raine the new

Upload: g-gordon-liddy

Post on 01-Jun-2018

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/9/2019 Raine the New

    1/7

    The new entropy law and the economic process

    Alan Raine *, John Foster, Jason Potts

    School of Economics, University of Queensland, Brisbane 4072, Australia

    1. Introduction

    It is now commonplace among modern evolutionary econo-

    mists to argue that the evolution of economic systems is a

    process of increasing structural complexity driven by the

    production of new knowledge. But much debate remains about

    how and why this might be. For a long time, the microfounda-

    tions of this approach have been soughtby way of analogy with

    biological evolution (Nelson and Winter, 1982; Hodgson, 1993).

    However, despite the intuitive neo-Darwinian appeal of that

    approach, it remains problematic, and without going into

    exactly why, it is fair to say that the appropriate foundations of

    the theory of economic evolution remains an open question.

    Many years ago, NicolasGeorgescu-Roegen (1971)argued

    that the entropy lawwas the ultimate foundation of dynamic

    economic analysis. In this paper, we continue along this line

    to argue that the evolution of economic systems is intimately

    connected to the second law of thermodynamics. However,

    the central point we shall make is that the meaning of the

    entropy law itself has not remained static, and that changes

    in the concept of the entropy law imply changes in the

    meaning of economic analysis in general, but especially in

    evolutionary economic analysis. In fact, the application of a

    reformulated second law presents an alternative interpreta-

    tion without reference to the problematic concept of entropy

    altogether.

    e c o l o g i c a l c o m p l e x i t y 3 ( 2 0 0 6 ) 3 5 4 3 6 0

    a r t i c l e i n f o

    Published on line 8 March 2007

    Keywords:

    Thermodynamics

    Evolution

    Self-organization

    Complexity

    Knowledge

    Economic development

    a b s t r a c t

    We argue that a reformulated second law of thermodynamics recently employed by

    Schneider and Kay [Schneider, E., Kay, J., 1994. Life as a manifestation of the second law

    of thermodynamics. Math. Comput. Model. 19, 2548] to conceptualize the relation between

    evolution, complexity and ecosystems can also be applied to economic systems. Utilizing

    thermoeconomic principles, this enables us to formalize the concept of economic evolution

    as the development of structural complexity to harness available energy from the environ-

    ment to avert degradation gradients. We conclude, speculatively, that as much as life is an

    inevitable consequence of the reformulated entropy law [Kauffman, S., 1993. The Origins of

    Order: Self Organization and Selection in Evolution. University of Oxford Press, New York;

    Schneider, E., Kay, J., 1994. Life as a manifestation of the second law of thermodynamics.

    Math. Comput. Model. 19, 2548], then this is also true of market economies for the same

    equilibrium seeking reasons. Market economies have experimentally proven themselves,

    more than any other known institutional arrangements, to abet the production of new

    knowledge and structural complexity, and therefore energy degradation. As a direct exten-

    sion of the Schneider and Kay hypothesis, market economies are evolutionary stable

    because of their efficacy in growing knowledge and increasing structural complexity; a

    consequence, we argue, that follows from thereformulated second lawof thermodynamics.

    The enormous energy transformations typical of market economies, consequent on their

    ability to induce and harness new transformations, are ultimately the reason they are

    selected.

    # 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    * Corresponding author. Tel.: +61 7 3365 6246; fax: +61 7 3365 7299.E-mail addresses:[email protected](A. Raine),[email protected](J. Foster),[email protected](J. Potts).

    a v a i l a b l e a t w w w . s c i e n c e d i r e c t . c o m

    j o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : h t t p : / / w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a t e / e c o c o m

    1476-945X/$ see front matter # 2007 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.ecocom.2007.02.009

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecocom.2007.02.009http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecocom.2007.02.009mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/9/2019 Raine the New

    2/7

    The Entropy Law and theEconomic Process (Georgescu-Roegen,

    1971) began this mode of analysis by building upon classical

    conceptions of the entropy law as applied to economic

    analysis. To this day, this approach underpins aspects of

    both evolutionary economics and ecological economics. While

    the concept of entropy may be well suited to applications in

    systems close to thermodynamic equilibrium, a more quali-

    tative approach is required to analyze long-run developmentin those systems far from thermodynamic equilibrium (FFE).

    Georgescu-Roegen (1971, 294/307) utilized Schumpeters dis-

    tinction between growth and development, and Lotkas endo-

    and exo-somatic instruments, to suggest that evolutionary

    developments in FFE economic systems might also be

    considered as qualitative processes of structural change.

    The notion that economic systems are dissipative struc-

    tures has been extended through the addition of the

    autocatalytics of self-organization (Foster, 1997; Witt, 1997).

