recent evolution of the european union’s audiovisual...

30
0 Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policy By Harvey B. Feigenbaum Professor of Political Science and International Affairs The George Washington University Washington DC 20052 [email protected] Prepared for presentation on the panel on Business and Sustainability, International Conference on Public Policy, Grenoble, France, June 26-28, 2013 Introduction When it comes to audiovisual policy and the regulation of the media, the conflict among the EU’s member-states is not so much structural as ideological. The conflicts over regulatory policy reflect the economic policy philosophies that to varying degrees

Upload: hoangtu

Post on 27-Apr-2018

227 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

0

Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policy

By

Harvey B. Feigenbaum

Professor of Political Science and International Affairs

The George Washington University

Washington DC 20052

[email protected]

Prepared for presentation on the panel on Business and Sustainability, International

Conference on Public Policy, Grenoble, France, June 26-28, 2013

Introduction

When it comes to audiovisual policy and the regulation of the media, the conflict

among the EU’s member-states is not so much structural as ideological. The conflicts

over regulatory policy reflect the economic policy philosophies that to varying degrees

Page 2: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

1

divide Europe: neoliberalism versus dirigisme. Despite the frequently repeated and much

lauded convergence of industrial countries’ policies toward the Right—the “Washington

Consensus” and the World Trade Organization are manifestations of this—preferences

among many EU (and OECD) members for an active state persist. Indeed, they have

intensified since the onset of the financial crisis of 2007-2009.

The problem is that the political winds favoring state activism blow more

strongly at the national level than in the supranational stratosphere of Brussels. Moreover,

these winds do not blow everywhere in Europe. Across many policy areas, Britain and

the Netherlands, and the northern countries more generally, have tended to favor a free-

market approach more than other EU members.1 Given that the decision making structure

of the EU still gives pride of place to the preferences of member-state governments,

largely due to the predominate role of the European Council, these northern preferences

are hardly negligible. While the streamlining of the decision-making structure

established by the Lisbon Treaty makes the organization more supranational by

increasing the role of majority voting in the Council, the expansion of the European

Union to include the former communist countries of Eastern Europe, most

overcompensating for their involuntary subjection to Soviet statism, has weighted the

structure toward neoliberalism. With the enthusiasm normally seen among new converts

to a religion, these countries have increasingly lined up with their “Anglo-Saxon” friends.

When their material subsidies are not in question, they join in the defense of markets. In

fact, the new Eastern members of the EU more frequently ally with the neoliberal

countries in the north, than the economically needy countries in the South (Peel, 2008:

1 A high-level US trade negotiator volunteered this to me in an e-mail.

Page 3: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

2

11). However, audiovisual policy involves not only issues of economics and technology,

but also of culture. This adds another layer of complication that often shapes the language

and consequences of the texts (Katz, 2005: 9). At risk is the cultural diversity of Europe.

This has both economic and political consequences.

This paper focuses on audiovisual and film policies precisely because the cultural

aspects of the policy raise the salience and divide opinion. Because countries not only

have different policy styles and philosophies, but also are differentially sensitive to the

cultural aspects of audiovisual and film policies, the degrees of conflict between member

states and the EU vary (Vogel, 1986; Gormley & Peters, 1992).

Audiovisual policies normally involve three kinds of issues: Choosing and

enforcing technical standards, regulating the domestic market, and supervising content

(Feigenbaum, 2002). At the EU level they also involve issues of international trade.

Finally, both audiovisual and film industry policies involve tax incentives and subsidies.

Subsidies always raise red flags, but it is the supervision of content that frequently

divides EU members most deeply and implies consequences for European cultural

diversity.

The Problem

The audiovisual media and film industries are economic behemoths that are

thought to have an impact on culture, and are therefore politically sensitive. The main

problem, as far as the EU has been concerned, is how protect and affirm the cultural

Page 4: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

3

assets of Europe (the dirigistes’ concern), without losing the economic possibilities

afforded by the entertainment industry and now, by new media (the neo-liberals’

concern).

Background

To some extent the differences between the two sides of the debate are defined by

their emphasis on either the cultural or the artistic aspects of audiovisual media. This is,

in historical terms, a somewhat recent debate. Although the impact of the film and

audiovisual industries may be cultural, the early film industry was commercial from its

inception. Europe and America traded intensely and competed vigorously from the end of

the 19th

century onward. The French film giants, Pathé and Gaumont, had initially been

part of the Edison Trust. They had had active branches in the US from the earliest days of

the industry. Before World War I the US imported more films from Europe than it

exported. After the First World War many of the indigenous European film industries

came into their own. The German industry had been founded in response to the

communication and propaganda needs of the military High Command before the Great

War. The new industry, with its Neubabelsburg studio complex, both competed with

Hollywood, and attracted the investment of major Hollywood studios (de Grazia, 2005).

