prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/zuee javaira.pdf · ii role of...

244
i ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED, EMERGING AND FRONTIER STOCK MARKETS Researcher: Supervisor: Zuee Javaira Dr. Arshad Hassan REG NO. 35-FMS/PHDFIN/S11 Associate Professor, CUST Co. Supervisor: Dr. Syed Zulfiqar Ali Shah Associate Professor, FMS, IIUI Faculty of Management Sciences INTERNATIONAL ISLAMIC UNIVERSITY, ISLAMABAD

Upload: others

Post on 13-Mar-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

i

ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS

IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM

DEVELOPED, EMERGING AND FRONTIER STOCK

MARKETS

Researcher: Supervisor:

Zuee Javaira Dr. Arshad Hassan

REG NO. 35-FMS/PHDFIN/S11 Associate Professor, CUST

Co. Supervisor:

Dr. Syed Zulfiqar Ali Shah

Associate Professor, FMS, IIUI

Faculty of Management Sciences

INTERNATIONAL ISLAMIC UNIVERSITY,

ISLAMABAD

Page 2: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

ii

ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS

IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM

DEVELOPED, EMERGING AND FRONTIER STOCK

MARKETS

Zuee Javaira

REG NO. 35-FMS/ Ph.D. Fin/S11

Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the

Ph.D. degree with the specialization in Finance

at the faculty of management sciences,

International Islamic University,

Islamabad.

Supervisor

Dr. Arshad Hassan April, 2018

Dr. Syed Zulfiqar Ali Shah

Page 3: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

iii

In the name of Allah, the most merciful and beneficent

Page 4: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

iv

DEDICATION

I dedicate this work to my parents Mr. and Mrs. Ghulam Mustafa Qureshi, who have

given me so much without expecting anything in return

Page 5: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

v

(Acceptance by the Viva Voice Committee)

Title of Thesis: “Role of Culture and Macroeconomic Shocks in Driving Herding Behavior: Evidence

from Developed, Emerging and Frontier Stock Markets”.

Name of Student: Zuee Javaira

Registration No: 35-FMS/PHDFIN/S11

Accepted by the Faculty of Management Sciences INTERNATIONAL ISLAMIC UNIVERSITY

ISLAMABAD, in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Ph.D. degree with the specialization

in Finance at the faculty of management sciences.

Viva Voce Committee

________________________

Dr. Arshad Hassan

(Supervisor)

________________________

Dr. Syed Zulfiqar Ali Shah

(Co-Supervisor)

_______________________

(External Examiner)

________________________

(Internal Examiner)

________________________

(Chairman HS & R)

________________________

(Dean)

Date:___________________

Page 6: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

vi

ABSTRACT

The basic purpose of this research is to investigate herding behavior, the role of culture, the effect of

macroeconomic shocks on herding behavior, and the existence of contagion of herding due to the crisis

and extreme shocks in the market. This study investigates the herding behavior towards market

consensus in a set of Developed, Emerging and Frontier Markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe.

For the identification of herding behavior towards market consensus this study employs return

dispersion models and the state space model. The time variation in herding behavior is identified by

estimating return dispersion model through Kalman filter estimation. One of the main objective of this

research is to determine the role of culture in driving herding behavior. This study employs Hofstede’s

six cultural dimensions of culture and introduces them as an explanatory variable in the return

dispersion model.

This study utilizes ARIMA residuals of macroeconomic variables and introduce them in state

space model to figure out the effect of unexpected shocks of this variable on investor herding behavior.

This study focuses on behavioral link namely contagion of herding (pure contagion) in a given set of

market and determines the cross country linkages of each market with a global leader (US) through

extreme shocks in macroeconomic components or crisis. For the said purpose conditional correlation

between herding measures is generated through diagonal VECH bivariate GARCH (1,1) model. The

major findings of the study report significant effect of herding behavior in the majority of the markets.

state space model measure provide better results for all measure.

Culture play a significant role in the determination of herding behavior. The presence of

cultural dimensions changes the magnitude of the herding behavior in sample countries. The herding

behavior of investor is affected by some macroeconomic shocks hitting the specific market. But

macroeconomic shocks do not seem to play a major role in defining herding behavior in most of the

markets. Majority of the markets exhibit a strong correlation with US market which is seen as turning

Page 7: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

vii

points of herding measure during a global financial crisis of 2007-2009. This correlation also increased

due to some specific macroeconomic shocks.

This study provides a complete analytical framework in developed emerging and frontier markets of

Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe, where economic, cultural, behavioral and external factors are

simultaneously integrated to provide a better explanation of herding behavior. Therefore, in its unique

design, this research is an attempt towards bridging a gap between, cultural finance, behavioral finance,

and standard finance.

Keywords: Herding Behavior, Cultural Dimensions, Macroeconomic Shocks, Financial Crisis,

Contagion of Herding.

Page 8: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

viii

COPYRIGHTS

Copyright 2017 by IIUI Student

All rights reserved. Reproduction in whole or in part in any form requires the prior written

permission of Ms. Zuee Javaira or designated representative.

Page 9: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

ix

DECLARATION

I hereby declare that this thesis, neither as a whole nor as a part thereof, has been copied out from any

source. It is further declared that I have prepared this thesis entirely on the basis of my personal effort

made under the sincere guidance of my supervisor and colleagues. No portion of work, presented in

this thesis has been submitted in support of any application for any degree or qualification of this or

any other university or institute of learning.

Ms. Zuee Javaira

PhD (Finance)

Faculty of Management Sciences

Page 10: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

x

APPRECIATION AND GRATITUDE

The writing of this thesis has been one of the most significant academic challenges I have had. Without

the support, patience, and guidance of my supervisors, Dr. Arshad Hassan, and Dr. Syed Zulfiqar Ali

Shah, this study would not have been achieved. It is to them that I owe my deepest gratitude. Their

wisdom and knowledge have been of great value to me. Their assistance and guidance in getting my

career started on the right foot have provided me with the foundation for a career in academia.

I wish to express my gratitude to Dr. Abdul Rashid, who helped me to learn some techniques. A very

special thanks is due to my friend and colleague Dr. Najam us Sahar for being there whenever I needed

it. I would like to thank the members of Higher Studies office of Department of Management Sciences,

International Islamic University Islamabad for their support and guidance throughout my MS-PhD

degree completion. I am deeply grateful to all members of the examination committee for agreeing to

read the manuscript and to participate in the defense of this thesis.

Special thanks to my family for their unwavering love, continuous encouragement, and quiet support.

I would like to express my deepest appreciation to my beloved Daughter, Haya Fatima, for her

tolerance of my occasional bad moods. Without her patience, understanding, and unconditional love,

I would not be able to achieve this goal, one that I thought was far beyond my reach.

Above all, I bow before and thank ‘Allah Almighty’ without whose blessings this work would have

never been completed.

Ms. Zuee Javaira

Page 11: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

xi

FORWARDING SHEET

The thesis entitled “Role of Culture and Macroeconomic Shocks in Driving Herding Behavior:

Evidence from Developed, Emerging and Frontier Stock Markets” submitted by Ms. Zuee Javaira as

partial fulfillment of Ph.D. degree with the specialization in Finance at the faculty of management

sciences, has completed under my guidance and supervision. The changes advised by the external and

the internal examiners have also been incorporated. I am satisfied with the quality of student’s research

work and allow her to submit this thesis for further process as per IIU rules & regulations.

Date:_______________________ Signature:___________________

Name : ____________________

Page 12: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

xii

Contents

Contents ........................................................................................................................................ xii

List of Abbreviation ...................................................................................................................... xx

Chapter no 1 .................................................................................................................................... 1

1. Introduction: ............................................................................................................................ 1

Background of the Study ......................................................................................................... 1

Theoretical Background .......................................................................................................... 4

Psychological Forces ....................................................................................................... 6

Sociology Forces .............................................................................................................. 6

Biological Forces ............................................................................................................. 7

Theorizing and Conceptualizing Investor Behavior under Sociological and Psychological

Forces. ................................................................................................................................................ 7

Bounded Rationality Theory ............................................................................................ 7

Prospect Theory ............................................................................................................... 8

Theory of Mind ................................................................................................................ 9

The ABC Model ............................................................................................................... 9

Conceptualizing ............................................................................................................. 10

Motivation of Study .............................................................................................................. 11

Research Gap: ....................................................................................................................... 13

Statement of the Research Problem ...................................................................................... 15

Research Questions: .............................................................................................................. 16

Objectives of Study: .............................................................................................................. 16

The significance of the Study: ............................................................................................... 17

Theoretical Contribution: ............................................................................................... 17

Practical Contribution .................................................................................................... 21

Page 13: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

xiii

Organization of the Study .................................................................................................. 23

2. Literature review and Theoretical Framework ..................................................................... 24

Traditional Finance: .............................................................................................................. 24

Rational preferences....................................................................................................... 24

Efficient Market Hypothesis: ......................................................................................... 25

Behavioral Finance ................................................................................................................ 28

Theories of Human Behavior: ........................................................................................ 30

Behavioral Biases: ......................................................................................................... 31

Herding Behavior: ................................................................................................................. 32

Theories of Herding Behavior ....................................................................................... 33

Models of Herding Behavior ......................................................................................... 34

Empirical Evidence on Institutional Investor Herding .................................................. 36

Empirical Evidence on Aggregate Market Activity....................................................... 38

Culture: .................................................................................................................................. 40

Empirical Studies of Cultural Finance: .......................................................................... 42

Contagion .............................................................................................................................. 43

Fundamental Based Contagion ...................................................................................... 45

Common Cause Contagion ............................................................................................ 45

Pure Contagion............................................................................................................... 46

Determinants of Herding Behavior ....................................................................................... 48

Stock Market Performance ............................................................................................ 48

Volatility of Stock .......................................................................................................... 49

Global Volatility ............................................................................................................ 49

Herding Behavior and Culture: ............................................................................................. 50

Individualism and Herding Behavior ............................................................................. 51

Page 14: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

xiv

Power Distance and Herding Behavior: ......................................................................... 52

Masculinity vs Feminist and Herding Behavior ............................................................ 52

Uncertainty Avoidance and Herding Behavior: ............................................................. 53

Long-term Orientation and Herding Behavior:.............................................................. 54

Indulgence versus Restraints .......................................................................................... 55

Effect of Macroeconomic Shocks on Herding ...................................................................... 55

Herding Behavior and Financial Contagion .......................................................................... 57

3. Data and Methodology .......................................................................................................... 59

Research Design: ................................................................................................................... 59

Data and Sample: ........................................................................................................... 59

Methodology ......................................................................................................................... 61

Measure of Herding ....................................................................................................... 61

Model Selection Criteria Applied to Return Dispersion and State Space Model .......... 65

Determinants of Herding Behavior ................................................................................ 66

Herding Behavior and Culture ....................................................................................... 67

The Effects of Macroeconomic Shocks on Herding ...................................................... 70

Herding and Financial Contagion: ................................................................................. 71

4. Results and Discussion ......................................................................................................... 75

Return Dispersion Model Based on Christie & Huang (1995) ............................................. 75

Descriptive Statistics of Cross-Sectional Standard Deviation ....................................... 75

Estimates of Herding Measure in Extreme Market Conditions ..................................... 78

Return Dispersion Model based on Chiang et al. (2000) ...................................................... 80

Descriptive Statistics of Cross-Sectional Absolute Deviation of Returns ..................... 80

Estimates of Herding Measure Based on Constant Coefficient Model ......................... 83

Estimates of Herding based on Chang and Zheng (2010) ............................................. 86

Page 15: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

xv

Time-Varying Model of Herding Behavior .......................................................................... 89

Descriptive Statistics of Time-Varying Herding Parameter .......................................... 89

The Time Series of Herding Coefficient ........................................................................ 92

Determinants of Herding Behavior ................................................................................ 99

Culture and Herding Behavior ............................................................................................ 103

Power distance and Herding Behavior ......................................................................... 103

Individualism and Herding Behavior ........................................................................... 103

Masculinity and Herding Behavior .............................................................................. 104

Uncertainty Avoidance and Herding Behavior ............................................................ 106

Long-Term Orientation and Herding Behavior ........................................................... 106

Indulgence and Herding Behavior ............................................................................... 107

Estimation of State Space Model: ....................................................................................... 108

Properties of Cross-Sectional Standard Deviation of betas ......................................... 108

Properties of Log of Cross-Sectional Standard Deviation ........................................... 111

Estimates of Herding Measure and State Space Model ............................................... 116

Properties of Herding Measure .................................................................................... 118

Evolution of Herding Measures over Time ................................................................. 120

Selection of best Model based on AIC and BIC ................................................................. 147

Estimation of Macroeconomic Shocks on Herding Behavior ............................................. 149

Contagion of Herding .......................................................................................................... 161

Impact of Crisis Dummy on Cross Correlation of Herding Behavior ......................... 162

Impact of Macroeconomic Shocks on Cross-Correlation of herding behavior ........... 166

5. Conclusion .......................................................................................................................... 170

Summary and Findings........................................................................................................ 170

Discussion ........................................................................................................................... 175

Page 16: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

xvi

Methodological Implications and limitation ....................................................................... 177

Generalizability ................................................................................................................... 178

Theoretical Implications ...................................................................................................... 178

For Risk Diversification ............................................................................................... 179

For Behavioral Asset Pricing Model............................................................................ 179

For Behavioral Portfolio Management ........................................................................ 180

Policy and Practical Implication ......................................................................................... 180

For Individual Investors ............................................................................................... 180

For Institutional Investors ............................................................................................ 181

For International Investors ........................................................................................... 181

For Financial Market Regulators ................................................................................. 182

Limitations of the Study ...................................................................................................... 182

Future Recommendations .................................................................................................... 183

References ................................................................................................................................... 184

Appendix 1 .................................................................................................................................. 217

Appendix 2 .................................................................................................................................. 220

Appendix 3 .................................................................................................................................. 221

Appendix 4 .................................................................................................................................. 222

Page 17: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

xvii

Table of Tables

Table 3.1: List of sample countries with starting dates ...................................................................... 60

Table 4.1: Descriptive statistics of Cross sectional Standard Deviation ............................................. 76

Table 4.2: Estimates of herding measure in extreme market conditions: CSSD ................................. 78

Table 4.3: Descriptive Statistics of Cross-Sectional Absolute Deviation CSAD ................................ 82

Table 4.4: Estimates of herding measure based on constant coefficient model: CSAD...................... 83

Table 4.5: Estimates of asymmetric herding behavior based on constant coefficient model: CSAD . 87

Table 4.6: Descriptive Statistics of herding coefficient determine by Dynamic Model ...................... 90

Table 4.7: Domestic and Cross-Market Determinants of Herding Behavior ..................................... 100

Table 4.8: Estimation of Individual Cultural Dimensions on Herding Behavior .............................. 105

Table 4.9: Descriptive statistics of Cross-Sectional Standard Deviation of betas ............................. 109

Table 4.10: Descriptive statistics of Log of cross-sectional standard deviation of betas .................. 111

Table 4.11: Estimates of Herding Measure and State Space Model .................................................. 114

Table 4.12: Descriptive statistics of Herding measure, Hmt ............................................................. 118

Table 4.13: Selection of model based on AIC and BIC ..................................................................... 147

Table 4.14: The structures of estimated ARIMA models with the order (p,d,q) of all macroeconomic

variables. ............................................................................................................................................ 150

Table 4.15: Impact of Macroeconomic shocks on Herding ............................................................... 159

Table 4.16: Tests of changes in correlations between herding towards market on behalf of unexpected

variations in macroeconomic variables in US countries. ................................................................... 164

Page 18: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

xviii

Table of Figures

Figure 1-1: Theoretical perspective of Financial Market Functioning; Source: (Tuyon & Ahmad, 2016)

................................................................................................................................................................ 5

Figure 1-2: Conceptualizing the Irrational Investor behavior (Source: Tuyon & Ahmad, 2016) ....... 10

Figure 2-1: Source: Schindler (2007) .................................................................................................. 30

Figure 4-1: Time series of 2,t in developed markets(continued) ......................................................... 95

Figure 4-2: Time series of 2,t in emerging and frontier market .......................................................... 97

Figure 4-3: Herding evolution in Australian Market ......................................................................... 121

Figure 4-4: Herding evolution in Australian Market ......................................................................... 122

Figure 4-5: Herding Evolution in Belgium Market ........................................................................... 123

Figure 4-6: Herding Evolution in Chinese Market ............................................................................ 124

Figure 4-7: Herding Evolution in Danish Market .............................................................................. 125

Figure 4-8: Herding Evolution in French Market .............................................................................. 126

Figure 4-9: Herding Evolution in German Market ............................................................................ 127

Figure 4-10: Herding evolution in Greece Market ............................................................................ 128

Figure 4-11: Herding evolution in Hong Kong Market ..................................................................... 129

Figure 4-12: Herding Evolution in Indian Market ............................................................................. 130

Figure 4-13: Herding Evolution in Indonesian Market ...................................................................... 131

Figure 4-14: Herding Evolution in Italian Market ............................................................................. 132

Figure 4-15: Herding Evolution in Japanese Market ......................................................................... 133

Figure 4-16: Herding Evolution in Korean market ............................................................................ 134

Figure 4-17: Herding Evolution in Malaysian Market ...................................................................... 135

Figure 4-18: Herding Evolution in Netherlands Market .................................................................... 136

Figure 4-19: Herding Evolution in New Zealand Market .................................................................. 137

Figure 4-20: Herding Evolution in Norway Market .......................................................................... 138

Page 19: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

xix

Figure 4-21: Herding Evolution in Pakistani Market ........................................................................ 139

Figure 4-22: Herding Evolution in Philippines Market ..................................................................... 139

Figure 4-23: Herding Evolution in Portugal Market.......................................................................... 140

Figure 4-24: Herding Evolution in Singapore market ....................................................................... 141

Figure 4-25: Herding Evolution in Spanish Market .......................................................................... 141

Figure 4-26: Herding Evolution in Sri Lankan Market ..................................................................... 142

Figure 4-27: Herding Evolution in Swedish Market.......................................................................... 143

Figure 4-28: Herding Evolution in Swiss Market .............................................................................. 144

Figure 4-29: Herding Evolution in Thai Market ................................................................................ 144

Figure 4-30: Herding Evolution in Turkish Market ........................................................................... 145

Figure 4-31: Herding Evolution in UK market .................................................................................. 146

Figure 4-32: Herding Evolution in US market .................................................................................. 147

Figure 4-33: Correlation between US and other developed markets herding measures .................... 161

Figure 4-34: Conditional Correlation Graph between US and other emerging and Frontier Markets

............................................................................................................................................................ 161

Page 20: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

xx

List of Abbreviation

EMH Efficient Market Hypothesis

CAPM Capital Asset Pricing Model

APT Arbitrage Pricing Theory

CBOE Chicago Board of Exchange

CSSD Cross Sectional Standard Deviation

CSAD Cross Sectional Absolute Deviation

LSV Lakonishok, Shleifer, & Vishny Model

OECD Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development

MSCI Morgan Stanley Capital International

ICB Industry Classification Benchmark

IMF International Monetary Fund

IP Industrial Production Index

MS Money Supply

ER Exchange Rates

IR Interest Rates

VIX Global Volatility Index

PDI Power Distance Index

IDV Individualism Index

MAS Masculinity Index

UAI Uncertainty Avoidance Index

LTO Long-Term Orientation Index

IVR Indulgence Index

ARIMA Auto Regressive Integrated Moving Average

Page 21: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

xxi

GARCH Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity

Page 22: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

1

Chapter no 1

1. Introduction:

Background of the Study

In a world of capitalist economies, a linkage between saver and borrower is bridged through some

sort of capital markets. In a corporate sector particularly, funds are collected for investors in order to

make productive use either through direct financing (issuance of securities to the public) or indirect

financing (borrowing through financial intermediaries). Proper functioning of markets is a primary

concern of all market players. Other than the functioning of the market, scholars, practitioners, and

regulators are also concerned about the ability of a market to process information. Therefore, the

efficiency of a market remains debatable since decades. According to traditional efficient market,

theory markets are efficient and investor decisions are based on the rational expectation of future prices

and price quickly incorporate the new information in a homogenous manner (Fama, 1965). Several

standard models of finance are based on the assumption of the efficient market hypothesis (EMH).

Subrahmanyam (2008) classifies standard finance models as (i) portfolio allocation based on expected

risk and return (ii) risk-based asset pricing models (iii) the pricing of contingent claims and (iv)the

Miller and Modigliani theorem and its augmentation by the theory of agency. The underlying rationale

of all classifications is value maximization through rational decision-making process. Strong empirical

support for EMH is found in the literature (Lucas, 1978; Lo & Hasanhodzic, 2010) but there remains

many questions unanswered like (a) why trading is done by individual investors? (b) Why factors other

than risk alter the returns across stocks.

The efficient market hypothesis is critically analyzed both empirically and theoretically, and

literature highlights several flaws like behavioral anomalies in modeling real-life security returns

(Shiller, 1999; and Summers, 1986). In order to answer the above-stated questions, researchers from

Page 23: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

2

social psychology interrupt in the financial world and find out that people behave in a very unusual

manner when there are monetary transactions. Imperfections in the market are attributed to numerous

cognitive biases (e.g., overconfidence, framing bias and loss aversion), human responses (social

influences, cultural norms, herding effect) and errors (investor overreaction) by behavioral economists

and investor’s decisions are sometimes very irrational and are often affected by emotional and

cognitive errors.

Herding behavior is one of the most popular behavioral explanations of market inefficiency and

excess volatility in financial markets. Investor choices on the basis of available information in a

financial market can be behaviorally explained as herd formation. This behavior often results in a

tendency of an investor to imitate the action of other market players. Herding is simply defined as

mimicking behavior where investors simply follow the market consensus or imitate the activities of

financial leaders (Hirshleifer & Teoh 2003).

Social interactions and psychological biases influence the decision-making process and a choice is

made from what is considered “rational”. So investor decision is not based exclusively on his own

information set rather it is a choice out of both, his judgments and how others are behaving in the

market. Therefore, Herding is a simple investment strategy based on the mimicking action of investors

based on market consensus (Bikhchandani & Sharma, 2000).

Theoretically, herding is classified into two main categories. One category tests herding behavior

with aggregate market data (Christie & Huang, 1995; Chang et al., 2000; Hwang & Salmon, 2004;

Chiang & Zheng 2010).The other category focuses on portfolio investors (e.g., Lakonishok et al., 1992;

Trueman, 1994; Welch, 2000). This study is an attempt to identify herding in major developed,

emerging and frontier markets using aggregate market data. This type of herding can be identified

using return dispersion or state space models. For return dispersion this study employed, linear and

nonlinear models proposed by Christie & Huang, (1995) and Chang et al. (2000), whereas herding due

to market consensus is examined by using state space model proposed by Hwang & Salmon (2004).

Page 24: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

3

Investor psychology and the environment in which decisions are made play a critical role in

the decision-making process of investor and sometimes prevent him from making rational choices.

Investor psychology is interpreted into behavioral biases that are explained through the investor’s

unavoidable tendency towards errors. Gervais, Heaton, & Odean (2011) find that overconfident

managers try their best to collect information that will improve their success rates and the values of

projects, and so tend to accept compensation contracts that involve excessive risk. Hence, they exhibit

herding behavior in the market.

Investor decision is highly affected by the value, norms, and belief of people living in a society.

All these attributes define the culture of a specific community. A major contribution of this research

is to impact of cultural differences on the presence and intensity of herding measure. Culture has been

scientifically defined in many ways since decades (Kroeber & Kluckhohn, 1952). This study relied

on the understanding given by Hofstede (1980). He defines culture as “the collective programming of

the mind distinguishing the members of one group or category of people from others”. This study uses

all six dimensions of Hofstede’s cultural dimensions in this regard. Return dispersion models

developed by Chang et al. (2000) is modified to test the presence of herding behavior.

Another limitation of previous studies is the use of the constant coefficient model in using

nonlinear return dispersion model, where the average measure of herding is assumed to be constant

over time. In the time of market stress, due to structural changes, these constant parameters fail to

uncover information about the market dynamics. Brown, Wei, & Wermers (2013) find more

pronounced herding behavior in mutual funds trade over time. Therefore, this research uses the time-

varying model to identify the changing effect of imitative behavior and the factor that determine this

dynamic nature of herding behavior.

Other than psychological and empirical evidence, this study also includes the effect of market

fundamentals like macroeconomic variables on herd formation. If the markets are efficient then

volatility in the market is explained by market fundaments and herding behavior cease to exist.

Page 25: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

4

Macroeconomic variables are fundamental in explaining market movements and expected to reflect

the market dynamics. The macroeconomic variables have long been used in research to figure out stock

market volatility (Bernanke & Kuttner, 2005; Rigobon & Sack, 2008). Specifically, the effect of

macroeconomic shocks and their effect on stock prices and volatility has been studied so far (Pearce

& Roley, 1985; and Bloom, 2009).The effect of these macroeconomic shocks and uncertainty shocks

like 9/11 on investor behavior is limited to developed markets only (Messis & Zapranis, 2014).

Therefore, this study attempt to explore the effects of macroeconomic shocks on the estimated herd

measures towards the market in a set of developed, emerging and frontier markets of Asia, Asia Pacific

and Europe. Previous studies on herding behavior include macroeconomic variable in the return

dispersion and state space models (Hwang & salmon, 2004; Tan, Chiang, Mason, & Nelling, 2008;

and Javaira & Hassan, 2015). These studies directly check the impact of macroeconomic variables on

herding behavior but this study is unique in a sense that the effect of unexpected variation in

macroeconomic variables is used to identify herding behavior.

When markets are integrated the financial crisis is transmitted from one market to another with

weak macroeconomic fundamentals. Chiang, Jeon, & Li (2007) suggest that during financial crisis risk

is transferred across markets due to contagion effect and herd formation further aggravates crisis in the

market. Therefore, this research investigates contagion due to herding in the period of financial crisis

between the sampled markets. Due to contagion the benefit of international portfolio diversification

eliminates. This situation results in the increase in co-movements of asset prices in two markets after

a crisis period. Economou et al. (2011) find a higher degree of co-movements in four European

markets. This study is an attempt to find out contagion of herding either due to macroeconomic shock

or crisis event.

Theoretical Background

Although significant, the theoretical background under the foundation of irrational behavior is

vague and kept aside in academic literature, policy and practice. In the literature of finance, the

Page 26: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

5

empirical findings on the behavioral disturbances have increasingly questioned the validation of

standard finance theory and models. This issue has gained importance and challenging because the

paradigm of behavioral finance and modern finance are differentiated with the viewpoint of the

theoretical building block and actual market behavior of an investor. Modern Finance explains the

investor decision on the basis of rationality and market efficiency. Whereas, proponents of behavioral

finance are of the view that investor behavior is bounded rational and collectively give rise to an

irrational market.

One of the major drawbacks of the behavioral finance research is the nonexistence of a unified

theory that can explain the origin caused and effects of investor irrational behavior. Behavioral finance

paradigm explains the complexity and dynamism of investor behavior and their decision making in a

complex system (Jacobs & Levy, 1989; Mitroi & Oproiu, 2014) through interdisciplinary theories. To

draw a theoretical background, it is necessary to coordinate the investors, security prices and markets

in a dynamic system.

Figure 1-1: Theoretical perspective of Financial Market Functioning; Source: (Tuyon & Ahmad, 2016)

From the above figure, it is clear that the investor behavior is the nucleus of the financial system

that determines the market and asset price behavior. Behavioral finance is based on the view that

investor are not fully rational and efficiency is not constant. The current theoretical foundation for

investors in behavioral finance paradigm based on the field of psychology are the bounded rationality

Market Behavior

Asset prices Behavior

Investors Behavior

Page 27: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

6

theory (Simon, 1955) and prospect theory (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979). According to psychology,

irrationality is a basic human trait (Ellis, 1976). It is argued that the anomalies are partially predictable

due to the human cognitive errors and Biases which normally leads to inefficiency (Schneider &

Lappen, 2000; Ritter, 2003). This offers support to hypothesis of the adaptive market efficiency Lo

(2004, 2005) as a representative theory for the financial market.

The theoretical perspective discussed above prove the collective effect of internal and external forces

namely, sociological, psychological and biological factors along with the modern finance paradigm on

investor behavior that ultimately shapes the asset pricing mechanism and overall market behavior.

Psychological Forces

Psychological forces affect the decision making and individual behavior through the influence of dual

cognitive-affective processes (Kahneman, 2003) errors and biases. These cognitive system thinking

generate errors in the decision-making process and these cognitive errors are collectively termed as

heuristics. Heuristics act as a rule of thumb to reduce the complexity of decision situation (Das &

Teng, 1999; Fuller, 1998; De Bondt, 1998). The biases also produced by the effective system of

cognition used in the decision-making process, these are sentiments, emotions, and mood (Etzioni,

1988).

Sociology Forces

In sociology investment in markets is considered as a social phenomenon, where individual

thinking decisions are not in isolation and the social influence occurs in a complex and uncertain

situation for decision making (Warneryd, 2001). This innate tendency is highlighted by Festinger

(1954) where people in social system compare their capacity and attitude to others and as a result it

affects their investment decisions. Keynes explain these traits as beauty contest where individuals

Page 28: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

7

decisions are taken by the belief system as others think and the way others behave in a market (Keynes,

1936). The examples of these traits are Herding, Cultural norms and Social Influence.

Biological Forces

The biological factors in human decision making are explained by the (Ellis, 1976). (Harlow &

Brown, 1990) argued that Individual risk tolerance is affected by the complex set of human

neurochemical system and personality characteristics. From a theoretical perspective, Murphy (2012)

provides an insight into the neuroscientific explanation of time-varying risk aversion and sequential

changes in human expectations. They further explain that the irrational behavior that causes mispricing

and ultimately inefficiency in financial markets is caused by the internally omitted biological

chemicals (Testosterone and Cortisol) that modify the brain state.

Theorizing and Conceptualizing Investor Behavior under Sociological and Psychological

Forces.

This dissertation has its theoretical foundation on the behavioral finance. Therefore, in this part

key theories explaining the application of behavioral finance in the decision-making process are

discussed. This research collectively tried to explain the rationality and irrationality argument in

investor decision making and tried to explain the architecture of bounded rational investor effects on

asset prices behavior and market behavior through sociological forces of herding behavior and culture

traits.

Bounded Rationality Theory

Bounded rationality theory was first presented by Simon (1955) and give an alternative

framework for human decision making. According to this theory, individual decision making is an

outcome of both rational and irrational elements. The decision taken by investors are generally

adaptive and goal oriented (Jones, 1999). Kahneman (2003) provide a conceptual framework of human

Page 29: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

8

decisions under the dual system of the human mind into intuition (system 1) and reasoning (system 2).

The first system is fast, emotional and effortless while the second system is relatively slower,

controlled and governed by rules (Tuyon & Ahmad, 2016). This theory solely fails to explain the

origin, cause, and effects of human behavior on decision making, rather it explains only the rational

and irrational component of the decision-making process (Ahmad, Ibrahim, & Tuyon, 2017).

According to literature, herding may occur due to the bounded rational behavior of investors because

their thinking process is affected by the variety of biases and follow a likely available rule of thumb

(Brunnermeier, 2001).

Prospect Theory

Kahneman & Tversky (1979) presented the prospect theory as an alternative model of decision

making under risk and uncertainty as the expected utility theory fails to explain the decision making

under risk and do not reflect the actual human behavior. This theory provides an alternative explanation

to the investor bounded rationality specifically under the uncertain situation. This theory evaluates

individual choice process under two phases, one is framing and the other is evaluation (Tuyon &

Ahmad, 2016). In the first phase, the individual frame a representation of acts, and outcome relevant

to the decision outcome. In a later stage, individuals assess all the available prospect and make choices.

Many scholars check the validity of applicability of this theory to asset prices like (Kliger &

Kudryavtsev, 2008; Hung & Wang, 2005; Barberis, 2013). According to this theory, the investment

decision making is influenced by some psychological factors that diverge them from rationality as

supported by the argument of bounded rationality as argued by Simon’s (1955) These psychological

factors are behavioral biases like herding behavior and could lead to decrease in investment returns

(Aggarwal, 2014). Therefore, in spite of following the rational logical processes for investment

decisions, investors generally make decisions based on these biases that exist in their mind.

Page 30: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

9

Theory of Mind

The existing theories of behavioral finance, namely prospect theory and Bounded rational theory

fails to explain the origin and cause of rational and irrational element in individual minds. Schlinger

(2009) & Jurist (2010) discuss the complexity of the mind and give an integrated framework of the

theory of mind based on the dual system of human minds as described by the neuroscience perspective.

Recently, cognitive science presented two systems of Human minds (Evans, 2003) namely cognitive

and effective system. The former one is linked with the beliefs, knowledge and intentions, and the later

one system that is accounted for emotions, sentiment, and mood (Poletti, Enrici, & Adenzato, 2012;

Alos-Ferrer & Strack, 2014). This system help in understanding the rational and irrational component

of the human mind and how they react in financial markets (Berlin, 2011). Several researchers applied

this theory to explain the fickle nature of financial system during the financial bubbles (De Martino,

O’Doherty, Ray, Bossaerts & Camerer, 2013). This theory can be applied to explain the irrational

herding behavior in stock markets specifically during extreme market stress and the surprise

component of fundamental announcements when they hit the global financial system.

The ABC Model

The theory of mind is one step ahead of the bounded rationality and prospect theory as it explains

the origin of decision-making process but fails to explain the causes and effects. The ABC model is

psychology based theory adopted to explain the cause and effects of irrational behavior on stock market

activity. This theory was developed by clinical psychologist Dr. Albert Ellis in 1950s. According to

this model, human behavior is an outcome of what people think and believe about themselves, other

individuals in the society and the world in general. The human system can be understood through ABC

system. Where A is the activating event, B is the core belief and C is the behavioral consequence

(Behavioral anomaly) (Ellis, 1976, 1991). More recently Brahmana, Hooy, & Ahmad (2012a, 2012b)

applied this theory to conceptualize the irrational behavior of investors in the stock markets through a

Page 31: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

10

psychological factor of mood. This theory can provide a helpful insight in explaining the sentiment-

driven herding behavior in a large set of global economies.

Conceptualizing

The above discussion provides two insight into the decision making the process of investors.

The origin of human behavior stems from the psychological factors. These psychological factors are

classified as both cognitive heuristics and affective biases (emotions, moods, and sentiments). These

biases along with sociological factors like herding and cultural traits cause the irrational investment

decision. These irrational investment decisions can be in the form of information use, investment

analysis, designing strategies and portfolio management strategies. If these strategies are affected by

the sociological and psychological factors, then they can ultimately affect the investment performance

and can result in an unfair determination of price and returns and exacerbated volatility due to increased

risk.

Figure 1-2: Conceptualizing the Irrational Investor behavior (Source: Tuyon & Ahmad, 2016)

Page 32: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

11

Motivation of Study

Over the last few decades, the importance of studying investors’ behavior has increased.

Specifically, when the associated impact of behavioral patterns with the stock prices is observed

(Blasco et al., 2012). It occurs when the traditional models fail to translate certain events (e.g bubbles)

in financial markets and the researchers try to consider the role of behavioral finance in explaining the

mechanics of investor decision making and its impact on stock prices.

During 90’s financial markets around the globe faced several financial crises. This poses a

question against the fragility of the financial system in front of economists and policymakers.

Researchers in the era realized the role of behavioral components associated with such episodes

(Devenow & Welch, 1996; Shleifer, 2000; Brunnermeier, 2001; Hirshleifer & Teoh, 2003). Cipriani

& Guarino (2008) argue that although the fundamentals are used to predict the episodes of crisis, the

probability of hitting the crisis exists for the country with sound macroeconomic fundamentals and

country with weak economic indicators. Fenzl & Pelzman (2012) explore the incompetency of

traditional theories in explaining and predicting the trends in financial markets and highlighted the role

of social and psychological forces working motivating the investor behavior. Economou et al. (2011)

claims that behavioral factors are closely linked factors behind the global financial crisis and

investigates the role of herding behavior during the Global Financial crisis of 2008 in four

Mediterranean stock markets. International capital markets and particularly emerging markets exhibit

more herding tendency (Teng & Liu, 2014). Increased pace of capital flows makes the global markets

more closed and vulnerable to shocks and crisis, which in turn increases the chances of contagion

under circumstances (Fischer, 1998).

Most of the previous literature is concerned with determining the fundamental linkages to this

crisis situation (Forbes & Rigobon, 2000). This research is motivated by the linkage that is not

explained by the fundamental one, rather it is a result of irrational investor’s behavior. Increase in risk

aversion, Financial panic, and herding behavior are examples of this linkage known as Pure contagion

Page 33: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

12

(Chiang et al., 2007). When an economy faces a shock, liquidity constraints compel them to take out

funds from the domestic and other markets due to the difference in economic fundamentals. This type

of trend is not only followed in domestic market but also in the foreign market and leads to shock that

is transmitted like a contagious disease (Teng & Liu, 2014).

With the emergence of behavioral finance little attention is paid to its linkage with culture.

Guizo, Sapienza, & Zingales (2006) studied that the economic outcomes might be affected by the

culture. The practices of finance are also affected by the culture of a society and an emerging field

called “cultural finance” has established itself, which was titled by Breuer & Quinten (2009). Culture

has gained the interest of academicians (Chui & Kwok, 2008; Breuer, Riesener, & Salzman, 2012). For

example, Chui & Kwok, (2008) investigate the impact of national culture on life insurance

consumption. Similarly, several authors document the role of culture in the development of financial

markets (De Jong & Semenov 2002; Dutta & Mukherjee 2012).

The relation of herding behavior and its impact on the stock market has been greatly explored

in literature but the focus of this research is to create a linkage between behavioral finance and cultural

finance. Culture and its effect as a variable have been studied in the literature (Chiang & Lin, 2015).

This study is unique in a way that it utilizes cultural dimensions as a cross-country determinants of

variance (as modulating variable) that change the magnitude of herding behavior in a cross-country

analysis.

This explanation makes the behavioral consideration relevant, as the financial decisions cannot be fully

explained under the traditional financial paradigm. Investors are prone to psychological biases and

affected by the social interactions. Thus, motivated by the above-stated argument this study in its

complete framework try to bridge the gap in the literature by investigating the impact of fundamental-

based shocks and sociological influences on the investor herding behavior.

Page 34: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

13

Research Gap:

This study draws following conclusions from critical theoretical and empirical literature review. There

are several questions raised in herding behavior research.

1. In a cross-cultural research, it is worthy to notice the differences in national culture especially

when investigating the herding behavior of an investor. National culture dominates the

investment decision making followed by their behavioral reaction to an information shock.

Therefore, in international stock markets, differences in national culture may provide some

insight in explaining the herd behavior of an investor. For example, eastern and Confucian

culture emphasizes ethics, humanism, obedience, and collectivism, indicating that a society

may have a low individualism, high power distance, low uncertainty avoidance, high

masculinity, and low long-term orientation. On the other hand, western culture is based on

reality, science, individualism, and happiness. Based on the ideals of human fundamental rights

that may prevent the emergence of herding behavior in developed markets. The purpose of this

study is to investigate the impact of culture on herding behavior of an individual investor and

to make a comparative analysis of this behavioral trait in three different cultures, Western

culture, Eastern culture and Confucian culture. This study is a contribution to the literature by

taking in to account the relationship between cultural dimensions and herding behaviors in a

cross-cultural research. Chang and Lin (2015) utilize five cultural dimensions to test the impact

of culture on herding behavior of an investor. This study in addition to dimensions used in

Chang & Lin (2015) utilize indulgence vs restraint to check the impact of culture as a

modulating variable on the intensity of herding behavior which is an added contribution.

2. Chiang et al. (2013) emphasize on the utilization of nonlinear reaction of investor behavior to

extreme market condition during large price swings. This study is an attempt to investigate this

behavior in states of market returns and volatility conditions. As Chiang et al. (2013) indicate

that the omission of these state influences in an empirical model is likely to result in inaccurate

Page 35: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

14

inferences regarding herding. The financial literature provides ample evidence of stock price

dynamics (Orléan, 2004; Akerlof & Shiller, 2009). Lux (1995) argues that market dynamics

and clustered volatility cannot be explained through rational bubbles, stationarity or rational

agent models, they explain the market dynamics through herding behavior and researchers

attest that stock prices continue to be abnormal and largely irregular in recent years (Blasco et

al., 2012; Chen, 2013). In a period of market stress, structural changes occur and constant

coefficient model fail to explain market dynamics (Balcilar & Demirer, 2014). When the

market undergoes extreme stress, structural changes are likely to result, and constant

coefficient estimators do not provide updated information to reveal market dynamics (Balcilar

et al., 2013). Therefore, this research is an attempt to identify nonlinear dynamic herding in a

large set of developed, emerging and frontier market.

3. Most of the research has documented the effect of unexpected variations in macroeconomic

variables or uncertainty shocks on stock market prices and volatility (Fama, 1981;

Wasserfallen, 1989; Pearce & Roley, 1985; Hondroyiannis & Papapetrou, 2001; Gjerde &

Saettem, 1999; Bloom, 2009). Messis & Zapranis (2014) find this effect in developed markets

of France, Germany, UK, USA, and China. This study motivates us to investigate the similar

effect to a large number of economies and contributes to the empirical literature by examining

the effect of unexpected component of macroeconomic variables on the correlation between

the US and other economies in a sample.

4. Previous research work like Coudert et al. (2011) examine the volatility spillover effect during

the financial crisis but ignore the pure linkages of contagion effect and the factors that

contribute to this effect. This study is an attempt to fulfill this gap by examining the contagion

of herding in the presence of adverse macroeconomic shocks and financial market crisis.

Messis & Zapranis (2014) conclude that mechanism of Chinese stock market fails to protect

investors from the contagion of herding in a limited set of developed economies but ignore the

Page 36: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

15

shift of contagion in developing economies. This research is a contribution towards identifying

countries in a large set of economies with lower effect of pure contagion to enjoy full benefit

of portfolio diversification.

5. This research work provides a complete framework of analysis in developed, emerging and

Frontier markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe, where economic, cultural, behavioral and

external factors are simultaneously integrated to provide a comprehensive analysis of herding

behavior. Therefore, in its unique design, this research is an attempt towards bridging a gap

between, cultural finance, behavioral finance, and standard finance.

Statement of the Research Problem

Current literature on herding behavior is mainly concerned with the identification of herding and its

market specific determinants (Tan et al., 2008). Individuals are prone to psychological biases that

influence their financial decisions; it is almost inevitable that their views of the world, as determined

by culture, play a role in how they act in financial markets (Shefrin & Statman, 2000). More

specifically in correlated markets, this mimetic behavior can lead to crisis spillovers or contagions in

adverse market conditions (Chiang et al., 2007). The recent turmoil in the global stock markets provide

reasons to believe that other than fundamental reasoning certain sociological factors and actions of

noise traders could have destabilized prices and pushed prices away from fundamentals. One of the

main underlying factors can be the herd behavior of investors. Therefore, there is an immense need to

identify imitating behavior of an investor particularly in the presence of diverse sociological (cultural)

and adverse macroeconomic (shocks and crisis) environment especially when markets are closely

linked, in a large set of developed, emerging and frontier markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe.

Page 37: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

16

Research Questions:

1. Does herding behavior of investor exist in Developed, Emerging and Frontier Markets of

Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe?

2. Which of the two measures (return dispersion or state space models) identify herding behavior

best in developed and emerging and frontier markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe?

3. Does external environment like culture affect the irrational behavior of investor?

4. What are the domestic and cross-market determinants of dynamic herding?

5. Do macroeconomic shocks have an impact on the estimated herd measures towards the

market?

6. Whether contagion of herding exists between the selected countries when adverse economic

conditions prevail in a specific country?

Objectives of Study:

The purpose of this research is to

1. To investigate the existence of herding behavior in Developed, Emerging and Frontier Markets

of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe.

2. To make a comparative analysis of return dispersion and state space models.

3. To investigate the impact of national culture on herding behavior of irrational investor.

4. To find out determinants of dynamic herding behavior.

5. To examine the effects of macroeconomic shocks on the estimated herd measures towards the

market.

6. To examine whether contagion of herding between the selected countries exists when adverse

economic conditions prevail in a specific country.

Page 38: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

17

The significance of the Study:

Over the past few decade, behavioral analysis have attracted the attention of both academic

researchers (Thaler, 2003; Shefrin’s, 2001) and practitioners (Sewell, 2005). Researchers of behavioral

finance have turned their focus towards the behavior of actual market participants from the traditional

models of behavioral finance that integrate ideas from psychological theories.

Theoretical Contribution:

This study has some theoretical implications for academicians. They are listed below.

For Risk management and Investment Decisions.

It is important to understand that how investors react in the presence of herd behavior in financial

markets and how they react to shift in trends and manage their portfolios. Above all how the risk affects

the expected return on investment.

According to economic models of portfolio theory, equity premium is the main reason of

participation of individual investors in the stock market (Hodgson, Breban, Streatfield, & Urwin.

2000). Theoretical models suggest that individual portfolio choice is derived by maximizing an

expected utility function conditional on their preferences and the rate of risk aversion is an important

parameter (Breuer et al., 2012). According to Markowitz model of portfolio theory, the individual risk

aversion parameters designs their choices between risky and riskless assets (Markowitz 1952). Risk

aversion is termed as a preference for a certain outcome over a prospect with an equal or greater

expected value (Tversky & Kahnemann 1981). Thus, according to theory more risk-averse usually

invest less in risky assets (Guiso, Haliassos, & Jappelli 2003). It is evident from empirical literature in

actual investor participate less in markets as implied by the standard portfolio theory and it can be

attributed to the inadequacy of the standard assumptions (Campbell, 2000).

In Behavioral finance evident irrationality of investor is explained through certain

psychological factors that give rise to the investor’s portfolio diversity (Shiller 2003). Heterogeneity

Page 39: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

18

in beliefs can be an outcome of intrinsic differences (Pompian, 2012). In a situation of high uncertainty

and complexity investors usually, ignore fundamental information and rely on their intuitions

(Kahneman & Riepe 1998). These intuitions give rise to several systematic errors and correlated

behavior in markets where investors overestimate their knowledge and underestimate risk and are

unable to control events (Giordani & Söderlind, 2006).

The psychology of an investor in a risky environment can be explained through sociological

forces like herding behavior and culture of a society that can provide a causal linkage from culture to

economic behavior (Guiso, Sapienza, & Zingales, 2009). The traditional relationship between risk and

return explained by the Capital Asset Pricing Model provides the basis for understanding the dynamics

of herding behavior on risk diversification. Chiang & Zheng (2010) stated that herd behavior describes

the increased correlation in trades due to the interaction of investors in stock market. So, in the

presence of herding behavior, a large number of securities are required in a portfolio to achieve the

same level of diversification due to the existence of an inferior degree of correlation. Herding has

negative implications in portfolio diversification, if there is a strong co-movement between stocks, the

benefit of diversification is eliminated as the stock prices tend to move in unison.

For Behavioral Asset Pricing Model

The risk involved in the pricing of investment under the current scenario has both fundamental

and behavioral components. Therefore, it is deemed necessary to incorporate behavioral factors like

herding while modeling the asset prices. As this research validates the effect of herding behavior and

its consequences on securities returns, therefore new asset pricing models suggested by several authors

should be utilized. For example, the behavioral asset pricing theory proposed by Shefrin and

Statman(1994), affects behavioral asset pricing model by Statman, Fisher & Anginer(2008) and

investor psychology in Hirshleifer (2001). By improving the information disclosure trading activity

of investors can be improved. This informational efficiency minimizes the risk of securities as prices

are determined on the basis of fundamentals. Better knowledge of market dynamics and clear

Page 40: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

19

understanding of factors behind irrational behavior could result in more accurate valuation, estimation,

and forecasting decisions.