    The process of self-organization was first clearly elucidated by

    Prigogine (1978) for chemical systems, by Haken (1978) for

    lasers, and then extended to biological systems byBrooks and

    Wiley(1986). Like these approaches, Foster andWitt argue thatself-organization is also the fundamental process at work in

    complex economic systems far from thermodynamic equili-

    brium.

    In the biological context, self-organization is viewed as a

    more fundamental explanation of the origins of order from

    disorder than natural selection (Depew and Weber, 1995).

    This is not an argument that neo-Darwinian evolutionary

    theory is wrong, but rather that evolution is a process that

    works upon the variety that is generated by processes of self-

    organization. Thus, selectionis a secondorderprocess which

    can only act upon the variety generated. This position has

    beenmostclearlystatedbyKauffman(1993, 2000) andthereis

    mounting evidence in biological research to support it. In theeconomic domain, the process of self-organization turns out

    to be much more sophisticated and, in many respects, it is a

    quite distinct process to that found in the biological domain

    (Foster, 2005).

    A basic puzzle remains: why do biological and socio-

    economic systems expand their structure (and populations)

    with the resultthat theyuse increasingamounts of free energy

    (and associated materials)? Generally, they expand to what-

    ever energetic limits exist and, as Malthus failed to perceive,

    economic self-organization can keep on extending these

    limits. The notions that biological populations will expand if

    they can, and that economic progresswill continue are taken

    for granted, but on reflection, it is not entirely obvious why. Ofcourse, it can be argued that we are genetically encoded to

    survive and that survival, over any considerable period of

    time, requires regular and reliable systems for thwarting the

    immediateimpacts of the entropylaw. In a niche rich with free

    energy, organisms over-perform and this is necessary to

    survive whatever large exogenous shock comes along. As a

    general rule, organisms do not just try to negate the entropy

    law, they seem to try to maximize the throughput of free

    energy.

    This was observed by Hatsopoulos and Keenan (1965),

    and more recently,Schneider and Kay (1994)in the context

    of net ecosystem energy absorption of solar energy. Biomass

    captures solar energy through the creation of more biomass

    as evidenced by the different amount of solar energy

    reflected by dense forest and deserts. This perspective

    turned around conventional thinking: dissipative structures

    do not just absorb free energy to fend off entropy; they exist

    in the first place because of the presence of free (solar)

    energy. They are structures that come into existence as

    energy throughput devices and, if conditions are not right,

    there will be no dissipative structures with autocatalyticproperties. Hence, without the availability of the appropriate

    chemical building blocks and the correct ambience, there

    will be no life.

    It is argued that the self-organization of the biosphere is

    concerned with the throughput of solar energy in a complex

    adaptive system of dissipative structures with autocatalytic

    properties. In turn, we can think of economic systems as

    knowledge based structures that have the capacity to

    throughput more energy than biological systems. Control

    over fire, water and wind were traditionally used to comple-

    ment human energy, while the modern economy has seen the

    focus shift to fossil fuels and nuclear power, especially for the

    provision of high quality electrical energy. Hence, the growthof structural complexity in economic systems is a conse-

    quence of the production of new knowledge in market-

    intermediated organizations. This could be seen as consistent

    with the Schneider and Kays interpretation of the reformu-

    lated second law of thermodynamics.

    In an economic environment, it could be postulated that

    there is an attractor, in the space of institutional arrange-

    ments towards which the acquisition of knowledge drives

    economic systems because the production of new knowledge

    maximizes the throughput of energy. The central argument is

    that, as economic systems grow and develop, we should

    expect to observe the following:

    (1) an increase in total energy throughput;

    (2) the development of more complex structures;

    (3) an increase in autocatalytic cycling activity and the

    institutional embedding of these processes;

    (4) the emergence of greater diversity;

    (5) the generation of more hierarchic levels; and

    (6) an increase in knowledge structures and their relative

    importance.

    We should expect all of these structural changes because

    all of them aid and abet increases in energy utilization. In

    this paper we shall not attempt to prove or test these

    hypotheses but, rather, explain why they are plausible asstatements about the nature of market economies, and why

    they are consistent with the second law of thermodynamics.

    This has important implications for the relation between

    economic systems and ecological systems, the nature and

    meaning of economic growth, and the analytical founda-

    tions of economics. Thus, the evolution of economic

    systems that occurs because of the production of new

    knowledge can be viewed as part of a natural process, and

    indeed can be viewed as an outcome of a unified thermo-

    dynamic principle.