Mussolini created the extensive Cinecittà film-making center outside of Rome; and the

French competed from the Eighth Arrondissement of Paris and eventually from studios in

Boulogne Billancourt and Saint Denis. The British had their own industry, the famous

names of Ealing, Pinewood and Shepperton come to mind, as did most of the countries of

Europe. This vibrant European growth was initially abetted by the advent of sound,

Page 5: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

4

which, at least briefly, served as a barrier to importation of foreign films. However, the

cumulative effect of the two world wars and the business acumen of Hollywood

eventually established the US as the hegemon of film (Izod, 1988; Feigenbaum, 2007).

American films were lavishly produced, opulently marketed and efficiently

distributed to markets around the world. In most countries, people preferred to watch

Hollywood films to local ones (Feigenbaum, 2007: 382-3). To some extent the

relationship between Hollywood and the world was reciprocal: world markets demanded

Hollywood films, and Hollywood films, as production costs rose, eventually needed

world markets to break even.

Graph 1 shows the top twenty producers of feature films as of 2009, but it is a bit

deceptive. Almost all of these countries produce for local consumption, though

Bollywood (i.e., not all Indian films) are significantly exported, primarily to diaspora

communities, and Nollywood (Nigeria) films, mostly videos, are popular within Africa.

Graph 1

TOP 20 PRODUCERS OF FEATURE FILMS, 2005-2009

Page 6: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

5

Total numner of films produced

India

Nigeria

United States*

China

Japan

Russia

France

Germany

Spain

Rep. Korea

Italy

United Kingdom

Indonesia

Brazil

Canada

Philippines

Switzerland

China, Hong Kong SAR

Turkey

Mexico

1,400

1,200

1,000

800

600

400

200

0

Source: UNESCO Institute for Statistics: From International Blockbuster to

National Hits, http://www.uis.unesco.org/culture/Documents/ib8-analysis-cinema-

production-2012-en2.pdf, p. 10, taken 14 March 2013

Though the data is somewhat older, Table 1 provides a useful comparison of the

relative levels of production costs in the different regions. The figure for US productions

is understated because the data include the costs of many low budget independent films

and made-for-television films.

Table 1

Page 7: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

6

Production Scale of Film in Selected Countries (1997)

Unit: Million Euro

The number of

production Total production costs

Production costs per

film

Germany 61 305 5.0

France 163 795 4.9

UK 115 969 8.4

US 673 8,662 12.9

Mexico 9 11 1.2

Argentina 32 48 1.5

Brazil 30 64 2.1

Egypt 55 35 0.6

Japan 278 914 3.3

India 697 300 0.4

China 88 47 0.5

Hong Kong 94 54 0.6

Philippines 210 30 0.1

Singapore 7 2 0.3

Korea 162 44 0.3

Taiwan 27 17 0.6

Australia 34 86 2.5

Data: European Audiovisual Observatory, UNESCO

Reproduced with permission from Byung-il Choi, “Culture as Trade Concern”, International

Studies Review, (December 2002), p. 6.

Graph 2 illustrates the trend in terms of numbers of movies.

Page 8: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

7

Graph 2

Film Production Trends in Major Regions (1980∼1999)

762

677661673713697

477

356

222

594600555560569

443

249278278289

239

319

320

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

80 85 90 95 96 97 98 99 00

US

EU-15

JP

Data: European Commission, Statistics on audiovisual services Data 1980-1999, 2001.

Reproduced with permission from Choi, p. 5.

In Graph 2 the line indicating “EU” films produced is somewhat deceiving. This

is not only because the category includes only those movies produced before the EU

enlarged to most of Eastern Europe, but especially because films produced in Europe

were rarely exported beyond their country of origin. In fact, one of the major issues for

European countries is that local films often have trouble finding distribution even within

the country of origin.

Part of the reason for rising production costs in the US was that Hollywood

studios saw lavish productions as a method to compete with television. Faced with the

widespread purchase of televisions after the Second World War, studios, which were

shorn of their theatrical profit centers by the Supreme Court’s Paramount decision in

1948 (U.S. v. Paramount, 1948), sought to use lavish decors and foreign locales as

Page 9: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

8

method of attracting audiences away from the free entertainment offered by the electronic

box in the living room (Hozic, 2001; Izod).

While this strategy was entirely created in response to the needs of the domestic

American market, the effect was to produce films that not only filled a gap in Europe left

by the wartime hiatus, but ended up with a product that Europeans had not the resources

to match. As a result, US films dominated world film markets everywhere they were

allowed to be shown(Table 2). Only in France, which enforces a quota in its cinemas, do

US films occasionally occupy less than 50% of the market. This is illustrated by Table 3

Table 2

Film Production: The European (EU) Market

feature-length

films1

adm.2

(millions) European film share

(%)4

US film share (%)

1991 471 605 17 73

1992 489 587 17 73

1993 504 666 15 75

1994 444 677 n.d. 74

1995 443 664 n.d. 72

1996 569 709 25 71

1997 560 765 32 66

1998 555 828 22 78

1999 603 810 29 69

Page 10: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

9

2000 602 844 23 73

2001 627 935 32 65

2002 644 938 28 70

2003 672 890 26 71

2004 3 770 1,006 30 67

2005 815 894 38 60

2006 883 926 33 64

2007 5 806 920 35 63

2008 849 925 33 66

2009 893 980 31 67

2 Estimates.

3 From 2004, Europe of 25.

5 From 2007, Europe of 27.

Updated on the 15/05/11.