For behavioral Portfolio Management

In a recent study Cuthberston, Nitzsche & O’Sullivan (2016) discuss the effect of behavioral biases on

fund managers, fund governance, and institutional structure. Therefore, the behavioral factor like

herding behavior can be easily incorporated into device investment analysis and maintain funds’

portfolios. The behavioral portfolio theory is given by Shefrin & Statman (2000) illuminates the need

to manage the risk arise through behavioral factors and its effect on investment portfolio returns, their

selection and diversification. Bollinger (2008) recommends adopting a combination approach by

utilizing the technical, fundamental, quantitative and behavioral factors collectively in order to design

management investment strategies. Along with behavioral approach, they can also incorporate the

effect of social influences like national culture. Policymakers should focus on the communications

channel with financial markets and manage the prospects of fluctuations in policy because herding can

aggravate in financial market due to change in macro information.

For culturally Diversified Markets

This study selects Developed, Emerging and Frontier Markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe.

Selection of these markets is based on two major reasons. First, this research is an attempt to make a

comparison of investor behavior between developed and emerging and frontier market. There are few

studies available where large number of markets are incorporated to test the herding behavior (Chiang

& Zheng, 2010; Chiang & Lin, 2015). In these studies only return dispersion model is employed, mean

risk based model of herding is ignored. While, Chen et al. (2013) incorporate both measures (return

dispersion and state space model) to test herding behavior in a large set off economies during a period

from 2000 to 2009 by employing firm specific daily returns data. This research added to empirical

literature in two ways, one by investigating herding in 31 stock markets using both measures but with

a larger data set with varying time length, secondly by employing industrial indices following the

Page 41: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

20

approach of Chiang & Zheng, (2010). Finally, this study contributes to the literature by making a

comprehensive analysis of culturally diversified markets. This contribution is a major focus of this

research.

Cross country investigation of investor behavior is incomplete if we ignore differences in

national culture. In a society people combine their values and conventional belief with their behavioral

norms to form a national culture. When applied to the financial market, investor reaction to information

arrival and the decision-making process is dominated by a culture of a society. Further, if a large

number of investors follows same investment strategy then this behavior can be translated into herd

formation. Therefore, the difference in national culture can help understanding the reasons behind

herding behavior. Hence, this study includes culture as an important factor in investigating herd

behavior in international stock markets.

Breuer & Quinten (2009) explain the advantage of incorporating cultural finance literature to

behavioral finance by saying “although Behavioral Finance assumes bounded rationality to be valid for

most countries, Cultural Finance implicitly supports the diverging relevance of certain behavioral patterns

between countries, and thus rationality defects”. Therefore, when an investor make cross-cultural

investment decisions, change in behavior become significant as we move from one society to another

due to social influence. Hence, one cannot ignore the role of culture in financial markets.

Unexpected macroeconomic environment and contagion of herding

A number of studies are available where researchers check the impact of unexpected components

of macroeconomic variables or uncertainty shocks like terrorist attacks on stock prices and volatility

(Fama, 1981; Pearce & Roley, 1985; Gjerde & Saettem, 1999; Bloom, 2009). Similarly, Messis &

Zapranis (2014) empirically investigate this impact on selected macroeconomic shock on herding

behavior of some developed economies towards Chinese stock market. This study motivates us to

investigate the similar effect to a large number of economies variable where this study contributes to

the empirical literature by examining the effect of an unexpected component of macroeconomic

Page 42: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

21

variables on the correlation between US and other economies in a sample. In order to figure out the

impact of certain macroeconomic shocks, this study employs Box-Jenkins methodology.

Financial contagion refers to transmission of crisis from one market to the other in different

locations (Corsetti, Pericoli & Sbracia, 2011). This is due to movements in asset prices in these

markets. Authors report two reasons for this contagion (Edward, 2000). Fundamental based contagion

where economic, financial, and trade linkages are the cause of this spillover effect. Second is the

behavioral approach where herding behavior is also responsible and plays important role in explaining

this contagion. This study is an attempt to separate this effect and examine financial contagion due to

herding behavior.

Practical Contribution

This study has several practical implications for practitioners and policymakers. Few are listed below

For Individual Investors

With the emergence of behavioral finance, few governments are designing a wide variety of programs

to provide financial and economic education to the general public and individual investors. The basic

purpose is to educate those individuals that are practically excluded from the formal financial sector.

They practically lack financial knowledge and make poor investment decisions. If these investment

decisions are influenced by the herd formation can lead to a huge disturbance in the financial markets.

Few researchers evaluate the impact of such program on subsequent financial behaviors (Lusardi,

2008; Lyons, 2010). The underlying benefit of these programs is based on lifecycle models and the

assumption of rational expectations, and the investors after this training sessions make optimal

decisions regarding saving and investment. Therefore, if the government of less sophisticated markets

provides financial education to the investors the problem of irrational decision making will resolve.

For Institutional Investors

Page 43: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

22

Institutional investors and particularly fund managers can get benefit from this study. As

origin, cause and effect of behavioral factor like herding could be utilized to device investment analysis

and related management strategies to implement certain decisions under the positive or negative

environment under the effect of this bias. Shefrin (2000), & Montier (2002) stress on the utilization of

behavioral biases in investment analysis to overcome the consequence inefficiency and fragility of the

financial system. The strategies devices by Baker & Riccardi (2014) can be utilized to get the full

benefit of optimal decision making.

For International Investors

This research has implications not only for the local investor but also for the international investor.

If the herding measures are correlated between two markets especially with global leaders then the

benefit of portfolio diversification is reduced as the same risk factors are transmitted across the markets

due to volatility spillovers or contagion of herding. This research has implication not only for the local

investor but also for the international investor. If the herding measures are correlated between two

markets then the benefit of portfolio diversification is reduced.

As economies are integrating, there are several trade ties and mutual benefits associated.

Therefore, while making investment decisions, both in local and foreign markets. A better

understanding of culture can help them achieve a sound decision. According to Shefrin (2000), an

investor should be well aware two things, one is his own “investment mistakes” and other is his

counterpart “error of judgment”. Therefore, by using this research, investors can educate themselves

about certain behavioral biases they are likely to be affected by and can take better steps to avoid them

and make decisions efficiently.

For Financial Market Regulators

This paper has highlighted one of the behavioral risk (herding behavior) stressed in Daniel

Hirshleifer & Teoh (2002). They suggest two steps to improve the public policy, one is designing of

such policies that can minimize the errors and second is to improve the efficiency of the market. Thus,

Page 44: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

23

the regulation of this risk factor will reduce the impact of irrational behavior and market imperfection.

Similarly, Suto & Toshino (2005) stress the need for governance of financial markets against the

behavioral risk factors. Asian markets are more vulnerable to sociological and psychological

inclinations as suggested by the (Kim & Nofsinger, 2007). Therefore, there is a need to frame the

financial regulations under the fund management industries in the markets of Asia. In the era of

globalization and transmission of shocks through behavioral channels has been validated through this

study, therefore there is an immense need to design global governance framework that will help the

international investors to play safely in the global financial market.

Organization of the Study

The basic structure of the thesis is given as follows:

Chapter 1 of the study includes a brief introduction, which outlines the purpose of research, the

gap in the literature, problem statement, main questions raised, objectives of the study and contribution

of the study (theoretical and practical).

Chapter 2, present a brief review of literature that includes the theoretical background and

framework of herding behavior and discusses the role of, culture and macroeconomic uncertainty in

investor herding behavior and how it affects the pricing mechanism underlying EMH. This section

also includes different models of herding, culture and its role in finance, its recent development and

discusses the relationship between behavioral and cultural finance.

Chapter 3, represents the research design, which includes the required data and methodology.

This section makes ways of linking the problem statement with outcome of the study.

Chapter 4, present results and their discussion in the light of theory and previous empirical

findings.

Chapter 5 provide the conclusion that includes summary of findings, implications of the study,

limitation of this research and recommendations for future research.

Page 45: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

24

Chapter 2

2. Literature review and Theoretical Framework

Literature review

Traditional Finance:

In the past thirty years, standard theories of finance face certain criticism on their applicability. As a

reaction behavioral explanation and theories emerged. Therefore, there is the immense need to

understand the classical paradigms of economics and Finance. This part of literature will throw light

on the foundations of standard finance from the perspective of individual behavior, their decision-

making process in financial markets and the resultant outcomes. In order to explain standard finance

two subsections are developed. In first section, this study discusses the rational preference of

individuals, the second section highlights the importance and implications of the efficient market

hypothesis.

Rational preferences

The rational expectation model is based on certain assumptions, these are “ 1) Individuals have

rational preferences, 2) they maximize their utility, 3) they make independent decisions by using

information” Ackert & Deaves, (2009).

According to Burton & Shah (2013), an investor is said to be rational, who make informed

decisions by making choices among certain alternative and given constraints in order to maximize their

utility. They further elaborate that according to utility theory, each individual owns a utility function

which is a representation of their investment choices that makes them better off.

Page 46: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

25

Efficient Market Hypothesis:

For more than thirty years, the efficient market hypothesis is considered as the building stone

of traditional financial system and a major investment theory. Since 90’s, financial economists widely

accepted this approach. Fama (1970) defines an efficient market as a market where active current

information is accessible to all market participants and market value of the individual security is

predicted by a large number of actively competing for rational profit maximizers. Individual and

aggregate stocks are efficient if they truly reflect all available information and with the arrival of news,

information is instantly incorporated in security prices (Malkiel, 2003).

About a century ago, Bachlier (1900) link the movement of stock returns to Brownian motion

while studying random processes in mathematical theory. After about fifty years this idea is elaborated

by Kendall(1953), he postulates that the commodity and stock prices follow a random walk. Cootner

(1964), Samuelson (1965), and Mandlebrot (2001) further supported this argument.

An efficient market is based on the notion of “random walk” or “fair game”. Former is based

on the idea that in an informationally efficient market future movement of the asset is independent of

the past movements. Whereas, later suggests that stock market speculation is a fair game, in which

overall none of the players gain a net profit (Bachelier, 1900).

Fama (1970) defines an efficient market hypothesis as a market, where all available

information is truly reflected in asset prices. He formally defines market efficiency in three levels

associated with the ability of a market to process information reflected in a stock price i.e., Weak form,

semi-strong form, and strong form efficiency. Weak form implies a random walk and prices

incorporates all historical information, the semi-strong form includes publically available information

which is reflected in stock prices of a firm, whereas strong form implies that prices reflect all private

and public information at any given time. Therefore, according to Fama (1970) market is efficient if

available information is classified as past intelligence, public intelligence, and privileged intelligence.

Page 47: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

26

EMH has its origin from Fama (1965) and Fama (1970). The rational expectation based theories

are later quantified by Sharpe (1964) named as Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), Arbitrage

Pricing Theory (APT) by Ross, 1976 and Black Scholes model of option pricing by Black (1972).

Both EMH and CAPM are interlinked as the CAPM is a test of EMH.

2.1.2.1 Empirical support for the efficient market hypothesis.

In 60’s efficient market hypothesis got heavy empirical support relied on serial correlation tests

and other mechanical trading rules. Niederhoffer & Osborne’s (1966) pointed out the monopolistic

access of insider information by a specialist or corporate managers which makes a strong form of

efficiency questionable. The methodology adopted to check efficiency is also criticized later by

Sweenay (1988). Taylor (1982) replaced the testing methodology and argued that the other tests

negated the random behavior of asset prices because traditional methods are not suitable to check

efficiency when there are trends. Instead, the author supported a price trend hypothesis. Studies prior

to 1970’s conclude that the markets are in general weak-form efficient.

According to Fama (1970), ample evidence supports the weak form and semi-strong form

efficiency whereas partial support is found for strong form efficiency with the exception of two papers

(Niederhoffer & Osborne’s, 1966; Schole, 1969). Similarly, Rendleman, Jones, & Latane (1982) find

out the reaction of the stock market to the quarterly earnings announcements. These findings support

the EMH as prices are adjusted back to equilibrium after the arrival of new information.

In modern literature, several studies validate the efficacy of efficient market hypothesis. Palan,

2004 finds efficiency in the valuation of stocks and options. Similarly, Timmermann & Granger (2004)

analyze the EMH from the perspective of a modern forecasting approach. Lo & Hasanhodzic, (2010)

examine the random and unpredictable behavior in Stock. Allen, Brealey & Myers (2011) analyzed

the assets of blue-chip companies and find a weak correlation in consecutive days returns, concluding

the non-predictability of future outcomes. While Wilson & Marashdeh (2007) explain that the co-

Page 48: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

27

integrated prices are consistent with EMH in the long run and inconsistent in short run. Similarly, Yen

& Lee (2008) presented a survey article that gives a chronological account of empirical findings and

concludes that evidence in favor of EMH still exists.

2.1.2.2 Critiques of the Efficient Market theory

In 1978 a special issue of Journal of financial economics was published that was designed for

the anomalies related to the efficient market hypothesis. In the editorial note Jensen (1978) elaborates

that although there is strong empirical evidence supporting EMH, there is evidence that is inconsistent

with the theory and cannot be ignored. They also raised question against the joint hypothesis. Ball

(1978) pointed out the inadequacy of asset pricing model which give rise to anomalous evidence.

Similarly, Thompson (1978) discusses that the abnormal returns are attributed to the inadequacy of

asset pricing model. Chiras & Manaster (1978) find the Chicago Board of Exchange (CBOE) market

inefficient due to the presence of abnormal profit for both member and non-members of CBOE.

According to literature, there are several anomalous findings in testing the joint hypothesis of

EMH and asset pricing model in equilibrium. It includes season effect of stock returns (Rozeff &

Kinney, 1976), January effect (Haugen & Lakonishok, 1988).

Later, Fama (1991) provides a second review of market efficiency literature and expands the

efficient market hypothesis by testing returns predictability using variables like dividend-price ratio,

earnings-price ratio, book-to-market ratio and various measures of the interest rates. Semi-strong form

and strong forms of efficiency are tested using event study methodology. With no exception, these

revisions also faced several challenges in the later years (Mishra, 2011).

Recent empirical research efforts are carried out on equity markets for the validity of the theory

in the developed and emerging economies. Empirical studies show that EMH is applicable in the Asian

stock market (Kim, Shamsuddin, & Lim, 2011). Mishra (2011) does not support random walk model

Page 49: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

28

for other developed markets (the US, UK, and Germany) and emerging economies (Brazil, India, South

Korea, China, Russia)

During Ball (2009) claims that the cause of the collapse of Lehman Brothers along with other

financial institutions during the global financial crisis was excessive faith in efficient markets that

resulted in market failure. Lee et al. (2010) examine the stationarity of real stock prices for a set of 32

developed and 26 developing economies and find that markets are inefficient during a period from

January 1999 to May 2007. Similarly, Eakins & Mishkin, (2012) investigated the strong form

efficiency and the results indicate market inefficiencies. Fakhry & Richter (2015) found increased

volatility and inefficiency during the recent financial and sovereign debt crises on the US and German

sovereign debt markets. Fakhry, Masood, & Bellalah, (2016) also find mixed efficiency during crisis

in GIPS markets. However, EMH is facing several criticism to date (Yao et al., 2014) and focus is

diverted to behavioral based anomalies (Hirshleifer, 2015).

Behavioral Finance

In reality, fundamental analysis based on efficient market hypothesis is unrealistic as it

completely ignores human behavior (Thaler, 1999). The hypothesis of rational investors and

instantaneous processing of information cannot be defined easily and is unrealistic due to unpredictable

human behavior. In order to overcome difficulties faced by the EMH a new paradigm emerged. In 90’s

a group of researchers with ample evidence against the EMH argues that this paradigm should be

replaced with the “Behavioral finance” approach (Thaler, 1999; Haugen, 1999; Shleifer, 2000). The

presence of anomalies and difficulty of traditional models to deal with the problems stimulates the

development of this approach. Behavioral finance is an emerging field of finance that explain how

psychological factors affect the behavior of an investor and influence their decision-making process in

financial markets that has an ultimate effect on asset prices. It serves as an alternative block of each of

the foundation block of standard finance model (Statman, 2008). According to Shefrin (2000),

Page 50: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

29

Behavioral finance is “a rapidly growing area that deals with the influence of psychology on the

behavior of financial practitioners”.

Barber & Odean (1999) declare that “people systemically depart from optimal judgment and

decision making. Behavioral finance enriches economic understanding by incorporating these aspects

of human nature into financial models.”

Glaser et.al, (2004) describes behavioral Finance as a field of study that relates market

phenomena with individual behavior by using the wisdom from both financial theory and

psychological field. Therefore, behavioral finance uses behavioral biases to explain certain anomalies

of standard finance models and provide measures to overcome them.

Behavioral finance literature has two classifications. First is detection of anomalies and their

explanation through behavioral models (Bondt & Thaler, 1985) and second is identification of biases

or individual behavior that classical theories of rational behavior fail to explain. (Odean, 1998).

There are various viewpoints in the literature about behavioral finance. The basis of this

paradigm can be explained by understanding the limits to arbitrage, which argues that in a market less

informed traders cause a disturbance that cannot be easily corrected by the informed traders (Barberis

& Thaler, 2003). Therefore, investor irrationality has a long-term and significant effect on the asset

prices. In order to explain this irrational behavior and inefficiency in asset markets behavioral finance

extract empirical evidence from cognitive psychology, where biases are formed due to the preferences,

beliefs, and means in which decisions are made, (Barberis & Thaler, 2003). Schindler (2007) states

that behavioral finance is an integration of three distinct fields of studies, where we combine

psychology, sociology, and standard finance to come up with the idea of behavioral finance. Where

psychology explain that how people exhibit certain biases systematically while making their

investment decisions based on their beliefs and preferences. Sociology help to explain the fact that a

large number of decisions made by investors is an outcome of social interaction rather than taken in

isolation. It is against the assumption of EMH that decisions are made without any external influence.

Page 51: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

30

Figure 2-1: Source: Schindler (2007)

Theories of Human Behavior:

In order to explain irrational investor behavior, few theories were presented by the authors derived

from psychology and sociology. Few of them are prospect theory and heuristics.

2.2.1.1 Prospect Theory:

Kahneman & Tversky (1979) are the founders of prospect theory and Daniel Kahneman was

later awarded Nobel Prize for economics. They are considered fathers of Behavioral Finance. Prospect

theory is based on the idea that people usually don’t always act rationally and under the condition of

uncertainty there are psychological biases due to certain psychological factors that influence their

choices.

The value maximization rule is different from standard finance. According to Prospect theory

gain and losses are considered rather than final wealth position. Schwartz (1998) postulates that instead

of the final state of wealth, investors normally evaluate their outcomes of losses and gains relative to

some reference points. Prospect theory establishes that people usually take riskier decisions if they

Behavioral Finance

Finance

SociologyPsychology

Page 52: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

31

face a possibility of losing money with a goal of loss aversion. Therefore, according to prospect theory,

portfolio allocation is based on the highest prospective utility that is obtained by the computation of

potential gains and losses. According to this theory, the investment decision making is influenced by

some psychological factors that diverge them from rationality as supported by the argument of

bounded rationality by Simon’s (1955). These psychological factors are behavioral biases like herding

behavior and can lead to decrease in investment returns (Aggarwal, 2014).

2.2.1.2 Heuristics:

These are the simple efficient rule of thumbs proposed to explain the decision-making process

of investors, especially when available information is incomplete or problems are complex (Park

Sabourian, 2011). Tversky & Kahneman (1981) describe the effect of human heuristics on the

investor’s decisions and argued that heuristic can be simple judgmental operation substitute for

complex problem-solving. They defined it as a strategy that most of the times yield a right solution

when applied to a given set of problems. Brabazon, (2000) explain heuristic as rule of thumbs that can

be applied in an uncertain situation and environment for making decisions.

Behavioral Biases:

Behavioral finance is laid on a foundation that a significant number of investors are affected by

behavioral biases that make their financial decisions irrational. These biases usually applied to

financial problems come from cognitive psychology literature. Shefrin (2007) defined bias as “bias is

nothing else but the predisposition towards error”. Researchers distinguish a long list of behavioral

biases; almost fifty of them are applied in different studies. Few researchers classify biases as

heuristics, while others call them judgment, belief or preferences, but many other classify them along

cognitive or emotional lines. List of these biases is presented in Appendix 1. Out of these biases, the

Page 53: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

32

main focus of this research is to investigate herding behavior. A thorough literature in this field of

behavioral finance is discussed in next section.

Herding Behavior:

Investor behavior in the market is often influenced by others. Investors usually adopt the

behavior of other by foregoing their own rational analysis. Herd behavior in investors leads to a

convergence of action (Hirshleifer & Teoh 2003). Christie & Huang (1995) defined herding as

“individuals who suppress their own beliefs and base their investment decisions solely on the collective

actions of the market, even when they disagree with its predictions”.

Herding can be best explained with an example given by Keynes (1936), an investor in the

market behaves like judges in a beauty contest, where the decision is based on others judgment rather

than on they actually think is the most beautiful. Shiller (2006) argues that herding is an irrational

behavior where investors imitate others blindly in the market. This is the most common and dangerous

mistake that is made by investors in the market while making an investment decision. The major

concern is not whether investor imitates others blindly but rather focused on why? To date, several

researchers tried to answer this question by separating true herding(intentional) and spurious herding

(Bikhchandani & Sharma, 2000; Holmes et al., 2013; Gavriilidis et al., 2013; Economou et al., 2015b;

Galariotis et al., 2015)

According to literature, there are two opposite views of herding: Rational and irrational

(Bikhchandani & Sharma, 2001). Rational view is based on the idea that optimal decision-making

process is sometimes altered by incentive issues or information difficulties. This type of herding arises

when investors decision follows Bayes rule by duplicating the decisions on others actions. According

to Badddeley (2010), the results of Bayesian models can be right only if the generated signal

transmitted down by the forerunners follow the right path. Hirshleifer & Teoh (2003) support this fact

by arguing that it is very natural to observe irrational behavior in rational settings. The irrational view

Page 54: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

33

is due to psychological bias where investors follow each other blindly while making a decision in the

market. This type of herding arises when investors base their decisions on emotional, sociological or

Psychological factors. Therefore, it can be argued that investor behavior in financial settings can be

irrational rational. Whether this decision is a result of an emotional reaction to the information or due

to “Herd Instinct” in financial decision making.

Welch (2000) discusses several incentives available to the investor for exhibiting herd behavior

in the market. These incentives can be Sanction on deviants, utility networks, positive payoff

externalities, informational externalities, agent-principal payoffs and many. All of these incentives are

theoretically defined and discussed.

Theories of Herding Behavior

Prior research explains herding pattern in three different aspects. First set explain the

psychology related effects of herding, which is related to the contagion of sentiment, i.e., behavioral

aspect of herding. Goldbaum (2008) attributes herding to the psychology of investor where a sense

of security is obtained by following the action of the majority. This type of herding is irrational of

near rational. Pingle (1995) conduct an experiment to figure out reasons of herding, they conclude that

investors herd after a change in decision-making environment, mostly in a competitive environment,

especially when they are taking decision for the first time. Lux (1995) based their decisions entirely

on observations as the available information set is limited and reliance on least available information

can lead to herd formation. The market is dominated by winners and driven by optimistic traders, rest

of the pessimistic investors follow the actions of optimistic ones.

The second set is relying on the effect driven by information set and rely on a model of

informational cascades. The action of more informed investors generate information for the less

informed investors and this information set is more valuable for the followers (Shleifer & Summers,

1990; Calvo & Mendoza, 2000; Chari & Kehoe, 2004; Froot, Scharfstein & Stein, 1992; Avery &

Page 55: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

34

Zemsky, 1998). In certain situations, investors largely based their decision on others judgment. It is

assumed that the previous decision taken exhibits private information of agent in the market. Use of

the available information is beneficial because the collection of private information can be time-

consuming and costly. This whole process ends up in herding behavior, where investor solely or to

some extent based their decision on available past information set (Banerjee 1992; Welch, 2000;

Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, & Welch 1992).

The final set of research is concerned with the reputational concern of manager that cause a

principal-agent problem. According to Morck, Shleifer, & Vishny, (1990), managerial performance in

an industry is evaluated on the basis of firm performance relative to overall industry and a bad

performance can lead to the firing of top management. Hence a manager with reputational concern

blindly follow the evaluation and forecasts of others and show his ability as an efficient agent by

imitating the footsteps of others. This type of herding is rational, utility maximizing, conscious, and

exogenous (Parker & Precter, 2005). Several authors provide evidence on the basis of reputational

concern of managers where they explain different kinds of agents. Scharfstein & Stein (1990); Zwiebel

(1995); Trueman (1994); Graham (1999). More recently, (Blake et al., 2015; Broeders et al. (2016)

investigate this type of herding in buying/selling of stocks, bonds, and other asset classes.

Models of Herding Behavior

In literature, empirical methodologies on herding are classified into two major categories

(Spyrou, 2013). The first type depends on microdata and focuses on a herding of a specific investor

type such as institutional investors. Lakonishok et al. (1992) and Sias (2004) present model to measure

this type of herding. The second type is, herding toward market consensus and is related to investor

type that relies on collective price and market activity data and is focused on the behavioral aspect of

herding. This type of herding is measured by Christie & Huang (1995), Chang et al. (2000) and Hwang

& Salmon (2004).

Page 56: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

35

Herding based on microdata is modeled by Lakonishok et al. (1992; LSV hereafter) and Sias

(2004). The basic idea behind LSV measure is that if a money manager can sell (buy) excessive

individual stocks then there exist herding behavior to the extent of that particular stock. The herding

is calculated as the ratio of net holdings (net buyers of the particular stock) to total institutional stock

holdings in that period excluding the adjustment factor due to the rise of a number of active buyers. If

there is herding then there is a cross-sectional increase in expected returns of the above metric, and in

the absence of herding, no expected value remains same.

Sias (2004) is second in the row to extend the model for institutional herding. They argue that

the number of institutional buying in each quarter will vary from one time to the previous time. It

means that institutional holdings will vary among cross-sections. If an investor follows this own

actions by trading in or out of the same assets then herding behavior can be measured by cross-sectional

correlation of demand of assets between times under consideration. This methodology evaluates the

position of institutional investors holding by the fraction of outstanding demand in each quarter. In

each time period position of the holder can be estimated as, If holdings decreases (increases) then the

investor is a seller (buyer).

The difference between two measures is that Lakonishok et al. (1992) measures cross-sectional

position indirectly, while Sias (2004) provides a direct measure of institutional investors herding

behavior among cross sections.

Herding towards market consensus is measured by return dispersion and state space models.

The first dispersion model is developed by Christie & Huang (1995), where they used cross-sectional

standard deviation (CSSD) on daily and monthly data and supports the prediction of asset pricing

model. He further concludes that herding is not an important determinant of asset pricing mechanism.

Future studies based on this model find mix results on the existence of herding behavior in extreme

market condition. Demirer & Kutan (2006) tested Chinese market and find no evidence of herding by

employing the same model. The major drawback of this approach is to find evidence of herding in

Page 57: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

36

extreme returns. According to empirical literature, herding behavior is usually observable during stress

periods but it may occur over the entire distribution (Christie & Huang, 1995). Therefore, this model

only captures herding in extreme events and fails to find out herding over time.

The second model of dispersion is presented by Chang et al. (2000). According to this measure,

during extreme market conditions return dispersion and market returns exhibit a nonlinear relationship.

The quadratic factor of returns in the model gives negative and significant results in the presence of

herding behavior. They investigate US, Hong Kong, Japan, Taiwan and South Korean markets and

find partial evidence of herding in Japan and significant herding behavior is observed in two emerging

markets of Korea and Taiwan. In both countries presence of herding is attributed to the presence of

speculative investors, the inefficiency of reliable company information and lots of government

intervention.

The second type of methodology of measuring herding is based on state space model proposed

by Hwang & Salmon (2004). This method focuses on the cross-sectional variability of factor

sensitivities. This particular model is chosen in this study for a number of reasons. First, the method

considers herding as a measure of the behavior of investors who track the performance of specific

factors, styles or macroeconomic signals, and thus proceed on buying or selling individual assets at

the same time disregarding their underlying risk-return relationship. Second, state space models allow

the detection of herding both in the normal and extreme market and provide a comprehensive analysis

of herding over time (Demirer et al., 2010). Finally, the model is free from the impact of idiosyncratic

factors as it focuses only on the variability of factor sensitivities (Hwang & Salmon, 2004). Chen

(2013) investigated herding towards market consensus by employing all three models in global stock

exchanges.

Empirical Evidence on Institutional Investor Herding

Lakonishok et al. (1992) examine positive feedback trading and herding using data of mutual

funds on US market and find no evidence of herding of pension fund managers. Only partial herding

Page 58: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

37

is observed in smaller stock holdings. Similarly, Grinblatt et al. (1995) investigate momentum and

herding in mutual fund industry of US market and find evidence against herding but in favor of herding

behavior. Wermers (1999) also find same behavior in US mutual fund industry. Nofsinger & Sias

(1999) investigate herding in the US and find the positive relationship of annual net institutional

holdings on returns from a period of 1977-1996. They conclude herding is present in the market due

to the greater impact of institutional investors on prices than individual investors. Kim & Wei (2002)

find the comparatively higher level of herding in institutional investor than an individual investor and

this effect is more pronounced in foreign investors. Li et al. (2016) investigate the behavior of Chinese

institutional and individual investors and find a high level of herding in informed institutional

investors. Lobão & Serra (2006) find significant institutional herding in Portuguese market using LSV

(1992) model. Similarly, Patro & Kanagaraj (2012) also employed LSV (1992) model in India mutual

fund industry and observe significant herding compare to developed markets.

Sias (2004) find herding as a result of institutional investor imitating behavior in trade of

securities over time and momentum strategies play a role in investor herding behavior. Li & Yung

(2004) find similar behavior in American ADR return. Strong evidence of institutional herding

behavior is observed in Choi & Sias (2009) model. They observe almost 39% correlation in the

institutional holding of one quarter to another quarter. Similarly, Guiterrez & Kelley (2008) find the

higher intensity of herding behavior in investor purchases and conclude that prices destabilize due to

buy herds and revert back to equilibrium due to sell herd formation. Kim & Nofsinger (2007) observe

that Japanese investor exhibit low level of herding than the US institutional investor over the cross

sections. Iihara et al. (2001) found herding of institutional herding in the Japanese market in yearly

interval ownership holding data. Chang & Dong (2006) also observe similar results by relating herding

to an idiosyncratic component of volatility. The presence of institutional herding with industry effect

is also documented well in international markets, (Voronkova & Bohl, 2005; Zhou & Lai, 2009; Choi

Page 59: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

38

& Sias, 2009; Gebka & Wohar, 2013; Gavriilidis et al., 2013). Other studies include (Andreu et al.,

2009 & 2015; Chaudhary, 2011; Walter & Weber, 2006).

Empirical Evidence on Aggregate Market Activity

Henker et al. (2006) find no herding in the Australian market by using intraday data. Cajueiro

& Tabak (2009) find out evidence of herding in extreme price movements in Japanese market using

Chang et al. (2000) model. Gleason, Mathur & Peterson (2004) used the model on US Exchange

Traded Funds (ETF) intraday data and find no herding during periods of extreme market movements.

Chiang & Zheng (2010) investigate 18 world markets and observe significant results in advanced and

Asian markets in bullish market trends. They find no herding in Latin American markets. Their results

depict more pronounced herding in a crisis situation and towards US market. Caporale et al. (2008)

find the presence of market-wide informational cascade in Greece. Similarly, Kapusuzoglu (2011)

finds the presence of herding and contagion of herding towards US market in turkey during the crisis.

Economou et al. (2011) investigate Italian, Greek, Portuguese and Spanish markets and observe no

herding in Spanish and Greek markets in the crisis period. They also find herding away from US market

rather than with it. Herding is observed in Greece and specifically in upmarket condition. During this

period correlation across countries is observed confirming the existence of common global component

responsible for herding behavior in the local market.

Caparrelli, D'Arcangelis, & Cassuto, (2004) investigate herding behavior in Italian stock

market. Henker, Henker, & Mitsios (2006) use intraday data and find no evidence of herding in the

Australian market by employing both Christie & Huang (1995) and Chang et al. (2000) model.

Cajueiro & Tabak (2009) investigate Japanese stock market and report herd formation in extreme price

movements using Chang et.al (2000) model. Similarly, Tan et al. (2008) investigate Chinese A and B

shares markets and find significant herding in both up and down market. Whereas, Chiang & Zheng

(2010) investigate same markets but find herding only in down market. Demirer, Kutan, & Chen (2010)

Page 60: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

39

investigate Taiwanese market at sectoral level and in the overall market and find significant results

especially during a market downturn. Prosad, Kapoor, & Sengupta (2012) find the presence of herding

in Indian market only in a crisis situation. Javed, Zafar, & Hafeez (2013) find no herding in Pakistani

market. Philippas et al. (2013) identify herding in US real estate investment trust (REIT) by using

CSAD model and find herding behavior due to macro shocks of REIT funding conditions and

deterioration of investor’s sentiment. Demirer et al. (2014) investigate the existence of herding in

American Depository Receipts (ADRs) and infer more evident herding at sector level than country

level. Hsieh, Yang, Yang, & Lee (2011) investigate 12 Asian markets by using return dispersion

models and find significant herding behavior. Garg & Gulati (2013) find no evidence of herding in

Indian stock market by employing Chang et al. (2000) under normal market conditions. Similarly,

Javaira & Hassan (2015) identify no evidence of herding during normal market conditions but

significant herding behavior during a crisis situation in Pakistani stock market.

In the recent years, Chiang, Tan, Li, & Nelling, (2013) estimated the return dispersion model

by using a time-varying approach through Kalman filter estimation and find out dynamic herding in

the US and ten Pacific-Basin markets. All markets except US display significant herding behavior.

Similarly, Yang & Chen (2015) investigate the time variation of herding behavior in Chinese, Hong

Kong, and Taiwanese market and find significant herding in greater China stock markets specifically

during the global financial crisis. They also observe that Chinese and Taiwanese markets exhibit a

higher response to US market factors and exhibit higher herding tendency during a turbulent period.

By using Hwang & Salmon (2004) model, Khan, Hassairi, & Viviani (2011) find the significant impact

of the global financial crisis on the herding tendency of UK, Italian, French, and German markets.

More specifically recent empirical literature following the particular market state has been

reported by several researchers. For example during the period of negative market returns (Zhou &

Lai, 2009; Goodfellow et al., 2009; Demirer et al.,2010; Economou et al., 2011; Gavriilidis et al., 2013;

Holmes et al., 2013) significant herding during positive market returns (Economou et al., 2015a;

Page 61: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

40

Economou et al., 2015b) under low volume state (Tan et al., 2008; Economou et al., 2011) and high

volume state (Gavriilidis et al., 2013; Economou et al., 2015b) the effect of declining volatility

(Economou et al., 2011; Holmes et al., 2013; Economou et al., 2015b), and high volatility (Blasco et

al., 2012; Economou et al., 2015b).

The above-mentioned studies are mainly focused on identifying the presence of herding behavior

in different economies. This research is different from the above-mentioned results in many ways, first,

this study tried to examine the presence of herding behavior using industrial level data in a large

dataset. Second, the major focus of this study is not merely the evaluation of herding behavior rather

this study incorporates both irrational component of fundamental factors along with social influences

like culture to provide a comprehensive analysis of investor irrationality. Specifically in a broader set

of global economies. Finally, this study also determines effect of pure contagion caused by the crisis

situation and macroeconomic information that has previously been ignored in the literature.

Culture:

For centuries understanding and defining culture has been of scientific appeal1. According to

Hofstede (1991), everything in the life of a person is affected by the culture of a society. Therefore, when

a study integrates a particular phenomenon in the cross-country analysis, it shall also consider culture. In

literature, there are several definitions of culture. Hofstede (1980) defines culture as “the collective

programming of the mind distinguishing the members of one group or category of people from others”.

Hill (2008) defines culture as “a system of values and norms that are shared among a group of people

and that when taken together constitute a design for living”.

From the definition of culture, it seems difficult to calculate culture in a quantitative manner.

In previous years several attempts are made to measure culture, where scales and dimensions are

1 See Kroeber and Kluckhohn, 1952.

Page 62: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

41

constructed to differentiate national culture. They are in the form of large-scale surveys, conducted

and filled by individuals of a society, mean values are identified in order to obtain quantitative cultural

characteristics (Reuter, 2011).

Schwartz (1994), Hofstede & Hofstede (2001) and House et al. (2004) give different

approaches on cultural dimensions. Among these dimensions, Hofstede’s and Schwartz’s are the most

extensively used in literature. Schwartz (1994) finds out three dimensions: egalitarianism vs.

hierarchy, mastery vs. harmony, and conservatism vs. autonomy conducted a survey of teachers and

student in 38 countries. Similarly, House et al. (2004) conducted a survey of 931 different

organizations and to 17300 managers in 62 countries from 1994 to 1997. They found nine dimensions

of culture: future orientation, assertiveness, gender equality, in-group collectivism, human orientation,

institutional collectivism, power distance, performance orientation, and uncertainty avoidance.

Hofstede & Hofstede (2001) used survey analysis during 1965-1971, collected data from IBM

employees in 50 countries and find five cultural dimensions. These dimensions are uncertainty

avoidance, power distance, masculinity, individualism, and long-term orientation.

Hofstede’s cultural dimensions are criticized by several authors. Kirkman et al. (2009) argued

that the dimensions are developed on the assumption that there is homogeneity in the country and did

not consider the effect of subcultures. McSweeny (2002) and Craig & Douglas (2006) state that the

study is conducted in 60’s and 70’s and evolve with the changing culture driven by economic growth,

globalization, or migration and cultures evolve during the time.

After all this criticism Hofstede & Hofstede (2001) repeated the analysis using data from 400

non-IBM employees from 30 countries and find a strong correlation between IBM and non-IBM

employees responses. Therefore, it is easier to interpolate these results to other contexts. Similarly,

House et al. (2004) criticize that the scales are determined only after the results of the survey, this

technique has a problem of biasness and influence the results. They further argue that the problems of

empirically-driven dimensions can be resolved by increasing the sample size and Hofstede & Hofstede

Page 63: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

42

(2001) fulfilled this requirement. In spite of all criticism, Hofstede’s dimensions are still used as most

clear simple and applicable measure in empirical analysis. (Kirkman et al., 2009).

Cultural theory has been in discussion since last decades and culture has become a

multidisciplinary approach since last few decades and several streams of research ranges from

sociology (Weber 1962), cognitive and social psychology (Hofstede 1991), anthropology (Malinowski

1961) and history to economics and management science (Meyer & Rowan, 1977; Stulz & Williamson,

2003) are found in literature. This distinct and broad field of research comprises a diversity of

approaches and provide a support for Cross-cultural analysis in fields mentioned above2.

Empirical Studies of Cultural Finance:

This study is an effort to investigate investor behavior in financial markets in the cross-country

analysis. Stulz & Williamson (2003) suggest that there are three main effects of culture in finance:

First, culture modify economic values in a country (e.g. use of alcohol in a country is allowed while is

prohibited in other countries); second, institutions are governed according to culture (difference in

legal systems across countries); third, economic resources are allocated according to culture (few

countries allocate more resources towards weapons and some spend more on infrastructure). Effect of

culture is mainly studied in a context that how it effect the laws and regulations. Anderson, Fedenia,

Hirschey, & Skiba, (2011) argued that culture not only affect investor behavior through legal and regulatory

framework but also has a direct effect. Similarly, Sapienza (2006) argued that due to difficulty in

measurement and ambiguity, the effect of culture is ignored is past.

Using culture in the financial decision-making process is an emergent field. Several authors

investigate the effect of cultural dimension on financial environment. In most of the cross-cultural

research, the authors have opted one dimension only and all dimensions collectively are rarely used to

2 Different cultural dimensions suggested by the authors unambiguously distinguish cultural groups from each other (Hofstede, 1980, 2001; Hall, 1985; Hall and Hall, 1990; or House et al., 2004).

Page 64: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

43

investigate their impact on investor behavior. The individualism is the most researched dimension

among all both empirically and theoretically. Chui, Titman, & Wei (2010) investigated the impact of

individualism on momentum profits, and find that investors in these countries and more overconfident.

This overconfidence results in excessive trade and generates momentum profits.

Other dimensions are also investigated like, Stultz & Williamson (2003) study the effect of

culture on financial institutions of a country. De Jong & Semenov (2002) study the effect of higher

level of masculinity and lower level of uncertainty avoidance on the stock market development in

OECD countries. Similarly, Ferris, Jayaraman, & Sabherwal (2013) conclude that overconfidence is

negatively related to long-term orientation and uncertainty avoidance, whereas, it is positively linked

with individualism. Schmeling (2009) uses uncertainty avoidance and individualism as a measure of

overreaction and herding behavior and conclude that stock returns are greatly influenced by investor

sentiments in such markets. Chang & Lin (2015) studies the effect of national culture on herding

behavior of an investor in a set of 50 stock markets and find a significant effect of culture on herding

behavior of investor.

Contagion

The interconnectedness of stock markets is defined as stock market integration. The famous

Markowitz portfolio theory states that for risk diversification investor rather than investing in single asset

choose a proportion of assets to make a portfolio. Henry Markowitz states, ‘Diversifying sufficiently among

uncorrelated risks can reduce portfolio risk toward zero’.3 So an investor can diversify his risk by investing

either in the national or international market. The benefit of this diversification is associated with lowest

and calm connections between the markets. If this market behaves homogeneously benefit of

diversification can be eliminated due to contagion effect. Levy & Sarnat, (1970) stated that investor can

3 Statement given in an interview with Wall street Journal on November 3, 2008

Page 65: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

44

get a benefit of international portfolio diversification if only stock markets are not integrated. As Bakeart

& Harvey, (1995) argues that the diversification of global systematic risk is almost impossible as the

markets share common sources of risk, therefore they behave in similar. This effect can be seen in the event

of Asian Financial Crisis of 1997 and Global Financial Crisis of 2007-2009. During this time period, most

of the integrated markets share the same level and source of risk. In the presence of complete market

integration, the expected risk and return of integrated markets is same (Bakeart & Harvey, 1995).

The connections in stock markets can be defined in two ways, one is the increased level of

interdependence among markets near complete integration. This is an extreme level of interdependence in

which repeated shocks become a part of market equilibrium (Forbes & Rigobon, 2002). In this case, before

and after the crisis there shall be no considerable variation followed by interdependence no “contagion”.

Forbes & Rigobon (2002) further elaborate the fact as if markets are highly correlated than both in crisis

and stable condition they will behave in a similar manner, and do not exhibit abnormal shocks, this effect

cannot be defined as contagion but simple interdependence.

The second channel considers contagion out of the market system. Contagion is epidemic and

spread like a disease. In the presence of contagion, the markets are not fully integrated and show significant

signs of shock transmission during turbulent periods (Corsetti et al., 2011). The term contagion into

literature has attracted the attention of economist in mid-1990s when the spread of financial crisis

approaches certain emerging markets that were fundamentally strong and are an example for the

policymakers of fundamentally unhealthy nations.4 In literature, contagion is defined in various ways

but simply contagion is the transmission of shock across the borders. Edward (2000) defines contagion

as the excess co-movement of returns after a change in market fundamentals or common shocks.

Kaminsky & Reinhart (2000) associate the probability of domestic crisis with having a knowledge of

crisis elsewhere. Edward (2000) define economic contagion as “situations where the extent and

4 See Masson (1998) for complete discussion.

Page 66: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

45

magnitude to which a shock is transmitted internationally exceeds what was expected ex-ante”. They

further elaborate that contagion is the excess co-movement of returns after a change in market

fundamentals or common shocks. The major reason behind this shock can be financial imbalances

across the border, housing bubbles, and lack of transparency, securitization, and complex financial

instruments. During contagion level of volatility, transmission is very high and further exacerbated

into panic due to irrational investor behavior. Bekaert et al. (2014) define “contagion” as co-

movements of markets and volatility spillover during crisis periods compared to non-crisis periods.

Leung, Schiereck, & Schroeder, (2017) investigate the contagion of crisis between exchange rate and

equity markets and observe the investors behavior leads to irrational phenomena like financial panics

(pure contagion) in excess of that implied by macroeconomic fundamentals (fundamental contagion).

There are three channels where shocks are transmitted to other economies, fundamental-based

contagion, common cause contagion and pure contagion (Moser, 2003)

Fundamental Based Contagion

If the shock from one market to other market transmitted through trade or financial links it is called

fundamental based contagion (Kaminsky et al., 2001). This transmission mechanism can be due to

trade ties or through competitive devaluation. The resultant effect of this interconnectedness is

spillover effect (Gerlach & Smets 1995). In emerging market global financial portfolios diversification

is a major cause of this contagion (Belke & Setzer, 2004). Kaminsky & Reinhart (2000) argue that

financial crisis affect multiple countries if they are financially interdependent. They argue that if the

economies have debts in countries where the impact of the crisis is high, then the probability of

contagion effect increases due to the integrated banking sector.

Common Cause Contagion

The common cause contagion occurs when the common fundamental news is the cause of

reallocation of assets. The basic cause of this type of contagion is an incomplete set of information due

Page 67: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

46

to which crisis is transmitted from one market to another (Belke & Setzer, 2004). The crisis in one

country generates a wakeup call in another country, as the market participants re-evaluate their

investment risk with the same fundamentals that are the root cause in the source country. Uncertainty

about the investment motivates the investor to sell the assets of the identified countries thereby shifting

the effect of crisis from one country to other due to increased volatility. Eichengreen et al. (1996)

argue that comparatively trade links are more severe than the fundamental based contagion. In fact,

the crisis around the globe has rekindled the literature on contagion [see Kalbaska & Gatkowski, 2012;

Metieu, 2012; Beirne & Fratzscher, 2013; Mink & De Haan, 2013; Ludwig, 2014; Eichengreen &

Gupta, 2015; Aizenman et al., 2016).

Pure Contagion

During the episodes of recent financial crisis like Asian crisis of 1997 and the Global financial

crisis of 2007 the international transmission of shocks is observed in countries that have negligible

economic linkages. Therefore, the explanation of crisis contagion is not possible with financial and

trade linkages alone and the existence of pure linkage make sense and theoretically this linkage centers

on herding. Herding contagion can be explained through the rational and irrational view of contagion.

This research is focused on the irrational view of herding, therefore, literature concerning this view is

discussed in detail. Bikhchandani & Sharma (2000) attribute major reason of herd behavior to the market

imperfection along with unfair compensation structures and reputation concerns. Thus, this type of herding

is due to Informational cascade, reputation-based herding, and financial linkages.

According to informational cascade, the market participants act sequentially and actions of first

few investors decide the future course of action. The leading investors may have a misleading set of

information that is followed by the rest of investors in the market (Bikhchandani & Sharma, 2000). In

the presence of information cascade, the country with the sound economic system is also not protected

due to speculative attack as observed in crisis period (Belke & Setzer, 2004). Another explanation of

Page 68: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

47

information content is the cost of information acquisition. Due to increased globalization and stock

market integration, the demand for information access has reduced in past few years. The stock markets

of emerging markets are highly volatile to rumors that may result in more contagion volatility

spillovers due to portfolio diversification (Calvo & Mendoza, 2000)

Reputation-Based Herding discussed by (Scharfstein & Stein, 1990; Trueman, 1994; Graham,

1999) & Welch, 2000) in this type of herding to maintain their reputation investors make sub-optimal

decisions by following the actions of benchmark against which their performance is measured.