    Thispaper is setoutas follows. InSection 2, we shall review

    the Schneider and Kay hypothesis about ecological systems

    and provide support for our claim that this can be extended to

    e c o l o g i c a l c o m p l e x i t y 3 ( 2 0 0 6 ) 3 5 4 3 6 0 355

  • 8/9/2019 Raine the New

    3/7

    economic systems. In Section 3, we shall review the basic

    principles of thermodynamics and attempt to elucidate the

    nature of the reformulated second law. In Section4, we link

    evolution and complexity from a thermodynamic perspective.

    In Section 5, the economic implications of thermodynamic

    evolution are considered before the concluding statement.

    2. Schneider and Kay on thermodynamics andecology

    Themodernreformulation of the relation between the entropy

    law and evolution of complex systems has major implications

    for economic theory, and particularly so in relation to the

    evolutionof knowledge. Indeed,we shall eventuallyargue that

    economic evolution is a natural consequence of thermody-

    namic processes. Schneider and Kay (1994) view all of

    evolution from such a perspective:

    We examine the thermodynamic evolution of various

    evolving systems. . .

    We take the reformulated second law,where non-equilibrium is described in terms of gradients

    maintaining systems at some distance away from equili-

    brium. The reformulated second law suggests that as

    systems are moved away from equilibrium they will take

    advantage of all available means to resist externally

    implied gradients . . . We argue that as ecosystems grow

    and develop, they should increase their total dissipation,

    develop more complex structures with more energy flow,

    increase their cyclingactivity, develop greater diversity and

    generate more hierarchic levels, all to abet energy

    degradation. Species which survive in ecosystems are

    those that funnel energy into their own production and

    reproduction and contribute to autocatalytic processeswhich increase the total dissipation of the ecosystem. In

    short, ecosystems develop in ways which systematically

    increases their ability to degrade the incoming solar

    energy. We believe that our thermodynamic paradigm

    makes it possible for the study of ecosystems to be

    developed from a descriptive science into a predictive

    science founded on the most basic principles of physics.

    (1994: 25)

    Schneider and Kay applied the energy gradient dissipation

    concept to the analysis of biological systemsby comparing the

    maturity of various ecosystems. Their hypothesis suggests

    that more mature ecosystems will re-radiate a lower amountof energy than less developed ecosystems by creating

    dissipative structures that capture and utilize more of the

    solar gradient. Theybase this upon an interpretation of input

    output (IO) tables of re-radiant energy collected by indepen-

    dent thermal imaging satellite data and collated byLuvall and

    Holbo (1991).

    Re-radiant energy compares the thermal heat expelled by

    the ecosystem with the original energy gradient imposed by

    the external environment. It is observed that more mature

    ecosystems radiate significantly less thermal heat. For

    example, clear-cut grassland was found to be comparable to

    a quarry, re-radiating about 3540% of solar radiation. Natural

    and plantation forests utilize around 85% of the incoming

    energy while extremely well developed 400-year-old Douglas

    fir forests harnessed greater than 90%. The results of these

    investigations provide support for the hypothesis that more

    highly self-organized ecosystems degrade more of the avail-

    able energy through the development of sophisticated energy

    harnessing mechanisms.

    It seems to us that Schneider and Kays basic idea may also

    apply to economic systems. By making a few elementarysubstitutions, this would seem to also be a provocative and

    promising approach to evolutionary economic analysis.

    Consider this:

    We argue that as economic systems grow and develop,

    they should increase their total dissipation, develop more

    complex structures with more energy flow, increase their

    cycling activity, develop greater diversity and generate

    more hierarchiclevels, allto abet energy degradation. Rules

    which survive in economic systems are those that funnel

    energy into their own production and reproduction and

    contribute to autocatalytic processes which increase the

    total dissipation of the system. . .

    We believe that ourthermodynamic paradigm makes it possible for the study

    ofeconomic systems to be developed from a descriptive

    science into a predictive science foundedon the most basic

    principles of physics.

    Economic systemsare highlyevolved ecosystems that have

    harnessed a new substrate knowledge that enables them to

    extend their organized complexity and, correspondingly, their

    dissipative potential (Miller, 1999; Potts, 2003). Economic

    systems increase the complexity (structure of interactions),

    cycling activity (habits, routines, competences and institu-

    tions), and hierarchic depth (organization and modular

    decomposition) of natural systems by accelerating, and beingaccelerated by, the production of new knowledge.

    The immediate implication is that economic systems are

    not outside Nature, and nor is Nature outside economic

    systems. The human species is a significant component of the

    ecosystem because our economic systems, made possible by

    our biologically supported and socially evolved knowledge

    systems, are highly effective means of doing what all other

    species are also doing from the perspective of the second law.

    Of all the species on this planet, Homo Sapiens is one of the

    most effective species at degrading energy.