Source: Conseil National du Cinema

Table 3

Film Receipts: The French Market

Market share in receipt (%)

French films

American films European films1 other films Total

1980 47.9 36.8 11.7 3.6 100.0

1981 50.7 31.3 14.9 3.2 100.0

1982 53.8 30.6 9.6 5.9 100.0

1983 47.1 35.4 10.7 6.8 100.0

1984 49.7 37.4 10.5 2.4 100.0

1985 44.9 39.4 11.7 3.9 100.0

Page 11: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

10

1986 44.4 43.0 10.6 2.1 100.0

1987 36.2 43.7 12.0 8.1 100.0

1988 39.6 45.7 10.7 4.0 100.0

1989 33.8 56.6 7.8 1.9 100.0

1990 37.4 56.6 5.3 0.7 100.0

1991 30.1 58.7 9.9 1.3 100.0

1992 35.1 58.3 4.3 2.3 100.0

1993 34.8 57.6 4.1 3.4 100.0

1994 28.3 61.3 8.6 1.9 100.0

1995 35.2 54.0 8.4 2.4 100.0

1996 37.3 54.7 6.0 2.0 100.0

1997 34.6 52.4 10.2 2.9 100.0

1998 27.4 63.8 7.7 1.1 100.0

1999 32.5 54.4 11.1 1.9 100.0

2000 28.1 63.2 6.1 2.6 100.0

2001 41.4 46.6 7.5 4.4 100.0

2002 34.6 50.2 8.4 6.8 100.0

2003 34.6 52.9 5.3 7.3 100.0

2004 38.4 48.3 9.4 3.9 100.0

2005 36.3 46.5 15.5 1.6 100.0

2006 44.6 44.7 8.8 1.9 100.0

2007 36.1 50.2 12.1 1.7 100.0

2008 45.2 44.0 9.1 1.7 100.0

2009 35.5 51.6 9.6 3.3 100.0

2010 33.8 49.9 14.7 1.6 100.0 1 Europe in the continental sense: from the Atlantic Ocean to Ural, except France .

Updated on the 15/05/2011. Source: Conseil National du Cinema

The story for television is a bit different. Audiovisual imports have been a source

of concern for many of the EU member states, but it is worth noting that American

dominance of television export markets was not entirely the same as its dominance of

feature films. The factor here is the proliferation of television channels beginning in the

1980s had been made possible by new technologies such as cable and satellite

(Feigenbaum, 2003). Digital technology greatly increased the number of TV channels

available and crucially, most were financed by advertising (Feigenbaum, 2011). With the

rapid increase in the number of channels France for instance went from three public

channels to over 90 in the period from 1980 to 2000. From 2000 to the present the

number of choices have grown exponentially, and there are now 956 channels (MAVIS

Page 12: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

11

2013).2

This limited revenues to broadcasters and the latter were forced to fill their

schedules with cheap American reruns. Other countries experienced similar growth and

were confronted by the same incentives. Because American television shows are

amortized over not only the huge domestic market, but also on secondary (re-run) and

international markets, unit costs of American shows are much lower than locally

produced European programming. American shows run from one-fourth to one-tenth the

cost of broadcasting a European show (Feigenbaum, 1996). Thus, the paradoxical result

was that the proliferation of channels led to the domination of European markets by

American shows that Europeans actually did not want to see (International Herald

Tribune, 2005).3 Programmers would accept a reduction in Nielson scores (a measure of

audience size) because American shows were so cheap that the cost savings made up for

the fact that American shows were less popular. This led to American dominance of EU-

US television trade. See Graph 2.

Consequences of American Market Penetration

The issues involved are not merely economic. It is true that Hollywood has

become increasingly dependent on international sales. Costs of production continue to

rise and significant revenue streams have been lost. Theatrical distribution is affected by

2

http://mavise.obs.coe.int/channel?event=listing&query_clauses={%22target_coun

try_id%22:%221%22,%22other_target_country_id%22:true}, taken February 15, 2013. 3 In a comparison of the most watched television shows in Australia, France, Italy, Sweden and the

United States, only in Australia was the most watched show an import. Curiously, once Australia is

excluded only France had an American production in the top ten: the movie Star Wars (International

Herald Tribune, 2005).