Compensation Based Herding is attached with the external rewards and the investors negate the rational

analysis in order to achieve the average level of performance in order to get incentives and to avoid the risk

of getting nothing (Maug & Naik, 1996). The theories argues that financial crises spread from one

country to another due to reasons not related to or explained by economic fundamentals, such as market

imperfections of herding behavior of international investors (Masson, 1999 or Mondria & Quintana-

Domeque, 2013; Beirne & Fraszter, 2013; Ludwig, 2014; Eichengreen & Gupta, 2015)

Page 69: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

48

Theoretical Framework:

Determinants of Herding Behavior

Stock Market Performance

The stock price behavior in the market is usually predicted in theory by the Random walk

hypothesis and is considered to be a salient feature of efficient markets (Fama, 1991). The sharp change

in returns resulting from the crash or uncertain situation causes a sharp decline in returns within a short

period of time that results in a stock market crash and huge losses in shareholders wealth. However,

these extreme variations in stock prices are against the fundamentals of random walk hypothesis and

negate the assumptions of market efficiency that successive prices are not serially correlated and

identically independent (Engle, 2002). This situation leads to market uncertainty and huge risk. Bailey

(2009) blame behavioral factors rather than the fundamental ones as a cause of this situation, they

argued that in spite of rational behavior markets are captivated by irrational behavior caused by some

behavioral linkages like herd behavior, noise trading, and the bandwagon effect. These effects cause

market inefficiency and lead to stock market price distortions, breakdown and eventual collapse

(Barberis & Shleifer, 2003).

Chang, Chen & Jiang (2012) argue that herding behavior during the specific period can push

the stocks’ return down or up. In stock markets, people generally follow two trends either positive

feedback trading (following the pattern of historical prices) (De Long et al., 1990) or herding where a

person follows the actions of others (Bikhchandani & Sharma, 2001). Both effects are a consequence

to each other and it is observed that in practice positive feedback traders usually sell stocks in falling

market and buy them in rising market whereas negative feedback traders behave in an opposite manner

(Sentana & Wadhwani, 1992). It is generally not known which type of feedback strategy do herding

investor follow in the market leading to positive or negative sign on the coefficient on the stock market

Page 70: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

49

return. Therefore, it can be hypothesis that that herding behavior is perceived to have correlated effect

with stock market performance (Grinblatt, Titman, & Wermers, 1995)

H1: Stock market performance has a feedback effect on the trading activity of investor thus

significantly affect the herding behavior of an investor.

Volatility of Stock

According to rational expectation models, uninformed trading increases the market price

volatility (Blasco et. al, 2012). The volatility of stock markets have certain markets implications as

correct estimates of correlation and volatility are needed for portfolio optimization, derivative pricing,

hedging and risk management. Under the traditional finance paradigm, where the markets are efficient,

prices instantly adjust to the arrival of new information and volatility is caused by the continuous of

prices to the information arrival. If the prices do not reflect adjustment to new information then it can

be due to certain market conditions or collective actions like herding ((Thaler 1991, Shefrin 2000).

Stock market volatility and its effect on herding behavior are widely tested (Chang et al., 2000, Tan et

al., 2008). It is observed that in extreme events and period of market stress stock market volatility

increases. Montgomery (1991) argues that during uncertain market conditions volatility increases, the

strong pressure in market increase the likelihood of making an error and the impulse to herd becomes

particularly strong. Therefore, stock market volatility can be an important determinant of herding

behavior. Thus we can hypothesize that stock return volatility has significant effect on herding

behavior

H2: Stock return volatility increases herding behavior in the stock market.

Global Volatility

The other main factor is the global market volatility, i.e. the transmission of stock market volatility

(Diebold & Yilmaz, 2009). During the financial crisis, this behavior is more obvious and irrespective

Page 71: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

50

of the channel adopted emergence of negative news is soon transmitted to the market participants

(Pericoli & Sbracia, 2003). The impact of Return volatility spillover is observed by Beirne et al. (2000)

from US market to some Pacific- basin market. Liu & Pan (1997) witness similar effect from US

market to Asian stock markets. Strong evidence of cross-market correlation is spotted during the period

of excessive volatility (Forbes & Rigobon, 2002; Butler & Joaquin, 2002). Thus we can hypothesize

that

H3: Global volatility has transmission effect from across the markets, therefore affect herding

behavior of investor in correlated markets.

Herding Behavior and Culture:

Each individual around the world behaves in a unique manner. If it is true then arguments built

by the practitioners of behavioral finance i.e the effect of psychological biases, their perception about

the world as established by Culture will not affect their investment decision in the market (Stultz &

Williamson, 2003). People generally share a collective set of experience that affects their investment

behavior in an emotional and cognitive manner (Statman, 2008). Culture practices can be imitated,

even when the behavior is not directly observable and it is cognitively presented in stories (Bruner,

1990). Both social psychology (Cialdini & Goldstein, 2004) and evolutionary psychology (Henrich &

Gil-white, 2001) confirm the hypothesis that people copy the behavior of likable others and behavior

of higher status. According to Losin, Dapretto & Iacoboni (2009) state that imitation takes place due

to the supply of plausible neural mechanism by mirror neuron system in humans. Therefore, it is an

established fact that the human imitative behavior is greatly affected by the surrounding environment

and especially the culture of a particular society. The purpose of this study is to establish the fact that

culture has an important role to play in the financial decision-making process of an investor specifically

to explain the intensity of herding tendency in a cross-cultural context. In this section, it is intended to

develop a hypothesis based on the effect of each cultural dimension on herding behavior.

Page 72: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

51

Individualism and Herding Behavior

The empirical literature provides evidence in favor of the existence of psychological

individual-specific factors that affect the individual investment in risky assets (Puri & Robinson, 2007;

Charness & Gneezy, 2010). On the other hand in behavioral finance investor portfolio diversity can

be attributed to psychological factors (Shum & Faig 2006). Hofstede & Hofstede (2001) argued that

individuals in collective societies are linked to each other in a strong and interrelated group, whereas people

in individualistic societies share a weak bond. Therefore, in individualist societies, investors prefer their

own opinion and are less likely to care about public opinion, in a society with a higher level of

individualism. Goodfellow et al. (2009) argue that if an investor is overconfident while making an

investment decision, they rely less on others and prefer their own beliefs. Similarly, Barber & Odean

(2001) state that an individualist is usually overconfident and value their predictions more, therefore

usually overestimate their evaluation about security prices. On contrary, with a lower level of

individualism, investor behavior is more converge towards market consensus and will cause herding

behavior (Chang & Lin, 2015). Similarly, it is observed that people in collectivist culture societies

people give more importance to others opinion and rely less on their private information (Chui et al.,

2010). Finally, Schmeling (2009) argues that if managers follow the market trends, this collectivism

leads to herding behavior. In accordance with cultural theory and the Hofstede framework, it is

hypothesized that culture can matter significantly as Individualism has the predicted sign. The country

high in the individualistic dimension the investors are the less likely to show herding behavior.

Therefore, it is hypothesized that,

H4: Individualist countries tend to be associated with overconfidence, thus decreases the intensity of

herding behavior.

Page 73: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

52

Power Distance and Herding Behavior:

Hofstede (1991) says that people are independent in low power distance countries and have own

initiative, while in high power distance societies they rely on others commands. Chui & Kwok (2008)

states that people in high power distance societies stated are also collectivists. In a high power distance

environment, people gain information in unequal conditions and society is unequal. Information is

acquired through the transaction made by others and people usually follow their leads, resulting in

herding behavior (Chang & Lin, 2015).

Conversely in low power distance society’s individuals share values like trust, equality, and

cooperation (Sinke 2012). Mihet (2013) also supported this argument by finding more trust and

harmony in countries with low power distance. House et al. (2004) also observe this fact and argued

that information is shared in countries with low power distance. Therefore, on the basis of

aforementioned literature, power distance leads to more herding but this association is not clearly

supported by the literature.

H5: Power distance has a significant effect on the herd behavior.

Masculinity vs Feminist and Herding Behavior

Masculinity and feminist are attributed to the role of each gender in the society and make a clear

distinction in a specific culture. According to this dimension, men are generally regarded as arbitrary,

strong, and focused on material achievement, while femininity is modest, tender, and focused on life

quality. Estes & Hosseini (1988) state that gender has an important role in defining the confidence

level of investor especially when they make decisions. They further contend that men are more

confident in making decisions. Yao & Hanna (2005) conclude that women tend to be more risk-averse

than men if they have to choose and risky asset with more life expectancy. Chang & Noorbakhsh

(2009) claime that in masculine societies, for getting higher returns people tend to hold more cash so

that they can exploit faster strategic opportunities. Therefore, in masculine societies, men are more

Page 74: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

53

ambitious and self-confident tend to be more success oriented and risk takers (Hofstede, 1991). Thus in

countries with high masculinity level, people are more materialistic and more likely to engage in selling

low and buying high in order to be opportunistic. This behavior tends to incline them towards high profits

to satisfy their greed, which results in more herding behavior.

H6: Masculine countries exhibit self-confidence and risk-taking behavior rely more on profits, which

leads to high level of herding.

Uncertainty Avoidance and Herding Behavior:

This dimension explains the comparison of countries on the basis of high and low uncertainty

avoidance when they face an uncertain or threatening situation. The individuals in high uncertainty

societies generally have an overreacting behavior and react more emotionally (Schmeling, 2009). They

find a herd-like behavior in countries with low level of individualism and high Uncertainty avoidance.

Hofstede & Hofstede (2001) state that things uncertain for one person may not be same for another

and risk avoidance is not similar to uncertainty avoidance. Li et al. (2013) examine the effect of the

culture on managerial decision making and conclude the negative relationship between corporate risk-

taking and uncertainty avoidance. This trait restrains them from taking high risk and exploring

innovative investments. People in high uncertainty avoidance culture are characterized with having

defined legal frameworks and safety measure, whereas, in a low uncertainty avoidance culture people

feel more natural and are more absorbent to varying behaviors, and avoid strict regulations (Park &

Lemaire, 2012). According to theory, a higher tracking error (i.e., safety margin) that is used to increase

portfolio risk shall lead, on average and in the longer run, to higher returns compared to the benchmark;

Thus, Uncertainty Avoidance may be a reason for lower returns generated by affected asset managers

(Beckmann et al., 2008). To reduce uncertainty, investors of societies with a higher value in this

dimension usually rely more on information research. The outcome may always be efficient and it will

remain debatable, but at least they try to obtain all relevant information required to make an efficient

Page 75: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

54

decision and chances of risk may reduce (Offerman & Hellman 1997). Uncertainty avoidance

commands people to track the same set of rules and avoid risk, thus usually behave in a similar manner

(Hofstede & Hofstede, 2001). Similarly, Sinke (2012) conclude that people with high uncertainty

avoidance exhibit more herding behavior. Therefore, we hypothesize that,

H7: High uncertainty avoidance leads to risk averseness, thus exhibit more herding behavior.

Long-term Orientation and Herding Behavior:

LTO refers to virtues, and especially persistence and frugality, which promote and encourage

the search for the orientation of future returns. Anderson et al. (2011) states that people in long-term

oriented countries are less myopic, which directs them towards more diversification and less herding

behavior. Due to this strong orientation towards fundamentals, one may be not surprised that the

preferred investment strategy is also derived from theory. Inefficient markets, it is rational to rely on

a long-term orientated buy and hold strategy, especially when facing long-term investment horizons,

and thus to refrain from following short-sighted sentiment driven trends and frequent portfolio shifts

that might cause high transaction costs. People with short-term orientation focus on fast outcomes,

therefore invest mostly in most liquid assets or assets like mutual funds. Lobao & Serra (2002) find

that mutual funds are short-term securities and evaluated quarterly, therefore are more inclined to

herding behavior in order to maintain reputation. Chang & Lin (2015) claim that STO culture society

investors prefer current returns, and are more inclined towards market opinion, it leads to and engage

in short-term trading and restrain them from long-term investment, therefore they exhibit more herding

behavior. Matsumoto (2007) argued long-term orientation is related to emotion and temperature of

fear is felt high, but this orientation is positively related to the emotion of joy, shame, and guilt. Park

& Lamaire (2012) argue that long-term oriented societies are more adhered to Confucian culture,

respect of family values, follow of traditions, respect for ancestor’s traits and honor of parents are

major characteristics of these societies and these attributes are more like collectivist traits. A clear

Page 76: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

55

direction of relationship cannot be theorized from literature. Thus, we can conclude that due to risk

aversion long-term orientation and collective traits, investor is influenced by the behavior of others.

H8: LTO is risk-averse and more affected by emotions and collective traits, thus exhibit more herding

behavior.

Indulgence versus Restraints

This dimension is a recent addition to the Hofstede dimensions after the work of Minkov (2009).

People in indulge societies satisfy their natural human desires of enjoying life by allowing free

gratification contrary to restraint societies that are more restrictive and regulated by strict norms. This

dimension explains the traits how individuals control their desires based on the way of their upbringing.

The indulge societies are more tilted towards positive emotions than negative emotions. This cultural

dimension has three classifications: “happiness and pleasure in life, the importance of leisure and

friendship, and life control”. This index is positively correlated to the power distance, authority, and

institutions. Highly restraint societies exhibit strict social norms and organized legal frameworks.

Markets in strong regulatory frameworks are usually transparent and less affected by human behavior.

The clear relationship with investor behavior cannot be supported through literature but it can be

argued that Individuals in highly indulged societies exhibit weak control over desires, whereas

societies with a low level of indulgence control their urges strongly. Therefore, it is hypothesized that

H9: IVR exhibits a significant effect on herding behavior.

Effect of Macroeconomic Shocks on Herding

Uncertainty is defined as people able to predict the likelihood of an event to happen (Knight,

1921). An uncertainty shock can be attributed to large dispersions in expected future outcomes. It is a

broad phenomenon: uncertainty can be macro level like GDP growth, micro level like firm growth and

non-economic event specific to war or climate change. The macro uncertainty is due to changes in

Page 77: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

56

macroeconomic variables and this volatility increases in a recession. The macroeconomic variables

and stock returns are endogenous variables, therefore their reaction to specific shock can be

simultaneous (Wasserfallen, 1989). Financial prices like exchange rates, bond yields and nonfinancial

measures like GDP and industrial production growth are more volatile in recession (Bloom, 2014). In

financial terms, it is explained in terms of determinants of discount rates or over future profitability,

both are a cause of increased stock volatility. Prieto et al. (2016) identify the impact of shocks to credit

spreads on the lag value of real and nominal variables, and financial variables also react simultaneously

to such disturbance. Gilchrist et al. (2009) identify financial shocks from the corporate bond spreads

that are orthogonal to general measures of economic activity, inflation, real interest rates, and various

financial indicators, as well as to equity returns of firms whose outstanding bonds are used to construct

credit spreads in the bond portfolios. Bachmann, Elstner, & Sims, (2013) found 64% higher Standard

deviation across forecast of IP (industrial production growth) in European economies during the

recession. Similarly, Campbell et al. (2000) investigate the variation in cross-firm stock returns and

50% increase in variation in the recession than boom. Bloom (2008) investigate us to market and

conclude that uncertainty shocks have significant effects on industrial production and employment. On

the other hand, Fernandez et al. (2008) find the persistent effect of these shocks in emerging markets.

Stock market volatility has also been previously used as a proxy for uncertainty at the firm level

(Leahy & Whited (1996) and Bloom, Bond & Van Reenen. (2007). A number of studies document the

impact of unexpected variation in macroeconomic variables or uncertainty shocks like London attack,

9/11 terrorist attacks on stock returns and volatility (Fama, 1981; Wasserfallen, 1989; Gjerde &

Saettem, 1999; Bloom, 2009). Faust (1998) & Uhlig (2005) analyze the impacts of shocks behind

economic uncertainty and changes in financial conditions on the macroeconomy.

Investor behavior is an important determinant of stock market volatility, an uncertain situation

related to market fundamentals can affect investor decision making. Blasco et al. (2012) and Messis &

Zapranis (2014a) investigate Spanish and Greek markets respectively and find a direct linear impact

Page 78: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

57

of herding on market volatility and conclude that herding to be an added risk factor. Therefore, this

study is an attempt to empirically investigate the impact of unexpected components of few

macroeconomic variables on the estimated herding measure. Messis & Zapranis (2014b) find this

effect on developed markets, like US, UK France Germany, and China. This fact motivates us to

investigate the impact of macroeconomic shocks on a set of developed and emerging and frontier

markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe. One of the added contributions of this research is the

inclusion of monetary variables like Industrial Production index, interest rates, exchange rate, and

money supply as macroeconomic variables. These variables have previously been used in literature to

find the impact of the macroeconomic shock on stock market volatility (Bloom, 2009) and herding

Behavior (Messis & Zapranis, 2014) in five developed markets. This study empirically contributes to

literature by investigating this impact in a large set of economies. Specifically, developing markets are

more sensitive to shocks as compared to the developed economies (Voronkova & Bohl, 2005) that are

previously ignored in literature. Hence, it is hypothesized that

H10: Macroeconomic uncertainty and crisis shocks have a significant effect on herding behavior.

Herding Behavior and Financial Contagion

Calvo & Reinhart (1996) define contagion as “investors’ reaction towards a country’s asset

return characteristics’ or to mimic the perceived optimal portfolio share assigned to a particular country

by an arbitrary “market” portfolio”. This study explains contagion in two ways, contagion related to

economic fundamentals and contagion related to herding behavior that is investor mentality.

Similarly, Forbes & Rigobon (2002) define contagion through the fundamental channel and

suggest that across the border linkages in stock prices, capital flows and exchange rates increases after

an uncertain shock in a country or group of countries.

Masson (1999) classifies three channels of international financial transmission, spillovers,

monsoonal effect and jumps in equilibrium. Spillover effect can be explained through real linkages

Page 79: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

58

like trade and other economic activities. The monsoonal effect arises from global environmental

changes and has global impacts. These two types are classified as fundamental ones and the last one

is considered as herding. The jumps are considered as a residual effect, where investor’s changing

expectations causes jumps between multiple equilibriums.

Kodres & Pritsker (2002) investigate financial contagion in a rational expectation model. They

state that contagion happens through cross-market rebalancing: when agents are hit by a shock in one

market, they need to rebalance their portfolio of assets; the presence of asymmetric information

exacerbates the price co-movements resulting from this rebalancing. Yuan (2005) suggests that

asymmetry in information and borrowing constraints are the reason of contagion. Economou et al.

(2011) find the contagion caused by herd behavior in European markets during the financial crisis.

Cross country herding behavior in addition to local market could be due to portfolio rebalancing

(Brunnermeier & Pedersen, 2009), risk premium and liquidity channels (Longstaff, 2010), and cross-

listing effects, (Chandar, Patro, & Yezegel 2009). Similarly, several authors discuss the possible causes

of contagion (Kyle & Xiong, 2001; Mondria, 2006; Kaminsky & Reinhart, 2000; Forbes & Rigobon,

2002). Allen & Gale (2000, 2007) attribute contagion effect to financial system fragility among

financial institutions. In the light of above argument, we develop following hypothesis,

H11: Crisis situation leads to herding behavior that can cause contagion effect.

H12: Contagion of herding is existing across the border due to unexpected shocks in macroeconomic

fundamental.

Page 80: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

59

Chapter 3

3. Data and Methodology

Research Design:

Data and Sample:

The dataset in this study consists of industry and Market index returns of Developed, Emerging

and Frontier Markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe. The countries are classified into two main

categories based on MSCI country classification: one category consists of developed markets of the

regions. The second classification includes emerging and frontier markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and

Europe. The three markets of China, Taiwan and Hong Kong under the classification are considered

as greater China markets. For the identification of herding behavior sample time period is selected on

the basis of the time of data availability. Some of the objectives require cross-country analysis,

therefore, data uniformity is required. In order to meet the said objectives the analysis time period is

restricted to a time span of January 2000 to December 2015. All the data for market and industrial

indices are obtained from DataStream international database. Industrial data is based on industrial

Classification Benchmark (ICB) which is a globally recognized standard, operated and managed by

FTSE International for categorizing companies and securities. The list of countries along with sample

size is discussed in table 3.1. Where no of shares represent the total numbers of firms included in data

stream to calculate the industrial indices fulfilling the requirements of industrial classification

benchmark standards for categorizing companies and securities. Dates represent the start time of the

data availability of each sampling country. The list of industries along with a number of sub-sectors is

given in Appendix 2.

To study the impact of macroeconomic shocks on herding measure, this study uses Industrial

Production Index (IP), Money Supply (MS), the Exchange rate and the deposit rate of each country.

Page 81: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

60

The macro data is retrieved from DataStream international, IMF database and the Eurostat. For global

volatility, global volatility index VIX is obtained from Chicago Board of exchange website.

To investigate the impact of culture, this study employs national culture indices proposed by

Hofstede & Hofstede (2001) for the five dimensions of national culture: Power distance, individualism,

masculinity, uncertainty avoidance, and long-term orientation, the data for cultural indices are

retrieved from Hofstede website. The list of the variable is given in Appendix 3.

Table 3.1: List of sample countries with starting dates

Developed Markets Emerging and Frontier Markets

Country Code No of shares Start Date Country Code No of shares Start Date

Australia AU 160 11/24/1992 China CA 100 5/12/1998

Austria OE 50 11/12/1992 India IN 100 1/2/1995

Belgium BG 90 4/10/1991 Indonesia ID 50 1/4/2000

Denmark DK 50 8/14/1991 Korea KO 100 8/21/1995

France FR 250 10/20/1997 Malaysia MY 90 12/30/1994

Germany BD 250 1/2/1981 Pakistan PK 50 1/2/1995

Greece GR 50 9/2/1992 Philippines PH 50 9/2/1994

Hong Kong HK 130 6/21/1991 Sri Lanka CY 50 1/3/1995

Italy IT 160 1/1/1998 Taiwan TA 70 1/5/1995

Japan JP 1000 1/5/1981 Thailand TH 50 1/16/1995

The Netherlands NL 130 1/4/1983 Turkey TK 50 3/16/1993

New Zealand NZ 50 12/2/1999

Norway NW 50 11/3/1983

Portugal PT 50 1/4/1993

Singapore SG 100 6/2/1998

Spain ES 120 3/4/1987

Sweden SD 70 10/1/1986

Switzerland SW 150 12/4/1990

The UK The UK 550 12/8/1986

US US 1000 1/1/1981

Page 82: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

61

Methodology

Measure of Herding

3.2.1.1 Return Dispersion Models

This study empirically investigates herding by using models developed by Christie & Huang (1995),

Chang et al. (2000) and Chang et al. (2010). Christie & Huang (1995) model is employed to estimate

the average proximity of individual stock returns to the realized market returns. Cross-sectional

standard deviation can be expressed as follows,

1

)(1

2

,,

N

RR

CSSD

N

i

tmti

t (1)

Where, N is the number of stocks in the aggregate market portfolio, Ri,t is the observed return on

industry index i for day t, and Rm,t is cross-sectional average returns of the aggregate market portfolio

for day t. Presence of herding behavior can be gauged by the occurrence of extreme market movements.

In the presence of herd behavior, dispersion between individual and market returns decreases. This

proximity in average returns can be measured through the model proposed by Christie & Huang

(1995):

t

L

t

LU

t

U

t DDCSSD 21 (2)

Where, 1U

tD , when the aggregate market portfolio returns in a given time period stay in the extreme

upper tail, and 0 otherwise. 1L

tD , if the aggregate market portfolio returns in the extreme lower tail

for a given time period and 0 otherwise. Thus, herd formation can be gauged by the presence of

negative, significant β1 and β2 coefficients.

Page 83: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

62

The above-given model is further refined by Chang et al. (2000). This study argues that dispersion in

returns is a nonlinear function of market returns. Instead of standard deviation, Chiang et al. (2000)

use cross-sectional absolute deviation (CSAD) which can be modeled as follows,

N

i

tmtit RRN

CSAD1

,, ||1

(3)

This model capture nonlinear effect by using general quadratic-form between CSADt and Rm,t, the

model developed by Chiang et al. (2000) is given as follows,

ttmtmt RRCSAD 2

,3,21 (4)

Where, CSADt measures return dispersion, |Rm,t| is an equally weighted realized return of industry

index on the day, t in its absolute form. The relationship between CSAD and Rm,t capture the presence

of herding. The presence of significant negative coefficient γ3 of the quadratic term of market return

is indicative of herding behavior.

In order to take in to account the asymmetric investor behavior in various market conditions, Chiang

& Zheng (2010) include linear term Rm,t. in the above model. It captures the asymmetry in investor

behavior under different market conditions. In this model + describe the relation between return

dispersion and market return when Rm,t > 0, while - shows the relation when Rm,t ≤ 0. The ratio

of (+ ) / ( ) represents the relative asymmetry between market returns and stock return

dispersion (Duffee, 2001).

ttmtmtmt RRRCSAD 2

,4,3,21 (5)

3.2.1.2 Time-Varying Model of Herding Behavior

3.1.4 Time-Varying Dispersion Models

Page 84: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

63

The above-stated model of herding presented by Chang et al. (2000) is static in nature means

it demonstrates the average relation between return dispersion and the square of market returns over

time. The time-varying or dynamic herding can be obtained by using Kalman filter approach. Chiang

et al. (2013) first use this approach on a sample of 10 pacific basin markets and observe the presence

of significant dynamic herding behavior in all markets except the US.

This approach is explained as:

ttmtmt rrCSAD 2

,2,10 (6)

𝑖,𝑡

= 𝑖,𝑡−1

+ 𝑣𝑖,𝑡 , 𝑣𝑖,𝑡 ~ 𝑁(0, 𝜎𝑣,𝑖2 ) , 𝑤ℎ𝑒𝑟𝑒, i=1, 2, 3 (7)

Equation (6) is a measurement equation and [𝛾0, 𝛾1, 𝛾2]′ is a vector of state variables. Equation (7) is

known as transition equation where state variables follow a random walk process. State series t

demonstrate time varying herding behavior in a given market during a specific time period.

3.2.1.3 State Space Models

The third type of model to measure herding is developed by Hwang & Salmon (2004). It measures

herding behavior at a monthly frequency, this model is based on the assumption that the time-varying

alpha and betas are constant within the limited period of one month. Capital asset pricing model in the

presence of rational investors and in equilibrium can be written as:

)()( mtimtitt rErE (8)

Where rit and rmt indicate the excess return of industry i and market return respectively and βit is the

systematic risk. Et(rmt) is the conditional expectation at time t. When herding occurs, Eq. (8) no longer

holds, resulting in the bias of expected return and risk. The model suggests that in the case of herding

towards the market, the following relationship holds:

𝐸𝑡𝑏(𝑟𝑖𝑡)

𝐸𝑡(𝑟𝑚𝑡)= 𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡

𝑏 = 𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡 − ℎ𝑚𝑡(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡 − 1) (9)

Page 85: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

64

where 𝐸𝑡𝑏(𝑟𝑖𝑡) and 𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡

𝑏 it are the biased expected returns on the industry and its observed beta

respectively. hmt is a latent herding parameter that is time varying. When hmt = 0, shown absence of

herding and the CAPM to holds in equilibrium. When hmt = 1, represents perfect herding towards

market indicating that all industries in the market change in accordance with the movements of the

market portfolio. When 0 < hmt < 1 show the presence of herding to some extent depending on the

intensity of hmt. In adverse herding should hmt < 0. When there is upward trend in the market, for an

industrial index with βit > 1 the CAPM suggests that Et (rit ) > Et (rmt ). There will be a downward

pressure on equity price due to the herding behavior of investors, making 0 < 𝐸𝑡𝑏(𝑟𝑖𝑡) < Et (rit ) For that

reason the industry looks less risky than it should, suggesting that 1 < 𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡𝑏 < βimt . The same order of

betas holds when the market goes down as investors will buy the equity pushing it upwards. For an

industry with βimt < 1, the inverse process holds and the biased beta increases with the market changes

(i.e. 1 > βb it > βit ) (Wang, 2008). When βit = 1, the equity is neutral to herding, while for adverse

herding (i.e. hmt < 0) an equity with βit > 1 means that Eb t (rit ) > Et (rit ) > Et (rmt ) and for an

industrial index with βit < 1 holds that Eb t (rit ) < Et (rit ) < Et (rmt ). The cross section mean of βbit

(βit) is 1 regardless of whether βit is biased or not. Thus, the cross sectional standard deviation is:

𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡𝑏 = √𝐸𝑐((𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡 − ℎ𝑚𝑡(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡 − 1) − 1)2 = √𝐸𝑐((𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡 − 1)2(1 − ℎ𝑚𝑡) = 𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐(𝛽𝑖𝑡)(1 − ℎ𝑚𝑡) (10)

Where Ec(.) represents the cross-sectional expectation. If it is assumed that 𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡

𝑏 are changing

overtime with the level of herding in the market and by taking logarithm on both sides, so eq (10) can

be written as,

log [𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡𝑏 )] = 𝜇𝑚 + 𝑣𝑚𝑡 (11)

Where 𝜇𝑚 = 𝐸[log [𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡𝑏 )]] and 𝑣𝑚𝑡~𝑖𝑖𝑑(0, 𝜎𝑚𝑣

2 ), state space model 1 is then estimated as

log [𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡𝑏 )] = 𝜇𝑚 + 𝐻𝑚𝑡 + 𝑣𝑚𝑡 (12)

𝐻𝑚𝑡 = ∅𝑚𝐻𝑚𝑡−1 + 𝑚𝑡

(13)

Where Hmt = (1- hmt ) and 𝑚𝑡

~𝑖𝑖𝑑(0, 𝜎𝑚𝑛2 ).Eqs. (12) and (13) are the standard state-space model

estimated by Kalman filter approach follows an AR(1) process

Page 86: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

65

. This methodology, focus on the time varying movements in the latent state variable, Hmt. When 𝜎𝑚𝑛2

= 0, it shows the absence of the herding which means that Hmt = 0 for all t. The existence of herding is

interpreted by significant value of 𝜎𝑚𝑛2 and a significant ∅ supports this specific autoregressive

structure.

Model Selection Criteria Applied to Return Dispersion and State Space Model

A number of model selection criteria available for the time series analysis. A model selection criterion

tries to find the best fitting model. These criteria are based on the complexity of model selection and

essentially penalize the likelihood based on the sample size and number of estimated parameters. This

model selection is achieved through the most precise fit with a parsimonious specification. Two

popular information criteria are the Akaike information criterion and the Bayesian information

criterion (or the Schwarz information criterion) used for the selection of dynamic models in various

fields are Akaike information criterion (AIC) and the Bayesian information criterion (BIC) (Penny et

al., 2004). When applying these criteria to different models, the best model is the one with the lowest

value of AIC and BIC.

The Akaike information criterion (AIC), developed by Hirotugu Akaike in 1971 and proposed by

Akaike (1974), is a relative measure of the fitting quality obtained by a statistical model. AIC

combines a measure of model fit with a measure of model complexity, with the assumption that the

smaller value if better. For a given data set and a given model,

AIC = −2 log L + 2p

Where, L is the maximum likelihood of the data, and p is the number of parameters in the model.

Here, −2 log L is a function of the prediction error which should be smaller as the smaller valued give

better estimates. This value describes the fitness of the data.

Page 87: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

66

The Bayesian information criterion (BIC), also named as the Schwarz criterion, was developed by

Schwarz (1978) and is a criterion for selecting models based on the posterior probabilities of the

comparing models. For a given dataset model is described as,

BIC = −2 log L + log(n)*p

Where p is the number of parameters in the model and n is the sample size in the model. The criteria

for model selection is same as the AIC model, the smaller value of BIC give better estimates.

Determinants of Herding Behavior

3.2.3.1 Internal Factors

3.2.3.1.1 Stock Market Performance

Stock market performance has a significant effect on investor imitating behavior. It is argued

that change in the price of a stock can greatly affect investor decision-making process (Grinblatt,

Titman, & Wermers, 1995). It is observed that in practice positive feedback traders usually sell stocks

in falling market and buy them in rising market whereas negative feedback traders behave in an

opposite manner (Sentana & Wadhwani, 1992). Therefore, stock market performance can be treated

as an important determinant of herding behavior. This stock market performance can be examined by

adding the stock market index returns

3.2.3.1.2 Volatility

In order to calculate conditional volatility of returns ARCH/GARCH specifications is

commonly used measures. These models are with the limitation of symmetric response even if the

positive news has a different effect from negative news (Black, 1976; Sentena, 1992; Bekaert & Wu,

2000). In certain financial time series, this response is often observed. High volatility is generally in

the presence of negative shocks than the positive shocks of the same intensity. In order to test this

asymmetric effect, the exponential GARCH (EGARCH) model of Nelson (1991) is employed to

Page 88: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

67

capture the leverage effects (stock price decline increase the firm debt to equity ratio (financial

leverage) and, consequently, the degree of risk (volatility). The equation of the conditional variance

for the EGARCH model takes the following form:

Where are the estimated coefficient parameters? The coefficient is the estimated GARCH

symmetric effect in the equation. Parameter capture the persistence of volatility in the event of a

certain state in the market. The larger value of is indicative of longer than usual subsistence of

volatility after the crisis period. The coefficient represents the asymmetric effect. If = 0 then model

is symmetric, however > 0 or < 0 represent asymmetry. If > 0 the positive shocks (good news)

generate higher volatility than of negative shock (bad news) of the same magnitude and vice versa.

3.2.3.1.3 Global Market Volatility

In order to assess global volatility, Chicago Board Options Exchange volatility index is used, known

as VIX. The VIX is formed using options implied volatilities and represent next 30 days expected

return volatility of S&P 500 index.

𝐻𝑒𝑟𝑑𝑡 = ∅0 + ∅1𝑅𝑚,𝑡 + ∅2�̂�𝑡2 + ∅3𝑉𝐼𝑋𝑡−1 + 𝜀𝑡 (14)

Where herd is the estimated herd coefficient derives through state space model. Rm,t is market return,

�̂�𝑡2 is the conditional variance based on asymmetric GARCH(1,1) process for each market. Cross herd

is cross market herding correlation and VIXt-1 is the lagged CBOE implied volatility index.

Herding Behavior and Culture

To investigate the relationship between national culture and herding behavior, this study uses six

dimensions of national culture suggested by Hofstede & Hofstede (2001). Index of all dimension of

culture employed by Hofstede & Hofstede (2001) are described in more detail below

1

1

1

12

1

2 loglog

t

t

t

ttt

Page 89: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

68

(1) Power distance index (PDI): Power distance index refers PDI which refers to the expectation and

acceptance of the disadvantaged members of the society towards the inequality of authority within

national institutions and organizations (Jong & Semenov, 2002)

(2) Individualism Index (IDV): IDV indicates that how much people of a society are loosely

connected and they look after themselves and their core families relative to society as a whole as in

collectivism. (Chui, Titman & Wei, 2010).

(3) Masculinity Index (MAS): In masculine societies major emphasis is on success and material

achievement, instead of the quality of life and concern for others. In masculine society, individuals are

more open to investment in foreign markets and are usually risk takers (Anderson et al., 2011). This

type of society promote competition and systems are basically market-based and reward the strong

players of the market, gender role is clearly discriminated. On contrary feminist societies are caring,

modest and more focused towards the quality of life.

(4) Uncertainty avoidance index (UAI): UAI refers the societies that are high in this dimension are

usually threatened to uncertainty and ambiguity when they have to deal an uncertain situation. This

trait affects their investment decision, as decision-making process is an outcome of a sense of security

derived from perceiving a threat, not by their achievements and capabilities (Dutta & Mukherjee,

2012). They accept investments with relatively lower risk and domestic investment over cross-border

diversification (Anderson et al., 2011)

(5) Long-term orientation index (LTO): long-term oriented societies focus on future returns and

promote and encourage long-term goals over short-term orientations. They are usually adaptive to the

rule and regulations and let the complexities of life settle at their own pace. Society follows virtue

driven by persistence and personal adaptability is important. They are more focused on relationship

and market positions. They prefer safe investments over the risky ones.

(6) Indulgence index (IVR): This trait has a very short history added following Minkov (2009). This

dimension refers to the situation how individuals have control over their desires. People in indulge

Page 90: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

69

societies satisfy their natural human desires of enjoying life by allowing free gratification. Whereas

restraint societies are relatively more restrictive and are more regulated by strict norms. The upbringing

of individuals has an impact on the way they control their impulses and desires. Individuals in highly

indulged societies exhibit weak control over desires, whereas societies with a low level of indulgence

control their urges strongly.

3.2.4.1 Model to Test the Impact of Culture on Herding Behavior.

In order to test and measure the effect of national culture on the presence of herding behavior, this

study employed the methodology proposed by Chiang et al. (2000) and Chiang & Zheng (2010) model

are employed. The selection of these models is based on their nature as they measure herding as a static

phenomenon. Culture is a non-variant variable and changes very slowly over time, therefore,

employment of culture in the time-varying model is almost impossible. After testing the presence of

herding through the above-stated model we include culture variable in the model, culture is treated as

a modulating variable and included as a dummy variable in model proposed by Chiang et al. (2000)

and Chiang & Zheng (2010), for each dimension median value is calculated (using all countries), if

the value lies above median it takes the value of 1, and 0 otherwise.

tti

s

tititititi RmDCRmRmRmCSAD 2

,,4

2

,3,2,1, ][][ (15)

Where CSAD is the cross-sectional absolute deviation of the market on the day for stock market

i, Rmi,t is the market return of that market on that particular day. The relationship between the absolute

value of Rmi,t, squared term of Rmi,t and CSAD represent the existence of herding behavior. The

significant negative value of γ3 indicates the presence of herding behavior. DC is the dummy of each

individual dimension of culture (PDI, IDV, MAS, UAI, LTO, and IVR). Each dimension bear the

value of 1 if that specific country lies above median average and zero otherwise. For 6 cultural variable,

this study runs six regressions of equation (15) by including one dummy of one cultural dimension at

Page 91: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

70

a time. This process is done to avoid the problem of dummy trap.5 The analysis is done by ordinary

least square regression used by (Blasco, Corredor, & Ferreruela, 2017). The presence of significant γ4

indicates the effect of each cultural dimension on the intensity of herding behavior. If the value is

negative then herding intensity decreases and vice versa.

The Effects of Macroeconomic Shocks on Herding

The main issue being explored in this section is the effects of macroeconomic shocks on the

estimated herd measures towards the market. However, the first thing needs to be done is to catch

unexpected components of the selected macroeconomic variables. For this purpose, the Box–Jenkins

methodology of an ARIMA (p, d, q) model is used. A fundamental notion behind the selection of this

model is the principle of parsimony. These models are appropriate for forecasting and provide better

results than over parametrized models6. According to Wasserfallen (1989), for the proxy of

unexpected elements in macroeconomic variables, the in-sample residuals from ARIMA models can

be utilized, with an expectation that they are partly rational. However, the fundamental forecast is

based on the historical values of the series itself. But the use of residuals from ARIMA model can

result in consistent parameter estimates but overstated levels of significance (Pagan, 1984). According

to ARIMA (Autoregressive integrated moving average) models future value exhibit a functional

relationship with past points, current points, and white noise error terms. This method can generate

rich hypothesis on the basis of few parameters only and the model can be extended to a random number

of parameters. To begin with, the general form of an ARIMA (p, d, q) model we first need to generate

the AR and MA process. An autoregressive process of order AR(p) can be written as,

𝑥𝑡 = 𝜑1𝑥𝑡−1 + 𝜑2𝑥𝑡−2 + 𝜑3𝑥𝑡−𝑝 + 𝜖𝑡

The moving order process for q order MA can be written as,

5 See, Astriou and Hall, (2007) 6 See Abeysinghe and Rajaguru, (2004).

Page 92: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

71

𝑥𝑡 = 𝜖𝑡 + 𝜗1𝑥𝑡−1 + 𝜗2𝑥𝑡−2 + 𝜗3𝑥𝑡−𝑞

The ARMA process with (p,q ) order can be written as

𝑥𝑡 = 𝜑1𝑥𝑡−1 + 𝜑2𝑥𝑡−2 + 𝜑3𝑥𝑡−𝑝 + 𝜖𝑡 + 𝜗1𝑥𝑡−1 + 𝜗2𝑥𝑡−2 + 𝜗3𝑥𝑡−𝑞

Where φ and are estimation parameters and 𝜖 represent the white noise stochastic error terms.

Next step is to generate a non-stationary series and define the first order difference of yt to make a

stationary series.

∆𝑦𝑡 = 𝑦𝑡 − 𝑦𝑡−1

Or by using a Lag operator we can have

∆𝑑𝑦𝑡 = (1 − 𝐿)𝑑𝑦𝑡

In the final form, ARIMA (p,d,q) model can be reported as follows

𝜑𝑝(𝐿)(1 − 𝐿)𝑑𝑦𝑡 = 𝜗𝑞(𝐿)𝜖𝑡 (16)

Where, L is the lag operator, d is the number of differences for becoming the stochastic variable Y

stationary, φp(L) = 1−φ1L−・ ・ ・−φpLp and q(L) = 1−1L−・ ・ ・−qL

q . The residuals of this

model are going to be used for investigating the effects of macroeconomic shocks on herding. These

residuals are then added to the Hwang and Salmon (2004) model.

Herding and Financial Contagion:

Empirical evidence suggests that the economic fundamentals predict the occurrence of a financial crisis

(Kaminsky & Reinhart, 2000), but in reality crisis usually occur when the fundamentals is weak or

may not occur when they are sound. This type of financial crisis is triggered by the herding behavior

of investor, where investors simply imitate the behavior of others.

To examine nature of contagion effect and interrelationship this study first calculate volatility by using

GARCH(1,1) model developed by Bollerslev (1986) and used for the calculation of correlation as,

Yt =M+Et Et ~ N(0, Ht) (17)

Page 93: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

72

Where Yt = [𝑦𝑖,𝑡

𝑦𝑘,𝑡]is a (2x1) vector containing the first difference of herding measures, where k is the

originator country and i represent rest of the countries. Conditional mean is represented by (2x1) vector

M=[𝜇𝑦𝑖

𝜇𝑦𝑘] and 2x2 Ht is the conditional covariance matrix.

The conditional variance-covariance equations of a diagonal VECH bivariate GARCH (1,1) can be

written as,

VECH(Ht) = D + EVECH(Et-1 Et-1) + FVECH(Ht-1 H

t-1) (18)

Where D is a 3x1 vector containing intercepts in the conditional variance-covariance equations, E and

F are 3 x 3 diagonal matrices consist of parameters with lagged square disturbance and on the lagged

variance or covariance respectively. The diagonal variance can be written as

ℎ11,𝑡 = 𝑑01 + 𝑒11𝜖1,𝑡−12 + 𝑓11ℎ11,𝑡−1 (19a)

ℎ12,𝑡 = 𝑑02 + 𝑒22𝜖1,𝑡−1𝑔2,𝑡−1 + 𝑓22ℎ12,𝑡−1 (19b)

ℎ22,𝑡 = 𝑑03 + 𝑒33𝜖2,𝑡−12 + 𝑓33ℎ22,𝑡−1 (19c)

The coefficient e11 and e33 represent the ARCH process in residuals from country i and originator

country k respectively. The parameters e22 and e33 are the covariance GARCH parameters between

country i and k respectively.

Whereas conditional correlation is calculated as follows (Alexander, 2001)

�̂�𝑡𝑘𝑖 =

�̂�𝑘𝑖,𝑡�̂�𝑘,𝑡�̂�𝑖,𝑡

⁄ (20)

Where k is the first difference of herd measure of US index and i the estimated herding measures from

the rest countries of the sample.

Certain macroeconomic variable and Crisis dummy are used to develop a model to test the changes in

herding correlation following the approach used by Messis & Zapranis (2014). The changes in the

correlation of herding measures between the sample countries during macroeconomic shocks and crisis

Page 94: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

73

period can be tested econometrically by using an OLS regression. This methodology is used by (Chiang

et al., 2007; Coudert & Gex, 2010 and Messis & Zapranis, 2014)

𝜌𝑡𝑘,𝑖 = 𝛼𝑘,𝑖 + 𝛽𝑘𝜌𝑡−1

𝑘,𝑖 + 𝛾1𝑘𝐷𝑐𝑟,𝑡 + 𝛾2

𝑘𝐷𝐸𝑅,𝑡 + 𝛾3𝑘𝐷𝐼𝑃,𝑡 + 𝛾3

𝑘𝐷𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛾4𝑘𝐷𝑀𝑆,𝑡 + 𝑢𝑡

𝑘,𝑖 (20)

Where, t-1, represent the lagged value of correlation measures between the originator countries

and the US. Dcr,t, DER,t, DIP,t, Di,t, DMS,t, are the dummies of crisis and macroeconomic shocks, whereas

k and i represent the respective countries and ut is the residual term. For the crisis dummy Global

financial crisis of 2008 is included. The dummy Dcr,t takes the value of 1 during a period from August

2007 to April 2009 and 0 otherwise. This crisis starts when an announcement is made by BNP Paribas

to cease the activities of three hedge funds. These funds are specialized in the US mortgage debt

(known as subprime mortgage crisis) and peaked with another shock of the collapse of Lehman

Brothers on September 15, 2008, the effects of this crisis concluded in the first quarter of 2009.

The other dummies DER,t, DIP,t, Di, t, DMS,t represent macroeconomic shocks dummies. These

dummies represent extreme shocks that are calculated on the basis of ARIMA residuals represented in

section 3.2.5. These shocks represent the extreme 10 percent of each ARIMA model residuals worst

realized values. The shocks are discussed under the extreme value theory and are generally lies in the

range of 1% to 10% (Longin & Solnik’s, 2001; Klein, 2013). Messis & Zapranis (2014) use the extreme

10% shocks to examine the maximum possible shocks, so this study follows the same approach. The

dummies take the value of 1 on each worst extreme 10 percent observation and zero otherwise.

In the above equation originator countries (k) are the markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe,

whereas i represent the US market. The significance and sign of each dummy represent the effect of

shock in each variable (exchange rate, Industrial production index, interest rates and money supply)

on the correlation coefficient of US herding measure. If the correlation coefficient change due to any

of these factors in any market. Then it can be stated that the contagion of herding exists due to a

macroeconomic shock or crisis.

Page 95: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

74

The experimental literature explore the effect of various macroeconomic variables (Belgacem,

and Lahiani, 2013; Messis & Zapranis, 2014; and Blasco 2009). However, the variable that have direct

effect on discount rate or expected cash flows have been found to have more consistent in the influence

(Gong & Dai (2017). Case (2000) and Catte, Girouard, Price, & André (2004) figure out the sensitivity

of asset prices to macroeconomic shocks including, changes in interest rates, industrial production,

and unexpected changes in the money supply. Similarly, Gong & Dai (2017) analyze significant effect

of Interest rate and exchange rates on herding behavior of investors in US market. Therefore, this

study incorporate interest rates, that is directly related with discount rate; exchange rate and growth

rate that influence expected cash flows and finally money supply that have impact on liquidity.

Page 96: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

75

Chapter 4

4. Results and Discussion

Return Dispersion Model Based on Christie & Huang (1995)

In the first section of analysis, this study discusses the results based on the return dispersion model of

Christie & Huang (1995).