    Knowledge that results in both creativity and productive

    cooperation has grown and led to economic self-organization

    (Foster, 1997). In turn, innovation has been subject to selectionmechanisms that have tended to enhance energy through-

    put.1 However, this is a very recent phenomenon in evolu-

    tionary time driven by the tremendous growth in knowledge

    and human population in the past 200 years. This has been

    facilitated by the spread of market economies based upon a

    globally adopted set of institutions for developing the means

    of creating, producing, distributing and consuming goods and

    services.

    1 We focus on the structural aspects of the adaptive process thatprecede selection by conscious choice in economic evolution,

    rather than the role of human agency.

    e c o l o g i c a l c o m p l e x i t y 3 ( 2 0 0 6 ) 3 5 4 3 6 0356

  • 8/9/2019 Raine the New

    4/7

    3. Whats new in thermodynamics

    The classical laws of thermodynamics, which were prompted

    by investigations into the efficiency of heat engines and

    formalized later in the 19th century, are approximately:

    0th law of thermodynamics: there exists energy2

    1st lawof thermodynamics: in an isolated system,energyisconstant

    2nd law of thermodynamics: the total entropy of an

    isolated system never decreases

    The second law, also known as the entropy law, is a

    statement about the quality of the energy conserved in

    accordance with the first law. The traditional entropy law

    states that anyreal processcan proceedonly in a direction that

    results in an entropy increase, which is to say that the

    extraction of work always involves a decrease in the quality of

    the energy remaining in an isolated system. The traditional

    interpretation stated what would not happenhigh quality

    energy turns into low quality energy by the extraction of workand never the reverse. No work process is ever 100% efficient,

    and so there exists a fundamental irreversibility in Nature.

    That, in itself, was and still is a very big idea. There is an

    arrow of time along the entropy gradient and this has all

    manner of implications for the other laws of physics. But this

    shall not be our concern. The issue here is whether entropy

    increase, or the arrow of time, conveyed the meaning of the

    second law appropriately. Long ago,Hatsopoulos and Keenan

    (1965), andKestin (1966)argued that entropy increase is not

    in fact the general meaning of the second law. In open

    environments, Schneider and Kay propose the following

    restatement:

    Thethermodynamicprinciplewhichgovernsthebehaviour

    ofsystemsis that,as they are movedawayfromequilibrium,

    they will utilize all avenues to counter theappliedgradients.

    Astheappliedgradientsincrease,sodoesthesystemsability

    to oppose further degradation. (1994: 28)

    This reformulation of the entropy law addresses what

    happens in reality a system will attemptto reach equilibrium

    and, in essence,the more pressure that is applied, the harder

    it will resist. Although only mildlyinteresting forsystems at or

    near equilibrium, as von Bertalanffy (1968), Prigogine (1978),

    Brooks and Wiley (1986) and Prigogine and Stengers (1997)

    have shown, it is a very interesting restatement for systemsthat are massively out of equilibrium. It is generally accepted

    that all natural processes can be viewed in light of the entropy

    law where global entropy increases may be partially offset by

    local system development (von Bertalanffy, 1968).

    This new interpretation argues that the essential meaning

    of the second law is that all real processes are equilibrium

    seeking, butthat does notthen imply that allreal processes are

    in equilibrium, which is a common misperception, at least

    among orthodox theoretical economists. Rather, all real

    processes are equilibrium seeking because many of them

    aremassivelyout of equilibrium as a consequence of gradients

    applied. Hence, life is an emergent phenomena created by the

    constant influx of solar radiation which maintains living

    systems in a non-equilibrium state.

    The reformulated second law is appropriate for the analysis

    of spatially fixed and open systems such as plants and forests.

    Such systems are subject to two opposing gradients: the

    thermodynamic degradation gradient and the incoming solarradiation gradient. Solar radiation provides the energy neces-

    sary for these systems to oppose thermodynamic degradation

    as implied by the entropy law. Schneider and Kay argue that

    this principle applies to all chemical and biological systems. To

    support thisargument, theyutilizethe workofLuvall andHolbo

    (1991)who found that more mature and complex ecosystems

    (e.g. rainforests) were more effective at dissipating energy

    gradients than less mature ecosystems (e.g. rock quarries), by

    the measure of re-radiant energy from each.

    However, Schneider and Kayare not alone in developing an

    alternative approach for analyzing thermodynamic develop-

    ment.Fath et al. (2001)reviewed 10 different thermodynamic

    principles used in environ network analysis in ecology andfound that they were differentiated by the primary focus of

    study (e.g. specific heat dissipation or total throughput), and

    not by alternative applications of the entropy law. Of the 10

    principles, the minimum specific dissipation principle (MSDP)

    is most applicable to the investigation of complex adaptive

    systems and implies that living systems will maximize energy

    flux but minimize the amount of specific dissipation as heat.