Page 13: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

12

the business cycle in ways that it had not been in earlier downturns. This is because

technology has created so many alternatives to the traditional movie theater that they are

no longer recession-proof in the way they were in earlier downturns. Similarly, the

decline of DVD sales which had in earlier times accounted for as much as 80% of gross

revenues (Epstein 2010), dropped off precipitously. However, even today, though

significantly threatened by piracy, DVDs represent the largest revenue stream ($16

billion in 2009)4 Thus, American film and television producers are keenly interested in

the European market, where piracy is less important and where theatrical and home-

entertainment distribution are crucial to defraying production costs.

The cultural consequences are supported mostly by anecdotal evidence, but they

are no less real. The problem is that there are only 24 hours in a day. To the extent that

Europeans are showing American programming on television, to the extent that

Europeans are going to American movies in their leisure time, American programming

and entertainment is replacing European programming and entertainment. Gradually

people begin to think in terms of American cultural references, rather than national or

European cultural references. There is already significant evidence that this is occurring

(Kuisel, 2003). Examples abound .The accused in French courts address the magistrate as

“vôtre honneur” rather than the appropriate term, “monsieur le juge,” having learned the

former from American cop shows. German law student query their professors as to why

they aren't learning to address juries, not realizing that the German legal system does not

have juries. Similarly, British colleagues have been referring to the categories of the

4 Epstein, http://www.edwardjayepstein.com/Quivering.htm, Taken March 24, 2013.

Page 14: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

13

political spectrum as running from “liberal” to “conservative,” (King) even though these

terms have very different meaning in Europe, and do not capture the differences between

socialist, communist, reactionary and fascist, options not present on the American

spectrum, and thus not present in American popular culture. As American images replace

local ones, political reference points gradually change. The cultural landscape not only

cedes to American commercial logos, but more importantly, to American political

categories. It is not only national identities which erode, but people’s perceptions of the

complex and nuanced world around them. Europeans are losing contact with their

heritage and have begun to accept a kind of politics more aligned with US traditions than

their own.

EU Policies: From TWF to AVMS

European countries have sought to meet the cultural challenge at the supranational level,

as well as the national and local levels. The most famous EU audiovisual policy is that

which derived from the directive “Television without Frontiers” (TWF) (EEC, 1989; EC

1997). This directive requires member countries to preserve, “where practicable”, at least

51% of prime time television viewing for European programming (10% from

independent European production companies). While countries have seen the phrase

“where practicable” as a loophole in the EU directive, even the highly neo-liberal British

have tended to observe the quotas (see Table 4). Other member countries of the

European Union are more stringent. Paris preserves for European products 60% of

fictional shows (news, sports and games do not count toward the quota), with quota of

40% of prime time reserved for French products. Eventually, the Directive came up for

Page 15: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

14

renewal and amendment as the Audio Video Media Services Directive, with the ambit of

the directive expanded to include “new media”, especially those that are internet and

satellite based (EC, 2007). There is, in this sector, a long established habit of labeling

media offerings as “services” so as to avoid the application of the GATT (now WTO)

agreements, though not without controversy. From its inception, the GATT (General

Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) had a special dispensation for “cinematographic films”,

though Americans and Europeans disagreed as to whether this covered television (Choi,

2002: 12). These media services as considered by the AVMS directive are meant to

extend the jurisdiction of EU regulation (and regulatory philosophy!) beyond

broadcasting, to include video-on-demand and broadband services (European

Commission, “AVMD – What’s New”, 2008). The language of the AVMS is careful to

note that audiovisual and media servides are both “economic” and “cultural”.

It was in the area of new media that the neo-liberal and dirigiste countries fought

it out. As everything does in the EU, the solution was a compromise. As both satellites

and internet have footprints larger than national borders, the question focused on how

content originating in one country would be treated in another country that might have

more restrictive content regulations. The solution was to adopt the “country of origin”

principle .This means that media providers must adhere to the restrictions of the country

in which they are located, while satellite broadcasters must adhere to the standards of

those countries where there is a satellite up-link (European Commission, 2008). Roughly

this means that, for example, British-based BSKY B, which provides Europeans with

professional sports, mind-numbing American entertainment, and a collection of

Page 16: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

15

cosmopolitan pornography, need not worry about French local content rules. Not

coincidentally, the British fought hard to include this principle, the French fought against

it.

Graph 3

Graph 3: Estimates of the trade of audiovisual programs between European Union and North

America (1988-2000) - USD Millions

Page 17: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

16

Source: Andre Lange, “Press Release: The Imbalance of Trade in Films and Televison

Shows Continues to Deteriorate”, European Audio Visual Observatory, Strasbourg, 9

April 2002, http://www.obs.coe.int/about/oea/pr/desequilibre.html, taken 6 May 2008.

Graph 4 helps us understand the strong support for the Television Without

Frontiers Directives. Graph 3 indicates at first glance that the Directives were not terribly

effective. Table 4, however, clarifies this a bit in that it shows the TWF Directives did

allow countries to reduce American programming in prime time, if they so desired. Here

we find that reduction in American programming approximates the liberal versus

“dirigiste” preferences dividing EU member states.

