FDR-BC 1 SDR-BC 2 FDR-BC 1 FDR-OC

BRCA

31 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0302 1.029833 1.0345 1.0161 1.1051 1.1946 1.354335 1.0999 1.0465 1.3034 1.4011 1.861537 1.1822 1.0848 1.5518 1.5958 2.432339 1.2627 1.1225 1.7927 1.7350 2.932241 1.3385 1.1580 2.0159 1.7070 3.235143 1.3004 1.1391 1.9045 1.5812 2.930045 1.2976 1.1358 1.8999 1.6926 3.013347 1.3026 1.1362 1.9167 1.8143 3.136749 1.3174 1.1414 1.9586 1.9083 3.2691

Mortality Ratios for Common Conditions and Diseases

DISEASE MEASUREMENT -RATIOSystolic bloodpressure 158-167 (men) 2.06Systolic bloodpressure 178-187 (women) 2.78Diabetes mellitus Men 2.50Build 40% overweight (women) 1.62Build 60% overweight (men) 2.60Epilepsy All types 2.78Alcoholism 5 drinks a day 3.00Smoking Average (men) 1.70Smoking 40 cigarettes/day (men) 2.00HIV 35-year-old male 50.00

Relative cost of term insurance

(No Family History: Cost = 100)

AGE TERM 1 FDR – OC 1 FDR – BC 2 FDR - BC BRCA10 109.01 113.51 140.80 205.203020 112.20 122.33 167.00 255.5110 112.52 111.81 138.20 240.684020 112.20 115.97 150.05 250.2410 108.87 106.00 120.32 172.365020 107.92 107.58 124.67 170.23

4574.180.140

20.205SelectionAdverseofCost

Adverse Selection Markov Model

•First model: Inelastic Demand

•Discrete-state, continuous-time Markov Model

Not TestedNot Insured

Not TestedInsured

Test NegativeNever Buy or Lapses

DEAD

Test NegativeSame Insurance

Test NegativeBuy Less

Test PositiveSame Insurance

Test PositiveBuy Less

Test NegativeBuy Insurance

412 6

Test NegativeBuy More

Test PositiveBuy More

7 10

11

9

2

Test PositiveBuy Insurance

5

14

Lapse

8

Test PositiveNever Buy or Lapses

13

1

3

Implicit Cost of Adverse Selection =

E.V. of Claim costs (Full information) E.V. of Claim costs (Allowable information)

Each state for which there is an outward transition translates to a differential equation (Thieles’s differential equation for reserves).

jk

t

j)1(

tjk

k)1(

t

jk

t

j)1(

tt

j)1(

t)VVb(VV

dt

d

where

Vtj( )1 Benefit reserve for State j at time t

Vtk()1 Benefit reserve for State k at time t

t Force of interest at time tbtjk Payments due upon transitions from state j

btjk to state k.tjk Intensity of transition from state j to state k

tjk at time t.

Behavioural Assumptions

Inelastic demand for insurance Rate of genetic testing: 0.05 Force of Interest: 0.05 Rate of insurance purchase: 0.05 Rate of lapsing before testing: 0.05 Rate of re-entry into State 1

from lapse state: 0.25

Behavioural Assumptions

If insured and test positive:

P(more insurance) = 0.27P(same insurance) = 0.70

P(less insurance) = 0.02P(lapse policy) = 0.01

If insured and test negative:

P(more insurance) = 0.01P(same insurance) = 0.75P(less insurance) = 0.17

P(lapse policy) = 0.07

Mortality improvements

Assumption: no mortality improvements Conservative since:

– Overall improvement: 0.65% per year– Oophorectomy (-50%)– Mastectomy (-90%)– Tamoxifen (-40%)

TERM

Age IncreasedBenefit

5 10 15 20

50 2 1.0004 1.0013 1.0020 1.0021

4 1.0006 1.0019 1.0029 1.0030

10 1.0012 1.0035 1.0054 1.0056

Adverse selection costs for a woman with no family history of BC or OC, insured at onset; basic benefit $1

Adverse selection costs for a woman with One FDR with OC. Age at onset: unknown

TERM

Age IncreasedBenefit

5 10 15 20

30 2 1.0023 1.0107 1.0194 1.0237

4 1.0057 1.0226 1.0409 1.0524

10 1.0158 1.0563 1.0999 1.1299

Adverse selection costs for a woman with one FDR with BC, age at Onset: 20-29.