    The MSDP is a generic form of the Schneider and Kay

    hypothesis that is consistent with the principles outlined by

    Lotka (1922a, 1922b). It is more applicable to mobile open

    systems (e.g. animals), which do not derive significant energy

    from environmental gradients directly. In fact, these systems

    must harness chemical energy from matter in the environ-ment to avert the gradient imposed by the second law.

    Essentially, this principle indicates that those FFE systems

    facing resource constraints will preferentially convert energy

    to structure, due to the efficiency gains of reusing structure in

    cyclic mechanisms.

    4. Thermodynamics, complex systems, andevolution

    Previous work on complex adaptive systems by Prigogine

    (1978),Brooks and Wiley (1986), andAllen (1998), recognized

    that biological, ecological and economic systems are nevernear classical thermodynamic equilibrium. Self-organization

    provides structures that throughput free energy in a way that

    resists the thermodynamic gradient and fuels maintenance,

    regeneration, and structural development. Biological, ecolo-

    gical andeconomic systemsare characterizedin terms of their

    local environment of interaction. These systems, in their

    different ways, can alter their local environments in order to

    exploit energy gradients.

    Simple open systems can be understood in terms of energy

    and entropy gradients. In cases where energy is imposed

    directly, usually heat and solar energy, dissipation is the

    expectedsystemresponse,as found in Bernardcells andsimilar

    systems close to thermodynamic equilibrium. In morecomplex

    2 All matter is ultimately energy as matter is a meta-stable

    energy structure.

    e c o l o g i c a l c o m p l e x i t y 3 ( 2 0 0 6 ) 3 5 4 3 6 0 357

  • 8/9/2019 Raine the New

    5/7

    biological systems (e.g. plants and animals) a direct energy

    gradient is not available, but energy is still required for system

    maintenance and structural development. These systems

    harness energy indirectly from complex transformations of

    energetic radiation, consumption of organic matter and the

    liberation of chemical energy. The formation of structural

    complexity enables the utilization of energy to counter the

    degradation gradient implied by the reformulated second law.Complex systems emerge and adapt through the creation

    of endogenous feedback processes, or subsystems, in order to

    solve energy problems. These self-organized processes create

    internal energy gradients that work synergistically within the

    context of a larger system to help resist thermodynamic

    degradation through the creation of new structure. The

    success of a new self-organized energy-utilization process

    is determined by its capacity to develop structure that can

    increase the energy available to resist the degradation

    gradient. In this context, evolution is a process that is

    accelerated when limitations upon current energy resources

    and processing mechanisms are reached.

    All forms of the entropy law imply that eventually physicalsystems wear out, so for a system to maintain itself over time,

    some type of regeneration mechanism is required.Cycling and

    autocatalysis perform a fundamental role in the maintenance

    processes of non-equilibrium systems (Kauffman, 2000;

    Christensen and Hooker, 1997). Autocatalytic processes are

    energetically efficient because the structure in which energy

    utilization occurs is retained for future use. Thus, these

    mechanisms are an important way of increasing dissipation

    and degradation.3 The notion of self-organized gradient

    dissipater activity within complex systems holds for non-

    equilibrium physical and chemical systems, and describes the

    process of their emergence and development (Prigogine and

    Stengers, 1997). Furthermore, the thermodynamic lawssuggest these processes will exist wherever there are energy

    gradients available to open systems. Schneider and Kay

    recognized, in the ecosystem context, that individuals actively

    seek to remove free energy from the environment, where:

    The origin of life should not be seen as an isolated event.

    Rather, it represents the emergence of yet another class of

    processes whose goal is the dissipation of thermodynamic

    gradients. (1994: 37)

    The evolutionary process describes the arrow of time while

    the laws of thermodynamics provide natural bounds andrules

    that determine each systems existence. The emergence of lifemaybe explained a consequence of thermodynamic laws that

    are consistent with evolutionary theories of system develop-

    ment. Self-organization is an important process in the

    evolution of biological systems that adapt in response to

    changesin the local environment. It would appearthat, given

    the self-organizational tendencies of thermodynamic sys-

    tems, more complex structures will be favored in evolution

    because they are more effective at degrading energy.

    What Corning (2002) refers to as thermoeconomic

    principles following Lotka (1922a, 1922b), and echoed by

    Georgescu-Roegen (1971),Boulding (1978),Schneider and Kay

    (1994), andBuensdorf (2000), characterize living systems as

    seeking to increase access to energy sources, and/or increase

    the efficiency of currently employed energy transformation

    processes. The development of technological and organiza-

    tional structures represents investments in organized com-

    plexity. Technological structures determine the necessary

    physical foundations for future energy transformation whilethe coordination of specialized elements within the context of

    a larger network structure is achieved through organizational

    rules. Complex adaptive systems emerge from the interaction

    of energetic and informational flows but such a process is not

    without limitboundaries exist and, when these are

    approached, structural discontinuities occur (Tainter, 1990).