Page 18: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

17

Graph 4

Imported American, European and other programming broadcast on TV channels

in Western Europe (1997-2001) As a percentage of total hours broadcast

Source: Andre Lange and Susan Newman, EUROPEAN AUDIOVISUAL OBSERVATORY,

Strasbourg, FranceYearbook 2002 - Film, Television, Video and Multimedia in Europe, 2002

Edition,

Vol. 5, "Television Channels - Programme Production and Distribution", pp.128, Press Release of 28

Janurary 2003; http://www.obs.coe.int/about/oea/pr/a02vol5.html, taken 6 May 2008.

Page 19: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

18

Table 4

Geographical Origin of TV Fiction Programmed by Major Networks (Sample Week 12-18 March

2000)

Domestic US European Other

United

Kingdom

Whole day 47% 43% 0% 10%

Prime Time

only 51% 49% 0% 0%

Germany Whole day 36% 57% 5% 2%

Prime Time

only 56% 44% 0% 0%

France Whole day 25% 56% 15% 5%

Prime Time

only 75% 25% 0% 0%

Italy Whole day 19% 64% 4% 13%

Prime Time

only 43% 51% 6% 0%

Spain Whole day 20% 56% 7% 17%

Prime Time

only 51% 37% 12% 0%

Source: Eurofiction, Press Release, European Cultural Observatory, 9 October 2001

http://www.obs.coe.int/about/oea/pr/pr_eurofiction_bis.html, taken 6 May 2008.

Page 20: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

19

What these data suggest, despite the arguments of the neo-liberals, is that the

protectionism put in place by the TWF Directives essentially was effective in those

countries that were interested in applying them.

Subsidies

If the main tool for protecting the European cultural space has been television

quotas, the EU strategy in the film market has been to provide subsidies. In the area of

film subsidies the role of the EU is, for the most part, a supplement to national subsidy

programs. Primarily, the EU subsidizes film by way of its MEDIA Plus and MEDIA

2007 programs, with the latest five year program authorized to spend about half a billion

euros (European Commission, “Media”, 2006). While this sounds like a lot of money, it

takes only a little reflection to realize this is less than the equivalent of one Hollywood

movie a year. However, the MEDIA programs are intelligently targeted, focusing on

important aspects of the audiovisual business as training, distribution and marketing

(European Council, 2000).5

Opposition to MEDIA, MEDIA Plus and MEDIA 2007, and the successor

MEDIA programs, has been limited. The neo-liberals are not so much outnumbered as

ignored As Shaun Woodward, UK creative industries minister under the last Labour

5

The European Union also offers a number of subsidy programs aimed at gearing up for digital

entertainmentt: digital content, digital television and radio aids, and retooling for the 16:9 screen ratio for

new, high definition, televisions.

Page 21: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

20

government complained: “We have a real battle to persuade our partners in the rest of

Europe that we are right (Tryhorn, 2006).” . For most of Britain’s neo-liberal allies, the

issue may not have been so much a disagreement with Britain on substance as on

strategy: cultural policy and film are not the places to make a stand.6 While English

hand-wringing is not uncommon when it comes to the EU, the lack of controversy among

member states is probably easy to understand, the subsidies accorded through the

MEDIA programs are simply too modest to attract the usual critics who worry about

layered bureaucracy, milk lakes and butter mountains.

However, the main non-budgetary constraint for the Commission is still

ideological. While member states are divided about the proper role for state intervention,

the professional economists of the Commission normally are not. Unsurprisingly, the

chief allies of the neo-liberals are the economists working in Berlaymont. As one analyst

put it, “the Commission seems to apply a model of classical economic analysis to the

audiovisual sector, which ignores, to some extent, the problematic of culture and artistic

expression (Herald, 2004: 11).” This attitude did not change with the newer iterations of

media policies after 2007.

In the course of my interviews in Brussels for this study, the main problem in the

film market, from the point of the view of the Commission, was the

compartmentalization of the film market. That is, the main problem from their

perspective was the fact that EU members’ films are not shown in each others’ markets.

Thus for them the problems of the industry could be solved by completion of the single

6 This was the opinion expressed to me in an e mail, of a USTR negotiator in the audiovisual issue

area.

Page 22: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

21

market for film. The professional economists of the Commission seem unaffected by the

looming presence of the American cultural juggernaut.

Subsidiarity

Audiovisual and film policies are, of course, part of the broader remit of the EU in

the area of culture. Justification for cultural policy at the supranational is found in Article

128 of the Treaty of Rome (later modified as Article 151 in the Treaty of Amsterdam),

This article authorizes the EU to contribute to the “flowering of the cultures of the

Member States.” It is to facilitate cooperation and supplement cultural policies of these

states. As such it has been deemed a “model application of subsidiarity”(Statement by EU

Council official Alan Forest in Sharp, 2006: 16).