TERM

Age IncreasedBenefit

5 10 15 20

30 2 1.0065 1.0177 1.0294 1.0386

4 1.0126 1.0369 1.0626 1.0825

10 1.0300 1.0893 1.1495 1.1935

TERM

Age IncreasedBenefit

5 10 15 20

40 2 1.0144 1.0380 1.0544 1.0523

4 1.0233 1.0632 1.0925 1.0928

10 1.0489 1.1322 1.1924 1.1949

TERM

Age IncreasedBenefit

5 10 15 20

50 2 1.0079 1.0197 1.0271 1.0250

4 1.0128 1.0331 1.0468 1.0449

10 1.0269 1.0698 1.0985 1.0952

Adverse selection costs for a woman with two FDR with BC, Age at Onset: 20-29

TERM

Age IncreasedBenefit

5 10 15 20

30 2 1.0089 1.0168 1.0237 1.0294

4 1.0186 1.0421 1.0631 1.0787

10 1.0445 1.1034 1.1510 1.1819

Sensitivity Analysis: 40-year old Woman, 2 FDR with BC

Adverse selection costs for a woman with two FDR with BC, age at Onset 20-29, who claims no family history of BC or OC;

Age Increased Benefit

5 10 15 20

30 2 1.2356 1.5149 1.7253 1.8490

4 1.2813 1.6364 1.9312 2.1263

10 1.4170 1.9933 2.5300 2.9260

Sensitivity Analysis: 40-year old Woman, 2 FDR with BC, but reports No family history of BC or OC

Second Model: Elastic Demand

Discrete-state, discrete time Markov model A cohort of 1,000 women is tracked down

for 20 years. Initially they are all insured for $100,000 under an annually renewable term policy, and untested for BRCA

Three decrements from initial cohort: death, lapse, testing for BRCA mutation

All may change their benefit each year

Adverse selection results from

Differentiated lapsing rates: women testing positive will exhibit a lower lapsing rate

Differentiated benefits: women testing positive are more likely to increase their benefits

Different reactions to price increases: women testing positive are more likely to accept a price increase

The insurance company

Will increase premiums as a result of adverse selection

Myopic reaction of insurer is assumed: each year, it calculates past losses, and attempts to recoup them by increasing premiums

The same % premium increase is applied to each rating cell

Twelve rating cells: Ages 30, 40, 50. 1 FDR-BC, 2 FDR-BC, 1 FDR OC, No family history

The insurer never fully recovers losses, as it is always one step behind: it does not anticipate the fact that customers constantly change insurance purchasing behaviour as a result of pricing decisions

Other pricing strategies are possible: the insurer could anticipate future mortality trends in portfolio

Elastic Demand

Marshall’s Law of Demand: PλQ = Cst λ is the constant elasticity of demand with

respect to price: λ = - (dQ/Q) / (dP/P) We expect “price elasticity” parameters

such that λpositives < λuntested < λnegatives

Elasticity Estimate Robust estimate of elasticity: 0.6579. Age, gender, education, marital status,

income, do not affect elasticity in a significant way.

Health status has little effect on elasticity Modified benefits are calculated based on

price increases due to adverse selection only (not on regular increases due to mortality)

Elasticity of Common Goods Electricity 0.13 Telephone 0.26 Eyeglasses 0.37 Tobacco products 0.46 Term Insurance 0.66 Kitchen appliances 0.67 Shoes 0.91 Shoe repair 1.31 China, tableware 1.54 Restaurant meals 2.27

Other Inputs in Model* Lapse rates: averaging 9% for untested, 2%

for positives, 9.5% for negatives* Annual testing rate: 5%* Annual interest rate: 5%* P(death) for all cases* P(test positive) =

– 0.40 (2 FDR BC)– 0.15 (1 FDR BC)– 0.08 (1 FDR OC)– 0.005 (No Family History)

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

Year

% I

ncr

ease

Annual Increases – 2 FDR BC 30

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

Year

% I

ncr

ease

Cumulative Increases – 2 FDR BC 30

Conclusions

Role of actuary:

In the presence of irreconcilable differences, in an emotional situation, inject figures in the debate to create a more rational discussion

Conclusions

The status quo is an acceptable compromise Insurers could accept a ban on the use of

genetic testing results Adverse selection is likely to be under 10% Insurers need to apply tight underwriting

standards concerning family history, and investigate applications vigorously

Conclusions

Consumers can accept family history The vast majority of applicants (no FH, 1

FDR-BC, 1 SDR) will be accepted at standard rates

A few applicants (1 FDR-OC, 2 FDR) will be accepted with a surcharge

Women testing positive will be accepted

Conclusions

Currently 92% to 96% are accepted at standard rates. A status quo would not change these percentages

Room for negotiation: large policies

These conclusions are only valid for term insurance