    5. Applications to economic systems

    We now wish to go beyond the Schneider and Kay framework,

    principally in the direction laid out already by Foster (1997,

    2000). Self-organizational processes implied by thermody-namics, mean that natural selection analogies, drawn from

    evolutionary biology, are inadequate to understand economic

    evolution (Foster, 1995; Witt, 1999; Buensdorf, 2000; Prigogine,

    2005). Economic systemsare highly evolved biological systems

    where the acquisition of knowledge yields much greater

    transformation potential.

    The evolution of economic systems is the result of the co-

    evolution of knowledge and energy transforming structures.

    However, the introduction of knowledge as a complement to

    energy in economic evolution implies that the traditional

    thermodynamic ontology is not sufficient for economic

    analysis. Socio-economic systems seek out and utilize knowl-

    edge to acquire novel solutions to energy transformationproblems. This quest to transform energy has led to the

    economic self-organization through the increasing utilization

    of knowledge.4

    The emergence of socio-economic complexity is highly

    correlated with the development of cognition and the creation

    of abstract representations of reality which are shared

    between individuals (Foster, 2005). So, economic systems

    are differentiated by the explicit role of knowledge in the

    development of structural complexity. Even though knowl-

    edge is created within the individual, the coordination of

    social communities requires that economic agents share a

    common understanding of their socio-economic environ-

    ment. The success of livingsystems in these contexts hasbeendetermined by their ability to develop andretain their physical

    capacity to transform energy and maintain stocks of useful

    knowledge for further transformation. Knowledge is useful

    3 Dissipation refers to the creation of heat while this is not

    necessarily so of degradation mechanisms.

    4 Archeological evidence of primitive tool complexity suggeststhat this evolutionary progression began about 4 million yearsago, facilitated by an enlarged cranium and the development ofgeneralized intelligence. It is postulated that the development anduse of knowledge was restricted to isolated contexts, until thebrain developed the ability to integrate general, social, technicaland natural history intelligences (Mithen, 1996). Major develop-ment advances in thelast 10 millenniaare attributed to this abilityto create, utilize, and evolve knowledge through abstract repre-

    sentation and experimentation.

    e c o l o g i c a l c o m p l e x i t y 3 ( 2 0 0 6 ) 3 5 4 3 6 0358

  • 8/9/2019 Raine the New

    6/7

    not just in transforming energy but also through the creation

    of socio-economic environments (system boundaries) which

    can enable new transformations not previously accessible.

    It is the role of knowledge that differentiates economic

    evolution from its ecological counterparts in the following

    ways.

    Sharing knowledge creates unique socio-political environ-ments, both within the individual mind and between

    individuals. Shared social institutions determine the rules

    for organization and a basis for the interaction of consti-

    tuent agents.

    Knowledge interactions imply that evolution may occur not

    just from experience but also experimental mechanisms

    (Potts, 2001; Mokyr, 2002; Foster, 2005).

    Economic systems do not reach growth limits as easily as in

    ecology, because of the continual innovation facilitated by

    new knowledge. This is true of all forms of economic

    organization but is relatively more successful in market

    economies where incentives are created to reward the

    development of new knowledge and its incorporation intoeconomic activities.

    The resource constraints of market economies appear

    unlimited due to their ability to induce and harness new

    knowledge developments (Dopfer et al., 2004). As these

    systems approach boundary limits, knowledge extends the

    boundaries themselves by introducing new sources or

    processing mechanisms. Long-term sustainability issues,

    inherent in market economies and economic growth, require

    recognition of not just thermodynamic and biophysical

    principles, but also the role of the production of new

    knowledge (Peet, 1994; Dyke, 1990).

    Economic growth results from the co-evolution of knowl-edge andthe physical means to process energy. The accumula-

    tion of knowledge is an evolutionary process, which may

    improve the degradation of energy by direct or indirect means,

    thereby increasing the production of useful energy. Tradition-

    ally, the focus of analysis in mainstream economics has been

    the utility maximizing microeconomic agent, who has no direct

    relation to energy or the second law of thermodynamics.

    However, knowledge augments physical structure through the

    provision of rules that facilitate ever-increasing processes of

    energy transformation, subject to stability in the social and

    natural environment. The self-organized accumulation of

    knowledge stocks may not only be the cause of economic

    growth, but the consequence of adaptive development accord-ing to the second law of thermodynamics.

    The evolution of social institutions is dependent upon

    available knowledge and energetic technologies. In the

    development of market economies, the emergence of new

    technologies has often been accompanied by institutional

    change, which facilitates technological incorporation into

    economic processes. Market economies are characterized by

    two essential institutions (access to free-markets and capital).