Descriptive Statistics of Cross-Sectional Standard Deviation

Table 4.1 presents descriptive statistics of cross-sectional standard deviation. Panel A reports

summary statistics of developed markets, whereas panel B gives a summary of emerging and frontier

markets around the globe as per MCSI country classification. When individual returns move in the

same direction as the market returns the cross-sectional standard dispersion is low. When the deviation

of individual and market returns increases, the CSSD also increases.

Among developed markets, the average daily CSSD of Greece is highest 1.575% followed by

Portugal at 1.545%. US exhibit lowest average CSSD of 0.605 among all developed markets. The

average cross-sectional dispersion of Norway (1.302), Hong Kong (1.290), Singapore (1.255),

Denmark (1.274), Sweden (1.130), Belgium (1.125), Austria (1.108) and Netherland (1.033) are above

1%. Whereas, the CSSD for Germany (0.816), Italy (0.995), Spain (0.989), New Zealand (0.961),

Australia (0.915), France (0.889), Switzerland (0.872) Japan (0.827) and UK (0.792) are all below

1%. Similarly, like returns Greece market exhibit highest standard deviation of 1.086% and US

market has the lowest standard deviation of CSSD among all developed markets. The maximum range

of CSSD is also observed in Greece at 8.003% and lowest in US market at 3.022.

Page 97: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

76

The minimum CSSD of all countries is approximately equal to zero which may be due to least

dispersion in few days over the entire period. The study used standard dispersion measure followed by

Christie & Huang (1995), therefore, all observations are greater than zero.

Table 4.1: Descriptive statistics of Cross sectional Standard Deviation Panel A: Developed Market

Country Obs Mean St. Dev Max Min Skewness Kurtosis

Australia 6028 0.915 0.470 4.433 0.000 1.651 8.601

Austria 6036 1.108 0.755 6.324 0.000 2.073 10.891

Belgium 6452 1.125 0.665 5.195 0.000 1.447 6.833

Denmark 6362 1.274 0.934 8.159 0.000 1.940 9.798

France 4572 0.889 0.518 3.259 0.000 1.312 5.137

Germany 9130 0.816 0.533 4.710 0.000 1.901 9.095

Greece 6087 1.575 1.086 8.003 0.000 2.006 9.520

Hong Kong 6427 1.290 0.809 5.903 0.000 1.591 7.412

Italy 4696 0.995 0.521 3.542 0.000 1.208 5.478

Japan 9130 0.827 0.541 4.686 0.000 1.638 8.041

Netherland 8608 1.033 0.666 5.185 0.000 1.806 8.046

New Zealand 3913 0.961 0.528 4.050 0.000 1.522 7.346

Norway 8417 1.302 0.763 6.333 0.000 1.691 8.464

Portugal 6000 1.547 1.303 9.715 0.000 2.398 11.097

Singapore 4588 1.255 0.774 5.498 0.000 1.599 7.144

Spain 7523 0.989 0.640 5.631 0.000 2.084 10.267

Sweden 7658 1.130 0.731 5.825 0.000 1.812 8.513

Switzerland 6569 0.872 0.534 4.212 0.000 1.578 7.285

UK 7584 0.792 0.501 4.029 0.000 1.898 8.779

US 9130 0.605 0.369 3.022 0.000 1.957 9.039

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier markets

Country Obs Mean St. Dev Max Min Skewness Kurtosis

China 4628 0.926 0.608 4.296 0.000 1.367 3.223

Page 98: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

77

India 5479 0.840 0.505 4.589 0.000 1.665 9.155

Indonesia 4173 1.461 0.861 6.097 0.000 1.386 6.417

Korea 5340 1.461 0.854 6.060 0.000 1.300 6.115

Malaysia 5480 0.881 0.567 4.091 0.000 1.628 7.371

Pakistan 5479 1.317 0.859 7.019 0.000 1.726 8.668

Philippines 5565 1.290 0.830 6.079 0.000 1.481 6.926

Sri Lanka 5456 1.119 0.849 6.077 0.000 1.679 7.706

Taiwan 5478 1.088 0.667 4.029 0.000 0.977 4.222

Thailand 5469 1.319 0.834 5.906 0.000 1.512 6.886

Turkey 5974 1.938 1.221 9.813 0.000 1.467 6.253

Note: statistical properties of Cross-sectional standard deviation calculated through 1

)(1

2

,,

N

RR

CSSD

N

i

tmti

t

Among developing markets the average daily CSSD of turkey is highest 1.938% and India

exhibit lowest average CSSD of 0.84 among all developed markets. The average cross-sectional

dispersion of Turkey (1.938), Indonesia (1.461), Korea(1.461), Thailand(1.319), Pakistan(1.317),

Philippines (1.29), Sri Lanka(1.119) Taiwan(1.088) are above 1%. Whereas, the CSSD for China

(0.926), Malaysia (0.881), India (0.84) are all below 1%. Similarly, like returns, Turkish market

exhibit a highest standard deviation of 1.221% and Indian market has the lowest standard deviation of

CSSD 0.505% among all developed markets. The maximum range of CSSD is also observed in turkey

at 9.813%.

By looking at the mean value of CSSD it is observed that large economies like Australia, UK,

Japan, and US have lower value as compared to other emerging economies and frontier markets in the

data set. A lower mean value means lower cross-sectional dispersion among returns as compared to

other developing economies in the data set. A higher standard deviation may be indicative of unusual

cross-sectional dispersion in returns due to unexpected shock or crisis situation (Chiang & Zheng,

2010). It means that emerging and frontier markets are relatively more sensitive to the unexpected

shocks and returns are more volatile in these markets compared to the developed economies.

Page 99: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

78

Estimates of Herding Measure in Extreme Market Conditions

Table 4.2, presents the result of return dispersion model in all developed, emerging and frontier

markets. It is observed that 1 and 2 coefficients are all significant and positive in the markets under

study. All estimations are based on OLS method using Newey- West heteroscedasticity-consistent

standard errors. The period of market stress is classified as the upper and lower 1% and 5% of the

market returns in all distributions. For almost all markets analyzed, this study does not observe the

presence of herding behavior in extreme market events or a period of market stress both in upper and

lower market. For all developed, emerging and frontier markets regression results yield positive and

significant 1 and 2 values. These findings are consistent with Christie & Huang (1995), they observe

similar results in US markets. Chen (2013) also observe similar results in a set of 69 developed,

emerging and frontier markets and observe positive and significant coefficients in both rising and

falling markets during 2000 to 2009. The added contribution of this study is to obtain the similar result

using industrial indices by employing larger data set which starts from the time period of availability

for different economies to 2015.

Table 4.2: Estimates of herding measure in extreme market conditions: CSSD Panel A: Developed Markets

Criterion for extreme = 1% Criterion for extreme = 5%

Country

Australia 0.009*** 0.010*** 0.008*** 0.009*** 0.005*** 0.004***

Austria 0.011*** 0.017*** 0.015*** 0.010*** 0.012*** 0.010***

Belgium 0.011*** 0.011*** 0.013*** 0.010*** 0.007*** 0.008***

Denmark 0.012*** 0.020*** 0.022*** 0.011*** 0.013*** 0.015***

France 0.009*** 0.008*** 0.003*** 0.009*** 0.004*** 0.002***

Germany 0.008*** 0.014*** 0.012*** 0.007*** 0.008*** 0.008***

Greece 0.015*** 0.018*** 0.017*** 0.014*** 0.013*** 0.012***

Hong Kong 0.013*** 0.020*** 0.032*** 0.012*** 0.010*** 0.015***

Page 100: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

79

Italy 0.010*** 0.008*** 0.009*** 0.009*** 0.005*** 0.006***

Japan 0.008*** 0.009*** 0.009*** 0.008*** 0.005*** 0.006***

Netherland 0.010*** 0.016*** 0.016*** 0.009*** 0.009*** 0.009***

New Zealand 0.009*** 0.011*** 0.009*** 0.009*** 0.007*** 0.007***

Norway 0.013*** 0.018*** 0.017*** 0.012*** 0.010*** 0.010***

Portugal 0.015*** 0.020*** 0.032*** 0.013*** 0.019*** 0.022***

Singapore 0.012*** 0.012*** 0.014*** 0.012*** 0.008*** 0.011***

Spain 0.010*** 0.013*** 0.012*** 0.009*** 0.008*** 0.008***

Sweden 0.011*** 0.014*** 0.016*** 0.010*** 0.008*** 0.010***

Switzerland 0.009*** 0.011*** 0.016*** 0.008*** 0.007*** 0.008***

UK 0.008*** 0.010*** 0.010*** 0.007*** 0.006*** 0.006***

US 0.006*** 0.008*** 0.008*** 0.006*** 0.004*** 0.004***

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier markets

Criterion for extreme = 1% Criterion for extreme = 5%

Country

China 0.009*** 0.005*** 0.007*** 0.009*** 0.006*** 0.006***

India 0.056*** 0.013*** 0.051*** 0.058*** 0.020*** 0.061***

Indonesia 0.014*** 0.017*** 0.020*** 0.013*** 0.011*** 0.014***

Korea 0.014*** 0.015*** 0.014*** 0.014*** 0.010*** 0.011***

Malaysia 0.014*** 0.015*** 0.014*** 0.014*** 0.010*** 0.011***

Pakistan 0.013*** 0.027*** 0.022*** 0.012*** 0.016*** 0.014***

Philippines 0.013*** 0.011*** 0.015*** 0.012*** 0.009*** 0.011***

Sri Lanka 0.011*** 0.019*** 0.021*** 0.010*** 0.012*** 0.016***

Taiwan 0.011*** 0.014*** 0.017*** 0.010*** 0.012*** 0.012***

Thailand 0.013*** 0.018*** 0.019*** 0.012*** 0.011*** 0.013***

Turkey 0.019*** 0.028*** 0.028*** 0.018*** 0.017*** 0.019***

Note: the results of estimation through Christie and Huang (1995) model t

L

t

LU

t

U

t DDCSSD 21 ***indicate statistical significance at 1%. **Indicate statistical significance at 5%. *Indicate statistical significance at 10%.

These findings are in line with previous research as in developed markets. Chang et al., 2000,

and Demirer, Gubo, & Kutan, A. M. (2007) find no evidence of herding in US market specifically in

Page 101: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

80

a period of large price swings. Caparrelli et al. (2004) analyze Christie & Huang (1995) model and

find significant positive coefficients βL and βU that refute the presence of herding behavior for the

period 1988-2001 in extreme market conditions. Gleason et al. (2004) investigate herding in AMEX

stock exchange by employing intraday data for Exchange Traded Funds (ETFs) and observe evidence

against herding in extreme market stress during the period of 1999-2000. Henker et al. (2006) employ

intraday data and investigate herding in Australian equity markets using Christie & Huang (1995)

model. They observe that in extreme market events dispersion of individual returns to market returns

increases supporting the assumption of rational asset pricing model and no evidence in favor of herding

observed during extreme market stress. Blasco & Ferreuela (2008) analyzed the developed markets of

Germany, United Kingdom, United States, Mexico, Japan, Spain, and France but only Spanish market

exhibit aggregate market behavior. Demirer & Kutan (2006) find no evidence of herding during the

period of large price swings in the Chinese market. Similarly, Tan et al. (2008) observe similar findings

in Chinese A & B market shares. Demirer, Kutan, & Chen, (2010) employed CSSD model during a

period of 1995 to 2000 and find no evidence of herding in Taiwanese stock market during extreme

stress in the stock market. Similarly, Huang, Lin, & Yang, (2015) found no evidence of herding during

market stress in the taiwanese stock market. Purba and Faradynawati (2011) examine herding in the

indonesian market during extreme market condition and find no evidence of herding.

It is concluded that during the period of large price swings equity return dispersion increases rather

than decreasing. These findings are consistent with the prediction of CAPM as the rational asset pricing

models state that equity return dispersion increases during the turbulent period.

Return Dispersion Model based on Chiang et al. (2000)

Descriptive Statistics of Cross-Sectional Absolute Deviation of Returns

Table 4.3 reports the results of summary statistics of cross-sectional absolute deviation of

returns. Among developed markets, the average daily CSAD of Greece is highest 1.202% followed by

Page 102: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

81

Portugal at 1.036%. US exhibit lowest average CSSD of 0.453 among all developed markets. The

average cross-sectional dispersion of Greece (1.202) and Portugal (1.036), are above 1%. Whereas,

the CSAD for Germany Norway (0.962), Hong Kong (0.928), Denmark(0.927), Singapore(0.91),

Sweden(0.828), Austria(0.811), Belgium(0.767), Netherland (0.763), Italy(0.743), Spain(0.722),

France (0.688), New Zealand (0.688), Australia(0.666), Switzerland(0.648), Japan(0.607),

Germany(0.602), UK(0.585), and US(0.453) are all below 1%. Similarly, like returns Greece market

exhibit highest standard deviation of 0.758% and US market has the lowest standard deviation of

CSAD among all developed markets at 0.275. The maximum range of CSAD is also observed in

Greece at 5.482%.

Among developing markets the average daily CSAD of turkey is highest at 1.43% and China exhibits

lowest average CSAD of 0.689 among all developed markets. The average cross-sectional dispersion

of Turkey (1.43), India (1.112), Korea (1.082), Malaysia (1.082), Indonesia (1.067) are above 1%.

Whereas, the CSAD for Thailand (0.992), Philippines (0.948), Pakistan(0.905), Sri Lanka (0.81),

Taiwan(0.758), China (0.689) are all below 1%. Similarly, like returns Turkish market exhibits

highest standard deviation of 0.888% and Chinese market has the lowest standard deviation of CSAD

0.452% among all emerging and frontier markets.

The minimum CSAD of all countries is approximately equal to zero which may be due to least

dispersion in few days over the entire period. The study used absolute deviation measure followed by

Chiang et al. (2000), therefore, all observations are greater than zero.

It is observed that the average CSAD of developed economies like US, UK, Germany, is lowest

among all developed markets, however in emerging economies Chinese market exhibit lowest mean

value among other markets in the sample. A lower mean value means lower cross-sectional absolute

dispersion among returns as compared to other economies in the data set. A higher standard deviation

may be indicative of unusual cross-sectional dispersion in returns due to unexpected shock or crisis

situation (Chiang & Zheng, 2010). It means that emerging and frontier markets are relatively more

Page 103: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

82

sensitive to the unexpected shocks as these markets are characterized by less sophisticated institutional

structures, regulatory frameworks are weak and less protection is available to the investor as markets

are volatile compared to the developed economies (Demirer & Kutan, 2006).

Table 4.3: Descriptive Statistics of Cross-Sectional Absolute Deviation CSAD Country Obs Mean St. Dev Max Min Skewness Kurtosis

Australia 6028 0.666 0.328 2.880 0.000 1.463 7.396

Austria 6036 0.811 0.530 4.198 0.000 1.857 6.487

Belgium 6452 0.767 0.444 3.730 0.000 1.505 7.436

Denmark 6362 0.927 0.646 4.995 0.000 1.548 6.897

France 4572 0.688 0.411 3.156 0.000 1.500 6.300

Germany 9130 0.602 0.381 3.252 0.000 1.852 8.938

Greece 6087 1.202 0.758 5.482 0.000 1.490 6.837

Hong Kong 6427 0.928 0.563 4.491 0.000 1.620 8.212

Italy 4696 0.743 0.386 2.972 0.000 1.245 5.796

Japan 9130 0.607 0.387 2.996 0.000 1.501 7.126

Netherland 8608 0.763 0.489 4.087 0.000 1.873 8.623

New Zealand 3913 0.688 0.344 2.592 0.000 1.182 6.242

Norway 8417 0.962 0.534 4.071 0.000 1.395 6.851

Portugal 6000 1.036 0.777 5.967 0.000 2.088 9.637

Singapore 4588 0.910 0.537 3.976 0.000 1.471 6.666

Spain 7523 0.722 0.443 4.433 0.000 2.005 10.539

Sweden 7658 0.828 0.517 4.563 0.000 1.773 8.741

Switzerland 6569 0.648 0.389 2.889 0.000 1.565 7.270

UK 7584 0.585 0.363 2.918 0.000 1.891 8.755

US 9130 0.453 0.275 2.394 0.000 2.025 9.574

Panel B: emerging and Frontier markets

Country Obs Mean St. Dev Max Min Skewness Kurtosis

China 4628 0.689 0.452 4.046 0.000 1.552 4.846

India 5479 1.112 0.645 5.360 0.000 1.208 5.745

Page 104: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

83

Indonesia 4173 1.067 0.618 4.592 0.000 1.346 6.597

Korea 5340 1.082 0.611 4.092 0.000 1.158 5.558

Malaysia 5340 1.082 0.611 4.092 0.000 1.158 5.558

Pakistan 5479 0.905 0.565 4.645 0.000 1.546 7.719

Philippines 5565 0.948 0.582 3.984 0.000 1.243 5.814

Sri Lanka 5456 0.810 0.616 4.992 0.000 1.756 8.643

Taiwan 5478 0.758 0.456 3.474 0.000 0.986 4.608

Thailand 5469 0.992 0.624 4.863 0.000 1.574 7.471

Turkey 5974 1.430 0.888 6.665 0.000 1.464 6.138

Note: statistical properties of measure cross-sectional absolute deviation calculated through

N

i

tmtit RRN

CSAD1

,, ||1

Estimates of Herding Measure Based on Constant Coefficient Model

Table 4.4 reports the results of return dispersion model based on Chang et al. (2000). They observe

herding behavior as a nonlinear function of market returns and cross-sectional absolute deviation. If

the nonlinear term in the model is negative and significant then herding is present in the market and

insignificant term reports the absence of herding and presence of rationality in the market.

Table 4.4: Estimates of herding measure based on constant coefficient model: CSAD Panel A: Developed Markets

Country R2

Australia 0.005*** 0.291*** 1.001 0.22

Austria 0.005*** 0.542*** -3.464*** 0.35

Belgium 0.005*** 0.419*** -1.227 0.32

Denmark 0.005*** 0.693*** -5.084*** 0.40

France 0.005*** 0.193*** -0.449 0.17

Germany 0.004*** 0.394*** -1.597*** 0.40

Greece 0.007*** 0.480*** -2.382*** 0.33

Hong Kong 0.006*** 0.385*** -1.832*** 0.31

Italy 0.005*** 0.238*** -1.076*** 0.21

Page 105: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

84

Japan 0.004*** 0.252*** -1.204*** 0.20

Malaysia 0.008*** 0.334*** -1.729*** 0.26

Netherland 0.005*** 0.396*** -1.230*** 0.35

New Zealand 0.005*** 0.538*** -5.061*** 0.29

Norway 0.006*** 0.421*** -2.149*** 0.32

Portugal 0.005*** 1.017*** -9.552*** 0.44

Singapore 0.006*** 0.469*** -3.654*** 0.27

Spain 0.005*** 0.362*** -1.586*** 0.30

Sweden 0.005*** 0.415*** -2.177*** 0.32

Switzerland 0.004*** 0.389*** -1.993*** 0.34

UK 0.004*** 0.279*** -1.045*** 0.23

US 0.003*** 0.185*** -0.399*** 0.21

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier Markets

Country R2

China 0.004*** 0.289*** -2.854*** 0.19

India 0.006*** 0.294*** -1.064*** 0.26

Indonesia 0.006*** 0.678*** -5.429*** 0.41

Korea 0.008*** 0.334*** -1.729*** 0.26

Malaysia 0.008*** 0.334*** -1.729*** 0.26

Pakistan 0.006*** 0.406*** -1.777*** 0.35

Philippines 0.006*** 0.433*** -2.815*** 0.28

Sri Lanka 0.004*** 0.819*** -5.672*** 0.56

Taiwan 0.004*** 0.479*** -4.834*** 0.38

Thailand 0.006*** 0.415*** -1.940*** 0.33

Turkey 0.008*** 0.462*** -1.548*** 0.39

Note: the results of estimation through Chang et al. (2000) model ttmtmt RRCSAD 2

,3,21

***indicate statistical significance at 1%. **Indicate statistical significance at 5%. *Indicate statistical significance at 10%.

From the Panel A and B of table 4.4, it is observed that herding is present in all the developed,

emerging and frontier markets except Australia, Belgium, and France. These results are consistent with

Page 106: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

85

Henker et al. (2006) and Chang & Zheng (2010) as they observe insignificant herding behavior in

Australian and French markets. It means that that information is communicated efficiently to investors

in Australian, Belgium and French equity market. Herding is more likely to be present in emerging

and developing markets due to their market characteristics including weak regulatory system,

immature financial system, control of the market in the hands of few institutional investors, the

existence of speculators, and transmission of highly volatile capital flows from international markets

(Economou et al., 2000). The negative significant sign of coefficient reports presence of herding

behavior in rest of the markets at 1% significance level.

The empirical literature provide support to Chang et al. (2000) model in both developed and

developing markets. Caparrelli et al. (2004) employ Chang et al. (2000) model and observe herding

under normal condition, using the same model they also observe an asymmetry in herding behavior

which is more pronounced during up market condition than down market. Economou, Kostakis, &

Philippas, (2011) examine four markets of Europe during 1998 to 2008 namely Spanish, Italian,

Portuguese and Greek and find strong evidence of herding in Italian and Greek stock market. Whereas

they Portuguese market shows unclear results depending on the choice of calculation of portfolios.

Spanish market provides insignificant results and rejects the hypothesis of the presence of

herding. Lao & Singh (2011), observe significant herding behavior in the stock market of China and

India. Tan et al. (2008) use Chang et al. (2000) methodology and analyze herding behavior in

asymmetric patterns of returns, trading volume and level of volatility in Chinese stock market Demirer

et al. (2014) investigate the existence of herding in American Depository Receipts (ADRs) and infer

more evident herding at sector level than country level. Hsieh, Yang, Yang, & Lee (2011) investigate

12 Asian markets by using return dispersion models and find significant herding behavior. Garg &

Gulati (2013) find no evidence of herding in Indian stock market by employing Chang et al. (2000)

under normal market conditions. Similarly, Javaira & Hassan (2015) identify no evidence of herding

Page 107: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

86

during normal market conditions but significant herding behavior during a crisis situation in Pakistani

stock market.

Mobarek, Mollah, & Keasey (2014) examine herding behavior in a large set of European

markets using sector level data and find no evidence of herding behavior find no evidence of herding

behavior under normal market condition in PIIGS (Portugal, Italy, Ireland, Greece, Spain),

Nordic(Finland, Norway Sweden Denmark) and Continental Europe (France Germany) with the

exception of Finland and Germany. Henker et al. (2006) find a nonlinear relationship in returns and

cross-sectional dispersion using daily data in Australian marker, but they observe insignificant result

when intraday data is employed. Zhou & Anderson (2013) employ quantile regression to the Chang et

al. (2000) methodology in US equity REIT for a period of 1980 to 2010. They find herding in bear

markets and normal market conditions only, and in high quantile of return dispersion.

It is observed that all developed markets except Australia, Belgium, and France exhibit herding

behavior. However, the presence of herding is observed in all emerging and frontier markets. These

outcomes are consistent with previous literature as herding is more likely to be present in emerging

and developing markets than in developed markets (Economou et al., 2000).

Estimates of Herding based on Chang and Zheng (2010)

Table 4.5 reports the results based on the return dispersion with asymmetric effect proposed by

Chang & Zheng (2010). Similar to the Chang et al. (2000) model all the developed, emerging and

frontier markets exhibit similar results. Herding is absent in Australia and Belgium but French market

exhibit significant herding behavior at 10% level of significance.

The underlying assumption of adding the term≠ 0, is to observe the relative asymmetry in

market returns and cross-sectional dispersion. As this coefficient is significant and positive, therefore

+ captures the relationship between return dispersion and market returns here the market returns

have a greater effect on cross-sectional returns return dispersion as Rm > 0. The effect of absolute

Page 108: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

87

market return is larger when the market returns are positive (+ ) than when the market returns are

negative (- . These results are calculated through the ratio (γ2+ γ3) / (γ3- γ2).

For most of the markets is significant and positive, however, almost all markets except Australia

and Belgium report significant herding behavior.

Table 4.5: Estimates of asymmetric herding behavior based on constant coefficient model: CSAD Panel A: Developed Markets

Country R2

Australia 0.005*** 0.018* 0.286*** 1.275 0.22

Austria 0.005*** 0.004 0.543*** -3.442*** 0.35

Belgium 0.005*** 0.014** 0.418*** -1.155 0.32

Denmark 0.005*** 0.024*** 0.689*** -4.912*** 0.40

France 0.005*** 0.010* 0.195*** -0.493* 0.17

Germany 0.004*** 0.010** 0.394*** -1.552*** 0.40

Greece 0.006*** 0.037*** 0.387*** -1.811*** 0.31

Hong Kong 0.006*** 0.015*** 0.293*** -1.021*** 0.26

Italy 0.005*** 0.009 0.239*** -1.060*** 0.22

Japan 0.004*** 0.027*** 0.250*** -1.099*** 0.20

Netherland 0.005*** 0.010* 0.395*** -1.188*** 0.35

New Zealand 0.005*** 0.013*** 0.536*** -4.848*** 0.29

Norway 0.006*** 0.022*** 0.417*** -1.977*** 0.32

Portugal 0.005*** 0.031** 1.021*** -9.571*** 0.45

Singapore 0.006*** 0.031*** 0.464*** -3.448*** 0.28

Spain 0.005*** 0.002*** 0.362*** -1.587*** 0.30

Sweden 0.005*** 0.019*** 0.416*** -2.181*** 0.32

Switzerland 0.004*** 0.012** 0.389*** -1.928*** 0.35

UK 0.004*** 0.007 0.278*** -0.997*** 0.23

US 0.003*** 0.001 0.185*** -0.394*** 0.21

Page 109: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

88

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier Markets

Country R2

China 0.004*** 0.001 0.289*** -2.849*** 0.17

India 0.006*** 0.015*** 0.293*** -1.021*** 0.26

Indonesia 0.006*** 0.045*** 0.666*** -4.967*** 0.42

Korea 0.008*** 0.013** 0.334*** -1.724*** 0.26

Malaysia 0.008*** 0.013 0.334*** -1.724*** 0.26

Pakistan 0.006*** 0.010 0.408*** -1.789*** 0.35

Philippines 0.006*** 0.030*** 0.440*** -2.938*** 0.29

Sri Lanka 0.004*** 0.041*** 0.811*** -5.542*** 0.56

Taiwan 0.004*** 0.007 0.478*** -4.794*** 0.38

Thailand 0.006*** 0.014 0.415*** -1.948*** 0.33

Turkey 0.008*** 0.016*** 0.460*** -1.523*** 0.39

Note: Properties of the estimates calculated through model ttmtmtmt RRRCSAD 2

,4,3,21

***indicate statistical significance at 1%. **Indicate statistical significance at 5%. *Indicate statistical significance at 10%.

Chang & Lin (2015) employ this model and observe herding behavior in a set of 49 developed,

emerging and frontier markets and observe significant herding behavior in most of the markets.

Similarly, Demirer, Kutan, & Zhang (2014) employ this model to test herding in ADR issues in 19

markets within country and sector-based portfolios.

It is observed that all developed markets except Australia, and Belgium exhibit herding behavior. By

setting French market also exhibit herding behavior. Similar to Chang et al. (2000), the presence

of herding is observed in all emerging and frontier markets. These findings are consistent with previous

studies as herding is more likely to be present in emerging and developing markets than in developed

markets (Economou et al., 2000).

Page 110: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

89

Time-Varying Model of Herding Behavior

Descriptive Statistics of Time-Varying Herding Parameter

Table 4.6 shows the descriptive statistics of the dynamic herding measure 2,t for all developed,

emerging and frontier markets. Panel A of the table 4.6 report summary statistics of time-varying

herding estimates of the developed markets. Except for Australia, Belgium, and Portugal all countries

exhibit a negative mean value of the herding measure. These signs are supported in most of the

countries with negative skewness, it means that herding is widely present in most of the developed

markets. These results are in contradiction with Chiang et al. (2013), they observe positive coefficient

of herding estimates in US market during the sample period and the negative mean coefficient in the

Australian market. However, the results of Chinese, Hong Kong, and Singaporean markets are in line

with this study. According to Garbade & Watchtel (1978), the coefficient estimates of OLS estimation

are not average of the time-varying coefficients.

It is observed that the mean value of AU, OE, BG, DK, BD, GR, HK, IT, NL, NZ, NW, PT,

SG, ES, SD, SW, UK, and US, are 1.00%, -5.40%, 11.60%, -0.60%, -2.50%, -3.40%, -5.40%, -1.20%,

-1.10%, -3.30%, 1.10%, -4.80%, -2.70%, -2.90%, -1.40%, and -1.30% respectively as compared to

the slope value of coefficient 1.00%, -3.46%, -1.23%, -5.08%, -1.60%, -2.38%, -1.83%, -1.08%, -

1.23%, -5.06%, -2.15%, -9.55%, -3.65%, -1.59%, -2.18%, -1.99%, -1.05%, and -0.40%. Except

Australian market, all markets exhibit large variations from the slope of the constant coefficient model.

All the negative time-varying coefficients are consistent with the earlier findings. The time-varying

coefficient validate the presence of herding. The maximum and minimum value of Singapore market

exhibit negative value of herding coefficient which means that the herding coefficient is present

throughout the sampling period. These findings are in contradiction with the results of Yang & Chen

(2015). They find no evidence of herding in Hong Kong and American markets. Time-varying herding

Page 111: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

90

behavior is absent in Japanese and French market over the entire sample period, therefore not included

in the results.

Table 4.6: Descriptive Statistics of herding coefficient determine by Dynamic Model Panel A: Developed Markets

Country Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev Maximum Minimum Skewness Kurtosis

Australia 2,t 6028 0.010 0.063 0.486 -0.144 1.304 7.745

Austria 2,t 6036 -0.054 0.088 0.293 -0.281 0.669 3.751

Belgium 2,t 6452 0.116 0.070 0.320 -0.022 0.813 2.735

Denmark 2,t 6362 -0.006 0.098 0.265 -0.253 0.202 2.539

Germany 2,t 9130 -0.025 0.063 0.419 -0.214 1.555 9.751

Greece 2,t 6087 -0.034 0.029 0.001 -0.114 -1.095 3.470

Hong Kong 2,t 6400 -0.054 0.035 0.053 -0.146 -0.475 3.098

Italy 2,t 4696 -0.012 0.028 0.078 -0.102 0.140 4.484

Netherland 2,t 8608 -0.011 0.061 0.256 -0.192 0.333 4.690

Norway 2,t 8391 -0.033 0.036 0.144 -0.124 1.618 8.217

Portugal 2,t 5999 0.011 0.194 0.698 -0.443 0.558 2.859

Singapore 2,t 4588 -0.048 0.008 -0.031 -0.067 -0.050 2.743

Spain 2,t 7522 -0.027 0.033 0.046 -0.155 -0.638 3.957

Sweden 2,t 7658 -0.029 0.029 0.071 -0.111 0.295 2.979

UK 2,t 7584 -0.014 0.033 0.100 -0.117 -0.074 2.762

US 2,t 9130 -0.013 0.022 0.054 -0.079 -0.310 2.910

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier Markets

Country Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev Maximum Minimum Skewness Kurtosis

China 2,t 4602 -0.025 0.006 -0.013 -0.042 -0.450 3.465

India 2,t 5479 -0.048 0.102 0.035 -0.111 0.894 4.432

Indonesia 2,t 4173 -0.043 0.046 0.099 -0.165 -0.137 3.424

Korea 2,t 5314 -0.059 0.026 0.000 -0.129 -0.405 2.460

Malaysia 2,t 5480 -0.091 0.059 0.043 -0.263 -0.523 2.635

Page 112: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

91

Pakistan 2,t 5479 -0.052 0.048 0.059 -0.182 -0.392 2.656

Philippines 2,t 5565 -0.058 0.030 -0.010 -0.136 -0.826 3.299

Sri Lanka 2,t 5455 -0.091 0.117 0.302 -0.424 0.528 3.898

Taiwan 2,t 5476 -0.036 0.015 -0.011 -0.067 -0.062 2.135

Thailand 2,t 5469 -0.037 0.021 0.026 -0.085 0.512 3.137

Turkey 2,t 5974 -0.003 0.017 0.024 -0.062 -1.440 5.940

Properties of the estimates calculated through state space model applied on ttmtmt rrCSAD 2

,2,10

Panel B of table 4.6 presents the results for the emerging and frontier markets. It is observed

that the mean values of CA, IN, ID, KO, MY, PK, PH, CY, TA, TH, and TK markets are -2.50%, -

4.30%, -4.30%, -5.90%, -9.10%, -5.20%, -5.80%, -9.10%, -3.60%, -3.70%, and -0.30% respectively

as compare to the slope value of coefficient -2.85%, -1.06%, -5.43%, 1.73%, -1.73%, -1.78%, -2.82%,

-5.67%, -4.83%, -1.94%, and -1.55%. All the mean value of the time-varying models are different

from the slope value of the constant coefficient model. Most of the coefficient in the time-varying

models are negatively skewed which means that during the sample period emerging markets show

persistent herding behavior. These findings are consistent with the Yang & Chan (2015), they find

significant time-varying herding in Taiwan and Chinese stock market. These findings are also

consistent with Chiang et al. (2013) as they observe significant time-varying herding behavior in a set

of emerging markets including China, Indonesia, Malaysia, Korea, Thailand and Taiwan. All the

markets show negative and significant mean value of herding coefficient in both studies. The

minimum-maximum range and the value of st. deviation in herding series indicate that among

emerging markets CY, MY, IN, ID, PK, and PH are higher and consistent than all other markets. The

correlation of herding measure is given in appendix 4.

Page 113: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

92

The Time Series of Herding Coefficient

4.3.2.1 Developed Markets

Figure 4.1 and 4.2 present the plot of time series estimates of herding coefficient 3,t calculated by

state space model using Kalman filter estimation along with the confidence interval of 95%. Figure

4.1 provides the results from the herding series estimates of 20 developed markets over time. The

sampling period for all series is different depending upon the data limitations. It is observed that

herding series in some developed markets do not display time variation. Belgium and Australian

markets show positive values over the entire period with the exception of few negative shocks in the

Australian market. These results are consistent with the constant coefficient model as the stated model

predict no herding in these two markets. These findings contradict to Chiang et al. (2013) as they

observe significant time-varying herding behavior in Australian market from the period of 1997 to

2008. Similarly, French market also provides evidence against herding behavior. These findings are in

line with a constant coefficient model where we observe no evidence of herding. Therefore it can be

concluded that French market exhibit no herding on average and over the time. The results of US

market also contradict with Chiang et al. (2013) as they find no evidence of herding in US market.

This study observe time-varying herding even the presence of mean value of -1.3% and negative

skewness also support the existence of herd behavior in US market.

In most of the time period Austrian market exhibits negative herding behavior and time-varying

value mostly prevailing in the negative region of the graph. The mean value of -5.4% also supports the

evidence. Denmark market exhibits mixed evidence. There are certain periods in which herding

coefficient lies in the negative regions and several positive coefficient periods are also observed. On

average this study can conclude that in general herding prevail in DK market.

German market shows significant herding behavior as most of the times herding coefficient

remains negative with a mean value of -2.5%. German market exhibits similar results with a constant

Page 114: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

93

coefficient model of Chang et al. (2000). In Greek market, strong evidence of herding behavior is

observed. The time series of herding coefficient remains in the negative region throughout the sample

period. The herding series exhibit negative mean value of -3.4% along with negative skewness and

max-min range of -11.4%. Therefore, GK market exhibits strong herding behavior as similar results is

obtained through the constant coefficient model.

Similar findings are observed in Hong Kong market. All of the coefficients of time series

observed to remain in the negative region of the graph with a mean value of -5.4% and negative

skewness. These findings are supported by the constant coefficient model. These findings are in line

with the Chiang et al. (2013) model but are in contradiction with Yang & Chen (2015) findings as they

observe the absence of time-varying herding behavior in HK market.

Italian market exhibits mixed time periods of increased and decreased dispersion. In several

time periods time-varying herding behavior is observed. This is confirmed by the presence of negative

mean value of -1.2% but evidence of intense herding is weakened by the presence of positive skewness.

Japanese market provides evidence against time-varying herding behavior. The constant coefficient

model reports strong evidence of herding, therefore, it can be said that on average the investors of

Japanese market exhibit herding behavior but it is non time varying in nature.

Netherland and Norwegian markets exhibit mixed evidence of time-varying herding behavior.

Several episodes of negative coefficient time periods with few periods of positive trends are witnessed.

However, New Zealand market provides results similar to Japan. In this market constant coefficient

model predict herding behavior but no evidence of this behavior is observed over time.

Singapore market exhibits strong evidence of herding behavior. Over the entire sample, period

herding behavior is consistent and negative. These results are supported by the findings of Chiang et

al. (2013). They also report strong evidence of time-varying herding behavior in Singapore. It is the

only market in the sample of the developed market where max-min range of -0.067 to -0.031 lies in

Page 115: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

94

the negative region of the market with a mean value of -4.8% and negative skewness. Thus SG market

displays strong evidence of herding and time-varying herding among all developed markets.

Spanish, Swedish and UK markets exhibit evidence like most of the markets. Mixed evidence

of time-varying herding behavior is observed. Several episodes of negative coefficient time periods

with few periods of positive trends. In several periods time-varying herding behavior is observed. This

is confirmed by the presence of negative mean value of -2.7%, -2.9% and -1.4% but evidence of intense

herding is weakened by the presence of positive skewness in Swedish market. However, Spanish and

UK market exhibit evidence stronger than Sweden due to the presence of negative skewness in both

markets. The presence of herding behavior in all three markets is also confirmed by the presence of

negative coefficient in the constant coefficient model of herding behavior.

The Swiss market exhibits surprising results like many other markets with the absence of time-

varying herding behavior. Like Japan and New Zealand time-varying nature of herding behavior is not

present in the Swiss market but the presence of constant negative coefficient in Chang et al. (2000)

model supports the presence of herding behavior in this particular market.

Therefore it can be concluded that a market exhibiting herding as a constant parameter does not display

same behavior over time. Chiang et al. (2013) argued that if a certain shock hits the economy during a

specific period it can be explained through linkages other than trade or fundamental.

This study observes time variation of herding behavior in all emerging markets. Few developed

markets like Belgium, France, New Zealand, and Switzerland exhibit time-invariant herding behavior.

Therefore, ample evidence of time variation of herding behavior in developed and developing markets

provide support to the hypothesis that herding behavior is a time-variant phenomenon, not a short-term

disequilibrium.

Page 116: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

95

-.4

-.2

.0

.2

.4

.6

199

21

99

3

199

4

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Australia

-.6

-.4

-.2

.0

.2

.4

.6

199

21

99

3

199

4

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficinet ± 2 RMSE

Austria

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

.4

199

1

199

2

199

3

199

4

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Belgium

-.4

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

.4

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Denmark

-1E+119

0E+00

1E+119

2E+119

3E+119

4E+119

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

France

-.4

-.2

.0

.2

.4

.6

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Germany

-.20

-.16

-.12

-.08

-.04

.00

.04

.08

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Greece

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

199

1

199

2

199

3

199

4

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Hong Kong

-.20

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

.15

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Italy

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

198

11

98

21

98

31

98

41

98

51

98

61

98

71

98

81

98

91

99

01

99

11

99

21

99

31

99

41

99

51

99

61

99

71

99

81

99

92

00

02

00

12

00

22

00

32

00

42

00

52

00

62

00

72

00

82

00

92

01

02

01

12

01

22

01

32

01

42

01

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Japan

Figure 4-1: Time series of 2,t in developed markets(continued)

Page 117: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

96

-.4

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

.4

.5

198

31

98

41

98

51

98

61

98

71

98

81

98

91

99

01

99

11

99

21

99

31

99

41

99

51

99

61

99

71

99

81

99

92

00

02

00

12

00

22

00

32

00

42

00

52

00

62

00

72

00

82

00

92

01

02

01

12

01

22

01

32

01

42

01

5Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Netherland

-.016

-.012

-.008

-.004

.000

.004

.008

.012

.016

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Newzealand

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Norway

-1.2

-0.8

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Portugal

-.10

-.08

-.06

-.04

-.02

.00

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Singapore

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Spain

-.20

-.16

-.12

-.08

-.04

.00

.04

.08

.12

.16

198

61

98

7

198

8

198

9

199

0

199

1

199

2

199

3

199

4

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Sweden

-.00006

-.00004

-.00002

.00000

.00002

.00004

.00006

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Switzerland

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

198

61

98

7

198

8

198

9

199

0

199

1

199

2

199

3

199

4

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

UK

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

1981

1982

1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

US

Figure 4.1: Time series of 2,t in Developed market

Page 118: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

97

-.06

-.05

-.04

-.03

-.02

-.01

.00

.01

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

China

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

India

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Indonesia

-.25

-.20

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Korea

-.5

-.4

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Malaysia

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Pakistan

-.20

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

199

4

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Philippines

-.8

-.6

-.4

-.2

.0

.2

.4

.6

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Sri Lanka

-.10

-.08

-.06

-.04

-.02

.00

.02

.04

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Taiwan

-.16

-.12

-.08

-.04

.00

.04

.08

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Thailand

-.100

-.075

-.050

-.025

.000

.025

.050

.075

.100

199

3

199

4

199

5

199

6

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

201

3

201

4

201

5

Herd Coefficient ± 2 RMSE

Turkey

Figure 4-2: Time series of 2,t in emerging and frontier market

Page 119: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

98

4.3.2.2 Emerging and Frontier Markets

Figure 4.2 reports the result of Time-varying herding estimates of emerging and Frontier

markets. This study observes that the evidence of time-varying herding behavior is stronger in

developing markets than developed markets. It is observed that Chinese market exhibit strong

evidence of herding behavior. Over the entire sample, herding behavior is consistent and negative.

These results are supported by the findings of Chiang et al. (2013) and Yang & Chen (2015). They

also observe strong evidence of time-varying herding behavior in the Chinese market. It can be

confirmed by the presence of max-min range -0.042 to -0.013 in the negative region of the figure

with a mean value of -2.5% and negative skewness. Similar outcomes are observed in case of

Korean, Philippines, and Taiwanese markets. All the mean values are negative -5.9%, -5.8%, and

-3.6% respectively with all series exhibiting negative skewness. However, in all the three markets,

the extreme value remained in the negative region of the graph.

All other markets except Sri Lanka and Thailand exhibit strong evidence of herding. In both

these markets, several episodes of increased and decreased dispersion are observed. On average

market exhibit herding behavior during the entire period as the negative mean value of coefficient

predict (-9.1% and -3.7%) but the value of Skewness is positive in both markets. However, Indian,

Indonesian, Malaysian and Pakistani markets exhibit strong evidence of herding with a very few

episode of increase dispersion in these markets. All four markets exhibit a negative mean value of

-4.8%, -4.3%, -9.1% and -5.2% and for Pakistan with negative skewness. All these markets support

the findings of the constant coefficient model where there exists strong support of herding

behavior. Turkish market exhibit time-varying herding behavior but the evidence is weak as the

mean value of the coefficient is 0.3% and max-min range of 0.024 to -0.062. The skewness is

although negative but the value nearer to zero is observed over the entire distribution.

Page 120: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

99

Therefore, it can be concluded that the time-varying herding behavior is more pronounced in

emerging markets than in developed markets. Voronkova & Bohl, (2005) argue that capital market

and especially the emerging markets exhibit more herding tendency as compared to the well-

developed markets (Wermer, 1999). The investor in these markets is normally irrational due to the

absence of information set needed to make reliable investments. Markets are fragile, the presence

of weak regulatory systems, the concentration of wealth in few hands and the strong influence of

speculators make the markets more volatile. Therefore, in order to make investment decisions

either they rely on the information set available in the market or follow the footsteps of large

institutional investors.

Determinants of Herding Behavior

In table 4.7 this study reports the effect of two domestic and one cross country factor of

herding behavior. Market returns as a proxy for market performance and volatility of domestic

market calculated through the asymmetric GARCH model are used as domestic factors. Whereas,

global market volatility is measured through CBOE implied volatility index VIX.

Panel A of the table 4.7 presents the results for the developed markets. It is observed that

stock market performance affect the herding behavior in Denmark and Portugal markets only and

this effect is positive. These findings are in contradiction with Chiang et al. (2013) as they observe

the negative significant effect of stock returns on herding behavior. An increase in stock returns

will increase herding behavior, these findings are similar to the findings of Tan et al. (2008) and

Mobarek et al. (2014). When there are positive returns in the stock market, investors tend to follow

the market consensus by discarding their own set of information and affirms that herding is more

prevalent in turbulent periods, when the market is facing extreme returns (Christie & Huang,

Page 121: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

100

1995). These findings are consistent with Duffee (2001), they find a higher aggregation of trading

volumes in days when the stock market is rising.

Except for Norway, all developed markets exhibit a significant relationship with increased

volatility at 1% significance level. Herding is positively related to the stock market volatility. The

herding coefficient has a negative sign, the negative sign of volatility in results can be interpreted

into increased dispersion. It means that stock return volatility has a significant effect on the herding

behavior of an investor. In more volatile periods investors set aside the information set available

with them and follow the market consensus. In few markets, effect is negative whereas for others

it is positive.

Table 4.7: Domestic and Cross-Market Determinants of Herding Behavior Panel A: Developed Markets

Country ∅0 ∅1 ∅2 ∅3 R2

Australia -0.1894*** 0.1434 -0.0190*** 0.0004 0.024

Austria -0.2991*** -0.1052 -0.0249*** 0.0003 0.034

Denmark -0.4303*** 0.2079** -0.0450*** -0.0003 0.216

Germany -0.1083*** 0.0050 -0.0129*** 0.0010*** 0.010

Greece 0.0070 -0.0214 0.0063*** 0.0006*** 0.083

Hong Kong 0.0977*** -0.0001 0.0173*** 0.0001 0.116

Italy 0.0897*** 0.0006 0.0096*** -0.0007*** 0.029

Netherland -0.3124*** -0.0639 -0.0280*** 0.0020*** 0.066

Norway -0.0456** 0.0087 -0.0021 -0.0004** 0.011

Portugal 0.4997*** 0.4594** 0.0402*** -0.0053*** 0.043

Singapore -0.0178** 0.0007 0.0027*** -0.0003*** 0.040

Spain -0.0023 0.0164 0.0027*** 0.0000 0.002

Sweden -0.1167*** -0.0094 -0.0069*** 0.0013*** 0.059

Page 122: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

101

UK 0.0884*** 0.0189 0.0100*** -0.0003* 0.031

US -0.0053* -0.0043 0.0072*** -0.0002* 0.031

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier Markets

Country ∅0 ∅1 ∅2 ∅3 R2

China -0.0307*** 0.0004 -0.0010*** -0.0001*** 0.077

India -0.0226* 0.0047 0.0040* -0.0004** 0.009

Indonesia -0.1426*** 0.0302 -0.0120*** -0.0005** 0.048

Korea 0.0320*** 0.0091 0.0130*** 0.0010*** 0.484

Malaysia 0.1256*** -0.0826 0.0209*** -0.0005** 0.101

Pakistan -0.0419*** 0.0946** 0.0022** 0.0005*** 0.008

Philippines -0.0698*** -0.0726** -0.0013 0.0000 0.001

Sri Lanka -0.1225*** 0.0105*** -0.0001 0.0013*** 0.014

Taiwan -0.0792*** -0.0131 -0.0058*** -0.0005*** 0.181

Thailand -0.0230** 0.0125 0.0037*** 0.0009*** 0.159

Turkey -0.0995*** -0.02 -0.0106*** 0.0005*** 0.305

Note: the results are obtained through OLS estimated of equation 𝐻𝑒𝑟𝑑𝑡 = ∅0 + ∅1𝑅𝑚,𝑡 + ∅2�̂�𝑡2 + ∅3𝑉𝐼𝑋𝑡−1 + 𝜀𝑡

***indicate statistical significance at 1%. **Indicate statistical significance at 5%. *Indicate statistical significance at 10%.