Derived historically from the body of Catholic social thought, the principle

maintains that policy-making should be as local as possible. In the general field of

cultural policy this has had many manifestations, and illustrated not least by programs

such as the “European City of Culture.” (established in 1985) which was transformed into

the “European Capital of Culture” program in 1999 (In 2013 the capitals are Marseilles

and Kosice). This is essentially a direct EU subsidy to European cities, which then use

the money to promote cultural activities.

Subsidiarity is especially in evidence in policies focusing on the film industry. In

the area of film production, much of the local subsidies are products of national tax

policies. Most countries, in and out of the EU, have set in place a series of tax

advantages for film-makers. The reason is not hard to understand: film production is not

Page 23: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

22

only glamorous, but it creates highly paid jobs with few “negative externalities”. That is,

the film industry is wealthy, facilitates the development of human capital and is non-

polluting. Many governments have put in place a series of tax credits, rebates and other

incentives to attract film producers. Britain and Germany have been especially active in

this area and have achieved dramatic results. However, the problem with these policies is

that they have most frequently gone to foreign producers. While the amounts vary from

year to year, Europeans have been less successful than Americans in taking advantage. In

one typical year eighty percent of German film industry tax breaks accrued to Hollywood

firms (O’Brian, 2004).

Such tax expenditures may nevertheless be helpful even if it is a Hollywood

movie being shot in Europe. This is because location shooting of even Hollywood films

maintains the demand for “below the line”7 talent. Their skills remain available for local

production when the Hollywood company leaves. Moreover, European states compete

with American and Australian states to offer tax breaks. However, so far this does not

seem to be a neo-liberal “race to the bottom.” In fact there is something of a dirigiste

element to the competition as New Mexico, Lousiana and Queensland have all built

soundstages with public funds to attract film companies.8 This area of public policy is

oddly reminiscent of the 1989 movie Field of Dreams: “Build it and they will come!

(IMDB, 2009)”

7 Stars, writers, the director and producers, are “above the line” talent. Everyone else involved in

film production is “below the line”.

8 This is a helpful reminder that while the “Anglo-Saxon” countries are considered to be “neo-

liberal”, state or provinicial governments in the US, Australia, and Canada, are often highly interventionist.

For an historical view, see Schonefield (1965).

Page 24: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

23

Audiovisual policy, however, offers a paradox. In many ways television markets,

if not film markets, are local affairs. In the United States television programming is

organized by “media markets,” some of which are very large (New York, Los Angeles),

while most are quite small (Roanoke, nestled in the Shenandoah Valley of Virginia, is an

example). Programming often varies considerably from market to market. (By contrast

the Motion Picture Association of America considers the US and Canada a single film

market, as is Europe and the Middle East). Similarly, in Germany the Bundeslaender are

crucial to the organization of public television. In Italy there are a profusion of local

channels. The paradox comes in because while television markets are local, television

ownership is multinational. Multinational communications firms that own media

broadcasters are becoming larger, while markets are becoming more concentrated

(McChesney, 1999; Baker, 2007).9 Thus the notion that television markets are local is

something of a mirage. The mix of cultural services (television programs, films) might

vary locally, but, excepting public television, control of production and distribution is

located at the supranational level.

The Consequences of Neoliberal Policy

As I have mentioned, the member states of the EU are conflicted about what to do

about culture. For the champions of quotas and subsidies, the problem is the erosion of

not only national identities, but of a supranational identity, as well. Along with

European integration there has been a self-conscious effort by the EU to construct a

9 There is some controversy on this point, as critics of this position focus on competition from new

media presenting a counterbalance to this concentration.

Page 25: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

24

European identity (Checkel, 2001; Bennhold, 2005). This new and barely formed

identity is equally at risk.

Moreover, changes in identity affect changes in economic behavior. George

Akerlof and Rachel Kranton have argued that group processes which alter identities, also

affect the utility calculations of individuals (2010: 23-4 and passim.) I believe that group

processes also affect innovation. Cultural diversity is a collective good and anecdotal

evidence suggests that it is a source of economic innovation. When we travel, we

constantly compare our discoveries abroad with what we know at home. The encounter of

different cultures can stimulate us to thinking in new ways. I think examples of the

benefits of exposure to cultural differences abound. One example is Starbucks: a US

entrepreneur married a small chain of coffee shops named for a character in American

literature to Italian coffee culture, and launched what became a $5 billion enterprise

(Vendriger, 2009). In the 1960s the US Postmaster General visited Europe and decided to

adopt the what became the “zip code”, a hybrid style of European mail systems, which

greatly improved the efficiency of mail delivery. Today, in response to Facebook,

German and French entrepreneurs have started social networking sites in their respective

languages, which quite become very profitable (Plamer, 2008).