    These create an interaction environment in which individual

    self-organization is feasible, facilitating the flow of energy and

    matter. Adam Smith (1950) and Sadi Carnot (1824), both

    respective fathers of their disciplines, understood that the

    application of technological and organizational innovations to

    production and consumption processes ultimately deter-

    mined the rate of economic growth.

    Market economies have proven to be more successful than

    other socio-political organizational systems in creating stable

    but flexible institutional environments for the production of

    new knowledge. Modern economic systems have been

    transformed into growth machines by the application of

    knowledge to solve economic problems by increasing thestructural complexity of the economy, resulting in a higher

    energy through-put than previously (Huber and Mills, 2005).5

    Furthermore, there has been a laudable movement toward

    increased energy conservation in economic activities in order

    to create sustainable growth. This does not contradict our

    thesis, as efficiency increases are invariably achieved with

    higher knowledge complexity or new technologies to isolate

    systems more effectively. Greater efficiency in energy use

    simply makes more energy available for the creation and

    development of new energy transformation structures.

    6. Conclusion

    The emergence of thermodynamic systems that sponta-

    neously self-organize is characterized by the formation of

    physical structures. These structures enable the system to

    harness the energy and materials necessary for maintenance

    and survival, and we associate these with the growth of

    knowledge in economic systems. Complexity emerges from

    hierarchical interactions that coordinate specialized sub-

    systems in an efficient manner, where the formation of

    internal structures and autocatalytic processes attain the

    energy necessary for maintenance, growth and development.

    TheworkofSchneiderandKayillustratestheeffectofenergy

    gradients upon system development and is most applicable tothe study of ecosystems and other spatially fixed, open system

    environments.The evidence suggests moremature ecosystems

    develop highly specialized mechanisms to harness as much

    energy as possible. Evolution tends to favour more complex

    structures because they are more effective at utilizing free

    energy, which is a consequence of the second law of thermo-

    dynamics. Ecological studies suggest that thermodynamic

    systems facing resource limits will invest in new structures

    that most efficiently harness the available resources.

    Economic systems are characterized by the explicit use of

    knowledge in harnessing energy, and consequently creating

    value. Traditional economic analysis has been reserved in its

    incorporation of energy, usually only as a factor of production.The reformulated second law suggests that knowledge

    structures be considered as unique complements that allow

    socio-economic systems to utilize more energy than other

    biological and ecological species. Knowledge coevolves with

    energy using structures, facilitating economic growth through

    the use of functional and organizational rules under the

    governance of social institutions.

    5 From an analytical perspective, log scales are usually requiredto plot human populations, energy usage, or wealth, when thetime scale extends beyond about 10 generations (Smil, 2003). Forevery other species on the planet, that is only true when we are

    talking about at least thousands of generations.

    e c o l o g i c a l c o m p l e x i t y 3 ( 2 0 0 6 ) 3 5 4 3 6 0 359

  • 8/9/2019 Raine the New

    7/7

    Evolutionary economists often speak of the production of

    newknowledge as being thecentralorganizing principle in their

    framework.Theyalsojustas often speakof complexsystems as

    being the central organizing principle in theirframework. Here,

    we have argued that the growth of knowledge as a process of

    increasing structural complexity in economic systems may be

    an outcome of the second law of thermodynamics. This idea

    may have potentially profound implications for the analysis ofeconomicgrowth andtransformation by fundamentally linking

    the throughput of energy to the emergence of ever more

    complex structures. Among other things, this may help explain

    the continual growth of the service sector as a proportion of

    economic activity as well as the increased scope of specializa-

    tion and inter-sector trade.

    r e f e r e n c e s

    Allen, P., 1998. Evolving complexity in social science. In: Altman,

    G., Koch, W. (Eds.), Systems: New Perspectives for theHuman Sciences. Waltyer de Gruyter, Berlin.

    Boulding, K., 1978. Ecodynamics: A New Theory of SocietalEvolution. Sage Publications, Beverly Hills.

    Brooks, D., Wiley, E., 1986. Evolution as Entropy: Toward aUnified Theory of Biology. University of Chicago Press,Chicago.

    Buensdorf, G., 2000. Self-organization and sustainability:energetic of evolution and the implications for ecologicaleconomics. Ecol. Econ. 33, 119134.

    Carnot, S., 1824. Reflections on the motive power of heat and onmachines fitted to develop that power. Translated byThurston, R., 1890. The Work of Sadi Carnot. Wiley, NewYork.

    Christensen, W., Hooker, C., 1997. Selection theory,

    organization and the development of knowledge. Evol.Cogn. 3, 4448.