The episodes of the recent financial crisis validate the effect interdependence of stock

market and transmission of volatility from one market to another (Diebold & Yilmaz, 2009).

Analysis into the causes of the recent crisis in financial markets indicate whenever the negative

news is generated in one market it is quickly absorbed by the participants of other markets,

irrespective of the channel through which this news is transmitted (Pericoli & Sbracia, 2003).

Most of the markets in the sample exhibit a significant effect on dynamic herding behavior

in developed markets. Ng (2000) observes a significant effect of volatility spillover from the US

towards different Pacific Basin markets. The global volatility index VIX is used as a proxy of

global volatility. Whaley (2009) argues that during market turmoil period VIX increases and the

Page 123: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

102

stock price will fall as a reaction to increased volatility, as a result, investors risk premium

increases. Hakkio & Keeton (2009) states that VIX capture both types of uncertainty arising from

fundamental channels or the investor sentiment effects. It is observed that except Australia,

Austria, Denmark, Hong Kong and Spain, all other market report a significant effect of global

volatility on herding behavior of local investor. The lagged value exhibit similar results as the local

volatility have on herding behavior. These findings are supported by the findings of Chang &

Zheng (2010) as they find a strong correlation between international stock markets.

Panel B of table 4.7 present results of the emerging and frontier markets, similar to

developed markets very few markets exhibit significant relationship of herding behavior to the

stock market performance. Only Pakistan, Philippine, and Sri Lankan markets exhibit the

significant effect of stock returns on herding behavior. However, except Philippine, all other

markets exhibit a significant relationship with Domestic and cross-market volatility on herding

behavior. These findings are supported by the findings of Tan et al. (2008), they state that herding

is more observable during period of increased volatility and trading volumes, similarly Gleason et

al. (2004) argue that generally, investors find comfort in mimicking the actions of others when

information flow in market is abnormal and volatility is high.

The role of stock market performance, domestic and global volatility cannot be neglected

in the determination of time variation of herding behavior and fulfill the purpose of the study.

Herding behavior is more pronounced in periods of high volatility and lagged value of global

volatility provide similar results as domestic volatility. These findings support the hypothesis that

herding behavior is affected by market performance, domestic and global volatility specifically

when market undergoes stress and are inefficient. These findings provide a support to ABC theory

that in the presence of social influence the emotions of the investors are affected by the market

Page 124: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

103

dynamics and they make cognitive errors in their decision-making process that leads to irrational

behavior of investors in the market.

Culture and Herding Behavior

Table 4.8 reports the results of the impact of culture on herding behavior. The results provide that

culture has a major contribution in investor’s decision-making process, specifically on herding

behavior. It is observed that except uncertainty avoidance and power distance all variables

including individualism, long-term orientation, masculinity, and indulgence have a significant

impact.

Power distance and Herding Behavior

This study shows that power distance index has no effect on herding behavior. According

to literature, there are no clear findings on the effect of power distance and herding behavior. This

study also concludes that there is no relationship in herding behavior and power distance, these

findings support the findings of Chang & Lin (2015) as they also do not find any support of the

relationship between high or low power distance and Herding behavior. These findings are

supportive of the fact given by Sinke (2012), they argue that in high power distance countries

institutional structure provides more investor protection and welfare. Thus these markets have

institutions with better quality and information flow is high (Chui et al., 2010). This argument

negates the presence of herding in countries with strong institutional setups.

Individualism and Herding Behavior

The dimension of individualism provides significant result when added as a moderating

variable in herding regression. The value is negative and significant at 10% level. It means that the

Page 125: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

104

dispersion in cross-sectional standard dispersion decrease by -3.630 percent if the society is high

in individualism. These findings are supported theoretically and empirically as the study

hypothesizes that individualism has negative significant effect on herding behavior. Increase in

individualism reduces herding behavior in a society therefore, reject the hypothesis of no effect on

10 percent significance level. These findings are supportive of the fact that collectivist societies

exhibit more herding behavior whereas individualist societies exhibit less herding behavior. These

results are consistent with Chang & Lin (2015) and Blsaco et al. (2017). In individualist societies,

people rely more on their own decision and take less effect from others and they are able to succeed

with their own capabilities. Thus they accept risks and are usually overconfident, act individually

and take less effect from the group. Schmeling (2009) studies the effect of individualism along

with uncertainty avoidance as a measure of overreaction and herding behavior and conclude that

investor sentiment is greatly affected by these virtues.

Masculinity and Herding Behavior

The results show that the dimension of masculinity has a significant effect when added as

a modulating variable in herding regression. The value is negative and significant at 1% level. It

means that the dispersion in cross-sectional standard dispersion decrease by -4.801 if there is one

unit increase in the dimension of masculinity thus exhibiting more herding. These findings have

theoretical and empirical support as the study hypothesize the negative significant effect of

masculinity on herding behavior. In masculine societies, individuals are ambitious and more self-

confident and the societies are driven by the attributes of competition and victory (Hofstede 1991).

These potentials make investor care for material things more, in order to overcome competition

they follow the strategies of others to maintain their reputation and engage in momentum profit,

Page 126: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

105

Table 4.8: Estimation of Individual Cultural Dimensions on Herding Behavior Power Distance Index (PDI)

C Rmi,t |Rmi,t| Rm2i,t PDI*[Rm2

i,t] 𝑅2̅̅̅̅ F-test

CSADi,t

0.003

(12.818)***

0.030

(1.090)

0.531

(7.378)***

-7.671

(-3.865)***

-0.377

(-0.116)

0.26 44.167***

Individualism Index (IDV)

C Rmi,t |Rmi,t| Rm2i,t IDV*[Rm2

i,t] 𝑅2̅̅̅̅ F-test

CSADi,t

0.003

(13.115)***

0.034

(1.264)

0.533

(7.741)***

-6.445

(-3.117)***

-3.630

(-1.677)*

0.29 46.199***

Masculinity index(MAS)

C Rmi,t |Rmi,t| Rm2i,t MAS*[Rm2

i,t] 𝑅2̅̅̅̅ F-test

CSADi,t

0.003

(13.206)***

0.027

(1.023)

0.521

(7.628)***

-3.879

(-1.667)*

-4.801

(-2.799)***

0.27 47.166***

Uncertainty avoidance Index(UAI)

C Rmi,t |Rmi,t| Rm2i,t UAI*[Rm2

i,t] 𝑅2̅̅̅̅ F-test

CSADi,t

0.003

(12.951)***

0.037

(1.452)

0.537

(7.687)***

-9.523

(-3.450)***

2.809

(1.476)

0.26 45.373***

Long term orientation Index(LTO)

C Rmi,t |Rmi,t| Rm2i,t LTO*[Rm2

i,t] 𝑅2̅̅̅̅ F-test

CSADi,t

0.004

(13.229)***

0.001

(0.041)

0.508

(7.037)***

1.821

(0.339)

-10.229

(-2.235)**

0.29 52.090***

Indulgence Index(IVR)

C Rmi,t |Rmi,t| Rm2i,t IVR*[Rm2

i,t] 𝑅2̅̅̅̅ F-test

CSADi,t

0.003

(13.159)***

0.015

(0.528)

0.515

(7.520)***

-7.928

(-3.852)***

4.910

(1.691)*

0.27 45.972***

Note: Estimation results of pool regression estimated through model tti

s

tititititi RmDCRmRmRmCSAD 2

,,4

2

,3,2,1, ][][

***indicate statistical significance at 1%. **Indicate statistical significance at 5%. *Indicate statistical significance at 10%.

Page 127: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

106

thus exhibiting more herding behavior. These findings are in line with Chiang and Lin (2015) &

Blasco et al. (2017). These findings are supported in a way that in masculine societies institutions

are controlled by the strong individuals of the society and rest of the individuals follows their traits

in order to increase their profit and avoid risk.

Uncertainty Avoidance and Herding Behavior

There is the insignificant effect of uncertainty avoidance on investor herding behavior,

witnessed by the presence of positive insignificant coefficient in table 4.8. In high uncertainty

avoidance societies, the investor usually feels comfort in following the consensus opinion.

Similarly, Sinke (2012) concludes that people with high uncertainty avoidance exhibit more

herding behavior. These results are in contradiction with Blasco et al. (2017) they found a decrease

in herding in high uncertainty avoidance societies. These findings are in line with Chang & Lin

(2015) as they found the insignificant effect of uncertainty avoidance on herding behavior. These

findings are in line with the theory where investors, in order to avoid risk, rely more on information

generate fewer returns on average and exhibit less herding behavior but against the hypothesis that

low-risk aversion leads to higher level of herding. This cultural dimension does not meet to fulfill

the objective as it has no modulating effect on the herding behavior of investors in the economies

under consideration.

Long-Term Orientation and Herding Behavior

The results in the presence of long-term orientation (LTO) exhibit a significant negative

relationship with cross-sectional absolute dispersion of returns. In the presence of significant LTO

dimension, the squared value of market return turned out to be negative. It means that when the

societies are LTO the herding behavior is absent. The markets in these societies are more

Page 128: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

107

regularized and individuals in these markets prefer safe investments over risky investments.

Investor is usually adaptive to the rules and regulations and lets the complexities of life settle at

their own pace. The decrease in dispersion due to interactive term can be explained through the

traits of long-term orientation. These societies follow the virtues driven by persistence and

personal adaptability, focused on relationship and market positions and prefer safe investments

over risky ones. Therefore, they follow the market directions. Virtues of long-term oriented itself

can be a possible reason for decrease in dispersion or market inefficiency. The value of moderating

term shows 10.229 Percent decrease with one unit increase in the level of long-term orientation.

These findings are in contradictions with Chang & Lin (2015) because they find insignificant effect

of long-term orientation on herding behavior.

These results can provide an explanation in favor of the asset pricing theory, due to this

strong orientation towards fundamentals, it is usually perceived that preferred investment strategy is

usually drawn from theory. Inefficient markets, large investors usually rely on a long-term oriented

strategies, especially when investment horizon is long-term and usually avoid short-sighted trends

based on sentiments that can result in frequent portfolio shifts (Beckmann, et al., 2008). The results

of the study support the hypothesis that long-term orientated societies are usually risk-aversed and

exhibit less herding behavior as they refrain from taking short-term sentiment based decisions.

Indulgence and Herding Behavior

The dimension of indulgence report a positive significant relationship with herding behavior of an

invetsor. The presence of indulgence decreases the dispersion of cross-sectional absolute returns,

it means that indulgence weakens the relationship and in its presence herding behavior decreases.

This effect can be seen by the increase in dispersion by 4.910 percent by one unit increase in

indulgence. It means that highly indulged societies exhibit less herding behavior. These

Page 129: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

108

observations are against the hypothesis that in the presence of more indulgence herding behavior

increases.

It is observed that power distance and uncertainty avoidance has no impact on herding behavior of

investor, however individualism, masculinity, and indulgence influence the relationship between

nonlinear returns and market dispersion. In the presence of long-term orientation, herding

coefficient becomes insignificant, slope dummy of interacting term decreases the dispersion of

returns.

Estimation of State Space Model:

Properties of Cross-Sectional Standard Deviation of betas

The first step is the estimation of betas through rational asset pricing model. They are

required to calculate the cross-sectional deviation of betas in order to identify dispersion in the

model. This study uses daily data to estimate betas and follows the approach of Hwang & Salmon

(2004). They used one month window to calculate OLS estimates of beta in order to avoid

overlapping intervals and statistical difficulties. These estimated betas are further used to calculate

the cross-sectional standard deviation of betas.

Table 4.9 provides some statistical properties of betas on the market portfolio. The results

of developed markets are reported in Panel A of Table 4.9. This study consists of 192 monthly

observations selected on the basis of active market participants from a period of 2000- 2015. Mean

value of all series are different from zero and positively skewed like all other volatility series. For

developed markets, the cross-sectional standard deviation of beta varies between a range from a

0.202 for Japan to 0.446 for Norway and the average mean value is 0.337. Similarly, the standard

deviation of the series varies from 0.027 for Japan to 0.188 for Denmark, with a mean value of to

Page 130: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

109

0.136. The Denmark market exhibit maximum value of 1.316, while Greek market exhibit lowest

value of 0.008 for cross-sectional standard deviation of beta. According to the Jarque Bera

statistics, all of the series for developed markets are not normal which can be justified by

significant positive skewness and excess kurtosis in all sample countries. The resultant Jarque Bera

statistics due to the deviation of skewness and Kurtosis from zero ranges from 541.040 for Italy to

27.546 for Sweden. These findings are similar to Hwang & Salmon (2004).

Table 4.9: Descriptive statistics of Cross-Sectional Standard Deviation of betas Panel A: Developed Markets

Country Obs Mean Std. Dev. Maxi Min Skewness Kurtosis JB

Australia 192 0.338 0.122 0.781 0.100 0.891 3.625 28.527***

Austria 192 0.252 0.145 0.916 0.053 1.797 7.222 245.984***

Belgium 192 0.400 0.095 0.806 0.163 0.774 4.582 39.185***

Denmark 192 0.531 0.188 1.316 0.181 1.384 5.783 123.220***

France 192 0.276 0.147 0.954 0.076 1.801 6.648 210.267***

Germany 192 0.282 0.120 0.680 0.124 1.327 4.303 69.900***

Greece 192 0.273 0.151 1.094 0.008 1.892 8.851 388.479***

Hong Kong 192 0.394 0.143 1.114 0.148 0.991 5.421 78.325***

Italy 192 0.313 0.107 0.880 0.154 2.066 10.111 541.040***

Japan 192 0.202 0.027 0.313 0.158 1.372 5.513 110.761***

Netherland 192 0.253 0.145 0.892 0.067 1.528 5.738 134.708***

New Zealand 192 0.381 0.175 1.082 0.098 1.560 6.168 158.227***

Norway 192 0.446 0.149 0.994 0.215 1.367 5.109 95.395***

Portugal 192 0.374 0.163 0.997 0.081 0.904 4.002 34.209***

Singapore 192 0.283 0.131 0.836 0.063 1.275 4.645 73.651***

Spain 192 0.327 0.130 0.965 0.145 1.962 8.419 358.106***

Sweden 192 0.368 0.176 0.947 0.109 0.918 3.272 27.546***

Switzerland 192 0.377 0.109 1.017 0.154 1.713 9.117 393.295***

Page 131: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

110

UK 192 0.388 0.170 0.984 0.081 1.215 4.515 65.563***

US 192 0.291 0.134 0.911 0.090 1.583 6.175 160.808***

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier Markets

Country Obs Mean Std. Dev. Max Min Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera

China 192 0.239 0.097 0.589 0.072 0.909 4.097 36.082***

India 192 0.348 0.138 1.027 0.114 1.738 7.744 276.625***

Indonesia 192 0.377 0.261 1.715 0.089 2.245 8.891 438.965***

Korea 192 0.398 0.130 0.964 0.159 1.566 6.695 187.719***

Malaysia 192 0.495 0.161 1.133 0.184 1.449 5.484 116.600***

Pakistan 192 0.430 0.128 0.826 0.172 0.528 3.404 10.233***

Philippines 192 0.259 0.151 0.985 0.056 2.003 8.310 353.949***

Sri Lanka 192 0.370 0.192 0.982 0.056 0.911 3.575 29.191***

Taiwan 192 0.368 0.084 0.615 0.139 -0.010 2.742 0.537

Thailand 192 0.407 0.123 0.888 0.180 0.970 4.556 49.479***

Turkey 192 0.387 0.068 0.627 0.207 0.279 3.056 2.525

Note: Betas are calculates using OLS estimates on capital asset pricing Model. Daily data is utilized to calculate

monthly betas on the factor. These betas are further utilized to calculate Cross-sectional dispersion of

betas 𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡𝑏 ).

Panel B reports summary statistics of emerging and Frontier markets, this study observes that

Malaysian markets exhibit a highest mean value of dispersion at 0.495 whereas Chinese markets

have lowest mean value among all, with a mean value of 0.371. The standard deviation of cross-

sectional dispersion of beta varies from 0.068 for turkey to 0.261 for Japan, with a mean value of

0.139. The Indonesian market exhibit maximum value of 1.715, while Philippines market exhibits

the lowest value of 0.056 for cross-sectional standard deviation of beta. Small dispersion from

mean represents a higher degree of herding behavior. According to the Jarque Bera statistics, most

of the series is not normal except Taiwan and Turkey which can be justified by significant positive

Page 132: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

111

skewness and excess kurtosis in most of the countries in the sample. The findings are similar to

the findings of Hwang & Salmon (2004).

Properties of Log of Cross-Sectional Standard Deviation

Table 4.10 represents the descriptive statistics of logarithmic cross-sectional dispersion of betas

from the mean value of equally weighted dispersion of betas. Betas are calculated using OLS

estimates on the market model. From a daily data over a period of 2000 to 2015 total 192 monthly

observations of betas are estimated which is further used in the calculation of logarithmic cross-

sectional dispersion of betas. This transformation is required for the application of Kalman filter

estimation.

The logarithmic cross-section deviation statistics reveal the insignificant value of Jarque Bera

statistics. The null hypothesis of normality is not rejected in these cases for most of the countries

of developed, emerging and frontier markets. Therefore, this study can employ Kalman filter for

the estimation of herding behavior in these markets.

Table 4.10: Descriptive statistics of Log of cross-sectional standard deviation of betas Panel A: Developed Markets

Country Obs Mean Std. Dev. Max Min Skewness Kurtosis JB

Australia 192 -0.575 0.181 -0.040 -1.048 0.279 3.114 2.598

Austria 192 -0.498 0.154 -0.107 -0.999 -0.055 2.998 0.099

Belgium 192 -0.657 0.236 0.083 -1.273 0.115 3.492 2.363

Denmark 192 -0.405 0.117 0.131 -0.788 0.683 6.905 136.884**

France 192 -0.299 0.145 0.119 -0.742 0.092 3.668 3.843

Germany 192 -0.607 0.199 -0.021 -1.119 0.497 3.151 8.087*

Greece 192 -0.591 0.168 -0.174 -0.911 0.409 2.748 5.868

Hong Kong 192 -0.625 0.243 0.039 -2.077 -1.045 8.793 303.402

Page 133: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

112

Italy 192 -0.432 0.158 0.047 -0.831 -0.167 2.825 1.132

Japan 192 -0.522 0.138 0.135 -0.814 1.009 5.749 93.078**

Netherland 192 -0.698 0.054 -0.505 -0.801 0.940 4.052 37.111**

New Zealand 192 -0.659 0.230 -0.050 -1.177 0.199 2.597 2.563

Norway 192 -0.457 0.193 0.034 -1.011 0.052 3.103 0.171

Portugal 192 -0.365 0.147 0.291 -0.667 0.910 4.720 50.175**

Singapore 192 -0.451 0.232 0.419 -1.093 0.427 4.694 28.782**

Spain 192 -0.591 0.191 -0.078 -1.203 0.049 3.167 0.301

Sweden 192 -0.513 0.148 -0.016 -0.839 0.642 3.607 16.128**

Switzerland 192 -0.483 0.203 -0.024 -0.961 0.095 2.302 4.185

UK 192 -0.440 0.116 0.007 -0.811 0.333 4.123 13.644**

US 192 -0.450 0.183 -0.007 -1.093 -0.041 3.400 1.333

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier Markets

Obs Mean Std. Dev. Max Min Skewness Kurtosis JB

China 192 -0.658 0.180 -0.230 -1.143 -0.296 3.079 2.861

India 192 -0.487 0.155 0.012 -0.943 0.317 3.543 5.567

Indonesia 192 -0.497 0.242 0.234 -1.049 0.568 3.273 10.920**

Korea 192 -0.417 0.137 0.154 -0.798 0.564 4.782 35.579**

Malaysia 192 -0.326 0.129 0.054 -0.734 0.390 3.792 9.876**

Pakistan 192 -0.376 0.157 0.391 -0.765 0.717 6.044 90.578**

Philippines 192 -0.645 0.222 -0.007 -1.252 0.198 3.348 2.221

Sri Lanka 192 -0.480 0.260 0.477 -1.253 0.068 3.640 3.426

Taiwan 192 -0.446 0.106 -0.211 -0.858 -0.694 3.634 18.636**

Thailand 192 -0.409 0.128 -0.052 -0.745 -0.005 3.127 0.131

Turkey 192 -0.420 0.077 -0.203 -0.685 -0.246 3.136 2.078

Note: Betas are calculates using OLS estimates on capital asset pricing Model. Daily data is utilized to calculate

monthly betas on the factor. These betas are further utilized to calculate Cross-sectional dispersion of betas which are

further transformed to their Logarithmic form log(𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡𝑏 ) to test the state space model.

Page 134: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

113

Panel A reports summary statistics of developed countries for the log standard dispersion

of betas. Mean value of Log(𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡𝑏 )) varies from -0.698 of Netherlands to -0.299 of France,

with a mean value of -0.516. The standard deviation of the series ranges between 0.243 for Hong

Kong to 0.054 for Netherland, with a mean value of 0.172. The Sri Lankan market exhibits highest

logarithmic standard dispersion, where as Hong Kong market exhibits lowest dispersion of -2.077.

In case of skewness Kurtosis and Jarque Bera statistics, most of the series exhibit state of normality

because of insignificant value of statistics. Therefore, this study can use Kalman filter for testing

herd formation in these markets.

Panel B of the table 4.10 reports summary statistics of the emerging and frontier markets.

Mean value of Log(𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡𝑏 )) varies from -0.658 for China to -0.326 for Malaysia with a mean

value of -0.469. Standard deviation of Log(𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡𝑏 )) ranges from 0.077 for Turkey to 0.260

for Sri Lanka, with a mean value of 0.163. Most of the series show insignificant value of Jarque-

Bera statistics and normality of data. Therefore, Kalman filter can be applied to test state space

model proposed by Hwang & Salmon (2004).

Page 135: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

114

Table 4.11: Estimates of Herding Measure and State Space Model Panel A: Developed Countries

Country 𝝁𝒎 𝝈𝒗𝒎 ∅𝒎 𝝈𝒏𝒎 𝝈𝒏𝒎/𝐒𝐃[𝐥𝐨𝐠 [𝑺𝒕𝒅𝒄(𝜷𝒊𝒎𝒕𝒃 )]] Log Likelihood AIC BIC

Australia -0.494(0.042)*** 0.132(0.117)*** 0.974(0.022)*** 0.017(0.864)*** 0.093 105.271 -1.055 -0.987

Austria -0.652(0.076)*** 0.196(0.110)*** 0.977(0.022)*** 0.028(0.779)*** 0.18 28.645 -0.257 -0.189

Belgium -0.406(0.019)*** 0.103(0.107)*** 0.886(0.074)*** 0.025(0.824)*** 0.106 148.013 -1.5 -1.432

Denmark -0.302(0.022)*** 0.116(0.195)*** 0.838(0.104)*** 0.048(0.703)*** 0.266 112.102 -1.126 -1.058

France -0.578(0.130)*** 0.121(0.135)*** 0.983(0.015)*** 0.037(0.450)*** 0.255 104.823 -1.05 -0.982

Germany -0.591(0.050)*** 0.020(1.190)*** 0.896(0.037)*** 0.075(0.175)*** 0.374 214.384 -2.192 -2.124

Greece -0.634(0.058)*** 0.205(0.094)*** 0.936(0.048)*** 0.045(0.838)*** 0.271 15.277 -0.118 -0.05

Hong Kong -0.427(0.072)*** 0.117(0.127)*** 0.981(0.018)*** 0.022(0.658)*** 0.089 122.235 -1.232 -1.164

Italy -0.518(0.027)*** 0.117(0.098)*** 0.901(0.065)*** 0.032(0.786)*** 0.133 120.275 -1.211 -1.143

Japan -0.697(0.010)*** 0.000(2.16E+08) 0.661(0.049)*** 0.040(0.078)*** 0.292 344.516 -3.547 -3.479

Netherland -0.644(0.055)*** 0.181(0.121)*** 0.936(0.042)*** 0.050(0.597)*** 0.389 33.511 -0.307 -0.24

New Zealand -0.461(0.034)*** 0.169(0.099)*** 0.947(0.048)*** 0.023(0.926)*** 0.101 59.396 -0.577 -0.509

Norway -0.328(0.076)*** 0.119(0.070)*** 0.988(0.012)*** 0.015(0.616)*** 0.079 125.07 -1.261 -1.193

Portugal -0.460(0.038)*** 0.217(0.104)*** 0.934(0.084)*** 0.029(1.512)*** 0.131 12.207 -0.085 -0.018

Singapore -0.591(0.028)*** 0.170(0.133)*** 0.892(0.085)*** 0.039(0.921)*** 0.167 53.046 -0.511 -0.443

Spain -0.484(0.067)*** 0.093(0.113)*** 0.973(0.018)*** 0.031(0.445)*** 0.163 153.819 -1.561 -1.493

Sweden -0.514(0.142)*** 0.116(0.128)*** 0.983(0.019)*** 0.037(0.481)*** 0.143 110.692 -1.111 -1.044

Switzerland -0.439(0.027)*** 0.097(0.119)*** 0.940(0.043)*** 0.022(0.762)*** 0.106 158.203 -1.606 -1.538

UK -0.445(0.060)*** 0.120(0.130)*** 0.949(0.030)*** 0.044(0.476)*** 0.564 103.381 -1.035 -0.967

Page 136: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

115

US -0.578(0.048)*** 0.108(0.183)*** 0.908(0.045)*** 0.060(0.398)*** 0.33 107.859 -1.082 -1.014

Panel B: Emerging and frontier Markets

Country 𝝁𝒎 𝝈𝒗𝒎 ∅𝒎 𝝈𝒏𝒎 𝝈𝒏𝒎/𝐒𝐃[𝐥𝐨𝐠 [𝑺𝒕𝒅𝒄(𝜷𝒊𝒎𝒕𝒃 )]] Log Likelihood AIC BIC

China -0.657(0.027)*** 0.133(0.155)*** 0.777(0.103)*** 0.076(0.563)*** 0.651 73.537 -0.724 -0.656

India -0.489(0.038)*** 0.104(0.163)*** 0.905(0.050)*** 0.049(0.468)*** 0.311 124.015 -1.25 -1.182

Indonesia -0.503(0.040)*** 0.199(0.140)*** 0.863(0.073)*** 0.069(0.601)*** 0.447 13.276 -0.097 -0.029

Korea -0.413(0.030)*** 0.123(0.093)*** 0.956(0.035)*** 0.017(0.825)*** 0.324 119.388 -1.202 -1.134

Malaysia -0.325(0.016)*** 0.083(0.421)*** 0.574(0.144)*** 0.081(0.534)*** 0.589 133.544 -1.349 -1.282

Pakistan -0.380(0.052)*** 0.171(0.031)*** 0.950(0.052)*** 0.026(0.811)*** 0.178 55.348 -0.535 -0.467

Philippines -0.646(0.048)*** 0.187(0.119)*** 0.936(0.050)*** 0.041(0.770)*** 0.261 33.051 -0.303 -0.235

Sri Lanka -0.480(0.026)*** 0.161(1.142)*** 0.410(0.284) 0.185(0.992)*** 1.246 -6.65 0.111 0.179

Taiwan -0.445(0.021)*** 0.073(0.197)*** 0.822(0.084)*** 0.044(0.405)*** 0.38 183.656 -1.871 -1.804

Thailand -0.409(0.014)*** 0.108(0.242)*** 0.697(0.200)*** 0.049(1.044)*** 0.46 127.425 -1.286 -1.218

Turkey -0.420(0.008)*** 0.069(0.163)*** 0.739(0.232)*** 0.023(1.313)*** 0.178 222.221 -2.273 -2.205

Note: results of the estimates of state space model of Hwang & Salmon (2004) model log [𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡𝑏 )] = 𝜇𝑚 + 𝐻𝑚𝑡 + 𝑣𝑚𝑡, where, 𝐻𝑚𝑡 = ∅𝑚𝐻𝑚𝑡−1 +

𝑚𝑡

***indicate statistical significance at 1%. **Indicate statistical significance at 5%. *Indicate statistical significance at 10%.

Page 137: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

116

Estimates of Herding Measure and State Space Model

Table 4.11 represents estimation results for the state space model presented in eq 12 & 13.

The results indicate strong evidence of herding in almost all markets, as the coefficient Hmt is

highly persistent and large and statistically significant value of AR(1) coefficient ∅m with the

exception of Sri Lanka. Furthermore, the value of coefficient ∅m is less than one without

exploding. When there is no herding in the market, the coefficient σnm is equal to zero. The results

indicate that the coefficient is non zero and significant for all countries indicating the presence of

herding behavior.

Panel A represents herding towards a market portfolio in developed markets. It can be

observed that Hmt indicate the highly persistent significant value of coefficient ∅m. The results show

that Norway has the highest coefficient value followed by France, Sweden, Hong Kong, Austria,

Australia, Spain, UK, New Zealand, Switzerland, Greece, Netherland, Portugal, US, Italy,

Germany, Singapore, Belgium, Denmark and Japan at, 0.988, 0.983, 0.983, 0.981, 0.977, 0.974,

0.973, 0.949, 0.947, 0.940, 0.936, 0.936, 0.934, 0.908, 0.901, 0.896, 0.892, 0.886, 0.838, and 0.661

respectively at 1% level of significance. All the values of the coefficient are less than 1 without

exploding which means that all series of herding behavior follows a stationary process. These

findings are consistent with Hwang & Salmon (2004), even the coefficient value for most of the

countries are higher than compared to their findings.

According to equation 13, when there is no herding towards portfolio in the market, the coefficient

σnm is equal to zero, however in all developed markets σnm the error term, is different from zero and

highly significant at 1% level of significance. When looking at the proportion of variability

explained by herding, this study observe highest variability in cross sectional dispersion of returns

Page 138: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

117

which can be explained through herding behavior in the market of UK (56.40%), followed

by Netherland (38.90%), Germany (37.40%), US (33.00%), Japan (29.20%), Greece (27.10%),

Denmark (26.60%), France (25.50%), Austria (18.00%), Singapore (16.70%), Spain

(16.30%), Sweden (14.30%), Italy (13.30%), Portugal (13.10%), Belgium (10.60%), Switzerland

(10.60%), New Zealand (10.10%), Australia (9.30%), Hong Kong (8.90%), and lowest in Norway

(7.90%). These findings are similar to the findings of Khan et al. (2011), they observe herding

using HS model in France, UK, Italy and German and find herding in extreme market returns.

Panel B of the table 4.11 reports the results herding towards a market portfolio in emerging

and developed markets. It can be observed that Hmt is highly persistent and the value of coefficient

∅m is highly significant for all countries except Sri Lanka. The results indicates that Korea has the

highest coefficient value followed by Pakistan, Philippines, India, Indonesia, Taiwan, China,

Turkey, Thailand, and Malaysia at 0.956, 0.950, 0.936, 0.905, 0.863, 0.822, 0.777, 0.739, 0.697

and 0.574 respectively at 1% level of significance. All the values of the coefficient are less than 1

without exploding which means that all series of herding behavior follow a stationary process.

These findings are consistent with Hwang & Salmon (2004), even the coefficient values for most

of the countries are higher than compared to their findings.

According to equation 13, when there is no herding towards portfolio in the market, if the

coefficient σnm is equal to zero. However, in emerging and frontier markets σnm the error term, is

different from zero and highly significant at 1% level of significance. When looking at the

proportion of variability explain by herding, this study observe that highest variability in cross-

sectional dispersion of returns is explained through herding behavior in the market of China

(65.10%) followed by Malaysia (58.90%), Thailand (46.00%), Indonesia (44.70%), Taiwan

(38.00%), Korea (32.40%), India (31.10%), Philippines (26.10%), and lowest in Turkey and

Page 139: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

118

Pakistan (17.80%). These findings are in line with Demirer et al. (2010) they investigate herding

across industrial sectors using HS (2004) model in Taiwanese market and find herd formation

during a period from 1995-2006. Similarly, Solakoglu & Nihat (2014) find significant herding

behavior of uninformed investors towards market portfolio during a period of 2000 to 2013 in

Turkish stock markets but insignificant herding behavior in informed traders.

All countries in the sample except Sri Lanka exhibit herding behavior around market

portfolio and particularly in stress. These findings are similar to Hwang & Salmon (2004) as the

main purpose of this research is to investigate the irrational herding. Information plays a crucial

role in investor’s decision-making process. Therefore, it can be concluded that herding is more

obvious if there is information asymmetry in the market.

Properties of Herding Measure

Table 4.12 presents the summary statistics of herding evolution hmt over the entire period.

Panel B of the table 4.12 reports the results for developed markets. The Norway market exhibits

lowest mean value of -0.037, and Sweden exhibits highest value of 0.033 of monthly herding index

with a mean value of -0.0046. The mean value is around 0 which means that on average due to

several cycles of adjustment from herding to adverse herding difference markets exhibit minimal

herding. The standard deviation of herding measure varies around 0.041% for Australia and

0.174% for Germany with a mean value of 0.10. The herding measure ranges from a maximum

of 0.407 for Germany to a minimum of -0.547 for Japan. According to JB statistics, herding series

for all developed markets are not normal.

Table 4.12: Descriptive statistics of Herding measure, Hmt Panel A: Developed Markets

Page 140: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

119

Obs Mean Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Skewness Kurtosis JB- stats

hmt_ Australia 192 -0.004 0.101 -0.128 0.052 -0.213 2.093 8.025**

hmt_ Austria 192 -0.005 0.203 -0.172 0.121 0.205 1.508 19.150***

hmt_ Belgium 192 0.002 0.127 -0.056 0.041 1.008 3.611 35.519***

hmt_ Denmark 192 0.002 0.16 -0.224 0.069 -0.58 4.247 11.524***

hmt_ France 192 -0.029 0.384 -0.257 0.151 1.348 4.323 23.219***

hmt_ Germany 192 -0.001 0.407 -0.312 0.166 0.444 2.745 72.141***

hmt_ Greece 192 0.009 0.174 -0.267 0.112 -0.718 2.897 6.830**

hmt_ Hong Kong 192 -0.005 0.138 -0.147 0.099 0.152 1.314 16.586***

hmt_ Italy 192 -0.003 0.186 -0.111 0.058 1.076 4.682 23.482***

hmt_ Japan 192 -0.019 0.282 -0.547 0.174 -0.976 3.425 59.702***

hmt_ Netherland 192 -0.015 0.267 -0.256 0.123 0.53 2.635 31.925***

hmt_ New Zealand 192 -0.001 0.15 -0.08 0.06 0.924 3.068 10.065***

hmt_ Norway 192 -0.037 0.158 -0.137 0.081 0.987 3.039 27.366***

hmt_ Portugal 192 0.010 0.107 -0.108 0.059 -0.334 1.898 31.204***

hmt_ Singapore 192 0.001 0.146 -0.109 0.066 0.089 1.958 13.271***

hmt_ Spain 192 -0.028 0.307 -0.172 0.109 1.467 4.557 8.934***

hmt_ Sweden 192 0.033 0.298 -0.327 0.160 0.307 1.89 88.278***

hmt_ Switzerland 192 0.000 0.117 -0.105 0.053 0.19 2.024 12.869***

hmt_ UK 192 -0.005 0.320 -0.226 0.128 0.83 3.138 8.782**

hmt_ US 192 0.003 0.395 -0.218 0.133 0.983 3.711 22.197***

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier markets.

Obs Mean Maximum Minimum Std. Dev. Skewness Kurtosis JB- stats

hmt_ China 192 -0.001 0.227 -0.327 0.098 -0.442 3.741 10.651***

hmt_ India 192 0.002 0.269 -0.248 0.103 0.442 2.911 6.300**

hmt_ Indonesia 192 0.006 0.299 -0.173 0.11 0.664 2.717 14.743***

hmt_ Korea 192 0.000 0.496 -0.335 0.118 0.548 4.831 36.422***

Page 141: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

120

hmt_ Malaysia 192 0.000 0.217 -0.235 0.08 0.411 3.368 6.499***

hmt_ Pakistan 192 -0.003 0.117 -0.118 0.07 -0.156 1.586 16.772***

hmt_ Philippines 192 0.001 0.227 -0.212 0.101 0.092 2.483 2.409

hmt_ Sri Lanka 192 -0.001 0.535 -0.513 0.163 -0.096 3.366 1.366

hmt_ Taiwan 192 0.001 0.122 -0.208 0.055 -0.677 3.567 17.250***

hmt_ Thailand 192 -0.409 -0.291 -0.534 0.046 -0.206 2.71 2.031

hmt_ Turkey 192 0.000 0.048 -0.049 0.021 -0.179 2.6 2.308

Note: properties of herding series calculates through hmt = 1-Hmt, where 𝐻𝑚𝑡 = ∅𝑚𝐻𝑚𝑡−1 + 𝑚𝑡

,

***indicate statistical significance at 1%. **Indicate statistical significance at 5%. *Indicate statistical significance at 10%.

Table 4.12 present the summary statistics of herding evolution hmt over the entire period.

Panel B of the table reports the results for developed markets. The Indonesian market exhibits

highest mean value of 0.006, and Thai market exhibit lowest mean value of -0.409 of monthly

herding index with a mean value of 0.037. The mean value is around 0 which means that on average

due to several cycles of adjustment from herding to adverse herding difference markets exhibit

minimal herding. The standard deviation of herding measure varies around to 0.021% for Turkey

to 0.163% for Sri Lanka with a mean value of 0.08. The herding measure ranges from a maximum

of 0.535 for Sri Lanka to a minimum of -0.049 for Turkey. According to properties of JB statistics,

herding series for all emerging and frontier market is not normally distributed. The herding series

of Philippines, Sri Lanka, Thailand, and Turkey display a normal distribution.

Further insight into the herding evolution has been discussed in next section

Evolution of Herding Measures over Time

Fig. 4.3 to Fig. 4.32 shows the evolution of herding measure hmt =1-exp(Hmt) in developed,

emerging and frontier markets. For most of the countries value of hmt is far less than one. It means

that during the sample period, most of the countries at no time display an extreme level of herding.

Page 142: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

121

From the period 1995 to 2015 this study observes several cycles of herding and adverse herding

towards the market value as the herding parameter hmt moves around its long-term zero average.

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

7,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

AUSTRALIA

(a) Market Index

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

.15

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

AUSTRALIA

(b) Hmt----- Herding Series

Figure 4-3: Herding evolution in Australian Market

Figure 4.3 reports the result of the Australian market. This study analyzes that over the

entire period from 2000 to 2015. Australian market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding

as the value is far away from 1 and is observed within a range of -0.128 to 0.10. It is also verified

by the signal to noise ratio of 0.093. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero and several

cycles herding and adverse herding are observed. The period from 2004 to 2008 is relatively

smooth and four attempts of adjustments to fundamentals are observed after that one peak of

adverse herding in 2009 with one adjustment is observed. Adverse herding is observed during

2000 to 2004, this time period is the aftermaths of the Dotcom Bubble burst that greatly affected

the Australian market. Another extreme peak of adverse herding is observed during the early phase

of 2009. This downfall started with the start of Global financial crisis in 2008, The stock market

decline by 17% by the end of January 2008 and further 41% in June 2009 from its level of Nov

2007, creating huge losses for investors, and large pension fund sector and provide several

concerns about the regulatory structure of the securities market.

Page 143: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

122

The Australian market quickly recovered from the turbulent period in mid-2009 better than many

developed markets 7, the situation is not without risks. Afterwards, positive value of herding is

observed from 2010 to 2015. This study observes a similar positive growth during a period of 2003

to 2007 and a sharp decline in the market index during the earlier phase of 2009. This time period

can be referred to the Global crisis that impacted the markets around the globe.

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

AUSTRIA

(a) Market Index

-.20

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

.15

.20

.25

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

AUSTRIA

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-4: Herding evolution in Australian Market

Figure 4-4 reports the results of Austrian stock market. Similar to Austrian market, there

is never an extreme level of herding in the market as the value is far away from 1 and the value is

observed within a range of -0.172 to 0.203 over the entire period. This is also substantiated by the

signal to noise ratio of 0.18. Several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. It is

observed that during a period of 2000 to 2008 Austrian market remained stable and grew at a

steady rate. Due to the strong institutional framework, the market is not destabilized by

macroeconomic imbalances and external shocks. The impact of the Global crisis remains moderate

but not negligible. The unique structure of the market helped it to avoid extreme macroeconomic

shocks that intensified the impact of the crisis. However, financial sector stability is the major

7 Gruen (2009) provide a comprehensive analysis of the triggering factors for the Global Financial Crisis and the reason as to how Australia is least affected than elsewhere.

Page 144: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

123

challenges faced by the Austrian authorities throughout the crisis period. External expansion and

Internal Stagnation of the Banking Sector exposed the Austrian market to financial contagion just

before the Global Financial Crisis that can be observed in part (b) of Figure 4.4. This effect is

further exacerbated by the Euro Crisis and Ukrainian/Russian crisis due to sanctions imposed by

the EU on Russia. Despite all these effects Austrian market is able to maintain low unemployment

and high living standards.

1,600

2,000

2,400

2,800

3,200

3,600

4,000

4,400

4,800

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

BELGIUM

(a) Market Index

-.08

-.04

.00

.04

.08

.12

.16

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

BELGIUM

(b) Hmt----Herding Series

Figure 4-5: Herding Evolution in Belgium Market

Figure 4-5 reports the results of Belgian stock market. Similar to other markets, there is

never an extreme level of herding in the market as the value is far away from 1 and the value is

observed within a range of -0.056 to 0.127 over the entire period. This is also substantiated by the

signal to noise ratio of 0.106 which implies that 10.6 percent change in dispersion of portfolio beta

is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero and several cycles of herding

and adverse herding are observed. The period from 2000 to 2001 is relatively smooth and shows

a low level of herding as the value remained close to zero. From 2002 to 2004 Belgian market

exhibits adverse herding. Belgian market faced almost six peaks of adverse herding during the

sample period with four adjustments. The time period of Global financial crisis is seen to have

least impact on the investor behavior as in most of the time period observe value in a positive

Page 145: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

124

region far away from 1. Adverse herding is observed during 2002 to 2004, similarly, another

episode of adverse herding is observed from the last quarter of 2005 to first quarter of 2008. In this

time period market activity of Belgian market slowed down due to the effect of the global financial

crisis. The financial sector of the market was greatly hit as the market faced a 12.5 % increase in

bankruptcies. At the end of third quarter of 2009, Belgium starts slow recovery in the

fundamentals. It can be observed in figure (a) of the graph. It is observed that from 2010 to 2015

with the exception of a small adjustment and positive herding from the last quarter of 2010 to 2012

the market faced an adverse herding. These findings can be related to the fact that herding behavior

of an investor is not affected by the fundamental driven factors but might be due to liquidity

withdrawal which may result into costly liquidation due to the banking crisis and as a result asset

prices collapse (Chang and Velasco, 2001).

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

7,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

CHINA

(a) Market Index

-.4

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

CHINA

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-6: Herding Evolution in Chinese Market

Figure 4-6 reports the result of the Chinese market. This study analyzes that over the entire period

from 2000 to 2015 Chinese market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value is far

away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.327 to 0.227. From table 4.12, it is

verified that the signal to noise ratio is 0.651 which implies that 65 percent change in dispersion

of portfolio beta is due to Herding. It means that Chinese market is one of the markets that are

Page 146: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

125

highly affected by the herding behavior. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero and

several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed.

From 2006 to 2009 Chinese market experienced a sharp increase followed by a sudden downfall.

In 2006 china reliance on debts increased to 170%. The simultaneously financial global crisis hit

the global market and that has an effect on the Chinese market as well witnessed by a sharp

downturn in both stock index and herding evolution. During this period the volume of debt

increased to almost 286% of GDP. According to Kaminsky & Reinhart (2000) countries with

strong financial interdependence are more likely to be affected by the same crisis. From 2008 to

2014 several cycles of herding observed in the positive range of the graph. During this period

Chinese market become less reliant on the export-based model as exports reduce from 35% to 29%

of GDP. Similarly, import reliance also reduces from 29% to 19% due to increased industrial

production as Chinese market exposure to foreign market capital flows decline.

0

200

400

600

800

1,000

1,200

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

DENMARK

(a) Market Index

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

DENMARK

(b) Hmt----Herding Series

Figure 4-7: Herding Evolution in Danish Market

Figure 4.7 reports the result of Denmark market. This study analyzes that over the entire period

from 2000 to 2015 Denmark market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value is

far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.224 to 0.16 from table 4.12. It is

also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.266 which implies that 26.6 percent change in

Page 147: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

126

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero

and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed.

Figure 4.8 reports the results of French stock market. Similar to other markets, there is

never an extreme level of herding in the market as the value is far away from 1 and the value is

observed within a range of -0.257 to 0.384 over the entire period. It is also verified by the signal

to noise ratio of 0.255 which implies that 25.5 percent change in dispersion of portfolio beta is due

to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero and several cycles of herding and

adverse herding are observed. French market exhibit adverse herding from 2003 to 2015 with an

adjustment in the end of 2008 that lasts until the mid of 2009.

From 2001 to 2003 French market face a sharp decline, this decline was caused by a shock

that was generated due to the adoption of Euro as a single currency. The French market settled

with Euro but as a result, inflation was created and consumers lost their confidence and changed

their consumption behavior, cut spending that resulted in reduced demand. The GDP growth

declines to 3.9% from 2001 to 1.1% in 2003. The GDP started to increase in 2004 and then again

a decline is observed in 2005.

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

7,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

FRANCE

(a) Market Index

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

.4

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

FRANCE

(b) Hmt----Herding Series

Figure 4-8: Herding Evolution in French Market

Page 148: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

127

Global Financial crisis significantly affects the French market as it leads to several bank

failure, the collapse of financial markets, reduced household consumption and a panic in overall

sectors of the market. This crisis leads to the financial crisis as it caused the wealth to be drowned

into the stock markets that result in reduced investment. As a result, government cuts spending to

rescue the French financial system. The GDP remains positive in 2007 but declined due to

decreased consumption. GDP further decline in 2008 but 2009 shows a recovery, this trend can be

observed in both parts of the graphs. This uprise in financial system during 2009 can be a result of

financial allocation by the Government that results in increased savings. Even the French market

is badly hurt by the crisis, in the last quarter of 2009 market recover from the recession. This study

observes an adjustment and a positive trend in investor herding behavior.

2,000

4,000

6,000

8,000

10,000

12,000

14,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

GERMANY

(a) Market Index

-.4

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

.4

.5

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

GERMANY

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-9: Herding Evolution in German Market

Figure 4.9 reports the result of the German market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Denmark market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the

value is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.312 to 0.407 from table

4.12. It is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.374 which implies that 37.4 percent change

in dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value

zero and several cycles herding and adverse herding are observed. The period of 2000 to 2006

Page 149: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

128

German market exhibit positive herding. From 2006 to 2015 several cycles of adverse herding are

observed with five adjustments in the different time periods. From 2007-2009 the time periods can

be classified as the Global financial crisis. During the global financial crisis, Germany underwent

a decline in GDP in last quarter of 2008 that continued to become negative in early 2009, the

recovery started in the third quarter and positive growth is observed in 2010. By the mid of 2011,

Germany is well on its way to recovery and Euro debt crisis had minimal effect on the German

economy and the growth cycle continued as one can observe it in the first part of the graph.