While it may be argued that none of these innovations would have been possible

had there not been an interchange between regions, it should be noticed that the very

Page 26: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

25

success of these innovations also undermines culture diversity. One need only walk into a

Starbucks in Paris or Rome to document this trend. Success leads to proliferation and

imitation. Cultural diversity, it seems, creates the conditions of its own destruction.

Conclusion

The European Union was founded by men who were born in the 19th

century. In

writing the Treaty of Rome, they were looking to solve what had been the pressing

problems of the inter-war period: poisonous nationalism and its consequent economic

manifestation, protectionism. Like Jean Monnet and others, they were repelled by a

vision that these pathologies might recur. Positively, however, they were inspired by

what they perceived to be the continental success of the United States. Their goal was to

push the Old Continent toward the American model.

While not all were federalists, the European founding fathers were convinced that

America’s success lay in its huge, domestic market. It was this market that allowed firms

to grow and to learn techniques that would serve them in the coming global competition

(Chander, 1977). Most importantly, it was the model based on mass production. This

was the manufacturing paradigm of Henry Ford that these men assumed would be

Europe’s destiny (Piore & Sable, 1984; Boyer, 1990).

However, by the time the Single Market was constructed in Europe, Fordism had

run its course in the US and had been replaced by a model dominated by services.

Europe’s decaying manufacturing base seems to be on borrowed time. The sages of

Brussels, like sages elsewhere, look to high technology services as a major part of the

solution to obsolete manufacturing. But does an economy based on services react the

Page 27: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

26

same way as one based on manufacturing? Do the bracing winds of competition fan the

flames of productivity, or merely extinguish potential innovations?

Audiovisual services are not only high tech, they have an influence well beyond

the economy. Such services may not be encouraged by using models derived from the era

of smoke-stack industries. The hot-house for orchids may be a better metaphor for the

needs of the new economy, rather than the automobile assembly line. Oddly, the success

of the EU’s liberalism may undermine its future. Policies that work in one economic

environment may be detrimental in another.

Neo-liberals and dirigistes each see the other as obsolete and out-moded. In times

when the whole European experiment seems at risk, a reevaluation of that project seems

in the cards. While cultural issues have normally inhabited the periphery, the implications

for innovation and rebirth should not be ignored. By preserving the past, one preserves

the future.

Works Cited

Akerlof, George A. and Rachel E. Kranton (2010), Identity Economics, Princeton: Princeton University Press

Baker, C. Edwin (2007). Media Concentration and Democracy: Why Ownership Matters Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

Balassa, Carol. (2008). “America’s Image Abroad: The UNESCO Cultural Diversity Convention and U.S. Motion Picture Exports,” Report, Curb Center for Art, Enterprise and Public Policy, Nashville: Vanderbilt University.

Bennhold, Katrin. (2005, April 26). “Quietly Sprouting: A European Identity,”, International Herald Tribune (Paris). [Online]. Available HTTP:

www.iht.com/articles/2005/04/26/news/enlarge2.php

Boyer, Robert. (1990). The Regulation School (Craig Charney, Trans.). New York:

Columbia University Press.

Chandler, Alfred D., Jr. (1977). The Visible Hand. Cambridge, Mass. and London,

England: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

Checkel, Jeffrey T. (2001). “Why Comply? Social Learning and European Identity

Change”, International Organization, 55:3, 553-588.

Page 28: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

27

Choi, Byung-il. (2002). “Culture as Trade Concern”, International Studies Review 4:3.

de Grazia, Victoria. (2005). Irresistible Empire. Cambridge MA: Belknap Harvard University Press.

Dinmore, Guy. (2008, April 16). “Berlusconi pledges speedy reform”, Financial Times. p. 3.

Epstein, Edward Jay, (2010) The Hollywood Economist. New York: Random

House

Eurofiction (2001). “Press Release, 9 October 2001.” European Cultural

Observatory. [Online]. Available HTTP:

www.obs.coe.int/about/oea/pr/pr_eurofiction_bis.html

European Commission. (2006, March 3). “European Commission > Media.” [Online]. Available HTTP: ec.europa.eu/information_society/media/index_en.htm

European Commission. (2008, April 30). “AVMD – What’s New.” [Online]. Available HTTP: ec.europa.eu/avpolicy/reg/avms/index_en.htm

European Council. (2000, December 9). Council decision of 22 December 2000. [Online]. Available HTTP: europa.eu.int/comm/avpolicy/mediapro/digprog_en.pdf

European Economic Community. (1989). Council Directive of 3 October 1989 on the coordination of certain provisions laid down by law, regulation or administrative action in Member States concerning the pursuit of television broadcasting activities “Television Without Frontiers”, 89/552/EEC.

European Parliament, Council (1997). Directive 97/36/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 30 June 1997 amending Council Directive 89/552/EEC on the coordination of certain provisions laid down by law, regulation or administrative action in Member States concerning the pursuit of television broadcasting activities, 97/36/EC.