    Corning, P., 2002. Thermoeconomics: beyond the second law. J.Bioecon. 4, 5788.

    Depew, D., Weber, B., 1995. Darwinism Evolving: SystemsDynamics and the Genealogy of Natural Selection. MITPress, Cambridge.

    Dopfer, K., Foster, J., Potts, J., 2004. Micromesomacro. J. Evol.Econ. 14, 263279.

    Dyke, C., 1990. Cities as dissipative structures. In: Weber, B.H.,Depew, D.J., Smith, J.D. (Eds.), Entropy, Information andEvolution. MIT Press, Cambridge.

    Fath, B., Patten, B., Choi, J., 2001. Complementarity of ecologicalgoal functions. J. Theor. Biol. 208, 493506.

    Foster, J., 1995. The impact of the self organization approach on

    economic science: why economic theory and history needno longer be mutually exclusive domains. Math. Comput.Simul. 39, 393398.

    Foster, J., 1997. The analytical foundations of evolutionaryeconomics: from biological analogy to economic self-organization. Struct. Change Econ. Dynam. 8, 427451.

    Foster, J., 2000. Competition selection, self-organization andJoseph A Schumpeter. J. Evol. Econ. 10, 311328.

    Foster, J., 2005. From simplistic to complex systems ineconomics. Cambridge J. Econ. 29, 873892.

    Georgescu-Roegen, N., 1971. The Entropy Law and the EconomicProcess. Harvard University Press, Harvard.

    Haken, H., 1978. Synergetics: An Introduction, 2nd English ed.Springer, Berlin.

    Hatsopoulos, G., Keenan, J., 1965. Principles of GeneralThermodynamics. Wiley, New York.

    Hodgson, G., 1993. Economics and Evolution: Bringing Life Backinto Economics. Polity Press, Cambridge.

    Huber, P., Mills, M., 2005. The Bottomless Well. Basic Books, NewYork.

    Kauffman, S., 1993. The Origins of Order: Self Organization andSelection in Evolution. University of Oxford Press, NewYork.

    Kauffman, S., 2000. Investigations. University of Oxford Press,New York.

    Kestin, J., 1966. A Course in Thermodynamics. BlaisdellPublishing, Waltham.

    Lotka, A., 1922a. Contribution to the energetics of evolution.Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 8, 147151.

    Lotka, A., 1922b. Natural selection as a physical principle. Proc.Natl. Acad. Sci. 8, 151154.

    Luvall, J., Holbo, R., 1991. Thermal remote sensing methods inlandscape ecology. In: Turner, M., Gardner, R. (Eds.),

    Quantitative Methods in Landscape Ecology. Springer, NewYork.

    Miller, G., 1999. Waste is good. Prospect 2, 1823.Mithen, S., 1996. The Pre-history of the Mind: A Search for the

    Origins of Art, Religion and Science. Phoenix, London.Mokyr, J., 2002. The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the

    Knowledge Economy. Princeton University Press, Princeton.Nelson, R., Winter, S., 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Change.

    Belknap Press, Cambridge.Peet, J., 1994. Energy and the Ecological Economics of

    Sustainability. Island Press, Washington, DC.Potts, J., 2001. Knowledge and markets. J. Evol. Econ. 11,

    413432.Potts, J., 2003. Toward an evolutionary theory of homo

    economicus: the concept of universal nomadism. In:

    Laurent, J. (Ed.), Evolutionary Economics and HumanNature. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.

    Prigogine, I., 1978. Time, structure and fluctuations. Science 201,777784.

    Prigogine, I., Stengers, I., 1997. The End of Certainty: Time,Chaos and the New Laws of Nature. Free Press, New York.

    Prigogine, I., 2005. The rediscovery of value and the opening ofeconomics. In: Dopfer, K. (Ed.), Evolutionary Foundations ofEconomics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

    Schneider, E., Kay, J., 1994. Life as a manifestation of the secondlaw of thermodynamics. Math. Comput. Model. 19,2548.

    Smil, V., 2003. Energy at the Crossroads: Global Perspectives andUncertainties. MIT Press, Cambridge.

    Smith, A., 1950. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the

    Wealth of Nations, 6th ed. Methuen, London.Tainter, J., 1990. The Collapse of Complex Societies, 1st

    paperback ed. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.von Bertalanffy, L., 1968. General Systems Theory: Foundations,

    Developments, Applications (revised ed.) Braziller, NewYork.

    Witt, U., 1997. Self-organization and economicswhat is new?Struct. Change Econ. Dynam. 8, 489507.

    Witt, U., 1999. Bioeconomics as economics from a Darwinianperspective. J. Bioecon. 1, 1924.

    e c o l o g i c a l c o m p l e x i t y 3 ( 2 0 0 6 ) 3 5 4 3 6 0360