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

GREECE

(a) Market Index

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

GREECE

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-10: Herding evolution in Greece Market

Figure 4.10 reports the result of the Greek market. This study analyzes that over the entire period

from 2000 to 2015 Greek market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value is far

away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.267 to 0.174 from table 4.12. It is also

verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.271 which implies that 27.1 percent change in dispersion

of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero and several

cycles herding and adverse herding are observed. From 2001 to 2007greek market observe herding

in the positive region this period is classified as a period of economic growth. This time started

shortly after joining the single currency. A sudden shock is observed with the tumbling down

position in 2008. This period is classified as the period of the financial crash of 2008. Like many

Page 150: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

129

other European markets, Greece is seriously affected. In late 2011 and 2012 government

implement several structural reforms to strengthen the economy that can be observed by the regain

of investor confidence in part (b) of the graph.

Figure 4.11 reports the result of Hong Kong market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Hong Kong market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the

value is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.147 to 0.138 from table

4.12. It is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.089 which implies that 8.9 percent change

in dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value

zero and several cycles herding and adverse herding are observed. Honk Kong economy observes

a downturn in 2008 following the Global financial crisis. Hong Kong economy is the trade-oriented

economy and hit hard by the crisis in terms of GDP, employment, and exports. The economic

growth declined by 6.4% in 2007 to 2.5% in 2008 which further declined to -2.5 in 2009. Exports

also declined by 21.8% in 2009 followed by the sharp decline in Hang Seng Index by 48% in these

years.

8,000

12,000

16,000

20,000

24,000

28,000

32,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

HONGKONG

(a) Market Index

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

.15

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

HONGKONG

(b) Hmt--- Herding Series

Figure 4-11: Herding evolution in Hong Kong Market

These time periods can be observed easily in part b of the graph. The herding evolution remains

in the adverse region after the introduction of the crisis situation. Hong Kong’s open economy left

Page 151: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

130

it exposed to the global economic slowdown, its integration with Chinese economy has reduced

the effect of the crisis. A recovery began in the third quarter of 2009, and the economy grew nearly

6.8% in 2010.

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

7,000

8,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

INDIA

(a) Market Index

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

INDIA

(b) Hmt----Herding Series

Figure 4-12: Herding Evolution in Indian Market

Figure 4.12 reports the result of the Indian market. This study analyzes that over the entire period

from 2000 to 2015 Indian market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value is far

away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.248 to 0.269 from table 4.12. It is also

verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.313 which implies that 31.3 percent change in dispersion

of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero and several

cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. The Indian economy is greatly affected by

the dotcom collapse (2000) and global recession of 2001 and also affected by the global uncertainty

caused by the invasion of Iraq in 2003. From 1997-2003 Indian economy faced a decline in GDP

growth to a level of 5.7 percent. The Indian economy performed well in coming years from 2003-

2008, and touch the peak of 9% increase in GDP per year for consecutive three years 2005-2008.

The Global financial crisis is observed to have minimal effect on investor herding behavior

as adverse herding is observed closer to 1 from 2007-2008. Adverse herding is observed during

2010–11 due to the widespread charges of corruption, which led to paralysis in decision making

Page 152: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

131

and huge bank losses the slowdown of the economy and lost investor confidence regained after

the defeat of the Congress Party. New political system tackle some of the serious problems and an

economic boost and investor confidence is observed after 2014 and growth increases to estimated

7.5 percent in 2015.

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

INDONESIA

(a) Market Index

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

.4

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

INDONESIA

(b) Hmt----Herding Series

Figure 4-13: Herding Evolution in Indonesian Market

Figure 4.13 reports the result of the Indonesian market. This study analyzes that over the

entire period from 2000 to 2015 Indonesian market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding

as the value is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.173 to 0.299 from

table 4.12. It is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.304 which implies that 30.4 percent

change in dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean

value zero and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed.

In early 2000, Indonesian economy is seen struggling to come out of the aftermaths of Asian

financial crisis of 1997 and is also going through the political instability that ended up the Suharto

regime. During this period Indonesian economy went through persistent capital outflow, exchange

rate volatility and inflationary pressures which led to fragile investor sentiment throughout a

decade (Jayasuriya & Leu, 2017). This phenomenon can be observed in Figure 4.13, from 2000 to

2009 Indonesian economy observes adverse herding with two peaks in 2006 and 2008. Former can

Page 153: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

132

be attributed to the political instability due to the firing of high profile government officials and

later is connected to the Global financial crisis which led to currency depreciation due to risk

perception as a result of declining export prospects. From mid-2009 Indonesian economy observe

large capital inflows which led to the recovery of the economic system as that can be observed in

figure 4.13, part b. Another extreme adverse herding shock observes in 2011 that can be an

outcome of European Debt crisis that generated a huge turmoil and reversal of cash flow, resulting

in increased risk perception and investors shifted their funds abroad. The Indonesian economy

quickly resumes in coming years with the exception of a most recent global shock that hits the

economy in May 2013.

10,000

15,000

20,000

25,000

30,000

35,000

40,000

45,000

50,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

ITALY

(a) Market Index

-.12

-.08

-.04

.00

.04

.08

.12

.16

.20

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

ITALY

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-14: Herding Evolution in Italian Market

Figure 4.14 reports the result of the Italian market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Italian market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value

is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.11 to 0.186 from table 4.12. It is

also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.133 which implies that 13.3 percent change in

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero

and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. During the global financial crisis,

Italian investor and banks suffered little in the early phase of the crisis after the collapse of the

Page 154: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

133

Lehman Brothers collapse in September 2008 (Quirico, 2010). This effect can be easily observed

in the time period from 2007 to the start of 2009. Italian economy observes an adverse herding

peak in 2010to 2013. This time period can be related to the Eurozone crisis that adversely affected

the Italian economy during these years. The economy contracted by around 10% since 2007

followed by a recession. The output is at its lowest, unemployment declined to 12%-13%,

followed by a cut in consumption and investment. Smaller enterprises suffer a decline in sales,

profitability, and lack of financing. The banking system turmoil exacerbates the volatility situation

and investor confidence as well.

6,000

8,000

10,000

12,000

14,000

16,000

18,000

20,000

22,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

JAPAN

(a) Market Index

-.6

-.5

-.4

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

JAPAN

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-15: Herding Evolution in Japanese Market

Figure 4.15 reports the result of the Japanese market. This study analyzes that over the

entire period from 2000 to 2015 Japanese market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as

the value is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.547 to 0.282 from table

4.12. It is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.292 which implies that 29.2 percent change

in dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value

zero and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. Japanese economy faced a

financial recession since 1990. A significant rise is observed after 2013 followed by a substantial

increase in money supply. The adverse herding peaks in the graph can be attached to 2000 US

Page 155: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

134

bubble and economic shutdown, the 2007 subprime mortgage crisis, and the 2008 Lehman

Brothers bankruptcy (a slight peak in adverse herding), and 2011 Eurozone crisis.

Figure 4.16 reports the result of Korea market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Korea market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value

is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.335 to 0.496 from table 4.12. It

is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.324 which implies that 32.4 percent change in

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero

and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. Highly fluctuating herding

behavior is observed in Korean market with several episodes of adverse and normal herding with

a number of adjustments.

50

100

150

200

250

300

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

KOREA

(a) Market Index

-.4

-.2

.0

.2

.4

.6

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

KOREA

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-16: Herding Evolution in Korean market

Figure 4.17 reports the result of Malaysian market. This study analyzes that over the entire period

from 2000 to 2015 Malaysian market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value is

far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.235 to 0.217 from table 4.12. It is

also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.589 which implies that 58.9 percent change in

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero

and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. During the global financial crisis,

Page 156: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

135

the share prices fell to 20% from 2007 to 2009. There is a massive outflow of short-term capital

flows in 2009. These shocks were rapidly absorbed due to sound financial and banking system.

There are several episodes of crisis but Malaysian economy managed it well due to strong banking

and reserve systems. The impact of the financial crisis of 2008 would have been much more severe

and shaken the investor confidence if it is not backed by the sound macroeconomic discipline and

timely actions taken by the Malaysian authorities by the Asian financial crisis.

400

600

800

1,000

1,200

1,400

1,600

1,800

2,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

MALAYSIA

(a) Market Index

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

MALAYSIA

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-17: Herding Evolution in Malaysian Market

Figure 4.18 reports the result of Netherlands market. This study analyzes that over the entire period

from 2000 to 2015 Netherlands market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value

is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.256 to 0.267 from table 4.12. It

is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.389 which implies that 38.9 percent change in

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero

and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. Two episodes of adverse herding

are observed in Netherlands market. One is witnessed in 2003 and another one is followed by the

Global financial crisis. The adverse herding in the first phase is witnesses after the first quarter of

2003 the time of largest downturn in the history of the stock market of Netherlands. Second adverse

Page 157: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

136

phase can be witnessed as the effect of Global Financial crisis. Both the Graphs simultaneously

exhibit downtrend. It means that investor is highly reactive to the stock market functioning.

200

300

400

500

600

700

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

NETHERLAND

(a) Market Index

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

NETHERLAND

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-18: Herding Evolution in Netherlands Market

Figure 4.19 reports the result of New Zealand market. This study analyzes that over the

entire period from 2000 to 2015 New Zealand market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding

as the value is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.08 to 0.15 from table

4.12. It is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.101 which implies that 10.1 percent change

in dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value

zero and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. In New Zealand, market

investor herding behavior is not much intense as the values are far away from 1. From 2000 to

2009 adverse herding is observed and from 2010 onward New Zealand investor exhibit normal

herding behavior towards market portfolio. Like other OECD markets, New Zealand also went

through economic slow-down after the global financial crisis in September 2008. The consumer

and business confidence decline but the economy recovered mainly through exports, strong

Government accounts and sound banking system proved to be the stable base. These policy boosts

led to an increase in the level of GDP in 2010 and 2011. The New Zealand stock market has

Page 158: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

137

recovered strongly from the global financial crisis from 1 April 2009 to 30 June 2015 that can be

seen in both Graphs

1,600

1,800

2,000

2,200

2,400

2,600

2,800

3,000

3,200

3,400

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

NEWZEALAND

(a) Market Index

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

.15

.20

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

NEWZEALAND

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-19: Herding Evolution in New Zealand Market

Figure 4.20 reports the result of Norwegian market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Norwegian market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the

value is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.137 to 0.158 from table

4.12. It is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.079 which implies that 7.9% percent change

in dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value

zero and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. Norwegian economy

experience a herding behavior from 2000 to 2003 after that period adverse herding is observed.

The initial decline in the stock market is attached to the dotcom bubble effect that is not adverse

for the Norwegian economy. The global financial crisis has significant effect followed by a drop

in market index beginning of 2008, as a result of the global financial countries. In 2009 the stock

markets increase and fall again during 2010.

Page 159: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

138

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

NORWAY

(a) Market Index

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

.15

.20

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

NORWAY

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-20: Herding Evolution in Norway Market

Figure 4.21 reports the result of Pakistani market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Pakistani market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the

value is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.118 to 0.117 from table

4.12. It is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.178 which implies that 17.8% percent

change in dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean

value zero and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. From figure 4.21, it is

observed that from 2005-2010 Pakistani investor exhibit adverse herding behavior. The herding

appears to be stationary and time-varying. This indicates that in most of the time period Pakistan

economy exhibit significant herding activities especially during and post-crisis periods it remains

negative. The time period of crisis is attributed global financial crisis of 2008. Before the global

financial crisis, three local crisis hits the economy. The domestic crisis period is stock market crash

of 2005, 2006 and 2008. During all three domestic crisis, the stock market shows persistent herding

behavior, as the herding coefficient remain negative during the crisis and the post-crisis period.

Page 160: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

139

0

5,000

10,000

15,000

20,000

25,000

30,000

35,000

40,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

PAKISTAN

(a) Market Index

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

.15

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

PAKISTAN

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-21: Herding Evolution in Pakistani Market

Figure 4.22 reports the result of Philippines market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Philippines market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the

value is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.212 to 0.227 from table

4.12. It is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.261 which implies that 26.1% percent

change in dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding.

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

7,000

8,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

PHILPINES

(a) Market Index

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

PHILIPPINES

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-22: Herding Evolution in Philippines Market

The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero and several cycles of herding and

adverse herding are observed. The Philippine economy faced a mild recession in 2003 and growth

rates are lower than 2 percent. Soon it recovered but the major increase in this unemployment is

observed aftermaths of the Lehman Brothers breakdown in late 2008.

Page 161: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

140

Figure 4.23 reports the result of Portuguese market. This study analyzes that over the entire period

from 2000 to 2015 Philippines market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value is

far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.108 to 0.107 from table 4.12. It is

also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.131 which implies that 13.1% percent change in

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding.

4,000

6,000

8,000

10,000

12,000

14,000

16,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

PORUGAL

(a) Market Index

-.12

-.08

-.04

.00

.04

.08

.12

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

PORTUGAL

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-23: Herding Evolution in Portugal Market

The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero and several cycles of herding and adverse

herding are observed. Several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. The Portuguese

economy is one of the best markets during 2002-2007 and continued to grow positively during

most of 2008. The impact of the global financial crisis is felt in last quarter of 2008 but it recovered

through timely reforms including growth in exports. Low exposure of the financial system to

banking system keep the country secure from turmoil. It can be easily observed in both panels of

the graph.

Figure 4.24 reports the result of Singapore market. This study analyzes that over the entire period

from 2000 to 2015 Singapore market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value is

far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.109 to 0.146 from table 4.12. It is

Page 162: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

141

also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.167 which implies that 16.7% percent change in

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding.

1,000

1,500

2,000

2,500

3,000

3,500

4,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

SINGAPORE

(a) Market Index

-.15

-.10

-.05

.00

.05

.10

.15

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

SINGAPORE

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-24: Herding Evolution in Singapore market

The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero and several cycles of herding and

adverse herding are observed. Despite increased employment in 2007 and 2008 and averaging a

growth rate of nearly 10 percent from 2004 to 2007. Singapore is the first and worst hit economy

in the East Asian country by the global economic crisis in July 2008. Till 2009 situation continued

after 2010 the growth rate increased at a rate of 3 to 5 % on average. After this period economy

recovered at a rapid pace.

4,000

6,000

8,000

10,000

12,000

14,000

16,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

SPAIN

(a) Market Index

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

.4

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

SPAIN

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-25: Herding Evolution in Spanish Market

Page 163: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

142

Figure 4.25 reports the result of the Spanish market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Spanish market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value

is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.172 to 0.307 from table 4.12. It

is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.163 which implies that 16.3% percent change in

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero

and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. During the 1990s and early 2000s,

Spain enjoyed rapid economic growth. Spain is now the 5th largest EU economy. The economy

hits badly by the global financial crisis. Overall Spanish economy faced adverse herding from

2002 to 2014, with very few adjustments.

Figure 4.26 reports the result of Sri Lankan market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Sri Lankan market exhibit extreme level of herding as the value is greater

than 0.5 in most of the regions and the value is observed within a range of -0.513 to 0.535 from

table 4.12. It is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 1.246 which implies that 124.6 % percent

change in dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean

value zero and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed.

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

7,000

8,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

SRILANKA

(a) Market Index

-.6

-.4

-.2

.0

.2

.4

.6

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

SRILANKA

(b) Hmt--Herding Series

Figure 4-26: Herding Evolution in Sri Lankan Market

Page 164: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

143

The Singapore economy exhibits an intense level of herding during the entire period. The

global financial crisis is no surprise as the economy in the whole time period faced several cycles

of herding and adverse herding.

Figure 4.27 reports the result of Swedish market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Swedish market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value

is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.327 to 0.298 from table 4.12. It

is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.143 which implies that 14.3% percent change in

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero

and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. In early years Swedish economy

observes positive herding behavior from 2005 onward several episodes of adverse herding are

observed, Sweden is traditionally highly dependent on exports, leaving the economy at the mercy

of the fluctuations in global markets. During the time the Krona appreciated that has worsened the

situation during the global financial crisis and the economy struggles through several structural

breaks.

400

600

800

1,000

1,200

1,400

1,600

1,800

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

SWEDEN

(a) Market Index

-.4

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

.4

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

SWEDEN

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-27: Herding Evolution in Swedish Market

Figure 4.28 reports the result of Swiss market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Swiss market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value

Page 165: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

144

is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.105 to 0.117 from table 4.12. It

is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.106 which implies that 10.6 percent change in

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero

and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed.

4,000

5,000

6,000

7,000

8,000

9,000

10,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

SWITZERLAND

(a) Market Index

-.12

-.08

-.04

.00

.04

.08

.12

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

SWITZERLAND

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-28: Herding Evolution in Swiss Market

The Swiss economy exhibits a major spike in 2011, the global financial crisis has little

effect on herding behavior but Eurozone crisis increases the intensity of herding as this time period

Switzerland, has been especially affected, as its major trading partner is the European Union.

Almost 60% of all its merchandise exports in 2010 went to the EU. The euro crisis hit the Swiss

economy through trade effects.

200

400

600

800

1,000

1,200

1,400

1,600

1,800

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

THAILAND

(a) Market Index

-.6

-.5

-.4

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

THAILAND

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-29: Herding Evolution in Thai Market

Page 166: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

145

Figure 4.29 reports the result of Thailand market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Thailand market exhibit extreme level of herding as the value is around

0.5 throughout the period and value is observed within a range of -0.534 to -0.291 from table 4.12.

It is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.46 which implies that 46 percent change in

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value of 0.5

and several cycles of adverse herding are observed. Thailand is the economy where this study

observe a continuous period of adverse herding as a dynamic process. This is due to the intense

role of the institutional investor in the market, the presence of information asymmetry and the high

cost of acquiring information leads the Thai investor towards intense herding behavior.

0

10,000

20,000

30,000

40,000

50,000

60,000

70,000

80,000

90,000

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

TURKEY

(a) Market Index

-.06

-.04

-.02

.00

.02

.04

.06

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

TURKEY

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-30: Herding Evolution in Turkish Market

Figure 4.30 reports the result of the Turkish market. This study analyzes that over the entire

period from 2000 to 2015 Turkish market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value

is far away from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.049 to 0.048 from table 4.12. It

is also verified by the signal to noise ratio of 0.178 which implies that 17.8 percent change in

dispersion of portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero

and several cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. Herding behavior in Turkish

market is between the ranges of very nominal values. And global crisis and Euro crisis fail to put

Page 167: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

146

strong pressure on the economy. Turkish economy followed a fast pace of growth in last years and

perform wonderfully since the global financial crisis. Therefore herding behavior has minimal

effect on the Turkish investors.

3,500

4,000

4,500

5,000

5,500

6,000

6,500

7,000

7,500

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

UK

(a) Market Index

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

.4

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

UK

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-31: Herding Evolution in UK market

Figure 4.31 reports the result of UK market. This study analyzes that over the entire period

from 2000 to 2015 UK market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value is far away

from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.226 to 0.320 from table 4.12. It is also verified

by the signal to noise ratio of 0.564 which implies that 56.4 percent change in dispersion of

portfolio beta is due to Herding. The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero and several

cycles of herding and adverse herding are observed. From the graph, one can observe that none of

the Global and Eurozone crisis affects the Herding behavior of UK investors. During both time

periods herding measure either remained in the positive region or value vary below -0.1.

Figure 4.32 reports the result of US market. This study analyzes that over the entire period

from 2000 to 2015 US market does not exhibit an extreme level of herding as the value is far away

from 1 and the value is observed within a range of -0.218 to 0.395 from table 4.12. It is also verified

by the signal to noise ratio of 0.33 which implies that 33 percent change in dispersion of portfolio

beta is due to Herding.

Page 168: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

147

600

800

1,000

1,200

1,400

1,600

1,800

2,000

2,200

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

US

(a) Market Index

-.3

-.2

-.1

.0

.1

.2

.3

.4

.5

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

2013

2014

2015

US

(b) Hmt---Herding Series

Figure 4-32: Herding Evolution in US market

The value of hmt fluctuates around mean value zero and several cycles of herding and

adverse herding are observed. Surprisingly during and after the global financial crisis, the US

investor exhibit positive herding and the value of herding remained in the positive region. The

intense level of herding had never been observed during the period.

Selection of best Model based on AIC and BIC

Table 4.13 reports the comparison of return dispersion models and state space models based on

the AIC and BIC. For model selection in classical settings, the exact likelihood value is needed to

compute model selection criteria such as the AIC or BIC (de Valpine 2008). According to the AIC

and BIC values, it is observed that the state space model presented by Hwang & Salmon (2004)

outperform as compared to the Return dispersion model proposed by the (Chiang et al., 2013).

This conclusion is based on the smaller values of AIC and BIC in state space model as compared

to the dynamic return dispersion model in all countries in a sample.

Table 4.13: Selection of model based on AIC and BIC Panel A: Developed Market

Country Return Dispersion Model State Space Model

AIC BIC AIC BIC

Page 169: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

148

Australia 0.213 0.218 -1.055 -0.987

Austria 0.928 0.933 -0.257 -0.189

Belgium -0.194 -0.189 -1.5 -1.432

Denmark -7.85 -7.844 -1.126 -1.058

France 0.38 0.386 -1.05 -0.982

Germany 0.375 0.381 -2.192 -2.124

Greece 1.627 1.631 -0.118 -0.05

Hong Kong 1.168 1.172 -1.341 -1.287

Italy 0.423 0.429 -1.211 -1.143

Netherland 0.621 0.624 -0.307 -0.24

New Zealand ----- ----- -0.577 -0.509

Norway 0.982 0.986 -1.261 -1.193

Portugal 1.541 1.546 -0.085 -0.018

Singapore 1.062 1.068 -0.511 -0.443

Spain 0.458 0.462 -1.561 -1.493

Sweden 0.803 0.807 -1.111 -1.044

Switzerland ----- ----- -1.606 -1.538

UK 0.093 0.097 -1.035 -0.967

US -0.441 -0.437 -1.082 -1.014

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier markets

Country Return Dispersion Model State Space Model

AIC BIC AIC BIC

China -8.413 -8.408 -1.125 -1.078

India 0.899 0.904 -1.25 -1.182

Indonesia 1.215 1.221 -0.097 -0.029

Korea 1.402 1.407 -1.202 -1.134

Malaysia 0.198 0.203 -1.22 -1.152

Page 170: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

149

Pakistan 1.06 1.065 -0.535 -0.467

Philippines 1.253 1.258 -0.303 -0.235

Sri Lanka 0.884 0.889 0.111 0.179

Taiwan 0.567 0.572 ------ -----

Thailand 1.184 1.189 -1.286 -1.218

Turkey 1.752 1.757 -2.273 -2.205

The superiority of the Hwang & Salmon (2004) model can be due to the fact that these models

incorporate the risk and return characteristics of the market and incorporate the effect of

fundamental information and also incorporate the effect of time series volatility. The return

dispersion model fails to capture this characteristic of the market. This is the reason, out of all

three measures this model has strong theoretical properties and provide better empirical results

which are further validated through the selection based criteria’s. These results meet the objective

of best model selection and have implication for future studies and markets.

Estimation of Macroeconomic Shocks on Herding Behavior

The extraordinary or infrequently occurring event has an important effect on modeling

financial and macroeconomic time series. These are classified as outliers or a specific shock. These

shocks have relative importance in behavioral finance literature and can be detected through

several methods based on intervention analysis as originally proposed by Box & Tiao (1975).

Another commonly used method is that of Tsay (1988). This study utilizes Box-Jenkins ARIMA

model for the detection of shocks that have an effect on the herding behavior of international markets.

Table 4.14 presents the results of the structure of estimated ARIMA model for the selected

macroeconomic variables. The basic idea behind the selection of in-sample residuals from the

estimated ARIMA-models as a proxy for the unexpected shocks is that the information is

Page 171: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

150

considered to be at least partly rational as the residuals have a zero mean value and observed to be

serially uncorrelated. The forecast is based on the past values of the series itself.

All variables except interest rates are transformed into the natural logarithmic. The first

step in the estimation of ARIMA model is to check the stationarity of data. The stochastic process

is assumed to be stationary if its mean and variance remain unchanged over time and covariance

depend on the lags between the time periods. In order to check stationarity of exchange rates,

industrial production index, Interest rates and money supply, correlogram of ACF and PACF and

unit root test (Augmented Dickey-Fuller) unit root test is applied. Unit root test is used to detect

the order of integration. At level, all series are found to be non-stationary, whereas, with a first

difference, the null hypothesis of unit root test is rejected. It means that all series are integrated to

order 1.

To reach the Parsimony each series is checked with different p and q orders. The residuals

obtained from these structures are further used to check the impact of macroeconomic shocks on

herding behavior and contagion of herding. Panel A of Table 4.14 presents results for the

developed markets. All series are integrated to order one and p and q orders vary significantly from

variable to variable. The ARIMA structures, with Schwartz Bayesian Criteria (SBC), along with

their R2 value is given. Highest p and q orders are observed in case of money supply in developed

markets. It is observed that in developed markets Interest rate appear to exhibit highest R-value

among all, whereas exchange rates exhibit lowest value R2 among other variables. In general, the

explanatory value of ARIMA residuals varies among countries.

Table 4.14: The structures of estimated ARIMA models with the order (p,d,q) of all

macroeconomic variables. Panel A: Developed Market

Exchange Rates Industrial Production Index Interest Rates Money Supply

Page 172: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

151

ARIMA SBC R2 ARIMA SBC R2 ARIMA SBC R2 ARIMA SBC R2

Australia (1,1,2) -3.61 0.16 (2,1,1) 1.45 0.74 (4,1,2) -5.09 0.14 (5,1,2) 4.04 0.07

Austria (1,1,2) 0.35 0.12 (1,1,2) 3.66 0.07 (3,1,2) -6.50 0.22 (2,1,2) 2.92 0.09

Belgium (1,1,2) 2.50 0.12 (2,1,3) 5.07 0.34 (3,1,1) -1.44 0.88 (4,1,5) 3.01 0.17

Denmark (3,1,1) -0.86 0.97 (3,1,3) 6.62 0.52 (2,1,2) -5.59 0.12 (2,1,3) 4.14 0.55

France (2,1,4) -0.84 0.09 (2,1,1) 3.44 0.08 (3,1,2) -6.47 0.55 (5,1,2) 3.15 0.33

Germany (3,1,2) -3.63 0.14 (2,1,2) 3.66 0.10 (1,1,1) -0.95 0.32 (4,1,3) 3.98 0.29

Greece (3,1,2) 6.80 0.14 (3,1,0) 4.95 0.37 (4,1,2) -1.84 0.27 (2,1,3) 4.00 0.55

Hong Kong (3,1,1) 2.35 0.30 (4,1,4) 5.10 0.19 (3,1,3) -3.77 0.10 (2,1,2) 3.93 0.05

Italy (1,1,2) 10.24 0.12 (2,1,3) 5.55 0.47 (3,1,2) -6.47 0.56 (2,1,4) 3.62 0.30

Japan (2,1,4) 4.73 0.1 (1,1,0) 4.59 0.03 (2,1,2) -9.09 0.12 (4,1,2) 1.02 0.42

Netherland (3,1,2) -3.28 0.14 (1,1,1) 4.50 0.10 (5,1,4) -5.26 0.27 (3,1,3) 3.75 0.10

New Zealand (3,1,2) -2.52 0.07 (4,1,4) 3.89 0.12 (3,1,2) -4.70 0.20 (2,1,2) 4.40 0.08

Norway (2,1,2) -0.07 0.10 (3,1,3) 4.94 0.28 (2,1,4) -4.72 0.21 (5,1,5) 3.10 0.76

Portugal (5,1,4) 6.16 0.19 (3,1,3) 6.39 0.73 (2,1,0) -4.12 0.24 (3,1,3) 3.18 0.09

Singapore (2,1,3) 2.82 0.45 (2,1,3) 7.18 0.47 (4,1,5) -4.48 0.189 (1,1,1) 2.77 0.087

Spain (3,1,2) 5.37 0.14 (2,1,2) 3.53 0.12 (2,1,2) -5.080 0.07 (2,1,3) 3.27 0.22

Sweden (2,1,2) 0.19 0.08 (3,1,2) 4.64 0.16 (3,1,2) -5.98 0.4 (2,1,4) 3.41 0.30

Switzerland (1,1,2) -4.12 0.06 (2,1,5) 5.22 0.50 (1,1,1) -5.40 0.07 (1,1,2) 3.11 0.35

UK (2,1,1) -3.83 0.11 (1,1,2) 2.79 0.06 (1,1,2) -5.60 0.13 (3,1,3) 0.89 0.22

US (2,1,1) -3.83 0.10 (2,1,2) 2.04 0.30 (1,1,2) -6.28 0.53 (2,1,3) 1.01 0.12

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier Market

Exchange Rates Industrial Production Index Interest Rates Money Supply

ARIMA SBC R2 ARIMA SBC R2 ARIMA SBC R2 ARIMA SBC R2

China (2,1,2) 0.88 0.29 (3,1,0) 4.67 0.33 (3,1,2) -3.32 0.09 (2,1,2) 2.87 0.28

India (2,1,3) 2.56 0.18 (4,1,5) 5.50 0.64 (2,1,0) -3.38 0.05 (3,1,4) 3.95 0.27

Indonesia (3,1,3) 5.52 0.10 (2,1,2) 6.13 0.75 (1,1,2) -0.32 0.37 (1,1,1) 3.68 0.03

Korea (3,1,3) 3.45 0.38 (1,1,1) 3.12 0.16 (3,1,2) -5.04 0.22 (2,1,2) -4.51 0.07

Malaysia (3,1,3) -2.65 0.12 (2,1,0) 5.25 0.28 (3,1,2) -7.42 0.13 (2,1,2) 2.98 0.12

Pakistan (3,1,2) 3.06 0.10 (3,1,2) 3.06 0.10 (4,1,4) -2.21 0.41 (4,1,4) -2.21 0.41

Page 173: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

152

Philippines (3,1,3) 2.58 0.18 (3,1,3) 6.58 0.23 (2,1,2) -3.01 0.23 (2,1,2) 4.58 0.22

Sri Lanka (4,1,4) 3.97 0.13 (2,1,1) 6.86 0.17 (1,1,3) -2.80 0.14 (2,1,2) 2.48 0.08

Taiwan (3,1,2) 0.83 0.29 (2,1,3) 4.75 0.15 (5,1,2) -2.91 0.2 (4,1,3) 1.80 0.23

Thailand (3,1,3) 2.01 0.14 (3,1,3) 6.74 0.37 (1,1,2) -4.54 0.17 (5,1,5) 4.64 0.76

Turkey (3,1,2) -2.44 0.08 (3,1,3) 6.56 0.39 (1,1,1) 4.73 0.47 (4,1,5) 5.80 0.13

Panel B of the table 4.14 present results for the emerging and frontier markets. All series are

integrated to order 1 and the p and q orders vary significantly. The ARIMA structures, with

Schwartz Bayesian Criteria (SBC), along with their R2 value is given. Like Developed markets,

Money supply exhibit highest AR and MA orders. It is observed that Industrial production index

exhibit highest R2 value among all, whereas exchange rate has the lowest R2 value in almost all

countries.

Table 4.15 reports the results of the effect of macroeconomic shocks on herding. The

estimated residuals from ARIMA models are included as an explanatory variable in the Hwang &

Salmon (2004) model. The findings show that in most of the countries Macroeconomic shocks

have an insignificant effect on investors herding behavior but in few cases, one or two of the four

variables have a significant effect on herding behavior of an investor. In some cases, the inclusion

of Macroeconomic shocks affects the intensity of herding behavior that can be observed through

the changed value of herding Coefficient.

Table 4.15 presents the results of the effect of macroeconomic shocks on investor herding

behavior. Panel A reports the results of developed markets. In general, it is concluded that none of

these shocks except few have a significant effect on the imitating behavior of investor. According

to Hwang & Salmon (2004) if the coefficient Hmt becomes insignificant then change in the

dispersion is due to macroeconomic fundamental not due to Herding. These findings are similar to

Page 174: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

153

Hwang & Salmon (2004) except few almost all macroeconomic shocks exhibit an insignificant

effect on investor herding behavior as the coefficient Hmt remains significant. In some countries,

it can be observed that exchange rate shocks(Austria and Portugal), Interest rate shocks(France)

and money supply shocks (Japan) have a significant effect on the return dispersion and in the

presence of these shocks the coefficient m is significant and high and nm is different from zero.

These findings are in line with Messis & Zapranis (2014) they examine four series of

macroeconomic shock and observe similar results.

From the table 4.15, it can be observed that Exchange rates shock significantly affect the

herding behavior in the Austrian market. The decrease in the dispersion can be interpreted into the

less correlated behavior of investors in the market and results in decrease herding behavior towards

market portfolio. These findings are similar to Gang & Dai (2017), they find a significant effect of

CNY depreciation on herding intensity. The Austrian economy in 1995 joined the European Union

and adopted Euro as the single currency in 1999. Euro as a single currency among EU can be

considered equivalent to an irrevocably fixed exchange rate that can be controlled through

adjustments in the European Union internally. The most recent crisis like US subprime, euro as a

common currency insulated the Euro area from the dollar depreciation and financial panic. But the

2010 Greek and Irish crisis and more specifically Euro debt crisis destabilize the ambitious

dominance of European integration process. Especially, the Austrian economy depends upon

international Sovereign debts as an external Financing, large unemployment and inflation result in

decrease investor confidence on unanimous currency. The decrease in Euro value over time can

be attributed to lesser consumer confidence and more correlated behavior.

Portugal market also exhibits similar results, there exists a negative relationship between

exchange rate shocks and cross-sectional standard deviation of portfolio betas. These results are

Page 175: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

154

supported as Cho, Choi, Kim, & Kim (2016) discuss that the investor reaction to change in

currency value is different in developed markets than in emerging markets, the flow of capital from

the market or in the market depends upon the Global market conditions and investors respond

accordingly. When there is a downward trend in the global market, emerging market investors

shift their funds to the developed markets, which results in a negative correlation of currency and

stock returns in developed, whereas the positive correlation between stock returns and currency

value in emerging markets. Same correlation is observed when global markets are in boom.

Therefore, the results are in line with the above-stated argument as the markets faced recession

there exists a negative relation between, stock return and currency value.

With increased trade and international diversification and investment, the role of interest

rates and exchange rates is getting more attention gradually Tsai (2012). The interest rate shock is

found to have a positive impact on the standard deviation of portfolio beta in the French market.

It implies that a positive shock in interest rates increase the magnitude of herding in the French

market. These findings are similar to Gang & Dai (2017), they find a significant effect of an

increase in interest rate on Chinese investor herding behavior. These findings are in line with Lee,

Liao, & Hsu (2015) and in contradiction with Philippas et al. (2013); Messis & Zapranis (2014).

This study reports the significant negative effect of money supply on the standard

dispersion of portfolio betas in the Japanese market. It is observed that the Herding coefficient m

is still positive and near to one and mn is different from zero confirming the presence of herding.

Whereas decreased dispersion leads to a reduction in herding intensity. According to Gong & Dai

(2017), the contractionary monetary policy means a decrease in reserve ratio has a significant

negative effect on the investor herding behavior. This study finds similar results in case of Japan.

Money supply is considered as the monetary policy coefficient (Keran, 1971). According to

Page 176: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

155

Maskay (2007), the change in money supply or the monetary policy are the most useful tools to

control the actual economic activity used by the central bank of the respective country. In literature

several authors like as Gupta (1974), Maskay (2007) consider money supply an important factor

in determining the stock prices. Monetary policy has a significant effect on the development and

behavior of stock prices. Money supply has a direct effect on the stock prices as the excess

availability of funds and reduced interest rates are linked with cheaper external financing both of

the factors lead to increased investment and consumption that can be translated into growth in

demand of shares (Ioannidis & Kontonikas, 2006).

In rest of the developed markets none of the macroeconomic shocks have significant effect

and herding remains prevalent in all markets, therefore it can be concluded that macroeconomic

shocks do not have a significant effect on the imitating behavior of an investor.

Panel B of the table 4.15 represent the results of the emerging and frontier markets, it can be

observed that exchange rate shocks exhibit a negative significant relationship with cross-sectional

standard deviation of portfolio betas in Chinese, Pakistani and Malaysian markets. Whereas there

exists a significant negative relationship of industrial production index on the cross-sectional

standard deviation of portfolio betas in Sri Lankan market and Thailand market exhibit negative

relation of interest rates and the positive effect of money supply shocks. This study shows that

with the introduction of macroeconomic shocks herding becomes insignificant in the Malaysian

and Taiwanese market. Rest of the markets exhibit similar results and no effect of macroeconomic

shocks is detected.

The effect of macroeconomic shocks on stock return dispersion can be due to several

reasons. One reason can be the implementation of economic reforms in recent years that include

financial liberalization in order to attract foreign capital and economic growth (Hajilee & Al

Page 177: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

156

Nasser, 2014) Second reason can be the shift of fixed exchange rates to managed-floating and free-

floating exchange rates which has increased the exposure of exchange rate volatilities. This

volatility can be translated into stock price volatility that has a negative or positive effect on

investor holdings (Chen & Diaz, 2012).

Ibrahim & Aziz (2003) investigate the dynamic relationship and negative correlation in different

exchange rates and stock prices in Malaysian market during a period 1977-1998. Abdalla &

Murinde (1997) investigate Pakistan, India, Korea, and the Philippines market and find co-

integration between stock prices and exchange rates and find unidirectional causality from

exchange rates during 1985 to 1994. Similarly, Lin (2012) investigate co-movement of stock

prices and exchange rates in different emerging Asian markets. They conclude that the emerging

markets have an advantage of local currency appreciation due to the flow of capital funds into the

markets and movement is not strong in export-oriented industries. Demirer et al. (2014) investigate

exchange rate as a plausible reason for investor herding behavior in the Korean market. This study

finds a significant effect of exchange rate shock on Chinese stock return dispersion, these findings

are similar to Gong & Dai (2017), they found that the depreciation in stock returns leads to more

correlated behavior i.e., Herding behavior.

The results indicate that in Pakistani stock market exchange rates shocks have a significant

negative effect on stock return dispersion, these findings are in contradiction with Javaira &

Hassan (2015). They find the insignificant effect of exchange rates on investor herding behavior

in Pakistani market during a period from 2002-2005. Malaysian market exhibit similar behavior.

These findings confirm the findings of Ibrahim & Aziz (2003) as they investigate the dynamic

relationship and negative correlation in different exchange rates and stock prices in Malaysian

market during a period 1977-1998. Malaysian market exhibits unique results as the herding

Page 178: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

157

coefficient become insignificant with the inclusion of macroeconomic shocks. According to

Hwang & Salmon (2004) significant macroeconomic announcement and insignificant herding

parameter, indicating that the cross-sectional dispersion in betas is due to macroeconomic shock

not due to herding behavior. This effect can be easily observed in the stock market of Malaysia, a

reduction in significance level is observed but the value of coefficient plus the noise term is still

different from zero.

Another unique result is realized in case of Sri Lankan market, the Herding behavior is

absent in Sri Lankan market before the inclusion of macroeconomic shock. After the inclusion of

macroeconomic shocks the Industrial production shock display positive significant results and the

Herding coefficient also become significant. It means that the shock in industrial production leads

to more correlated behavior of investors in Sri Lankan market and results in herd formation.

According to results Thailand market exhibit negative relation of interest rates and the

positive effect of money supply shocks. Brahmasrene & Jiranyakul (2007) found a positive effect

of money supply and stock prices in Thai stock market. Results of Thai market are interesting in

aspects that it is the only market where the significance of two macroeconomic factors is observed.

Monetary policy is devised to control inflation in a market, this outcome is a collective action of

money supply and interest rate changes (Asghapur et al., 2014). According to Loisel, Pommeret,

& Portier, (2012), the tightening of monetary policy make entrepreneur inclined to borrow, the

investment in new technology increases and if the expectation about productivity is positive. It

results in decreased herd formation and fragility in the stock market also declines.

The findings show that in most of the countries Macroeconomic shocks have an insignificant effect

on investors herding behavior but in few cases, one or two of the four variables have a significant

effect on herding behavior of an investor. In some cases, inclusion of Macroeconomic shocks

Page 179: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

158

affects the intensity of herding behavior that can be observed through the changed value of herding

Coefficient. These findings are consistent with the asset pricing model in the presence of sound

fundamentals investors behavior is rational, however unexpected shocks in the economy give rise

to uncertain situations which could be triggered by the social influences.

Page 180: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

159

Table 4.15: Impact of Macroeconomic shocks on Herding Panel A: Developed Markets

Country ER IP IR MS

Australia -0.493(0.048)** 0.130(0.121)** 0.974(0.023)** 0.017(0.864)** -0.182(0.336) 0.003(0.029) 0.415(0.967) -0.012(0.010)

Austria -0.642(0.092)** 0.192(0.118)** 0.980(0.020)** 0.027(0.748)** -0.127(0.057)** -0.006(0.012) -0.036(1.922) 0.010(0.015)

Belgium -0.405(0.021)** 0.103(0.111)** 0.904(0.068)** 0.023(0.886)** -0.004(0.011) 0.000(0.001) 0.021(0.071) 0.013(0.007)

Denmark -0.302(0.022)** 0.112(0.217)** 0.822(0.113)** 0.051(0.705)** 0.076(0.071) 0.000(0.002) 0.686(0.654) -0.004(0.005)

France -0.603(0.080)** 0.115(0.140)** 0.970(0.023)** 0.042(0.435)** -0.123(0.077) 0.005(0.007) 0.268(0.121)* 0.006(0.008)

Germany -0.590(0.048)** 0.022(1.001)** 0.901(0.034)** 0.074(0.183)** -0.012(0.151) 0.002(0.004) 0.023(0.033) 0.001(0.003)

Greece -0.637(0.064)** 0.206(0.111)** 0.940(0.048)** 0.044(0.895)** 0.002(0.003) 0.001(0.005) -0.129(0.386) 0.012(0.013)

Hong Kong -0.442(0.074)** 0.117(0.128)** 0.979(0.020)** 0.021(0.703)** -0.002(0.012) -0.002(0.003) 0.220(0.304) 0.010(0.007)

Italy -0.521(0.025)** 0.115(0.117)** 0.868(0.084)** 0.038(0.803)** 0.000(0.000) -0.001(0.003) 0.202(1.412) -0.005(0.008)

Japan -0.699(0.010)** 0.000(1.89E+07) 0.661(0.083)** 0.039(0.221)** 0.001(0.001) -0.001(0.001) -0.416(0.955) -0.010(0.006)*

Netherland -0.650(0.054)** 0.183(0.131)** 0.934(0.043)** 0.051(0.633)** -0.332(0.382) 0.008(0.007) 0.187(1.612) -0.003(0.012)

New Zealand -0.462(0.036)** 0.170(0.104)** 0.954(0.043)** 0.021(0.961)** 0.043(0.222) -0.013(0.010) -0.089(0.734) 0.004(0.008)

Norway 0.008(0.075)** 0.116(0.094)** 0.989(0.012)** 0.016(0.687)** -0.077(0.051) -0.002(0.004) -0.132(0.496) 0.007(0.010)

Portugal -0.453(0.037)** 0.211(0.115)** 0.914(0.111)** 0.034(1.577)** -0.008(0.003)** -0.002(0.004) 0.168(0.904) 0.000(0.016)

Singapore -0.584(0.032)** 0.169(0.128)** 0.913(0.072)** 0.035(0.944)** 0.018(0.051) -0.002(0.002) -0.796(0.609) -0.028(0.049)

Spain -0.486(0.062)** 0.090(0.118)** 0.975(0.018)** 0.029(0.448)** -0.002(0.002) 0.002(0.006) -0.511(0.372) 0.004(0.007)

Sweden -0.511(0.139)** 0.116(0.136)** 0.983(0.021)** 0.038(0.507)** -0.028(0.040) 0.005(0.005) 0.335(1.045) -0.004(0.009)

Switzerland -0.438(0.027)** 0.097(0.120)** 0.944(0.042)** 0.021(0.772)** -0.109(0.304) 0.001(0.003) 0.469(0.594) 0.004(0.009)

UK -0.429(0.078)** 0.120(0.135)** 0.965(0.026)** 0.040(0.479)** 0.194(0.332) -0.007(0.010) 0.478(0.669) 0.003(0.029)

Page 181: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

160

US -0.564(0.063)** 0.111(0.158)** 0.948(0.032)** 0.049(0.414)** 0.144(0.279) 0.020(0.015) -0.305(0.889) -0.042(0.031)

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier Markets

Country ER IP IR MS

China -0.660(0.027)** 0.125(0.190)** 0.746(0.117)** 0.082(0.580)** -0.064(0.036)* -0.010(0.007) 0.337(0.387) 0.011(0.014)

India -0.486(0.039)** 0.101(0.176)** 0.904(0.050)** 0.051(0.468)** -0.020(0.014) 0.001(0.003) -0.302(0.200) -0.003(0.005)

Indonesia -0.498(0.040)** 0.191(0.150)** 0.838(0.084)** 0.078(0.568)** 0.000(0.005) -0.006(0.004) 0.047(0.119) -0.011(0.010)

Korea -0.413(0.032)** 0.125(0.106)** 0.962(0.035)** 0.016(0.917)** 0.005(0.011) 0.002(0.006) 0.162(0.711) -0.001(0.004)

Malaysia -0.325(0.017)** 0.070(0.891)** 0.512(0.165) 0.093(0.596) -0.207(0.116)* -0.003(0.004) -0.854(1.598) -0.009(0.011)

Pakistan -0.386(0.051)** 0.168(0.081)** 0.949(0.052)** 0.026(0.870)** 0.032(0.011)** -0.001(0.002) 0.283(0.255) 0.007(0.018)

Philippines -0.644(0.017)** 0.220(0.119)** -0.921(0.542)* 0.009(10.483) -0.018(0.023) -0.003(0.003) -0.551(0.369) -0.003(0.007)

Sri Lanka -0.476(0.028)** 0.139(1.454)** 0.423(0.241)* 0.198(0.826)** 0.007(0.014) -0.005(0.003)* 0.122(0.410) 0.030(0.024)

Taiwan -0.452(0.010)** 0.107(0.123)** 0.931(26.857) 0.000(636.219) -0.017(0.026) 0.005(0.004) 0.057(0.221) 0.007(0.018)

Thailand -0.406(0.014)** 0.103(0.292)** 0.665(0.228)** 0.050(1.128)** 0.004(0.017) 0.001(0.002) -0.845(0.411)** 0.010(0.004)**

Turkey -0.419(0.006)** 0.075(0.137)** 0.913(0.157)** 0.007(2.563)** -0.085(0.105) 0.000(0.001) 0.000(0.003) -0.001(0.003)

***indicate statistical significance at 1%. **Indicate statistical significance at 5%. *Indicate statistical significance at 10%.