European Parliament, Council (2007). Directive 2007/65/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 11 December 2007 amending Council Directive 89/552/EEC on the coordination of certain provisions laid down by law, regulation or administrative action in Member States concerning the pursuit of television broadcasting activities, “Audiovisual Media Services Directive,” 2007/65/EC.

Feigenbaum, Harvey B. (2002). “Public Policy and the Private Sector in Audiovisual Industries,” UCLA Law Review, 49:6, pp. 1767-1781.

Feigenbaum, Harvey B. (2003, March). “Digital Technology Jumps the Border,” Scientific American, pp. 54-59.

Feigenbaum, Harvey B. (2007). “Hegemony or Diversity in Film and Television? The US, Europe and Japan”, Pacific Review, 20:3, 371-396.

Feigenbaum, Harvey B. (2009). “The Paradox of Television Privatization: When More is Less,” Policy and Society.

Page 29: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

28

Feigenbaum, Harvey B.(1996) “Why Hollywood is Like Japan, Only Better,” Business in the Contemporary World, 81: 1. pp. 36-42.

Gormley, Jr, William T. , and B. Guy Peters, (1992). “ National Styles of Regulation: Child

Care in Three Countries,” Entomologia Experimentalis et Applicata, 25:4, 381-399.

Herald, Anna. (2004). “EU Film Policy: Between Art and Commerce,” European Diversity

and Autonomy Papers-EDAP, 3. [Online]. Available HTTP: eurac.edu/edap

Hooghe, Liesbet, and Gary Marks (2008). “European Union?”, West European Politics, 31: 1&2, 108-129.

Hozic, Aida (2001). Hollyworld, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

IMDB. (2009, March 4). “Field of Dreams.” [Online]. Available HTTP:

www.imdb.com/title/tt0097351/

International Herald Tribune (2005, May 23) “Television: Most-watched Programs.” (2005, May 23). International Herald Tribune. 10.

Izod, John. (1988). Hollywood at the Box Office: 1895-1986. New York: Columbia University Press.

Katz, Yaron. (2005). Media Policy for the 21st Century in the United States and Europe. Cresskill NJ: Hampton Press.

Kuisel, Richard. (2003). "Debating Americanization: The Case of France." In Beck, Ulrich, Natan Szaider, and Rainer Winter (Eds.). Global America? The Cultural Consequences of Globalization. Liverpool, UK: Liverpool University Press.

Lange, Andre and Susan Newman (2003). “Press Release of 28 Janurary 2003.” [Online]

Available HTTP: www.obs.coe.int/about/oea/pr/a02vol5.html

Lange, Andre and Susan Newman. (2002). “ Vol. 5 – Television Channels – Programme Production and Distribution,” in Yearbook 2002 - Film, Television, Video and Multimedia in Europe. EUROPEAN AUDIOVISUAL OBSERVATORY, Strasbourg, France

Lange, Andre. (2002, April 9). “Press Release: The Imbalance of Trade in Films and Televison Shows Continues to Deteriorate”, European Audio Visual Observatory.

[Online]. Available HTTP: www.obs.coe.int/about/oea/pr/desequilibre.html

McChesney, Robert W. Rich Media, Poor Democracy. Champaign-Urbana: University of Illinois Press.

Mediasalles. (2007). “European Cinema Yearbook, 2007.” [Online]. Available HTTP:

www.mediasalles.it/ybk07fin//

O’Brian, Kevin J. (2004, December 13). “German Tax Break May not Make Cut,” International Herald Tribune.

Peel, Quentin. (2008, May 1). “A Profitable Union”, Financial Times. p. 11.

Piore, Michael J. and Charles F. Sable. (1984). The Second Industrial Divide. New York: Basic Books.

Page 30: Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual Policyarchives.ippapublicpolicy.org/IMG/pdf/panel_60_s1_feigenbaum.pdf · Recent Evolution of The European Union’s Audiovisual

29

Plamer, Maija. (2008, May 6). “Europe finds its voice online,” Financial Times, p. 12.

Schonefield, Andrew (1965). Modern Capitalism, New York: Oxford University Press.

Sharp, Cris. (2006). “’In Uno Plures’? EU Cultural Policy and the Governance of Europe,” Cultural Analysis, 5, 7-26.

Tryhorn, Chris (2006, June 29). “Minister attacks EU media plans”, Guardian Unlimited. [Online]. Available HTTP:

www.guardian.co.uk/international/story/0,,1808894,00.html

U.S. v. Paramount , 334 US 131 (Supreme Court 1948).

Vendriger, Yonatan (2009 March 4). “Starbucks: History and Timeline.” [Online]. Available HTTP: pages.emerson.edu/Courses/Fall03/IN115A/Assignments_In/midterm/vendriger/coffee_culture/page7.html

Vogel, David. (1986). National Styles of Regulation: Environmental Policy in Great Britain and the United States. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.