Page 182: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

161

Contagion of Herding

Figure 4.33 and 4.34 present the results of conditional correlation between the herding measure of

US and rest of the developed countries. It is observed that this correlation coefficient increases

during turbulent period. Specifically this increase is more observable in the third quarter of 2007

and peaked in the first quarter of 2008. All markets do not exhibit variation in herding measure

-1.2

-0.8

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

AUSTRALIA AUSTRIA

BELGIUM DENMARK

FRANCE GERMANY

GREECE HONGKONG

ITALY JAPAN

NETHERLAND NEWZEALAND

NORWAY PORTUGALSINGAPORE SPAIN

SWEDEN SWITZERLAND

UK

Figure 4-33: Correlation between US and other developed markets herding measures

-1.2

-0.8

-0.4

0.0

0.4

0.8

1.2

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

CHINA INDIA

INDONESIA KOREA

MALAYSIA PAKISTAN

PHILPINES SRILANKA

TAIWAN THAILAND

TURKEY

Figure 4-34: Conditional Correlation Graph between US and other emerging and Frontier Markets

with US market. In both the Graphs it is noted that this peak time period for countries is arbitrary

around 2007 to 2009. In general this correlation increased with the exception of few countries.

Page 183: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

162

This study explains the transmission of contagion of herding through two channels, one is the crisis

shocks and the other is the macroeconomic shocks. Both channels are explained below.

Impact of Crisis Dummy on Cross Correlation of Herding Behavior

Panel A of Table 4.16 reports the results of effect of crisis shock on correlation of herding

measure between US and other developed markets. To test the hypothesis of increased correlation

in the presence of crisis, this study conducts OLS estimations. In general this study observe that,

the crisis dummy is observed to have significant impact on this increased correlation in those

economy that are particularly closely interacted with US economy through certain strategic ties.

These results validate the objective of this study that contagion of herding exists during crisis

situation. It is observed that correlation coefficient of US herding measure increased during period

of crisis period in markets of Denmark, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, whereas as Greek and

Swiss markets exhibit opposite results. During the crisis period the correlation coefficient instead

of increasing decreases. This study observes significant decrease in correlation during global

financial crisis by a value of 1% and 0.6% in Greece and Swiss markets respectively. This effect

can be related to the strong financial system in Swiss market. Banks have huge deposits to draw

on and are less dependent on short-term money markets, the freezing-up of which has brought so

many to the brink of collapse. In addition to that Swiss banks got their monetary response right

from the start, they have less need for a fiscal stimulus than other countries.

The correlation of herding measure between US and Denmark increases by 11.7% due to

global financial crisis, similarly French and US herding coefficient correlation increases by 2.4%

during crisis followed by 7.6% in Italian market and 4.3% in Japanese market. These findings are

similar to Ramchand & Susmel (1997). They analyze the relationship between correlation and

Page 184: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

163

variance of US market with other markets and conclude that during a high volatility state of US

market this correlation increases on average by 2 to 3.5 times. All these results are at least

statistically significant at 10% significance level. These findings can be related to stock market

integration. Markets which are highly integrated exhibit more correlated behavior in turbulent

periods like crisis (Chiang et al., 2007). Lin et al. (1994) investigate the correlation of volatility

measures between Japan and US markets and find the global impact of market returns on each

other. Rest of the markets exhibit insignificant effect on herding measure during turbulent period.

Hyde et al. (2007) examine the co-movement of returns between Asia-Pacific, US and European

markets and conclude that Germany, UK and Japan markets change in time and vary across

frequencies. Similar findings are observed by Rua & Nunes (2009) in US, UK Germany and

Japanese markets. Chiang et al. (2007) relate correlated behavior of all markets after crisis to

herding behavior. According to McMillan & Speight (2010) the behavior of market investors give

rise to volatility spillover that has a subsequent contagion effects. This effect can be attributed to

speculation markets due to movement in one market. Thus, contagion of herding emerges due to

information transmission.

Panel B of table 4.16 reports the results of crisis dummy on conditional correlation of

herding measure between US and rest of the emerging and developed markets. It is observed that

Chinese Korean, and Malaysian measure of herding correlation decreases by 2.23%, 1.45% and

2.1% in all three markets respectively that can be spotted by the significant negative values. The

Indian, Pakistani, and Philippines market exhibit increase in correlation of herding measure during

global financial crisis by a value of 3.9% in India 2.1% in Pakistan, and 4.5% in Philippines. Messis

& Zapranis (2014) find significant effect of global financial crisis on conditional correlation

Page 185: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

164

between Chinese and US stock market. Similarly, Graham et al. (2012) observe that integration of

the US and emerging markets over time.

Table 4.16: Tests of changes in correlations between herding towards market on behalf of

unexpected variations in macroeconomic variables in US countries. Country ki k Dcr

Der Dip Dir Dms R2

Australia

-0.228***

(-6.919)

0.234***

(3.697)

-0.027

(-0.460)

-0.084*

(-1.770)

0.126*

(1.672)

-0.076*

(-1.609)

0.004

(0.069)

0.09

Austria

0.019

(1.633)

0.841**

(22.350)

-0.017

(-0.622)

0.012

(0.472)

-0.057**

(-2.228)

0.028**

(1.979)

-0.019

(-0.952)

0.75

Belgium

0.050**

(4.555)

0.792**

(16.953)

-0.001

(-0.136)

-0.010

(-1.119)

0.010

(1.474)

0.002

(0.248)

0.007

(0.857)

0.60

Denmark

0.016

(0.940)

0.143**

(2.273)

-0.032

(-0.993)

0.030

(0.805)

0.035

(0.728)

0.108***

(3.514)

-0.043

(-1.071)

0.07

France

0.198***

(8.894)

0.276***

(4.896)

0.117***

(3.393)

-0.050

(-1.078)

0.044

(0.844)

0.107**

(2.004)

0.034

(0.617)

0.16

Germany

0.003

(0.656)

0.962***

(61.884)

0.024**

(2.283)

0.002

(0.154)

-0.001

(-0.123)

-0.013

(-1.386)

0.005

(0.328)

0.94

Greece

-0.014***

(-4.879)

0.441***

(4.289)

-0.010*

(-1.664)

0.002

(0.670)

-0.001

(-0.227)

-0.011

(-1.499)

-0.001

(-0.232)

0.275

Hong Kong

0.005

(0.606)

0.712***

(14.060)

0.008

(0.368)

0.017

(0.747)

0.019

(0.865)

0.003

(0.110)

0.048**

(2.239)

0.563

Italy

0.266***

(10.360)

-0.255***

(-3.178)

0.076*

(1.722)

0.036

(0.854)

0.085

(1.555)

-0.019

(-0.319)

-0.114**

(-1.966)

0.13

Japan

-0.039**

(-2.506)

0.203***

(2.968)

0.043*

(1.765)

-0.053

(-1.528)

0.012

(0.288)

-0.055

(-1.563)

-0.012

(-0.424)

0.07

Netherland

0.007*

(2.606)

0.779***

(21.946)

-0.004

(-0.727)

-0.002

(-0.524)

0.010**

(2.111)

0.003

(0.802)

0.007

(1.889)

0.67

New Zealand 0.005 0.857*** -0.016 -0.002 0.006 0.015* 0.020 0.83

Page 186: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

165

(0.907) (27.718) (-1.201) (-0.335) (0.498) (1.713) (1.353)

Norway

-0.009

(-0.734)

0.832***

(15.443)

0.005

(0.286)

-0.031

(-1.124)

0.042

(1.391)

0.008

(0.245)

0.031

(1.146)

0.72

Portugal

-0.002

(-0.209)

0.812***

(9.693)

-0.011

(-0.827)

-0.007

(-0.399)

0.024*

(1.769)

-0.018

(-1.521)

0.000

(0.026)

0.75

Singapore

0.056***

(4.779)

0.733***

(14.361)

0.006

(0.427)

0.016

(1.109)

0.003

(0.239)

-0.011

(-0.654)

-0.004

(-0.200)

0.67

Spain

0.039***

(3.664)

0.809***

(16.711)

0.015

(0.410)

0.021

(0.921)

-0.048*

(-1.692)

0.014

(0.502)

-0.006

(-0.312)

0.70

Sweden

0.018***

(4.192)

0.859***

(40.043)

-0.002

(-0.513)

-0.001

(-0.244)

-0.003

(-0.614)

0.001

(0.180)

-0.008

(-1.154)

0.91

Switzerland

0.008*

(1.864)

0.854***

(16.149)

-0.006**

(-2.121)

-0.004

(-1.080)

0.002

(0.545)

-0.005

(-0.618)

0.010

(1.069)

0.89

UK

0.018***

(4.192)

0.859***

(40.043)

-0.002

(-0.513)

-0.001

(-0.244)

-0.003

(-0.614)

0.001

(0.180)

-0.008

(-1.154)

0.91

Panel B: Emerging and Frontier Markets

Country ki k Dcr Der Dip Dir Dms R2

China

0.161***

(5.185)

0.315***

(4.447)

-0.223**

(-2.402)

0.031

(0.580)

0.126***

(2.955)

-0.015

(-0.331)

-0.022

(-0.441)

0.18

India

0.009

(1.053)

0.907***

(28.699)

0.039*

(1.844)

0.006

(0.485)

0.029

(1.164)

-0.005

(-0.169)

-0.028

(-1.098)

0.856

Indonesia

-0.013

(-1.115)

0.662***

(14.585)

0.029

(0.898)

-0.022

(-0.844)

-0.025

(-0.983)

-0.005

(-0.173)

0.000

(-0.022)

0.47

Korea

-0.040

(-1.365)

0.347***

(6.152)

-0.145**

(-2.388)

0.006

(0.092)

0.017

(0.233)

-0.036

(-0.597)

-0.044

(-0.527)

0.14

Malaysia

0.029***

(0.007)

0.867***

(0.024)

-0.012*

(0.007)

0.009

(0.009)

-0.003

(0.007)

-0.002

(0.008)

0.004

(0.011)

0.86

Page 187: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

166

Pakistan

0.011**

(2.031)

0.689***

(16.645)

0.021*

(1.670)

-0.036**

(-2.320)

0.004

(0.293)

0.010

(0.814)

-0.020

(-1.527)

0.61

Philippines

0.072***

(5.822)

0.390***

(6.070)

0.045*

(1.729)

-0.004

(-0.110)

-0.036

(-0.719)

0.033

(1.339)

-0.018

(-0.654)

0.18

Sri Lanka

-0.008

(-0.909)

0.914***

(28.135)

-0.016

(-0.503)

0.031

(1.060)

0.016

(0.860)

0.021

(1.310)

-0.008

(-0.367)

0.84

Thailand

0.039***

(3.664)

0.809***

(16.711)

0.015

(0.410)

0.021

(0.921)

-0.048*

(-1.692)

0.014

(0.502)

-0.006

(-0.312)

0.70

Turkey

-0.008

(-0.909)

0.914***

(28.135)

-0.016

(-0.503)

0.031

(1.060)

0.016

(0.860)

0.021

(1.310)

-0.008

(-0.367)

0.84

***indicate statistical significance at 1%. **Indicate statistical significance at 5%. *Indicate statistical significance at 10%.

Impact of Macroeconomic Shocks on Cross-Correlation of herding behavior

This regression analysis aims to investigate the impact of macroeconomic shock in one of

the developing, emerging and frontier markets on the pairwise correlation coefficient of herding

measures. Minimum acceptance criteria is selected at 10% in line with the herding literature.

Chiang et al. (2007) argued that public news in one market can be regarded as information for the

rest of the markets in a region due to herding behavior. Therefore, if the markets are highly

integrated with each other the effect of herding contagion can be more intense in magnitude. In

this section of the study contagion of herding due to macroeconomic shock is discussed.

Panel A of the table 4.16 presents the results of macroeconomic shocks on correlated

behavior of developed markets with US. It is observed that only in Australian market exchange

rate shock have significant negative effect of 8.4% on investors herding behavior. It is generally

believed that if investors are uncertain about the fluctuations in exchange rates, they normally sell

the currency that could lead to a crisis situation not driven by the fundamental value (Obstfeld,

1986). Imperfections in the market can also imbalance the fundamental values (McKinnon & Pill,

Page 188: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

167

1997). Cho et al. (2016) discuss that the reaction of developed and emerging market is different to

the changes in exchange rates along with different market conditions. When there is downturn in

global market capital flow is directed towards developed markets from the developing markets,

that generate a positive correlation of stock returns and exchange rates in emerging markets,

however negative effect on the developed markets. Markets follow same trend in up markets.

The effect of interest rate shock is more obvious in most of the markets, like Australia,

Austria, Denmark, France and New Zealand. Except Australian market, it is evident that all

markets exhibit positive interest rate shocks on correlation between herding measures. The interest

rate shock is linked to the financial markets. Frankel & Rose (1996) examine the role of interest

rate in determining the financial crisis. Klein (2013) investigates the significant impact of short

term rates, term spread and first difference of on the dispersion of stock returns during spillovers

from US market to other markets. During spillover they find significant effect of interest rates,

however without spillover these variables reduce the dispersion of returns. It means that in the

time of volatility investors combine the macroeconomic information with their risk perception and

react accordingly. This view can be justified by the “Wake up call hypothesis”. According to this

hypothesis, in the event of crisis the investors in other markets reevaluate their investment risk

with similar market fundamentals. Due to the fear of facing similar conditions they overreact and

spread instability that has a contagion effect spread in other markets. This effect can be related to

the evidence of positive significant coefficient of interest rates in this study.

In case of money supply this study observes that in almost all markets, money supply shock

has insignificant effect on herding behavior. This money supply shock can be translated in to the

monetary policy shock as discussed previously in section 4.6. Only Hong Kong markets exhibit

significant effect of herding correlation with opposite signs at 5% significance level. It is argued

Page 189: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

168

that contractionary monetary policy shock increases the herding behavior in an market, while

expansionary policy has displayed anti herding behavior of an investor (Gong & Dai, 2017).

Similarly, effect of industrial production shocks are also observed on herding correlation between

the US and respective countries in the sample, Australian, Netherland and Portuguese markets

exhibit the positive effect of industrial production shocks on herding correlation.

Panel B provides the results of macro-economic shocks on the correlation of US and other

emerging and frontier markets macroeconomic shocks. It is observed that except few most of the

macro economic shocks in almost all markets have no impact on the correlation of herding

measures of certain markets. Several authors argued that contagion in herding is principally caused

by the behavioral factors and that are independent of the economic fundamentals (Khan & Park,

2009)

It is observed that correlation of herding measure between US, Pakistan and US, Taiwan

is affected by the shock in exchange rates against US dollar. Lin (2012) investigates the co-

movement of stock returns and exchange rates in a set of emerging market industries. They observe

weak correlation in export oriented societies and find the contribution of capital account flows as

a channel between exchange rate fluctuation and stock returns. Generally depreciation in local

currency is perceived as a “bad news” in emerging markets and benefit is taken by currency

appreciation due to capital inflow in these markets as discussed by Cho et al. (2016).

In Chinese and Thai markets herding correlation with US is affected by the shocks in

industrial production. It is observed that Chinese shock impact have positive effect on correlation

in herding measure. In the specific time period Chinese market faced a decline in industrial

production. Whereas shock in Thai market has negative effect on correlation of herding measure.

Bekaert, et al. (2014) finds significant effect of US market contagion on manufacturing and

Page 190: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

169

production sector. They argued that usually external crisis has minimal effect on investor behavior,

instead local investors usually focused on domestic factors and react adversely due to poor

macroeconomic fundamentals, and weak regulatory structures.

In general it is observed that more integrated markets exhibit more intense effect of herding

contagion. The volatility spillovers in one market can generates contagion effect in other markets

due to investor behavior, this behavioral impact generate speculations that have impact across the

markets. In general certain macroeconomic shocks specifically in developed markets exhibit

significant effect on herding correlation, these results are consistent with the findings of Mylonidis

& Kollias (2010). The results of the study indicate that correlation between herding measure can

provide an incentive of portfolio diversification to investors. The significance of certain

macroeconomic shocks validate the hypothesis that Macroeconomic uncertainty and crisis shocks

have significant effect on herding behavior, but this effect is observed in a limited set of economies.

These findings can be related to the wake-up call hypothesis where similarities are observed in

two markets if any crisis event or a specific shock hits the market (Chiang et al., 2007). These

findings meet the objectives that not only the turbulent situation but also the unexpected

components of macroeconomic information has significant effect on the inefficient behavior of

market participants in stock markets.

Page 191: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

170

Chapter 5

5. Conclusion

Summary and Findings

The basic purpose of this research is to investigate herding behavior, the role of culture and

macroeconomic shocks on herding behavior, and the existence of contagion of herding due to the

crisis and macroeconomic shocks in the market. This study investigates herding behavior towards

market consensus in a set of Developed, Emerging and Frontier Markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and

Europe. In general, this study employed data on daily and monthly frequency from a period of

varying starting dates (depends on the data availability) to December 2015. For the identification

of herding behavior towards market consensus, this study employs return dispersion models

proposed by Christie & Huang (1995), Chang et al. (2000), and Chiang & Zheng (2010) and the

state space model of Hwang & Salmon (2004). In order to meet few objective return dispersion

models are used over a time of varying frequencies. For some fundamental based objectives state

space model is used, due to the nature and requirement of analysis.

The findings of the study suggest that during the period of extreme stress equity return

dispersion increases rather than decreasing. These outcomes are consistent with the prediction of

CAPM as the rational asset pricing models state that equity return dispersion increases during the

turbulent period. Christie & Huang (1995) model similar to previous literature fails to capture

herding in extreme stress in any of the markets under observation. This model faces certain

criticism, therefore, this study employed two other models to test herding behavior.

The second model is nonlinear return dispersion model proposed by Chang et al. (2000)

and Chiang & Zheng (2010). The findings based on these models report significant herding

Page 192: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

171

behavior in majority of markets. It is observed that all developed markets except Australia,

Belgium, and France exhibit herding behavior when (using Chang et al. (2000model. By

setting Chiang & Zheng, 2010), the French market also exhibits herding behavior along

with other markets in the sample. However, the presence of herding is observed in all emerging

and frontier markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe. These findings are consistent with previous

studies as herding is more likely to be present in emerging and developing markets (Demirer &

Kutan, 2006).

The evidence of strong herding in developing markets can be due to certain market

characteristics including weak regulatory system, immature financial system, control of market in

the hands of few institutional investors, the existence of speculators, and transmission of highly

volatile capital flows from international markets (Economou et al., 2000). As rational asset pricing

model assumes a linear relationship between returns that is why Christie & Huang (1995) model

is unable to capture herding in extreme market returns. In the presence of herding relationship of

returns and cross-sectional dispersion becomes nonlinear, Chang et al. (2000) and Chiang & Zheng

(2010) include the nonlinear term in the model. That is why this measure provides better results in

most of the markets.

One of the main objectives of this research is to determine the role of culture in driving

herding behavior. This study employs Hofstede’s six cultural dimensions of culture and introduces

them as modulating variables in the Chiang et al. (2000) and Chiang & Zheng (2000) model. It is

observed that power distance and uncertainty avoidance has no impact on herding behavior of

investor, however individualism, masculinity, and indulgence influence the relationship between

nonlinear returns and market dispersion. In the presence of long-term orientation, herding

coefficient becomes insignificant, slope dummy of interacting term decreases the dispersion of

Page 193: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

172

returns. The effect of these factors can be analyzed from different aspects, first, investor relation

to rational opportunistic behavior. Second, herding is seen as a way to learn from psychological

forces in the market (less importance of fundamentals). Third, another strong relation exists

between herding and cost of getting information. In addition to these many influences, the cultural

dimension of individualism, masculinity, and indulgence also appeared to contribute to a better

understanding of herding behavior of individual investors.

Previous literature provides ample evidence on the use of a constant coefficient model of

return dispersion. Research on time variation of herding behavior in return dispersion model is

very limited. This study uses Kalman filter for the estimation of time-varying herding behavior

through return dispersion in a large sample of markets, including developed, emerging and frontier

markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe. The impact of domestic and cross-border determinants

on time series herding behavior is also observed. This study detects time variation of herding

behavior in all emerging markets and majority of the developed markets. Like Belgium, France,

New Zealand, Singapore and Switzerland exhibit time-invariant herding behavior. Therefore, it

can be concluded that developed and developing markets provide support to the hypothesis of

time-variant herding phenomenon, not a short-term disequilibrium. This time variation is mainly

dependent upon the stock market functionality and presence of volatility in the market. The role

of stock market performance, domestic and global volatility cannot be neglected in the

determination of time variation of herding behavior. Herding behavior is more pronounced in

periods of high volatility and lagged value of global volatility provides similar results as domestic

volatility.

The second line of the methodology adopted is state space model of herding behavior.

Herding towards market portfolio is identified through this model. Hwang & Salmon (2004) argue

Page 194: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

173

that the state space model of cross-sectional beta dispersion provide a better measure. This measure

is based on the cross-sectional dispersion of betas, therefore conditioned on fundamental and other

factors in the market. The outcomes of this measure provide better results among all of the markets

as the market dynamics are properly captured. All countries in the sample except Sri Lanka exhibit

herding behavior around market portfolio and particularly in stress. The Graphs from the herding

evolution validate the observation because herding evolution is observed in rising and falling

markets. The major crisis in the sample is a Global financial crisis. One can observe that a

significant reaction of all market participants of developed and emerging markets said to have

affected by this event and can be seen as sharp spikes and turning points in the herding behavior.

Therefore, Hwang & Salmon (2004) model provides a comprehensive analysis of dynamics of

herding spotted from both estimation results and time series of herding evolution. According to

these results, Sri Lanka is the only market in the region where the full benefit of portfolio

diversification can be enjoyed.

The role of a macroeconomic factor helps in understanding the market structure and

mechanism. Herding behavior is the deviation of the market from its fundamental structure,

therefore unexpected variation in macroeconomic variables can help to understand the investors

herding behavior. For this purpose ARIMA residuals are incorporated in Hwang & Salmon (2004)

model to figure out the effect of unexpected shocks on a macroeconomic variable on investor

herding behavior. It is generally observed that macroeconomic fundamentals itself do not explain

herding behavior of an investor (Hwang & Salmon, 2004) but the unexpected variations in these

variables can contribute to irrational investor behavior (Messis & Zapranis , 2014). In majority of

the markets macroeconomic shocks provide insignificant effect but in few cases, one or two of the

four variables have significant effect on herding behavior of an investor. In some cases, the

Page 195: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

174

inclusion of Macroeconomic shocks affects the intensity of herding behavior that can be observed

through the changed value of herding Coefficient. Therefore, it can be concluded that not

macroeconomic variable itself, but the unexpected variation in macroeconomic components

influence the herding behavior of an investor in few markets.

In the era of globalization and internationalization, along with fundamental, trade and other

linkages between the market participants cannot be explained without describing the behavioral

impact of the decision-making process. According to the literature, other than fundamental and

common cause linkages certain behavioral factors play a vital role in the transmission mechanism

of volatility and crisis (Chiang et al., 2007). This study focuses on the behavioral link namely

contagion of herding (pure contagion) in a given set of markets and determines the cross country

linkages of each market with a global leader (US) through extreme shocks in macroeconomic

components or crisis. For the said purpose conditional correlation between herding measures is

generated through diagonal VECH bivariate GARCH (1,1) model. In order to assess the factors

contributing to this correlation, OLS regression is used to employ the dummy variables of extreme

shock due to macroeconomic news and due to the common global financial crisis on the

conditional correlation series for each country under analysis (having significant herding

behavior).

In general, it is observed that more integrated markets exhibit the more intense effect of

herding contagion. The volatility spillovers in one market can generate contagion effect in other

markets due to investor behavior, this behavioral impact generates speculations that have an impact

on the markets. In general certain macroeconomic shocks and financial crisis specifically in

developed markets exhibit a significant effect on herding correlation, these results are consistent

with the findings of Mylonidis & Kollias (2010). These outcomes can be related to the wake-up

Page 196: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

175

call hypothesis where similarities are observed in two markets if any crisis event or a specific

shock hits the market (Chiang et al., 2007). These findings provide interesting insight, as the

shocks itself do not exhibit significant effect on a herding behavior of investor in local markets but

have significant impact on the correlation of herding series with US market. Therefore, it can be

concluded that if there is contagion of herding in from one economy to another, then fundamental

and crisis shocks both contribute to irrationality of investor behavior in target market.

Discussion

In this section this study focusses on the main contribution of the study and discuss that to how

much extent the cultural differences and adverse macroeconomic conditions affect the herding

intensity of an investor in a global context.

The herding behavior affected by the degree of individualism, which has direct

implications for the stock market pricing and market efficiency. In individualist societies usually

investors exhibit less herding behavior but these characteristics can be analyzed in different ways.

Usually some rational component of herding behavior trigger the whole market mimetic actions

and predecessors follows the actions of market players. This behavior is obvious when investors

give more weightage to psychological forces rather than market fundamentals. Other than these

problems information disadvantage, personal experience and reputation concerns defined in to

career steps also matters. Therefore, one can say that individualist behavior can be a cause of

cultural differences. However, the change in behavior is complex to understand as other factors

also contribute like the type of financial system and its degree of development, the surrounding

Page 197: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

176

information and the regulatory framework. Therefore, the herding behavior of investor cannot be

easily understandable solely in cultural environment.

Masculinity and indulgence have direct influence on the strategic investment decision and

behavior. It can be argued that Individuals in highly indulged societies exhibit weak control over

desires, whereas societies with a low level of indulgence control their urges strongly. These

findings suggest that masculinity and indulgence has important implication for herding in stock

market as the markets characterized by these dimension indicate competition, achievement and

success. These characteristics are supposed to reduce herding but in practice promote more intense

herding behavior in the market. These findings can be explained with reference to reputational

concern of herding behavior where investor in order to maintain its reputation follow the practices

of bench mark while making investment strategies and decisions.

Moreover in masculine societies there are more men than women and hold overrepresentation in

leading position in asset management. Males are more aggressive and less risk averse and

characterized by overconfidence. These characteristics give rise to more aggressive investment

styles where other investors in the market due to lack of information and high cost of obtaining

relevant information follows the market consensus to maintain their reputation.

Along with the cultural variables, Global as well as domestic market volatility are observed to be

significant determinants of the time-varying herding behavior in almost all developed, emerging

and frontier markets. It is observed that the role of global factors specifically the U.S. market–

related factor, CBOT volatility index (VIX) dominate the time variation in herding behavior

Page 198: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

177

specifically in emerging and frontier markets and this behavior is more obvious during the global

financial crisis of 2008. Therefore, has major implication for market efficiency under the financial

crisis. This suggests that market stress in the United States not only harvested by the investor of

other developed, emerging and frontier markets but also have behavioral implication. The herding

behavior of the investor show strong correlation with US market and this behavior has contagious

effect that is more intense during adverse macro environment and crisis situation.

Methodological Implications and limitation

In order to observe the best measure to capture the herding towards market consensus

towards the market, this study employs all three models available Christie & Huang (1995), Chang

et al. (2000), and Chiang & Zheng (2010) and the state space model of Hwang & Salmon (2004).

As rational asset pricing model assumes a linear relationship between returns that is why Christie

& Huang (1995) model based on CAPM is unable to capture herding in extreme market returns.

In the presence of herding relationship of returns and cross-sectional dispersion becomes

nonlinear, Chang et al. (2000) and Chiang & Zheng (2010) include the nonlinear term in the model.

The results provide comparatively better outcomes than Christie & Huang (1995).

It is observed that herding appears during a crisis period and disappears after giving a flight

to the fundamentals of the market. The first model only observes it under extreme stress while the

second class of return dispersion models negates the effect of fundamentals and other factors. The

return dispersion model fails to capture this characteristic of the market. Therefore, this study

employs Hwang & Salmon (2004) model to address these shortcomings. Hwang & Salmon (2004)

not only conditioned on fundamental and other factors but it also incorporates the effect of time

Page 199: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

178

series volatility. This is the reason, out of all three measures this model has strong theoretical

properties and provide better empirical results.

This study provides an additional insight into the existing literature by examining the best

model to identify the herding behavior of an investor in dynamic settings. It is observed that model

based on the state space model better predicts the time variation of herding behavior as the value

of AIC and BIC are lower as compared to return dispersion models.

In order to capture unexpected component this study employed ARIMA models to generate

residuals of macroeconomic structure over GARCH methodology. According to literature, these

models are appropriate for forecasting and provide better results than over parametrized models.

Generalizability

The results of this study are generalizable as it uses a large dataset of sampled countries that

include developed, emerging and frontier markets of Asia, Asia Pacific and Europe. The market

participants of other markets not included in the data set sharing similar culture similarities or

market dynamic can use this research as a benchmark for their decision-making process. The

generalizability of this study is further supported by the use of larger data set. In this time period

history of the global economy shared several events that have common effects around the globe.

Therefore, in the wake of an uncertain event in future, this research can be used to understand the

market dynamics collectively.

Theoretical Implications

This study has some theoretical contributions for academicians. They are listed below.

Page 200: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

179

For Risk Diversification

The traditional relationship between risk and return explained by the Capital Asset Pricing

Model provides the basis for understanding the dynamics of herding behavior on risk

diversification. Chiang & Zheng (2010) stated that herd behavior describes the increased

correlation in trades due to the interaction of investors in stock market. So, in the presence of

herding behavior, a large number of securities are required in a portfolio to achieve the same level

of diversification due to the existence of an inferior degree of correlation. Herding has negative

implications in portfolio diversification, if there is a strong co-movement between stocks, the

benefit of diversification is eliminated as the stock prices tend to move in unison. This study

indicates that a large number of markets in the sample exhibit herding behavior and some of the

markets exhibit a strong correlation in herding measures. Therefore, it can be implied that investing

in these markets prevent the investor from enjoying the full benefit of diversification and their risk

increases.

For Behavioral Asset Pricing Model

The risk involved in the pricing of investment under the current scenario has both

fundamental and behavioral components. Therefore, it is deemed necessary to incorporate

behavioral factors like herding while modeling the asset prices. As this research validates the effect

of herding behavior and its consequences on securities returns, therefore new asset pricing models

suggested by several authors should be utilized. For example, the behavioral asset pricing theory

proposed by Shefrin and Statman(1994), affects behavioral asset pricing model by Statman, et al.

(2008) and investor psychology in Hirshleifer (2001). By improving the information disclosure

trading activity of investors can be improved. This informational efficiency minimizes the risk of

Page 201: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

180

securities as prices are determined on the basis of fundamentals. Better knowledge of market

dynamics and clear understanding of factors behind irrational behavior could result in more

accurate valuation, estimation, and forecasting decisions.

For Behavioral Portfolio Management

In Behavioral finance irrationality of investors can be explained in several ways and several

psychological factors give rise to investor portfolio diversity (Shum & Faig 2006). Heterogeneity

in beliefs can be an outcome of intrinsic differences (He & Shi 2010). In a situation of high

uncertainty and complexity investors usually, ignore fundamental information and rely on their

intuitions (Kahneman & Riepe 1998). These intuitions give rise to several systematic errors and

correlated behavior in markets where investors overestimate their knowledge and underestimate

risk and are unable to control events (Giordani & Söderlind, 2006).

Professional portfolio managers can use this study to make better strategies and funds that

are behaviorally centered. Along with behavioral approach, they can also incorporate the effect of

social influences like national culture. Policymakers should focus on the communications channel

with financial markets and manage the prospects of fluctuations in policy because herding can

aggravate in financial market due to change in macro information.

Policy and Practical Implication

This study has several practical implications for practitioners and policymakers. Few are listed

below

For Individual Investors

With the emergence of behavioral finance, few governments are designing a vast range of

programs to provide economic and financial education to the individual investors and general

public. The basic purpose is to educate those individuals who are practically omitted from the

Page 202: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

181

formal financial sector. They practically lack financial knowledge and make poor investment

decisions. If these investment decisions are influenced by the herd formation, these can lead to a

huge disturbance in the financial markets. Few researchers estimate the effect of such program on

consequent financial behaviors (Lusardi, 2008; Lyons, 2010). Therefore, if the government of less

sophisticated markets particularly emerging and frontier markets provide financial education to

the investors the problem of irrational decision making can be resolved to reduce the impact of

speculators in the market.

For Institutional Investors

Institutional investors and particularly fund managers can get benefit from this study. As

origin, cause and effect of behavioral factor like herding could be utilized to device investment

analysis and related management strategies to implement certain decisions under the positive or

negative environment under the effect of this bias. Shefrin (2000), and Montier (2002) stress on

the utilization of behavioral biases in investment analysis to overcome the consequence

inefficiency and fragility of the financial system. The strategies devices by Baker & Riccardi

(2014) can be utilized to get the full benefit of optimal decision making.

For International Investors

This research has implication not only for the local investor but also for the international

investor. If the herding measures are correlated between two markets especially global leaders then

the benefit of portfolio diversification is reduced as the same risk factors are transmitted across the

markets due to volatility spillovers or contagion of herding. The results indicate that correlation

between herding measure can provide an incentive for portfolio diversification to investors.

Page 203: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

182

For Financial Market Regulators

This paper has highlighted one of the behavioral risk (herding behavior) stressed in Daniel

Hirshleifer & Teoh (2003). They suggest two steps to improve the public policy, one is designing

of such policies that can minimize the errors and second is to improve the efficiency of the market.

Thus, the regulation of this risk factor will reduce the impact of irrational behavior and market

imperfection. Similarly, Suto & Toshino (2005) stress the need for governance of financial markets

against the behavioral risk factors. Asian markets are more vulnerable to sociological and

psychological inclinations as suggested by the (Kim & Nofsinger, 2007). Therefore, there is a need

to frame the financial regulation under the fund management industries in the markets of Asia. In

the era of globalization and transmission of shocks through behavioral channels has been validated

through this study, therefore there is an immense need to design global governance framework that

will help the international investors to play safely in the global financial market.

Limitations of the Study

The first limitation of this research is the identification of irrational herding of individual

herding particularly towards market consensus. The rational herding normally done by the

institutional investor is completely ignored due to data limitations.

Another limitation of this research is an inability to differentiate between spurious and

intentional herding in the stock market.

Herding behavior in the stock markets specifically in developing market is driven mostly

by the financial analyst (Graham, 1999; Welch, 2000). They contribute to making an

informational cascade which is thus followed by the individual investors. This type of

herding is also not captured in this study.

Page 204: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

183

Future Recommendations

Future research can examine other macro information on herding and further distinguish

between spurious herding and intentional herding in the stock market.

The institutional investors, specifically asset managers have a strong influence on the

herding behavior, particularly, when herding is caused by the informational cascade. It may

be interesting to incorporate their view and behavior to check the robustness of this analysis

specifically with reference to cultural dimensions.

It can be beneficial in the market to understand the interaction between investor types.

Different type of investors share different set of information like individual and

institutional investors, domestic and foreign investors and their reaction in the market can

also be different.

The results from this research validate the effect of time variation in herding behavior but

literature is limited to few markets. Future research can identify the factors behind these

time dynamic specifically in a large set of emerging market around the globe.

There is useful evidence that cultural differences cause different behavior, yet the way how

behavior is changed may be complex. It may be useful to incorporate further factors such

as the type of financial system and its degree of development, the information surrounding

it, or the regulatory framework to get a more comprehensive picture of investor behavior.

This research can be extended to the other markets of the economy also, like real estate,

commodity markets, and currency market. These all markets play important role in the

economy.

Page 205: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

184

References

Abdalla, I. S., & Murinde, V. (1997). Exchange rate and stock price interactions in emerging

financial markets: evidence on India, Korea, Pakistan and the Philippines. Applied

financial economics, 7(1), 25-35.

Ackert, L., & Deaves, R. (2009). Behavioral Finance: Psychology, decision-making, and markets:

Cengage Learning.

Aggarwal, R. (2014). Animal spirits in financial economics: A review of deviations from economic

rationality. International Review of Financial Analysis, 32, 179-187.

Ahmad, Z., Ahmad, Z., Ibrahim, H., Ibrahim, H., Tuyon, J., & Tuyon, J. (2017). Institutional

investor behavioral biases: syntheses of theory and evidence. Management Research

Review, 40(5), 578-603.

Ahmad, Z., Ibrahim, H., & Tuyon, J. (2017). Institutional investor behavioral biases: syntheses of

theory and evidence. Management Research Review, 40(5).

Aizenman, J., Jinjarak, Y., & Park, D. (2016). Fundamentals and Sovereign Risk of Emerging

Markets. Pacific Economic Review, 21(2), 151-177. doi: 10.1111/1468-0106.12160

Akaike, H. (1998). Information theory and an extension of the maximum likelihood principle

Selected papers of hirotugu akaike (pp. 199-213): Springer.

Allen, F., & Gale, D. (2000). Financial contagion. Journal of Political Economy, 108(1), 1-33.

Allen, F., & Gale, D. (2007). Systemic risk and regulation The risks of financial institutions (pp.

341-376): University of Chicago Press.

Alós-Ferrer, C., & Strack, F. (2014). From dual processes to multiple selves: Implications for

economic behavior. Journal of Economic Psychology, 41, 1-11.

Page 206: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

185

Anderson, C. W., Fedenia, M., Hirschey, M., & Skiba, H. (2011). Cultural influences on home

bias and international diversification by institutional investors. Journal of Banking &

Finance, 35(4), 916-934.

Asteriou, D., & Hall, S. G. (2007). Applied Econometrics: A Modern Approach Using Eviews and

Microfit Revised Edition: Palgrave Macmillan.

Avery, C., & Zemsky, P. (1998). Multidimensional uncertainty and herd behavior in financial

markets. American economic review, 724-748.

Bachelier, L. (1900). Théorie de la spéculation: Gauthier-Villars.

Bachmann, R., Elstner, S., & Sims, E. R. (2013). Uncertainty and economic activity: Evidence

from business survey data. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5(2), 217-249.

Baddeley, M., Burke, C., Schultz, W., & Tobler, P. (2010). Impacts of Personality on Herding in

Financial Decision-Making: Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge.

Bailey, W., Cai, J., Cheung, Y. L., & Wang, F. (2009). Stock returns, order imbalances, and

commonality: Evidence on individual, institutional, and proprietary investors in China.

Journal of Banking & Finance, 33(1), 9-19.

Baker, H. K., & Ricciardi, V. (2014). How biases affect investor behaviour.

Ball, R. (1978). Anomalies in relationships between securities' yields and yield-surrogates. Journal

of financial economics, 6(2), 103-126.

Ball, R. (2009). The global financial crisis and the efficient market hypothesis: what have we

learned? Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 21(4), 8-16.

Banerjee, A. V. (1992). A simple model of herd behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,

797-817.

Page 207: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

186

Barber, B. M., & Odean, T. (1999). The courage of misguided convictions. Financial Analysts

Journal, 55(6), 41-55.

Barberis, N. C. (2013). Thirty years of prospect theory in economics: A review and assessment.

The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27(1), 173-195.

Barberis, N., & Thaler, R. (2003). A survey of behavioral finance. Handbook of the Economics of

Finance, 1, 1053-1128.

Beckmann, D., Menkhoff, L., & Suto, M. (2008). Do culture influence asset managers’ views and

behavior? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 67(3), 624-643.

Beirne, J., & Fratzscher, M. (2013). The pricing of sovereign risk and contagion during the

European sovereign debt crisis. Journal of International Money and Finance, 34, 60-82.

Beja, A., & Goldman, M. B. (1980). On the dynamic behavior of prices in disequilibrium. The

Journal of Finance, 35(2), 235-248.

Bekaert, G., Ehrmann, M., Fratzscher, M., & Mehl, A. (2014). The global crisis and equity market

contagion. The Journal of Finance, 69(6), 2597-2649.

Bekaert, G., & Harvey, C. R. (1995). Time‐varying world market integration. The Journal of

Finance, 50(2), 403-444.

Bekaert, G., & Wu, G. (2000). Asymmetric volatility and risk in equity markets. Review of

financial studies, 13(1), 1-42.

Belgacem, A., & Lahiani, A. (2013). Herding behavior around US macroeconomic

announcements. Journal of Applied Business Research, 29(5), 1401–1410.

Berlin, H. A. (2011). The neural basis of the dynamic unconscious. Neuropsychoanalysis, 13(1),

5-31.

Page 208: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

187

Bernanke, B. S., & Kuttner, K. N. (2005). What explains the stock market's reaction to Federal

Reserve policy? The Journal of Finance, 60(3), 1221-1257.

Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D., & Welch, I. (1992). A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and

cultural change as informational cascades. Journal of Political Economy, 992-1026.

Bikhchandani, S., & Sharma, S. (2000). Herd behavior in financial markets. IMF Staff Papers,

279-310.

Black, F. (1972). Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing. Journal of Business, 444-

455.

Blasco, N., Corredor, P., & Ferreruela, S. Can agents sensitive to cultural, organizational and

environmental issues avoid herding? Finance Research Letters. doi:

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.frl.2017.01.006

Blasco, N., Corredor, P., & Ferreruela, S. (2012). Does herding affect volatility? Implications for

the Spanish stock market. Quantitative Finance, 12(2), 311-327.

Bloom, N. (2009). The impact of uncertainty shocks. Econometrica, 77(3), 623-685.

Bloom, N. (2014). Fluctuations in uncertainty. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28(2), 153-

175.

Bollerslev, T. (1986). Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity. Journal of

Econometrics, 31(3), 307-327.

Bollinger, J. (2005). Combining Technical and Fundamental Analysis. Paper presented at the CFA

Institute Conference Proceedings.

Bondt, W. F., & Thaler, R. (1985). Does the stock market overreact? The Journal of Finance,

40(3), 793-805.

Page 209: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

188

Box, G. E., & Tiao, G. C. (1975). Intervention analysis with applications to economic and

environmental problems. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 70(349), 70-79.

Brabazon, T. (2000). Behavioural Finance: A new sunrise or a false dawn? 28th August.

Brahmana, R. K., Hooy, C.-W., & Ahmad, Z. (2012). Weather, investor irrationality and day-of-

the-week anomaly: case of Indonesia. Journal of Bioeconomics, 14(2), 129-146.

Brealey, R. A., Myers, S. C., Allen, F., & Mohanty, P. (2012). Principles of corporate finance:

Tata McGraw-Hill Education.

Breuer, W., Riesener, M., & Salzmann, A. J. (2014). Risk aversion vs. individualism: what drives

risk taking in household finance? The European Journal of Finance, 20(5), 446-462.

Breuer, W., & Quinten, B. (2009). Cultural finance. Available at SSRN 1282068.

Brown, N. C., Wei, K. D., & Wermers, R. (2013). Analyst recommendations, mutual fund herding,

and overreaction in stock prices. Management Science, 60(1), 1-20.

Bruner, J. (1990). Culture and human development: A new look. Human development, 33(6), 344-

355.

Brunnermeier, M. K. (2001). Asset pricing under asymmetric information: Bubbles, crashes,

technical analysis, and herding: Oxford University Press on Demand.

Brunnermeier, M. K., & Pedersen, L. H. (2009). Market liquidity and funding liquidity. Review of

financial studies, 22(6), 2201-2238.

Burton, E., & Shah, S. (2013). Behavioral finance: understanding the social, cognitive, and

economic debates: John Wiley & Sons.

Page 210: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

189

Butler, K. C., & Joaquin, D. C. (2002). Are the gains from international portfolio diversification

exaggerated? The influence of downside risk in bear markets. Journal of International

Money and Finance, 21(7), 981-1011.

Cajueiro, D. O., & Tabak, B. M. (2009). Multifractality and herding behavior in the Japanese stock

market. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals, 40(1), 497-504.

Calvo, G. A., & Mendoza, E. G. (2000). Rational contagion and the globalization of securities

markets. Journal of International Economics, 51(1), 79-113.

Calvo, S. G., & Reinhart, C. M. (1996). Capital flows to Latin America: is there evidence of

contagion effects? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper(1619).

Campbell, J. Y. (2000). Asset pricing at the millennium. The Journal of Finance, 55(4), 1515-

1567.

Caparrelli, F., D'Arcangelis, A. M., & Cassuto, A. (2004). Herding in the Italian stock market: a

case of behavioral finance. The Journal of Behavioral Finance, 5(4), 222-230.

Case, K. E. (2000). Real estate and the macroeconomy. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,

20, 119–162.

Caporale, G. M., Economou, F., & Philippas, N. (2008). Herd behavior in extreme market

conditions: The case of the Athens stock exchange.

Catte, P., Girouard, N., Price, R., & André, C. (2004). Housing markets, wealth and the business

cycle. OECD Working Paper No. 394.

Chandar, N., Patro, D. K., & Yezegel, A. (2009). Crises, contagion, and cross-listings. Journal of

Banking & Finance, 33(9), 1709-1729.

Page 211: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

190

Chang, C.-H., & Lin, S.-J. (2015). The effects of national culture and behavioral pitfalls on

investors' decision-making: Herding behavior in international stock markets. International

Review of Economics & Finance, 37, 380-392.

Chang, E. C., Cheng, J. W., & Khorana, A. (2000). An examination of herd behavior in equity

markets: An international perspective. Journal of Banking & Finance, 24(10), 1651-1679.

Chang, E. C., & Dong, S. (2006). Idiosyncratic volatility, fundamentals, and institutional herding:

Evidence from the Japanese stock market. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 14(2), 135-154.

Chang, R., & Velasco, A. (2001). A model of financial crises in emerging markets. The Quarterly

Journal of Economics, 116(2), 489-517.

Chari, V. V., & Kehoe, P. J. (2004). Financial crises as herds: overturning the critiques. Journal

of Economic Theory, 119(1), 128-150.

Chen, J.-H., & Diaz, J. F. (2012). Spillover and asymmetric-volatility effects of leveraged and

inverse leveraged exchange-traded funds. Journal of Business and Policy Research, 7(3),

1-10.

Chen, T. (2013). Do investors herd in global stock markets? Journal of Behavioral Finance, 14(3),

230-239.

Chiang, T. C., Jeon, B. N., & Li, H. (2007). Dynamic correlation analysis of financial contagion:

Evidence from Asian markets. Journal of International Money and Finance, 26(7), 1206-

1228.

Chiang, T. C., & Zheng, D. (2010). An empirical analysis of herd behavior in global stock markets.

Journal of Banking & Finance, 34(8), 1911-1921.

Chiang, T. C., Li, J., Tan, L., & Nelling, E. (2013). Dynamic herding behavior in Pacific-Basin

markets : Evidence and implications. Multinational Finance Journal, 17(3/4), 165–200.

Page 212: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

191

Chiras, D. P., & Manaster, S. (1978). The information content of option prices and a test of market

efficiency. Journal of financial economics, 6(2), 213-234.

Cho, J.-W., Choi, J. H., Kim, T., & Kim, W. (2016). Flight-to-quality and correlation between

currency and stock returns. Journal of Banking & Finance, 62, 191-212.

Choe, H., Kho, B.-C., & Stulz, R. M. (1999). Do foreign investors destabilize stock markets? The

Korean experience in 1997. Journal of financial economics, 54(2), 227-264.

Choi, N., & Sias, R. W. (2009). Institutional industry herding. Journal of financial economics,

94(3), 469-491.

Christie, W. G., & Huang, R. D. (1995). Following the pied piper: Do individual returns herd

around the market? Financial Analysts Journal, 51(4), 31-37.

Chui, A. C., & Kwok, C. C. (1998). Cross‐Autocorrelation Between A Shares And B Shares In

The Chinese Stock Market. Journal of financial research, 21(3), 333-353.

Chui, A. C., Titman, S., & Wei, K. J. (2010). Individualism and momentum around the world. The

Journal of Finance, 65(1), 361-392.

Cialdini, R. B., & Goldstein, N. J. (2004). Social influence: Compliance and conformity. Annu.

Rev. Psychol., 55, 591-621.

Cohen, K. J. (1966). [The Random Character of Stock Market Prices., Paul H. Cootner]. The

Journal of Business, 39(4), 532-535.

Corsetti, G., Pericoli, M., & Sbracia, M. (2011). Correlation analysis of financial contagion.

Financial contagion: the viral threat to the wealth of nations, 604, 11.

Page 213: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

192

Coudert, V., & Gex, M. (2010). The credit default swap market and the settlement of large defaults.

International Economics, 123, 91-120. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/S2110-

7017(13)60015-3

Cuthbertson, K., Nitzsche, D., & O'Sullivan, N. (2016). A review of behavioural and management

effects in mutual fund performance. International Review of Financial Analysis, 44, 162-

176.

Das, T., & Teng, B. S. (1999). Cognitive biases and strategic decision processes: An integrative

perspective. Journal of Management Studies, 36(6), 757-778.

De Bondt, W. F. (1991). What do economists know about the stock market. Journal of Portfolio

Management, 17(2), 84-91.

De Bondt, W. F. (1995). Investor psychology and the dynamics of security prices. Paper presented

at the AIMR Conference Proceedings.

De Bondt, W. F. (1998). A portrait of the individual investor. European economic review, 42(3),

831-844.

De Martino, B., O’Doherty, J. P., Ray, D., Bossaerts, P., & Camerer, C. (2013). In the mind of the

market: Theory of mind biases value computation during financial bubbles. Neuron, 79(6),

1222-1231.

Demirer, R., & Kutan, A. M. (2006). Does herding behavior exist in Chinese stock markets?

Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 16(2), 123-142.

Demirer, R., Gubo, D., & Kutan, A. M. (2007). An analysis of cross-country herd behavior in

stock markets: a regional perspective. Journal of International Financial Markets,

Institutions and Money, 3(1), 123-142.

Page 214: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

193

Demirer, R., Kutan, A. M., & Chen, C.-D. (2010). Do investors herd in emerging stock markets?:

Evidence from the Taiwanese market. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,

76(2), 283-295.

Demirer, R., Kutan, A. M., & Zhang, H. (2014). Do ADR investors herd?: Evidence from advanced

and emerging markets. International Review of Economics & Finance, 30, 138-148.

Di Quirico, R. (2010). Italy and the global economic crisis. Bulletin of Italian Politics, 2(2), 3-19.

Diebold, F. X., & Yilmaz, K. (2009). Measuring financial asset return and volatility spillovers,

with application to global equity markets*. The economic journal, 119(534), 158-171.

Duffee, G. R. (2001). Asymmetric cross-sectional dispersion in stock returns: evidence and

implications. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.

Duo, J., Fu–Ming, X., Xue–Ling, C., Teng–Fei, L., & Jun–Wei, Z. (2010). The Psychological

Mechanism and Influence Factors of Herd Behavior of Investors in the Capital Market.

Advances in Psychological Science, 18(05), 810-818.

Dutta, N., & Mukherjee, D. (2012). Is culture a determinant of financial development? Applied

Economics Letters, 19(6), 585-590.

Economou, F., Gavriilidis, K., Goyal, A., & Kallinterakis, V. (2015). Herding dynamics in

exchange groups: Evidence from Euronext. Journal of International Financial Markets,

Institutions and Money, 34, 228-244.

Economou, F., Kostakis, A., & Philippas, N. (2011). Cross-country effects in herding behavior:

Evidence from four south European markets. Journal of International Financial Markets,

Institutions, and Money, 21(3), 443-460.

Eichengreen, B., Rose, A. K., & Wyplosz, C. (1996). Contagious currency crises (No. w5681).

National bureau of economic research.

Page 215: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

194

Ellis, A. (1976). The biological basis of human irrationality. Journal of individual psychology,

32(2), 145.

Ellis, A. (1991). The revised ABC's of rational-emotive therapy (RET). Journal of rational-

emotive & cognitive-behavior therapy, 9(3), 139-172.

Etzioni, A. (1999). Normative-affective factors: Toward a new decision-making model Essays in

Socio-Economics (pp. 91-119): Springer.

Eun, C. S., Wang, L., & Xiao, S. C. (2015). Culture and R2. Journal of financial economics,

115(2), 283-303. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2014.09.003

Evans, J. S. B. (2003). In two minds: dual-process accounts of reasoning. Trends in cognitive

sciences, 7(10), 454-459.

Fakhry, B., Masood, O., & Bellalah, M. (2016). The Efficiency of the GIPS Sovereign Debt

Markets during Crisis. International Journal of Business, 21(1), 87.

Fakhry, B., & Richter, C. (2015). Is the sovereign debt market efficient? Evidence from the US

and German sovereign debt markets. International Economics and Economic Policy, 12(3),

339-357.

Fama, E. F. (1965). The Behavior of Stock-Market Prices. The Journal of Business, 38(1), 34-105.

doi: 10.2307/2350752

Fama, E. F. (1970). Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work*. The Journal

of Finance, 25(2), 383-417.

Fama, E. F. (1981). Stock returns, real activity, inflation, and money. The American Economic

Review, 545-565.

Fama, E. F. (1991). Efficient capital markets: II. The Journal of Finance, 46(5), 1575-1617.

Page 216: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

195

Fenzl, T., & Pelzmann, L. (2012). Psychological and social forces behind aggregate financial

market behavior. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 13(1), 56-65.

Ferris, S. P., Jayaraman, N., & Sabherwal, S. (2013). CEO overconfidence and international

merger and acquisition activity. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 48(01),

137-164.

Festinger, L. (1954). A theory of social comparison processes. Human relations, 7(2), 117-140.

Fischer, S. (1998). Reforming the International Monetary System. Draft paper prepared for the

David Finch Lecture, Melbourne, Australia, presented November 9.

Forbes, K. J., & Rigobon, R. (2002). No contagion, only interdependence: measuring stock market

co-movements. The Journal of Finance, 57(5), 2223-2261.

Frankel, J. A., & Rose, A. K. (1996). Currency crashes in emerging markets: An empirical

treatment. Journal of International Economics, 41(3), 351-366.

Froot, K. A., Scharfstein, D. S., & Stein, J. C. (1992). Herd on the street: Informational

inefficiencies in a market with short‐term speculation. The Journal of Finance, 47(4),

1461-1484.

Fuller, R. J. (1998). Behavioral finance and the sources of alpha. Journal of Pension Plan

Investing, 2(3), 291-293.

Garg, A., & Gulati, R. (2013). Do investors herd in the Indian market. Decision, 40(3), 181-196.

Gavriilidis, K., Kallinterakis, V., & Ferreira, M. P. L. (2013). Institutional industry herding:

Intentional or spurious? Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and

Money, 26, 192-214.

Page 217: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

196

Gervais, S., Heaton, J., & Odean, T. (2011). Overconfidence, compensation contracts, and capital

budgeting. The Journal of Finance, 66(5), 1735-1777.

Giordani, P., & Söderlind, P. (2003). Inflation forecast uncertainty. European economic review,

47(6), 1037-1059.

Gjerde, Ø., & Saettem, F. (1999). Causal relations among stock returns and macroeconomic

variables in a small, open economy. Journal of International Financial Markets,

Institutions and Money, 9(1), 61-74.

Glaser, M. , Nöth, M. and Weber, M. (2008). Behavioral Finance. In Blackwell Handbook of

Judgment and Decision Making (eds D. J. Koehler and N. Harvey).

doi:10.1002/9780470752937.ch26

Gleason, K. C., Mathur, I., & Peterson, M. A. (2004). Analysis of intraday herding behavior among

the sector ETFs. Journal of Empirical Finance, 11(5), 681-694.

Goldbaum, D. (2008). Coordinated investing with feedback and learning. Journal of Economic

Behavior & Organization, 65(2), 202-223.

Gong, P., & Dai, J. (2017). Monetary policy, exchange rate fluctuation, and herding behavior in

the stock market. Journal of Business Research, 76, 34-43. doi:

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2017.02.018

Graham, J. R. (1999). Herding among investment newsletters: Theory and evidence. The Journal

of Finance, 54(1), 237-268.

Graham, M., Kiviaho, J., & Nikkinen, J. (2012). Integration of 22 emerging stock markets: A three-

dimensional analysis. Global Finance Journal, 23(1), 34-47.

Page 218: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

197

Grinblatt, M., Titman, S., & Wermers, R. (1995). Momentum investment strategies, portfolio

performance, and herding: A study of mutual fund behavior. The American Economic

Review, 1088-1105.

Guiso, L., Jappelli, T., & Haliassos, M. (2000). Household portfolios: An international

comparison.

Guiso, L., Haliassos, M., & Jappelli, T, 2000. "Household Portfolios: An International

Comparison," CSEF Working Papers 48, Centre for Studies in Economics and Finance

(CSEF), University of Naples, Italy.

Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2009). Cultural biases in economic exchange? The

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(3), 1095-1131.

Gupta, M. C. (1974). Money Supply and Stock Prices: A Probabilistic Approach. Journal of

Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 9(01), 57-68.

Gutierrez, R. C., & Kelley, E. K. (2008). The Long‐Lasting Momentum in Weekly Returns. The

Journal of Finance, 63(1), 415-447.

Harlow, W., & Brown, K. C. (1990). Understanding and assessing financial risk tolerance: a

biological perspective. Financial Analysts Journal, 46(6), 50-62.

Hajilee, M., & Al Nasser, O. M. (2014). Exchange rate volatility and stock market development

in emerging economies. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 37(1), 163-180. doi:

10.2753/PKE0160-3477370110

Hakkio, C. S., & Keeton, W. R. (2009). Financial stress: what is it, how can it be measured, and

why does it matter? Economic Review-Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 94(2), 5.

Haugen, R. A. (2002). The Inefficient Stock Market: What Pays Off and why: Prentice Hall.

Page 219: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

198

Haugen, R. A., & Lakonishok, J. (1988). The incredible January effect: The stock market's

unsolved mystery: Business One Irwin.

Henker, J., Henker, T., & Mitsios, A. (2006). Do investors herd intraday in Australian equities?

International Journal of Managerial Finance, 2(3), 196-219.

Henrich, J., & Gil-White, F. J. (2001). The evolution of prestige: Freely conferred deference as a

mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evolution and human

behavior, 22(3), 165-196.

Hill, C. (2008). International Business: Competing in the global marketplace. Strategic Direction,

24(9).

Hirshleifer, D. (2015). Behavioral finance. Annual Review of Financial Economics, 7, 133-159.

Hirshleifer, D., & Hong Teoh, S. (2003). Herd behavior and cascading in capital markets: A review

and synthesis. European Financial Management, 9(1), 25-66.

HJ Reuter, C. (2011). A survey of ‘culture and finance'. Finance, 32(1), 75-152.

Hodgson, T. M., Breban, S. J., Ford, C. L., Streatfield, M. P., & Urwin, R. C. (2000). The concept

of investment efficiency and its application to investment management structures. British

Actuarial Journal, 6(3), 451-545.

Hofstede, G. (1991). Cultures and organizations-software of the mind: intercultural cooperation

and its importance for survival: McGraw-Hill.

Hofstede, G. (2001). Culture's Consequences: Comparing Values, Behaviors, Institutions and

Organizations Across Nations: SAGE Publications.

.Holmes, P., Kallinterakis, V., & Ferreira, M. (2013). Herding in a concentrated market: a question

of intent. European Financial Management, 19(3), 497-520.

Page 220: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

199

Hondroyiannis, G., & Papapetrou, E. (2001). Macroeconomic influences on the stock market.

Journal of Economics and Finance, 25(1), 33-49.

House, R. J., Hanges, P. J., Javidan, M., Dorfman, P. W., & Gupta, V. (2004). Culture, leadership,

and organizations: The GLOBE study of 62 societies: Sage publications.

Hung, M.-W., & Wang, J.-Y. (2005). Asset prices under prospect theory and habit formation.

Review of Pacific Basin Financial Markets and Policies, 8(01), 1-29.

Hsieh, M.-F., Yang, T.-Y., Yang, Y.-T., & Lee, J.-S. (2011). Evidence of herding and positive

feedback trading for mutual funds in emerging Asian countries. Quantitative Finance,

11(3), 423-435.

Huang, T.-C., Lin, B.-H., & Yang, T.-H. (2015). Herd behavior and idiosyncratic volatility.

Journal of Business Research, 68(4), 763-770.

Hwang, S., & Salmon, M. (2004). Market stress and herding. Journal of Empirical Finance, 11(4),

585-616.

Hyde, S., Bredin, D., & Nguyen, N. (2007). Chapter 3 Correlation dynamics between Asia-Pacific,

EU, and US stock returns Asia-Pacific Financial Markets: Integration, Innovation and

Challenges (pp. 39-61): Emerald Group Publishing Limited.

Ibrahim, M. H., & Aziz, H. (2003). Macroeconomic variables and the Malaysian equity market: A

view through rolling subsamples. Journal of economic studies, 30(1), 6-27.

Iihara, Y., Kato, H. K., & Tokunaga, T. (2001). Investors’ herding on the Tokyo stock exchange.

International Review of Finance, 2(1‐2), 71-98.

Ioannidis, C., & Kontonikas, A. (2006). Monetary policy and the stock market: some international

evidence. UK: University of Bath and University of Glasgow.

Page 221: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

200

Jacobs, B. I., & Levy, K. N. (1989). The complexity of the stock market. The Journal of Portfolio

Management, 16(1), 19-27. doi: 10.3905/jpm.1989.409244

James, M. (2002). Behavioral Finance. Insights into Irrational Minds and Markets. West Sussex,

England: John Wiley & Sons.

Javaira, Z., & Hassan, A. (2015). An examination of herding behavior in Pakistani stock market.

International Journal of Emerging Markets, 10(3), 474-490.

Javed, T., Zafar, N., & Hafeez, B. (2013). Herding behavior in Karachi Stock Exchange.

International Journal of Management Sciences and Business Research, 2, 2226-8235.

Jayasuriya, S., & Leu, S. (2017). Volatile Capital Flows and Macroeconomic Performance in

Indonesia: An SVAR Analysis. Economic Papers: A journal of applied economics and

policy, 36(2), 135-155.

Jiranyakul, K., & Brahmasrene, T. (2007). The relationship between government expenditures and

economic growth in Thailand. Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research,

8(1), 93.

Jong, E. d., & Semenov, R. (2002). Cross-country differences in stock market development: a

cultural view: University of Groningen, Research Institute SOM (Systems, Organisations,

and Management).

Jurist, E. L. (2010). Mentalizing minds. Psychoanalytic Inquiry, 30(4), 289-300.

Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. The

American economic review, 93(5), 1449-1475.

Kahneman, D., & Riepe, M. W. (1998). Aspects of investor psychology. The Journal of Portfolio

Management, 24(4), 52-65.

Page 222: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

201

Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk.

Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 263-291.

Kalbaska, A., & Gątkowski, M. (2012). Eurozone sovereign contagion: Evidence from the CDS

market (2005–2010). Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 83(3), 657-673.

Kaminsky, G. L., & Reinhart, C. M. (2000). On crises, contagion, and confucian. Journal of

International Economics, 51(1), 145-168.

Kapusuzoglu, A. (2011). Herding in the Istanbul Stock Exchange (ISE): A case of behavioral

finance. African Journal of Business Management, 5(27), 11210-11218.

Kendall, M. G., & Hill, A. B. (1953). The analysis of economic time-series-part i: Prices. Journal

of the Royal Statistical Society. Series A (General), 116(1), 11-34.

Keran, M. W. (1971). Expectations, money, and the stock market: Research Department [of the]

Federal Reserve Bank.

Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory. London, New York.

Khan, H., Hassairi, S. A., & Viviani, J.-L. (2011). Herd behavior and market stress: The case of

four European countries. International Business Research, 4(3), 53.

Khan, S., & Park, K. W. K. (2009). Contagion in the stock markets: The Asian financial crisis

revisited. Journal of Asian Economics, 20(5), 561-569.

Khresna Brahmana, R., Hooy, C.-W., & Ahmad, Z. (2012). Psychological factors on irrational

financial decision making: Case of day-of-the week anomaly. Humanomics, 28(4), 236-

257.

Kim, J. H., & Shamsuddin, A. (2008). Are Asian stock markets efficient? Evidence from new

multiple variance ratio tests. Journal of Empirical Finance, 15(3), 518-532.

Page 223: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

202

Kim, J. H., Shamsuddin, A., & Lim, K.-P. (2011). Stock return predictability and the adaptive

markets hypothesis: Evidence from century-long US data. Journal of Empirical Finance,

18(5), 868-879.

Kim, K. A., & Nofsinger, J. R. (2007). The behavior of Japanese individual investors during bull

and bear markets. The Journal of Behavioral Finance, 8(3), 138-153.

Kim, W., & Wei, S.-J. (2002). Foreign portfolio investors before and during a crisis. Journal of

International Economics, 56(1), 77-96.

Kirkman, B. L., Chen, G., Farh, J.-L., Chen, Z. X., & Lowe, K. B. (2009). Individual power

distance orientation and follower reactions to transformational leaders: A cross-level,

cross-cultural examination. Academy of Management Journal, 52(4), 744-764.

Klein, A. C. (2013). Time-variations in herding behavior: Evidence from a Markov switching SUR

model. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions, and Money, 26, 291-304.

Kliger, D., & Kudryavtsev, A. (2008). Reference point formation by market investors. Journal of

Banking & Finance, 32(9), 1782-1794.

Knight, F. H. (2012). Risk, uncertainty, and profit: Courier Corporation.

Kodres, L. E., & Pritsker, M. (2002). A rational expectations model of financial contagion. The

Journal of Finance, 57(2), 769-799.

Kroeber, A. L., & Kluckhohn, C. (1952). Culture: A critical review of concepts and definitions.

Papers. Peabody Museum of Archaeology & Ethnology, Harvard University.

Kyle, A. S., & Xiong, W. (2001). Contagion as a wealth effect. The Journal of Finance, 56(4),

1401-1440.

Page 224: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

203

Lakonishok, J., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1992). The impact of institutional trading on stock

prices. Journal of financial economics, 32(1), 23-43.

Lao, P., & Singh, H. (2011). Herding behavior in the Chinese and Indian stock markets. Journal

of Asian Economics, 22(6), 495-506.

Lee, C.-C., Lee, J.-D., & Lee, C.-C. (2010). Stock prices and the efficient market hypothesis:

Evidence from a panel stationary test with structural breaks. Japan and the world economy,

22(1), 49-58.

Lee, Y.-H., Liao, T.-H., & Hsu, C.-M. (2015). The Impact of Macroeconomic Factors on the

Herding Behaviour of Investors. Asian Economic and Financial Review, 5(2), 295-304.

Li, D. D., & Yung, K. (2004). Institutional herding in the ADR market. Review of Quantitative

Finance and Accounting, 23(1), 5-17.

Li, W., Rhee, G., & Wang, S. S. Differences in herding: Individual vs. institutional investors.

Pacific-Basin Finance Journal. doi: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.pacfin.2016.11.005

Lin, C.-H. (2012). The comovement between exchange rates and stock prices in the Asian

emerging markets. International Review of Economics & Finance, 22(1), 161-172.

Lin, W.-L., Engle, R. F., & Ito, T. (1994). Do bulls and bears move across borders? International

transmission of stock returns and volatility. Review of financial studies, 7(3), 507-538.

Lo, A. (2005). Reconciling Efficient Market Hypothesis with Behavioral Finance: The adaptive

Markets Hypothesis. Journal of Financial & Quantitative Analysis, 39, 142-184.

Lo, A. W. (2004). The adaptive markets hypothesis. The Journal of Portfolio Management, 30(5),

15-29.

Page 225: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

204

Lo, A. W., & Hasanhodzic, J. (2011). The evolution of technical analysis: financial prediction

from Babylonian tablets to Bloomberg terminals (Vol. 139): John Wiley & Sons.

Lobao, J., & Serra, A. P. (2002). Herding behavior evidence from Portuguese mutual funds.

Unpublished Working Paper. Instituto de Estudos Financieros e Fiscais, Portugal.

Loisel, O., Pommeret, A., & Portier, F. (2012a). Monetary Policy and Herd Behavior: Leaning

Against Bubbles: Banque de France. Working Paper No. 412.

http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2192466

Losin, E. A. R., Dapretto, M., & Iacoboni, M. (2009). Culture in the mind's mirror: how

anthropology and neuroscience can inform a model of the neural substrate for cultural

imitative learning. Progress in brain research, 178, 175-190.

Longstaff, F. A. (2010). The subprime credit crisis and contagion in financial markets. Journal of

financial economics, 97(3), 436-450.

Longin, F., Solnik, B. (2001). Extreme correlation of international equity markets? Journal of

Finance, 56 (2), 649–676.

Lucas, R. E. (1978). Asset Prices in an Exchange Economy. Econometrica, 46(6), 1429-1445. doi:

10.2307/1913837.

Ludwig, A. (2014). A unified approach to investigate pure and wake-up-call contagion: Evidence

from the Eurozone's first financial crisis. Journal of International Money and Finance, 48,

125-146.

Lusardi, A., & Mitchell, O. S. (2008). Planning and financial literacy: How do women fare? :

National Bureau of Economic Research.

Lux, T. (1995). Herd behavior, bubbles, and crashes. The economic journal, 881-896.

Page 226: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

205

Malik, S. U., & Elahi, M. A. (2014). Analysis of Herd Behavior Using Quantile Regression:

Evidence from Karachi Stock Exchange (KSE) (No. 55322). University Library of Munich,

Germany.

Malkiel, B. G. (2003). The efficient market hypothesis and its critics. Journal of economic

perspectives, 59-82.

Malinowski, B. (1922). Argonauts of the Western Pacific. New York: EP Dutton & Co.

MANAGEMENT REPORT, 2224.

Malinowski, B. (1950). Argonauts of the Western Pacific: An Account of Native Enterprise and

Adventure in the Archipelagoes of Melanesian New Guinea, by Bronislaw Malinowski...

with a Preface by Sir James George Frazer... With 5 Maps, 65 Illustrations, and 2 Figures:

Routledge & K. Paul.

Mandal, A. (2011). Empirical Study of Herd Behavior: The National Stock Exchange, India.

International Journal of Financial Management, 1(3), 1.

Mandlebrot, B. (2001). Scaling in financial prices: Multifractals and the star equation. Quantitative

Finance, 1, 124-130.

Markus, H. R., & Kitayama, S. (1991). Culture and the self: Implications for cognition, emotion,

and motivation. Psychological Review, 98(2), 224.

Maskay, B. (2007). Analyzing the effect of a change in Money supply on stock prices. The park

place economist, 15(1), 72-79.

Masson, P. (1999). Contagion:: macroeconomic models with multiple equilibria. Journal of

International Money and Finance, 18(4), 587-602.

McKinnon, R. I., & Pill, H. (1997). Credible economic liberalizations and overborrowing. The

American Economic Review, 87(2), 189-193.

Page 227: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

206

McMillan, D. G., & Speight, A. E. (2010). Return and volatility spillovers in three euro exchange

rates. Journal of Economics and Business, 62(2), 79-93.

McSweeney, B. (2002). Hofstede’s model of national cultural differences and their consequences:

A triumph of faith-a failure of analysis. Human relations, 55(1), 89-118.

Metiu, N. (2012). Sovereign risk contagion in the Eurozone. Economics Letters, 117(1), 35-38.

Messis, P., & Zapranis, A. (2014a). Herding behavior and volatility in the Athens Stock Exchange.

The Journal of Risk Finance, 15(5), 572-590.

Messis, P., & Zapranis, A. (2014b). Herding towards higher moment CAPM, contagion of herding

and macroeconomic shocks: Evidence from five major developed markets. Journal of

Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 4, 1-13.

Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and

ceremony. American journal of sociology, 83(2), 340-363.

Mink, M., & De Haan, J. (2013). Contagion during the Greek sovereign debt crisis. Journal of

International Money and Finance, 34, 102-113.

Minkov, M. (2009). Predictors of differences in subjective well-being across 97 nations. Cross-

Cultural Research, 43(2), 152-179.

Mishkin, F. S., & Eakins, S. G. (2006). Financial Markets and Institutions: Pearson Education.

Mishra, P. (2011). Weak form market efficiency: evidence from emerging and developed world.

The Journal of Commerce, 3(2), 26.

Mitroi, A., & Oproiu, A. (2014). Behavioral finance: new research trends, socionomics and

investor emotions. Theoretical and applied economics, 18(4), 593.

Page 228: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

207

Mobarek, A., Mollah, S., & Keasey, K. (2014). A cross-country analysis of herd behavior in

Europe. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 32, 107-127.

Mondria, J. (2006). Evidence of financial contagion through attention reallocation: Working Paper

available at http://individual. utoronto. ca/jmondria.

Mondria, J., & Quintana‐Domeque, C. (2013). Financial contagion and attention allocation. The

Economic Journal, 123(568), 429-454.

Montgomery, J. D. (1991). Social networks and labor-market outcomes: Toward an economic

analysis. The American economic review, 81(5), 1408-1418.

Morck, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1990). Do managerial objectives drive bad acquisitions?

The Journal of Finance, 45(1), 31-48.

Moser, T. (2003). What is international financial contagion? International Finance, 6(2), 157-178.

Murphy, A. (2012). Biology-induced effects on investor psychology and behavior. International

Review of Financial Analysis, 24, 20-25.

Mylonidis, N., & Kollias, C. (2010). Dynamic European stock market convergence: Evidence from

rolling cointegration analysis in the first euro-decade. Journal of Banking & Finance,

34(9), 2056-2064.

Nelson, D. B. (1991). Conditional Heteroskedasticity in Asset Returns: A New Approach.

Econometrica, 59(2), 347-370. doi: 10.2307/2938260

Ng, A. (2000). Volatility spillover effects from Japan and the US to the Pacific–Basin. Journal of

International Money and Finance, 19(2), 207-233.

Niederhoffer, V., & Osborne, M. F. M. (1966). Market making and reversal on the stock exchange.

Journal of the American Statistical Association, 61(316), 897-916.

Page 229: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

208

Nisbett, R. E., Peng, K., Choi, I., & Norenzayan, A. (2001). Culture and systems of thought:

holistic versus analytic cognition. Psychological Review, 108(2), 291.

Nofsinger, J. R., & Sias, R. W. (1999). Herding and feedback trading by institutional and

individual investors. The Journal of Finance, 54(6), 2263-2295.

Obstfeld, M. (1986). How integrated are world capital markets? Some new tests: National Bureau

of Economic Research Cambridge, Mass., USA.

Odean, T. (1998). Do investors trade too much? Available at SSRN 94143.

Offermann, L. R., & Hellmann, P. S. (1997). Culture's consequences for leadership behavior:

National values in action. Journal of cross-cultural psychology, 28(3), 342-351.

Palan, S. (2004). The efficient market hypothesis and its validity in today's markets. Master thesis.

Graz: Faculty of Social and Economic Sciences, Karl-Franzens University, Graz.

Park, A., & Sabourian, H. (2011). Herding and contrarian behavior in financial markets.

Econometrica, 79(4), 973-1026.

Parker, W. D., & Prechter, R. R. (2005). Herding: An interdisciplinary integrative review from a

socioeconomic perspective. Available at SSRN 2009898.

Patro, A., & Kanagaraj, A. (2012). Exploring the herding behavior in Indian mutual fund industry.

Asian Journal of Finance & Accounting, 4(1), 189-204.

Pearce, D. K., & Roley, V. V. (1985). Stock prices and economic news: National Bureau of

Economic Research Cambridge, Mass., USA.

Penny, W. D., Stephan, K. E., Mechelli, A., & Friston, K. J. (2004). Comparing dynamic causal

models. Neuroimage, 22(3), 1157-1172.

Page 230: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

209

Pericoli, M., & Sbracia, M. (2003). A primer on financial contagion. Journal of Economic Surveys,

17(4), 571-608.

Persaud, A. (2000). Sending the herd off the cliff edge: the disturbing interaction between herding

and market-sensitive risk management practices. The Journal of Risk Finance, 2(1), 59-65.

Philippas, N., Economou, F., Babalos, V., & Kostakis, A. (2013). Herding behavior in REITs:

Novel tests and the role of financial crisis. Internastional Review of Financial Analysis, 29,

166-174.

Pingle, M. (1995). Imitation versus rationality: An experimental perspective on decision making.

The Journal of Socio-Economics, 24(2), 281-315.

Prieto, E., Eickmeier, S., & Marcellino, M. (2016). Time Variation in Macro-Financial Linkages.

Journal of Applied Econometrics, 31(7), 1215-1233. doi: 10.1002/jae.2499

Prosad, J. M., Kapoor, S., & Sengupta, J. (2012). An examination of herd behavior: An empirical

evidence from Indian equity market. International Journal of Trade, Economics and

Finance, 3(2), 154-157.

Poletti, M., Enrici, I., & Adenzato, M. (2012). Cognitive and affective Theory of Mind in

neurodegenerative diseases: neuropsychological, neuroanatomical and neurochemical

levels. Neuroscience & Biobehavioral Reviews, 36(9), 2147-2164.

Pompian, M. M. (2012). Behavioral finance and investor types: managing behavior to make better

investment decisions: John Wiley & Sons.

Purba, A.V., Faradynawati, I. A. A. (2011). An Examination of Herd Behavior in The Indonesian

Stock Market. International Conference on Business and Management Research.

Page 231: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

210

Ramchand, L., & Susmel, R. (1998). Variances and covariances of international stock returns: The

international capital asset pricing model revisited. Journal of International Financial

Markets, Institutions and Money, 8(1), 39-57.

Rendleman, R. J., Jones, C. P., & Latane, H. A. (1982). Empirical anomalies based on unexpected

earnings and the importance of risk adjustments. Journal of financial economics, 10(3),

269-287.

Ritter, J. R. (2003). Behavioral finance. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 11(4), 429-437.

Rigobon, R., & Sack, B. (2008). Noisy macroeconomic announcements, monetary policy, and

asset prices. In Asset prices and monetary policy (pp. 335-370). University of Chicago

Press.

Ross, S. A. (1976). The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal of Economic Theory,

13(3), 341-360.

Rozeff, M. S., & Kinney, W. R. (1976). Capital market seasonality: The case of stock returns.

Journal of financial economics, 3(4), 379-402.

Rua, A., & Nunes, L. C. (2009). International comovement of stock market returns: A wavelet

analysis. Journal of Empirical Finance, 16(4), 632-639.

Samuel Craig, C., & Douglas, S. P. (2006). Beyond national culture: implications of cultural

dynamics for consumer research. International Marketing Review, 23(3), 322-342.

Samuelson, P. A. (1965). Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly. Industrial

management review, 6(2), 41-49.

Sapienza, P., Zingales, L., & Guiso, L. (2006). Does culture affect economic outcomes? : National

Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 232: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

211

Scharfstein, D. S., & Stein, J. C. (1990). Herd behavior and investment. The American Economic

Review, 465-479.

Schindler, M. (2007). Rumors in financial markets: Insights into behavioral finance (Vol. 413):

John Wiley & Sons.

Schlinger, H. D. (2009). Theory of mind: An overview and behavioral perspective. The

Psychological Record, 59(3), 435.

Schmeling, M. (2009). Investor sentiment and stock returns: Some international evidence. Journal

of Empirical Finance, 16(3), 394-408.

Scholes, M. S. (1970). A test of the competitive market hypothesis: the market for new issues and

secondary offerings. University of Chicago.

Schwartz, S. H. (1994). Are there universal aspects in the structure and contents of human values?

Journal of social issues, 50(4), 19-45.

Schwartz, S. H. (1998). Rationality gone awry. Decision making inconsistent with economic and

financial theory, 28-31.

Sentana, E., & Wadhwani, S. (1992). Feedback traders and stock return autocorrelations: evidence

from a century of daily data. The economic journal, 415-425.

Sewell Jr, W. H. (2005). Logics of history: Social theory and social transformation: University of

Chicago Press.

Sewell, M. (2007). Behavioural finance. University of Cambridge.

Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. The Quarterly Journal of Economics,

69(1), 99-118.

Page 233: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

212

Sharpe, W. F. (1964). Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of

risk*. The Journal of Finance, 19(3), 425-442.

Shefrin, H. (2000). Beyond greed and fear: Understanding behavioral finance and the psychology

of investing: Oxford University Press.

Shefrin, H. (2007). Behavioral finance: biases, mean-variance returns, and risk premiums. Paper

presented at the CFA Institute Conference Proceedings Quarterly.

Shiller, R. J. (1990). Speculative prices and popular models. The Journal of Economic

Perspectives, 55-65.

Shiller, R. J. (1999). Human behavior and the efficiency of the financial system. Handbook of

macroeconomics, 1, 1305-1340.

Shleifer, A. (2000). Inefficient markets: An introduction to behavioral finance: Oxford university

press.

Shleifer, A., & Summers, L. H. (1990). The noise trader approach to finance. The Journal of

Economic Perspectives, 19-33.

Sias, R. W. (2004). Institutional herding. Review of financial studies, 17(1), 165-206.

Sinke, J. (2012), “Investor Sentiment and Stock Returns: A Cultural and International View”,

Master Thesis in Finance, Tilburg University

Solakoglu, M. N., & Demir, N. (2014). Sentimental herding in Borsa Istanbul: informed versus

uninformed. Applied Economics Letters, 21(14), 965-968. doi:

10.1080/13504851.2014.902015

Spyrou, S. (2013). Herding in financial markets: a review of the literature. Review of Behavioral

Finance, 5(2), 175-194.

Page 234: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

213

Statman, M., Fisher, K. L., & Anginer, D. (2008). Affect in a behavioral asset-pricing model.

Financial Analysts Journal, 64(2), 20-29.

Statman, M. (2008). Countries and culture in behavioral finance. Paper presented at the CFA

Institute Conference Proceedings Quarterly.

Stiglitz, J. E., & Furman, J. (1998). Economic crises: evidence and insights from East Asia.

Brookings papers on economic activity, 1(2), 1-114.

Stulz, R. M., & Williamson, R. (2003). Culture, openness, and finance. Journal of financial

economics, 70(3), 313-349.

Subrahmanyam, A. (2008). Behavioural finance: A review and synthesis. European Financial

Management, 14(1), 12-29.

Suto, M., & Toshino, M. (2005). Behavioural biases of Japanese institutional investors: Fund

management and corporate governance. Corporate Governance: An International Review,

13(4), 466-477.

Sweeney, R. J. (1988). Some new filter rule tests: Methods and results. Journal of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis, 23(03), 285-300.

Tan, L., Chiang, T. C., Mason, J. R., & Nelling, E. (2008). Herding behavior in Chinese stock

markets: An examination of A and B shares. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 16(1), 61-77.

Taylor, S. J. (1982). Tests of the random walk hypothesis against a price-trend hypothesis. Journal

of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 17(01), 37-61.

Teng, Y.-P., & Liu, Y. A. (2014). The study of herding behavior among the Greater China Stock

Markets during Financial Crisis. Journal of Interdisciplinary Mathematics, 17(2), 163-197.

Page 235: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

214

Thaler, R. H. (1999). Mental accounting matters. Journal of Behavioral decision making, 12(3),

183-206.

Thaler, R. H. (2010). The end of behavioral finance.

Thompson, R. (1978). The information content of discounts and premiums on closed-end fund

shares. Journal of financial economics, 6(2), 151-186.

Timmermann, A., & Granger, C. W. (2004). Efficient market hypothesis and forecasting.

International Journal of forecasting, 20(1), 15-27.

Trueman, B. (1994). Analyst forecasts and herding behavior. Review of financial studies, 7(1), 97-

124.

Tsai, I.-C. (2012). The relationship between stock price index and exchange rate in Asian markets:

A quantile regression approach. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions

and Money, 22(3), 609-621.

Tsay, R. S. (1988). Outliers, level shifts, and variance changes in time series. Journal of

forecasting, 7(1), 1-20.

Tuyon, J., & Ahmad, Z. (2016). Behavioural finance perspectives on Malaysian stock market

efficiency. Borsa Istanbul Review, 16(1), 43-61.

Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1981). The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice.

Science, 211(4481), 453-458.

Voronkova, S., & Bohl, M. T. (2005). Institutional traders’ behavior in an emerging stock market:

Empirical evidence on polish pension fund investors. Journal of Business Finance &

Accounting, 32(7‐8), 1537-1560.

Page 236: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

215

Wasserfallen, W. (1989). Macroeconomics news and the stock market: evidence from Europe.

Journal of Banking & Finance, 13(4), 613-626.

Wärneryd, K. Stock-market Psychology: How People Value and Trade Stocks,(2001):

Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

Weber, M. (1962). Basic Concepts in Sociology. Translated and with an introduction by HP

Secher. New York: Philosophical Library.

Welch, I. (2000). Herding among security analysts. Journal of financial economics, 58(3), 369-

396.

Wermers, R. (1999). Mutual Fund Herding and the Impact on Stock Prices. The Journal of

Finance, 54(2), 581-622. doi: 10.1111/0022-1082.00118

Whaley, R. E. (2009). Understanding the VIX. The Journal of Portfolio Management, 35(3), 98-

105.

Wilson, E. J., & Marashdeh, H. A. (2007). Are Co‐integrated Stock Prices Consistent with the

Efficient Market Hypothesis? Economic Record, 83(s1), S87-S93. doi: doi:10.1111/j.1475-

4932.2007.00409.x

Yang, W.-R., & Chen, Y.-L. (2015). The response of dynamic herd behavior to domestic and US

market factors: Evidence from the greater china stock markets. Emerging Markets Finance

and Trade, 51(sup1), S18-S41.

Yao, J., Ma, C., & He, W. P. (2014). Investor herding behaviour of Chinese stock market.

International Review of Economics & Finance, 29, 12-29.

Yen, G., & Lee, C.-f. (2008). Efficient market hypothesis (EMH): past, present and future. Review

of Pacific Basin Financial Markets and Policies, 11(02), 305-329.

Page 237: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

216

Yuan, K. (2005). Asymmetric price movements and borrowing constraints: A rational expectations

equilibrium model of crises, contagion, and confucian. The Journal of Finance, 60(1), 379-

411.

Zhou, J., & Anderson, R. I. (2013). An empirical investigation of herding behavior in the US REIT

market. The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 47(1), 83-108.

Zwiebel, J. (1995). Corporate conservatism and relative compensation. Journal of political

Economy, 103(1), 1-25.

Page 238: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

217

Appendix 1

Table 1: List of Biases

Cognitive Bias Description

Overconfidence bias Excessive confidence in one's own answers to questions. For example, for certain

types of question, answers that people rate as "99% certain" turn out to be wrong

40% of the time.

Representative Bias According to this bias people identify common component in entirely different event

by fitting a completely unknown and new one event to the current. Tversky and

Kahneman (1974) argued that individuals usually judge probabilities “by the degree

to which A is representative of B, that is, by the degree to which A resembles B.”

Anchoring and

Adjustment bias

While making estimates to find resulting answers, people usually hooked up in an

initial state. (Slovic, & Lichtenstein, 1971).

Cognitive

dissonance bias

When newly acquired information conflicts with preexisting understandings, people

often experience mental discomfort—a psychological phenomenon known as

cognitive dissonance.

Availability Bias Estimating what is more likely by what is more available in memory, which is biased

toward vivid, unusual, or emotionally charged examples.

Self-attribution bias Self-attribution bias refers to the tendency of individuals to ascribe their successes

to innate aspects, such as talent or foresight, while more often blaming failures on

outside influences, such as bad luck.

Page 239: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

218

Illusion of control

bias

People not only overestimate others' ability to know themselves but also

overestimate their ability to judge others.

Ambiguity Aversion

Bias

The tendency to avoid options for which missing information makes the probability

seems "unknown".

Gambler Fallacy

bias

Gambler fallacy is a false impression of the precision of the law of chance (Tversky

and Kahneman, 1971). It occurs when an investor wrongly forecast the reversal in

stock prices and trade in a market with an expectation that random event are self-

correcting.

Self-control bias The ability to restrain emotions and impulses; choosing to stick to one’s plans. It

can be depleted with use but increased over time.

Excessive Optimism

bias

Excessive optimism refers to the inclination of people to prefer the probability of

occurrence of favorable outcomes to that of unfavorable outcomes.

Mental accounting

bias

Mental accounting is the tendency of keeping separate accounts by the people on

different subjective motives, often has an irrational and negative effect on

consumption decision and other behaviors (Thaler, 1999)

Confirmation bias The tendency of interpreting and searching information in a way that is in

confirmation with one's preconceptions.

Page 240: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

219

Hindsight bias Shiller (2000) explains this bias as a tendency of a person to overestimate their

ability to have predicted an outcome before it actually happened. Therefore, it is a

psychological fact in which past events seem to be more prominent than they

appeared while they were occurring.

Recency bias It is the tendency by which an individual weigh recent events more than previous

events.

Framing bias Using an approach or description of the situation or Framing issue that is too

narrow. Also, drawing different conclusions based on how data is presented

Disposition effect The tendency to selling overvalued assets and buying assets that are undervalued.

Professors Shefrin and Statman (1985) developed the idea of loss aversion into a

theory called the ‘disposition effect’, which indicates that individuals tend to sell

winners and hold losers.

Herding effect Herding behavior is a tendency where an investor simply imitates the action of

others.

Page 241: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

220

Appendix 2

Table 2: Industry Classification based on Industrial classification bench mark

Industries Sub sectors

Oil & Gas 5

Basic Materials 12

Industrials 21

Consumer Goods 19

Health Care 5

Consumer Services 16

Telecommunications 2

Utilities 5

Financials 39

Technology 7

Page 242: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

221

Appendix 3

Table 3: List of variables and their description

Variables Abbreviations Description

Cross sectional standard

deviation of returns

CSSD CSSD is standard measure of dispersion

Cross sectional absolute

deviation of returns

CSAD CSADt is absolute measures of return dispersion

Industry returns Ri,t Ri,t is the observed return on industry index i for day t

Market returns Rm,t Rm,t is cross-sectional average of the number of returns in the

aggregate market portfolio for day t.

Cross sectional Standard

deviation of betas 𝑆𝑡𝑑𝑐(𝛽𝑖𝑚𝑡

𝑏 ) Stdc(Bimt) is a standard measure of beta dispersion.

Volatility �̂�𝑡2 �̂�𝑡

2 is a measure of volatility, the conditional variance based on

asymmetric GARCH(1,1)

Global Volatility index VIXt-1 Lagged value of CBOE global implied volatility Index

Individualism index, IDVi IDV is the tendency by which the people are not closely connected

and are more concerned about themselves or their families.

masculinity index, MASi, MAS index define the clear difference between gender roles.

uncertainty avoidance

index,

UAIi UAI is the level of threat perceived during an uncertain or unknown

situation.

power distance index PDIi, PDI describe the unequal power distribution in an organizations.

Long-term orientation LTOi LTO defines the virtues by which promote and encourage the search

of future returns orientation.

Indulgence Index IVRi IVR refers to the situation how individuals have control over their

desires.

Exchange Rate ER ER is the measure of exchange rate shocks at time t.

Money supply MS MS is the money supply in a given country at a given time period t.

Interest rates i Short term rates in a given economy at time t.

Industrial production IP IP is the industrial production index of a country at time t

Page 243: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

222

Appendix 4

Table 4: Correlation between herding measure Hmt

Panel A: Developed Markets

Code AU OE BG DK FR BD GR HK IT JP NL NZ NW PT SG ES SD SW UK US

AU 1

OE -0.68** 1

BG -0.44** 0.22** 1

DK -0.45** 0.46** 0.58 1

FR -0.74** 0.65** 0.62** 0.64** 1

BD -0.72** 0.64** 0.53** 0.52** 0.81** 1

GR -0.19** 0.44** 0.061 0.26** 0.00 0.085 1

HK -0.71** 0.91** 0.14 0.34** 0.56** 0.60** 0.44** 1

IT -0.58** 0.61** 0.45** 0.63** 0.82** 0.64** 0.03 0.49** 1

JP -0.34** 0.12 0.21** 0.19** 0.05 0.21** 0.54** 0.17* 0.01 1

NL 0.067 0.15* 0.16** 0.28** 0.39** 0.20** -0.39** 0.02 0.56** -0.52** 1

NZ 0.69** -0.68** -0.13** -0.20** -0.42** -0.41** -0.37** -0.68** -0.32** -0.24** 0.27** 1

NW -0.65** 0.73** 0.35** 0.37** 0.77** 0.75** -0.03 0.68** 0.66** -0.03 0.40** -0.37** 1

PT 0.28** -0.2** 0.072 0.17* -0.32** -0.28** 0.50** -0.13 -0.21** 0.26** -0.25** 0.11 -

0.60** 1

SG 0.10 0.26** 0.23** 0.17* 0.18* 0.17* -0.02 0.18* 0.26** -0.33** 0.62** 0.08 0.42** -0.14* 1

ES -0.65** 0.65** 0.44** 0.53** 0.85** 0.76** 0.06 0.53** 0.76** 0.14** 0.42** -0.27** 0.85** -0.43** 0.22** 1

SD -0.77** 0.79** 0.32** 0.46** 0.67** 0.78** 0.41** 0.80** 0.53** 0.38** -0.02 -0.55** 0.75** -0.20** 0.15* 0.71** 1

SW -0.98** 0.70** 0.43** 0.45** 0.78** 0.73** 0.18** 0.73** 0.61** 0.31** -0.03 -0.68** 0.67** -0.30** -0.12 0.68** 0.78** 1

UK -0.64** 0.39** 0.78** 0.67** 0.79** 0.66** 0.02* 0.30** 0.65** 0.28** 0.20** -0.20** 0.47** -0.03 -0.01 0.66** 0.44** 0.64** 1

US -0.75** 0.53** 0.65** 0.59** 0.79** 0.74** 0.01 0.43** 0.67** 0.27** 0.21** -0.30** 0.60** -0.19** 0.00 0.74** 0.60** 0.74** 0.88** 1

** indicate significance at 5%, * indicate significance at 1%

Page 244: prr.hec.gov.pkprr.hec.gov.pk/jspui/bitstream/123456789/9496/1/Zuee Javaira.pdf · ii ROLE OF CULTURE AND MACROECONOMIC SHOCKS IN DRIVING HERDING BEHAVIOR: EVIDENCE FROM DEVELOPED,

223

Appendix 4 (Continued…)

Panel B: Emerging and Developed Markets

Probability CA IN ID KO MY PK PH CY TA TH TK US

CA 1

IN 0.07 1

ID -0.03 -0.20** 1

KO 0.03 -0.02 0.22** 1

MY 0.25** 0.25** 0.08 0.12 1

PK 0.30** 0.41** -0.38** -0.06 0.34** 1

PH 0.12 0.12** -0.20** -0.32** -0.06 0.48** 1

CY 0.06 -0.06 0.07 0.06 0.12 -0.11 -0.29** 1

TA 0.31** 0.20** -0.05 -0.08 0.12 0.28** 0.28** -0.1 1

TH -0.12 0.24** 0.04 -0.03 0.01 0.08 0.27** 0.06 0.17* 1

TK 0.27** 0.16* -0.06 0.11 0.14* 0.40** -0.11 0.20** 0.04 0.03 1

US 0.16* 0.52** -0.44** -0.19** 0.14* 0.34** 0.34** -0.19** 0.26** 0.31** -0.17* 1

** indicate significance at 5%, * indicate significance at 1%